24.01.2015 Views

Disincentivising overbidding for toll road concessions

Disincentivising overbidding for toll road concessions

Disincentivising overbidding for toll road concessions

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

3 │ TOLL ROAD CASE STUDIES<br />

Discussion<br />

The intellectual appeal of flexible-term <strong>concessions</strong>, and the LPVR approach specifically, is perhaps stronger than<br />

their applicability. 97 They commonly incorporate asymmetries, which the private sector dislikes—<strong>for</strong> example, the buyout<br />

call option which a government can exercise is not accompanied by a put option allowing the private sector to sell<br />

the concession. Other parties, particularly equity providers, may be troubled by possible limited upside potential and<br />

may have reservations about entering into a business where operating efficiency improvements do not translate into<br />

higher rates of return. In addition, the fact that LPVR <strong>concessions</strong> are usually bounded by an absolute maximum term<br />

(duration cap) means that, by term end, it may be possible that concessionaires with underper<strong>for</strong>ming assets will<br />

remain loss-making.<br />

Various authors have suggested enhancements to address this latter asymmetry. 98 Typical solutions include the<br />

specification of a minimum concession term or—less politically palatable—having unlimited term extensions. Neither<br />

of these approaches appears to have enjoyed widespread acceptability. Other researchers have proposed the use<br />

of least present value of net revenues to take account of the existence of fixed operations and maintenance (O&M)<br />

costs in <strong>toll</strong> <strong>road</strong> operations. 99 However, this, too, remains conceptual. This international review of concession<br />

mechanisms demonstrates that flexible-term <strong>concessions</strong> generally remain a minority application. That said, they<br />

merit consideration if only as an example of a different approach to the twin issues of demand uncertainty and<br />

<strong>overbidding</strong>.<br />

On the other hand, flexible-term <strong>concessions</strong> (such as those based on the LPVR) are more likely to appeal to debt<br />

providers, as the attractive bond pricing on some Chilean <strong>toll</strong> <strong>road</strong> deals suggests. Concession grantors may also<br />

warm to this approach since it makes no direct call on government finances and places no upward pressure on<br />

<strong>toll</strong> tariffs. Grantors can adjust tariffs (within reason) to reflect b<strong>road</strong>er pricing policy objectives and, in terms of<br />

aggregate revenue receipts, concessionaires will not be affected. The role of such mechanisms in limiting the<br />

incentives <strong>for</strong> contract renegotiation is proven, especially in host jurisdictions with a propensity to renegotiate. A<br />

recession in Chile prompted widespread contractual renegotiations <strong>for</strong> <strong>toll</strong> <strong>road</strong> <strong>concessions</strong>; the only contracts not<br />

renegotiated were those based on the LPVR mechanism. By reducing renegotiating expectations, bidders have less<br />

incentive to inflate their <strong>for</strong>ecast from the outset.<br />

3.4 Construct-then-concession<br />

At its simplest, traffic <strong>for</strong>ecasts comprise three components: opening-year demand, a ramp-up profile and a longerterm<br />

growth trajectory. Analysis of the <strong>for</strong>ecasting errors associated with greenfield projects repeatedly demonstrates<br />

that the greatest contributor to such errors is getting the opening-year demand estimate wrong. Although departures<br />

from the longer-term growth trajectory will have a cumulative effect over time, the most economically sensitive time<br />

<strong>for</strong> <strong>toll</strong> <strong>road</strong> <strong>concessions</strong> tends to be the early years, which is when any project distress and/or default are most<br />

typically observed. One practical way of mitigating traffic risk is there<strong>for</strong>e to expose the private sector to projects<br />

once their opening-year and ramp-up periods have passed. In other words, the public sector would have the <strong>road</strong><br />

constructed, possibly through traditional procurement, and would steward it through its <strong>for</strong>mative years be<strong>for</strong>e letting<br />

(leasing) it to a concessionaire as a maturing ‘brownfield’ asset with a considerably reduced risk profile. 100 This is<br />

effectively what happened with 407ETR in Toronto (see Box 3.5). 101<br />

97 An international review <strong>for</strong> this study found only four, possibly five examples of <strong>toll</strong> <strong>road</strong> <strong>concessions</strong> employing the LPVR approach.<br />

98 See, <strong>for</strong> example, Vassallo, J. (2010), ‘Flexible-Term Highway Concessions: How Can They Work Better’, Transportation Research Record:<br />

Journal of the Transportation Research Board, 2187, 22–8.<br />

99 See, <strong>for</strong> example, Nombela, G. and de Rus, G. (2003), ‘Flexible-Term Contracts <strong>for</strong> Road Franchising’, available at http://uctc.net/research/<br />

papers/660.pdf<br />

100 A variant on this model was used by the Queensland State Government, through the state-owned Queensland Motorways, to fund projects such<br />

as the Logan Motorway and the Gateway Bridge Update.<br />

101 This case study was compiled from publicly available reports and presentations, and—critically—through correspondence with several individuals<br />

close to the project at the time. The authors are most grateful to those individuals who wished to remain anonymous.<br />

39

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!