12.04.2015 Views

The wine delusion

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Economics and Philosophy<br />

PHIL S­161<br />

___________________________<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>wine</strong> <strong>delusion</strong><br />

Why prices and ratings don’t matter<br />

Praveen Vaidyanathan<br />

HARVARD UNIVERSITY<br />

Summer 2014<br />

Professor Frank Thompson<br />

HARVARD UNIVERSITY<br />

Department of Philosophy<br />

1


Abstract<br />

People can never tell whether a <strong>wine</strong> is a lemon or not until they open the bottle.<br />

Even if they do, they certainly can't get their heads around it. For <strong>wine</strong> comes in just<br />

two colours, and yet, gives people over 15,000 options to pick from; more choice<br />

than any other product. Such is the complexity of <strong>wine</strong> that people lack the<br />

confidence to complain. So, how do people go about buying a bottle of <strong>wine</strong>? <strong>The</strong>ir<br />

best guess is to rely on two things: price and ratings. People assume that the more<br />

expensive <strong>wine</strong> will taste better than the cheaper <strong>wine</strong>. People assume that the <strong>wine</strong><br />

recommended by critics will taste better. It seems logical to assume that the more<br />

expensive the <strong>wine</strong> is, the better the critics will think of it. Reasonable as it may seem for<br />

other markets, for <strong>wine</strong>, it just doesn’t work. This paper uses behavioural economics and<br />

empirical evidence to prove that. It explores preferences, choices and risks in picking <strong>wine</strong>.<br />

Whilst suggesting refreshing ways for people to see <strong>wine</strong> like never before.<br />

2


A bizarre market<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>wine</strong> market works in a peculiar way. Sellers know more about the product than<br />

buyers do, causing an imbalance in power (Reiss, 2013, p. 233). Economists call this<br />

principle, ‘information asymmetry’. Because people can’t access the quality before buying<br />

it, their decisions involve risk. Which would mean that low­quality products could dominate<br />

the market (Akerlof, 1970). This theory was predicted by the Nobel Prize­winning<br />

economist George Akerlof. Akerlof called it ‘lemons theory’, applying it to the used car<br />

market. <strong>The</strong> word lemon refers to defective cars sold on the used car market. <strong>The</strong> word<br />

cherry refers to good cars sold on the used car market. People can never really tell whether<br />

a car is a cherry or a lemon before buying it (Veseth, 2007). So their best guess is that it is<br />

of average quality. <strong>The</strong> price they pay reflects the average quality. Realising that they can<br />

never get a justified price, cherry owners refrain from selling. Which would leave the market<br />

with lemons (Akerlof, 1970). <strong>The</strong> <strong>wine</strong> market is quite like the used cars market, only more<br />

bizarre. People can never tell whether a <strong>wine</strong> is a lemon or not until they open the bottle.<br />

Even if they do, they certainly can't get their heads around it. Because <strong>wine</strong> is complex; so<br />

much so that people lack the confidence to complain (Sutherland, 2013). So, how do<br />

people go about buying a bottle of <strong>wine</strong>? <strong>The</strong>ir best guess is to rely on two things: price<br />

and expert opinion. People assume that the more expensive <strong>wine</strong> will taste better than the<br />

cheaper <strong>wine</strong>. People assume that the <strong>wine</strong> recommended by critics will taste better than<br />

the rest (Dubner, 2010). But according to the British psychologist Richard Wiseman (cited<br />

in Sample, 2011) who has been testing those assumptions over and over again, among<br />

experts and amateurs alike, the answer is clear: the chances of anyone identifying a <strong>wine</strong><br />

3


as expensive or cheap based on taste alone is 50:50. <strong>The</strong> same odds as flipping a coin.<br />

So bizarre is the <strong>wine</strong> market that is refuses to accommodate even the most basic law of<br />

economics. Which is, people buy more when the prices are low and less when the prices<br />

are high. Economists call this principle, ‘law of demand’. Because <strong>wine</strong> is unlike a typical<br />

good, its audience, the ‘loyals’, the ‘snobs’ and the ‘conspicuous’, often violate the law of<br />

demand while making decisions. For instance, the loyals may not buy more or buy less with<br />

change in prices; the snobs may not buy more when prices fall; the conspicuous would buy<br />

more when prices rise (Thornton, 2009, pp. 219­21).<br />

<strong>The</strong> elixir of snobs<br />

<strong>The</strong>re are over 15,000 <strong>wine</strong> products to choose from. No other industry offers<br />

people so many choices (Thornton, 2013, p. 3). People believe these products have<br />

different characteristics. Such is its toll on the human capacity, leaving people confused.<br />

Perhaps its confusion is an intended illusion, a trick. For <strong>wine</strong> comes in just two colours:<br />

red and white. And yet, it seems so hard to pick one. So hard that the English poet<br />

Kingsley thought ‘Red or white?’ were the three most depressing words in the English<br />

language (Sutherland, 2014). So, why is <strong>wine</strong> still popular? Why are people taking so much<br />

trouble drinking a drink so confusing? One that people can never get their heads around,<br />

let alone have the confidence to complain. Perhaps the <strong>wine</strong> market thrives itself on<br />

confusion at the expense of clarity. A startup named Vinetrade set up a simple site for<br />

people to buy and sell <strong>wine</strong>s online. Vinetrade soon had to shut down because people<br />

resisted ordering <strong>wine</strong> online. Turns out, that the whole online thing killed the joy of being<br />

4


part of an elite group that used fancy words like ‘tannin’ and ‘oak’ (Mayassi, 2013). So, why<br />

is confusion revered? What is the correlation between confusion and popularity? In popular<br />

culture for instance, there is a meme on the theme nerds are cool. It works because nerds<br />

seem to have a certain IQ, too hard for the average Joe to understand. So cool that<br />

Hollywood filmmakers have been ditching superheroes for nerds (Hu, 2013). Similarly, the<br />

British adman Rory Sutherland thinks that <strong>wine</strong>’s popularity may be Freudian, ‘not in the<br />

sexual sense, but in the sense of what the Austrian psychologist Sigmund Freud called der<br />

Narzißmus der kleinen Differenzen or ‘the narcissism of small differences’ (Sutherland,<br />

2013). As Sutherland (2013) puts, ‘<strong>The</strong> advertising business is often criticised for<br />

exploiting this bias: to provide customers with a superficial sense of uniqueness endless<br />

trivial product variations are created to provide “an ersatz sense of otherness which is only<br />

a mask for an underlying uniformity and sameness”.’ In other words, the absurd complexity<br />

of <strong>wine</strong> may be essential to its popularity. For its drinkers to show status and<br />

connoisseurship, it is necessary for the market to be absurdly confusing to navigate<br />

(Sutherland, 2013). Which creates a sense of snobbery among <strong>wine</strong> drinkers; the<br />

superficial culture that is, <strong>wine</strong>. This peculiar narcissistic urge opens up an opportunity for<br />

people to advertise their own discernment, of what good <strong>wine</strong> is.<br />

Is <strong>wine</strong> genuine?<br />

So, what really is good <strong>wine</strong>? How do people know what good <strong>wine</strong> is? What<br />

makes one <strong>wine</strong> better than another? <strong>The</strong> Château Lafite Rothschild Bordeaux is<br />

considered by many to be the world’s best <strong>wine</strong>. Thomas Jefferson was among its<br />

5


admirers. Jefferson’s 100­year old Lafite was recently sold at an auction for $156,000, the<br />

most expensive sale ever (Mayassi, 2013). A recent bottle commands just over $400; older<br />

bottles cost three times as much or more. Wine experts talk of its taste as if it were an<br />

expensive piece of art (Mayassi, 2013). Because people assume a linear relationship<br />

between price and <strong>wine</strong>, they would believe a Lafite should taste different. But it’s unclear<br />

anyone can actually tell the difference between a $2000 Lafite and a $2 Two­Buck Chuck.<br />

Wisemen (cited in Sample, 2011) confirms that the probability of someone picking fine<br />

<strong>wine</strong> from cheap <strong>wine</strong> is at 47%. <strong>The</strong> same chances as flipping a coin. <strong>The</strong> American<br />

economist Robert Goldstein, along with his Swedish counterparts, Anna Dreber and Johan<br />

Almenberg, published a paper in the Journal of Wine economics that drew results from<br />

over 6000 blind tastings. Findings confirmed a few important observations: there is no<br />

correlation between price and the perceived quality of <strong>wine</strong>; there is no correlation between<br />

quality and enjoyment of <strong>wine</strong>; neither amateurs or experts can consistently differentiate<br />

between fine <strong>wine</strong>s and cheap <strong>wine</strong>s, nor identify the flavors within them (Goldstein et al.,<br />

2008). If a $10, $100, and $1,000 bottle all roughly taste the same, what explains the<br />

difference in their price tags? Maybe it’s a sign of wealth to impress others with expensive<br />

things. Maybe it’s an occasion for which something pricey feels special. But the underlying<br />

truth is that it is about expectations. It turns out that people who spend more on something<br />

expect to enjoy it more (Berdik, 2012, p. 78). Is this expectation rational or justified? In a<br />

cheeky study, the French economist Frederic Brochet tested a brand of table <strong>wine</strong> on <strong>wine</strong><br />

experts. Cheeky in that it reflected a model of behaviour in which reactions depend on the<br />

way things are presented. Behavioural economists call this principle, ‘framing’ (Bendle and<br />

6


Chen, 2014). Brochet served the same <strong>wine</strong> disguised in two different bottles, one cheap<br />

and one pricey. Experts praised the <strong>wine</strong> served from the pricey bottle as ‘excellent’,<br />

‘flavoursome’ and ‘balanced,’ whilst rejecting the <strong>wine</strong> served from the cheaper bottle as<br />

‘weak’, ‘flat’ and ‘unbalanced’ (Brochet, 2001). Beneath the framing lies a reason,<br />

expectations. Expectations are built into our brain’s tasting gear. People have thousands of<br />

taste buds, which are but blunt instruments. <strong>The</strong>se can tell if something is sweet, sour,<br />

bitter, salty or savoury. <strong>The</strong>ir main purpose is to know what’s edible, not distinguish flavours<br />

(Berdik, 2012). Besides tasting things, people can smell. Smell is the result of our constant<br />

sniffing of thousands of chemical compounds. What people smell is both the anticipation<br />

and fulfillment of a <strong>wine</strong>’s promise. It is easier to fool the nose than the mouth. <strong>The</strong> smell<br />

that people know of is the combination of many, many chemicals. <strong>The</strong>re are 213 known<br />

odor compounds in cheddar cheese and 466 in grapes according to Maarse (cited in<br />

Berdik, 2012). People’s reaction to these depend on odor concentration and context. In<br />

one study that tested the same smell, cued with the words ‘cheddar cheese’ or ‘body odor’,<br />

the former was found to be more pleasant. Even in the absence of odor, when prompted<br />

with the same words, people found ‘cheddar cheese’ better (Araujo et al., 2005). <strong>The</strong> truth<br />

is, people don’t need to overthink about the attributes of a <strong>wine</strong> to enjoy its flavour or check<br />

if it’s worthy of the price. So, why not disregard flavour specifics and look at taste<br />

preferences?<br />

7


For the sake of justification<br />

Do people like what they like, or do they like only what they expect to like? How<br />

much of our preference is already decided even before the first sip? <strong>The</strong> behavioural<br />

economist Dan Ariely asked the question, ‘Do we dislike what we expect to dislike?’ Dan<br />

Ariely’s team tested beer with a dash of vinegar on college students. When the students<br />

were told about the vinegar before they drank the beer, 70% didn’t like it. When the<br />

students were told about the vinegar after they drank the beer, more than 50% liked it. <strong>The</strong><br />

test tells us that expectations not only change what we think we should enjoy, but<br />

significantly changes our experiences itself (Ariely et al., 2006; Berdik, 2012). Marketers<br />

spend billions on advertising to craft emotional appeals towards brands. But prices are just<br />

numbers. People assume that expensive stuff is better. Behavioural economists call this<br />

principle, ‘price­quality heuristic’ (Berdik, 2012). Berdik (2012) feels that people use price<br />

as a guide. That is, if something is expensive, then it is likely to be of higher quality than<br />

something that is cheaper. Hence, people tend to justify a pricey product. Basically, they<br />

follow the crowd, and end up paying for the premium like everybody else does. Quality<br />

expectations may be fairly accurate on products with available objective measures of<br />

quality. For experiential goods such as <strong>wine</strong>, the price­quality rule is less accurate (Berdik,<br />

2012).<br />

<strong>The</strong> unnatural<br />

Unlike many of our basic consumer biases, the belief that price signals value isn’t<br />

evolutionarily natural. <strong>The</strong> American economist Laurie Santos has done years on research<br />

8


on this area by teaching monkeys to use money. Santos’ (2006) ‘monkeynomics’ research<br />

found that monkeys share most human consumer quirks . Like humans, monkeys fear<br />

potential losses more than they value potential gains of the same size. Behavioural<br />

economists call this principle, ‘loss­aversion’ (Bendle & Chen, 2013, p. 18). Like humans,<br />

monkeys value something more once they own it than they would before owning it.<br />

Behavioural economists call this principle, ‘endowment effect’ (Bendle & Chen, 2013, p. 4).<br />

<strong>The</strong> only thing monkeys don’t seem to share with us is the price­quality heuristic. Monkeys<br />

seem to understand what price means, but are not affected by price in the same way<br />

humans are. <strong>The</strong>y know more quantity would cost more. <strong>The</strong>y know to buy their favourite<br />

treats on sale. But, they don’t think one treat is inherently better just because it costs more<br />

(Santos et al., 2006). Which suggests that our overestimation on price may not be as<br />

deeply ingrained as other consumer biases. Meaning, our expectations on price can be<br />

easier to overcome. Or as Santos (2006) puts, ‘if we just have the right experiences and<br />

pay attention to our real preferences.’<br />

<strong>The</strong> flight from expectations<br />

So, people like what they expect to like, and their preferences can be fundamentally<br />

influenced by price and labels (Thornton, 2013). But, what really are our preferences? Have<br />

our real preferences been swayed by critics, society and others? Are preferences shaped<br />

by our own expectations the only preferences we have? Turns out, dividing real from<br />

shaped preferences is hard (Berdik, 2012). Research from the economics faculty of<br />

Stanford and Caltech found that pleasure from expectations is real. Subjects were told to<br />

9


taste five different <strong>wine</strong> bottles, priced at $5, $10, $35, $35, $45 and $90 respectively.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re were however only three bottles, with the $5 bottle labelled as $45 and $90 bottle<br />

labelled as $10. <strong>The</strong> results, as noted by Plassmann et al (cited in Berdik, 2012), showed<br />

that the more expensive the <strong>wine</strong>, the more they liked it. In other words, increasing the price<br />

of the same <strong>wine</strong> significantly increases the pleasure one gets from it. <strong>The</strong>se results mean<br />

that our brains connect sensory properties with expectations on how it should be. Knowing<br />

something beforehand about the quality of an experience gives us valuable additional<br />

information (Berdik, 2012). But our brains can’t evaluate this value in detail. Because it<br />

requires time, effort and thought. Our brains tend to default to mental shortcuts. Behavioural<br />

economists call this principle, ‘cognitive bias’ (Moesgaard­Kjeldsen, 2014). It sets up<br />

expectations based on the pre­experience. However, if our expectations were well beyond<br />

our actual experience, there would be a clash. Behavioural economists call this principle,<br />

‘contrast effect’ (Berdik, 2012). Which means, an average <strong>wine</strong> will taste even worse if<br />

people expected it to taste really well, or paid a lot for it. <strong>The</strong> contrast effect works exactly<br />

the same in opposite too. So, perhaps the only way to find our true preferences is to avoid<br />

expectations.<br />

<strong>The</strong> truths<br />

Blind tasting has been a saving ground, especially when it comes to dealing with<br />

problems of expectations on price versus quality. Goldstein (2008) published a manifesto<br />

in <strong>The</strong> Wine Trials with three useful arguments. First, expectations, especially those based<br />

on price, rule our evaluation of <strong>wine</strong>. Goldstein (2008) writes, ‘By questioning <strong>wine</strong> prices,<br />

10


you will become less of a slave to expectations and more of a student of your own palate.’<br />

Goldstein’s (2008) study revealed that everyday <strong>wine</strong> drinkers actually enjoyed expensive<br />

<strong>wine</strong> less. That is, people who are unaware of price do not get more enjoyment from<br />

expensive <strong>wine</strong>s. Second, experts and critics who guide our <strong>wine</strong> preferences are<br />

notoriously inconsistent, unreliable and untrustworthy. This is an issue, especially because<br />

peoples’ <strong>wine</strong> preferences are largely swayed by critics’ preferences. Critics rate <strong>wine</strong>s<br />

with scores on gold­standard magazines like Wine Spectator and Wine Advocate, seen<br />

as bibles of the industry. <strong>The</strong> American <strong>wine</strong> critic Robert Parker is undisputedly the<br />

world’s most influential person in <strong>wine</strong>, and has been since the last three decades. Parker<br />

also happens to be the editor­in­chief of its leading magazine, Wine Advocate. <strong>The</strong> Parker<br />

100­point score is the standard rating system for the <strong>wine</strong> market. So powerful is Parker<br />

that he wasn't exaggerating when he once said, ‘I can make or break a <strong>wine</strong>.’ In 2008,<br />

Goldstein went on to undercut the authority of such experts with a stunt that garnered<br />

international press. He put in the $250 application to Wine Spectator for a badge called<br />

the ‘Award of Excellence’. It is awarded to restaurants that have the best <strong>wine</strong> lists. He set<br />

up a fake restaurant, a website, a phone number with a Milan address. Its fake menu<br />

featured a list of the worst­rated <strong>wine</strong>s in the last two decades, reviewed by the very own<br />

Wine Spectator. Despite the size and obviousness of the error, his fake restaurant<br />

received an ‘Award of Excellence’. <strong>The</strong> only voicemail on his fake restaurant's phone<br />

number was left by Wine Spectator’s advertising department, to announce the news and<br />

enquire if they wanted to place an ad in their magazine. Critics are not only inconsistent<br />

11


and unreliable, they are also untrustworthy, says Goldstein (2008). To call them fake<br />

wouldn't be an understatement.<br />

Speaking of taste<br />

So, how sensitive are our palates to the taste expectations of <strong>wine</strong> descriptions?<br />

Consider this description by Robert Parker:<br />

…is a real treat as this cuvee flirts with perfection. Already revealing some pink and amber at the edge, the<br />

color is surprisingly evolved for a <strong>wine</strong> from this vintage. However, that’s deceptive as the aromatics offer<br />

incredible aromas of dried flowers, beef blood, spice, figs, sweet black currants and kirsch, smoked game,<br />

lavender, and sweaty but attractive saddle leather­like notes. Full­bodied and massively endowed, with<br />

abundant silky tannins, it possesses the balance to age for 30+ years.’ (McFadden, 2014)<br />

When an item promises multiple benefits, it is less convincing than items that<br />

appear to do only one thing. Behavioural economists call this principle, ‘goal dilution’<br />

(Sutherland, 2009). If only <strong>wine</strong> critics and writers knew about it. What could everyday<br />

drinkers make of such flowery descriptions? If anything, they do one thing well: confuse. So<br />

they’re actually doing a good job, if confusing people is the real intention. But if the real<br />

intention is to help people match words with <strong>wine</strong>s, they’re far from helpful. <strong>The</strong> American<br />

economist Roman Weil ran tests to see if people could match words with <strong>wine</strong>. Weil (cited<br />

in Berdik, 2012) gave subjects three glasses of <strong>wine</strong>, two of which were the same; along<br />

with two descriptions written by the same critic. Simple as it may seem, only half of them<br />

matched it right. <strong>The</strong>y would have done just as well flipping a coin. Unlike the blunt signal of<br />

12


price, flavour expectations of such flowery descriptions is nothing but a joke to the human<br />

capacity. Besides, nothing expresses approval like a Parker score of 90­plus or a gold<br />

medal, both of which correlate to higher prices. In other words, it would mean logical for the<br />

best­tasting <strong>wine</strong>s to pick up 90­plus scores and medals. But to Goldstein, that’s far from<br />

the truth. Wine Spectator makes $1 million in application fees for its ‘Award of Excellence’<br />

every year. And Goldstein’s own stunt made it quite clear: money talks. To take it a step<br />

further, Goldstein (cited in Berdik, 2012), along with economists Craig Riddell and Orley<br />

Ashenfelter, compared Wine Spectator­style ratings to ‘Zagat’ ratings, which is done much<br />

the same way, except that it is awarded to restaurants for the best food menu. Results<br />

showed that for each point awarded, the price of a meal rose up to 48% (Berdik, 2012).<br />

Things take time<br />

Goldstein’s (2008) price­signal study, which placed results onto a 100­point ratings<br />

scale, found that pricier <strong>wine</strong>s averaged 7 points lower among everyday drinkers and 4<br />

points higher among experts. Which means, when people are freed of expectations, their<br />

preferences would differ from that of the experts. So it seems perfectly reasonable to<br />

assume that critics’ tastes may well have been corrupted. If people could pick <strong>wine</strong>s purely<br />

on blind tasting, would they still prefer expensive <strong>wine</strong>s? Goldstein has helped launch a<br />

<strong>wine</strong> research institute in California’s Napa Valley. Whose aim is to, by bringing together<br />

behavioural economists and <strong>wine</strong> enthusiasts, explore the gap between subjective quality<br />

and price in the <strong>wine</strong> industry. It seeks to compare the effects and relationship of a <strong>wine</strong>’s<br />

region, price, bottle type, sensory characteristics and preferences across people, experts<br />

13


and <strong>wine</strong>makers. Peoples’ tendency to default to others opinion explains the popularity of<br />

critic ratings and reviews despite economics research (Thornton, 2013), which is working<br />

to undercut the value of expert authority by revealing its blatant inconsistencies (Goldstein,<br />

2008). Goldstein (cited in Berdik, 2012) believes that recommendations need to be<br />

‘starting points’ not ‘ending points’ put to further testing. Trying to figure out our real <strong>wine</strong><br />

preferences does take time. But that doesn’t mean people should fall prey to the<br />

pseudo­preferences of critics. Which Goldstein (cited in Berdik, 2012) sums up tastefully,<br />

‘<strong>The</strong>re’s a huge amount of bullshit in the <strong>wine</strong> world.’ Which takes us to the third argument<br />

in his manifesto, blind tasting is the only way to find out our true preference (Goldstein,<br />

2008). Just not the type blind tasting experts seem to follow.<br />

Intuition versus data<br />

A Paso Robles <strong>wine</strong>ry once sent the same <strong>wine</strong> to a <strong>wine</strong> competition under three<br />

different labels. One was rejected as ‘undrinkable’, the other won a double gold medal<br />

(Sutherland, 2013). <strong>The</strong> State Fair competition in California is the world's biggest in <strong>wine</strong><br />

judging. Its judges taste <strong>wine</strong> blindly, free from expectations, fortunately, staying true to<br />

Goldstein’s manifesto. But since 2003, they fatefully agreed to test their consistency, and<br />

report findings in the Journal of Wine Economics. Now, there is overwhelming evidence to<br />

show that their long­term judgements based on blind preferences were inconsistent<br />

(Berdik, 2012). <strong>The</strong>y have repeatedly tried to update, redefine or find new ways to find<br />

consistency in their results. <strong>The</strong>y have tried many times, some half­way through<br />

competitions, to find that elusive consistency. No matter how hard or how many times they<br />

14


tried, their inconsistent results didn’t seem to budge. <strong>The</strong>y still voted to retain and eliminate<br />

the same <strong>wine</strong>s. Berdik (2012) confirms that even the small minority of consistent tasters<br />

were often wildly inconsistent the next. Without expectations that are based on price, expert<br />

palates seem lost. To a point where the State Fair organisers were compelled to post a<br />

video interview titled, ‘Are Wine Competitions a Hoax?’ featuring its chief judge, G.M.<br />

Pucilowski. It’s clear that the <strong>wine</strong> market conducts itself on methodologies that are neither<br />

rigorous nor accurate (Goldstein, 2008). Two decades ago, the American economist Orley<br />

Ashenfelter offered the <strong>wine</strong> market a compelling tool using the power of simple statistics<br />

to outdo the world’s most accurate critics (Kahneman, 2011, p. 223). Ashenfelter came up<br />

with a formula that could predict the future prices of <strong>wine</strong> based on data, not human<br />

intuition. His formula was simple:<br />

∆ price =<br />

­12.15 + (β1 * Winter rainfall) + (β2 * Average summer temperature)<br />

+ (β3 * Harvest rainfall) + (β4 * Age of Vintage)<br />

It created an uproar in the <strong>wine</strong> market, with Robert Parker calling the economist ‘an<br />

absolute total sham’ (New, 2013). Perhaps Parker and his fraternity were concerned with<br />

the plight of the fancy world of <strong>wine</strong> ratings and its pricing should an economist’s formula<br />

beat a critic’s intuition. Unfortunately for them, Ashenfelter’s formula turned out to be<br />

extremely accurate (Kahneman, 2011, p. 224). Kahneman (2011) confirmed that the<br />

correlation between its prediction and actual prices was above .90. Ashenfelter’s formula<br />

found praise from the Nobel­prize winning psychologist Daniel Kahneman (cited in New,<br />

2013) who feels, ‘Whenever we can replace human judgement by a formula, we should at<br />

15


least consider it.’ Algorithms are beating intuition in chess, jeopardy and diagnosis these<br />

days (New, 2013). But the <strong>wine</strong> market continues to be sceptical toward such innovation,<br />

sticking to its flawed methodologies and conventional tasting techniques.<br />

Following the herd<br />

It is debatable whether <strong>wine</strong> critics or competitions are giving out scores and<br />

medals with the intention of helping people deal with uncertainty or of quality. <strong>The</strong> viticulture<br />

researcher Maynard Amerine spent decades understanding <strong>wine</strong> quality, growing<br />

conditions, <strong>wine</strong>making techniques, colouring, flavour, storage and so on. <strong>The</strong> State Fair<br />

rating system was designed on Amerine’s work (Berdik, 2012, p. 95). Amerine (cited in<br />

Berdik, 2012) believes that judges’ personal preferences do not come into play whilst<br />

judging, or are consciously ignored. He sees <strong>wine</strong> judging as a legitimate profession with<br />

fixed, common and consistent standards. Both Amerine and Pucilowski agree that experts<br />

and people don’t look for the same thing when they taste <strong>wine</strong>. But both have contradicting<br />

views on the real value they bring to people. Pucilowski feels that the reason why people<br />

might pay attention to <strong>wine</strong> critics or competitions is to see if they agree with the word of<br />

the expert. In other words, to check if preferences match. Amerine thinks otherwise. He<br />

feels that the reason why people might pay attention to <strong>wine</strong> critics or competitions is not to<br />

match preferences, but to pick quality (Berdik, 2012). But why should people expect their<br />

own preferences to match with the preferences of anyone else, or of experts? Especially<br />

when experts themselves, with all their fancy experience, can’t seem to evaluate <strong>wine</strong><br />

16


quality consistently. So, how can people actually figure out what they really like or dislike?<br />

What is the type of blind tasting that Goldstein hopes would actually make sense to people.<br />

Being humble<br />

Many sceptics believe that blind tasting is nothing without <strong>wine</strong>’s context. <strong>The</strong><br />

context includes everything from the <strong>wine</strong>, the food, the company, the occasion to the<br />

setting. <strong>The</strong>y agree that some <strong>wine</strong>s may be better than others, but the satisfaction people<br />

get from them depends on the context, which is discounted with conventional blind tasting<br />

sessions. Even Amerine believes that sensory evaluation is the true measure of <strong>wine</strong><br />

(Berdik, 2012). It is the quality of the <strong>wine</strong> in the glass in the context that matters. Which<br />

matches with the aim of Goldstein’s manifesto: personal preference. As it does with the<br />

democratic views of the New York Times <strong>wine</strong> writer Eric Asimov, who feels that opinions<br />

of critics and blind tastings should not be revered with authority they don’t possess. Asimov<br />

(cited in Berdik, 2012) hopes for a consensus, when he said, ‘let’s stay humble with <strong>wine</strong>.’<br />

He wants a culture of being comfortably ambivalent rather than being sure of others,<br />

anyone, or ourselves for that matter. Goldstein’s take on being humbled is for people to<br />

challenge themselves. He wants people to find the abilities and limitations of their palate.<br />

Goldstein believes that this knowledge is enough to sift through nonsense confidently,<br />

instead of trusting experts. Enough to make for great armour along with our real<br />

preferences, which we know evidently from Santos’ (2006) ‘monkeynomics’ and Caltech’s<br />

(2008) contrast effect research, are independent of expectations.<br />

17


Putting on the sceptical hat<br />

Blind tasting may not take people to their true preferences. But finding true<br />

preferences can be a work­in­progress even if it’s never found. If any, it opens up people to<br />

knowing how much they don’t know about what they really like (Berdik, 2012). Likes and<br />

dislikes are part of our own selves. Expectations may offer suggestions to our preferences;<br />

some useful, some not so much. Just as the Greek philosopher Heraclitus believed, ‘<strong>The</strong><br />

only thing that is constant is change,’ our preferences, too, are anything but consistent.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y are constantly being changed, evolved, influenced, and by nature, can certainly do<br />

with some questioning and discovery. At the heart of questioning and discovery is trial and<br />

error (Sutherland, 2014). In <strong>The</strong> Black Swan, the Lebanese­American mathematician<br />

Nassim Taleb explains the human tendency of trial and error in finding simplistic<br />

explanations retrospectively. <strong>The</strong> trial and error approach has defined human progress,<br />

from steam engine to aspirin. <strong>The</strong> human act of discovery through trial and error is what<br />

Taleb (cited in Sutherland, 2014) calls ‘stochastic tinkering’. <strong>The</strong> notion that people make<br />

progress on their own without really understanding how it works. In the notoriously complex<br />

<strong>wine</strong> market, where even expert preferences are about as consistent as flipping coins, trial<br />

and error seems like a reasonable way for people to find better and more genuine<br />

preferences (Sample, 2011; Sutherland, 2014; Berdik, 2012). How is Taleb’s use of the<br />

phrase ‘teaching birds to fly’ so different from unreliable experts telling people ‘how to<br />

drink’ or ‘how or enjoy’ a glass of <strong>wine</strong>? By using purchase data on more than 77 million<br />

shopping trips over 7 years, the Dutch economist Bart Bronnenberg matched shoppers’<br />

actual choices to their knowledge and found an interesting correlation: the more informed<br />

18


people are the more likely they are to pick store brands (Bronnenberg et al., 2014). If we<br />

flipped it around a bit, it makes sense the other way too. That is, if people simply<br />

recognised the <strong>wine</strong> market’s absurd complexity as an illusion to stay fancy, disregard<br />

advertising appeals and fluffy citics, the unfair bias against cheap <strong>wine</strong>s would become<br />

redundant. While this isn’t the case for many other experiential goods, it certainly holds true<br />

to <strong>wine</strong>. Whether people find their true preferences or learn anything about <strong>wine</strong> at all, they<br />

can at least be happy by merely knowing that a $10 <strong>wine</strong> can give them a $100<br />

experience. Or as Goldstein and Asimov believe, will motivate people to strip experts of<br />

their undue reverence, stay humble about not knowing <strong>wine</strong>, and be bold enough to wear a<br />

sceptical hat when it comes to picking <strong>wine</strong>.<br />

­­<br />

19


References<br />

Akerlof, G 1970, '<strong>The</strong> market for lemons: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism',<br />

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84, 488­500.<br />

Araujo, I 2005, ‘Cognitive modulation of olfactory processing’, Neuron, 46:4, pp. 671­79.<br />

Ariely, D, Lee, L and Frederick, S 2006, ‘Try it, you’ll like it: the influence of expectation,<br />

consumption and revelation on preferences for beer, ‘ Psychological Science, 17:12, pp.<br />

1054­58.<br />

Bendle, N, Chen, P 2013, Behavioural economics for kids, Neil Bendle, pp. 3­30,<br />

retrieved 12 July 2013,<br />

<br />

Berdik, C 2012, Mind over mind: the surprising power of expectations, Penguin Group,<br />

New York.<br />

Brochet, F 2001, ‘Chemical object representation in the field of consciousness,’ General<br />

Oenology Laboratory, Bordeaux School of Oenology, France.<br />

Bronnenberg, J, Dube, Jean­Pierre, Gentzkow, M, Shapiro, J 2014, ‘Do pharmacists buy<br />

Bayer? Informed shoppers and the brand premium’, NBER working paper, paper No.<br />

20295.<br />

Dubner, S, 2010, Freakonomics: do <strong>wine</strong> experts of prices matter?, Marketplace<br />

Freakonomics Radio, retrieved 20 July 2014,<br />

<br />

Goldstein, R, Almenberg, J, Dreber, A, Emerson, J, Herschkowitsch, A and Katz, J 2008,<br />

‘Do more expensive <strong>wine</strong>s taste better? Evidence from a large sample of blind tastings,<br />

Journal of Wine Economics, Vol. 3, No. 1, pp. 1­9.<br />

Hu, Z 2013, Real life (male) nerds: Hollywood’s new superheroes, Tribeca, retrieved 22<br />

July 2013,<br />

<br />

20


Moesgaard­Kjeldsen, S, 2014, ‘15 Cognitive biases that prevent us from thinking<br />

rationally,’ ReflectD, weblog post, retrieved 22 July 2014,<br />

<br />

McFadden, I 2014, 1998, 2001 & 2007 Bonneau Chateauneuf: Celestins & Cuvee<br />

Speciale, Crush, retrieved 22 July 2014,<br />

<br />

Reiss, J 2013, Philosophy of economics: a contemporary introduction, Routledge, Oxon<br />

Mayassi, A 2013, <strong>The</strong> price of <strong>wine</strong>, Priconomics, retrieved 17 July 2014,<br />

<br />

Kahneman, D 2011, Thinking fast and slow, Farrar, Straus and Girox, New York<br />

Sample, I 2011, Expensive <strong>wine</strong> and cheap plonk taste the same to most people, <strong>The</strong><br />

Guardian, retrieved 22 July 2014,<br />

<br />

Sutherland, R 2014, This thing for which we have no name, Edge, retrieved 20 July 2014,<br />

<br />

Sutherland, R 2013, Why does anyone drink <strong>wine</strong>?, <strong>The</strong> Spectator, retrieved 15 July 2014,<br />

<br />

Sutherland, R 2009, Why advertising needs behavioural economics, Campaign, retrieved<br />

20 July 2014, <br />

Thornton, J 2013, American Wine Economics: an exploration of the U.S Wine Industry,<br />

University of California Press, California.<br />

Thornton, J 2009, <strong>The</strong> tangles economics of American <strong>wine</strong>, Wine­Searcher, retrieved 16<br />

July 2014,<br />

<br />

Veseth, M 2007, Wine, branded <strong>wine</strong> and the market for lemons, Wine Economist,<br />

retrieved 21 July 2014,<br />

<br />

21

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!