09.07.2015 Views

A-La-Carte Pricing in the Airline Industry - Graduate Student ...

A-La-Carte Pricing in the Airline Industry - Graduate Student ...

A-La-Carte Pricing in the Airline Industry - Graduate Student ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

A-<strong>La</strong>-<strong>Carte</strong> <strong>Pric<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>Industry</strong>: Drivers, Consumer Effects, and Policy OptionsMercatus Policy EssayByGabriel OkolskiMaster of Arts, EconomicsGeorge Mason UniversityThe Mercatus Center at George Mason UniversitySummer 2010


AcknowledgementsI wish to thank Jerry Ellig and Jerry Brito of The Mercatus Center at George MasonUniversity as well as Aleta Best of <strong>the</strong> U.S. Department of Transportation for review<strong>in</strong>g thisessay and provid<strong>in</strong>g many helpful <strong>in</strong>sights dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> writ<strong>in</strong>g and edit<strong>in</strong>g process. I am alsograteful to a number of conversations I‘ve had with <strong>in</strong>dividuals at Mercatus and DOT who havehelped me th<strong>in</strong>k through <strong>the</strong>se issues. I bear all responsibility for any errors <strong>in</strong> this essay.1


IntroductionAnyone who has flown regularly dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> past ten years has certa<strong>in</strong>ly noticed majorchanges <strong>in</strong> pric<strong>in</strong>g for ancillary products and services offered by <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry. Gone are<strong>the</strong> days of complimentary domestic meals <strong>in</strong> coach, two checked bags without charge, and <strong>the</strong>ability to sit <strong>in</strong> an exit row without pay<strong>in</strong>g extra. Instead, <strong>the</strong> typical air traveler currently faces amenu of add-ons and fees for services that have ei<strong>the</strong>r been unbundled from <strong>the</strong> price of a ticketor have been offered as a new product or service.Media reports (Kiley 2009, Seaney 2008) and anecdotal experience suggest that such feeshave been <strong>the</strong> source of cont<strong>in</strong>ued consumer compla<strong>in</strong>ts about <strong>the</strong> air travel experience. Onepopular <strong>the</strong>ory beh<strong>in</strong>d airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ rationale for <strong>the</strong>se charges seems to be that airl<strong>in</strong>es are ―nickeland dim<strong>in</strong>g‖ consumers to squeeze out more profits at <strong>the</strong> consumer‘s expense. This popularassumption obscures <strong>the</strong> economics beh<strong>in</strong>d a major change <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> way airl<strong>in</strong>es price travel.Ra<strong>the</strong>r than offer<strong>in</strong>g a variety of related products and services with <strong>the</strong> price of a ticket, airl<strong>in</strong>eshave begun <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly collect<strong>in</strong>g ancillary revenues from consumers; this term refers to anyrevenue ―beyond <strong>the</strong> sale of tickets that is generated by direct sales to passengers, or <strong>in</strong>directly aspart of <strong>the</strong> travel experience.‖ (Sorensen 2009, 15) Bag fees have been, perhaps, <strong>the</strong> most visibleof <strong>the</strong>se. At <strong>the</strong> time of writ<strong>in</strong>g, only two large U.S. airl<strong>in</strong>es—JetBlue Airways and SouthwestAirl<strong>in</strong>es—allow most customers to check a first bag for no additional fee, while only Southwestoffers its customers a second complementary checked bag.As will be discussed, this paper asserts that this change <strong>in</strong> pric<strong>in</strong>g constitutes an ancillaryrevenue movement that took place with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> mid-late 2000s. In light ofthis change <strong>in</strong> most airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ bus<strong>in</strong>ess models, this paper will analyze <strong>the</strong> drivers and effects of a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry from an economic perspective. The paper comb<strong>in</strong>es


Chapter 1: Background and Review of Relevant LiteratureGiven frequent competitive changes, high capital costs, and susceptibility to supply-anddemandshocks, commercial aviation represents a vibrant and unique <strong>in</strong>dustry that is at <strong>the</strong> centerof a number of economic questions and analyses. The economics literature, along with relatedliteratures on bus<strong>in</strong>ess, operations management, and similar fields, conta<strong>in</strong>s an extensiveselection of papers cover<strong>in</strong>g a variety of topics, rang<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>the</strong> effects of deregulation toairport congestion mitigation to revenue management techniques (see, for example, Brueckner2002, Brumelle & Walczak 2003, and Morrison & W<strong>in</strong>ston 1989). None<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong> issue of a-lacartepric<strong>in</strong>g and <strong>the</strong> ancillary revenue movement <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry has been largelyuntouched by formal researchers <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> economics field. Given <strong>the</strong> fact that this shift <strong>in</strong> pric<strong>in</strong>ghas affected all carriers and has potential effects on passengers‘ welfare, this area merits analysisand discussion. This paper will thus seek to contribute to <strong>the</strong> economics literature by beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>gto analyze this previously unexplored topic <strong>in</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e pric<strong>in</strong>g strategy.This chapter will beg<strong>in</strong> by provid<strong>in</strong>g airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry context for <strong>the</strong> history and eventsbeh<strong>in</strong>d <strong>the</strong> ancillary revenue trend and will refer to l<strong>in</strong>es of research that are important to thisanalysis. Specifically, a good deal of research exists perta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> concept of pricedifferentiation via two-part pric<strong>in</strong>g, which characterizes airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ new pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangements. Thischapter will also discuss <strong>the</strong> economic literature on bundl<strong>in</strong>g, and how <strong>the</strong> concept of bundl<strong>in</strong>gties <strong>in</strong>to two-part pric<strong>in</strong>g and price differentiation. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>the</strong>re is a long established l<strong>in</strong>e ofresearch about entrepreneurship and <strong>the</strong> process by which entrepreneurs discover new<strong>in</strong>novations <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>dustry.In addition to outl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g key works and concepts from <strong>the</strong>se relevant l<strong>in</strong>es of literature,this chapter will also discuss <strong>the</strong> methodology beh<strong>in</strong>d <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terviews conducted for this paper.3


Additionally, <strong>the</strong> chapter will provide an overview of <strong>the</strong> most relevant topics discussed dur<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> qualitative research.Def<strong>in</strong>itionsThis paper uses a number of terms referr<strong>in</strong>g to ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry or a-la-cartepric<strong>in</strong>g that ought to be clarified prior to any sort of formal discussion. The first <strong>in</strong>volves adist<strong>in</strong>ction between network carriers and low-cost-carriers (LCCs). Network carriers are thosethat operate flights us<strong>in</strong>g a hub-and-spoke system, (Brady 2005) which offers passengers nonstopservice from a non-hub city to <strong>the</strong> hub or offers <strong>the</strong>m connect<strong>in</strong>g service between two non-hubcities through <strong>the</strong> hub. Network airl<strong>in</strong>es, which <strong>in</strong>clude American Airl<strong>in</strong>es, Cont<strong>in</strong>ental Airl<strong>in</strong>es,Delta Air L<strong>in</strong>es, United Airl<strong>in</strong>es, and US Airways, are often referred to as ―legacy airl<strong>in</strong>es‖because <strong>the</strong>ir existence predates deregulation. 1LCCs, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, are airl<strong>in</strong>es that use a low-cost bus<strong>in</strong>ess model, which may<strong>in</strong>clude attributes such as a s<strong>in</strong>gle class of service, utilization of one aircraft type, limited <strong>in</strong>flightservices, service to smaller airports, and lower employee wages and benefits. Examples of LCCs<strong>in</strong>clude Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es, Spirit Airl<strong>in</strong>es, and JetBlue Airways. In addition to LCCs, <strong>the</strong>Bureau of Transportation Statistics identifies a third group of regional carriers that operatesmaller aircraft and provide service from small cities to network carriers‘ hubs. These carriersoften operate under <strong>the</strong> brand<strong>in</strong>g of a network airl<strong>in</strong>e and share largely harmonized customerservice and fee policies with <strong>the</strong>ir network counterparts. Thus, for <strong>the</strong> purpose of this paper, <strong>the</strong>ywill be implicitly <strong>in</strong>cluded under <strong>the</strong> network carrier head<strong>in</strong>g.1 Northwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es, which is mentioned dur<strong>in</strong>g this paper, was part of this category prior to its merger with DeltaAir L<strong>in</strong>es. As of writ<strong>in</strong>g, Cont<strong>in</strong>ental Airl<strong>in</strong>es and United Airl<strong>in</strong>es plan to merge <strong>in</strong>to a s<strong>in</strong>gle network carrier.4


A number of terms relat<strong>in</strong>g to various concepts <strong>in</strong> a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g also merit def<strong>in</strong>itionat this po<strong>in</strong>t. Ancillary revenue refers to revenue an airl<strong>in</strong>e earns beyond <strong>the</strong> sale of its coreproduct of airl<strong>in</strong>e tickets (Sorensen 2009, 15). Such revenue can be generated by directly sell<strong>in</strong>gto customers or earn<strong>in</strong>g commissions from o<strong>the</strong>r companies by sell<strong>in</strong>g hotel stays, car rentals, etc.A-la-carte features refer to <strong>the</strong> amenities that customers can add to <strong>the</strong>ir travel experiences; suchproducts typically <strong>in</strong>volve checked luggage, onboard food, priority board<strong>in</strong>g, etc. (15) With<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>realm of a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>the</strong>re are two broad categories of products and services. Unbundl<strong>in</strong>grefers to those products that were previously <strong>in</strong>cluded with <strong>the</strong> price of a ticket but are now be<strong>in</strong>goffered for a separate charge to most or all customers. Perhaps <strong>the</strong> most visible example ofunbundl<strong>in</strong>g to consumers is checked luggage, which was previously offered to customers for free.In addition to unbundl<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>the</strong>re are also new products and services that were not previouslyoffered with or without a ticket but have been <strong>in</strong>troduced by airl<strong>in</strong>es as an ancillary revenuestream. An example of such a new service is a fee that coach passengers can pay to ga<strong>in</strong> accessto product attributes that are generally reserved for bus<strong>in</strong>ess class or elite frequent-flyercustomers.Vestiges of RegulationTo fully understand <strong>the</strong> events surround<strong>in</strong>g airl<strong>in</strong>e product and service unbundl<strong>in</strong>g andancillary revenue generation, one should look back to <strong>the</strong> regulation of <strong>the</strong> U.S. air transport<strong>in</strong>dustry; it was dur<strong>in</strong>g this time that airl<strong>in</strong>es bundled a number of related products and serviceswith <strong>the</strong> ticket. Start<strong>in</strong>g with <strong>the</strong> Civil Aeronautics Act <strong>in</strong> 1938, <strong>the</strong> federal governmentestablished <strong>the</strong> Civil Aeronautics Board (CAB), which had <strong>the</strong> power to regulate route entry andexit, fares, mergers and acquisitions, and subsidies. Unable to offer discounted fares <strong>in</strong> order to5


compete with <strong>the</strong>ir rivals to attract customers, <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>es opted to offer <strong>in</strong>creased qualityproducts and services <strong>in</strong> order to lure travelers (Goetz & Vowles 2009, 253). One example of thisresponse to price regulation is manifested <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> ―lounge wars‖—airl<strong>in</strong>es began compet<strong>in</strong>g wi<strong>the</strong>ach o<strong>the</strong>r by outfitt<strong>in</strong>g certa<strong>in</strong> planes with lavish lounges, complete with piano bars, pokermach<strong>in</strong>es, musicians, and magicians (Vietor, 78–79). On a more mundane level, competitiveconstra<strong>in</strong>ts gave airl<strong>in</strong>es an <strong>in</strong>centive to provide high-quality food and dr<strong>in</strong>k offer<strong>in</strong>gs, and o<strong>the</strong>rperks, such as <strong>in</strong>flight movies, to lure customers onboard.The lack of price competition led to a number of economic studies dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> 1970s<strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g that unregulated airl<strong>in</strong>es may be able to lower fares and show<strong>in</strong>g that competition <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry could be robust without government <strong>in</strong>volvement. (79) The appo<strong>in</strong>tment ofderegulation advocate Alfred Kahn as CAB chairman provided a catalyst for <strong>the</strong> Airl<strong>in</strong>eDeregulation Act, which removed government control over route entry and exit and fares.Despite deregulation of <strong>the</strong>se functions, <strong>the</strong> federal government reta<strong>in</strong>s widespread control overmerger approval, safety, and o<strong>the</strong>r areas of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry.Two observations aris<strong>in</strong>g from deregulation are germane to this paper. First, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> periodfollow<strong>in</strong>g deregulation, airl<strong>in</strong>es responded to <strong>the</strong>ir newly acquired pric<strong>in</strong>g freedom bydevelop<strong>in</strong>g more <strong>in</strong>tricate and advanced ways to maximize revenues and yields be<strong>in</strong>g generatedby flight activity. This development of revenue management techniques occurred with a rapidpace <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1980s, follow<strong>in</strong>g deregulation, and cont<strong>in</strong>ued to evolve <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> 1990s. All <strong>in</strong> all,airl<strong>in</strong>es spent considerable time and resources research<strong>in</strong>g and develop<strong>in</strong>g new yieldmanagement techniques, which <strong>in</strong>clude sell<strong>in</strong>g fares <strong>in</strong> ―buckets‖ and better differentiat<strong>in</strong>g pricesfor various groups of passengers (Chiang, et al. 2006, 98). Concurrent with <strong>the</strong> discovery anddevelopment of <strong>the</strong>se new methods, airl<strong>in</strong>es also developed <strong>the</strong> hub and spoke model, by which6


nearly all flights orig<strong>in</strong>ate from or term<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>in</strong> one or more ―hub‖ cities. While this <strong>in</strong>novationallowed air carriers to offer services to more customers through connect<strong>in</strong>g it<strong>in</strong>eraries, it alsogenerated <strong>in</strong>creased complexities <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ pric<strong>in</strong>g structures. Such complexities fur<strong>the</strong>rhelped to <strong>in</strong>centivize <strong>in</strong>novations <strong>in</strong> revenue management <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> decade follow<strong>in</strong>g deregulation(Smith, et al., 11).Second, airl<strong>in</strong>es cont<strong>in</strong>ued to offer a number of ancillary products and services that werevestiges from <strong>the</strong> regulation days of competition on a quality dimension. In some cases, this wasa deliberate strategic decision. Follow<strong>in</strong>g deregulation, a f<strong>in</strong>ancially pressured American Airl<strong>in</strong>es,unable to cut its costs to a competitive level, chose to brand itself as a full-service airl<strong>in</strong>e targetedat bus<strong>in</strong>ess travelers. Despite broad cuts <strong>in</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r areas post deregulation, American Airl<strong>in</strong>esma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>ed service for reservations, ticket<strong>in</strong>g, baggage handl<strong>in</strong>g, and <strong>in</strong>-flight amenities (Vietor,94). O<strong>the</strong>r legacy carriers adopted a similar strategy to compete with a grow<strong>in</strong>g list of no-frills,low-cost entrants <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> newly liberalized market.Thus, <strong>the</strong> persistence of complimentary services and products, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g luggage check,food, and beverages, can be seen partly as a competition strategy and partly as a vestige fromderegulation. It is important to note that while many of <strong>the</strong>se services have been unbundled from<strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e ticket, some cont<strong>in</strong>ue to persist as remnants from <strong>the</strong> time of regulation.Complimentary soft dr<strong>in</strong>ks cont<strong>in</strong>ue to be <strong>the</strong> norm for most U.S. carriers, and most domesticairl<strong>in</strong>es offer <strong>in</strong>flight snacks at no charge and free full meals on <strong>in</strong>ternational flights. 22 Only some budget carriers, such as Allegiant Air or Spirit Airl<strong>in</strong>es, do not offer complimentary soft dr<strong>in</strong>ks onboard.Cont<strong>in</strong>ental Airl<strong>in</strong>es only announced <strong>in</strong> 2010 that it planned to do away with free passenger meals at meal timeson domestic flights.7


The Start of <strong>the</strong> Ancillary Revenue MovementThe majority of <strong>the</strong> public likely became familiar with notions of ancillary revenue andunbundl<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong> 2008. In February of that year, United Airl<strong>in</strong>es announcedthat it would charge customers pay<strong>in</strong>g certa<strong>in</strong> non-refundable fares a $25 fee for check<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>second bag on domestic and Canada-bound flights (Carey 2008). Frequent flyers with elite statuson <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e (those who flew a certa<strong>in</strong> amount of miles over <strong>the</strong> course of a calendar year)would be exempt from <strong>the</strong> charge, which was <strong>the</strong> first of its k<strong>in</strong>d among large U.S. airl<strong>in</strong>es. 3Despite <strong>in</strong>itial reluctance to follow, <strong>the</strong> rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g four network airl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong>stituted second bagcharges with<strong>in</strong> three months of <strong>the</strong> announcement.As o<strong>the</strong>r airl<strong>in</strong>es began to match United‘s charge, ano<strong>the</strong>r carrier took <strong>the</strong> next big a-lacartepric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>itiative. In May 2008, American Airl<strong>in</strong>es announced that it would extend itssecond-bag fee to <strong>the</strong> first checked bag as well. One month later, United Airl<strong>in</strong>es and USAirways <strong>in</strong>stituted similar first-bag fees (Maynard 2008). By <strong>the</strong> late fall, all U.S. networkcarriers, along with a large numbers of LCCs, such as AirTran Airways, had some sort of fee formost customers check<strong>in</strong>g any luggage. Airl<strong>in</strong>es with first or bus<strong>in</strong>ess class cab<strong>in</strong>s and frequentflyer programs generally waived baggage fees for premium customers and those with elite status.Additionally, two large airl<strong>in</strong>es held out (and, as of writ<strong>in</strong>g, cont<strong>in</strong>ue to hold out) from <strong>in</strong>stitut<strong>in</strong>gfees for all bags. JetBlue Airways, a low-cost carrier, only <strong>in</strong>stituted a second-bag fee but stillallows customers to check a first bag for free. Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es, <strong>the</strong> largest U.S. airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>terms of domestic passenger board<strong>in</strong>gs and a long-time LCC chose to reta<strong>in</strong> its policy ofcharg<strong>in</strong>g for any bags checked <strong>in</strong> addition to <strong>the</strong> two-bag allotment.3 Some discount carriers such as Spirit Airl<strong>in</strong>es and <strong>the</strong> now-defunct Skybus were charg<strong>in</strong>g for bags before thispo<strong>in</strong>t.8


While <strong>the</strong> year of <strong>the</strong> bag fee may have brought <strong>the</strong> issue of ancillary revenues andunbundl<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> public consciousness, <strong>the</strong> unbundl<strong>in</strong>g trend actually had its roots earlier <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>decade. Most airl<strong>in</strong>es reduced or elim<strong>in</strong>ated meal service on most domestic flights follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>attacks of September 11th, which resulted <strong>in</strong> widespread revenue losses for <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry(Sharkey 2001). Food on domestic flights did not completely disappear, however; around 2003,airl<strong>in</strong>es began <strong>the</strong>ir first earnest tests of onboard food sales (Sharkey 2003). As discussed more <strong>in</strong>later chapters, food-for-purchase, with its roots <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> demand shock of September 11th, hasturned out to be a revenue source. A number of airl<strong>in</strong>es currently sell food, rang<strong>in</strong>g from snacksto full meals, on domestic flights of sufficient length.In addition to checked luggage and food, a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g has grown <strong>in</strong>to o<strong>the</strong>r types ofonboard products that were previously <strong>in</strong>cluded with a ticket. Follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitution of firstand second checked bag fees, many airl<strong>in</strong>es have <strong>in</strong>stituted charges for exit row seats andbulkhead seats that offer additional legroom. On American Airl<strong>in</strong>es and JetBlue Airways,customers must pay for pillows and blankets, previously offered for free.Two-Part TariffsIn its analysis of ancillary revenues, this paper characterizes airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ new pric<strong>in</strong>garrangement as two-part tariffs, a subject that has been covered extensively <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> economicsliterature. A two-part tariff is a price discrim<strong>in</strong>ation technique by which a firm charges a lumpsumfee for <strong>the</strong> ability to purchase goods along with a per-unit charge for <strong>the</strong> purchase of thosegoods (Carlton & Perloff 2005, 314). One of <strong>the</strong> more traditional examples of two-part tariffs <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> literature is that of a country club, which charges a membership fee, plus a usage fee formembers to play golf, access a restaurant, or use o<strong>the</strong>r facilities.9


In <strong>the</strong>se examples, this fee exists solely to give consumers access to purchase a good.Locay and Rodriguez (1992), however, discuss how a movie <strong>the</strong>ater exhibits a type of two-parttariff by charg<strong>in</strong>g patrons for entry with a movie ticket and allow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m to purchase popcornand o<strong>the</strong>r goods at an additional fee (954). In this case, <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>itial charge entitles customers tosome sort of product <strong>in</strong> addition to <strong>the</strong> right to purchase additional goods and services. Themovie <strong>the</strong>ater case can be likened to <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry case of a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g: airl<strong>in</strong>es chargeconsumers a base fare, which entitles <strong>the</strong>m to <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e ticket. The base fare also givescustomers access to purchase o<strong>the</strong>r goods and services, such as <strong>the</strong> ability to check bags, meals,etc., on an a-la-carte basis.From a <strong>the</strong>oretical perspective, two-part tariffs are generally seen as a pricediscrim<strong>in</strong>ation technique by monopoly firms or firms with a high degree of market power(Carlton & Perloff 2005, 301). In a standard neoclassical analysis of monopoly two-part tariffs,<strong>the</strong> access charge is set to capture <strong>the</strong> consumer surplus that exists for all units purchased. Thispresents <strong>the</strong> firm with a challenge, however, s<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> amount of <strong>the</strong> access charge is constra<strong>in</strong>edby lower consumer surplus levels of consumers who demand less of <strong>the</strong> good at a given pricethan o<strong>the</strong>r consumers. Because of <strong>the</strong> loss of consumers when <strong>the</strong> access charge rises, two-partpric<strong>in</strong>g is unable to capture <strong>the</strong> same amount of consumer surplus as first-best pricediscrim<strong>in</strong>ation techniques when <strong>the</strong> firm faces consumers with heterogeneous demands. Thisassumes, of course, that <strong>the</strong> firm must charge a s<strong>in</strong>gle access fee to all consumers.One of <strong>the</strong> earliest thorough analyses of two-part tariffs was conducted by Oi (1971),who discussed <strong>the</strong> dilemma of whe<strong>the</strong>r an amusement park should allow entry for free andcharge monopoly prices for <strong>the</strong> rides, or whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> park should charge an entry free but allowfree rides. While <strong>the</strong> park enjoys a monopoly position, under traditional analysis, <strong>the</strong> monopolist10


would not be able to capture all consumer surplus by pric<strong>in</strong>g where its marg<strong>in</strong>al cost equalsmarg<strong>in</strong>al revenue. This is due to <strong>the</strong> fact that a number of thrill seekers will not enter <strong>the</strong> park atall because of <strong>the</strong> high price. By charg<strong>in</strong>g an entry fee, <strong>the</strong> monopolist is able to capture <strong>the</strong>consumer surplus that <strong>the</strong> customers enjoy after purchas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir desired quantity of goods at acerta<strong>in</strong> price. Oi po<strong>in</strong>ts out that <strong>the</strong> amusement park faces a tension between rais<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> entry feeand los<strong>in</strong>g part of its customer base. Oi‘s paper bears relevance for an analysis of two-part tariffs<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong>dustry; much like <strong>the</strong> amusement park, an airl<strong>in</strong>e enjoys a monopoly positiononce <strong>the</strong> consumer is onboard. This gives airl<strong>in</strong>es ability to engage <strong>in</strong> some degree of pricediscrim<strong>in</strong>ation, as is <strong>the</strong> case for an amusement park.While Oi and a number of subsequent researchers analyze two-part tariffs for amonopolist, Locay and Rodriguez (1992) show that two-part pric<strong>in</strong>g can serve as an equilibriumstrategy under competition. They demonstrate that competitive firms employ<strong>in</strong>g a two-part tariffwill price <strong>the</strong> good/service above marg<strong>in</strong>al cost while hav<strong>in</strong>g an entry fee that is below marg<strong>in</strong>alcost (955). The authors base <strong>the</strong>ir model on <strong>the</strong> assumption that goods and services are purchasedby groups of people, ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>in</strong>dividuals. Thus, hav<strong>in</strong>g groups of <strong>in</strong>dividuals provides, <strong>in</strong>essence, some level of market power by constra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dividuals‘ ability to shop around at o<strong>the</strong>rfirms. This is one potential factor that prevents competition from driv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> price of <strong>the</strong>ancillary good to equal its marg<strong>in</strong>al cost.Button (2005) discusses <strong>the</strong> potential feasibility of two-part tariffs <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustryfrom a general perspective, discuss<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> access charges as a way to cover capital costs. (255)Button seems to discuss two-part tariffs <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> context of airl<strong>in</strong>e ―subscriptions,‖ but f<strong>in</strong>ds limitedpotential use for this type of pric<strong>in</strong>g mechanism <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry. While some scholars mayhave seen limited applicability of two-part prices <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry, airl<strong>in</strong>es have pursued11


this strategy. None<strong>the</strong>less, Button makes a po<strong>in</strong>t that airl<strong>in</strong>es may have difficulty <strong>in</strong>approximat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> capital costs attributed to a s<strong>in</strong>gle airl<strong>in</strong>e consumer. Thus, while airl<strong>in</strong>es havetaken a two-part pric<strong>in</strong>g strategy, <strong>the</strong>y still may face some difficulty <strong>in</strong> decid<strong>in</strong>g how <strong>the</strong>y plan todivide base fees and ancillary charges.Bundl<strong>in</strong>g/Unbundl<strong>in</strong>gFrom an economic perspective, bundl<strong>in</strong>g refers to a tie-<strong>in</strong> sales arrangement by which afirm sells its goods <strong>in</strong> packages (Adams & Yellen 1976, 475). Two types of bundl<strong>in</strong>g arecommonly employed. A pure bundle occurs when a product or service is only available as part ofa bundle. An example of this is N<strong>in</strong>tendo‘s Wii gam<strong>in</strong>g console, which is sold with ―Wii Sports,‖a sports simulator. Nei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> console nor <strong>the</strong> game is offered separately by <strong>the</strong> retailer. Firmsmay also offer a mixed bundle, <strong>in</strong> which consumers can ei<strong>the</strong>r purchase <strong>the</strong> relevant goods <strong>in</strong> apackage or separately. Such is <strong>the</strong> case with combo meals offered at fast food restaurants.Stigler (1963) was one of <strong>the</strong> earliest economists to show <strong>the</strong> profitability of a bundl<strong>in</strong>gstrategy, apply<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>ory of bundl<strong>in</strong>g to production companies that only offered movies to<strong>the</strong>aters <strong>in</strong> bundles. Stigler showed that if two exhibitors valued film X at $8,000 and $7,000,respectively and film Y at $2,500 and $3,000, respectively, <strong>the</strong> studio could only charge $7,000and $2,500 for a separate offer<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong> movies. Alternatively, <strong>the</strong> studio could offer bothmovies toge<strong>the</strong>r, and given consumer demand, earn revenue of $10,000, $500 more than <strong>the</strong>separate offer<strong>in</strong>g would yield.As shown by Stigler, <strong>the</strong> profitability of bundl<strong>in</strong>g as a pric<strong>in</strong>g strategy is ultimatelydependent on <strong>the</strong> negative correlation between <strong>the</strong> consumer demands for each product. Adamsand Yellen (1976) conducted <strong>the</strong> first methodical analysis of bundl<strong>in</strong>g, show<strong>in</strong>g that bundl<strong>in</strong>g12


essentially sorts consumers <strong>in</strong>to groups with different reservation price characteristics, andallows firms to extract consumer surplus (476). The authors show that with a mixed bundl<strong>in</strong>gstrategy, a monopolist is ultimately able to create two separate markets for different customers.Schmalensee (1984) builds upon Adams and Yellen‘s <strong>in</strong>tuition by deriv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> generalconditions under which bundl<strong>in</strong>g is a profitable strategy for a monopolist. One importantimplication from his derivation is that bundl<strong>in</strong>g may be a more successful strategy whenmarg<strong>in</strong>al costs of provid<strong>in</strong>g components of <strong>the</strong> bundle are very low.O<strong>the</strong>r researchers analyze bundl<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> competitive market structures. For example,Matutes and Regibeau (1992) discuss <strong>the</strong> profitability of bundl<strong>in</strong>g strategies <strong>in</strong> a duopoly marketwhere customers put toge<strong>the</strong>r multiple components of a bundle to reach <strong>the</strong>ir ideal po<strong>in</strong>t. Theauthors f<strong>in</strong>d that mixed bundl<strong>in</strong>g can decrease firm profits <strong>in</strong> a duopoly, and may thus be used byan <strong>in</strong>cumbent firm to discourage entry.Airl<strong>in</strong>es that had previously bundled a variety of services with an airl<strong>in</strong>e ticket haveclearly unbundled many of those and moved to a two-part pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangement. Some aspects of<strong>the</strong> bundl<strong>in</strong>g literature po<strong>in</strong>t to some considerations that may have driven unbundl<strong>in</strong>g. Forexample, ris<strong>in</strong>g marg<strong>in</strong>al costs for ancillary products due to ris<strong>in</strong>g fuel prices may have <strong>in</strong>creased<strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centive to unbundle. None<strong>the</strong>less, economic <strong>the</strong>ory does not appear to have any clearconclusions about <strong>the</strong> connection between bundl<strong>in</strong>g/unbundl<strong>in</strong>g and two-part tariffs. In one paper,Murphy (1977) discusses two-part tariffs along with bundl<strong>in</strong>g and f<strong>in</strong>ds that bundl<strong>in</strong>g would earnmore profits than two-part tariffs, with equal number of consumers with high and low demandfor <strong>the</strong> products be<strong>in</strong>g bundled.Despite a lack of conclusive research, <strong>the</strong> unique conditions of <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry implythat air carriers should pursue a two-part tariff strategy if <strong>the</strong>y decide to unbundle products13


and/or services. This is because consumer demand for an ancillary good offered by an airl<strong>in</strong>e isexclusively cont<strong>in</strong>gent on purchase of <strong>the</strong> base fare. For example, nobody would want to pay fora bag check service or a meal onboard <strong>the</strong> airplane if she were not go<strong>in</strong>g to undertake a trip.Given that <strong>the</strong>se products are offered exclusively to complement <strong>the</strong> air travel experience, anairl<strong>in</strong>e faces somewhat of a dichotomous choice between bundl<strong>in</strong>g with a s<strong>in</strong>gle price andunbundl<strong>in</strong>g with a two-part price.The Role of EntrepreneurshipOne of <strong>the</strong> key factors weigh<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to an airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s pric<strong>in</strong>g decision and o<strong>the</strong>r bus<strong>in</strong>essstrategies is <strong>the</strong> role of <strong>the</strong> entrepreneur. It is important to remember that pric<strong>in</strong>g decisions at <strong>the</strong>airl<strong>in</strong>e are ultimately made by <strong>in</strong>dividuals who become aware of new profit opportunities <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>field and decide to take action based on future rewards. This basic notion goes back to Kirzner(1973), who emphasized that <strong>the</strong> human element of <strong>the</strong> entrepreneur is a more germanedescription of <strong>in</strong>novation than a faceless organization that is solv<strong>in</strong>g a simple optimizationproblem. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore Kirzner‘s work, as well as <strong>the</strong> earlier work by Schumpeter (1947),emphasizes that entrepreneurial <strong>in</strong>novations require alertness to previously unexploitedopportunities and some sense of ―creative response‖ to take action <strong>in</strong> reply to those opportunities(150).Kirzner asserts that <strong>the</strong> entrepreneurial process is rooted <strong>in</strong> a framework of means andends that def<strong>in</strong>es <strong>the</strong> entrepreneur‘s economiz<strong>in</strong>g problem (Kirzner 1973, 32–33). Ultimately, abus<strong>in</strong>essperson wishes to achieve a certa<strong>in</strong> set of goals (ends) but faces constra<strong>in</strong>ts as to <strong>the</strong>potential courses of action to achieve <strong>the</strong>m (means). Ultimately, human action leads14


entrepreneurs to become alert to new goals and <strong>the</strong> discovery of previously unrecognized meansof achiev<strong>in</strong>g those goals.The process of becom<strong>in</strong>g aware to new, more profitable opportunities is not necessarilyperfect—even those who have <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation to develop new entrepreneurial opportunities maynot discover those opportunities due to an <strong>in</strong>ability to see relationships between <strong>the</strong> means and<strong>the</strong> ends of <strong>the</strong> opportunity (Shane & Venkataraman 2000, 222). Ultimately, <strong>the</strong> entrepreneuralso has limited time and attention that can be spent on a certa<strong>in</strong> idea. The existence of morelucrative opportunities may take focus away from o<strong>the</strong>r opportunities that may be relevant butare relatively less important or lucrative.As Gifford po<strong>in</strong>ts out, entrepreneurs possess<strong>in</strong>g scarce attention also face a choicebetween allocat<strong>in</strong>g attention to current operations or <strong>in</strong>novat<strong>in</strong>g new strategies to achieveprofitability (Gifford 1992, 276). Ultimately, Gifford f<strong>in</strong>ds that a firm‘s propensity to search fornew profit opportunities is a function of how susta<strong>in</strong>able <strong>the</strong> current bus<strong>in</strong>ess arrangement is <strong>in</strong>generat<strong>in</strong>g profits. With limited attention to allocate, airl<strong>in</strong>es were likely focused on ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gstrategies that generated modest profits through <strong>the</strong> late 1990s, prior to <strong>the</strong> events of September11th. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> nature of <strong>the</strong> LCC threat was still uncerta<strong>in</strong> at that time, weaken<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>centives to look for radically new pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangements dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> 1990s.In addition, as Gifford discusses, <strong>the</strong> entrepreneur must often bear uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty whenresearch<strong>in</strong>g and purs<strong>in</strong>g new strategies, a very different concept from a predictable risk. Perhaps<strong>the</strong> first economist to seriously discuss and analyze risk and uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty was Knight (1921), whois well known for his dist<strong>in</strong>ction between <strong>the</strong> two concepts. Knight def<strong>in</strong>es risk as a characteristicthat can be measured and understood by <strong>the</strong> entrepreneur, whereas uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty cannot truly bemeasured (I.I.26). For example, a situation of entrepreneurial risk would <strong>in</strong>volve know<strong>in</strong>g that a15


new production process will have a 32 percent chance of improv<strong>in</strong>g efficiency, while uncerta<strong>in</strong>tywould <strong>in</strong>volve not know<strong>in</strong>g what <strong>the</strong> probability of efficiency improvement would be. Knightemphasizes that uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty is a factor that can <strong>in</strong>terfere with competitive outcomes as predictedby pure economic <strong>the</strong>ory (III.VII.45). Thus, while a two-part tariff <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry may bean equilibrium strategy, as predicted by economic <strong>the</strong>ory, uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty (comb<strong>in</strong>ed with o<strong>the</strong>rentrepreneurial factors) likely delayed its implementation.Interview DataThis paper <strong>in</strong>corporates qualitative data from <strong>in</strong>terviews that were conducted with variousemployees at a U.S. network carrier <strong>in</strong> January 2010. The research <strong>in</strong>volved seven personnelwork<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> positions related to corporate plann<strong>in</strong>g, revenue management, and productdevelopment. Participants were <strong>in</strong>terviewed <strong>in</strong> person at <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s headquarters to obta<strong>in</strong>qualitative data about <strong>the</strong> history of <strong>the</strong> ancillary revenue trend <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry, key driversof this phenomenon, economic considerations <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e makes with regards to a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g,specific experiences at <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e, and o<strong>the</strong>r factors. Interviews followed <strong>the</strong> general <strong>in</strong>terviewguide format: similar general questions were asked to each <strong>in</strong>terviewee (some were omittedbased on his/her area of knowledge), with different follow-up questions asked based on <strong>the</strong>responses. All <strong>in</strong>terviewees are granted anonymity <strong>in</strong> this paper, as is <strong>the</strong> carrier itself. Thiscondition was necessary to ensure that <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e would participate <strong>in</strong> this research.To identify participants will<strong>in</strong>g to participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> study, <strong>the</strong> author contacted anemployee at <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e who set up <strong>the</strong> discussions with relevant personnel. Because of thisarrangement, <strong>the</strong> selection of participants cannot be considered a random sample, and thuscannot be used for any def<strong>in</strong>itive conclusions about a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g at that carrier or at o<strong>the</strong>rs.16


Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, because <strong>the</strong> responses came exclusively from participants work<strong>in</strong>g at a s<strong>in</strong>glenetwork carrier, f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs from <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terviews alone may ignore key considerations for LCCs andcannot be generally applied to <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry as a whole.None<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong> responses are still useful to build <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>oretical framework that isdiscussed <strong>in</strong> this paper. Interview responses were used to guide research <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong>ories that arerelevant for analyz<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> ancillary revenue movement. While no def<strong>in</strong>itive conclusions can bedrawn, <strong>the</strong>se f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs represent a first step to apply<strong>in</strong>g economic <strong>the</strong>ory to airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ a-la-cartepric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>itiatives.In-depth discussions of <strong>the</strong> key f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs from <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terviews will be discussed <strong>in</strong> fur<strong>the</strong>rdetail throughout <strong>the</strong> follow<strong>in</strong>g sections, as <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>oretical framework is discussed. Some broadcategories of discussion are worth not<strong>in</strong>g at this po<strong>in</strong>t, however. First, with regards to <strong>the</strong> centralquestion of this paper, <strong>in</strong>terviewees discussed a number of drivers that resulted <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> tim<strong>in</strong>g of<strong>the</strong> ancillary revenue movement. Nearly all <strong>in</strong>terviewees discussed <strong>the</strong> key role of pressures togenerate revenues dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> 2000s, along with <strong>the</strong> roles of ris<strong>in</strong>g costs and a general <strong>in</strong>ability toraise fares to a level that provided f<strong>in</strong>ancial viability.Many <strong>in</strong>terviewees discussed <strong>the</strong> carrier‘s limited experience with some early ancillaryproduct offer<strong>in</strong>gs that provided encouragement to <strong>in</strong>stitute bag fees. Ano<strong>the</strong>r driver appeared tobe technological changes—such as <strong>the</strong> ability to provide onl<strong>in</strong>e book<strong>in</strong>gs and self-servicesecurity kiosks—along with stricter security measures follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> September 11th terroristattacks. There was some disagreement among <strong>in</strong>terviewees to what extent ris<strong>in</strong>g fuel pricesspecifically triggered <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitution of checked bag fee charges by rais<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>al cost oftransport<strong>in</strong>g a bag. Most <strong>in</strong>terviewees also spoke, ei<strong>the</strong>r directly or <strong>in</strong>directly, to <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong>ancillary revenue movement was largely an emergent phenomenon, aris<strong>in</strong>g from an17


entrepreneurial awareness that a multi-part pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangement could be used to raise revenuesand more efficiently differentiate customers based on <strong>the</strong>ir will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay for certa<strong>in</strong>ancillary services.Some discussion took place about <strong>the</strong> existence of a first-mover problem by which firms<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry were reluctant to bear potentially uncerta<strong>in</strong> costs of unbundl<strong>in</strong>g and reluctant tooffer ancillary services for fear that <strong>the</strong> costs would outweigh <strong>the</strong> benefits. Interviewees po<strong>in</strong>tedto relatively long lags <strong>in</strong> firms decid<strong>in</strong>g whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y would <strong>in</strong>stitute bag fees, and <strong>the</strong> carrier‘sown <strong>in</strong>-depth analysis to determ<strong>in</strong>e whe<strong>the</strong>r charg<strong>in</strong>g bag fees would be worthwhile. In a similarve<strong>in</strong>, <strong>in</strong>terviews touched upon <strong>the</strong> competitive nature of <strong>the</strong> ancillary revenue trend. Participantsalso mentioned that ancillary revenues could help provide ano<strong>the</strong>r dimension upon which airl<strong>in</strong>escan compete and reduce <strong>the</strong>ir position as providers of a commodity-type product.Interviewees agreed that unbundl<strong>in</strong>g and new a-la-carte products have paid off for <strong>the</strong>airl<strong>in</strong>e, exceed<strong>in</strong>g expectations <strong>in</strong> many areas. None<strong>the</strong>less, multiple discussions po<strong>in</strong>ted topotential challenges to offer products and services that fit with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s brand and providesometh<strong>in</strong>g that is value-added for customers. Some <strong>in</strong>terviewees also said that bag fees lead to amore equitable fee structure by which customers who do not check bags no longer subsidize <strong>the</strong>costs attributed to those who do check bags. While such claim implies that baggage fees (ando<strong>the</strong>r a-la-carte <strong>in</strong>itiatives) put downward pressure on fares, a number of <strong>in</strong>terviewees doubtedthat this was <strong>the</strong> case, likely due to <strong>the</strong> lack of a visible drop <strong>in</strong> fares follow<strong>in</strong>g unbundl<strong>in</strong>g. Two<strong>in</strong>terviewees said, however, that ancillary revenues would likely drive down base air fares <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>future.Multiple <strong>in</strong>terviewees discussed how a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g motivates improvements <strong>in</strong>product quality for consumers, but that such improvements are more likely for onboard products18


(such as food) than for checked baggage. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong>re is evidence that customers do notappear to be as outraged by additional fees as might be portrayed <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> media, judg<strong>in</strong>g by salesbe<strong>in</strong>g generated from ancillary services, but that customers seem to have difficulty separat<strong>in</strong>gnew product <strong>in</strong>itiatives from unbundl<strong>in</strong>g.Look<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> future, all <strong>in</strong>terviewees <strong>in</strong>dicated that ancillary revenues will rema<strong>in</strong> apermanent part of <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e bus<strong>in</strong>ess model, and that current holdouts (namely, SouthwestAirl<strong>in</strong>es) would likely adopt policies such as checked baggage fees <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> future. There appearedto be <strong>in</strong>dications that a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g may fundamentally change <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e pric<strong>in</strong>g model bymotivat<strong>in</strong>g carriers to fill planes at lower base fares if <strong>the</strong>y are able to generate enough ancillaryrevenues associated with <strong>the</strong> flight (similar to a cruise ship fill<strong>in</strong>g rooms at low prices to reapadditional onboard revenue). F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>the</strong>re was widespread opposition to potential government<strong>in</strong>tervention to curtail fees and charges. Most responders seemed to <strong>in</strong>dicate that similar practicesare allowed <strong>in</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>dustries, and that limitations, along with onerous taxes on <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry,would fur<strong>the</strong>r tie airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ hands.19


Chapter 1 ReferencesAdams, William James and Yellen, Janet L. 1976. ―Commodity Bundl<strong>in</strong>g and <strong>the</strong> Burden ofMonopoly.‖ The Quarterly Journal of Economics. Vol. 90, No. 3, pp. 475-498.Brady, Jennifer. 2005. ―Data Review: Employment <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>Industry</strong>.‖ Journal ofTransportation and Statistics.Vol. 8, No. 1, available athttp://www.bts.gov/publications/journal_of_transportation_and_statistics/volume_08_number_01/html/data_review/<strong>in</strong>dex.html.Brueckner, Jan K. 2002. ―Airport Congestion When Carriers Have Market Power.‖ TheAmerican Economic Review. Vol. 92, No. 5, pp. 1357-1375.Brumelle, Shelby & Walczak, Darius. 2003. ―Dynamic Airl<strong>in</strong>e Revenue Management withMultiple Semi-Markov Demand.‖ Operations Research. Vol. 51, No. 1, pp. 137-148.Button, Kenneth. 2005. ―The Economics of Cost Recovery <strong>in</strong> Transport: Introduction.‖ Journalof Transport Economics and Policy. Vol. 39, No. 3, at 241-257.Carlton, Dennis W. & Perloff, Jeffrey M. 2005. Modern Industrial Organization: Fourth Edition.Boston: Pearson/Addison Wesley.Carey, Susan. 2008. ―Ano<strong>the</strong>r Reason Not to Overpack.‖ The Wall Street Journal onl<strong>in</strong>e.February 5, available at http://onl<strong>in</strong>e.wsj.com/article/SB120215479391841875.html.Chiang, Wen-Chyuan, Chen, Jason C.H., & Xu, Xiaoj<strong>in</strong>g. 2006. ―An Overview of Research onRevenue Management: Current Issues and Future Research.‖ International Journal ofRevenue Management. Vol.1, No. 1, pp. 97-128.Gifford, Sharon. 1992. ―Allocation of Entrepreneurial Attention.‖ Journal of Economic Behaviorand Organization, Vol. 19, pp. 265-284.20


Goetz, Andrew R. & Vowles, Timothy M. 2009. ―The Good, <strong>the</strong> Bad, and <strong>the</strong> Ugly: 30 Years ofUS Airl<strong>in</strong>e Deregulation.‖ Journal of Transport Geography. Vol. 17, pp. 251-263.Kirzner, Israel M. 1973. Competition and Entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of ChicagoPress.Knight, Frank H. 1921. Risk, Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty, and Profit. Library of Economics and Liberty,accessed 25 March 2010, available athttp://www.econlib.org/library/Knight/knRUP1.html.Locay, Luis & Rodriguez, Alvaro. 1992. ―Price Discrim<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>in</strong> Competitive Markets.‖ TheJournal of Political Economy. Vol. 100, No. 5, pp. 954-965.Matutes, Carmen & Regibeau, Pierre. 1992. ―Compatibility and Bundl<strong>in</strong>g of ComplementaryGoods <strong>in</strong> a Duopoly.‖ The Journal of Industrial Economics. Vol. 40, No. 1, at 37-54.Maynard, Michel<strong>in</strong>e. 2008. ―Like American, More Airl<strong>in</strong>es Add Fees for Check<strong>in</strong>g Luggage.‖The New York Times Onl<strong>in</strong>e, June 13.Morrison, Steven A. & W<strong>in</strong>ston, Clifford. 1989. ―Airl<strong>in</strong>e Deregulation and Public Policy.‖Science. Vol. 245, No. 4919, pp.707-711.Murphy, Michael. 1977. ―Price Discrim<strong>in</strong>ation, Market Separation, and <strong>the</strong> Multi-Part Tariff.‖Economic Inquiry. Vol. 15, pp. 587-599.Oi, Walter Y. 1971. ―A Disneyland Dilemma: Two-Part Tariffs for a Mickey Mouse Monopoly.‖The Quarterly Journal of Economics. Vol. 85, No. 1, pp. 77-96.Perry, Motty. 1984. ―Susta<strong>in</strong>able Positive Profit Multiple-Price Strategies <strong>in</strong> ContestableMarkets.‖ Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 32, pp. 246-265.Shane, Scott & Venkataraman, S. 2000. ―The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field ofResearch.‖ The Academy of Management Review. Vol. 25, No. 1, pp. 217-226.21


Sharkey, Joe. 2001. ―Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Travel: In a Sign of Desperate Times, Many Airl<strong>in</strong>es on Many ofTheir Flights Will Serve no Meals.‖ The New York Times, October 24, p. C6.Sharkey, Joe. 2003. ―On The Road: Two Airl<strong>in</strong>es Are Test<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> Concept of Sell<strong>in</strong>g MealsAloft.‖ The New York Times. January 7, p. C6.Schmalensee, Richard. 1984. ―Gaussian Demand and Commodity Bundl<strong>in</strong>g.‖ The Journal ofBus<strong>in</strong>ess. Vol. 57, No. 1, pp. S211-S230.Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1947. ―The Creative Response <strong>in</strong> Economic History.‖The Journal ofEconomic History. Vol. 7, No. 2, pp. 149-159.Smith, Barry C., Leimkuhler, John F., & Darrow, Ross M. 1992. ―Yield Management atAmerican Airl<strong>in</strong>es.‖ Interfaces. Vol. 22, No. 1, pp. 8-31.Stigler, George. 1963. ―A Note on Block Book<strong>in</strong>g.‖ Supreme Court Review, pp. 152-157.Sorensen, Jay. 2009. The Guide to Ancillary Revenue and A <strong>La</strong> <strong>Carte</strong> <strong>Pric<strong>in</strong>g</strong>. Idea Works.Vietor, Richard H.K. 1990. ―Contrived Competition: Airl<strong>in</strong>e Regulation and Deregulation, 1925-1988.‖ The Bus<strong>in</strong>ess History Review. Vol. 64, No. 1, pp. 61-108.22


Chapter 2: Why, and Why Now? The Theory and Drivers Beh<strong>in</strong>d <strong>the</strong> Ancillary RevenueMovementWith an extensive menu of pric<strong>in</strong>g options from which to choose, an airl<strong>in</strong>e hasconsiderable leeway <strong>in</strong> determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g its pric<strong>in</strong>g structure as part of its bus<strong>in</strong>ess strategy. Dur<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> 2000s, however, a number of airl<strong>in</strong>es concurrently adopted a strategy based on unbundl<strong>in</strong>gcerta<strong>in</strong> product attributes from <strong>the</strong> fare and built a bus<strong>in</strong>ess model <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly based on a-lacartepric<strong>in</strong>g and ancillary revenue.This chapter will address relevant economic <strong>the</strong>ory, applied to <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ experience <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> 2000s, that expla<strong>in</strong>s why this new pric<strong>in</strong>g paradigm became prom<strong>in</strong>ent with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry.The first part of this chapter is devoted to a discussion of static economic <strong>the</strong>ory that expla<strong>in</strong>sairl<strong>in</strong>es‘ rationale <strong>in</strong> us<strong>in</strong>g a multi-part pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangement and why this has emerged as anequilibrium <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry. In addition to this ―why‖ discussion, <strong>the</strong> chapter will also present adiscussion of <strong>the</strong> dynamic changes that have occurred <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry and lie beh<strong>in</strong>d multipleairl<strong>in</strong>es‘ a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>itiatives. This second section will discuss <strong>the</strong> ―why now‖ element ofa-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g to expla<strong>in</strong> why <strong>the</strong> ancillary revenue movement <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>es occurred <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>2000s.Why? Two-Part Tariffs as an <strong>Industry</strong> EquilibriumTwo airl<strong>in</strong>e customers are seldom identical. Whereas fly<strong>in</strong>g was once a luxury onlyaccorded to higher-<strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>dividuals, an airplane flight today conta<strong>in</strong>s a cross section ofbus<strong>in</strong>ess travelers, college students, pleasure seekers, and work<strong>in</strong>g-class families. The effects ofderegulation, which opened up <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry to price competition as well as technological<strong>in</strong>novations, have driven <strong>the</strong> real price of air travel down dramatically over <strong>the</strong> past 30 years.23


Between 1993 and 2007 alone, average domestic one-way fares fell from around $300 to $220 <strong>in</strong>real terms (Goetz and Vowles 2009, 257). With lower prices, airl<strong>in</strong>es now face a broad customerbase composed of <strong>in</strong>dividuals with a variety of tastes and preferences.Even prior to <strong>the</strong> ancillary revenue movement, airl<strong>in</strong>e pric<strong>in</strong>g techniques were developedto differentiate among different types of consumers. For example, before <strong>the</strong> 2000s (though it hasmade a comeback <strong>in</strong> recent months), airl<strong>in</strong>es offered discount fares to travelers that stayed at<strong>the</strong>ir dest<strong>in</strong>ation dur<strong>in</strong>g a Saturday night. This practice ultimately served as price discrim<strong>in</strong>ationtechnique to ensure that customers with high valuation of time and high will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay—usually non-leisure bus<strong>in</strong>ess travelers—would not receive <strong>the</strong> deepest discounts (Gale & Holmes1993, 144). Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, fewer discount seats are offered dur<strong>in</strong>g peak times when <strong>the</strong> most timesensitivecustomers would want to arrive and depart.While such pric<strong>in</strong>g techniques are aimed at pric<strong>in</strong>g differently based on consumerreservation prices and extract<strong>in</strong>g additional consumer surplus for <strong>the</strong> base fare, a basic evaluationof <strong>the</strong> travel experience <strong>in</strong>dicates that <strong>the</strong>re may be additional opportunities for pricedifferentiation. Historically, airl<strong>in</strong>es have not solely been <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess of provid<strong>in</strong>g passengerswith a seat from po<strong>in</strong>t A to po<strong>in</strong>t B: once passengers are onboard, airl<strong>in</strong>es have provided mealsand snacks, dr<strong>in</strong>ks, and enterta<strong>in</strong>ment. The existence of various cab<strong>in</strong> classes of service—first,bus<strong>in</strong>ess, premium economy, or economy—represents an effort to extract additional surplus fromconsumers with high will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay for additional features.Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, airl<strong>in</strong>es may be able to benefit from market power once <strong>the</strong> passenger isonboard <strong>the</strong> aircraft to engage <strong>in</strong> price differentiation. Economic <strong>the</strong>ory dictates that a firm‘sability to differentiate among its customers depends on its ability to exercise market power(Carlton & Perloff 2005, 294). As discussed earlier <strong>in</strong> relation to Oi‘s (1971) paper about an24


amusement park‘s monopoly position, an airl<strong>in</strong>e has some ability to serve as a monopolist once<strong>the</strong> aircraft doors have been closed. Additionally, <strong>the</strong> only place an airl<strong>in</strong>e customer can obta<strong>in</strong>checked luggage service is from <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e from which <strong>the</strong> ticket is bought; to date, compet<strong>in</strong>gairl<strong>in</strong>es or o<strong>the</strong>r shipp<strong>in</strong>g firms do not offer to take any customer‘s bag before flight and return itright after.Despite a limited monopoly position and certa<strong>in</strong> aspects of price differentiation via cab<strong>in</strong>class, prior to unbundl<strong>in</strong>g and a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>re may have been numerous opportunities tocapture additional customer revenues, and some of <strong>the</strong>se opportunities may still exist. Teichert etal. analyze <strong>the</strong> stated preference data of 5,800 airl<strong>in</strong>e customers and f<strong>in</strong>d that customersegmentation by cab<strong>in</strong> class alone does not fully capture customers‘ preference heterogeneity.Instead, <strong>the</strong>y suggest airl<strong>in</strong>es should use additional product attributes to more effectively targetvary<strong>in</strong>g customer will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay (Teichert et al. 2008, 239–240).As shown by Teichert et al., customer heterogeneity gives airl<strong>in</strong>es a variety of options todifferentiate through different onboard products. From a strategic standpo<strong>in</strong>t, airl<strong>in</strong>es facecustomers who are spatially distributed along a sort of preference map for <strong>the</strong> air travelexperience. A key consideration an airl<strong>in</strong>e must make, <strong>the</strong>refore, is what sort of pric<strong>in</strong>garrangement and what sort of products it should offer to target customers that are located <strong>in</strong>different positions along a distribution of tastes for onboard product attributes.In such a way, an airl<strong>in</strong>e fac<strong>in</strong>g a distribution of customer taste experiences a situationsimilar to <strong>the</strong> one outl<strong>in</strong>ed by Hotell<strong>in</strong>g (1929) <strong>in</strong> his paper about duopolistic competition forspatially distributed customers. Hotell<strong>in</strong>g considered <strong>the</strong> decision that a firm would make <strong>in</strong>differentiat<strong>in</strong>g itself to capture <strong>the</strong> greatest amount of revenue from consumers uniformlydistributed along a l<strong>in</strong>ear space (he spoke of a ma<strong>in</strong> street <strong>in</strong> a town). He found that a firm <strong>in</strong>25


such a scenario faces strong <strong>in</strong>centives to position itself <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> center of <strong>the</strong> distribution tocapture as many consumers as possible from <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r firm. Despite a potential <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> totalwelfare if each firm positions itself at oppos<strong>in</strong>g quarters of <strong>the</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e, thus reduc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> distanceconsumers would have to travel, this outcome is untenable given each firm‘s <strong>in</strong>centives.Hotell<strong>in</strong>g po<strong>in</strong>ts out that real-world firms compet<strong>in</strong>g for customers distributed <strong>in</strong> a qualityspace validate his <strong>the</strong>ory: ―Buyers are confronted everywhere with an excessive sameness. Whena new merchant or manufacturer sets up shop he must not produce someth<strong>in</strong>g exactly like what isalready on <strong>the</strong> market. . . . But <strong>the</strong>re is an <strong>in</strong>centive to make <strong>the</strong> new product very much like <strong>the</strong>old, apply<strong>in</strong>g some slight change which will seem an improvement to as many buyers as possiblewithout ever go<strong>in</strong>g far <strong>in</strong> this direction‖ (54).Each airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s choice <strong>in</strong> product offer<strong>in</strong>gs can often be found to exhibit a number ofqualities of ―sameness‖ to <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry standard—most airl<strong>in</strong>es have similar seat pitch, similarcab<strong>in</strong> class offer<strong>in</strong>gs, etc. Hotell<strong>in</strong>g‘s classic model is, of course, an abstraction, especially due toa number of constra<strong>in</strong>ts on <strong>the</strong> model (such as normally distributed consumers and a one-productduopoly market). Salop (1979) elaborates on <strong>the</strong> Hotell<strong>in</strong>g model by position<strong>in</strong>g multiple firmson an <strong>in</strong>f<strong>in</strong>ite l<strong>in</strong>e or unit circle and adds ano<strong>the</strong>r outside commodity to <strong>the</strong> economy. Salop f<strong>in</strong>dsthat, <strong>in</strong> a similar manner to Hotell<strong>in</strong>g‘s model, a firm faces low <strong>in</strong>centive to provide productvariety relative to <strong>the</strong> social optimum (152). This leaves customers worse off than <strong>the</strong>y o<strong>the</strong>rwisecould have been <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> total welfare-maximiz<strong>in</strong>g sett<strong>in</strong>g.While airl<strong>in</strong>es may face spatially distributed customers, unlike <strong>the</strong> firms <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hotell<strong>in</strong>gand Salop models, <strong>the</strong>y do not charge constant per-unit prices for air travel. Ra<strong>the</strong>r than a l<strong>in</strong>earpric<strong>in</strong>g arrangement, airl<strong>in</strong>es charge different prices based on distance flown, time of day, and avariety of o<strong>the</strong>r supply and demand factors. A carrier‘s fares do not necessarily exhibit a l<strong>in</strong>ear26


elationship: a flight that covers twice <strong>the</strong> distance as ano<strong>the</strong>r will not necessarily cost twice asmuch (for example, a flight from New York to Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C. can often cost as much as aflight from New York to <strong>La</strong>s Vegas). Given <strong>the</strong>se non-l<strong>in</strong>ear price arrangements and a spatialdistribution of customers, what sort of pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangements can be expected?Armstrong and Vickers (2001) develop a framework for analyz<strong>in</strong>g situations <strong>in</strong> whichfirms with non-l<strong>in</strong>ear pric<strong>in</strong>g compete by offer<strong>in</strong>g ―deals‖ such as tariffs, bundles of outputs, etc.In a similar fashion to Hotell<strong>in</strong>g‘s location model, Armstrong and Vickers‘ model positionsconsumers with<strong>in</strong> a utility space, where consumers differ <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir tastes for <strong>the</strong> product attributessupplied by firms. One of <strong>the</strong> key dist<strong>in</strong>ctions allow<strong>in</strong>g for analysis of <strong>the</strong> effects of non-l<strong>in</strong>earpric<strong>in</strong>g is <strong>the</strong> fact that, <strong>in</strong>stead of analyz<strong>in</strong>g changes <strong>in</strong> consumers transportation costs per unit ofproduct consumed (<strong>the</strong> costs that consumers bear by mov<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>the</strong>ir position to purchase froma given firm), <strong>the</strong> authors‘ utility space <strong>in</strong>volves a transport cost per product. In many ways, thistransport cost per product can be likened to an airl<strong>in</strong>e consumer‘s costs of mov<strong>in</strong>g away from herideal for an onboard product to buy <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s offer<strong>in</strong>g.Armstong and Vickers analyze a competitive situation where customers haveheterogeneous tastes accord<strong>in</strong>g to some characteristic that is unobservable by firms. Under <strong>the</strong>seconditions, <strong>the</strong>y f<strong>in</strong>d that two-part tariffs based on marg<strong>in</strong>al costs emerge as an equilibriumstrategy for each firm <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> market. A later paper by <strong>the</strong> authors (2008) shows this result to be aunique equilibrium. Their result arises out of <strong>the</strong> authors‘ demonstration that under a Hotell<strong>in</strong>gmodel, two-part tariffs emerge as an equilibrium solution for both firms because <strong>the</strong> firm is ableto effectively charge more to those who are spatially located closer and less to those locatedfar<strong>the</strong>r away, thus cater<strong>in</strong>g to various groups of customers (Armstrong & Vickers 2001, 589).When customers exhibit some sort of unknowable private <strong>in</strong>formation, so long as it is27


uncorrelated with <strong>the</strong>ir spatial location, firms must assume a uniform distribution of customersand revert to <strong>the</strong> Hotell<strong>in</strong>g solution (600).The example presented by Armstrong and Vickers is, of course, a stylized model thatonly compares a situation of duopoly competition. While on certa<strong>in</strong> routes, competition mayonly consist of two air carriers, for <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry overall, <strong>the</strong>re are a number of airl<strong>in</strong>es compet<strong>in</strong>gfor customers and market share. Despite its shortcom<strong>in</strong>gs, however, <strong>the</strong> Armstrong and Vickersanalysis gets at <strong>the</strong> heart of expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g an airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s use of a two-part pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangement tofur<strong>the</strong>r differentiate among consumers who have heterogeneous preferences. Some consumersare located ―far away‖ from an airl<strong>in</strong>e that provides baggage check, meals, and o<strong>the</strong>r ancillaryservices, mean<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>the</strong>y have little use for such services and can go to o<strong>the</strong>r airl<strong>in</strong>es closer to<strong>the</strong>ir ideal. These consumers have high costs associated with mov<strong>in</strong>g away from <strong>the</strong>ir ideal po<strong>in</strong>t;<strong>the</strong>se costs are likened to transport costs <strong>in</strong> Hotell<strong>in</strong>g-type models. Conversely, o<strong>the</strong>r consumersare ―close‖ to <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s product offer<strong>in</strong>gs. A s<strong>in</strong>gle price fails to extract <strong>the</strong> additionalrevenues that can be taken from <strong>the</strong> close customers who exhibit higher will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay for<strong>the</strong> service, as it must be lowered to attract <strong>the</strong> far away consumer. These consumers are lesswill<strong>in</strong>g to pay for ancillary products and services and are more will<strong>in</strong>g to undertake travel when<strong>the</strong> entry price is dropped.In a later paper, Armstrong and Vickers argue that <strong>the</strong> equilibrium fixed fee under <strong>the</strong>two-part tariff balances <strong>the</strong> firm‘s loss of profit on exist<strong>in</strong>g consumers aga<strong>in</strong>st its ga<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>profitable consumers from <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r firm (Armstrong & Vickers 2010). This commentunderscores <strong>the</strong> role that that two-part pric<strong>in</strong>g and unbundl<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> context of <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e<strong>in</strong>dustry plays. By be<strong>in</strong>g able to charge a base fare separate from fixed baggage fees, <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>ecan appeal to price sensitive customers who may be close to select<strong>in</strong>g ano<strong>the</strong>r while still28


ecoup<strong>in</strong>g additional revenues from those customers who strongly prefer onboard ancillaryservices.A number of <strong>in</strong>terviews at <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e po<strong>in</strong>t to <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> decision to engage <strong>in</strong> a-lacartepric<strong>in</strong>g is <strong>in</strong> fact an attempt to deal with vary<strong>in</strong>g consumer valuation for ancillary productsand services. As one <strong>in</strong>terviewee said, ―I th<strong>in</strong>k [a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g] is a constant balanc<strong>in</strong>g actaround how . . . you f<strong>in</strong>d someth<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>the</strong> customer values and is will<strong>in</strong>g to pay for versus itssometh<strong>in</strong>g that not only do <strong>the</strong>y not value but . . . also someth<strong>in</strong>g that costs us a lot of money.‖Ano<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>terviewee echoed this rationale: ―I th<strong>in</strong>k that I would say that airl<strong>in</strong>es have, you know,for a long period of time before this realized that <strong>the</strong>y were provid<strong>in</strong>g services that had very highcosts associated with <strong>the</strong>m that were not necessarily appreciated by <strong>the</strong> passengers andappreciated by some passengers and not o<strong>the</strong>rs. It didn‘t seem like a good bus<strong>in</strong>ess model to be<strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>.‖In discuss<strong>in</strong>g price differentiation, ano<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>terviewee mentioned an aspect perta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g tocustomers‘ elasticity of demand at different parts of <strong>the</strong> purchase process. ―We joke about this,but anybody who travels knows that vacation dollars are worth less than regular dollars,‖ <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>terviewee said. ―When you‘re on your way to Hawaii, you make a lot of different decisionsthan if you‘re <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> home search<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> Internet for <strong>the</strong> lowest fares.‖ From <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>oreticalperspective outl<strong>in</strong>ed above, a customer‘s preference <strong>the</strong>n may not only be spatially distributedbut also may also exhibit some sort of time dimension. Thus consumers at <strong>the</strong> time of travel mayhave <strong>the</strong>ir ideal preference shift closer to <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s product offer<strong>in</strong>gs, fur<strong>the</strong>r allow<strong>in</strong>g forextract<strong>in</strong>g consumer surplus through a two-part pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangement that levies additional feesfor services offered dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> travel experience. This separate pric<strong>in</strong>g time gives airl<strong>in</strong>es an29


additional price differentiation dimension relative to o<strong>the</strong>r firms us<strong>in</strong>g two-part tariffs, such asamusement parks and movie <strong>the</strong>aters.Why Now? Drivers and Tim<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong> Ancillary Revenue MovementAs proposed <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> section above, a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry is a stableequilibrium aris<strong>in</strong>g from customer heterogeneity and distribution <strong>in</strong> a spatial framework. So longas duopolistic firms <strong>in</strong> such a situation employ non-l<strong>in</strong>ear pric<strong>in</strong>g, Armstrong and Vickers predictthat a two-part tariff will emerge as a stable equilibrium <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry. If two-part tariffs and a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g are profitable strategies for airl<strong>in</strong>es, given vary<strong>in</strong>g customer preferences anddifferent valuations of ancillary services, <strong>the</strong>re rema<strong>in</strong>s an additional nagg<strong>in</strong>g question: why haveairl<strong>in</strong>es waited until <strong>the</strong> 2000s to implement a bus<strong>in</strong>ess model focused on ancillary revenueswhen <strong>the</strong>y have had pric<strong>in</strong>g freedom s<strong>in</strong>ce deregulation?Though <strong>in</strong>terviewees broadly discussed conditions endemic to <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry as awhole, <strong>in</strong>terview data can only be assumed to apply to that air carrier alone. None<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong>sedata can be comb<strong>in</strong>ed with <strong>in</strong>dustry facts and economic <strong>the</strong>ory to build a model of why airl<strong>in</strong>esmight not have adopted an a-la-carte model earlier. Ultimately, it appears as if <strong>the</strong>re are fourprimary rationales for this observed delay: revenue pressure from excess capacity and low-costcarrier (LCC) competition, technological and exogenous changes, <strong>the</strong> role of entrepreneurialattention, and solv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> first-mover problem.Revenue Pressure from Excess Capacity and LCC CompetitionThe clearest conclusion from <strong>in</strong>terviewees was that a struggle to raise revenues was <strong>the</strong>pr<strong>in</strong>cipal reason why airl<strong>in</strong>es began unbundl<strong>in</strong>g certa<strong>in</strong> products and services—most prom<strong>in</strong>ently30


aggage fees—and look<strong>in</strong>g for o<strong>the</strong>r avenues for <strong>in</strong>stitut<strong>in</strong>g new products and services <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>2000s. This pressure <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> 2000s came from two pr<strong>in</strong>cipal sources. Follow<strong>in</strong>g a time of modest<strong>in</strong>dustry profits <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> late 1990s (Doganis 2002, 18–19), <strong>the</strong> September 11th terrorist attacksresulted <strong>in</strong> weak demand for commercial air travel. Ito and Lee estimate that <strong>the</strong> terrorist attacksresulted <strong>in</strong> a negative demand shock of 37.8 percent <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> month after <strong>the</strong> attacks (87), as well asan ongo<strong>in</strong>g drop <strong>in</strong> demand of 7.4 percent through 200 (89). With<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> four days follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>attacks, <strong>the</strong> Air Transport Association estimated that airl<strong>in</strong>es lost $1.4 billion due to <strong>the</strong>shutdown of <strong>the</strong> national air transportation system, and <strong>in</strong>dustry losses <strong>in</strong> 2001 totaled more than$7 billion due to <strong>the</strong> drop <strong>in</strong> passenger demand (Mak<strong>in</strong>en 2002, 30).While September 11th can be viewed largely as an exogenous shock, <strong>the</strong>re are alsoendogenous factors that exacerbated <strong>the</strong> pressures to generate more revenues. Rid<strong>in</strong>g a wave of<strong>in</strong>creased profitability <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> late 1990s, a number of legacy carriers entered <strong>the</strong> 2000s wi<strong>the</strong>xtremely high costs relative to o<strong>the</strong>r airl<strong>in</strong>es, largely due to high employee wages and restrictivelabor contracts, higher capital costs, a commitment to provid<strong>in</strong>g a number of onboard services(such as onboard meal service), and o<strong>the</strong>r factors (Morrell 2005, 306–309). This cost differentialis evidenced by <strong>the</strong> fact that while legacy airl<strong>in</strong>es collectively susta<strong>in</strong>ed multi-billion dollarlosses <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> years follow<strong>in</strong>g 2001, <strong>the</strong> LCCs collectively rema<strong>in</strong>ed profitable (Hecker 2005, 7).It is also one of <strong>the</strong> reasons that legacy airl<strong>in</strong>es undertook post-September 11th <strong>in</strong>itiatives to cutfixed costs through efforts such as outsourc<strong>in</strong>g a variety of functions and elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g aircraftweight (and, <strong>in</strong> many cases, associated services) to use less fuel.Follow<strong>in</strong>g an improvement <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry after <strong>the</strong> attacks, airl<strong>in</strong>es aga<strong>in</strong> faced stiffrevenue pressures as fuel expenses <strong>in</strong>creased due to a rise <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> price of petroleum. Between2007 and 2008, <strong>the</strong> average U.S. jet fuel price <strong>in</strong>creased by 37.6 percent, from 216.5 cents per31


gallon to 298 cents per gallon: dur<strong>in</strong>g previous years <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> decade, fuel never rose more than51.9 cents per gallon from one year to ano<strong>the</strong>r (ATA 2009). While fuel costs historically madeup 10 to 15 percent of passenger airl<strong>in</strong>e operat<strong>in</strong>g costs, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> third quarter of 2008 that figurerose to an average of 35 percent (ATA). With fuel costs mostly fixed by exogenous prices(airl<strong>in</strong>es still undertook many efforts to <strong>in</strong>crease fuel efficiency and elim<strong>in</strong>ate unnecessary fuelburn), air carriers faced <strong>in</strong>creased pressure <strong>in</strong> order to generate additional revenues to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>profitable.In basic economic terms, <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry faced two stages of shocks—first, a demandshock resulted <strong>in</strong> decreased demand for air travel, with customers will<strong>in</strong>g to buy less air travel atevery possible price. Second, <strong>the</strong> rise <strong>in</strong> oil prices generated a supply shock, with airl<strong>in</strong>es will<strong>in</strong>gto supply a lower quantity of air travel at every possible price. Classical microeconomic <strong>the</strong>orypredicts that a perfectly competitive market would have responded with: (a) a drop <strong>in</strong> capacityand a lower price for <strong>the</strong> demand shock and (b) a drop <strong>in</strong> capacity and a higher price for <strong>the</strong>supply shock.<strong>Industry</strong> data display trends consistent with this <strong>the</strong>oretical <strong>in</strong>terpretation. Figure 2.1shows U.S. scheduled passenger airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ Available Seat Miles (ASMs) and Revenue PassengerMiles (RPMs) from 1996 to 2009. A sizable drop <strong>in</strong> capacity can be seen between 2001 and 2002,and capacity rema<strong>in</strong>s below trend until <strong>the</strong> mid-2000s. After level<strong>in</strong>g off <strong>in</strong> 2007, capacity aga<strong>in</strong>appears to fall after that year. Figure 2.2 shows domestic average airfares from 1996 to 2009.Immediately follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> September 11th attacks, airfares fell considerably. This low wasfollowed by a gradual <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> fares until 2008, however, when prices rose above <strong>the</strong> pre-2001po<strong>in</strong>t. In 2008, fares began a dramatic decl<strong>in</strong>e, however, likely <strong>in</strong> response to a global economicdownturn.32


Figure 2.1: U.S. Airl<strong>in</strong>es Available Seat Miles (ASMs) and Revenue Passenger Miles(RPMs) 4Figure 2.2: U.S. Airl<strong>in</strong>es Domestic Average Airfares <strong>in</strong> Constant Dollars 54 Source: Bureau of Transportation Statistics T-100 Data, all domestic scheduled passenger service.5 Source: Bureau of Transportation Statistics Orig<strong>in</strong> and Dest<strong>in</strong>ation Survey data, all domestic scheduled passengerservice. Airfares calculated on a round-trip basis or one way if no return is purchased.33


Despite <strong>the</strong>se <strong>in</strong>dications that <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry adjusted to reach equilibrium, numerous<strong>in</strong>terviewees <strong>in</strong>dicated that <strong>the</strong>ir airl<strong>in</strong>e had a will<strong>in</strong>gness to raise fares, but was unable to do sobecause of excess capacity <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> market. Discuss<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> post-September 11th operat<strong>in</strong>g marketspecifically, one <strong>in</strong>terviewee said, ―Clearly <strong>the</strong> supply and demand side equation was out ofwhack. . . . And even throughout <strong>the</strong> high fuel costs for <strong>the</strong> entire decade, I th<strong>in</strong>k that <strong>the</strong>re wasjust too much supply to allow . . . price <strong>in</strong>creases to happen.‖ The employee spoke specificallyabout overcapacity be<strong>in</strong>g driven largely by <strong>the</strong> entry of LCCs and putt<strong>in</strong>g negative pressure onfares, and several o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>terviewees corroborated this claim. The notion of overcapacity <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry has also been widely discussed by <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong>siders and analysts (Clark 2009,Mutzabaugh 2005).Despite some level of consensus that <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry is unable to reach equilibriumbecause of overcapacity, <strong>the</strong>re seems to be no consensus on why this is <strong>the</strong> case. An overcapacityargument <strong>in</strong>dicates that <strong>the</strong>re is some sort of market failure or competitive discrepancy thatprevents a stable equilibrium of <strong>in</strong>dustry supply and demand. Given historically low profitmarg<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry s<strong>in</strong>ce deregulation, it is unlikely that airl<strong>in</strong>es would be<strong>in</strong>centivized to enter <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e market because of <strong>the</strong> promise of high economic profits.Alternatively, core <strong>the</strong>ory seems to provide a compell<strong>in</strong>g explanation as to why <strong>in</strong>dividualairl<strong>in</strong>es struggled to raise fares due to overcapacity.The <strong>the</strong>ory of <strong>the</strong> core <strong>in</strong> economics goes back to Edgeworth, who first analyzed thisconcept <strong>in</strong> 1881 (Telser 1994, 152). The core refers to <strong>the</strong> set of market outcomes that marketparticipants prefer to any possible submarket <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g a subset of traders (154). Thus, <strong>the</strong> coreexists when no market participant has an <strong>in</strong>centive to pursue a deal with any s<strong>in</strong>gle o<strong>the</strong>rparticipant or coalition of participants. This <strong>the</strong>ory also sheds light on situations <strong>in</strong> which market34


participants are unable to reach a pareto-efficient equilibrium. In an empty core situation, <strong>the</strong>terms that market coalitions would be will<strong>in</strong>g to accept cannot be met by <strong>the</strong> market as a whole(155). In an empty core situation, market equilibration requires that a seller drop out of <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>dustry. Do<strong>in</strong>g so, however, raises <strong>the</strong> price above <strong>the</strong> rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g firms‘ m<strong>in</strong>imum average costs.Thus, buyers may compel <strong>the</strong> seller (or ano<strong>the</strong>r) to re-enter <strong>the</strong> market, thus return<strong>in</strong>g it to a stateof disequilibrium (Sjostrom 1993, 421).A number of scholars have applied <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>ory of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>ability to f<strong>in</strong>e-tune supply tosatisfy market demand as a rationale for overcapacity problems <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry. Button(1996) analyzes <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e market <strong>in</strong> Europe, conduct<strong>in</strong>g an empirical analysis to see whe<strong>the</strong>rcompetitors were potentially cooperat<strong>in</strong>g to avoid an empty core. The results from a series ofcross-sectional data from 1990 and analyses of <strong>the</strong> cost structure of <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>gdiscont<strong>in</strong>uities <strong>in</strong> firms‘ marg<strong>in</strong>al costs when <strong>the</strong>y are below average costs, <strong>in</strong>dicate that <strong>the</strong>airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry may exhibit <strong>the</strong> properties of an empty core (286–287). O<strong>the</strong>r authors have alsosuggested <strong>the</strong> presence of an empty core. Antoniou (1998) conducts a test of European marketdata, similar to that of Button, to determ<strong>in</strong>e whe<strong>the</strong>r an empty core, <strong>in</strong>stead of collusion or cartels,expla<strong>in</strong>s mergers <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> European airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry. He f<strong>in</strong>ds a number of statistically significantvariables, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g variability of demand and passenger seat availability be<strong>in</strong>g positivelycorrelated with European airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ traffic shares, po<strong>in</strong>t<strong>in</strong>g toward an empty core <strong>the</strong>ory (51).It rema<strong>in</strong>s unclear whe<strong>the</strong>r a two-part tariff fully resolves an empty core problem <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry or solves for some o<strong>the</strong>r overcapacity problem. It is certa<strong>in</strong>ly plausible that us<strong>in</strong>gtwo-part prices when consumers are heterogeneous could allow for a previously unstablecapacity mix to prevail as an equilibrium solution <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry. Fur<strong>the</strong>r research is needed toascerta<strong>in</strong> whe<strong>the</strong>r a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g solves <strong>the</strong>se issues.35


Despite this open question, it is certa<strong>in</strong> that empty core disequilibrium lead<strong>in</strong>g to excesscapacity would <strong>in</strong>terfere with <strong>the</strong> natural supply and demand dynamics that would allow pricesand capacity to adjust <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> wake of exogenous shocks. Fac<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>ability to set fares at a levelthat would at least allow <strong>the</strong>m to break even, air carriers thus faced additional pressure todiscover o<strong>the</strong>r pric<strong>in</strong>g techniques that would allow <strong>the</strong>m to rema<strong>in</strong> competitive <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>marketplace and earn revenues <strong>the</strong>y were unable to capture through an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> prices.Ano<strong>the</strong>r factor add<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> revenue pressure from <strong>the</strong>se exogenous shocks and perhapscontribut<strong>in</strong>g to overcapacity <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong>volves <strong>the</strong> competitive threat of LCCs. Interviewssuggested that <strong>the</strong> network carrier faced little pressure from LCCs <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1980s and 1990s andwas unsure whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>se carriers would materialize <strong>in</strong>to a significant threat. While long-timeLCC Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>ed profitability throughout <strong>the</strong> 1980s and 1990s, that periodwas marked by <strong>the</strong> failure of several low-cost carriers, such as People Express and PacificSouthwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es. None<strong>the</strong>less, a number of small operations, such as Valujet and VanguardAirl<strong>in</strong>es, also started up <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1990s to utilize <strong>the</strong> low-cost model. As one <strong>in</strong>terviewee said, ―Asyou get through <strong>the</strong> n<strong>in</strong>eties, you get past <strong>the</strong> denial that LCCs will just somehow not be able togrow much because <strong>the</strong>y‘re po<strong>in</strong>t to po<strong>in</strong>t, or whatever <strong>the</strong>y were at <strong>the</strong> time. . . . Clearly <strong>the</strong>yhave a bus<strong>in</strong>ess plan that works and you have to reth<strong>in</strong>k yours.‖As Franke (2005) po<strong>in</strong>ts out, major network carriers did not take <strong>the</strong> LCC threat seriouslyuntil <strong>the</strong> 1990s, and even <strong>the</strong>n, <strong>the</strong>y perceived it as a regional phenomenon restricted to a nichemarket (17). None<strong>the</strong>less, he po<strong>in</strong>ts out that it was actually <strong>the</strong> downturn <strong>in</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e demandfollow<strong>in</strong>g September 11th that actually help <strong>the</strong> LCCs fur<strong>the</strong>r attract previous network carriercustomers who were look<strong>in</strong>g to pay less for air travel (15). As mentioned above, LCCs actuallyrema<strong>in</strong>ed profitable follow<strong>in</strong>g this period while <strong>the</strong> network airl<strong>in</strong>es took heavy losses. It was36


also dur<strong>in</strong>g this time that Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es matured from a regional operator mostly <strong>in</strong>sou<strong>the</strong>rn states <strong>in</strong>to a robust nation-wide operation, and airl<strong>in</strong>es such as JetBlue Airways <strong>in</strong> NewYork and AirTran Airways <strong>in</strong> Atlanta organized significant operations at major airports tocompete directly with network carriers.Thus by <strong>the</strong> 2000s, LCC competition compounded <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r structural shocks affect<strong>in</strong>gnetwork airl<strong>in</strong>es. This new group of leaner competitors only <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>the</strong> pressure on largeairl<strong>in</strong>es to raise additional revenues to rema<strong>in</strong> viable <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> market, a task made even moredifficult by an overcapacity problem that prevented a fare <strong>in</strong>crease to an equilibrium level. Inaddition to putt<strong>in</strong>g pressure on airl<strong>in</strong>es to seek out additional revenue sources, <strong>the</strong> LCC threatalso gave airl<strong>in</strong>es an <strong>in</strong>centive to target ―no-frills‖ travelers ma<strong>in</strong>ly concerned with a low farewhile ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g a high level of onboard service for those customers who valued such offer<strong>in</strong>gs.In total, this pressure created a climate that <strong>in</strong>centivized <strong>in</strong>novation <strong>in</strong> new pric<strong>in</strong>g techniquesthat had previously been ignored.Technological Advances and Airport ChangesWhile certa<strong>in</strong> pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangements may be <strong>the</strong>oretically sound, real-world logistical andoperational factors <strong>in</strong>crease transaction costs that may mitigate ga<strong>in</strong>s from two-part pric<strong>in</strong>g orunbundl<strong>in</strong>g. While offer<strong>in</strong>g goods <strong>in</strong> a s<strong>in</strong>gle package may not allow for price discrim<strong>in</strong>ationtechniques and o<strong>the</strong>r revenue enhancements, separat<strong>in</strong>g different elements of a product can becostly, requir<strong>in</strong>g new techniques to collect revenues, costs to <strong>in</strong>form employees, and new typesof packag<strong>in</strong>g and product presentation.One <strong>in</strong>terviewee spoke broadly about technological barriers that hamperedimplementation of many a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g techniques. The first one dealt with <strong>the</strong> nature of37


transactions at <strong>the</strong> airport. Historically, customers could clear security without a ticket, andobta<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir board<strong>in</strong>g passes at <strong>the</strong> gate beh<strong>in</strong>d <strong>the</strong> security checkpo<strong>in</strong>t. The <strong>in</strong>terviewee said thatbecause of <strong>the</strong> high levels of <strong>the</strong> complexity at airport gates—such as load<strong>in</strong>g and unload<strong>in</strong>gaircraft and respond<strong>in</strong>g to o<strong>the</strong>r customer concerns—this would be an <strong>in</strong>convenient place to givecustomers <strong>the</strong> option to purchase a-la-carte products and services. The <strong>in</strong>terviewee po<strong>in</strong>ted out,―Post-September 11th, everyth<strong>in</strong>g moved forward of security, so customers at least have to havesome sort of piece of paper at that po<strong>in</strong>t of <strong>the</strong> process.‖A technological <strong>in</strong>novation allowed airl<strong>in</strong>es to more easily offer ancillary options topassengers now obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g travel documents beh<strong>in</strong>d <strong>the</strong> security l<strong>in</strong>e: <strong>the</strong> implementation ofautomated check-<strong>in</strong> kiosks. Use of <strong>the</strong>se systems began <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> late 1990s, largely as a way to cutlabor costs. As <strong>the</strong> participant noted, ―This has turned <strong>in</strong>to a pretty efficient place for us to do amarket<strong>in</strong>g transaction. . . . You‘ve already got your credit card <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> mach<strong>in</strong>e, we know who youare, we‘ve matched it up with your reservation record. This is a great opportunity for us to go,‗Oh you know you‘re sitt<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> back of <strong>the</strong> coach cab<strong>in</strong>. Would you like to sit <strong>in</strong> a better seat[for an extra charge]?‘‖ Thus <strong>in</strong>creased automation reduced <strong>the</strong> transaction costs <strong>in</strong>volved withoffer<strong>in</strong>g passengers unbundled products or o<strong>the</strong>r a-la-carte offer<strong>in</strong>gs for <strong>the</strong>ir trip.Ano<strong>the</strong>r technological driver of <strong>the</strong> ancillary revenue movement <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>creasedability of airl<strong>in</strong>es to offer tickets to <strong>the</strong>ir customers directly through <strong>the</strong>ir own websites. Over <strong>the</strong>past several years, <strong>in</strong>creased proportions of customers have been utiliz<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>se websites <strong>in</strong> lieuof onl<strong>in</strong>e travel agents (such as Expedia, Travelocity, etc.) and brick-and-mortar travel agents.Given <strong>the</strong> fact that an airl<strong>in</strong>e may wish to offer customers a wide menu of options, and that suchoptions and prices vary across different customers, <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terviewee said that it was difficult to get<strong>the</strong>se services to list and present a-la-carte options <strong>in</strong> a way that would be streaml<strong>in</strong>ed and38


comprehensible to consumers. Additionally, once a customer is on <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s website, ei<strong>the</strong>r topurchase a ticket or to check <strong>in</strong> for a flight, <strong>the</strong> carrier is able to directly offer ancillary productsand services to <strong>the</strong> customer, provid<strong>in</strong>g an additional sell<strong>in</strong>g opportunity. Thus improved airl<strong>in</strong>ewebsite technologies, and a shift toward <strong>the</strong>se sites, have given <strong>the</strong> carrier more control over<strong>in</strong>form<strong>in</strong>g consumers and offer<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>se products.A f<strong>in</strong>al technological consideration <strong>in</strong>volves transactions that occur onboard <strong>the</strong> aircraftfor products and services offered <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> cab<strong>in</strong> (such as meals). The <strong>in</strong>troduction of a large volumeof transactions onboard <strong>in</strong>evitably requires some form of onboard payment, if customers areallowed to make a choice at <strong>the</strong> po<strong>in</strong>t of purchase (one alternative scenario <strong>in</strong>volves passengerschoos<strong>in</strong>g options such as meals at time of book<strong>in</strong>g, but this may <strong>in</strong>clude an undesirable lag forcustomers). Without credit card reader technology, this <strong>in</strong>evitably means that flight attendantswould need to have large hold<strong>in</strong>gs of cash to make change. Even if such was <strong>the</strong> case,scrambl<strong>in</strong>g to make change may reduce customer utility and <strong>the</strong> onboard experience.A number of <strong>in</strong>terviewees po<strong>in</strong>ted to <strong>the</strong> importance of credit card readers that havebecome more available <strong>in</strong> recent years and ―cashless cab<strong>in</strong>‖ technologies that streaml<strong>in</strong>etransactions by obviat<strong>in</strong>g this need for flight attendants to hold money. As one <strong>in</strong>terviewee said,―Now that everyone‘s go<strong>in</strong>g to cashless (cab<strong>in</strong>s) or putt<strong>in</strong>g credit card readers onboard, basicallythat opens up a whole new world of what you can charge for, so I th<strong>in</strong>k that creates a spacewhere <strong>the</strong>re‘s go<strong>in</strong>g to be even more product <strong>in</strong>novation onboard.‖ The availability of thistechnology has likely driven some of <strong>the</strong> unbundl<strong>in</strong>g efforts <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> realm of food and onboardpurchase.39


The Role of Entrepreneurial AttentionRevenue pressure and technological and o<strong>the</strong>r shifts refer to <strong>the</strong> two dynamic changesthat occurred <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> past 10 years that drove a move toward expanded a-lacartepric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry. None<strong>the</strong>less, even if <strong>the</strong>se factors did not exist, a revenuemaximiz<strong>in</strong>gairl<strong>in</strong>e is always, <strong>in</strong> a sense, revenue pressured, and older technology could haveaccommodated some forms of unbundl<strong>in</strong>g and a-la-carte sell<strong>in</strong>g. Thus, <strong>the</strong>se factors expla<strong>in</strong> whatmade airl<strong>in</strong>es more likely to pursue a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g strategies <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> 2000s, but <strong>the</strong>y do notexpla<strong>in</strong> why air carriers had left unexploited profit opportunities untouched before that time.Based on <strong>in</strong>terview data, <strong>the</strong> best explanation for this seems to lie <strong>in</strong> a consideration of <strong>the</strong>human entrepreneurial element and <strong>the</strong> risk and uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty that underlies many bus<strong>in</strong>essdecisions.As discussed <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> literature review, it is ultimately entrepreneurs who drive bus<strong>in</strong>essdecisions and make decisions on <strong>the</strong> best means to achieve a certa<strong>in</strong> end, based on <strong>in</strong>formation at<strong>the</strong> time. Look<strong>in</strong>g back to <strong>the</strong> post-deregulation era, entrepreneurs‘ attention and awareness wasfocused on capitaliz<strong>in</strong>g on revenue opportunities aris<strong>in</strong>g from a newly obta<strong>in</strong>ed freedom tochoose prices and structure routes.One <strong>in</strong>terviewee po<strong>in</strong>ted to <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong>se efforts at redef<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e routestructure and develop<strong>in</strong>g new yield management <strong>in</strong>novations were <strong>the</strong> most press<strong>in</strong>gopportunities dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> 1980s. As Franke (2005) po<strong>in</strong>ts out, a profitable period <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1990s and<strong>the</strong> progress of computer technology turned <strong>in</strong>dustry attention to network management systemsthat facilitated sophisticated quantitative analyses (15). Franke fur<strong>the</strong>r discusses <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong>development of <strong>the</strong>se mechanized optimization strategies meant that airl<strong>in</strong>es spent <strong>the</strong>irresources on optimiz<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir dest<strong>in</strong>ation and hub portfolio <strong>in</strong> relation to o<strong>the</strong>r carriers (16).40


Interview data also <strong>in</strong>dicate that network optimization and revenue management <strong>in</strong>itiativesrepresented <strong>the</strong> ―low-hang<strong>in</strong>g fruit‖ follow<strong>in</strong>g deregulation. As one <strong>in</strong>terviewee said of <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>novation <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1980s and early 1990s, ―[We were] so busy do<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> th<strong>in</strong>gs right <strong>in</strong> front of usthat are worth so much. How do you stop and say, ‗Hey wait, we should go over here and pickoff this too.‘ You wouldn‘t know to ask <strong>the</strong> question.‖ Thus, from <strong>the</strong> standpo<strong>in</strong>t ofentrepreneurial alertness, which is scarce and can be allocat<strong>in</strong>g to ei<strong>the</strong>r manag<strong>in</strong>g currentbus<strong>in</strong>ess plans or develop<strong>in</strong>g new profit opportunities (Gifford 1992, 276), airl<strong>in</strong>e entrepreneurslikely maximized <strong>the</strong>ir returns by focus<strong>in</strong>g attention on optimiz<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir pric<strong>in</strong>g, revenue, androute strategies.It should be noted that research <strong>in</strong>to unbundl<strong>in</strong>g certa<strong>in</strong> elements began to take place <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> late 1990s and early 2000s, well before a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g became <strong>the</strong> operat<strong>in</strong>g norm formost airl<strong>in</strong>es. One <strong>in</strong>terviewee worked at two o<strong>the</strong>r network carriers previous to his currentairl<strong>in</strong>e and said that two early attempts at a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g around this time, <strong>in</strong> which he was<strong>in</strong>volved, were not found to be profitable bus<strong>in</strong>ess strategies. This fact highlights <strong>the</strong>evolutionary aspect to entrepreneurship: entrepreneurial attention did not focus on <strong>the</strong> potentialfor a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g until o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>novations were exhausted and competition began to grow. Theshocks of September 11th and fuel price <strong>in</strong>creases, as discussed above, focused fur<strong>the</strong>rentrepreneurial effort <strong>in</strong>to develop<strong>in</strong>g new pric<strong>in</strong>g strategies.Additionally, early bus<strong>in</strong>ess decisions <strong>in</strong> response to those shocks gave airl<strong>in</strong>es someexperience and market-tested proof of <strong>the</strong> potential for ancillary revenues. For example,follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> September 11th attacks, carriers faced decisions whe<strong>the</strong>r to cut meals orenhancements to <strong>the</strong>ir cab<strong>in</strong> products that became overly costly <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> new operat<strong>in</strong>genvironment. Examples of such enhancements <strong>in</strong>cluded American Airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ decision to add41


additional legroom throughout its fleet‘s coach cab<strong>in</strong> and United Airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ Economy Plus cab<strong>in</strong>,which offers a cab<strong>in</strong> class between <strong>the</strong>ir coach and bus<strong>in</strong>ess class products.The decision to cut or scale back <strong>the</strong>se products may have provided entrepreneurs with<strong>in</strong>creased awareness to <strong>the</strong> ga<strong>in</strong>s from a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g techniques; recently discont<strong>in</strong>uedproducts provided an opportunity for airl<strong>in</strong>es to experiment with new ancillary products. Forexample, as discussed <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>troduction, many carriers began re<strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g meals and heaviersnacks as part of food-for-purchase programs. And while American Airl<strong>in</strong>es completely didaway with its enhanced legroom product, United Airl<strong>in</strong>es began offer<strong>in</strong>g coach customers accessto Economy Plus for an a-la-carte fee, based on availability. These early forays <strong>in</strong>to a-la-cartepric<strong>in</strong>g likely gave airl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>the</strong> impetus to enact fur<strong>the</strong>r unbundl<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>itiatives and provideduseful experience regard<strong>in</strong>g what sort of ancillary charges would earn revenue for <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>es.The evolv<strong>in</strong>g awareness of profitable unbundl<strong>in</strong>g strategy as a driver of <strong>the</strong> ancillary revenuemovement of <strong>the</strong> 2000s cannot be understated.Solv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> First-Mover ProblemUltimately, <strong>the</strong> only way a firm truly knows <strong>the</strong> outcome of a certa<strong>in</strong> pric<strong>in</strong>g change isthrough a market test. This <strong>in</strong>dicates that <strong>the</strong>re will always be some level of uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty <strong>in</strong>volvedwith a change to <strong>the</strong> pric<strong>in</strong>g structure, as discussed <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> literature review. This uncerta<strong>in</strong>tyabout an emerg<strong>in</strong>g technology or market conditions can spell out a disadvantage for first movers<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry and give late movers a ga<strong>in</strong>, potentially discourag<strong>in</strong>g or delay<strong>in</strong>g adoption of aspecific <strong>in</strong>novation (Lieberman & Montgomery 1988, 47). Ultimately, <strong>the</strong> first mover may riskmonetary or non-monetary losses if market conditions turn out to be less favorable thanorig<strong>in</strong>ally expected; this is tied <strong>in</strong> with <strong>the</strong> fact that o<strong>the</strong>r firms can free ride on <strong>the</strong> risks42


undertaken by <strong>the</strong> first mover. None<strong>the</strong>less, Wernerfelt and Karnani (1987) po<strong>in</strong>t out that certa<strong>in</strong>factors may mitigate <strong>the</strong> reluctance to be <strong>the</strong> first mover, factors such as first-mover advantagesor <strong>the</strong> ability to <strong>in</strong>fluence <strong>the</strong> way that <strong>the</strong> uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty is resolved. Hoppe (2000) formalizes <strong>the</strong>analysis of technological uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty <strong>in</strong> an economic model, show<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>in</strong> equilibrium, <strong>the</strong>second mover has a strategic advantage that arises from observ<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> profitability of <strong>the</strong> firstmover‘s actions (316).Multiple <strong>in</strong>terviewees characterized <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry situation surround<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> decision tounbundle <strong>the</strong> second and first bag fees as hav<strong>in</strong>g elements of a first-mover disadvantage for aircarriers <strong>in</strong> 2008. As one <strong>in</strong>terviewee said, ―First mover tends to carry a pretty big risk, and s<strong>in</strong>ce<strong>the</strong> technology is slow to catch up, [an airl<strong>in</strong>e runs] <strong>the</strong> risk of be<strong>in</strong>g out <strong>the</strong>re for quite a bit oftime. Someone may want to match you today, but <strong>the</strong>ir systems may not enable <strong>the</strong>m to catch upfor six months, a year, weeks. And you‘re k<strong>in</strong>d of tak<strong>in</strong>g it on <strong>the</strong> sh<strong>in</strong> until everyone catches up.‖Ultimately, <strong>in</strong>terviewees said that <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e only felt comfortable charg<strong>in</strong>g bag fees when it wascerta<strong>in</strong> that it could earn revenue from that strategy even <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> case where all o<strong>the</strong>r airl<strong>in</strong>esmoved to a free checked-bag policy.Once aga<strong>in</strong>, even with sound analysis, uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty is still a factor that may limit a firmfrom tak<strong>in</strong>g action. For example, U.S. Airways likely had strong market research and soundanalysis before it <strong>in</strong>stituted a policy of charg<strong>in</strong>g for onboard soft dr<strong>in</strong>ks <strong>in</strong> 2008. None<strong>the</strong>less,amid consumer backlash and no similar fee from o<strong>the</strong>r large network carriers, it withdrew <strong>the</strong>charge several months later. While <strong>the</strong>re is no substitute for a market test, revenue pressure ando<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>centives fac<strong>in</strong>g airl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> 2000s made <strong>the</strong>m more likely to take <strong>the</strong> plunge and bearany potential uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty to reap additional revenue.43


ConclusionThis discussion <strong>in</strong> this chapter outl<strong>in</strong>es a cohesive <strong>the</strong>ory for why most U.S. airl<strong>in</strong>es havemoved toward an ancillary revenue model based on two-part pric<strong>in</strong>g and why this change did notcome about until <strong>the</strong> 2000s. From a <strong>the</strong>oretical perspective, <strong>the</strong> two-part pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangementallows airl<strong>in</strong>es to price differentiate and capture additional revenues from customers withheterogeneous tastes for ancillary products and services. By separat<strong>in</strong>g ancillary fees, an airl<strong>in</strong>eis able to obta<strong>in</strong> additional revenue from consumers who highly value such attributes, while stillattract<strong>in</strong>g customers who prefer not to pay for such additional products and services.While this strategy represents a strategic equilibrium for airl<strong>in</strong>es, entrepreneurialattention was focused on o<strong>the</strong>r aspects of <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e bus<strong>in</strong>ess follow<strong>in</strong>g deregulation such asrevenue management and network plann<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>novations. None<strong>the</strong>less, chang<strong>in</strong>g conditions fromLCC competition and exogenous shocks <strong>in</strong>creased airl<strong>in</strong>e entrepreneurs‘ <strong>in</strong>centives to seek outunbundl<strong>in</strong>g and a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g strategies. Given <strong>the</strong>se <strong>in</strong>centives, and an <strong>in</strong>ability to raisesufficient revenues through fare <strong>in</strong>creases due to excess capacity, entrepreneurs began exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gways to fur<strong>the</strong>r earn revenues from consumers through price differentiation methods.While <strong>the</strong>oretically sound, <strong>the</strong>se pric<strong>in</strong>g techniques came with uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty and potentialfirst mover problems. Given a difficult economic environment and competitive pressure, <strong>the</strong>potential payoffs from ancillary revenue relative to <strong>the</strong> uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty compelled airl<strong>in</strong>es to ―pull <strong>the</strong>trigger‖ and accept uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty associated with mov<strong>in</strong>g to an a-la-carte model.Ultimately, <strong>the</strong> four factors discussed as primary drivers to <strong>the</strong> ancillary revenuemovement comb<strong>in</strong>ed to create <strong>the</strong> ideal conditions for a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g to emerge <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> mid-late2000s. First, <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry was buffeted by shocks that affected airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ balance sheets and left<strong>the</strong>m try<strong>in</strong>g to f<strong>in</strong>d additional sources of revenue. At <strong>the</strong> same time, new technological changes44


made certa<strong>in</strong> pric<strong>in</strong>g mechanisms more feasible than <strong>the</strong>y were <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> past. These factures<strong>in</strong>centivized entrepreneurs to devote additional attention to a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g and ancillaryrevenue <strong>in</strong>itiatives and encouraged <strong>the</strong>m to explore previously unutilized or underutilizedstrategies. Despite some uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty as to <strong>the</strong> best way to proceed, <strong>the</strong> dire circumstances <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>dustry, technological changes, and new entrepreneurial awareness gave carriers <strong>the</strong> ability toovercome <strong>the</strong> first-mover problem and proceed with fully develop<strong>in</strong>g a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g models.Thus, one can best characterize <strong>the</strong> shift to a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g as evolutionary, <strong>in</strong>stead ofrevolutionary. The development of a number of factors, both endogenous and exogenous to <strong>the</strong>airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry, go<strong>in</strong>g back to deregulation, f<strong>in</strong>ally created <strong>the</strong> conditions under which airl<strong>in</strong>escould beg<strong>in</strong> mov<strong>in</strong>g toward an a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g model. In <strong>the</strong> follow<strong>in</strong>g chapters, <strong>the</strong> paper willexam<strong>in</strong>e what <strong>the</strong> effects of this evolution have been, not only for airl<strong>in</strong>es but also for <strong>the</strong>consumer.45


Chapter 2 ReferencesAir Transport Association. 2009. ―Fuel 101: From Well to W<strong>in</strong>g.‖ June 15, accessed March 12,2010, available at http://www.airl<strong>in</strong>es.org/Energy/Fuels101/Pages/Fuel101.aspx.Air Transport Association. ―energy/fuel.‖ accessed March 12, 2010, available athttp://www.airl<strong>in</strong>es.org/economics/energy/.Antoniou, Andreas. 1998. ―The Status of <strong>the</strong> Core <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>Industry</strong>: The Case of <strong>the</strong>European Market.‖ Managerial and Decision Economics. Vol. 19, pp. 43-54.Armstrong, Mark & Vickers, John. 2001. ―Competitive Price Discrim<strong>in</strong>ation.‖ The RANDJournal of Economics. Vol. 32, No. 4, pp. 579-605.Armstrong, Mark & Vickers, John. 2010. ―Competitive Nonl<strong>in</strong>ear <strong>Pric<strong>in</strong>g</strong> and Bundl<strong>in</strong>g.‖ TheReview of Economic Studies. Vol. 77, pp. 30-60.Button, Kenneth. 1996. ―Liberalis<strong>in</strong>g European Aviation: Is There an Empty Core Problem?‖Journal of Transport Economics and Policy. Vol. 30, No. 3: Key Issues <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>Competitive Airl<strong>in</strong>e System, pp. 275-291.Carlton, Dennis W. & Perloff, Jeffrey M. 2005. Modern Industrial Organization: Fourth Edition.Boston: Pearson/Addison Wesley.Clark, Nicola. 2009. ―Deep Losses Forecast for Airl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong> 2010.‖ The New York Times onl<strong>in</strong>e,December 16, available at http://www.nytimes.com/2009/12/16/bus<strong>in</strong>ess/16iata.html.Doganis, Rigas. 2002. Fly<strong>in</strong>g Off Course: The Economics of International Airl<strong>in</strong>es. New York:Routledge.Franke, Markus. 2005. ―Competition Between Network Carriers and Low-Cost Carriers–RetreatBattle or Breakthrough to a New Level of Efficiency?‖ The Journal of Air TransportManagement. Vol. 10, pp. 15-21.46


Gale, Ian L. & Holmes, Thomas J. 1993. ―Advance-Purchase Discounts <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Presence ofAggregate Demand Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty.‖ The American Economic Review. Vol. 83, No. 1, pp.135-146.Gifford, Sharon. 1992. ―Allocation of Entrepreneurial Attention.‖ Journal of Economic Behaviorand Organization. Vol. 19, pp. 265-284.Goetz, Andrew R. & Vowles, Timothy M. 2009. ―The Good, <strong>the</strong> Bad, and <strong>the</strong> Ugly: 30 Years ofUS Airl<strong>in</strong>e Deregulation.‖ Journal of Transport Geography. Vol. 17, pp. 251-263.Hecker, JayEtta Z. 2005. ―Commercial Aviation: Structural Costs Cont<strong>in</strong>ue to Challenge LegacyAirl<strong>in</strong>es‘ F<strong>in</strong>ancial Performance.‖ Government Accountability Office Testimony Before<strong>the</strong> Committee on Commerce, Sciences, and Transportation, Subcommittee on Aviation,U.S. Senate. July 13, available at http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d05834t.pdf.Hoppe, Heidrun C. 2000. ―Second-Mover Advantages <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Strategic Adoption of NewTechnology Under Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty.‖ International Journal of Industrial Organization. Vol.18, pp. 315-338.Hotell<strong>in</strong>g, Harry. 1929. ―Stability <strong>in</strong> Competition.‖ The Economic Journal. Vol. 39, No. 153, pp.41-57.Ito, Harumi & Lee, Dar<strong>in</strong>. 2005. ―Assess<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> Impact of <strong>the</strong> September 11 Terrorist Attacks onU.S. Airl<strong>in</strong>e Demand.‖ Journal of Economics and Bus<strong>in</strong>ess. Vol. 57, pp. 75-95.Lieberman, Marv<strong>in</strong> B. & Montgomery, David B. 1988. ―First-Mover Advantages.‖ StrategicManagement Journal. Vol. 9, pp. 41-58.Mak<strong>in</strong>en, Gail. 2002. ―The Economic Effects of 9/11: A Retrospective Assessment.‖Congressional Research Service Report for Congress, September 27, available athttp://www.fas.org/irp/crs/ RL31617.pdf.47


Morrell, Peter. 2005. ―Airl<strong>in</strong>es With<strong>in</strong> Airl<strong>in</strong>es: An Analysis of US Network Airl<strong>in</strong>e Responsesto Low Cost Carriers.‖ Journal of Air Transport Management. Vol. 11, pp. 303-312.Mutzabaugh, Ben. 2005. ―Southwest CEO Discusses ‗Excess Capacity,‘ Denver Expansion.‖USA Today onl<strong>in</strong>e, Today <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Sky blog, November 2, available athttp://www.usatoday.com /travel/ flights/today/2005-11-02-sky-archiveoct27_x.htm.Oi, Walter Y. 1971. ―A Disneyland Dilemma: Two-Part Tariffs for a Mickey Mouse Monopoly.‖The Quarterly Journal of Economics. Vol. 85, No. 1, pp. 77-96.Salop, Steven C. 1979. ―Monopolistic Competition with Outside Goods.‖ The Bell Journal ofEconomics. Vol. 10, No. 1, pp. 151-156.Sjostrom, William. 1993. ―Antitrust Immunity for Shipp<strong>in</strong>g Conferences: An Empty CoreApproach.‖ The Antitrust Bullet<strong>in</strong>. Vol. 38, at 419-423.Teichert, Thorsten, Edlira, Shehu, & von Wartburg, Iwan. 2008. ―Customer SegmentationRevisited: The Case of <strong>the</strong> Airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>Industry</strong>.‖ Transportation Research Part A. Vol. 42,pp. 227-242.Telser, Lester G. 1994. ―The Usefulness of Core Theory <strong>in</strong> Economics.‖ The Journal ofEconomic Perspectives. Vol. 8, No. 2, pp. 151-164.Wernerfelt, Birger & Karnani, Aneel. 1987. ―Competitive Strategy Under Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty.‖Strategic Management Journal. Vol. 8, pp. 187-194.48


Chapter 3: Airl<strong>in</strong>e Considerations for <strong>Pric<strong>in</strong>g</strong> A <strong>La</strong> <strong>Carte</strong>The previous chapter discussed <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> drivers beh<strong>in</strong>d <strong>the</strong> tim<strong>in</strong>g and emergence ofairl<strong>in</strong>es‘ <strong>in</strong>creased focus on ancillary revenues through a two-part pric<strong>in</strong>g agreement. Build<strong>in</strong>g on<strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>ory that airl<strong>in</strong>es employ<strong>in</strong>g a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g are price differentiat<strong>in</strong>g among customerswith heterogeneous tastes, this chapter will focus on <strong>the</strong> considerations that an airl<strong>in</strong>e makes <strong>in</strong>decid<strong>in</strong>g what products and services it will offer a la carte and which ones it will cont<strong>in</strong>ue tobundle with <strong>the</strong> price of an airl<strong>in</strong>e ticket. In essence, this chapter provides some of <strong>the</strong> ―how‖that accompanies <strong>the</strong> previously discussed ―why‖ beh<strong>in</strong>d a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g.Payoffs From Ancillary RevenueBefore discuss<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong> depth, <strong>the</strong> various factors affect<strong>in</strong>g an airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s decision on whenand where to use a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g, it is worth not<strong>in</strong>g that unbundl<strong>in</strong>g of checked baggage andsell<strong>in</strong>g of o<strong>the</strong>r services appears to have been a largely profitable enterprise for most domesticairl<strong>in</strong>es. Dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terviews, all <strong>in</strong>terviewees who were asked whe<strong>the</strong>r unbundl<strong>in</strong>g is ―pay<strong>in</strong>g off‖unequivocally stated that it has generated more revenues than expected. One <strong>in</strong>terviewee saidthat <strong>the</strong> a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>itiatives are expected to generate about eight times <strong>the</strong> amount ofrevenue predicted by <strong>the</strong> carrier‘s <strong>in</strong>itial estimates <strong>in</strong> 2008.The <strong>in</strong>dustry overall appears to be earn<strong>in</strong>g more revenue from bag fees, new onboardproducts, and o<strong>the</strong>r charges that it would have without <strong>the</strong>se <strong>in</strong>itiatives. Despite decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>grevenue from ticket sales <strong>in</strong> 2009, due to lower fares and lower demand, and a 17 percent drop <strong>in</strong>total revenues, <strong>the</strong> five U.S. legacy carriers (American Airl<strong>in</strong>es, Cont<strong>in</strong>ental Airl<strong>in</strong>es, DeltaAirl<strong>in</strong>es 6 , United Airl<strong>in</strong>es, and US Airways) saw a 19 percent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> ancillary revenues, onaverage, dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> course of <strong>the</strong> year (Airl<strong>in</strong>e Weekly 2010, 1). In <strong>the</strong> third quarter of 2009, <strong>the</strong>6 Includes figures for Delta Air L<strong>in</strong>es and Northwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es.49


most recent quarter for publicly reported data, U.S. airl<strong>in</strong>es collected approximately $2 billion <strong>in</strong>ancillary fees, up 36.4 percent from <strong>the</strong> third quarter of 2008 (Bureau of TransportationStatistics). In that quarter, ancillary revenue comprised 6.9 percent of total <strong>in</strong>dustry revenues, upfrom 4.1 percent <strong>the</strong> previous year.The composition of ancillary revenue also po<strong>in</strong>ts to <strong>the</strong> success that network carriers <strong>in</strong>particular have had with this technique. Figure 3.1 below shows <strong>the</strong> top five airl<strong>in</strong>es, worldwide,for ancillary revenues for 2006 and 2008. While only one American network carrier was <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>top five <strong>in</strong> 2006, U.S. network airl<strong>in</strong>es came to dom<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>the</strong> top three spots on <strong>the</strong> list <strong>in</strong> 2008.Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> top ancillary revenue earners <strong>in</strong> 2008 earn considerably more than those fromjust two years prior.Figure 3.1: Top Five Airl<strong>in</strong>es by Ancillary Revenue Earn<strong>in</strong>gs 7Annual Results – Calendar Year 2006 Annual Results – Calendar Year 2008$554,015,908 United Airl<strong>in</strong>es $2,202,148,438 American Airl<strong>in</strong>es$482,103,581 Ryanair $1,601,562,500 United Airl<strong>in</strong>es$252,268,141 easyJet $1,501,464,844 Delta Airl<strong>in</strong>es$179,288,475 Alaska Airl<strong>in</strong>es $834,614,578 Ryanair$84,419,785 Aer L<strong>in</strong>gus $612,093,164 QantasWhile a-la-carte offer<strong>in</strong>gs have turned <strong>in</strong>to profitable revenue centers for <strong>the</strong> major U.S.carriers, one additional factor must be considered: <strong>the</strong> effect of ancillary revenues on o<strong>the</strong>rrevenues. While carriers may be generat<strong>in</strong>g larger volumes of ancillary revenues, <strong>the</strong>se ga<strong>in</strong>s arepotentially offset by decl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong> ticket revenues, ei<strong>the</strong>r from reduction <strong>in</strong> base fares or from fewerpeople fly<strong>in</strong>g on airl<strong>in</strong>es with <strong>the</strong> most burdensome fee structures. Only a thorough econometricanalysis could determ<strong>in</strong>e <strong>the</strong> effect of a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g on fares and thus <strong>the</strong> effects on base fare7 Chart taken from Sorensen 2007, 11.50


evenue. Such an analysis is outside <strong>the</strong> scope of this paper; however, it would be an importantopportunity for future research to determ<strong>in</strong>e whe<strong>the</strong>r this strategy has improved producer welfare<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry.Of course, not all carriers have completely made <strong>the</strong> shift to an a-la carte pric<strong>in</strong>g model.Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es has yet to charge any fees for <strong>the</strong> first and second checked bag and foroffer<strong>in</strong>gs such as exit row seats. In fact, <strong>the</strong> carrier has aggressively advertised <strong>the</strong> fact that itdoesn‘t charge such fees, and that its competitors do. Such a strategy, after cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>g to hold outfrom tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> fee leap for two years, <strong>in</strong>dicates that <strong>the</strong>re may be payoffs to attract<strong>in</strong>g additionalcustomers by permitt<strong>in</strong>g complementary bag check. Of course, Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es has alwayspursued a different bus<strong>in</strong>ess strategy than <strong>the</strong> legacy carriers. None<strong>the</strong>less, o<strong>the</strong>r low-costcarriers (LCCs) with similar operat<strong>in</strong>g structures to Southwest (limited aircraft types, quickturnaround times, etc.) have also made <strong>the</strong> shift to <strong>in</strong>creased sources of ancillary revenue.Southwest has asserted that it has experienced an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> load factors from what itcharacterizes as customers switch<strong>in</strong>g from o<strong>the</strong>r carriers. Dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terviews, however, subjects<strong>in</strong>dicated that <strong>the</strong>ir carrier‘s load factors were also strong, and that <strong>the</strong>y have seen no appreciabledecl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> traffic. Indeed, legacy airl<strong>in</strong>e load factors have rema<strong>in</strong>ed steady over recent years, and<strong>in</strong> January 2010, Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ load factor of 72.1 percent rema<strong>in</strong>ed below <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustryaverage of 74.9 percent (New Mexico Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Weekly). Though <strong>the</strong> exact figure cannot bedisclosed for confidentiality reasons, <strong>the</strong> carrier at which <strong>in</strong>terviews were conducted, along withall o<strong>the</strong>r network carriers, experienced above-average load factors dur<strong>in</strong>g this month.Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, a look at Southwest‘s monthly load factors show no appreciable <strong>in</strong>creaseimmediately <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> wake of o<strong>the</strong>r airl<strong>in</strong>es unbundl<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir bag fees (which Southwest heavilyadvertises as its competitive advantage). Figure 3.2 shows <strong>the</strong> data: a noticeable cyclical51


variation is present, with peaks dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> summer and troughs dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> w<strong>in</strong>ter. Southwest‘ssummer load factors <strong>in</strong> 2008, <strong>the</strong> year dur<strong>in</strong>g which baggage unbundl<strong>in</strong>g took place, are slightlylower than those <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> previous year. While load factors <strong>in</strong>crease for summer 2009, <strong>the</strong> peak isnot much higher than that for summer 2007. Perhaps <strong>the</strong> only major <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> load factorscomes for w<strong>in</strong>ter 2009/2010, when Southwest‘s trough is much higher than it was <strong>in</strong> previousw<strong>in</strong>ters. As mentioned above, however, despite its <strong>in</strong>creased performance, its load factors wereactually lower than <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry average <strong>in</strong> that month. The data <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> graph below show noevidence that Southwest is ga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g customers from its policy of not charg<strong>in</strong>g a first- or secondcheckedbag fee.Figure 3.2: Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es Load Factors by Month, January 2007–March 2010 8If Southwest is not actively attract<strong>in</strong>g customers due to no-bag-fee policies, <strong>the</strong>re may beo<strong>the</strong>r rationales for why it, and o<strong>the</strong>r airl<strong>in</strong>es, may be stay<strong>in</strong>g away from expand<strong>in</strong>g its a-la-carteoffer<strong>in</strong>gs. First, Southwest may face a unique distribution of customers that does not conform to<strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>oretical analysis presented <strong>in</strong> chapter 2. One <strong>in</strong>terviewee also noted that Southwest tends8 Source: various press releases report<strong>in</strong>g Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es traffic statistics.52


to fly shorter routes where it competes with o<strong>the</strong>r modes of transportation, such as automobile orrail, that allow a traveler to br<strong>in</strong>g a certa<strong>in</strong> volume of luggage for free. Such competition maythus constra<strong>in</strong> Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ ability to charge for <strong>the</strong> first and second checked bag. Also,despite its no-fee mantra, Southwest has taken some limited steps toward ancillary revenues; oneexample <strong>in</strong>cludes a priority board<strong>in</strong>g fee.Brand ConsiderationsWhen <strong>in</strong>teract<strong>in</strong>g with a company, customers often engage with what <strong>the</strong>y understand asa company‘s brand. The brand <strong>in</strong>volves a comb<strong>in</strong>ation of names, terms, signs, symbols, ordesigns that allow a consumer to identify a seller‘s or group of sellers‘ products and servicesfrom its/<strong>the</strong>ir competitor(s) (Keller 1993, 2). There are ample writ<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> market<strong>in</strong>g literaturedevoted to <strong>the</strong> concept of <strong>the</strong> brand, specifically evaluat<strong>in</strong>g consumers‘ brand awareness, a brandimage, and o<strong>the</strong>r related concepts.From an economic <strong>the</strong>ory perspective, brands also play an important role, though thisconcept has received less attention <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> literature. Ultimately, a brand lowers transaction costsby reduc<strong>in</strong>g consumer search costs. Buyers can use brand <strong>in</strong>formation along with o<strong>the</strong>r heuristicsto make purchas<strong>in</strong>g decisions when consider<strong>in</strong>g a number of competitors. The brand provides<strong>in</strong>formation about unobserved attributes of <strong>the</strong> firm that can be used along with price <strong>in</strong>formation,personal preferences, and o<strong>the</strong>r factors to make a utility-maximiz<strong>in</strong>g purchas<strong>in</strong>g decision (seeKle<strong>in</strong> & Leffler 1981, 629–633).As customers face decisions on how to purchase based partially on brand<strong>in</strong>g, firms face achoice on where <strong>the</strong>y want to position <strong>the</strong>ir brands <strong>in</strong> relation to customers so as to maximizerevenues. In this way, vary<strong>in</strong>g brands serve as a means of spatial competition by which firms can53


compete for customers <strong>in</strong> a manner similar to that <strong>the</strong>oretically proposed <strong>in</strong> Hotell<strong>in</strong>g‘s locationmodel (Sapp<strong>in</strong>gton & Wernerfelt 1985, 283). Build<strong>in</strong>g a strong or positively recognized brandcan be an asset: <strong>in</strong> an analysis of <strong>the</strong> market for liquor products, Sapp<strong>in</strong>gton and Wernerfelt f<strong>in</strong>dthat firms with stronger brand names are more likely to move away from <strong>the</strong>ir ―base‖ and be ableto capture more customers. (286) None<strong>the</strong>less, a firm that positions itself too far from an idealposition is likely to beg<strong>in</strong> los<strong>in</strong>g customers because it gets too far away from its base customers.Dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terviews, numerous respondents noted that <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s position as a full-servicenetwork carrier creates a certa<strong>in</strong> brand image. As one <strong>in</strong>terviewee said, ―If you were to askpeople to list airl<strong>in</strong>es . . . [our airl<strong>in</strong>e] would not be at <strong>the</strong> top of <strong>the</strong> list as likely to have <strong>the</strong>lowest fares. What we would like to th<strong>in</strong>k is if you talked to a bunch of bus<strong>in</strong>ess travelers andasked <strong>the</strong>m to pick <strong>the</strong>ir top five airl<strong>in</strong>es, <strong>the</strong>n [our airl<strong>in</strong>e] would be among <strong>the</strong> top of those forbus<strong>in</strong>ess travel.‖ Because network carriers offer customers a network of flights to a broad set ofdomestic and <strong>in</strong>ternational dest<strong>in</strong>ations, a customer look<strong>in</strong>g to fly from Rochester, NY to RapidCity, SD would likely be unable to complete <strong>the</strong> it<strong>in</strong>erary on a s<strong>in</strong>gle LCC. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, untilrecently, network airl<strong>in</strong>es had offered <strong>the</strong>ir customers with a comparatively higher level ofservices, and <strong>the</strong>y still offer customers <strong>the</strong> option to purchase additional add-ons that LCCs ando<strong>the</strong>r carriers do not provide. For example, few non-network airl<strong>in</strong>es offer true first or bus<strong>in</strong>essclass cab<strong>in</strong>s, full meals for purchase, and o<strong>the</strong>r amenities.One popular reaction to <strong>in</strong>creased fees and unbundl<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> media is <strong>the</strong> perception thatairl<strong>in</strong>es have been ―nickel and dim<strong>in</strong>g‖ <strong>the</strong>ir customers. None<strong>the</strong>less, this abstraction ignores <strong>the</strong>fact that certa<strong>in</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>es cater to certa<strong>in</strong> types of customers. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to an <strong>in</strong>terviewee, <strong>the</strong>carrier‘s bus<strong>in</strong>ess-oriented focus manages much of <strong>the</strong> potential for a loss of customers due tonickel and dim<strong>in</strong>g concerns: bus<strong>in</strong>ess-oriented customers are likely to have higher reservation54


prices and will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay for unbundled products and are likely to have already paid a higherprice for <strong>the</strong>ir tickets. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, a significant portion of bus<strong>in</strong>ess customers‘ travel is paid forby <strong>the</strong> employer and not personally borne by <strong>the</strong> traveler herself. As ano<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>terviewee notedthat <strong>the</strong> customers who often have <strong>the</strong> highest expectations for service and who tend to feel <strong>the</strong>most personally affected by fees and charges are <strong>in</strong>frequent travelers: ―It‘s unbelievable. Thesepeople pay <strong>the</strong> lowest possible price and <strong>the</strong>y have <strong>the</strong>se really high standards, and I th<strong>in</strong>k part of<strong>the</strong> challenge is that <strong>the</strong>y don‘t fly that often.‖That is not to say that an airl<strong>in</strong>e with sympa<strong>the</strong>tic customers is able to charge for nearlyall possible amenities offered onboard. For example, Michael O‘Leary recently announced thathis European ultra-discount airl<strong>in</strong>e Ryanair could start charg<strong>in</strong>g customers to use <strong>the</strong> lavatoryonboard its planes (Mutzabaugh 2009). While such a policy would likely be met with revulsion(and could motivate a large shift <strong>in</strong> passenger to airl<strong>in</strong>es that do not levy this charge) <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>United States, consumers <strong>in</strong> Europe are already used to pay<strong>in</strong>g for bathroom use <strong>in</strong> many areas.Thus, cultural expectations may provide a sort of basel<strong>in</strong>e that makes customers more or lesswill<strong>in</strong>g to accept a certa<strong>in</strong> type of pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangement. One <strong>in</strong>terviewee po<strong>in</strong>ted out that <strong>the</strong>secultural expectations may play <strong>in</strong>to certa<strong>in</strong> customers view<strong>in</strong>g an airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s policy as cheap: ―InEurope, you go <strong>in</strong>to a restaurant and you order a sandwich. They come back with bread and meatand cheese, and that‘s it. . . . Americans don‘t have that mentality.‖In order to fur<strong>the</strong>r manage <strong>the</strong> ―nickel and dim<strong>in</strong>g‖ perception, <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e appears to putemphasis on provid<strong>in</strong>g products that provide added value to <strong>the</strong> consumer, especially when itcomes to <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>troduction of new ancillary products and services. One respondent said that <strong>the</strong>airl<strong>in</strong>e conducts extensive market research to determ<strong>in</strong>e what programs will benefit consumerswhile position<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e brand to capture additional consumer revenues. This process is not55


always perfect, however. For example, US Airways became <strong>the</strong> first U.S. carrier to <strong>in</strong>stitute acharge for soft dr<strong>in</strong>ks onboard domestic flights <strong>in</strong> 2008. Follow<strong>in</strong>g several months of customercompla<strong>in</strong>ts and with no o<strong>the</strong>r legacy carrier match<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> charge, <strong>the</strong> carrier elim<strong>in</strong>ated this fee(Castro 2009). Likewise, United Airl<strong>in</strong>es abandoned plans for a 2008 pilot program that would<strong>in</strong>volve food for purchase on certa<strong>in</strong> transatlantic flights leav<strong>in</strong>g from Wash<strong>in</strong>gton Dulles Airport,due largely to customer compla<strong>in</strong>ts (Phillips 2008).Indeed, certa<strong>in</strong> elements play <strong>in</strong>to customer perception of <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e brand and restricthow far away an airl<strong>in</strong>e is able to move. For example, one <strong>in</strong>terviewee noted that a free soft dr<strong>in</strong>kon board has a ―really emotional attachment‖ for <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s customers. Ultimately, customersmay have strong perceptions tied to <strong>the</strong> service brand, and an airl<strong>in</strong>e wish<strong>in</strong>g to move away fromits brand image faces a potential decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> total revenues.Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, exist<strong>in</strong>g network carriers and higher-service LCCs may be constra<strong>in</strong>ed bypast experiences with <strong>the</strong>ir brands and historical associations with <strong>the</strong> carrier‘s products andservices. For example, Allegiant Air, which became a popular leisure travel airl<strong>in</strong>e only <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>past decade, has always been based on a no-frills, a-la-carte model. Indeed, it is one of <strong>the</strong> fewdomestic carriers that charges for a soft dr<strong>in</strong>k onboard. Despite this fact, Allegiant is rarelycalled out <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> media for be<strong>in</strong>g one of <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>es guilty of ―nickel and dim<strong>in</strong>g.‖ This is likelydue to <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> carrier never offered <strong>the</strong>se amenities for free and thus never changedcourse from its orig<strong>in</strong>al bus<strong>in</strong>ess plan.As discussed above, <strong>the</strong> brand reduces transaction costs by giv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> consumer a modelof what sort of products and services <strong>the</strong>y can expect from <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e and how <strong>the</strong>y compare tocompetitors. One potential challenge <strong>the</strong> firm may face, however, is if customer perception of <strong>the</strong>brand does not align with <strong>the</strong> actual product offer<strong>in</strong>gs and service quality attributed to <strong>the</strong>56


company. Two <strong>in</strong>terviewees discussed that this is a particular challenge for customers who are<strong>in</strong>cl<strong>in</strong>ed to see all new fees as nickel and dim<strong>in</strong>g, even when <strong>the</strong>y appear to be value added. Thus,<strong>the</strong> carrier pays attention to educat<strong>in</strong>g customers whenever possible about <strong>the</strong> difference betweenunbundled fees and new product/service options, and how a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g can add value.Given <strong>the</strong> constant media barrage by Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es, <strong>in</strong>terviewees admit that <strong>the</strong>re is<strong>in</strong>creased pressure to educate consumers. One <strong>in</strong>terviewee acknowledged, however, ―I th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>the</strong>re‘s a better way we could manage our customers‘ expectations as well.‖Ultimately, <strong>the</strong>se costs to educate consumers have <strong>the</strong> potential to improve brand imageand allow <strong>the</strong> carrier to capture more consumers away from its base who currently misperceiveor do not understand <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s product attributes. Interview data seem to support <strong>the</strong> spatialcompetition <strong>the</strong>ory of brand<strong>in</strong>g—it appears as if <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e is try<strong>in</strong>g to strike a balance betweencaptur<strong>in</strong>g additional customer revenue away from its base while not alienat<strong>in</strong>g its core customers.Interview responses tell a story of an attempt to capture <strong>the</strong> most revenue, at <strong>the</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>, by f<strong>in</strong>etun<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> position of <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s brand.Complexity and Ability to Deliver <strong>the</strong> ProductIt may come as a surprise to those who see unbundl<strong>in</strong>g fees as simply a way for an airl<strong>in</strong>eto nickel and dime customers to pad its own balance sheet, but accord<strong>in</strong>g to multiple<strong>in</strong>terviewees, <strong>the</strong>ir airl<strong>in</strong>e considers a drop <strong>in</strong> checked luggage due to fees to be a significantbenefit. Ultimately, checked luggage adds additional complexity to an air transport operation byrequir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> carrier to handle <strong>the</strong> customer‘s bag, conduct a security scan, load it on <strong>the</strong> correctplane, transfer it to ano<strong>the</strong>r aircraft if <strong>the</strong> passenger is connect<strong>in</strong>g, and unload it. While much of<strong>the</strong>se costs are fixed, <strong>the</strong>re are additional variable costs: with more bags, <strong>the</strong>re is an <strong>in</strong>creased57


chance for bags to get delayed or get lost, lead<strong>in</strong>g to costs <strong>in</strong>volved with compensat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>customers and track<strong>in</strong>g down <strong>the</strong> bags. Complexity has fur<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>creased s<strong>in</strong>ce September 11th—follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> attacks, airl<strong>in</strong>es became required to scan all checked luggage and to ensure that anyluggage loaded onto a plane would be unloaded if its owner did not board <strong>the</strong> flight.Perhaps it is no surprise <strong>the</strong>n that one <strong>in</strong>terviewee said she would welcome third-partycompetition (likely <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> form of a cargo operation) offer<strong>in</strong>g to take customers‘ bag for a fee.None<strong>the</strong>less, this example highlights a fur<strong>the</strong>r consideration that enters <strong>in</strong>to a decision tounbundle products: transaction costs aris<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>the</strong> extra complexity that certa<strong>in</strong> products orservices add to <strong>the</strong> core product of provid<strong>in</strong>g a customer with a seat from po<strong>in</strong>t a to po<strong>in</strong>t b.Thus <strong>in</strong> addition to generat<strong>in</strong>g revenues from customers who have high valuations for certa<strong>in</strong>ancillary services, <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e also is able to cut variable costs aris<strong>in</strong>g out of complexity,especially for those customers who had weak valuations for <strong>the</strong> products <strong>in</strong> question.Changes <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>al cost of deliver<strong>in</strong>g ancillary products and services, driven byendogenous and exogenous factors, may also play <strong>in</strong>to a decision to unbundle. As discussed <strong>in</strong>chapter 1, bundl<strong>in</strong>g tends to be more common <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustries where marg<strong>in</strong>al costs ofproducts/service <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> bundle are low. Prime examples <strong>in</strong>clude television channels, softwarebundles, or fast-food combo meals. There appears to be mixed evidence as to whe<strong>the</strong>r unbundledproducts experienced large <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>al costs.Presumably, as fuel prices rose substantially <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> late 2000s, <strong>the</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>al cost ofcarry<strong>in</strong>g a checked bag onboard <strong>the</strong> plane would <strong>in</strong>crease as <strong>the</strong> price of <strong>the</strong> additional fuel tocarry <strong>the</strong> bag <strong>in</strong>creased. None<strong>the</strong>less, dur<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>terview, one participant said that <strong>the</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>alcost of carry<strong>in</strong>g a bag had not <strong>in</strong>creased materially. None<strong>the</strong>less, ano<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>terviewee said hebelieved that fuel did <strong>in</strong>deed lead to a decision to charge for bags. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, it is widely58


ecognized that <strong>in</strong>creased cost-consciousness drove many airl<strong>in</strong>es to remove galleys <strong>in</strong> order tosave weight and thus fuel (Alexander 2006). In light of <strong>the</strong>se actions, and comb<strong>in</strong>ed with <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>creased security-related complexity, <strong>the</strong>re may have been a cost-reduc<strong>in</strong>g motivation beh<strong>in</strong>dunbundl<strong>in</strong>g bags, meals, and certa<strong>in</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r services.While certa<strong>in</strong> ancillary revenues can reduce complexity costs, especially those attributedto customers with low valuations, <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>troduction of new pric<strong>in</strong>g schemes may <strong>in</strong>troduce addedcomplexities that could mitigate potential ga<strong>in</strong>s. For example, fac<strong>in</strong>g a checked baggage charge,customers can be expected to substitute some of <strong>the</strong>ir checked baggage for carry-on luggage.Anecdotally, <strong>the</strong> overhead b<strong>in</strong>s on flights now frequently fill up before board<strong>in</strong>g is complete,requir<strong>in</strong>g some items to be checked at <strong>the</strong> gate. These lengthy procedures not only dim<strong>in</strong>ish <strong>the</strong>customer experience, but <strong>the</strong>y may <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>the</strong> potential for delay costs. None<strong>the</strong>less, one<strong>in</strong>terviewee said that while <strong>the</strong>re have been additional carry-on bags, <strong>the</strong>re have been fewadverse impacts on <strong>the</strong> complexity of <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s operation: ―When we were look<strong>in</strong>g at[unbundl<strong>in</strong>g bag fees] <strong>in</strong>itially and it <strong>in</strong>itially came out, we found that whatever (<strong>the</strong> Departmentof) Homeland Security had issued had more of an impact than our fees.‖In some cases, complexity costs for certa<strong>in</strong> services may <strong>in</strong>hibit <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s ability toconsistently provide a certa<strong>in</strong> type of product or service to its customers. Multiple <strong>in</strong>tervieweesspoke about <strong>the</strong> issue of ―deliverability‖ as a chief concern when consider<strong>in</strong>g products tounbundle or sell on an a-la-carte basis. In particular, one <strong>in</strong>terviewee po<strong>in</strong>ted to <strong>the</strong> somewhatdispersed timeframe for baggage fee rollout as a function of airl<strong>in</strong>es ensur<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>the</strong>y had <strong>the</strong>technology to adequately charge customers and manage revenues <strong>in</strong>com<strong>in</strong>g from baggage fees.In o<strong>the</strong>r cases, uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty may limit <strong>the</strong> options for delivery—for example, <strong>in</strong> certa<strong>in</strong> cases,59


customers may pay to upgrade to a higher service cab<strong>in</strong>, only to have <strong>the</strong> aircraft downgraded toa smaller type with <strong>the</strong> seat no longer available.In many cases, operational disruptions perta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g to ancillary products can raisecomplexity costs by requir<strong>in</strong>g additional mechanisms <strong>in</strong> place to accommodate customers whodid not receive <strong>the</strong> product or service <strong>the</strong>y were promised. In <strong>the</strong> case of unbundl<strong>in</strong>g, especially,customers will demand more reliable product delivery if <strong>the</strong>y are pay<strong>in</strong>g for a service that waspreviously free. Because of <strong>in</strong>creased consumer expectations, unbundl<strong>in</strong>g puts <strong>in</strong>creased pressureon <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e to offer <strong>the</strong> service <strong>in</strong> a consistent manner. Ultimately, <strong>the</strong> predicted ability toprovide customers with an advertised service may potentially <strong>in</strong>crease complexities and coststhat <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e must factor when mak<strong>in</strong>g a decision to unbundle. Fail<strong>in</strong>g to do so can result <strong>in</strong>foregone ancillary revenues or perhaps a shift <strong>in</strong> customers to o<strong>the</strong>r airl<strong>in</strong>es that provide moreconsistent ancillary products/services.Competitive ConsiderationsAs discussed <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> example <strong>in</strong> chapter 2, airl<strong>in</strong>es provide service <strong>in</strong> a competitiveenvironment where <strong>the</strong>y must respond to <strong>the</strong> market decisions of o<strong>the</strong>rs. Even <strong>in</strong> cases where anairl<strong>in</strong>e operates <strong>the</strong> only nonstop flight on a route, it still may face competitive pressure fromcarriers that offer one- or multi-stop service to <strong>the</strong> dest<strong>in</strong>ation. For example, airl<strong>in</strong>e loyaltyprograms have been able to capture connect<strong>in</strong>g customers away from nonstop customers byoffer<strong>in</strong>g a non-price attribute for travelers to consider. A passenger who values mileage accrualon one connect<strong>in</strong>g airl<strong>in</strong>e (largely aided by elite status at certa<strong>in</strong> mileage levels) may be will<strong>in</strong>ghave a higher reservation price for that airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s services, relative to ano<strong>the</strong>r nonstop airl<strong>in</strong>e(Department of Transportation 2009, 23–24).60


In <strong>the</strong> neoclassical framework, competition occurs solely on a price and quantitydimension; however, real-world competition also occurs <strong>in</strong> a quality dimension. In <strong>the</strong> case offrequent-flyer miles, <strong>the</strong> potential to earn miles used for future travel lowers <strong>the</strong> real price oftravel when one commits to a s<strong>in</strong>gle airl<strong>in</strong>e; however, it also improves quality though varioustype of frequent-flyer perks and benefits. Thus higher levels of quality or different qualityattributes can be used to attract customers from one firm to ano<strong>the</strong>r.In <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry, quality competition was widely seen dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> regulation era, asairl<strong>in</strong>es were unable to compete on price. S<strong>in</strong>ce deregulation, however, prices have fallendramatically (Smith and Cox, 2010). While <strong>the</strong>re have cutbacks <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> quality of <strong>the</strong> air travelexperience <strong>in</strong> terms of frills and o<strong>the</strong>r services, due to more vigorous competition on a pricedimension, <strong>the</strong>re have also been quality improvements <strong>in</strong> terms of service frequency and o<strong>the</strong>rdimensions (Ellig and Crandall 1997, 40–44). With <strong>the</strong> return of price competition and <strong>the</strong>prom<strong>in</strong>ence of no-frills LCCs, airl<strong>in</strong>es especially face a potential perception as providers of acommodity product, which only <strong>in</strong>volves <strong>the</strong> attributes of fly<strong>in</strong>g a customer from po<strong>in</strong>t A topo<strong>in</strong>t B. 9 As <strong>the</strong> goods or services <strong>in</strong> a market approach homogeneity, quality competitionbecomes less likely and price competition will dom<strong>in</strong>ate. Such a situation beg<strong>in</strong>s to approach <strong>the</strong>economic ideal of perfect competition, where firms with <strong>the</strong> lowest costs will be able to earnprofits. The commoditization of air travel can be particularly harmful to network carriers, whichhave historically had higher operat<strong>in</strong>g costs than LCCs.While an ancillary revenue model may spell out fewer services that are <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>price, it allows customers a better opportunity to personalize <strong>the</strong> travel experience based on <strong>the</strong>irpreferences and thus reduces <strong>the</strong> commoditization of <strong>the</strong> overall service. In many cases, <strong>the</strong>airl<strong>in</strong>e may also be able to offer a greater number of value-added services on an a-la-carte basis9 This can especially be <strong>the</strong> case <strong>in</strong> short-haul air travel. See, for example, Tarry 2010.61


than it would if it offered that product to all customers. This is because high costs may prohibitcerta<strong>in</strong> product offer<strong>in</strong>gs to all customers, but <strong>the</strong> ability to recover those costs from specificcustomers with high valuations can facilitate a value-added transaction that o<strong>the</strong>rwise would nothave happened.Numerous <strong>in</strong>terviewees spoke to <strong>the</strong> fact that unbundl<strong>in</strong>g and new a-la-carte productsprovide a way for <strong>the</strong>ir airl<strong>in</strong>e to differentiate <strong>the</strong>ir product from o<strong>the</strong>rs. One <strong>in</strong>tervieweespecifically said that <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e was constantly th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g about way to <strong>in</strong>novate and create uniqueproducts that will attract customers and add value. Ano<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>terviewee spoke directly to <strong>the</strong> factthat differentiat<strong>in</strong>g can help make airl<strong>in</strong>es ―less of a commodity,‖ thus generat<strong>in</strong>g values forcustomers and airl<strong>in</strong>es alike. He specifically spoke to <strong>the</strong> importance of this differentiation vis-àvis<strong>the</strong> presence of discount carriers offer<strong>in</strong>g seats with few frills; simply remov<strong>in</strong>g products andservices would only br<strong>in</strong>g network airl<strong>in</strong>es closer to <strong>the</strong> LCC realm <strong>in</strong> which <strong>the</strong>y would facestiffer price competition.Despite try<strong>in</strong>g to differentiate <strong>the</strong>mselves from o<strong>the</strong>r airl<strong>in</strong>es, however, all airl<strong>in</strong>es facesomewhat of a challenge from third-party travel sellers (such as Expedia or Travelocity) thatattempt to compare <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s offer<strong>in</strong>gs with those of its competitors. As one <strong>in</strong>terviewee said,―We don‘t have control over what <strong>the</strong>ir user <strong>in</strong>terface looks like. . . . They‘re try<strong>in</strong>g to makeeveryone look <strong>the</strong> same, and we‘re try<strong>in</strong>g to make ourselves different.‖ This is likely a problemfor <strong>the</strong> multitude of airl<strong>in</strong>es that offer products and services on an a-la-carte basis and participate<strong>in</strong> onl<strong>in</strong>e travel distribution systems. Ultimately, <strong>the</strong> notion that network airl<strong>in</strong>es are us<strong>in</strong>g a-lacarte<strong>in</strong>itiatives to differentiate <strong>the</strong>mselves may be at odds with distributors try<strong>in</strong>g to streaml<strong>in</strong>e<strong>in</strong>formation about <strong>the</strong> travel process to <strong>the</strong>ir customers.62


As certa<strong>in</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>es attempt to use a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g as a means of product differentiation,<strong>the</strong>y may face pressure from airl<strong>in</strong>es that are uniquely suited to compete <strong>in</strong> such an environment.For example <strong>in</strong> 2008, Allegiant Air topped all carriers with ancillary revenue as a percent of totalrevenue with 22.7 percent (<strong>the</strong> next highest U.S. carrier was JetBlue with 10.3 percent)(Sorensen 2009, 33). Allegiant, which has seen large network expansions recently, may representan airl<strong>in</strong>e that has largely formed its product <strong>in</strong> a new ancillary revenue-centric environment. Upand-com<strong>in</strong>gcarriers, free from previous customer expectations about service levels, may be freeto build a strong ancillary revenue model from <strong>the</strong> ground up, tak<strong>in</strong>g advantage of even moreopportunities than legacy airl<strong>in</strong>es are.When asked about <strong>the</strong> potential for new entrants to take <strong>the</strong> ancillary revenue model thathas been benefit<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> network carriers and use it aga<strong>in</strong>st <strong>the</strong>m, <strong>in</strong>terviewees said <strong>the</strong>y werealways conscious to competitive threats, but did not believe that this would be a serious concern<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> near future. In particular, numerous <strong>in</strong>terviewees po<strong>in</strong>ted out that many of <strong>the</strong> upstarts donot offer <strong>the</strong> same network breadth or depth as <strong>the</strong> network carriers, and <strong>the</strong>ir competition isoften constra<strong>in</strong>ed to leisure and o<strong>the</strong>r niche markets. Despite this fact, however, it should benoted that <strong>the</strong> LCC competitive threat <strong>in</strong> general was largely underestimated <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1980s and1990s. S<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong>n, <strong>the</strong>se carriers have proved to be a formidable force. Thus <strong>the</strong> potential for newentrants to ga<strong>in</strong> an advantage <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> ancillary revenue realm, by earn<strong>in</strong>g more revenues fromnetwork airl<strong>in</strong>es or ga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g additional market share, is not out of <strong>the</strong> question.ConclusionWhile chapter 2 established a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>es as an equilibrium solution <strong>in</strong>a <strong>the</strong>oretical sense, this chapter discusses some of <strong>the</strong> real-world considerations that affect an63


airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s decision to offer a certa<strong>in</strong> product on an a-la-carte basis. Ultimately, a carrier seek<strong>in</strong>g tomaximize revenue from its operation may face additional costs <strong>in</strong> terms of brand reputation,complexity, and competition that may make unbundl<strong>in</strong>g less of an attractive strategy than it is <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong>ory. In many ways not discussed by <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>oretical model, however, an ancillary revenuemodel may bolster an airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s competitive position by allow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> carrier to differentiate itselffrom <strong>the</strong> commodity view of air travel.The considerations discussed <strong>in</strong> this chapter all come down to one key consideration for<strong>the</strong> air carrier: will unbundl<strong>in</strong>g a certa<strong>in</strong> product better allow it to earn revenues through productdifferentiation, or will <strong>the</strong> costs of unbundl<strong>in</strong>g outweigh <strong>the</strong> benefits? As <strong>in</strong>dicated <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>itialdiscussion, airl<strong>in</strong>es appear to have found a way to turn a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to a profitable strategy.As time goes on and <strong>the</strong> ancillary revenue model fur<strong>the</strong>r evolves, however, <strong>the</strong>se considerationswill cont<strong>in</strong>ue to weigh <strong>in</strong>to an airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s bus<strong>in</strong>ess decision.64


Chapter 3 ReferencesAirl<strong>in</strong>e Weekly. 2010. ―Special Report – Ancillary Revenue: It‘s Not Non-Core Anymore.‖February.Alexander, Keith L. 2006. ―American Airl<strong>in</strong>es to Remove Its Rear Galleys.‖ Wash<strong>in</strong>gton PostOnl<strong>in</strong>e. February 9, available at http://www.wash<strong>in</strong>gtonpost.com/wpdyn/content/article/2006/02/08/AR2006020802366.html.Bureau of Transportation Statistics. 2009. ―Third-Quarter 2009 Airl<strong>in</strong>e F<strong>in</strong>ancial Data: Airl<strong>in</strong>esReport Improved Operat<strong>in</strong>g Marg<strong>in</strong>s.‖ December 14, available athttp://www.bts.gov/press_releases/ 2009/bts059_09/html/bts059_09.html.Castro, Kimberly. 2009. ―US Airways Drops Nonalcoholic Dr<strong>in</strong>k Fees.‖ US News onl<strong>in</strong>e.February 23, available at http://www.usnews.com/money/blogs/luxe-life/2009/02/23/usairways-drops-nonalcoholic-dr<strong>in</strong>k-fees.Ellig, Jerry & Crandall, Robert. 1997. ―Economic Deregulation and Customer Choice: Lessonsfor <strong>the</strong> Electric <strong>Industry</strong>.‖ The Center for Market Processes.Keller, Kev<strong>in</strong> L. 1993. ―Conceptualiz<strong>in</strong>g, Measur<strong>in</strong>g, and Manag<strong>in</strong>g Customer-Based BrandEquity.‖ The Journal of Market<strong>in</strong>g. Vol. 57, No. 1, pp. 1-22.Kle<strong>in</strong>, Benjam<strong>in</strong> & Leffler, Keith B. 1981.―The Role of Market Forces <strong>in</strong> Assur<strong>in</strong>g ContractualPerformance.‖ The Journal of Political Economy. Vol. 89, No. 4 (1981), pp. 615-641.Mutzabaugh, Ben. 2009. ―Ryanair: You May Soon Have to ‗Pay to Pee.‘‖ USA Today onl<strong>in</strong>e,Today <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Sky blog. February 27, available athttp://www.usatoday.com/travel/flights/item.aspx?ak= 63417699.blog&type=blog.65


New Mexico Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Weekly. 2010. ―Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ Load Factor Soars <strong>in</strong> January.‖February 5, available athttp://www.bizjournals.com/albuquerque/stories/2010/02/01/daily43.html.Phillips, Matt. 2008. ―United Backs Off Plan to Cut Free Meals From Transatlantic Flights.‖ TheWall Street Journal onl<strong>in</strong>e, The Middle Seat Term<strong>in</strong>al blog. September 2, available athttp://blogs.wsj.com/middleseat/2008/09/02/united-backs-off-plan-to-cut-free-mealsfrom-transatlantic-flights/.Sapp<strong>in</strong>gton, David E.M. &Wernerfelt, Birger. 1985. ―To Brand or Not to Brand? A Theoreticand Empirical Question.‖ The Journal of Bus<strong>in</strong>ess, Vol. 58, No. 3, pp. 279-293.Smith, Fred L. Jr. & Cox, Braden. 2010. ―Airl<strong>in</strong>e Deregulation.‖ The Concise Encyclopedia ofEconomics. The Library of Economics and Liberty.accessed April 25, 2010, available athttp://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/Airl<strong>in</strong>eDeregulation.html.Sorensen, Jay. The Guide to Ancillary Revenue and a la <strong>Carte</strong> <strong>Pric<strong>in</strong>g</strong>. Idea Works, 2009.Tarry, Chris. 2010. ―Focus: Low-cost commodity.‖ Airl<strong>in</strong>e Bus<strong>in</strong>ess onl<strong>in</strong>e. January 21,available at http://www.flightglobal.com/articles/2010/01/21/337437/focus-low-costcommodity.html.U.S. Department of Transportation. 2010. Show Cause Order 2010-2-8. February 13. availableathttp://www.regulations.gov/search/Regs/contentStreamer?objectId=0900006480a9285f&disposition=attachment&contentType=pdf.66


Chapter 4: Consumer Response and Welfare Effects from A-<strong>La</strong>-<strong>Carte</strong> <strong>Pric<strong>in</strong>g</strong>While airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ shift to an a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g policy has resulted <strong>in</strong> additional revenue forairl<strong>in</strong>es and impacted elements of <strong>the</strong>ir bus<strong>in</strong>ess strategy, <strong>the</strong> consumers who ultimately fill <strong>the</strong>seats are subject to a number of effects that impact welfare. Most importantly, multiple-partprices have <strong>the</strong> potential to make certa<strong>in</strong> consumers better off, by reduc<strong>in</strong>g base fares, and o<strong>the</strong>rsworse off by result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> higher overall prices for those us<strong>in</strong>g ancillary products, who now mustpay a fee. There are additional effects, such as changes <strong>in</strong> product quality, that fur<strong>the</strong>r impactconsumer welfare. This chapter will look at ways <strong>in</strong> which a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g affects consumers‘utility.Ultimately, <strong>the</strong>re are a number of consumer-oriented issues that this chapter will discuss:<strong>the</strong> nature of consumers‘ response to a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g, potential downward pressure that a-lacartefees have on base fares, improvements <strong>in</strong> product quality, and welfare ga<strong>in</strong>s from additionalconsumer choice. Ra<strong>the</strong>r than attempt<strong>in</strong>g to def<strong>in</strong>itively quantify benefits and costs (a task leftopen for future research), this chapter will <strong>in</strong>stead broadly discuss <strong>the</strong> various factors that affectconsumer welfare due to a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry. These effects ultimately havepolicy implications that will be discussed <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> follow<strong>in</strong>g chapter.The Consumer Response to A-<strong>La</strong>-<strong>Carte</strong> <strong>Pric<strong>in</strong>g</strong>As outl<strong>in</strong>ed a number of times throughout this paper, unbundl<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>itiatives and newancillary fees have elicited largely negative reactions <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> media (Kiley 2009, Seaney 2008).Airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>terview data, as well as o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>formation, however, cast doubt as to whe<strong>the</strong>r consumersentiments are accurately portrayed <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> media and whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> media may <strong>in</strong>dicate more of adrop <strong>in</strong> utility than is actually occurr<strong>in</strong>g.67


A number of <strong>in</strong>terviewees po<strong>in</strong>ted out that <strong>the</strong> largely negative reaction <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> media doesnot accurately reflect <strong>the</strong> actual experience <strong>the</strong> carrier has had with its customers. When askedwhe<strong>the</strong>r customer compla<strong>in</strong>ts matched media rhetoric, one <strong>in</strong>terviewee responded, ―No, not atall. . . . It‘s a complicated bus<strong>in</strong>ess; it‘s hard to get it right and occasionally <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terpretations bypundits are almost accurate, but its more common that <strong>the</strong>y‘re a little bit <strong>the</strong> wrong way.‖More importantly, however, he <strong>in</strong>dicated that <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e had not seen a major shift <strong>in</strong>passengers to carriers such as Southwest that <strong>in</strong>clude more services <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> base fare: ―For <strong>the</strong> firstyear, nobody flocked to Southwest, period. No share transfer . . . nobody lost load factor for this.‖While <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terviewee stated that more recently, Southwest may have been able to poach certa<strong>in</strong>more <strong>in</strong>frequent flyers, he said <strong>the</strong> carrier‘s load factors rema<strong>in</strong> strong due to <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e pick<strong>in</strong>gup customers from o<strong>the</strong>r carriers <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> meantime. It should be remembered, of course, that loadfactors are a function of a number of different supply and demand factors—for example, anairl<strong>in</strong>e may be los<strong>in</strong>g customers, but if it cuts down on <strong>the</strong> number of seats it is offer<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>n itsload factors may rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> same or even <strong>in</strong>crease.None<strong>the</strong>less, a cursory look at <strong>the</strong> data confirm that Southwest has not ga<strong>in</strong>ed anysignificant load factor bump from its no-bag-fee policies. Look<strong>in</strong>g at Southwest‘s load factors isimportant due to <strong>the</strong> fact that add<strong>in</strong>g capacity is, <strong>in</strong> many ways, more difficult than remov<strong>in</strong>gcapacity. If Southwest were see<strong>in</strong>g a sizable <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> customers from fee-charg<strong>in</strong>g airl<strong>in</strong>es, itwould be unable to quickly add aircraft to accommodate <strong>in</strong>creased travelers and should<strong>the</strong>oretically see load factors <strong>in</strong>crease. While its load factors have been climb<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> recentmonths, Southwest still rema<strong>in</strong>s below a number of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry‘s top ancillary revenuegenerators. As shown <strong>in</strong> chapter 3, Southwest‘s load factors have cont<strong>in</strong>ued to show a similarcyclical variation even after most o<strong>the</strong>r airl<strong>in</strong>es have begun charg<strong>in</strong>g for bags. While <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s68


load factors did start to rise above its past performance dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> w<strong>in</strong>ter 2009/2010, its loadsstill rema<strong>in</strong>ed below <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry average. This lack of any appreciable shift of customers fromlegacy and o<strong>the</strong>r fee-charg<strong>in</strong>g carriers to Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es is shown <strong>in</strong> figure 4.1 below.Figure 4.1: Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es Load Factors by Month, January 2007-March 2010 10If customers are not flee<strong>in</strong>g carriers that charge fees, one must consider o<strong>the</strong>r factors thatfuel <strong>the</strong> negative perception of a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> media. One <strong>in</strong>terviewee po<strong>in</strong>ted out that<strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>es are an easy target <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> media, and that a-la-carte prices may carry a sensationalelement that may garner media attention: ―I th<strong>in</strong>k it‘s very relatable: everybody basically travelsat some po<strong>in</strong>t, and <strong>the</strong>y all have <strong>the</strong>ir own horror story about <strong>the</strong>ir own experience. I just th<strong>in</strong>kthat it resonates with a very wide audience of people, and it‘s easy to tell <strong>the</strong> sensational side of<strong>the</strong> story and not <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r side of <strong>the</strong> co<strong>in</strong>.‖ None<strong>the</strong>less, some <strong>in</strong>terviewees po<strong>in</strong>ted out that <strong>the</strong>10 Source: Various press releases report<strong>in</strong>g Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es traffic statistics.69


airl<strong>in</strong>e, and even <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry as a whole, could do a better job of manag<strong>in</strong>g customerexpectations of a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g by better <strong>in</strong>form<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m about its costs and benefits.Department of Transportation (DOT) data, show<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> number of compla<strong>in</strong>ts thatcustomers filed aga<strong>in</strong>st airl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong> a given month, also support <strong>the</strong> fact that consumers may besomewhat <strong>in</strong>different to a-la-carte fees and charges. Figure 4.2 shows <strong>the</strong> total number ofmonthly compla<strong>in</strong>ts that travelers filed with DOT aga<strong>in</strong>st U.S. airl<strong>in</strong>es, as well as <strong>the</strong> number ofbaggage-specific compla<strong>in</strong>ts that travelers filed aga<strong>in</strong>st U.S. and <strong>in</strong>ternational airl<strong>in</strong>es.As seen <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> graph, <strong>the</strong>re is a large peak <strong>in</strong> compla<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong> late 2007, follow<strong>in</strong>g lowerlevels <strong>in</strong> 2006. It should be noted that this peak took place before airl<strong>in</strong>es began unbundl<strong>in</strong>g bagfees from <strong>the</strong> fare, en masse. Before this major unbundl<strong>in</strong>g took place, both overall and baggagecompla<strong>in</strong>ts actually fell and rema<strong>in</strong>ed relatively constant <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> months dur<strong>in</strong>g baggageunbundl<strong>in</strong>g. Compla<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>the</strong>n exhibit a noticeable decl<strong>in</strong>e go<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to 2009, an unexpected resultif one assumes, a priori, that consumers are largely angry about additional baggage fees.70


Figure 4.2: DOT Airl<strong>in</strong>e Compla<strong>in</strong>ts per Passenger Emplaned,January 2006–January 2010 11While <strong>the</strong> number of passenger compla<strong>in</strong>ts may be governed by a number of factors,<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g total system volume, fare levels, and <strong>the</strong> overall quality of non-ancillary services, <strong>the</strong>secompla<strong>in</strong>t data do not show any immediate effect of a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>itiatives on customerdissatisfaction. One important potential reason for this is that after an airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>stitutes a bag fee,it sees a drop <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> number of checked bags. This implies fewer opportunities to lose ormishandle a bag, potentially result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> lower compla<strong>in</strong>ts. None<strong>the</strong>less, this factor iscounterbalanced by <strong>the</strong> fact that once passengers have to pay for checked luggage, <strong>the</strong>y may bemore compelled to compla<strong>in</strong> to DOT if <strong>the</strong>ir luggage is lost or mishandled.There are additional plausible hypo<strong>the</strong>ses for why compla<strong>in</strong>ts have fallen slightly. Onsome level, some customers may be will<strong>in</strong>g to accept a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangements because11 Source: DOT Air Travel Consumer Reports, availableathttp://airconsumer.dot.gov/reports/<strong>in</strong>dex.htm.Passengers emplaned <strong>in</strong>cludes <strong>in</strong>ternational and domesticpassengers.71


<strong>the</strong>y have not significantly impacted <strong>the</strong> customer‘s price of travel or perhaps because somecustomers understand, on some level, that fees result <strong>in</strong> lower fares for <strong>the</strong>ir preferred level ofservice (a po<strong>in</strong>t that will be discussed below). Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, compla<strong>in</strong>ts may be fall<strong>in</strong>g because alarge number of passengers can just carry on <strong>the</strong>ir bags, <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g little <strong>in</strong>convenience to <strong>the</strong>m.Regardless of <strong>the</strong> exact reasons, <strong>the</strong> volume of customer compla<strong>in</strong>ts provides fur<strong>the</strong>r evidencethat a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g has not resulted <strong>in</strong> a sharp <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> consumer dissatisfaction.The Fee/Fare Connection and Consumer WelfareThe <strong>the</strong>oretical foundation of two-part pric<strong>in</strong>g clearly outl<strong>in</strong>es a tension that <strong>the</strong> firmfaces between rais<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> per-unit charge and lower<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> lump-sum entry fee. In his paper on<strong>the</strong> subject, Oi po<strong>in</strong>ts out that <strong>the</strong> amusement park loses part of its customer base when it raises<strong>the</strong> entry fee because of additional customers who no longer derive sufficient surplus to enter <strong>the</strong>marker. Oi ma<strong>the</strong>matically shows that <strong>the</strong>re is a negative relationship between <strong>the</strong> lump sum feeand <strong>the</strong> per-unit price; ceteris paribus, a monopolistic firm cannot simply add an entry feewithout lower<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> per-unit price (Oi 1971, 79–80).Extrapolated <strong>in</strong>to markets that exhibit higher level of competition, <strong>the</strong> ability to simplyadd a fee onto a price, without lower<strong>in</strong>g that price, will be fur<strong>the</strong>r constra<strong>in</strong>ed by o<strong>the</strong>r firms‘abilities to provide more favorable pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangements. Just as competition <strong>in</strong> markets withs<strong>in</strong>gle-price arrangements tends to dissipate profits, airl<strong>in</strong>es may be expected to compete awaysome of <strong>the</strong> revenues earned from a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangements. While airl<strong>in</strong>es do exhibitcerta<strong>in</strong> degrees of market power, this may not be sufficient to stifle a competitive dissipation ofsome ancillary revenues though base fare <strong>in</strong>creases. For example, dur<strong>in</strong>g regulation, airl<strong>in</strong>es72


enjoyed monopoly positions as <strong>the</strong> only carrier on certa<strong>in</strong> routes, but competition forced <strong>the</strong>m tocompete on a quality dimension to dissipate profits (Goetz &Vowles, 253).Given this competitive nature of <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry, it is <strong>the</strong>refore plausible that <strong>the</strong>separation of a s<strong>in</strong>gle ticket price <strong>in</strong>to a two-part price would mean that <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitution of a perunitcharge would put some downward pressure on <strong>the</strong> entry price, which is, <strong>in</strong> this case, <strong>the</strong> fare.Absent some sort of change <strong>in</strong> supply or demand that would motivate a change <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> price,airl<strong>in</strong>es are thus <strong>the</strong>oretically limited <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir ability to simply tack on additional fees whileleav<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> fare untouched.Despite this <strong>the</strong>ory, an <strong>in</strong>terview question about this fee-fare relationship yielded anumber of responses <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>the</strong> carrier has not made operations decisions <strong>in</strong> light of a-lacartepric<strong>in</strong>g that would put downward pressure on <strong>the</strong> base fare. One <strong>in</strong>terviewee said that a faredecrease is ―not a direct manifestation‖ of a move to an a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g model. Ano<strong>the</strong>rparticipant said that while <strong>the</strong>re ―may be a shred of truth‖ to a higher fee, lower fare connection,―fares are a product of someth<strong>in</strong>g entirely . . . strong and powerful <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> competitivemarketplace, but not <strong>in</strong> any way boosted or harmed by <strong>the</strong> surround<strong>in</strong>g fees.‖ Based on responses,however, <strong>in</strong>terviewees may have mis<strong>in</strong>terpreted questions about whe<strong>the</strong>r fares were lower than<strong>the</strong>y o<strong>the</strong>rwise would have been due to a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g as ask<strong>in</strong>g whe<strong>the</strong>r fares were actuallylower follow<strong>in</strong>g a shift <strong>in</strong> pric<strong>in</strong>g.None<strong>the</strong>less, o<strong>the</strong>r participants <strong>in</strong>dicated that <strong>the</strong>re may <strong>in</strong>deed be a downward effect onfares. One participant also expressed uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty about <strong>the</strong> question, but po<strong>in</strong>ted out that she seesthat enact<strong>in</strong>g a fee ―does not have a one-to-one‖ relationship on decreas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> fare (mean<strong>in</strong>gthat a one dollar <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> fees would decrease base fares by less than one dollar percent).Ano<strong>the</strong>r participant said he believed that <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> long run, a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>itiatives have <strong>the</strong>73


potential to lower fares, but that <strong>the</strong> economic forces driv<strong>in</strong>g such a change would not ―happenwith <strong>the</strong> stroke of a pen.‖ This <strong>in</strong>dicates a belief <strong>in</strong> price stick<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry, prevent<strong>in</strong>gshort-run equilibration, due <strong>in</strong> part, perhaps, to <strong>the</strong> excess capacity problem discussed earlier.This comment may also <strong>in</strong>dicate that o<strong>the</strong>r factors may cont<strong>in</strong>ue to drive price <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>short run.Some respondents, even though <strong>the</strong>y claimed not to believe <strong>in</strong> any sort of fee-fareconnection, implicitly <strong>in</strong>dicated fees‘ downward pressure on fares by discuss<strong>in</strong>g a sort of subsidy.Such a situation occurs when consumers who don‘t utilize bundled services end up subsidiz<strong>in</strong>gthose who do when such services are <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> ticket price. As one <strong>in</strong>terviewee said,―These services are not enjoyed uniformly by our customers; to just raise <strong>the</strong> fare; you‘re ask<strong>in</strong>geverybody to chip <strong>in</strong>. Some people eat <strong>the</strong> sandwiches and some people don‘t, and if somepeople take two bags and some people don‘t . . . customers don‘t derive <strong>the</strong> same amount ofvalue from each one of <strong>the</strong>m. So ra<strong>the</strong>r than try to subsidize <strong>the</strong> two bag guy with <strong>the</strong> zero bagguy and raise everyth<strong>in</strong>g, I personally th<strong>in</strong>k it makes more sense to [charge] people for what <strong>the</strong>ywant and don‘t charge for what <strong>the</strong>y don‘t want.‖ Ano<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>terviewee similarly noted that <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>dustry needs ―to start gett<strong>in</strong>g to a place where not everyth<strong>in</strong>g is tied to <strong>the</strong> base fare and thatcustomers aren‘t subsidiz<strong>in</strong>g each o<strong>the</strong>r for services that <strong>the</strong>y don‘t value.‖Such comments about a subsidy <strong>in</strong>dicate that when faced with <strong>the</strong> option to rais<strong>in</strong>g faresfor all customers, airl<strong>in</strong>es have <strong>in</strong>stead chosen to charge an additional fee to customers who valueand utilize a certa<strong>in</strong> fee/service (this may, none<strong>the</strong>less, be comb<strong>in</strong>ed with a base fare <strong>in</strong>crease ifmarket dynamics dictate). By implication, this means that <strong>the</strong>re is a negative relationshipbetween fees and fares, as predicted by economic <strong>the</strong>ory. Interviewees may have decided not to74


characterize this negative pressure when asked directly, because many fares have been ris<strong>in</strong>gdespite <strong>the</strong> enactment of fees.Ascerta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> true effect that a-la-carte fees have on <strong>the</strong> base fare requires a regressionanalysis controll<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>the</strong> multitude of o<strong>the</strong>r factors that affect an airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s prices. Such ananalysis is outside of <strong>the</strong> scope of this paper. None<strong>the</strong>less, a cursory look at U.S. carriers‘ airfaredata yields some prelim<strong>in</strong>ary conclusions about potential effects on base fares. Figure 4.3 showsU.S. airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ average domestic fares between <strong>the</strong> first quarter of 2006 and <strong>the</strong> third quarter of2009 (<strong>the</strong> most recent quarter for which data are available). The graph <strong>in</strong>cludes <strong>the</strong> five currentU.S. legacy carriers, as well as five low-cost carriers (LCCs). Of specific <strong>in</strong>terest are <strong>the</strong> averagefares of Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es, which does not charge a first-and-second bag fee, and JetBlueairways, which does not charge for a first checked bag but charges for a second.75


Figure 4.3 – U.S. Airl<strong>in</strong>es Average Fare (One Way), 2006-2009 12Consider<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> fact that bag fee unbundl<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>itiatives largely occurred dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> firstthree quarters of 2008, <strong>the</strong> data <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> graph above show a post-third quarter drop <strong>in</strong> fares for allairl<strong>in</strong>es, except for Southwest, which sees a fare drop at <strong>the</strong> end of 2008. This drop is largelyconsistent with <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>ory that <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>troduction of a fee would cause a drop <strong>in</strong> fares, however amore thorough statistical analysis is needed to determ<strong>in</strong>e how much of this effect, if any, iscaused by unbundl<strong>in</strong>g efforts.A drop <strong>in</strong> fares of LCCs JetBlue and Southwest <strong>in</strong>dicate that <strong>the</strong>re may be o<strong>the</strong>rdynamics that caused fares to drop at this time, most likely <strong>the</strong> nascent economic downturn.However <strong>the</strong>se carriers see a much lower drop <strong>in</strong> fees, <strong>in</strong> percentage terms, than that of <strong>the</strong>12 Source: DOT Orig<strong>in</strong> and Dest<strong>in</strong>ation Data.76


legacy airl<strong>in</strong>es and AirTran Airways and Frontier Airl<strong>in</strong>es (which began charg<strong>in</strong>g bag fees). Thefare decreases are also less than <strong>the</strong> legacy carriers. One <strong>the</strong>oretical explanation for this is that<strong>the</strong> amount of decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> Southwest‘s fares and some of <strong>the</strong> decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> JetBlue‘s expla<strong>in</strong>s o<strong>the</strong>rmarket pric<strong>in</strong>g factors, such as consumer demand and <strong>in</strong>put prices, while <strong>the</strong> additional drop thato<strong>the</strong>r carriers experience represents <strong>the</strong> drop attributable to bag fees.It should be noted that Spirit Airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ fees rema<strong>in</strong> relatively flat dur<strong>in</strong>g this period.None<strong>the</strong>less, that carrier reduced its fares after <strong>the</strong> first quarter <strong>in</strong> 2008. That airl<strong>in</strong>e begancharg<strong>in</strong>g for a first bag <strong>in</strong> June 2007, however, almost a year earlier than o<strong>the</strong>r airl<strong>in</strong>es. Theearlier tim<strong>in</strong>g of Spirit‘s fare drop is not surpris<strong>in</strong>g: <strong>in</strong> announc<strong>in</strong>g its first-bag fee, Spirit alsopledged to lower its system-wide fares (Associated Press 2007). None<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong>re isapproximately a n<strong>in</strong>e-month lag between <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitution of a first bag fee and a decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> fares.Ano<strong>the</strong>r relevant comparison to show <strong>the</strong> base fare effects of unbundl<strong>in</strong>g decisions<strong>in</strong>volves evaluat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> ratio of airl<strong>in</strong>es that do not charge fees to those that do. Figure 4.4 belowshows <strong>the</strong> ratio of JetBlue Airways and Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ average fare to <strong>the</strong> average legacycarrier fare from 2006 to 2009. Concurrently with most network airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ bag fee unbundl<strong>in</strong>gefforts, <strong>the</strong> ratio of Southwest‘s fares to <strong>the</strong> legacy average rises and rema<strong>in</strong>s relatively steadythrough 2009. This conclusively <strong>in</strong>dicates that Southwest‘s base fares rise <strong>in</strong> relation to itsnetwork competitors immediately as <strong>the</strong>y beg<strong>in</strong> tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> bag fee revenue. JetBlue‘s fares alsorise after <strong>the</strong> middle of 2008, however <strong>the</strong> magnitude of <strong>the</strong> price <strong>in</strong>crease is less than that ofSouthwest and doesn‘t br<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> ratio to a substantially higher po<strong>in</strong>t than it has been <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> past.This may be because JetBlue still charges for a second check bag, and is thus earn<strong>in</strong>g someadditional bag revenue.77


Figure 4.4: Ratio of JetBlue Airways and Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es’ Average Fares to <strong>the</strong> Averageof All Network Carriers, 2006–2009Once aga<strong>in</strong>, while no def<strong>in</strong>itive conclusions can be drawn from <strong>the</strong> graphs above, airl<strong>in</strong>esthat have chosen not to unbundle <strong>the</strong> first bag, namely JetBlue Airways and Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es,do have an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> base fares relative to o<strong>the</strong>r carriers. Additionally, <strong>the</strong> earlier tim<strong>in</strong>g ofSpirit Airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ fare drop and its explicit announcement of lower fares provide evidence that <strong>the</strong><strong>the</strong>oretical predictions described above may be plausible. This l<strong>in</strong>k is not conclusive or def<strong>in</strong>itive,and merits fur<strong>the</strong>r research to control for o<strong>the</strong>r factors impact<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> fare to determ<strong>in</strong>e <strong>the</strong> trueeffect that a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g has on base airfares.In <strong>the</strong> case that a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g exerts a downward pressure on base fares, <strong>the</strong>re arevary<strong>in</strong>g welfare effects for different types of consumers. On a more general level, however,78


Armstrong and Vickers (2010), whose model was discussed <strong>in</strong> chapter 2 as <strong>the</strong> underly<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>orybeh<strong>in</strong>d airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ a-la-carte price strategy, discusses <strong>the</strong> overall effects on welfare from two-parttariffs as a non-l<strong>in</strong>ear price strategy. The authors f<strong>in</strong>d that ultimately, <strong>the</strong> two-part pric<strong>in</strong>garrangement leads to higher total welfare, <strong>in</strong>creased producer welfare, and decreased consumerwelfare (51). Increases <strong>in</strong> producer and total surplus are due to firms extract<strong>in</strong>g additionalconsumer surplus through <strong>the</strong> two-part tariff and a cost-based l<strong>in</strong>ear price reduc<strong>in</strong>g abovemarg<strong>in</strong>alcost pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> imperfect competition. Armstrong and Vickers discuss that variousfactors may affect this welfare calculation, however. For example, if customer heterogeneityrises above a certa<strong>in</strong> level, total welfare will be reduced (despite producer welfare be<strong>in</strong>gimproved). If consumers strongly associate with a certa<strong>in</strong> brand, however, <strong>the</strong> positive effect onoverall welfare will be multiplied, but consumer welfare will still be lower.Applied to <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>es, <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>oretical welfare effects above apply if fares drop when feesare <strong>in</strong>stituted. These welfare effects are tied <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> subsidy discussed by <strong>in</strong>terviewees.Assum<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>the</strong> reduction <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> base fare is not greater than <strong>the</strong> fees <strong>the</strong> passengers pay, a-lacartepric<strong>in</strong>g is extract<strong>in</strong>g additional surplus from consumers who used to utilize <strong>the</strong>se for freeand mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m worse off. This is because, under <strong>the</strong> previous arrangement, <strong>the</strong> costs ofprovid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>se benefits to a concentrated number of consumers were dispersed across allpassengers, regardless of whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y used <strong>the</strong> service. In <strong>the</strong>ory, <strong>the</strong>se costs would not only<strong>in</strong>clude operational costs, but also <strong>the</strong> opportunity cost of not charg<strong>in</strong>g a fee for <strong>the</strong> service. With<strong>the</strong> new a-la-carte structure, a person check<strong>in</strong>g two bags and order<strong>in</strong>g an onboard meal nowbears a greater responsibility for pay<strong>in</strong>g for that service. Of course, <strong>the</strong> additional fee is<strong>the</strong>oretically offset by a fare that is lower than it o<strong>the</strong>rwise would have been. It must be79


emembered that this characterization assumes static product quality; <strong>the</strong> next section willconsider <strong>the</strong> effects of changes <strong>in</strong> quality of <strong>the</strong> ancillary products/services.Look<strong>in</strong>g at <strong>the</strong> ratio of Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ fares to <strong>the</strong> legacy carrier average provides aback-of-<strong>the</strong>-envelope estimate of <strong>the</strong> potential fare effects from baggage unbundl<strong>in</strong>g. Assum<strong>in</strong>gthat this ratio rema<strong>in</strong>ed constant <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> first quarter of 2009 <strong>in</strong>stead of chang<strong>in</strong>g, one canextrapolate what <strong>the</strong> average fares of all legacy airl<strong>in</strong>es would have been absent <strong>the</strong> baggage feeunbundl<strong>in</strong>g. If legacy airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ fares kept pace with those of Southwest <strong>in</strong>to 2009, <strong>the</strong>se carrierswould have charged a first-quarter 2009 fare of $223.71 <strong>in</strong>stead of <strong>the</strong> $201.42 that <strong>the</strong>y actuallycharged. This would represent a decl<strong>in</strong>e of $22.29 for <strong>the</strong> average network carrier ticket fare thatoccurred because bag fees were <strong>in</strong>stituted. For <strong>the</strong> average passenger, this value would more thaneclipse <strong>the</strong> price of check<strong>in</strong>g a first bag on any airl<strong>in</strong>e at <strong>the</strong> time (and still eclipses <strong>the</strong> price ofmany airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ current first-bag charges). Though this is a cursory calculation ignor<strong>in</strong>g a numberof o<strong>the</strong>r factors, it <strong>in</strong>dicates that <strong>the</strong> average network carrier who pays to check one bag may stillbe pay<strong>in</strong>g less for her ticket.Customers who do not utilize ancillary services are made better off so long as <strong>the</strong>y paybase fares that are less than <strong>the</strong>y would be under <strong>the</strong> s<strong>in</strong>gle-price scenario. Unfortunately,because <strong>the</strong>ir analysis only considers a two-part price for one good (whereas airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ access feealso entitles customers to a ticket), Armstrong and Vickers do not consider <strong>the</strong> welfareimplications of consumers who only pay only one of <strong>the</strong> prices. None<strong>the</strong>less, basic <strong>in</strong>tuition<strong>in</strong>dicates that customers who did not utilize ancillary services before <strong>the</strong> fees are better off. Solong as fares are driven downward, <strong>the</strong>re is no need for <strong>the</strong>se customers to pay an extra premiumto cover o<strong>the</strong>r customers‘ usage of certa<strong>in</strong> products. This may be part of <strong>the</strong> reason whycustomer reaction and compla<strong>in</strong>ts may be more measured than what is seen <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> media; one80


<strong>in</strong>terviewee mentioned that fewer than half of its customers checked a bag. One of a networkairl<strong>in</strong>e‘s core customer groups is bus<strong>in</strong>ess travelers, who tend to pack light and carry bags <strong>in</strong>to<strong>the</strong> cab<strong>in</strong> (though many bus<strong>in</strong>ess passengers do not pay fees because of employer-sponsoredtravel or elite status with a frequent flyer program). These customers may realize, <strong>in</strong>tuitively, that<strong>the</strong>y do benefit from not hav<strong>in</strong>g ancillary products and services bundled <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> fare if <strong>the</strong>y werepay<strong>in</strong>g a sort of subsidy under <strong>the</strong> previous arrangement.One additional consideration must be made regard<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> potential for <strong>in</strong>creased overallwelfare—<strong>the</strong> fact that a price change affect<strong>in</strong>g different consumers implicitly affects consumeruse based on consumer valuation. For example, with a bag fee <strong>in</strong>stituted, <strong>the</strong> number ofcustomers who check bags is likely to decrease due to <strong>the</strong> law of demand, a trend supported byresponses dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terviews. With some consumers opt<strong>in</strong>g not to pay <strong>the</strong> bag fee, airl<strong>in</strong>es do notneed to provide a product to consumers who do not highly value luggage check but werereceiv<strong>in</strong>g it as a subsidy previously.Here<strong>in</strong> lies <strong>the</strong> key efficiency ga<strong>in</strong> result<strong>in</strong>g from a bag fee—by charg<strong>in</strong>g customers whovalue a service for <strong>the</strong> use of that service, airl<strong>in</strong>es (so long as <strong>the</strong>y are pric<strong>in</strong>g efficiently) arehelp<strong>in</strong>g to guide total consumer resources to <strong>the</strong>ir highest-valued use. Thus while somepassengers are made better off and some passengers are made worse off, <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ a-la-cartepric<strong>in</strong>g arrangement can be viewed as a move that improves efficiency overall. This argument, ofcourse, h<strong>in</strong>ges on <strong>the</strong> fact that bag fees are set based on market supply and demand dynamic, andthat carriers aren‘t us<strong>in</strong>g market power to charge monopoly bag prices. Fur<strong>the</strong>r research toanswer this question could exam<strong>in</strong>e whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>re is evidence of a markup over marg<strong>in</strong>al cost forbag fees.81


One additional consideration that must be made, however, arises from tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>efficiency argument to <strong>the</strong> extreme—why wouldn‘t airl<strong>in</strong>es simply enact a-la-carte fees for alldifferent products that could be used onboard? For example, <strong>the</strong>re could be charges for lavatoryuse, soft dr<strong>in</strong>ks, for r<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> flight attendant call button, for turn<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>the</strong> read<strong>in</strong>g light, etc.Interviews <strong>in</strong>dicated that consumers may desire to have <strong>the</strong> option to use certa<strong>in</strong> services free ofcharge and may be will<strong>in</strong>g to accept a sort of subsidy arrangement. For o<strong>the</strong>r services, <strong>the</strong>re maybe health/safety issues that make a bundl<strong>in</strong>g arrangement preferable to an a-la-carte model.Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, airl<strong>in</strong>e brand<strong>in</strong>g, as discussed earlier, may play a role <strong>in</strong> prevent<strong>in</strong>g an airl<strong>in</strong>e fromunbundl<strong>in</strong>g nearly all services for fear of becom<strong>in</strong>g perceived as overly cheap travel provider.One <strong>in</strong>terviewee po<strong>in</strong>ted to free soft dr<strong>in</strong>ks as one of <strong>the</strong> services that most consumersprefer to receive with <strong>the</strong> price of a ticket: ―We did a bunch of research around what matters forpeople and what doesn‘t, and oddly a dr<strong>in</strong>k on board has this really emotional attachment for ourcustomer.‖ She added that <strong>the</strong> revenue ga<strong>in</strong>s to be achieved from charg<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>the</strong> soda were alsonegligible. This <strong>in</strong>dicates that with low potential for ancillary revenues from certa<strong>in</strong> items, <strong>the</strong>airl<strong>in</strong>e is better off bundl<strong>in</strong>g certa<strong>in</strong> items or services. This is because <strong>the</strong> potential revenuesga<strong>in</strong>ed from such items are less than <strong>the</strong> costs of los<strong>in</strong>g customers to airl<strong>in</strong>es with a morepreferred arrangement. Of course, surveys and market data can mask customers‘ true preference,and some o<strong>the</strong>r airl<strong>in</strong>es do charge for soft dr<strong>in</strong>ks. These carriers (for e.g., Allegiant Air, SpiritAirl<strong>in</strong>es) are currently seen as offer<strong>in</strong>g a totally no-frills experience; if consumers beg<strong>in</strong> toextend such a conception to o<strong>the</strong>r carriers, <strong>the</strong>re may be a potential for added fees <strong>in</strong> this area <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> future.82


Changes <strong>in</strong> Product QualityWhile <strong>the</strong> above discussion focuses on <strong>the</strong> prices and quantities of airfare, competitionand price changes also occur on a quality dimension. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, consumer welfare is impactednot only by changes <strong>in</strong> price relative to quantity, but also price relative to quality. As an example,based on her utility function, a consumer may be better off buy<strong>in</strong>g a glass with her favorite sportsteam‘s logo on it for $5 than receiv<strong>in</strong>g a low-quality plastic cup laden with sponsor ads for freewith <strong>the</strong> purchase of a ticket to a professional sport<strong>in</strong>g event. Ultimately, improvements <strong>in</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>eancillary product quality have <strong>the</strong> potential to improve consumer utility from product offer<strong>in</strong>gsrelative to when <strong>the</strong>y were bundled with <strong>the</strong> price of a ticket.In accordance with <strong>the</strong> law of demand, a consumer‘s ideal quality when product price iszero, or close to zero, differs from a consumer‘s preferred quality when a higher price is set.Buyers who consumed some quantity of low quality products given away at no cost may nolonger wish to consume those products if <strong>the</strong> price rises. For producers, this means that offer<strong>in</strong>gsuch products on <strong>the</strong> market at a fee will only allow <strong>the</strong>m to capture small amounts of revenuethat may not justify <strong>the</strong> costs of offer<strong>in</strong>g those products. As an <strong>in</strong>tuitive example, an airl<strong>in</strong>epassenger may eat a free meal onboard an aircraft, even if she f<strong>in</strong>ds it to be of low quality. If <strong>the</strong>airl<strong>in</strong>e beg<strong>in</strong>s charg<strong>in</strong>g any amount for that same meal, however, <strong>the</strong> customer may not consumeit.Interview data <strong>in</strong>dicate that <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e, and likely all carriers <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry, face strong<strong>in</strong>centives to improve product quality when charg<strong>in</strong>g customers for a product or service,especially when <strong>the</strong> product is one that has been previously <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> price of a ticket. One<strong>in</strong>terviewee mentioned <strong>the</strong> example of airl<strong>in</strong>e meals: ―[If we‘re] go<strong>in</strong>g to try and charge $12 for ameal, we need to provide a meal that‘s comparable to when <strong>the</strong>y pay $12 somewhere else and so83


<strong>the</strong>re‘s . . . a quality issue <strong>the</strong>re. I feel like . . . it does pressure you to sort of deliver it because<strong>the</strong> customer‘s expectations rise.‖ Indeed <strong>the</strong> meals that had previously been <strong>the</strong> butt of jokes (asdescribed by <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terviewee) have been replaced by more appeal<strong>in</strong>g options. For example, DeltaAir L<strong>in</strong>es offers food that has been designed by celebrity chef Todd English for purchase onlonger domestic flights, and American Airl<strong>in</strong>es offers onboard menu selections from BostonMarket.Ano<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>terviewee agreed that meals exhibited <strong>the</strong> characteristic of productimprovement. He expressed doubt that <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centive to improved quality applied to certa<strong>in</strong>products such as checked baggage to attract consumer revenue. The data may support this claim:Figure 4.5 shows <strong>the</strong> relationship between mishandled baggage reports per 1,000 customers andbaggage revenue per passenger for select airl<strong>in</strong>es. As seen from <strong>the</strong> ord<strong>in</strong>ary least squares l<strong>in</strong>e ofbest fit, <strong>the</strong> amount of consumer revenue has no significant correlation with <strong>the</strong> amount ofbaggage revenue per passenger. None<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong> coefficient of determ<strong>in</strong>ation is extremely low at0.003 and <strong>the</strong> P value is 0.862, <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>the</strong> result of this l<strong>in</strong>e of best fit is not statisticallysignificant.While this simple relationship is not conclusive, it <strong>in</strong>dicates that fur<strong>the</strong>r research may bewarranted to determ<strong>in</strong>e whe<strong>the</strong>r airl<strong>in</strong>es with high volumes of bag revenue have not improvedbaggage handl<strong>in</strong>g quality. Such a phenomenon could potentially be a manifestation of consumers‘demand <strong>in</strong>elasticity for baggage fees: consumers need<strong>in</strong>g to transport a checked bag have fewo<strong>the</strong>r options than to pay <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e to transport <strong>the</strong> luggage. Airl<strong>in</strong>es may ultimately face littlepressure to improve product quality when <strong>the</strong>y unbundle services for which consumers have fewalternatives.84


Figure 4.5: Plot of Mishandled Baggage Reports/Baggage Revenue and Regression L<strong>in</strong>e 13.On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, consumers have more alternatives with regards to products such asonboard food or <strong>in</strong>flight enterta<strong>in</strong>ment. For example, consumers have a wide variety of foodoptions available <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airport (food that can be brought onto <strong>the</strong> plane), as well as a number ofenterta<strong>in</strong>ment options through iPods, personal DVD players, magaz<strong>in</strong>es, etc. Improvement <strong>in</strong>food quality has already been mentioned; a number of domestic airl<strong>in</strong>es offer complimentaryseatback television for free with recent movies available for purchase. 14 Ano<strong>the</strong>r manifestation ofimproved product quality for goods with elastic demand <strong>in</strong>cludes JetBlue Airway‘s unbundl<strong>in</strong>gof pillows and blankets <strong>in</strong> 2008 (JetBlue Airways 2008). Instead of unwashed items reused bymany customers, however, <strong>the</strong> for-sale pillow and blankets are made of tox<strong>in</strong>-repellent fabricsand environmentally friendly materials. Additionally, consumers who purchase <strong>the</strong> $7 amenity13 Source: DOT Bureau of Transportation Statistics T-100 Data and DOT Air Travel Consumer Reports. Data <strong>in</strong>cludema<strong>in</strong>l<strong>in</strong>e carriers subject to mandatory baggage compla<strong>in</strong>t report<strong>in</strong>g and is limited to domestic travel. <strong>Student</strong>’s tstatistic = 0.18, P value = 0.862.14 Two notable examples are Delta Air L<strong>in</strong>es and JetBlue Airways.85


kit are able to keep <strong>the</strong> pillow and blanket and also receive a $5 coupon to Bed Bath & Beyond.American Airl<strong>in</strong>es recently <strong>in</strong>stituted a similar program.While airl<strong>in</strong>e consumers us<strong>in</strong>g ancillary products and services may be pay<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>the</strong>m,<strong>the</strong>re is evidence that <strong>in</strong> some cases <strong>the</strong>y are receiv<strong>in</strong>g higher product quality for <strong>the</strong>irexpenditures than <strong>the</strong>y would be if such products and services were <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> fare.Ultimately, this quality improvement should be factored <strong>in</strong>to any analysis of <strong>the</strong> welfare ga<strong>in</strong>sand losses. While a consumer may need to pay $12 for a meal that was given for free before,better quality means that <strong>the</strong> consumer is better off than if she were pay<strong>in</strong>g for a meal whosequality was unchanged before it was unbundled. Thus improved quality works <strong>in</strong> an oppositedirection to <strong>the</strong> welfare losses that some customers experience and perhaps could lead to welfareenhancement for customers who strongly value product quality and are will<strong>in</strong>g to pay for it.Despite quality improvements, it should be noted that certa<strong>in</strong> elements of a-la-cartepric<strong>in</strong>g may produce <strong>the</strong> potential for adverse impact on quality. A prime example deals withcarry-on baggage: customers now face <strong>in</strong>centives to br<strong>in</strong>g additional luggage <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> cab<strong>in</strong> toplace <strong>in</strong>to overhead b<strong>in</strong>s. Anecdotally, this scenario has led to less room for onboard space and<strong>the</strong> frequent need to ―gate check‖ any excess carry-on luggage that does not fit <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> cab<strong>in</strong>.Though <strong>in</strong>terviewees stated that <strong>in</strong>creased onboard complexity from bag fees have notsignificantly affected <strong>the</strong>ir airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s on-time performance, more complexity dur<strong>in</strong>g board<strong>in</strong>g has<strong>the</strong> potential to reduce <strong>the</strong> quality and welfare for all consumers.It appears as if airl<strong>in</strong>es may be able to mitigate such negative effects through fur<strong>the</strong>r feesand charges. In April 2010, Spirit Airl<strong>in</strong>es announced that <strong>in</strong> an effort to reduce overhead b<strong>in</strong>crowd<strong>in</strong>g and offer even lower fares, it would beg<strong>in</strong> charg<strong>in</strong>g customers who br<strong>in</strong>g a carry-onbag that does not fit under <strong>the</strong> seat (Mart<strong>in</strong> 2010). It is unclear whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>se fees will survive86


ecent congressional opposition to a carry-on bag fee and whe<strong>the</strong>r o<strong>the</strong>r higher-service airl<strong>in</strong>eswould match <strong>the</strong> charge (Hefl<strong>in</strong> 2010). None<strong>the</strong>less, it should be noted that even quality effectsfrom a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g have an implication for airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ future charges and <strong>the</strong> fur<strong>the</strong>rdevelopment of an a-la-carte <strong>in</strong>dustry structure.Ga<strong>in</strong>s from Consumer ChoiceThe previous section discussed <strong>the</strong> importance of product quality and its effect primarilyon consumers who buy <strong>the</strong> product. There is an additional consideration to be made, however,apply<strong>in</strong>g to all customers who fly. Because of a carrier‘s ability to generate revenue fromancillary products and services, a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g provide consumers with an expanded menu ofoptions, some of which are of higher quality than o<strong>the</strong>rwise been provided. Depend<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>the</strong>time until <strong>the</strong>ir travel plans and amount of future uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty for preferences for onboard services,some travelers benefit from know<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>the</strong>y will have <strong>the</strong> option to obta<strong>in</strong> additional on-boardproducts if <strong>the</strong>y so please.Ultimately, consumers benefit from hav<strong>in</strong>g additional choices available to <strong>the</strong>m for futurepurchase, even if <strong>the</strong>y do not end up utiliz<strong>in</strong>g that service. For example, while a certa<strong>in</strong> customermay not end up purchas<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>flight movie ex post, she may, ex ante, value <strong>the</strong> option topurchase that service dur<strong>in</strong>g her flight. As Petr<strong>in</strong> (2002) po<strong>in</strong>ts out <strong>in</strong> his analysis of newproducts <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> m<strong>in</strong>ivan market <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1970s, consumers experience welfare ga<strong>in</strong>s when <strong>the</strong>yreceive additional choices <strong>in</strong> a certa<strong>in</strong> product market. Ultimately, additional choice generallyhelps to mitigate a firm‘s ability to exercise market power and opens up consumers to welfareenhanc<strong>in</strong>goptions that were not previously available. This case can be applied to retail servicesat <strong>the</strong> airport: while consumers had <strong>the</strong> opportunity to purchase certa<strong>in</strong> products before board<strong>in</strong>g87


(such as meals, books, and blankets), consumers now have <strong>the</strong> opportunity to obta<strong>in</strong> a differentproduct quality and level of convenience by buy<strong>in</strong>g on board. Additionally, competition fromairl<strong>in</strong>es will put fur<strong>the</strong>r pressure on airport retailers to offer consumers with competitive prices.Interviewees reiterated that <strong>the</strong>y believe <strong>the</strong> a-la-carte model is beneficial <strong>in</strong> provid<strong>in</strong>gconsumers with additional options and ability to customize <strong>the</strong>ir trip. As one <strong>in</strong>terviewee said,―It‘s k<strong>in</strong>d of a w<strong>in</strong>-w<strong>in</strong> for customers and for <strong>the</strong> companies because it lets people reallycustomize <strong>the</strong>ir experience.‖ She also said that while airl<strong>in</strong>e customers may be unaccustomed to<strong>the</strong> idea of customization and benefits from additional choice, some of those same people areaccustomed to it <strong>in</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r sett<strong>in</strong>gs: ―You know people go on Chipotle.com and <strong>the</strong>y spend 15m<strong>in</strong>utes customiz<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir $5 burrito.‖It should be remembered, however, that fast casual restaurants offer<strong>in</strong>g a variety oftopp<strong>in</strong>gs on one‘s food often offer <strong>the</strong>m for free. Consumers, of course, would be even better offif <strong>the</strong>y could choose additional options to customize <strong>the</strong>ir travel plans at no additional cost. Dueto factors discussed earlier, however, offer<strong>in</strong>g certa<strong>in</strong> ancillary products and services for free isnot a revenue-maximiz<strong>in</strong>g strategy for many airl<strong>in</strong>es. Thus, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> case of <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry,consumer benefits from expanded choices are only possible with those options com<strong>in</strong>g at anadded fee. In <strong>the</strong> alternative scenario, which represents <strong>the</strong> way airl<strong>in</strong>es previously operated,passengers get add-ons for free, but <strong>the</strong>ir set of choices is much more limited.Early unbundl<strong>in</strong>g efforts and current a-la-carte product development <strong>in</strong>itiatives, many ofwhich are <strong>in</strong>troduced experimentally by airl<strong>in</strong>es, may drive changes <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> air travel experiencethat have <strong>the</strong> potential to fur<strong>the</strong>r expand consumer choice and generate consumer welfarebenefits. In discuss<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> future of ancillary revenues, many <strong>in</strong>terviewees spoke of <strong>the</strong> potentialfor airl<strong>in</strong>es to expand <strong>the</strong> products and services <strong>the</strong>y are able to sell onboard <strong>the</strong> aircraft. In such88


a way, airl<strong>in</strong>es may move closer to <strong>the</strong> type of model employed by a cruise ship operator or acas<strong>in</strong>o—with large portions of ancillary revenue generated onboard <strong>the</strong> ship or <strong>in</strong>side <strong>the</strong> cas<strong>in</strong>o,<strong>the</strong>se firms have an <strong>in</strong>centive to offer low prices <strong>in</strong> order to fill rooms <strong>in</strong> order to generaterevenues from guests‘ o<strong>the</strong>r spend<strong>in</strong>g. For example, one <strong>in</strong>terviewee spoke about sell<strong>in</strong>gadditional items to customers such as coupon books for dest<strong>in</strong>ations.There are a number of reasons why <strong>the</strong> majority of carriers may not offer this sort ofmodel currently. For example, <strong>the</strong>y may not have <strong>the</strong> expertise or technology currently necessaryto beg<strong>in</strong> to sell some seats at cheap prices <strong>in</strong> order to generate onboard revenues. From anentrepreneurial standpo<strong>in</strong>t, <strong>the</strong>re may be some uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty associated with <strong>the</strong> profitability ofprovid<strong>in</strong>g many additional add-ons. Ano<strong>the</strong>r potential limit perta<strong>in</strong>s to <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s brand. The<strong>in</strong>troduction of a new product also is tied to where <strong>the</strong> carrier wishes to position itself <strong>in</strong> relationto its customers <strong>in</strong> a Hotell<strong>in</strong>g-type location space. Perhaps offer<strong>in</strong>g a multitude of additionaltravel add-ons may make network airl<strong>in</strong>es and high-service LCCs appear ―cheap,‖ which maymove carriers away from <strong>the</strong>ir target group of consumers. In do<strong>in</strong>g so, <strong>the</strong>se airl<strong>in</strong>es may faceprofit losses o<strong>the</strong>r airl<strong>in</strong>es that offer a number of associated travel products and a lower cost oftravel. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, entrepreneurs <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e may simply be unsure of <strong>the</strong> benefits of offer<strong>in</strong>gadditional onboard services. Thus far, <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry has not moved far beyond Sky Mall catalogs<strong>in</strong> terms of onboard retail sales. Perhaps as airl<strong>in</strong>es ga<strong>in</strong> more experience from sell<strong>in</strong>g onboardamenities, entrepreneurs will become aware to new profitable opportunities for cab<strong>in</strong> sales.If <strong>the</strong>y do become more prevalent, new a-la-carte product opportunities have <strong>the</strong>potentially to dramatically change <strong>the</strong> way airl<strong>in</strong>es price travel. One <strong>in</strong>terviewee said: ―Over time,I th<strong>in</strong>k you‘ll see <strong>the</strong> desire to fill seats because if you get people on <strong>the</strong> plane, you can sell to<strong>the</strong>m, whereas before, historically, it‘s been sort of <strong>the</strong> opposite. You ga<strong>in</strong>ed by not hav<strong>in</strong>g89


[certa<strong>in</strong> customers] because <strong>the</strong>re‘s all <strong>the</strong>se costs; if I put a guy on <strong>the</strong> plane, I‘ve got to givehim a turkey sandwich, I‘ve got to do this, I‘ve got to do that, I‘ve got to take his bag. . . . This<strong>in</strong>centive to fill a plane could lead airl<strong>in</strong>es offer last-m<strong>in</strong>ute empty seats at highly discountedprices, <strong>in</strong> a similar way that a <strong>La</strong>s Vegas hotel may attract a gambler with a low last-m<strong>in</strong>ute roomprice. Such a pric<strong>in</strong>g strategy would be fundamentally different from <strong>the</strong> current arrangement, <strong>in</strong>which last-m<strong>in</strong>ute seats often carry a significant premium.Even standby board<strong>in</strong>g, which is used to fill up <strong>the</strong> very last seats on a plane, carriesadditional charges for most customers. Just as last-m<strong>in</strong>ute fares carry a premium from timesensitivecustomers who are will<strong>in</strong>g to pay to travel on short notice, standby travel commands apremium because it gives time-sensitive customers <strong>the</strong> opportunity to arrive at <strong>the</strong>ir dest<strong>in</strong>ationsearlier. It should be noted, none<strong>the</strong>less, that certa<strong>in</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>es occasionally offer last-m<strong>in</strong>uteairfares through <strong>the</strong>ir websites or through third-party travel providers. One potential reason whythis strategy has not been expanded yet, however, is that <strong>the</strong>se deals may <strong>in</strong>centivize flexiblebudget travelers to always wait until <strong>the</strong> last m<strong>in</strong>ute to ga<strong>in</strong> fire-sale deals. Such problem issolved <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> hotel <strong>in</strong>dustry by websites such as Hotwire.com, which sells last-m<strong>in</strong>ute rooms butdoes not disclose <strong>the</strong> hotel‘s identity until after book<strong>in</strong>g. Currently, a number of websites followthis strategy for airl<strong>in</strong>e travel, mostly for <strong>in</strong>tercont<strong>in</strong>ental flights. As airl<strong>in</strong>es fur<strong>the</strong>r develop <strong>the</strong>irancillary products, an <strong>in</strong>creased number of tickets may be sold <strong>in</strong> such a manner.These lower prices have <strong>the</strong> potential to confer additional benefits to consumers who donot utilize ancillary products and services by lower<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> fare even fur<strong>the</strong>r. Additionally, <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>centive to cont<strong>in</strong>ue to expand <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s set of product offer<strong>in</strong>gs expands consumer choices,conferr<strong>in</strong>g fur<strong>the</strong>r benefits. While one <strong>in</strong>terviewee said that <strong>the</strong> ―sky is <strong>the</strong> limit‖ when it comesto unbundl<strong>in</strong>g, it is important to remember an airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s ability to sell may ultimately be90


constra<strong>in</strong>ed by aircraft weight limitations and cost. While an airl<strong>in</strong>e may want to offer anonboard gift shop for example, <strong>the</strong> added weight and space on <strong>the</strong> aircraft may drive prices tounsusta<strong>in</strong>able levels.Aircraft space and weight restrictions may also mean that some ancillary products wouldbe unavailable to customers when <strong>the</strong>y want to purchase <strong>the</strong>m. While, as discussed <strong>in</strong> chapter 3,<strong>in</strong>terviewees said <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e focuses on <strong>the</strong> ability to deliver on a product, <strong>in</strong> some cases,unpredictable demand may lead to scarcity onboard <strong>the</strong> aircraft. For example, some customersmay not be able to purchase <strong>the</strong>ir desired food selections if <strong>the</strong> aircraft is not loaded with ampleprovisions. Ultimately, if customers experience repeated unpredictability <strong>in</strong> be<strong>in</strong>g able to obta<strong>in</strong>a certa<strong>in</strong> ancillary product or service, <strong>the</strong>ir welfare ga<strong>in</strong>s from additional choice may bedim<strong>in</strong>ished.ConclusionThis chapter has outl<strong>in</strong>ed a number of <strong>the</strong> welfare considerations that affect all consumerstravell<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> an airl<strong>in</strong>e market marked by a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g. Perhaps most significantly, <strong>the</strong>reappears to be limited evidence that fees may place downward pressure on base fares. Futureresearch is needed to determ<strong>in</strong>e <strong>the</strong> presence and nature of any fee-fare effect, controll<strong>in</strong>g foro<strong>the</strong>r factors. Such research is important <strong>in</strong> determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> changes <strong>in</strong> consumer welfare forconsumers who do and do not utilize ancillary services. So long as fees put negative pressure onfares, a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g promotes a more efficient arrangement by remov<strong>in</strong>g a sort of subsidythat customers who did not utilize ancillary services had to pay. Additionally, future researchshould also fur<strong>the</strong>r ascerta<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> effects of improved product quality and additional consumerchoice aris<strong>in</strong>g from a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g.91


Chapter 4 ReferencesArmstrong, Mark & Vickers, John. 2010. ―Competitive Nonl<strong>in</strong>ear <strong>Pric<strong>in</strong>g</strong> and Bundl<strong>in</strong>g.‖ TheReview of Economic Studies. Vol. 77, pp. 30-60.Associated Press. 2007. ―Spirit Airl<strong>in</strong>es to Charge for All Checked Baggage: Fliers Must BuyCoffee, O<strong>the</strong>r In-Flight Dr<strong>in</strong>ks, but Carrier Slash<strong>in</strong>g Airfares.‖ msnbc.com. March 7,available at http://www.msnbc.msn.com/id/17484546/.Bureau of Transportation Statistics. 2010. ―January 2010 Airl<strong>in</strong>e Traffic Data: System Traffic Up1.5 Percent from January 2009.‖ April 15. available athttp://www.bts.gov/press_releases/2010/ bts018_10/html/bts018_10.html.Goetz, Andrew R. & Vowles, Timothy M. 2009. ―The Good, <strong>the</strong> Bad, and <strong>the</strong> Ugly: 30 Years ofUS Airl<strong>in</strong>e Deregulation.‖ Journal of Transport Geography. Vol. 17, pp. 251-263.Hefl<strong>in</strong>, Jay. 2010. ―Schumer Intros Bill Bann<strong>in</strong>g Airl<strong>in</strong>e Carry-On Fee.‖ The Hill onl<strong>in</strong>e. April14, available at http://<strong>the</strong>hill.com/blogs/on-<strong>the</strong>-money/domestic-taxes/92205-schumer<strong>in</strong>tros-bill-bann<strong>in</strong>g-airl<strong>in</strong>e-carry-on-fee.JetBlue Airways. 2008. ―Press Release: No More Dirty Pillow Talk: JetBlue Airways andCleanBrands Partner to Offer <strong>the</strong> World‘s Cleanest Travel Pillow and Blanket Kit.‖August 4, available at http://<strong>in</strong>vestor.jetblue.com/phoenix.zhtml?c=131045&p=irolnewsArticle&ID=1182805.Kiley, David.2009 ―Airl<strong>in</strong>e Fees Run Amok--Pag<strong>in</strong>g Congress.‖ Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Week onl<strong>in</strong>e,September 19, available athttp://www.bus<strong>in</strong>essweek.com/<strong>the</strong>_thread/brandnewday/archives/2009/09/airl<strong>in</strong>e_fees_ru.html.92


Mart<strong>in</strong>, Hugo. 2010. ―Spirit Airl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>La</strong>unches $45 Carry-On Fee.‖ Los Angeles Times onl<strong>in</strong>e.April 7, available at http://articles.latimes.com/2010/apr/07/bus<strong>in</strong>ess/la-fi-spirit7-2010apr07.Oi, Walter Y. 1971. ―A Disneyland Dilemma: Two-Part Tariffs for a Mickey Mouse Monopoly.‖The Quarterly Journal of Economics. Vol. 85, No. 1, pp. 77-96.Petr<strong>in</strong>, Amil. 2002. ―Quantify<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> Benefits of New Products: The Case of <strong>the</strong> M<strong>in</strong>ivan.‖ TheJournal of Political Economy. Vol. 110, No. 4, pp. 705-729.Seaney, Rick. 2008. ―Why Airl<strong>in</strong>es Are Nickel and Dime-<strong>in</strong>g You.‖ ABC News onl<strong>in</strong>e. April 23,available at http://abcnews.go.com/Bus<strong>in</strong>ess/Bus<strong>in</strong>essTravel/story?id=4696928&page=1.93


Chapter 5: The Policy Implications of <strong>the</strong> Ancillary Revenue MovementWith many airl<strong>in</strong>es radically chang<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir pric<strong>in</strong>g structures for ancillary services over<strong>the</strong> past decade, passengers have not been <strong>the</strong> only ones to take note of <strong>the</strong> changes. On a numberof occasions, government officials have denounced airl<strong>in</strong>e fees and discussed potentialregulatory options (Maynard 2009). Perhaps <strong>the</strong> strongest language came <strong>in</strong> April 2010, whenSpirit Airl<strong>in</strong>es announced that it would beg<strong>in</strong> charg<strong>in</strong>g customers to br<strong>in</strong>g certa<strong>in</strong> carry-onluggage <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> cab<strong>in</strong> (fees were only exempted for baggage that could fit underneath <strong>the</strong>passenger‘s seat). In response, Department of Transportation (DOT) Secretary Ray <strong>La</strong>Hood saidthat <strong>the</strong> department would be consider<strong>in</strong>g rulemak<strong>in</strong>g action to prevent Spirit from enact<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>fee: ―I th<strong>in</strong>k it‘s a bit outrageous that an airl<strong>in</strong>e is go<strong>in</strong>g to charge someone to carry on a bag andput it <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> overhead. And I‘ve told our people to try and figure out a way to mitigate that. Ith<strong>in</strong>k it‘s ridiculous‖ (Elliott 2010).Contrary to <strong>the</strong> notion that a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g results <strong>in</strong> some sort of market failure, <strong>the</strong>analysis <strong>in</strong> this paper suggests that this type of pric<strong>in</strong>g emerged <strong>in</strong> part due to an empty coremarket failure and that <strong>the</strong> arrangement is likely welfare enhanc<strong>in</strong>g. Thus, any government<strong>in</strong>tervention that restricts carriers‘ ability to charge certa<strong>in</strong> ancillary fees for costly services thatare highly valued by consumers, such as baggage check, threatens to move <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry awayfrom an arrangement aimed at reach<strong>in</strong>g equilibrium. The onus is ultimately on government toprove that it would be correct<strong>in</strong>g some sort of market failure, preserv<strong>in</strong>g competition, orcorrect<strong>in</strong>g an efficiency-stifl<strong>in</strong>g externality.While <strong>the</strong>re has been no formal, publicly available government analysis of <strong>the</strong> potentialharms of airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g policies, policy makers have implicitly proposed threeprimary rationales for why government ought to regulate or legislate a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>94


airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry. First, <strong>the</strong>y claim that certa<strong>in</strong> charges are anti-consumer because <strong>the</strong>y forcecustomers to pay for a service that ought to be <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> a ticket. Second, airl<strong>in</strong>es are evad<strong>in</strong>gtaxes by <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g revenue sources from ancillary fees, which are not subject to <strong>the</strong> same taxesthat apply to base fare revenues. Third, airl<strong>in</strong>es are underprovid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation about fees,lead<strong>in</strong>g customers to make different choices than <strong>the</strong>y would if <strong>the</strong>y were fully <strong>in</strong>formed. Thischapter will analyze <strong>the</strong> merits beh<strong>in</strong>d each of <strong>the</strong>se ma<strong>in</strong> rationales for government <strong>in</strong>tervention,as well as <strong>the</strong> merits of <strong>the</strong> policy options that would likely be used to correct each problem.The Proper Role of Government and Incentives for RegulationBefore discuss<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> merits of each of <strong>the</strong> rationales for regulatory or legislative<strong>in</strong>tervention, it is worth provid<strong>in</strong>g some brief discussion what role government ought to have <strong>in</strong>foster<strong>in</strong>g market efficiency and protect<strong>in</strong>g consumers <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry. Economistsgenerally argue that government <strong>in</strong>tervention <strong>in</strong> a market should be predicated on provid<strong>in</strong>gsome sort of public good or resolv<strong>in</strong>g a market failure (Arrow 1969). In pursu<strong>in</strong>g this end,regulation serves to prevent deadweight losses from excessive market power, mitigate economic<strong>in</strong>efficiency aris<strong>in</strong>g from externality effects, and provide public goods that are demanded byconsumers but underprovided (or unprovided) by producers.Despite <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>oretical ideal for government as a welfare-enhanc<strong>in</strong>g entity whoseregulation is aimed at correct<strong>in</strong>g problems <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy, <strong>the</strong>re are a number of compet<strong>in</strong>gexplanations for how regulation operates and what <strong>in</strong>centives may drive a certa<strong>in</strong> regulatorystructure. Stigler (1971) argued that private firms expend resources to capture <strong>the</strong> regulatorysystem <strong>in</strong> order to obta<strong>in</strong> regulations that would harm competitors or bolster <strong>the</strong>ir own position<strong>in</strong> a market. O<strong>the</strong>r scholars po<strong>in</strong>t to different rationales for government rules. For example,95


Niskanen (1968) po<strong>in</strong>ts to <strong>the</strong> budget-maximiz<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>centive that regulatory agencies face <strong>in</strong>mak<strong>in</strong>g decisions about regulation. Because of <strong>the</strong>ir desire to expand <strong>the</strong> scope and budget of<strong>the</strong>ir agency, regulators may construct regulation or programs that do not maximize net benefitsfor <strong>the</strong>ir sponsors (voters or <strong>in</strong>terest groups).Perhaps most relevant to this paper is Posner‘s (1971) <strong>the</strong>ory that regulation has <strong>the</strong>effects of compell<strong>in</strong>g a firm to provide certa<strong>in</strong> customers with a subsidized product or service at<strong>the</strong> expense of o<strong>the</strong>r customers. As such, regulation often imposes a de facto tax on certa<strong>in</strong> usersthat is transferred to o<strong>the</strong>r users of a certa<strong>in</strong> service; this tax allows for provision of some servicethat would o<strong>the</strong>rwise be unprovided or underprovided <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> market. Posner mentions a numberof potential examples, such as natural gas producers be<strong>in</strong>g forced to sell at prices that do not<strong>in</strong>clude scarcity rents, thus benefit<strong>in</strong>g current consumers as <strong>the</strong> expense of future customers (23).As will be discussed fur<strong>the</strong>r below, regulation of certa<strong>in</strong> a-la-carte products and services mayhave this effect of tax<strong>in</strong>g certa<strong>in</strong> users for <strong>the</strong> benefit of o<strong>the</strong>rs.One additional dist<strong>in</strong>ction ought to be made between regulation and legislation. WhileDOT and <strong>the</strong> Federal Aviation Adm<strong>in</strong>istration are primarily tasked with regulat<strong>in</strong>g airl<strong>in</strong>es‘practices, <strong>the</strong>se agencies ultimately receive <strong>the</strong>ir mandates from Congress. Various members ofCongress have been vocal about <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>in</strong>tention to <strong>in</strong>vestigate and fight fees; RepresentativeJames L. Oberstar, chairman of <strong>the</strong> House Committee on Transportation and Infrastructure hasbeen one of <strong>the</strong> ma<strong>in</strong> supporters of an <strong>in</strong>vestigation <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> trend, commission<strong>in</strong>g a GovernmentAccountability Office report on <strong>the</strong> subject. Additionally, Senator Charles Schumer, along witho<strong>the</strong>r lawmakers, <strong>in</strong>troduced legislation <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> senate to ban airl<strong>in</strong>es from charg<strong>in</strong>g fees for carryonluggage (Hefl<strong>in</strong> 2010). Congress thus could issue laws curtail<strong>in</strong>g airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ ability to chargefees, laws that would take precedence over an agency‘s regulation.96


It should be mentioned that Congress need not necessarily legislate <strong>in</strong> order to motivateaction on airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ pric<strong>in</strong>g policies. As outl<strong>in</strong>ed by We<strong>in</strong>gast and Moran (1985), <strong>the</strong> legislature‘scontrol over bureaucratic agencies‘ budget, roles, and function<strong>in</strong>g can be leveraged <strong>in</strong> order tomotivate agency action. For example, if a given member of Congress has significant <strong>in</strong>fluence <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> appropriations process over DOT and wishes to curtail ancillary fees, she could compel thatagency to undertake action that would achieve that end. Thus, politicians‘ <strong>in</strong>centives to curtailairl<strong>in</strong>e bag fees could result <strong>in</strong> rulemak<strong>in</strong>g by bureaucrats. Such rulemak<strong>in</strong>g would likely reign <strong>in</strong>fees <strong>in</strong> a way that meets <strong>the</strong> objectives of <strong>the</strong> legislative majority or those Members of Congresswho <strong>in</strong>fluence and control various committees.Consumer Harm/Travel Necessity Rationale for RegulationSen. Robert Menendez, a co-author of <strong>the</strong> bill that <strong>in</strong>tents to prevent airl<strong>in</strong>es fromcharg<strong>in</strong>g consumers to put carry-on bags <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> overhead b<strong>in</strong>, said dur<strong>in</strong>g a CNN <strong>in</strong>terview <strong>in</strong>April 2010: ―It seems that air carriers are cross<strong>in</strong>g a l<strong>in</strong>e that will end [by] pric<strong>in</strong>g middle-classfamilies right out of be<strong>in</strong>g able to fly, and that‘s not right. While airl<strong>in</strong>es have a right to set prices,families should have <strong>the</strong> right to br<strong>in</strong>g a change of clo<strong>the</strong>s with <strong>the</strong>m and not be gouged for it‖(CNN 2010, para. 8). Additionally, a request from representatives Oberstar and Jerry Costellodirect<strong>in</strong>g GAO to commission a report on a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g refers to ancillary fees as potentially―excessive‖ (House Committee on Transportation and Infrastructure 2009). These comments<strong>in</strong>dicate one of <strong>the</strong> primary rationales beh<strong>in</strong>d government action: consumers are be<strong>in</strong>g unfairlycharged for products and services that are travel necessities, and such products should be<strong>in</strong>cluded with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> price of a ticket.97


Necessity is ultimately a term that does not apply to all customers for all relevant fees.Even <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> case of overhead b<strong>in</strong> fees, <strong>the</strong>re are still customers who pack sufficiently few itemssuch that <strong>the</strong>y can put <strong>the</strong>m under <strong>the</strong> front seat for no additional cost. In case of checkedbaggagefees only, <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>in</strong>terviewees <strong>in</strong>dicated that <strong>the</strong> amount of checked luggagedecl<strong>in</strong>ed after <strong>the</strong> fee was imposed <strong>in</strong>dicates that check<strong>in</strong>g a bag is not a necessity. Necessityimplies that consumers‘ demand is perfectly <strong>in</strong>elastic, mean<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>the</strong>y would pay any price fora service. This concept is more of an ideal <strong>in</strong> economic <strong>the</strong>ory than a reality.Even under <strong>the</strong> assumption that all ancillary services are <strong>in</strong>deed travel necessities, itshould be noted that government regulation does not force <strong>the</strong> bundl<strong>in</strong>g of certa<strong>in</strong> necessarycomponents with <strong>the</strong>ir partner goods <strong>in</strong> a number of o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>dustries. For example, a computerpr<strong>in</strong>ter is unable to pr<strong>in</strong>t pages without two components: paper and <strong>in</strong>k cartridges; <strong>the</strong>secomponents can roughly be categorized as necessities for us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> product. None<strong>the</strong>less,retailers sell a number of pr<strong>in</strong>ter models without <strong>the</strong>se two necessary <strong>in</strong>puts, and governmentaction does not compel firms to offer bundles of pr<strong>in</strong>ters, <strong>in</strong>k cartridges, and paper to consumers.It is also noteworthy that some retail pr<strong>in</strong>ters are sold with <strong>in</strong>k cartridges, just as someairl<strong>in</strong>es have held out from charg<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir consumers certa<strong>in</strong> fees. If such items were reallynecessities, <strong>the</strong>n one would expect a shift of all customers to those firms that offer bundledoptions, thus forc<strong>in</strong>g o<strong>the</strong>r firms to provide this more favorable arrangement. This analysis, ofcourse, only applies to a competitive market; <strong>in</strong> monopoly markets <strong>the</strong>re may be <strong>the</strong> potential forcustomers to receive <strong>the</strong>ir less-preferred arrangements. A dearth of <strong>in</strong>dustry profits would<strong>in</strong>dicate that pure monopoly or even high degrees of <strong>in</strong>dustry-wide market power is not a seriousproblem for <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>es.98


Thus <strong>the</strong> travel necessity argument is arbitrary, ignores market forces, and does notexpla<strong>in</strong> why government has allowed o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>dustries to unbundle <strong>the</strong>ir services. Unlike <strong>the</strong> caseof some o<strong>the</strong>r regulations requir<strong>in</strong>g bundl<strong>in</strong>g for safety or o<strong>the</strong>r reasons, such as requir<strong>in</strong>g thatauto manufacturers provide <strong>the</strong>ir cars with seat belts, <strong>the</strong>re has been no safety argument forrequir<strong>in</strong>g checked-bag fee restrictions. There have also been no serious arguments that some sortof collusion is driv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>se fee <strong>in</strong>creases.None<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong> clearest policy option to deal with such a scenario <strong>in</strong>volves forc<strong>in</strong>gairl<strong>in</strong>es to <strong>in</strong>clude certa<strong>in</strong> ancillary products and services with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> price of a ticket. This could<strong>in</strong>clude requir<strong>in</strong>g carriers to <strong>in</strong>clude a first- and second-bag option for free, along with a list ofservices and products that airl<strong>in</strong>es have not yet unbundled on a large scale (such as lavatory use,free carry-on luggage, etc.). Given <strong>the</strong> fact that this regulatory option would largely be driven byconsumer pressure to force airl<strong>in</strong>es to provide customers with a perceived ―free‖ service, it islikely to be based on popular expectations about what ought to be <strong>in</strong>cluded with an airplaneticket. It is unclear whe<strong>the</strong>r such a def<strong>in</strong>ition would <strong>in</strong>clude items such as meals on domesticflights, which were unbundled <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> early 2000s.An option requir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>clusion of various ancillary products/services would still giveairl<strong>in</strong>es control over base fares. Follow<strong>in</strong>g up on <strong>the</strong> earlier discussion, if <strong>the</strong>re is <strong>in</strong> fact anegative relationship between ancillary fees and base fares, forc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>clusion of fees <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> basefare would result <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> airfares for all consumers. As a result, <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry would bereturned to an orig<strong>in</strong>al condition with lower total welfare. As a corollary, <strong>the</strong> effective subsidythat existed, whereby certa<strong>in</strong> customers who didn‘t use ancillary services paid <strong>the</strong> same as thosewho did, would be restored. In a sense, such a government policy may actually harm some of <strong>the</strong>consumers that <strong>the</strong> government would aim to help: occasional leisure ticket travelers and those99


who do not check luggage would end up pay<strong>in</strong>g higher fares to accommodate those passengerswho fly more often and check <strong>the</strong>ir luggage.This particular regulatory structure thus has <strong>the</strong> effects outl<strong>in</strong>ed by Posner (1971): certa<strong>in</strong>customers are effectively taxed <strong>in</strong> order to provide o<strong>the</strong>r customers with a service that wouldo<strong>the</strong>rwise not be provided for free by <strong>the</strong> market. This explanation underscores <strong>the</strong> potentialpolicy importance of know<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> statistical connection between fees and fares; Posner evensuggests that government should conduct an analysis <strong>in</strong>ternal cross subsidies aris<strong>in</strong>g fromregulation for public record (47). Even without def<strong>in</strong>itive <strong>in</strong>formation, however, <strong>the</strong> fact that ana-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g model is prevail<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> absence of price regulation <strong>in</strong>dicates that thisarrangement may be efficient given market conditions.None<strong>the</strong>less, efficiency does not necessarily equate with consumers be<strong>in</strong>g better off; asdiscussed <strong>in</strong> chapter 4, airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangements are likely to <strong>in</strong>crease total welfare, butreduce consumer welfare by requir<strong>in</strong>g consumers who use ancillary services to pay for <strong>the</strong> onesthat <strong>the</strong>y value. Ultimately, this may be one of <strong>the</strong> fundamental drivers of legislative action.Consumers who previously utilized services such as free bag check and bulkhead seatassignment now are required to pay for <strong>the</strong>m, ra<strong>the</strong>r than hav<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir costs dispersed among allcustomers. It may ultimately be this group that is exert<strong>in</strong>g pressure on members of Congress torestrict bag fees. Though <strong>the</strong>re is no hard evidence to support this claim, some public choice<strong>the</strong>ory predicts that members of Congress will be responsive to <strong>the</strong> desires of <strong>the</strong> median voter <strong>in</strong>her district.Hav<strong>in</strong>g experienced <strong>the</strong> benefits of an ancillary revenue model, airl<strong>in</strong>es be<strong>in</strong>g forced toprovide a certa<strong>in</strong> set bundle of services may attempt to offer premium, upgraded versions of aproduct, <strong>in</strong> a similar manner to different cab<strong>in</strong> class offer<strong>in</strong>gs. Assum<strong>in</strong>g that government does100


not mandate some sort of quality standard, airl<strong>in</strong>es may be able to drive some ancillary revenuefrom those consumers wish<strong>in</strong>g to pay a premium for a higher-quality product. Of course, such anarrangement will be a second-best alternative because airl<strong>in</strong>es will still need to provide a freeservice to customers who do not value <strong>the</strong> service enough to pay market rates for it. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmorecerta<strong>in</strong> ancillary services, such as baggage check, may be unlikely to susta<strong>in</strong> a ―premium‖ option.As an option similar to enforc<strong>in</strong>g some sort of standard, government can also set a limiton <strong>the</strong> level of ancillary fees that an airl<strong>in</strong>e can charge. In many ways, a requirement sett<strong>in</strong>g amenu of products and services that must be provided with a ticket is a sort of special case thatlimits ancillary charges at zero. Work<strong>in</strong>g backwards from <strong>the</strong> analysis above, a limit may havesimilar, albeit less severe effects on total welfare. For example, fares of base tickets may rise,albeit less than would be <strong>the</strong> case if a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g were prohibited. Additionally, absentmarket failure, a fee limit would represent a sub-optimal pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangement, though closer toefficiency than a requirement that certa<strong>in</strong> products/services be <strong>in</strong>cluded as part of a ticket.Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong>re are difficulties associated with decid<strong>in</strong>g whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> optimal limit would beset, based on an evaluation of market forces and <strong>in</strong>flation, and such difficulties could place costson regulatory agencies.Tax Evasion RationaleAno<strong>the</strong>r explicit motivation for regulation <strong>in</strong>volves differences <strong>in</strong> taxation on <strong>the</strong> basefares and fees that an airl<strong>in</strong>e charges. In a September 2009 rul<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>the</strong> Internal Revenue Servicefound that aviation taxes do not apply to revenue from bag fees, along with revenue from mealsand certa<strong>in</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r ―non-transportation‖ services (Department of <strong>the</strong> Treasury 2009, 7). As airl<strong>in</strong>esbeg<strong>in</strong> to collect significant portions of <strong>the</strong>ir revenues from a-la-carte fees and ancillary services,101


<strong>the</strong>y are lower<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir effective tax rate by <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g revenues that cannot be subject to aviationtaxes and fees. This effective loss <strong>in</strong> tax revenues to <strong>the</strong> government has gotten explicit attentionfrom some lawmakers; as Representative Oberstar said, ―Maybe we have to teach [airl<strong>in</strong>es] alesson, and make <strong>the</strong>m pay <strong>the</strong>ir fair share‖ (Maynard 2009).From a <strong>the</strong>oretical perspective, a revenue-maximiz<strong>in</strong>g government faces <strong>the</strong> problem ofsett<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> tax structure so as to maximize returns from taxes; tax rates above or below anoptimal po<strong>in</strong>t will yield sub-optimal revenues. 15 While <strong>the</strong> effective tax rate on airfare <strong>in</strong>creasedsharply after September 11th, this rise has occurred concurrently to a drop <strong>in</strong> base fares. As aresult, <strong>the</strong> constant dollar value of total taxes and fees collected on <strong>the</strong> average ticket hasrema<strong>in</strong>ed steady near <strong>the</strong> $50 level s<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> early 1990s (Karlsson 2010, at 12). This stability<strong>in</strong>dicates that policy makers levy<strong>in</strong>g taxes may have found a tax structure that <strong>the</strong>y feel generatesan optimal amount of revenue. Of course, <strong>the</strong>re may be o<strong>the</strong>r factors, such as <strong>in</strong>terest grouppressure or some sort of regulatory <strong>in</strong>ertia, that are contribut<strong>in</strong>g to this stable level.Despite this stability, however, a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g, especially if fees put negative pressureon fares, allow airl<strong>in</strong>es to partially avoid <strong>the</strong> government‘s tax structure. With airl<strong>in</strong>es lower<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> effective tax rate through <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g use of fees, a revenue-maximiz<strong>in</strong>g government mayseek to use regulation or legislation to recoup additional revenue lost through different pric<strong>in</strong>gschemes. A New York Times article po<strong>in</strong>ted out <strong>the</strong> potential significant impact of <strong>the</strong>se taxes:from January through November 2009, extend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> 7.5 percent excise fare tax to fees wouldhave generated $225 million <strong>in</strong> additional tax revenue, provided that airl<strong>in</strong>es decided to collect<strong>the</strong> same amount of ancillary revenue with <strong>the</strong> taxes <strong>in</strong> place (Maynard 2009).15 This is <strong>the</strong> notion of <strong>the</strong> <strong>La</strong>ffer curve, credited to Arthur <strong>La</strong>ffer but pioneered by earlier economists such asKeynes. See <strong>La</strong>ffer 2004.102


If ancillary revenues did become taxed, however, it is unclear how much <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>eswould change <strong>the</strong>ir behavior <strong>in</strong> collect<strong>in</strong>g ancillary fees when it comes to <strong>the</strong> level of <strong>the</strong> feesbe<strong>in</strong>g charged and <strong>the</strong> number of fees. When it comes to <strong>the</strong> level of <strong>the</strong> fees, one must consider<strong>the</strong> relative elasticities of supply and demand for ancillary products. It should be noted thatvarious researchers have estimated a range of elasticities of demand for air travel based on stagelength, cab<strong>in</strong> class, and o<strong>the</strong>r factors (See Gillen, et al. 2008). These ranges of estimates may beuseful <strong>in</strong> extrapolat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> elasticity of demand for certa<strong>in</strong> ancillary services <strong>in</strong> future studies.A neoclassical economic analysis of taxes largely predicts that so long as consumerdemand is not perfectly elastic, some of an imposed tax will be passed along to consumers.Unfortunately, <strong>the</strong>re is no systematic measurement of <strong>the</strong> slope of consumers‘ demand curve forair travel‘s associated services. Given <strong>the</strong> fact, however, that <strong>the</strong> number of bags be<strong>in</strong>g checkedhas fallen s<strong>in</strong>ce checked bag fees were <strong>in</strong>troduced, it is reasonable to assume that demand is notperfectly elastic. Thus, if government extended taxes to ancillary fees, it is likely that some ofthose taxes would be passed on to consumers, as <strong>the</strong>y currently are <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> case of airl<strong>in</strong>e tickets.In deal<strong>in</strong>g with <strong>the</strong> tax effects on <strong>the</strong> number of products/services carry<strong>in</strong>g an ancillaryfee, one must look to whe<strong>the</strong>r a tax evasion strategy actually plays <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s decision. Ifairl<strong>in</strong>es are <strong>in</strong>deed us<strong>in</strong>g a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g as a tax evasion scheme, and for no o<strong>the</strong>r reason, <strong>the</strong>imposition of taxes would remove a sort of arbitrage opportunity and <strong>in</strong>centivize <strong>the</strong>m to returnto a bundl<strong>in</strong>g strategy. If, however, tax evasion does not play any role <strong>in</strong> a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>the</strong>n<strong>the</strong>y would keep <strong>the</strong>ir fees <strong>in</strong> place due to <strong>the</strong> added welfare ga<strong>in</strong>s and simply reap less revenuethan <strong>the</strong>y did under untaxed a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g. There is also a chance that <strong>the</strong> rationale for a-lacartepric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>cludes element of both tax evasion and economic efficiency; <strong>in</strong> this case, airl<strong>in</strong>eswould remove some of <strong>the</strong>ir ancillary fees, but not all of <strong>the</strong>m.103


Unsurpris<strong>in</strong>gly, no airl<strong>in</strong>es have claimed to use ancillary revenue to evade taxes. An<strong>in</strong>terviewee comment<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>the</strong> matter also said that avoid<strong>in</strong>g taxes was not a pr<strong>in</strong>cipal rationalefor a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g efforts: ―I don‘t th<strong>in</strong>k that when people started do<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>se th<strong>in</strong>gs that it hadreally occurred to us. Maybe some, but it was not a driver.‖ Despite this <strong>in</strong>terviewee‘s comment,air carriers aware of <strong>the</strong> tax structure would none<strong>the</strong>less face strong <strong>in</strong>centives to shift revenue tountaxed ancillary earn<strong>in</strong>g. As outl<strong>in</strong>ed by Maynard (2009), mentioned above, <strong>the</strong> revenue ga<strong>in</strong>sto an airl<strong>in</strong>e from not pay<strong>in</strong>g taxes may be significant. Because of <strong>the</strong> sensitive nature of thisquestion, fur<strong>the</strong>r research is needed to determ<strong>in</strong>e <strong>the</strong> true nature of airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ <strong>in</strong>tentions vis-à-vistax evasion.Ultimately, determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> merits and effects of a tax on ancillary fees depends oncurrently unobserved characteristics, such as elastiticties and <strong>the</strong> motivation for tax evasion.What can be said is that, under <strong>the</strong> current arrangement and ignor<strong>in</strong>g distribution effects,customers who utilize a-la-carte products and airl<strong>in</strong>es are better off than <strong>the</strong>y would be under asystem that taxes ancillary products. These consumers also bear less of <strong>the</strong> tax than <strong>the</strong>y wouldunder a bundled pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangement if <strong>the</strong>re is a negative fee-fare connection. Assum<strong>in</strong>g,however, that taxes on ancillary products are raised to <strong>the</strong> same level as taxes on <strong>the</strong> fare,consumers who use ancillary products actually bear additional tax burden than <strong>the</strong>y would <strong>in</strong> abundled arrangement. Assum<strong>in</strong>g a negative fee-fare connection and assum<strong>in</strong>g that airl<strong>in</strong>es passfee and fare taxes onto <strong>the</strong> consumers at <strong>the</strong> same rate, a customer utiliz<strong>in</strong>g an a-la-carte service<strong>in</strong> an unbundl<strong>in</strong>g scenario pays a higher portion of <strong>the</strong> tax than she did <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> bundled scenario:because she is pay<strong>in</strong>g a higher fare and fee than <strong>the</strong> previous bundled fare (which was subject toa cross subsidy), she thus pays a larger amount of taxes.104


Thus, government apply<strong>in</strong>g a tax to ancillary fees has <strong>the</strong> potential to <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>the</strong> costs ofa number of consumers who do not pay for ancillary services. While this is <strong>the</strong> case forconsumers, a tax rule is likely to be less burdensome than a ban on certa<strong>in</strong> ancillary fees becauseit cont<strong>in</strong>ues to allow airl<strong>in</strong>es to utilize a total welfare-enhanc<strong>in</strong>g strategy that is still, as discussedby this paper, more efficient than <strong>the</strong> bundled pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangement. The ma<strong>in</strong> difference is thatairl<strong>in</strong>es and customers will pay more taxes under this arrangement than <strong>the</strong>y would have had towithout a regulation.The merits of this approach are affected by one o<strong>the</strong>r factor: <strong>the</strong> extent to which <strong>the</strong>collected taxes are redistributed to airl<strong>in</strong>e customers <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> form of value-added goods or servicesthat would be unprovided or underprovided by firms. As discussed by a number of scholars and<strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong>siders, however, <strong>the</strong>re are <strong>in</strong>dications that airl<strong>in</strong>e customers‘ taxes are not currentlycommensurate with <strong>the</strong> level of services <strong>the</strong>y receive. Meade (2000) po<strong>in</strong>ts out that <strong>the</strong> ticket taxsystem does not accurately allocate costs based on a passenger‘s marg<strong>in</strong>al use of <strong>the</strong> airtransportation system, largely due to a lack of account<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>the</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>al costs imposed byaircraft of certa<strong>in</strong> size and <strong>in</strong>ability to assess o<strong>the</strong>r FAA costs (215). Meade br<strong>in</strong>gs up o<strong>the</strong>rdistortions that exist, such as <strong>the</strong> fact that different customers pay<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>the</strong> same seat facedifferent tax amounts (214). Button (2005) po<strong>in</strong>ts out a claim that was central to an aviationtaxation debate <strong>in</strong> 2006—general aviation, mostly utilized by high-<strong>in</strong>come travelers, extensivelyutilizes aviation <strong>in</strong>frastructure and creates congestion without pay<strong>in</strong>g a commensurate amountcompared to airl<strong>in</strong>es (19).Also, as discussed above, those utiliz<strong>in</strong>g a-la-carte products also end up pay<strong>in</strong>g an<strong>in</strong>creased share of <strong>the</strong> tax burden <strong>in</strong> an unbundled scenario (with taxes on fees) relative to abundled scenario. These customers are likely to receive <strong>the</strong> same level of tax-funded service <strong>in</strong>105


each scenario, mean<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>the</strong>y see less return for <strong>the</strong>ir taxes when a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g is <strong>in</strong> effect.Given <strong>the</strong>se <strong>in</strong>equities, <strong>the</strong>re is doubt as to whe<strong>the</strong>r consumers who are taxed on <strong>the</strong> fees <strong>the</strong>ypay would see a welfare <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> proportion to <strong>the</strong>ir tax contribution.<strong>La</strong>ck of Consumer Information RationaleA third common claim by a number of public figures is that airl<strong>in</strong>es are not provid<strong>in</strong>gsufficient <strong>in</strong>formation about fees to customers, who are be<strong>in</strong>g duped <strong>in</strong>to choos<strong>in</strong>g airl<strong>in</strong>es ormak<strong>in</strong>g decisions that <strong>the</strong>y o<strong>the</strong>rwise would not have chosen under perfect <strong>in</strong>formation.Comments by DOT Secretary <strong>La</strong>Hood <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> aforementioned <strong>in</strong>terview seem to support thisrationale for regulation: ―This idea of try<strong>in</strong>g to deceive people with some little amount of pr<strong>in</strong>tthat nobody can read, or somewhere tucked away, I don‘t agree with that‖ (Elliott 2010).As discussed <strong>in</strong> chapter 4, however, customers do not seem to be express<strong>in</strong>g asubstantially higher level of compla<strong>in</strong>ts that may be associated with some sort of deception. In<strong>the</strong> end, perhaps consumers simply become upset when <strong>the</strong>y arrive at <strong>the</strong> airport and are facedwith pay<strong>in</strong>g an additional fee before board<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> aircraft. While customers would face feesearlier (and perhaps be more aware to <strong>the</strong>m) if <strong>the</strong>y were charged dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> book<strong>in</strong>g process,do<strong>in</strong>g so is often unfeasible because customers may not know about travel details, such as howmuch luggage <strong>the</strong>y plan to pack, until closer to <strong>the</strong> trip date. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, as mentioned <strong>in</strong>chapter 2, pric<strong>in</strong>g at <strong>the</strong> time of travel is a price differentiation method used to attract customers‘potential higher will<strong>in</strong>gness to pay while travell<strong>in</strong>g.Despite <strong>the</strong> fact that customers do not pay fees until <strong>the</strong>y are close to <strong>the</strong> trip date,<strong>in</strong>terview data, as well as actual experience with airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ websites, <strong>in</strong>dicate that <strong>in</strong>formation maybe adequately provided to consumers. A number of <strong>in</strong>terviewees emphasized that provid<strong>in</strong>g106


consumers with <strong>in</strong>formation about fees and charges was an important aspect of <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘sservice brand. As one <strong>in</strong>terviewee said, ―We try to make it so that when an offer is presented to<strong>the</strong> customer <strong>the</strong>y clearly understand <strong>the</strong> benefits and <strong>the</strong>y have a clear way to say ‗yes‘ or ‗no.‘‖O<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>terviewees po<strong>in</strong>ted out that given Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ aggressive market<strong>in</strong>g about o<strong>the</strong>rair carriers‘ bag fees and a-la-carte charges, consumers have been largely primed to expect a-lacartepric<strong>in</strong>g.Additionally, dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> book<strong>in</strong>g process on a number of airl<strong>in</strong>e websites, consumers are<strong>in</strong>formed that additional fees may apply; <strong>the</strong>se are usually associated by l<strong>in</strong>ks to a description ofadditional prices for ancillary products and services. Figure 5.1 below shows <strong>the</strong> author‘s ownrat<strong>in</strong>gs of ―poor,‖ ―fair,‖ and ―good‖ for how several airl<strong>in</strong>es disclose ancillary fee <strong>in</strong>formationon <strong>the</strong>ir websites, for whe<strong>the</strong>r baggage fee <strong>in</strong>formation is disclosed dur<strong>in</strong>g book<strong>in</strong>g, and whe<strong>the</strong>rfood-for-purchase fees (if applicable) are clearly disclosed dur<strong>in</strong>g book<strong>in</strong>g (criteria for rat<strong>in</strong>gsdescribed <strong>in</strong> footnote).107


Figure 5.1: Ancillary Fee Disclosure on Airl<strong>in</strong>e Websites 16Comprehensivefee <strong>in</strong>formationavailable fromhome page?Baggage fee<strong>in</strong>formationprovideddur<strong>in</strong>gbook<strong>in</strong>g?Food purchase<strong>in</strong>formationprovideddur<strong>in</strong>gbook<strong>in</strong>g?AmericanAirl<strong>in</strong>esCont<strong>in</strong>entalAirl<strong>in</strong>esDeltaAirl<strong>in</strong>esUnitedAirl<strong>in</strong>esUSAirwaysAirTranAirwaysJetBlueAirwaysSpiritAirl<strong>in</strong>esFair Fair Fair Fair Fair Fair Fair FairFair Fair Good Good Fair Fair Good PoorGood N/A Fair Fair Fair Poor N/A PoorAs seen <strong>in</strong> figure 5.1, all airl<strong>in</strong>es provide ei<strong>the</strong>r fair or good disclosure of baggage feesdur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> book<strong>in</strong>g process except Spirit Airl<strong>in</strong>es, which none<strong>the</strong>less offers <strong>in</strong>formation buried <strong>in</strong>a long paragraph of text dur<strong>in</strong>g book<strong>in</strong>g. All airl<strong>in</strong>es also provide <strong>in</strong>formation on o<strong>the</strong>r ancillaryproduct fees, though customers must visit a number of different pages on <strong>the</strong> site to obta<strong>in</strong> all<strong>in</strong>formation. For <strong>the</strong> most part, airl<strong>in</strong>es provid<strong>in</strong>g food-for-purchase provide some level ofdisclosure to customers that fees will apply once onboard; AirTran Airways and Spirit Airl<strong>in</strong>eswere <strong>the</strong> only ones to poorly disclose such <strong>in</strong>formation.This survey of airl<strong>in</strong>e websites shows that <strong>the</strong> carriers are provid<strong>in</strong>g with <strong>in</strong>formationabout bag fees (arguably <strong>the</strong> one that most affects consumers) dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> book<strong>in</strong>g process, aswell as provid<strong>in</strong>g consumers with o<strong>the</strong>r fee <strong>in</strong>formation. Far from be<strong>in</strong>g relegated to f<strong>in</strong>e pr<strong>in</strong>t,this <strong>in</strong>formation often appears as a highlighted l<strong>in</strong>k appear<strong>in</strong>g when <strong>the</strong> passenger selects <strong>the</strong>16 Source: airl<strong>in</strong>es’ websites, accessed April 29, 2010. For <strong>the</strong> first category, poor <strong>in</strong>dicates no ability to f<strong>in</strong>d fee<strong>in</strong>formation from <strong>the</strong> website, fair <strong>in</strong>dicates <strong>in</strong>formation is available, but requires visit<strong>in</strong>g multiple pages, good<strong>in</strong>dicates existence of a s<strong>in</strong>gle page with comprehensive fee <strong>in</strong>formation. For <strong>the</strong> second category, poor <strong>in</strong>dicatesno <strong>in</strong>formation disclosed or <strong>in</strong>formation buried <strong>in</strong> long paragraph of text, fair means disclosure text or l<strong>in</strong>k ishighlighted but f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g it requires search<strong>in</strong>g, good <strong>in</strong>dicates a l<strong>in</strong>k to bag fee <strong>in</strong>formation clearly visible tocustomers. For <strong>the</strong> third category, poor means no food-for-purchase <strong>in</strong>formation give, fair means <strong>the</strong> customer isnotified that food will be available for purchase but pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation must be found elsewhere, good meansnotification and food pric<strong>in</strong>g is clearly available.108


flight(s) she wishes to purchase. In addition, bag fees and charges have come under <strong>in</strong>creasedfocus <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> media, mak<strong>in</strong>g it unlikely that customers that regularly follow <strong>the</strong> news or use <strong>the</strong>Internet would be oblivious to potential fees and would not check with an airl<strong>in</strong>e about relevantcharges prior to book<strong>in</strong>g. While some first-time or <strong>in</strong>frequent airl<strong>in</strong>e customers may be taken bysurprise by fees, claims that <strong>the</strong>re is broad mis<strong>in</strong>formation seem largely unjustified.None<strong>the</strong>less, a potential government law or rule may require all airl<strong>in</strong>es to list allpotential consumer charges when customers book a ticket, and perhaps dur<strong>in</strong>g o<strong>the</strong>r times dur<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> travel process. A rule may also require airl<strong>in</strong>es to use some formatt<strong>in</strong>g standard to ensure thatthis <strong>in</strong>formation is readily visible to consumers. As discussed fur<strong>the</strong>r below, this sort ofrequirement would <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>the</strong> costs of <strong>the</strong> relevant regulatory agency <strong>in</strong> charge of determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gand enforc<strong>in</strong>g this requirement.In addition to be<strong>in</strong>g largely unnecessary, such a requirement may lead to questions about<strong>the</strong> desired level of <strong>in</strong>formation provided to consumers. For example, should an airl<strong>in</strong>e have todisclose <strong>the</strong> price of every s<strong>in</strong>gle food and beverage item available for purchase onboard, orwould it be sufficient to note that food and certa<strong>in</strong> beverages are only available for purchase?Arbitrary l<strong>in</strong>es of disclosure may ultimately lead to <strong>in</strong>equity between <strong>in</strong>formation requirementsfor airl<strong>in</strong>es and for o<strong>the</strong>r travel <strong>in</strong>dustries (for example, hotels and rental cars).None<strong>the</strong>less, from total welfare perspective, some sort of <strong>in</strong>formation requirement wouldbe <strong>the</strong> least <strong>in</strong>trusive regulatory option, with perhaps some ga<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> welfare if <strong>the</strong> costs of post<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation are low. Ceteris paribus, provid<strong>in</strong>g consumers with more <strong>in</strong>formation helps tofoster efficient decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g among market participants. While many travelers may befamiliar with <strong>the</strong> ancillary fee structure that many airl<strong>in</strong>es have adopted <strong>in</strong> recent years, <strong>the</strong>re isalways potential that some first-time flyers who have little access to media outlets will be109


unaware of certa<strong>in</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e pric<strong>in</strong>g policies. None<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong> fact that this group is likely to bevery small means <strong>the</strong>re are few benefits.Once aga<strong>in</strong>, so long as <strong>the</strong> costs are sufficiently low, <strong>in</strong>formation disclosure should notsignificantly add to an airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s costs. None<strong>the</strong>less, if requirements <strong>in</strong>volve mandatory disclosure<strong>in</strong> television advertisements, or o<strong>the</strong>r costly means of disclosure, <strong>the</strong> benefits to consumers mayoutweigh <strong>the</strong> onerous costs. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong>re may be difficulty deal<strong>in</strong>g with any requirementthat mandates disclosure by third-party travel providers, each of whom has <strong>in</strong>centives to provideits customers with a standardized menu of book<strong>in</strong>g fees. Additionally, if regulations requiredbook<strong>in</strong>g agents who communicate with customers via telephone to disclose fees, <strong>the</strong>y would<strong>in</strong>evitably end up spend<strong>in</strong>g additional time <strong>in</strong>form<strong>in</strong>g consumers, requir<strong>in</strong>g airl<strong>in</strong>es to pay extrato staff <strong>the</strong>se functions.In addition to impos<strong>in</strong>g menu costs on firms, disclosure requirements also impose costson government agencies to determ<strong>in</strong>e, monitor, and enforce <strong>the</strong> requirements. For example, <strong>the</strong>government currently requires that airl<strong>in</strong>es notify customers when <strong>the</strong>re is a change <strong>in</strong> aircrafttype or when a different airl<strong>in</strong>e is carry<strong>in</strong>g its passengers on a flight through a codeshar<strong>in</strong>gagreement. For <strong>the</strong>se requirements, <strong>the</strong> Department of Transportation is responsible foranalyz<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> costs and benefits of <strong>the</strong> program, which <strong>in</strong>volves department time and resourcesfor determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g program viability. Costs to government could potentially be exacerbated if aregulatory agency decides to monitor whe<strong>the</strong>r disclosure is proceed<strong>in</strong>g as required. Enforcementactions aga<strong>in</strong>st a carrier <strong>in</strong> violation also have <strong>the</strong> potential to channel time and resources toenforc<strong>in</strong>g a rule that has few consumer benefits. These and o<strong>the</strong>r government costs must beadded to <strong>the</strong> private burdens of an <strong>in</strong>formation disclosure requirement.110


While an <strong>in</strong>formation disclosure requirement may be beneficial for consumers andpromote a more efficient market, a revenue-maximiz<strong>in</strong>g government may be less concernedabout <strong>the</strong> state of consumer education than a decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> its own revenue or <strong>the</strong> demand of voters<strong>in</strong> a congressional member‘s home district. Overall, reduc<strong>in</strong>g consumers‘ <strong>in</strong>formation costs doesnot substantially affect <strong>the</strong> government‘s revenue position when it comes to foregone taxes fromancillary fees. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, constituents driv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir members of Congress to action are likelyto be more cognizant of issues related to a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g and more <strong>in</strong>cl<strong>in</strong>ed to check with anairl<strong>in</strong>e to see what fees <strong>the</strong>y will potentially face onboard. Any constituent pressure, <strong>the</strong>refore, isless likely to be aimed at improv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation and more likely aimed at remov<strong>in</strong>g changes thatsome passengers may see as excessive or unwarranted. Thus, overall, an <strong>in</strong>formation disclosurerequirement is not likely to rema<strong>in</strong> a stand-alone option for regulat<strong>in</strong>g baggage fees; if such a lawor regulation were enacted, it would likely be part of some broader <strong>in</strong>itiative <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g some of<strong>the</strong> options listed above.What Should Be Done?In addition to <strong>the</strong> options above, government has <strong>the</strong> option to not regulate airl<strong>in</strong>escollect<strong>in</strong>g ancillary revenues beyond current requirements and to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry status quo.This would keep airl<strong>in</strong>es free to determ<strong>in</strong>e <strong>the</strong>ir own pric<strong>in</strong>g schemes and let market forces<strong>in</strong>fluence how consumers are <strong>in</strong>formed by airl<strong>in</strong>es about such fees and charges. While this wouldcerta<strong>in</strong>ly be <strong>the</strong> easiest option for <strong>the</strong> government to implement, s<strong>in</strong>ce it does not require anyaction, it is none<strong>the</strong>less <strong>the</strong> least likely to be politically feasible due to <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centives fac<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>government, as discussed above.111


One important consideration <strong>in</strong>volves preserv<strong>in</strong>g freedom for companies <strong>in</strong> a competitivemarket to decide appropriate pric<strong>in</strong>g that will maximize revenue, based on consumer demand andcompetition from o<strong>the</strong>r firms. The federal government has made it clear that airl<strong>in</strong>es provide avital service to <strong>the</strong> country, as evidenced by a $15 billion airl<strong>in</strong>e bailout authorized by Congressfollow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> September 11th attacks (Bailey 2002, 18). Despite its apparent desire for a robustsystem that provides access to many parts of <strong>the</strong> country at reasonable prices, <strong>the</strong> federalgovernment levies relatively high taxes (relative to o<strong>the</strong>r products and services <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> economy)of nearly 16 percent of <strong>the</strong> ticket price (MIT Ticket Tax Project 2010). Airl<strong>in</strong>e profit marg<strong>in</strong>shave been historically slim s<strong>in</strong>ce deregulation, with fierce competition <strong>in</strong> a number of markets.If anyth<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>the</strong> growth of a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g has allowed airl<strong>in</strong>es to garner additionalrevenues <strong>in</strong> an attempt to improve profitability dur<strong>in</strong>g adverse economic conditions.Interventions beyond some sort of <strong>in</strong>formation requirement have <strong>the</strong> potential to fur<strong>the</strong>r harmrevenues and make it more difficult for airl<strong>in</strong>es to cultivate a robust nationwide air transportationnetwork. So long as <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>ory outl<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> this paper is correct and a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g represents awelfare ga<strong>in</strong> for <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry, government <strong>in</strong>tervention could be stifle economic efficiencyand fur<strong>the</strong>r handicap <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ ability to rema<strong>in</strong> commercially viable.Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, while consumer welfare may have decl<strong>in</strong>ed from ancillary revenue<strong>in</strong>itiatives, this decl<strong>in</strong>e is associated with a more equitable pric<strong>in</strong>g policy, whereby customerswho value a service must pay to use it and those who do not value it are not forced <strong>in</strong>tosubsidiz<strong>in</strong>g it for <strong>the</strong> rest of <strong>the</strong>ir customers. Given that Southwest Airl<strong>in</strong>es does not charge firstor second checked bag fees and airl<strong>in</strong>es have vary<strong>in</strong>g fee structures, <strong>the</strong> average customer is, on<strong>the</strong> marg<strong>in</strong>, clearly will<strong>in</strong>g to accept such a pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangement. If not, she would take her112


us<strong>in</strong>ess to a no-fee carrier, provid<strong>in</strong>g o<strong>the</strong>r airl<strong>in</strong>es with an <strong>in</strong>centive to re-bundle <strong>the</strong>se serviceswith <strong>the</strong> price of <strong>the</strong> ticket.Additionally, o<strong>the</strong>r travel-related <strong>in</strong>dustries that exhibit similar types of pric<strong>in</strong>garrangements are able to exist free from government regulation about what ought to be <strong>in</strong>cluded<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> product def<strong>in</strong>ition. Even <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> case that government allows airl<strong>in</strong>es to cont<strong>in</strong>ue tounbundle ancillary products and services but imposes additional taxes on <strong>the</strong>m, <strong>the</strong>re is no clearevidence that such an arrangement would make for more equitable shar<strong>in</strong>g of tax burdens by airtravelers. Before government decides to impose additional taxes, it should fix <strong>the</strong> aforementioned<strong>in</strong>equities <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> system and provide some show<strong>in</strong>g that taxes will be used to fund welfareenhanc<strong>in</strong>gservices that would not o<strong>the</strong>rwise be provided by <strong>the</strong> private sector.Viewed from this perspective, <strong>the</strong> government‘s ideal action should be as little<strong>in</strong>tervention <strong>in</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g realm as possible. While an <strong>in</strong>formation requirement is<strong>the</strong> least burdensome option, even this alternative may not be necessary given widespread mediaattention to fares and fees and current consumer <strong>in</strong>formation policies and may even be welfarereduc<strong>in</strong>g on net. None<strong>the</strong>less, it is evident that additional taxes on ancillary fees and limits on<strong>the</strong>se fees have <strong>the</strong> potential to disrupt a pric<strong>in</strong>g arrangement that market participants havedeemed acceptable. Absent some show<strong>in</strong>g that airl<strong>in</strong>es have used market power or collusion toachieve <strong>the</strong>se policies, restrictive regulations would only hurt <strong>in</strong>dustry revenues and manyconsumers worse off by lead<strong>in</strong>g to higher fares, less choice, and lower product quality.113


Chapter 5 ReferencesArrow, Kenneth J. 1969. ―The Organization of Economic Activity: Issues Pert<strong>in</strong>ent to <strong>the</strong> Choiceof Market Versus Non-Market Allocations.‖ In R.H Haveman and J. Margolis (eds)Public Expenditure and Policy Analysis. Chicago: Markham, available athttp://www.econ.ucsb.edu/~tedb/Courses/UCSBpf/read<strong>in</strong>gs/ArrowNonMktActivity1969.pdf.Bailey, Elizabeth E. 2002. ―Aviation Policy: Past and Present.‖ Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Economic Journal.Vol.69, No. 1, pp. 12-20.Button, Kenneth J. 2005. ―The Taxation of Air Transportation.‖ George Mason UniversitySchool of Public Policy: Center for Transportation Policy, Operations, and Logistics.April 2005, available at http://www.gmupolicy.net/transport2003/airl<strong>in</strong>etaxation.pdf.CNN Wire Staff. 2010. ―Schumer: Several Airl<strong>in</strong>es Vow Not to Charge for Carry-On Bags.‖CNN.com. April 19, available athttp://www.cnn.com/2010/TRAVEL/04/18/carry.on.fees/<strong>in</strong>dex.html.Department of <strong>the</strong> Treasury. 2009. Internal Revenue Service, Letter Rul<strong>in</strong>g No. 201002004.September 28, available at http://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-wd/1002004.pdf.Elliott, Christopher, 2010, ―<strong>La</strong>Hood on Spirit‘s Carry-On Baggage Fees: ‗We‘re Gonna Hold <strong>the</strong>Airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s Feet to <strong>the</strong> Fire on This.‘‖ Elliott.org, April 8, available athttp://www.elliott.org/blog/lahood-on-spirits-carry-on-baggage-fees-were-gonna-hold<strong>the</strong>-airl<strong>in</strong>es-feet-to-<strong>the</strong>-fire-on-this/?utm_source=feedburner&utm_medium=feed&utm_campaign=Feed:+elliottorg+%28Elliott%29.114


Gillen, David W., Morrison, William G., & Stewart, Christopher. 2008. ―Air Travel DemandElasticities: Concepts, Issues and Measurement – F<strong>in</strong>al Report.‖ Department of F<strong>in</strong>anceCanada. available at http://www.f<strong>in</strong>.gc.ca/consultresp/Airtravel/airtravStdy_-eng.asp.Hefl<strong>in</strong>, Jay. 2010. ―Schumer Intros Bill Bann<strong>in</strong>g Airl<strong>in</strong>e Carry-On Fee.‖ The Hill onl<strong>in</strong>e. April14, available at http://<strong>the</strong>hill.com/blogs/on-<strong>the</strong>-money/domestic-taxes/92205-schumer<strong>in</strong>tros-bill-bann<strong>in</strong>g-airl<strong>in</strong>e-carry-on-fee.House Committee on Transportation and Infrastructure. 2009. Letter from James L. Oberstar andJerry F. Costello to Gene Dodaro. August 6, available athttp://transportation.house.gov/Media/file/press/GAO_Airl<strong>in</strong>e_Fees_Study_request081109.pdf.Karlsson, Joakim. 2010. ―Trends <strong>in</strong> Aviation Taxes and Fees.‖ Transportation Research Board of<strong>the</strong> National Academies, Ma<strong>in</strong>l<strong>in</strong>e and Regional Airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>Industry</strong> Status Update. January11, available at http://faculty.dwc.edu/karlsson/KarlssonTRB2010.pdf.<strong>La</strong>ffer, Arthur B. 2004. ―The <strong>La</strong>ffer Curve: Past, Present, and Future.‖ The Heritage FoundationBackgrounder. No. 1765. June 1, available at http://www.gateshome.com/files/<strong>La</strong>ffer%20Curve%20-%20Past%20Presetn%20and%20Future.pdf.Maynard, Michel<strong>in</strong>e. 2009. ―Worried About Los<strong>in</strong>g Tax Revenue, Congress to InvestigateAirl<strong>in</strong>es‘ Fees.‖ The New York Times Onl<strong>in</strong>e, November 13, available athttp://www.nytimes.com/2009/11/14/ bus<strong>in</strong>ess/14fees.html.Meade. Carolyn P. 2000. ―Aviation Taxes: Can We Leave FAA Fund<strong>in</strong>g on Auto-Pilot?‖Virg<strong>in</strong>ia Tax Review. Vol. 20, pp. 191-228.MIT Ticket Tax Project website. 2010. accessed April 29, 2010. available at http://web.mit.edu/TicketTax/.115


Niskanen, William A. 1968. ―The Peculiar Economics of Bureaucracy.‖ The American EconomicReview. Vol. 58, No. 2, pp. 293-305.Posner, Richard A. 1971. ―Taxation by Regulation.‖The Bell Journal of Economics andManagement Science. Vol. 2, No. 1 (1971), pp. 22-50.Stigler, George J. 1971. ―The Theory of Economic Regulation.‖ The Bell Journal of Economicsand Management Science. Vol. 2, No. 1, pp. 3-21.We<strong>in</strong>gast, Barry R. & Moran, Mark J. 1983. ―Bureaucratic Discretion or Congressional Control?Regulatory Policymak<strong>in</strong>g by <strong>the</strong> Federal Trade Commission.‖ The Journal of PoliticalEconomy. Vol. 91, No. 5, pp. 765-800.116


ConclusionsThis paper has analyzed various aspects of airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ efforts to unbundle parts of <strong>the</strong>irproduct as well as <strong>in</strong>troduce new a-la-carte products. In addition to discuss<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> drivers andeconomic <strong>the</strong>ory beh<strong>in</strong>d this trend, <strong>the</strong> paper has analyzed some of <strong>the</strong> primary effects of a-lacartepric<strong>in</strong>g on airl<strong>in</strong>es and customers. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>the</strong> paper has analyzed several policyalternatives that government may be consider<strong>in</strong>g, as policy makers contemplate regulat<strong>in</strong>g a-lacartefees <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry.The unique onboard amenities that air travelers receive have a long history, go<strong>in</strong>g back to<strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry‘s period of regulation. Many of <strong>the</strong>se services rema<strong>in</strong>ed, as air carriers beganto develop <strong>the</strong> next generations of <strong>the</strong>ir bus<strong>in</strong>ess models based on revenue managementtechniques, improved network plann<strong>in</strong>g, and advanced forecast<strong>in</strong>g methods. It was not untilrevenue pressure <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> 2000s, exacerbated by an excess capacity problem, forced airl<strong>in</strong>es to f<strong>in</strong>dnew sources of revenue. While entrepreneurs <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry had been <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>irawareness of <strong>the</strong> potential ga<strong>in</strong>s from a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g models, it was <strong>the</strong> shocks of <strong>the</strong> 2000sthat f<strong>in</strong>ally encouraged <strong>the</strong>m to make <strong>the</strong> shift.From an economic perspective, airl<strong>in</strong>es‘ adoption of a two-part pric<strong>in</strong>g strategy allows<strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e to better differentiate among its heterogeneous customer base. Ultimately, airl<strong>in</strong>es areable to extract additional consumer surplus from passengers who value ancillary services enoughto pay for <strong>the</strong>m. In do<strong>in</strong>g so, however, <strong>the</strong>y have potentially ended a subsidy that o<strong>the</strong>rconsumers who did not use such ancillary products and services paid to <strong>the</strong>ir fellow consumers.With <strong>in</strong>dications that fees put downward pressure on base fares, customers may now have accessto lower base fares, should <strong>the</strong>y decide to pack light, carry <strong>the</strong>ir bags <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> cab<strong>in</strong>, and eat <strong>the</strong>irmeals at home.117


Far from be<strong>in</strong>g a mechanical solution to an economic optimization problem, however,airl<strong>in</strong>es are constantly explor<strong>in</strong>g and evaluat<strong>in</strong>g when to <strong>in</strong>troduce new a-la-carte products. Suchdecisions are highly cont<strong>in</strong>gent upon <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e‘s choice of where to position its brand, andwhe<strong>the</strong>r it can deliver new products to <strong>the</strong> consumer. This process may generate dynamicbenefits for consumers <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> forms of improved product quality and potential changes to <strong>the</strong>airl<strong>in</strong>e bus<strong>in</strong>ess model. As airl<strong>in</strong>es develop <strong>the</strong> a-la-carte model fur<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong>re is a chance thatairl<strong>in</strong>es may end up emulat<strong>in</strong>g a cruise ship or cas<strong>in</strong>o that lures last-m<strong>in</strong>ute customers <strong>in</strong> wi<strong>the</strong>xtremely low prices only to recoup ancillary revenues from <strong>the</strong>m. This model would be goodfor consumers by giv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m additional options for low base fare travel.Given <strong>the</strong> fact that airl<strong>in</strong>es have been able to capture many consumers‘ welfare and thatancillary revenues are largely untaxed, it unsurpris<strong>in</strong>g that politicians and policy makers havetargeted a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry as ripe for regulation. None<strong>the</strong>less, most ofWash<strong>in</strong>gton‘s options for regulat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>es would likely dim<strong>in</strong>ish total welfare <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e<strong>in</strong>dustry and only handicap a new source of revenue that has helped airl<strong>in</strong>es overcome adverseeconomic conditions and an excess capacity problem. Regardless of <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>tents of government,most policies are likely to do more harm than good.This paper is an <strong>in</strong>itial economic treatment of airl<strong>in</strong>e ancillary revenues, and this subjectis ripe for future research. In particular, new work <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> area ought to target <strong>the</strong> specific role thatuncerta<strong>in</strong>ty and a potential empty core problem had <strong>in</strong> determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> tim<strong>in</strong>g of <strong>the</strong> ancillaryrevenue movement. Additionally, econometric studies ought to explore whe<strong>the</strong>r a-la-cartepric<strong>in</strong>g has, ceteris paribus, raised airl<strong>in</strong>e revenues and whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>troduction of fees has astatistically significant negative correlation with base fares. Analysis of <strong>the</strong>se issues wouldprovide some real-world evidence to <strong>the</strong> questions deal<strong>in</strong>g with producer and consumer welfare,118


as well as elucidate additional nuance beh<strong>in</strong>d <strong>the</strong> potential effects of lawmak<strong>in</strong>g or rulemak<strong>in</strong>gaimed at ancillary revenues.The realm of a-la-carte pric<strong>in</strong>g is ultimately a dynamic process driven by humanentrepreneurs who are constantly be<strong>in</strong>g made aware of new pric<strong>in</strong>g and revenue opportunities.Perhaps <strong>the</strong> most <strong>in</strong>trigu<strong>in</strong>g aspect of ancillary revenues <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry deals with <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>novations that have yet to be seen. Indeed, new <strong>in</strong>novations <strong>in</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e product offer<strong>in</strong>gs have<strong>the</strong> potentially to fur<strong>the</strong>r change <strong>the</strong> airl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry, and will provide numerous opportunities forfuture research.Perhaps what makes <strong>the</strong> issue so ripe for study is this fact that <strong>the</strong> ancillary revenuemovement represents a major change for such a vibrant and important <strong>in</strong>dustry. One <strong>in</strong>tervieweeput <strong>the</strong> issue <strong>in</strong> perspective best: ―Part of it too is that we actually want to change <strong>the</strong> model. Thisairl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>dustry is fundamentally broken. I th<strong>in</strong>k we pay higher taxes than any o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>in</strong>dustry,<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g tobacco and alcohol, and that essentially you need to start gett<strong>in</strong>g to a place where noteveryth<strong>in</strong>g is tied to <strong>the</strong> base fare and that customers aren‘t subsidiz<strong>in</strong>g each o<strong>the</strong>r for servicesthat <strong>the</strong>y don‘t value.‖ With airl<strong>in</strong>es hav<strong>in</strong>g taken one more step to ―fix‖ <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry, it will be<strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g to see what new changes and developments are on <strong>the</strong> horizon.119

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!