11.07.2015 Views

the role of property rights in natural resource management, good ...

the role of property rights in natural resource management, good ...

the role of property rights in natural resource management, good ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

CONTENTSACRONYMS AND ABBREVIATIONS .................................................. iiSUMMARY................................................................................................ iii1.0 INTRODUCTION.............................................................................. 12.0 THE MANY TYPES OF PROPERTY RIGHTS TO NATURALRESOURCES....................................................................................... 32.1 BASIC PROPERTY RIGHTS CONCEPTS ............................................................ 32.1.1 The Rights Bundle............................................................................. 32.1.2 Property Rights Regimes................................................................. 52.2 TENURE SECURITY AND ENFORCEMENT OF PROPERTY RIGHTS.................. 82.3 OTHER IMPORTANT ASPECTS OF PROPERTY RIGHTS REGIMES ANDNATURAL RESOURCES...................................................................................102.3.1 Property Rights Systems Are Dynamic......................................102.3.2 Property Rights to Land Versus Natural Resources...............122.4 DISCUSSIONS AND TRENDS FROM THE LITERATURE ................133.0 PROPERTY RIGHTS IN ACTION................................................. 163.1 PROPERTY RIGHTS TO LAND AND NATURAL RESOURCES: KEYOBSERVATIONS ..............................................................................................163.2 FIVE KEY CHALLENGES TO A RIGHTS-BASED APPROACH FOR BETTERNATURAL RESOURCE MANAGEMENT ..........................................................183.2.1 Manag<strong>in</strong>g and Channel<strong>in</strong>g Chang<strong>in</strong>g Market Incentives ..........183.2.2 Harmoniz<strong>in</strong>g with Government Policies—Focus onDevolution/Decentralization........................................................213.2.3 Build<strong>in</strong>g on Customary Property Rights Regimes....................223.2.4 Balanc<strong>in</strong>g Equity and Efficiency.....................................................253.2.5 Enforcement <strong>of</strong> Property Rights <strong>in</strong> a Chang<strong>in</strong>g World...........274.0 GENERAL PRINCIPLES.................................................................. 31REFERENCES.......................................................................................... 35ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR i


ACRONYMS AND ABBREVIATIONS CBNRMENRMAFAOHIV/AIDSLTPRNGONRMNTFPUSAIDCommunity-Based Natural Resource ManagementExpanded Natural Resources Management ActivityFood and Agriculture Organization (United Nations)Human Immunodeficiency Virus/Acquired Immune Deficiency SyndromeLand Tenure and Property RightsNongovernmental OrganizationNatural Resource ManagementNon-Timber Forest ProductUnited States Agency for International Developmentii ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR


SUMMARY Property <strong>rights</strong> and <strong>the</strong> <strong>role</strong> <strong>the</strong>y play <strong>in</strong> susta<strong>in</strong>able <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> <strong>management</strong>, <strong>good</strong> governance andempowerment <strong>of</strong> poor communities is ga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g significant attention <strong>in</strong> development and environmentalprogramm<strong>in</strong>g. Literature and practical experience are <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly draw<strong>in</strong>g attention to <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> as animportant consideration <strong>in</strong> rural empowerment and susta<strong>in</strong>able <strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s.Moreover, development agencies are <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly recogniz<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> as a critical factor determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>ghow land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s are used and managed, and how benefits from <strong>the</strong>se <strong>resource</strong>s are distributed.The purpose <strong>of</strong> this paper is to provide an overview <strong>of</strong> critical <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> concepts for non-<strong>property</strong><strong>rights</strong> specialists <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> design and implementation <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> programs. This paper has foursections. Section 1 def<strong>in</strong>es <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> context <strong>of</strong> land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s. It illustrates whypractitioners should consider <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> when pursu<strong>in</strong>g susta<strong>in</strong>able <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> <strong>management</strong>, <strong>good</strong>governance, and socioeconomic empowerment objectives. Section 2 is an overview <strong>of</strong> critical concepts <strong>in</strong><strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>, specifically, <strong>the</strong> notion <strong>of</strong> “bundles <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong>”, <strong>the</strong> range <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regimes (e.g.,private, community, state), <strong>the</strong> nature <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> and factors critical for security <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong>. Section 2also provides an overview <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> k<strong>in</strong>ds <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> frequently encountered <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> non-Western context,as well as <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> reforms that many states and donors are currently implement<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>natural</strong><strong>resource</strong> and governance arena. Section 3 beg<strong>in</strong>s with a short series <strong>of</strong> key observations for <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>programmers about <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> reforms. It <strong>the</strong>n explores five important challenges to achiev<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> bestfit between <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems and environmental or development objectives, draw<strong>in</strong>g from a variety <strong>of</strong>land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> sectors and issues such as agriculture, fisheries, forest <strong>resource</strong> use and biodiversityconservation. Specific topics addressed comprise manag<strong>in</strong>g and channel<strong>in</strong>g chang<strong>in</strong>g market <strong>in</strong>centives;harmoniz<strong>in</strong>g with government policies, with a focus on decentralization and devolution; build<strong>in</strong>g oncustomary <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regimes; balanc<strong>in</strong>g equity and efficiency; and enforcement <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> <strong>in</strong> achang<strong>in</strong>g world. 1 Section 3 also analyzes specific policies, experiences and <strong>in</strong>terventions where consideration<strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> has, or could have, successfully <strong>in</strong>formed and streng<strong>the</strong>ned a <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> program.F<strong>in</strong>ally, Section 4 summarizes key pr<strong>in</strong>ciples <strong>in</strong> land and <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> reforms with implications for <strong>natural</strong><strong>resource</strong> <strong>management</strong>, governance and livelihood security <strong>in</strong> rural areas.1While this piece serves as an <strong>in</strong>troduction to <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> for <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> specialists, ARD’s Land Tenure and Property RightsFramework and associated tools may be used for guidance on operational <strong>in</strong>tegration <strong>of</strong> land and <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> issues <strong>in</strong>to broaderdevelopment, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>, programs (ARD, 2005). The LTPR Framework places land and <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> concerns with<strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> context <strong>of</strong> governance viewed broadly, economic growth, <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> <strong>management</strong>, and poverty reduction. The associatedmaterials <strong>in</strong>clude: an assessment tool for identify<strong>in</strong>g land and <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> issues <strong>in</strong> any given location, a survey <strong>of</strong> land and <strong>property</strong><strong>rights</strong> concerns <strong>in</strong> USAID presence countries, and an assessment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> severity <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> issues <strong>in</strong> each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se USAID presencecountries.ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR iii


1.0 INTRODUCTIONProperty <strong>rights</strong> or “tenure” refers to control over and access to <strong>resource</strong>s, that is, <strong>the</strong> way <strong>in</strong> which people(<strong>in</strong>dividually or collectively) hold <strong>rights</strong> and responsibilities to land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s upon it. Thus, <strong>the</strong>issue <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> raises fundamental questions <strong>of</strong> who claims <strong>rights</strong> to what <strong>resource</strong>s, who has accessto <strong>the</strong> land and associated <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, and who has <strong>the</strong> responsibility for manag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>se lands. Ofparticular <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>the</strong>n is how land and <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> create <strong>in</strong>centives or dis<strong>in</strong>centives for susta<strong>in</strong>able<strong>management</strong> and governance <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s such as agricultural lands, forest <strong>resource</strong>s, freshwater andcoastal <strong>resource</strong>s, wild species <strong>of</strong> plants or animals or watersheds. These fundamental <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>questions become even more critical where <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> markets are concerned, such as markets fortimber or non-timber forest products, wildlife, ecotourism, agricultural products, payment for environmentalservices and o<strong>the</strong>r revenue-generat<strong>in</strong>g activities.Control or access to land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s is important for susta<strong>in</strong>able <strong>management</strong>, <strong>good</strong> governanceand empowerment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rural poor for several reasons:1. Land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s are important assets for <strong>in</strong>dividuals and households <strong>in</strong> meet<strong>in</strong>g subsistenceneeds <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g food and shelter. To that end, access to land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s (renewable <strong>natural</strong><strong>resource</strong>s <strong>in</strong> particular) is critical for poverty alleviation and food security.2. Land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s provide important assets for <strong>in</strong>come generation for most rural households.Rural households may generate <strong>in</strong>come through production <strong>of</strong> cash crops, or from collection and sale <strong>of</strong>forest, mar<strong>in</strong>e or coastal <strong>resource</strong>s. Indeed, households with secure <strong>rights</strong> to land are typically better <strong>of</strong>fthan those with <strong>in</strong>secure, limited or no land <strong>rights</strong>(FAO, 2002a).3. Property <strong>rights</strong> are a critical tool for promot<strong>in</strong>g selfrelianceamong <strong>the</strong> poor. Specifically, improved accessto arable land can provide <strong>in</strong>centives for greater<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> time and labor toward enhanc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong><strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> base, lead<strong>in</strong>g to greater productivity <strong>of</strong>arable lands and hence greater food security at <strong>the</strong>household level. To that end, secure access to land and<strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s is essential for last<strong>in</strong>g solutions tosusta<strong>in</strong>able land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> use and<strong>management</strong>, as well as poverty alleviation.Box 1. Property Rights, Access andIncentives Regard<strong>in</strong>g NaturalResourcesProperty <strong>rights</strong>, and secure access to andcontrol over land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s cangenerate critical <strong>in</strong>centives for conservationand susta<strong>in</strong>able use, <strong>management</strong> andgovernance <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s. Insecure,unclear, limited or short-term <strong>property</strong><strong>rights</strong> can <strong>in</strong>hibit susta<strong>in</strong>able land and <strong>natural</strong><strong>resource</strong> <strong>management</strong> and discouragestakeholders from act<strong>in</strong>g as long-termstewards <strong>of</strong> land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s.4. Secure land and <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> are a critical element <strong>of</strong>a <strong>rights</strong>-based approach to developmentprogramm<strong>in</strong>g. 2 The <strong>rights</strong>-based approach serves to ensure that program designers proactively considerwomen, m<strong>in</strong>orities, <strong>in</strong>digenous and o<strong>the</strong>r marg<strong>in</strong>alized groups <strong>in</strong> development programs (FAO, 2002a).Underly<strong>in</strong>g each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se concerns is susta<strong>in</strong>ability <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong> base, which is <strong>of</strong>ten highly correlated to<strong>the</strong> level <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> security characteristic <strong>of</strong> key <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> users.2The <strong>rights</strong>-based approach to development places human <strong>rights</strong> at <strong>the</strong> center <strong>of</strong> development policy, and <strong>in</strong>cludes economic, social andcultural, as well as civil and political <strong>rights</strong> (Maxwell, 1999).ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 1


Secure <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> are an important element <strong>of</strong> rural empowerment. Where <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> are weak ornonexistent, rural populations may be displaced or customary access and control over <strong>resource</strong>s may bechallenged by outside <strong>in</strong>terest groups. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, secure <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> that are protected by law canempower rural communities, ensur<strong>in</strong>g participation <strong>in</strong> critical decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g processes related to <strong>the</strong><strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, and o<strong>the</strong>r social political processes.Given <strong>the</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> <strong>in</strong> provid<strong>in</strong>g critical <strong>in</strong>centive for susta<strong>in</strong>able <strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> landand <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, and potential for subsistence livelihoods and <strong>in</strong>come generation as well as ruralempowerment, <strong>the</strong> nature <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>, what constitutes <strong>the</strong>se <strong>rights</strong>, and what makes for secure <strong>rights</strong>needs to be clearly understood. Conversely, a better understand<strong>in</strong>g is needed <strong>of</strong> how <strong>in</strong>secure, unclear, limitedor short-term <strong>rights</strong> to land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s provide dis<strong>in</strong>centives for susta<strong>in</strong>able use and <strong>management</strong><strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s. Indeed, failure to take <strong>in</strong>to consideration land and <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> at <strong>the</strong> outset <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> programmay <strong>in</strong>advertently elim<strong>in</strong>ate <strong>in</strong>dividual or collective <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>, foster<strong>in</strong>g poverty, <strong>in</strong>equity, social<strong>in</strong>stability, or <strong>in</strong> some cases, conflict. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, failure to grasp <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centive structures <strong>in</strong>herent <strong>in</strong> landand <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> arrangements may lead to unsusta<strong>in</strong>able outcomes (FAO, 2002a).2 ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR


2.0 THE MANY TYPES OFPROPERTY RIGHTS TONATURAL RESOURCES:CONCEPTS, CHARACTERISTICSAND IMPLICATIONSControl over and access to land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s may be understood as an <strong>in</strong>dividual’s or group’s claimto a bundle <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong>. These <strong>rights</strong> typically <strong>in</strong>clude authority to use, manage, and transfer land and various<strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s on it. People’s <strong>rights</strong>, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>, weigh heavily <strong>in</strong> matters <strong>of</strong> fairness, equity,and justice, and can be understood and analyzed through a simple and long-stand<strong>in</strong>g model that portrays<strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> as bundles <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong>. 3 This concept <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> serves to keep <strong>the</strong> multi-dimensionality,social embeddedness and <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutional breadth and depth at <strong>the</strong> forefront <strong>of</strong> development andenvironmental plann<strong>in</strong>g. 42.1 BASIC PROPERTY RIGHTS CONCEPTS2.1.1 The Rights BundleA bundle <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong> comprises a set <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong> that may <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>the</strong> right to use a <strong>resource</strong>, <strong>the</strong> right to manage it,and <strong>the</strong> right to transfer (assign or reassign) <strong>management</strong> and use <strong>rights</strong>. 5 Also discussed below is <strong>the</strong> commonyet imprecise term, ownership. Each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se <strong>rights</strong> (summarized <strong>in</strong> Box 2) may be seen as a strand with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong><strong>rights</strong> bundle.3Henry Ma<strong>in</strong>e first conceptualized bundles <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong> <strong>in</strong> his classic book, Ancient Law, published <strong>in</strong> 1861.4Social embeddedness here refers to <strong>the</strong> social, economic and political relations, and associated <strong>in</strong>stitutions with<strong>in</strong> which land and <strong>property</strong><strong>rights</strong> are situated and are constituted. This can be illustrated with <strong>the</strong> follow<strong>in</strong>g observations. Property <strong>rights</strong> entail cultural and socialmean<strong>in</strong>g; for example, <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> system is a fundamental element uphold<strong>in</strong>g cultural identity <strong>in</strong> many customary societies. In <strong>the</strong>political realm, <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> and <strong>the</strong> ability to manipulate <strong>the</strong>m, confer power. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> are <strong>in</strong>timately related with <strong>the</strong>distribution <strong>of</strong> wealth, and thus provide powerful <strong>in</strong>centives for <strong>the</strong>ir protection. The expression <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> with<strong>in</strong> each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>sedoma<strong>in</strong>s has <strong>the</strong> potential ei<strong>the</strong>r to clarify or to stra<strong>in</strong> exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong> regimes and <strong>the</strong> larger socio-political doma<strong>in</strong>s <strong>of</strong> which <strong>the</strong>y forma fundamental part.5Our proposed categorization <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> to <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s is <strong>in</strong>spired by some exist<strong>in</strong>g models, such as that presented <strong>in</strong>Fortmann, Louise. (1988). The Tree Tenure Factor <strong>in</strong> Agr<strong>of</strong>orestry with Particular Reference to Africa, from Fortmann and Bruce, Whose Trees?Proprietary Dimensions <strong>of</strong> Forestry, p.17; and that presented <strong>in</strong> Ostrom (1999) pp. 339.ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 3


Use <strong>rights</strong>. The most observable types <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>are use <strong>rights</strong>, ei<strong>the</strong>r to non-consumptive use <strong>of</strong> a <strong>resource</strong>or withdrawal <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong> such as ga<strong>the</strong>r<strong>in</strong>g deadwood<strong>in</strong> a forest, graz<strong>in</strong>g livestock <strong>in</strong> a pasture, produc<strong>in</strong>g cropson agricultural lands, or fish<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a pond. Use <strong>rights</strong> are asvaried as are uses <strong>of</strong> a unit <strong>of</strong> land and <strong>the</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>sit conta<strong>in</strong>s. For example, use <strong>rights</strong> to a parcel <strong>of</strong> land may<strong>in</strong>clude <strong>the</strong> right to farm, to pasture, to plant trees, to cuttrees, to build a house, to establish a non-agriculturalenterprise, to exploit <strong>the</strong> land as a quarry, or anycomb<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> such <strong>rights</strong>. Use <strong>rights</strong> to trees may <strong>in</strong>clude Box 2. The Four Strands <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> “Rights Bundle” Various strands <strong>in</strong> a bundle <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong> related to a unit <strong>of</strong> land and associated <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s may <strong>in</strong>clude: • Right to use, • Right to manage, • Right to transfer (assign or reassign) use and <strong>management</strong> <strong>rights</strong>, and • Right to “own”. fruit or leaf ga<strong>the</strong>r<strong>in</strong>g, honey collection, removal <strong>of</strong> bark or branches, or removal <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> tree itself. Use <strong>rights</strong> to a body <strong>of</strong> water may <strong>in</strong>clude dr<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g, bath<strong>in</strong>g, wash<strong>in</strong>g clo<strong>the</strong>s, water<strong>in</strong>g livestock, fish<strong>in</strong>g or diversion for irrigation. Management <strong>rights</strong>. Management <strong>rights</strong> are an order higher than use <strong>rights</strong>, and are <strong>in</strong>termediate between use and full ownership (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g transfer) <strong>rights</strong>. Management <strong>rights</strong> consist <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> right to organize and assign use <strong>rights</strong>. The manager <strong>of</strong> a unit <strong>of</strong> land or a stock <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s typically has authority to makeland use and production decisions that have implications for <strong>the</strong> various use <strong>rights</strong> holders. Just as <strong>management</strong> <strong>rights</strong> can be dist<strong>in</strong>ct from use <strong>rights</strong>, <strong>management</strong> <strong>rights</strong> are also <strong>of</strong>ten dist<strong>in</strong>ct from transfer (or ownership) <strong>rights</strong>. For <strong>in</strong>stance, a wetland may be legally owned by <strong>the</strong> state, but <strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> wetland, that is, rules <strong>of</strong> when and where people can fish or how much fish can be withdrawn may be decided upon by a village council. Typically, <strong>in</strong> such cases, <strong>the</strong> village council will manage <strong>the</strong> wetland with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> overarch<strong>in</strong>g regulations imposed by <strong>the</strong> state—as for <strong>in</strong>stance, a state imposition <strong>of</strong> ban on fish<strong>in</strong>g dur<strong>in</strong>g specific times <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> year. In such cases, <strong>the</strong> village council does not hold <strong>the</strong> right to transfer <strong>the</strong> wetland (ownership or <strong>management</strong>) to ano<strong>the</strong>r entity. This authority will rest with <strong>the</strong> state. Transfer right. Transfer <strong>rights</strong> exist at a still higher order than use and <strong>management</strong> <strong>rights</strong>. Transfer <strong>rights</strong> refer to <strong>the</strong> authority to assign or reassign both <strong>management</strong> and use <strong>rights</strong>. A transfer <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong> may bedef<strong>in</strong>itive and absolute, that is, <strong>the</strong> transfer may <strong>in</strong>clude all <strong>rights</strong> <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> bundle. The ability to def<strong>in</strong>itively transfer <strong>the</strong> entire <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> bundle is a typical feature <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems predom<strong>in</strong>ant <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> West, and may be referred to as alienation right. However, a transfer <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> may also apply to someth<strong>in</strong>g less than <strong>the</strong> entire <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> bundle. For example, it is common <strong>in</strong> non-Western societies for a family or a community to transfer <strong>management</strong> and use <strong>rights</strong> attached to a specific parcel to a new arrival. The transferred <strong>rights</strong> <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>the</strong> right to exclude all o<strong>the</strong>rs, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g community members, from certa<strong>in</strong> uses <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> transferred parcel such as crop cultivation. Rights granted to <strong>the</strong> new arrival are <strong>of</strong>ten quite secure, and may even be considered permanent. But <strong>the</strong> right to transfer <strong>the</strong> use and <strong>management</strong> <strong>rights</strong> is typically withheld from a new arrival with<strong>in</strong> a given community. Ownership. In contrast to <strong>the</strong> <strong>rights</strong> categories presented above, def<strong>in</strong>ition <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> term ownership, as applied to land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, is nei<strong>the</strong>r precise nor rigorous. It is a useful term, and unavoidable with<strong>in</strong> a discussion <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>. The term is used here simply to <strong>in</strong>dicate priority claims to <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> bundle made on <strong>the</strong> part <strong>of</strong> an <strong>in</strong>dividual, a private entity or a state. Priority <strong>rights</strong> can be thought <strong>of</strong> as a claim <strong>of</strong> authority to manage and adm<strong>in</strong>ister <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> bundle. The concept <strong>of</strong> ownership may vary depend<strong>in</strong>g upon <strong>the</strong> socio-political context. For example, alienation <strong>rights</strong>, taken for granted <strong>in</strong> Western <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems, may be entirely absent from <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> bundle claimed by <strong>the</strong> customary owners <strong>of</strong> land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s. 6 A Westerner tends to th<strong>in</strong>k <strong>of</strong> ownership as a <strong>rights</strong> bundle that 6For example, <strong>in</strong> some rural areas <strong>of</strong> Gu<strong>in</strong>ea, households may not transfer agricultural parcels to outsiders without <strong>the</strong> consent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>customary community authority structure (Fischer et al, 1995). It can also happen that a land “owner” is not authorized to make<strong>management</strong> decisions regard<strong>in</strong>g his or her <strong>property</strong>, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g such a fundamental decision dur<strong>in</strong>g which years to cultivate specific parcels,4 ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR


generally <strong>in</strong>volves a relatively concentrated <strong>rights</strong> bundle <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g a nearly exhaustive set <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong> strands asillustrated by <strong>the</strong> equation: ownership = use <strong>rights</strong> + <strong>management</strong> <strong>rights</strong> + transfer <strong>rights</strong> + alienation <strong>rights</strong>. 7A non-Westerner may th<strong>in</strong>k <strong>of</strong> ownership <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> historically established priority <strong>rights</strong> to a particulararea or set <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s on <strong>the</strong> part <strong>of</strong> a community or clan. In such a system, assignment <strong>of</strong> use and<strong>management</strong> <strong>rights</strong> is based on <strong>the</strong> family, clan, religious or ethnic identity <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> holder ra<strong>the</strong>r than on formallegal precepts.2.1.2 Property Rights RegimesThe number and identity <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> holders <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> strands <strong>of</strong> a <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> bundle determ<strong>in</strong>e <strong>the</strong> category <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regime. Typically, <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regimes are envisioned <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> four broad categories:private <strong>property</strong>, common <strong>property</strong>, public <strong>property</strong>, and open access (see Box 3). Thus, private <strong>property</strong>refers to cases where all strands <strong>of</strong> a <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> bundle associated with a unit <strong>of</strong> land (or <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>)Box 3. The Idealized Property RightsRegimesPrivate <strong>property</strong> occurs when <strong>the</strong> strands <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> bundle are held by a <strong>natural</strong> orlegal person (ARD, Inc., 2005).Common <strong>property</strong> exists where <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>strands are shared among members <strong>of</strong> acommunity or association.Public <strong>property</strong> is established when <strong>the</strong> strands<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> bundle are concentrated, held andmanaged by <strong>the</strong> government.Open access occurs where ei<strong>the</strong>r no specific<strong>rights</strong> to land or <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s have beenassigned or claimed by holders.may be held by a <strong>natural</strong> (real <strong>in</strong>dividual) or a legalperson (e.g., corporation). Where <strong>the</strong> strands <strong>of</strong> a private<strong>property</strong> bundle are shared among members <strong>of</strong> a def<strong>in</strong>edgroup such as a community, that <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regimeis designated as common <strong>property</strong>. In contrast to bothprivate and common <strong>property</strong>, strands <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong><strong>rights</strong> bundle may be held and managed by <strong>the</strong>government, <strong>in</strong> which case <strong>the</strong> term public <strong>property</strong> isapplied. F<strong>in</strong>ally, open access refers to land or <strong>natural</strong><strong>resource</strong>s that have no specific right holders associatewith <strong>the</strong>m. While such a situation is extremely rare, <strong>in</strong>reality, land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s <strong>of</strong>ten experience openaccess situations where claimed <strong>rights</strong> are unenforceable<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> face <strong>of</strong> an absence <strong>of</strong> legitimacy or <strong>the</strong> means toexclude anyone from use. This situation creates apowerful dis<strong>in</strong>centive for <strong>good</strong> governance, <strong>of</strong>tenlead<strong>in</strong>g to a competition to capture <strong>resource</strong>s <strong>in</strong> a raceaga<strong>in</strong>st o<strong>the</strong>r users.Westerners tend to reduce <strong>property</strong> regimes to a simple dichotomous set: private <strong>property</strong> or public <strong>property</strong>.In both cases <strong>the</strong> strands tend to be tightly packaged and backed up by law with government mechanisms forenforcement <strong>of</strong> exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regimes (see Figure 1). In <strong>the</strong> ideal situation, <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>bundle is held entirely by <strong>the</strong> state (public <strong>property</strong>) or <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual or corporation (private <strong>property</strong>). Inreality, <strong>the</strong> complete <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> bundle is never entirely held by a s<strong>in</strong>gle agent. 8 Thus, a private <strong>property</strong>claim does not normally convey unlimited authority to its holder <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> how <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong> can be used. Incases <strong>of</strong> privately held <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, <strong>the</strong> strands frequently rema<strong>in</strong> subject to government regulations(e.g., limits on logg<strong>in</strong>g that regulate clear cutt<strong>in</strong>g on steep slopes, anti-pollution regulations that prohibitlandowners from dispos<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> certa<strong>in</strong> poisonous chemicals <strong>in</strong> surface waters that traverse <strong>the</strong>ir lands, wildlifeand fish harvest<strong>in</strong>g controls <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> daily and bag limits). This <strong>in</strong> essence circumscribes or truncates <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>rights</strong> conta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> a bundle. For example, an owner <strong>of</strong> forested lands located <strong>in</strong> a particular zonemay be required to obta<strong>in</strong> a government permit prior to conversion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> forest for alternative uses, orthat may be <strong>in</strong>stead reserved for a community-level body such as a council <strong>of</strong> elders (Fischer et al, 1995). This example from Gu<strong>in</strong>ea isdiscussed <strong>in</strong> Section 3.7This concept <strong>of</strong> ownership is greatly simplified as compared to that detailed by Honoré (1961) cited <strong>in</strong> Bromley (1989). Honoré’sportrayal <strong>of</strong> ownership identifies eleven characteristics that are said to be present <strong>in</strong> full, or liberal, ownership (p.187). Bromley, Daniel W. 1989.Economic Interests and Institutions: The Conceptual Foundations <strong>of</strong> Public Policy. New York, NY: Basil Blackwell Inc. pp. 187-190.8De facto situations are <strong>of</strong>ten close to reflect<strong>in</strong>g customary rules, differ<strong>in</strong>g significantly from de jure rules.ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 5


engag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> timber harvests beyond def<strong>in</strong>ed levels. Never<strong>the</strong>less, one normally expects that where private<strong>property</strong> exists, most strands <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> bundle are controlled by a <strong>natural</strong> or legal person.FIGURE 1. TYPICAL WESTERN PROPERTY RIGHTS MODELPrivate <strong>rights</strong> to land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s are usuallyrestricted <strong>in</strong> specific ways based on governmentregulations.Uses <strong>of</strong> publicly held land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s are specifiedby government policies and may be freely enjoyed, availablefor a fee, or completely restricted depend<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>the</strong> nature <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> use.Designat<strong>in</strong>g land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s as “public <strong>property</strong>” is generally justified <strong>in</strong> environmental terms suchas creat<strong>in</strong>g forest reserves or powers <strong>of</strong> em<strong>in</strong>ent doma<strong>in</strong> exercised to create public <strong>in</strong>frastructure facilities,parks, watershed governance and <strong>management</strong> areas. In o<strong>the</strong>r cases, lands are by default public because no<strong>in</strong>dividual or group has been assigned <strong>rights</strong> to <strong>the</strong>m. In public <strong>property</strong> contexts, one would reasonablyexpect a higher degree <strong>of</strong> government control and def<strong>in</strong>ition regard<strong>in</strong>g publicly available use <strong>rights</strong> than is <strong>the</strong>case where <strong>property</strong> is held privately. In <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> publicly held (government-controlled) <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s,sets <strong>of</strong> use <strong>rights</strong>—from tree fell<strong>in</strong>g, to pastur<strong>in</strong>g livestock, to park visitation, to water consumption—areusually def<strong>in</strong>ed by <strong>the</strong> government and distributed to <strong>the</strong> public on a fee or non-fee basis. Most <strong>of</strong>tengovernments grant use <strong>rights</strong> to <strong>in</strong>dividuals and corporations for specified time periods. Governmentstemporarily transfer use <strong>rights</strong> through permits and leases.As <strong>the</strong> discussion moves toward a context <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s <strong>in</strong> non-Western rural sett<strong>in</strong>gs, <strong>the</strong> concept andreality <strong>of</strong> common <strong>property</strong> and open access renewable <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s becomes more important.Distribution <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> to renewable <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s is <strong>of</strong>ten much more complex <strong>in</strong> non-Westernthan <strong>in</strong> Western countries. In contrast to <strong>the</strong> relatively concentrated bundles prevalent <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Western contexts,<strong>in</strong> non-Western countries <strong>the</strong> strands <strong>of</strong> a bundle may be spread across a dizzy<strong>in</strong>g array <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividuals andgroups, as well economic operators and state agencies. Often one can observe multiple claims to <strong>the</strong> samestrand with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> bundle (see Figure 2). Multiple claims may arise with<strong>in</strong> or across <strong>property</strong><strong>rights</strong> systems classified as ei<strong>the</strong>r legally recognized (formal) or recognized under customary law (<strong>in</strong>formal).6 ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR


FIGURE 2. AN EXAMPLE OF A USE RIGHTS BUNDLE Figure 3 illustrates multiple claims to some <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> conta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>rights</strong> bundle concern<strong>in</strong>g aparticular forest. In this case, forest <strong>resource</strong>s are <strong>the</strong> object <strong>of</strong> both a local <strong>in</strong>formal common <strong>property</strong>regime, as represented <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> left hand section <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> figure, and a formal statutory regime represented by <strong>the</strong>middle and right hand sections <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> figure.FIGURE 3. AN EXAMPLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS TO NATURAL RESOURCES TYPICAL IN A NON-WESTERN SETTING Rights claimed by resident populations and Government claims are based on Often <strong>rights</strong> to <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>sbased on customary claims may legally established <strong>rights</strong> to determ<strong>in</strong>e may be obta<strong>in</strong>ed for a fee forencompass <strong>the</strong> entire <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> distribution and holders <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> commercial purposes. Feebundle but are usually supervised by <strong>resource</strong> <strong>management</strong> and use <strong>rights</strong>. structures and adm<strong>in</strong>istrationcustomary authorities and distributed Such claims may encompass <strong>the</strong> may or may not conform toamong households, <strong>in</strong>terest groups, and entire <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> bundle. stated policies.<strong>in</strong>dividuals.ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 7


Open access lands and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, sometimes referred to as “non-<strong>property</strong>,” exemplify lack <strong>of</strong> specific<strong>rights</strong>, or unenforceable <strong>rights</strong>. In contrast to common <strong>property</strong> regimes, open access <strong>resource</strong>s have nonamed and known group that claims <strong>the</strong>m, and no specific <strong>in</strong>stitutional arrangements designed to ensureproper governance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong>. Also unlike common <strong>property</strong>, <strong>in</strong> open access areas by def<strong>in</strong>ition noparticular <strong>in</strong>dividual or group has authority to exclude anyone from us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong>. Open access iscommon <strong>in</strong> mar<strong>in</strong>e contexts, where access to <strong>resource</strong>s beyond a specified distance from land may be freeand unrestricted to all. Open access areas may <strong>in</strong>clude rangelands, forests, or wetlands. It is important to notethat common <strong>property</strong>, public <strong>property</strong>, or private <strong>property</strong> may at times “slip <strong>in</strong>to” open access status wherelocal <strong>in</strong>stitutions, governments, or <strong>in</strong>dividuals responsible for govern<strong>in</strong>g and ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m lack <strong>the</strong> abilityto effectively monitor and enforce rules <strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong> use. For <strong>in</strong>stance, protected areas legally fall<strong>in</strong>g understate jurisdiction <strong>of</strong>ten experience open access situations (and are hence characterized as “paper parks”), dueto lack <strong>of</strong> effective mechanisms for monitor<strong>in</strong>g and enforcement.In some circumstances “hybrid” <strong>property</strong> regimes exist. These regimes comb<strong>in</strong>e vary<strong>in</strong>g elements <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><strong>rights</strong> regimes <strong>of</strong> private, public and common <strong>property</strong> systems. The def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g characteristic <strong>of</strong> hybrid<strong>property</strong> regimes is that <strong>the</strong> strands <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> bundle are shared among private and publicentities. Hybrid <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regimes <strong>in</strong>clude co-managed <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s or community-based <strong>natural</strong><strong>resource</strong> <strong>management</strong>, <strong>in</strong> which use and <strong>management</strong> <strong>rights</strong> are shared between government agencies andcommunity-based organizations.As generally perceived, private, public, and common <strong>property</strong> regimes are idealized forms <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong>regimes. Even <strong>the</strong> hybrid models generally ignore many ideological, legal, and social aspects systemicallyembedded <strong>in</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems. As a result, <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> regime types presented above—private, public,common, and open access—have been somewhat dryly referred to as <strong>the</strong> “big four” (Wiber, 2005).Never<strong>the</strong>less, if used sensibly, this taxonomy <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regimes is a useful tool for analyz<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong>issues and implications <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> program or project development contexts.In addition, multiple forms <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> <strong>of</strong>ten coexist <strong>in</strong> any given location (Coward, 2006). In o<strong>the</strong>rwords, <strong>in</strong>dividuals may hold <strong>rights</strong> to private lands, and at <strong>the</strong> same time, have <strong>rights</strong> to <strong>resource</strong>s held <strong>in</strong>common such as collectively managed fisheries <strong>resource</strong>s <strong>in</strong> a state-owned wetland. 9 It is important to notealso that <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> are impermanent and <strong>of</strong>ten change over time. As Coward notes, <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>arrangements are made and remade, particularly when <strong>the</strong>re are shifts <strong>in</strong> political or economic power.2.2 TENURE SECURITY AND ENFORCEMENT OF PROPERTY RIGHTSTenure security is characterized by enforceability <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>, and refers to <strong>the</strong> degree to which<strong>in</strong>dividual or group <strong>rights</strong> to land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s are recognized and protected. A lack <strong>of</strong> securityimplies <strong>in</strong>sufficient capacity to defend a <strong>property</strong> right aga<strong>in</strong>st compet<strong>in</strong>g claims, encroachment, or eviction.Insecurity <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> <strong>in</strong>vites conflict, discourages <strong>in</strong>vestment, 10 and <strong>in</strong> some <strong>in</strong>stances createsdis<strong>in</strong>centives for susta<strong>in</strong>able land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> stewardship, for <strong>in</strong>stance by <strong>in</strong>stigat<strong>in</strong>g land clear<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>efforts to legitimize land claims (see Unruh et al. 2005). Numerous factors play a <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> level<strong>of</strong> tenure security. As summarized <strong>in</strong> Box 4, <strong>the</strong>se <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>the</strong> legitimacy <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>, <strong>in</strong>stitutions9Such coexist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> are best illustrated <strong>in</strong> a “communal” tenure system not unusual <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> non-Western context. In acommunal tenure, <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> are <strong>of</strong>ten derived from <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> <strong>of</strong> a community, such as a l<strong>in</strong>eage, a village, orano<strong>the</strong>r social group (Bruce, 2004). In such a case, <strong>rights</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual landholders can be limited by <strong>the</strong> community from which those<strong>rights</strong> are derived.10A <strong>good</strong> summary <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economic advantages obta<strong>in</strong>ed through security <strong>of</strong> tenure is provided <strong>in</strong> Place, Roth and Hazell, Land TenureSecurity and Agricultural Performance <strong>in</strong> Africa: Overview <strong>of</strong> Research Methodology, <strong>in</strong> Bruce and Mighot-Adholla, Search<strong>in</strong>g for Land TenureSecurity <strong>in</strong> Africa, Dubuque, Iowa: Kendall/Hunt Publish<strong>in</strong>g Company, 1994 (sponsored by <strong>the</strong> World Bank).8 ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR


••••Box 4. Elements <strong>of</strong> Tenure SecurityTenure security is characterized by:Legitimacy,Institutional back<strong>in</strong>g,Clarity, andExcludability.available to support legitimate <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> (Me<strong>in</strong>zen-Dicket al., 2004), clarity <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong>, and excludability <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se <strong>rights</strong>(Lawry, 1990).Legitimacy. A lead<strong>in</strong>g factor <strong>in</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>enforceability is <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> legitimacy <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong><strong>rights</strong> system <strong>in</strong> which <strong>the</strong> claimed <strong>rights</strong> are anchored. Ahigh degree <strong>of</strong> legitimacy encourages voluntary complianceon <strong>the</strong> one hand, and discourages challenges to recognized<strong>rights</strong> on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r. A high degree <strong>of</strong> legitimacy reduces <strong>the</strong> need for repressive responses and elaborate<strong>in</strong>stitutions for dispute resolution. Property <strong>rights</strong> ga<strong>in</strong> legitimacy through laws and associated <strong>in</strong>stitutions (seeTable 1). A diverse set <strong>of</strong> laws and <strong>in</strong>stitutions may legitimate <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> claims; however, <strong>the</strong>se typically<strong>in</strong>volve customary law enforced by a local governance unit such as village <strong>in</strong>stitutions and elected orappo<strong>in</strong>ted <strong>in</strong>stitutional or village authorities. The statutory system is def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> written laws (de jure) enactedand enforced by a central or regional government. 11 Customary <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regimes are <strong>of</strong>ten referred toas non-formal (de facto) systems. These typically <strong>in</strong>corporate unwritten rules, <strong>of</strong>ten characterized by <strong>property</strong><strong>rights</strong> systems <strong>of</strong> considerable complexity. Customary <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems, which have evolved along with<strong>the</strong> societies <strong>in</strong> which <strong>the</strong>y are rooted, <strong>of</strong>ten enjoy a degree <strong>of</strong> legitimacy <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> eyes <strong>of</strong> local people that farexceeds that <strong>of</strong> (imposed) statutory laws. Indeed, <strong>in</strong> many parts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> non-Western world, it is <strong>the</strong> customary<strong>rights</strong> that legitimate <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> <strong>in</strong> rural areas. For <strong>in</strong>stance <strong>in</strong> West African countries, Toulm<strong>in</strong> (2005­2006) notes that <strong>rights</strong> to only 2-3 percent <strong>of</strong> land may be formally recognized under statutory law. A majority<strong>of</strong> those parcels are localized <strong>in</strong> urban or o<strong>the</strong>r commercialized areas. Various sets <strong>of</strong> laws (formal and nonformal)may contradict each o<strong>the</strong>r result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> overlapp<strong>in</strong>g claims and at times conflict.TABLE 1. SUPPORT FOR ENFORCEMENT OF CUSTOMARY PROPERTY RIGHTS TOVILLAGE LANDS AND NATURAL RESOURCES: THE ROLE OF LEGITIMACYRights HolderCOMMUNITYCOUNCIL OFELDERSHEADS OFHOUSEHOLDSHOUSEHOLDMEMBERSType <strong>of</strong>Rightsownership<strong>rights</strong>transfer <strong>rights</strong><strong>management</strong><strong>rights</strong>use <strong>rights</strong>Basis for LegitimacyTraditional authoritystructures <strong>of</strong> community;shared history andtraditionsTraditional authoritystructures <strong>of</strong> communityTraditional authoritystructures <strong>of</strong> communityand householdsTraditional authoritystructures <strong>of</strong> householdbacked up by communityChallenges to LegitimacyGovernment claims to manage reserves,waterways, watersheds, fisheries and wildlife,as well as o<strong>the</strong>rwise “vacant” lands;development <strong>of</strong> land marketsHereditary posts los<strong>in</strong>g power and authority;fragmentation <strong>of</strong> authority as it shifts fromcommunity-level toward households andnuclear familiesHousehold fragmentation and assertion <strong>of</strong>claims to portions <strong>of</strong> family common lands onpart <strong>of</strong> nuclear familiesMoney economy develops creat<strong>in</strong>g livelihoodoptions for household members beyondfarm<strong>in</strong>g; encourages land markets)Institutional Back<strong>in</strong>g. Institutions are necessary to enforce <strong>the</strong> specific legal system that provides legitimacyto a set <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>. These <strong>in</strong>stitutions (associated with each legal system) are responsible for mak<strong>in</strong>gand modify<strong>in</strong>g rules <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> regime; monitor<strong>in</strong>g compliance with those rules; sanction<strong>in</strong>g persons who <strong>in</strong>fr<strong>in</strong>gerules; mediat<strong>in</strong>g any result<strong>in</strong>g conflicts; dissem<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation about results <strong>of</strong> monitor<strong>in</strong>g; sanction<strong>in</strong>g;resolv<strong>in</strong>g disputes; and mobiliz<strong>in</strong>g <strong>resource</strong>s, leaders and staff to conduct all <strong>the</strong>se functions. The11O<strong>the</strong>r sets <strong>of</strong> laws and rules regard<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> may apply depend<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>the</strong> context and <strong>the</strong> specific site. For <strong>in</strong>stance, Me<strong>in</strong>zen-Dick et al. (2004) identify religious or “project” laws that may apply to specific areas.ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 9


espective <strong>resource</strong>s is manageable, and different uses <strong>in</strong>terfere little with each o<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> various claimed<strong>rights</strong> can endure for extended periods. Sometimes such systems were re<strong>in</strong>forced by a prohibition on fencebuild<strong>in</strong>garound agricultural parcels that were used seasonally by transhumant herders (see Figure 4). But ascompetition for <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong> <strong>in</strong>tensifies, circumstances may favor re<strong>in</strong>forcement or extension <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong> heldby one group and <strong>the</strong> weaken<strong>in</strong>g or disappearance <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong> held by a compet<strong>in</strong>g group. Compared totranshumant pastoralists, farmers enjoy <strong>the</strong> advantage <strong>of</strong> occupy<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> same area year round. A developmentsuch as <strong>in</strong>tensification <strong>of</strong> agriculture over time, or simply heightened demand and competition for land, canfavor use <strong>rights</strong> holders who cont<strong>in</strong>uously occupy, or are <strong>in</strong> close proximity to, a <strong>resource</strong> that hascustomarily been shared on a seasonal basis.FIGURE 4. CHANGE OF RIGHTS OVER TIMESimilarly, Figure 5 illustrates how <strong>the</strong> designation <strong>of</strong> a forest reserve by <strong>the</strong> government can change <strong>property</strong><strong>rights</strong> at <strong>the</strong> local level. Here, <strong>in</strong>itial customary <strong>rights</strong> <strong>of</strong> settled agriculturalists to cultivation and collection <strong>of</strong>non-timber forest products (NTFPs), and pastoralist <strong>rights</strong> to seasonal forag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> livestock and water use arealtered as <strong>the</strong> government grants timber concessions to an urban entrepreneur. In this illustration, while <strong>the</strong><strong>rights</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> settled farmer are reta<strong>in</strong>ed and recognized <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> statutory system, pastoralist seasonal <strong>rights</strong> arenot, possibly due to lack presence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> pastoralists at <strong>the</strong> time customary <strong>rights</strong> were recorded by <strong>the</strong> state.FIGURE 5. STATE FORESTS: COMPETING INTERESTSROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 11


have been, and cont<strong>in</strong>ue to be, managed as a common <strong>property</strong> <strong>resource</strong>. Pastoralist groups may manage this<strong>resource</strong> through seasonal movements and a rotational system <strong>of</strong> use. In order to limit excessive use <strong>of</strong> apasture <strong>resource</strong>, graz<strong>in</strong>g may be regulated to specified areas dur<strong>in</strong>g specific times. When carry<strong>in</strong>g capacity isreached, graz<strong>in</strong>g is shifted to adjacent parcels. This ensures that no unit <strong>of</strong> land is overgrazed. The ability tomove over large areas reduced, to some degree, herder vulnerability to drought and constra<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>of</strong> land quality<strong>of</strong> fixed plots (Fernandez-Gimenez, 2006; Thomson, 1992). Recent trends <strong>in</strong> land privatization, however, hasreduced mobility <strong>of</strong> pastoralist groups, conf<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g graz<strong>in</strong>g to relative small land parcels, and as a resultsignificantly reduc<strong>in</strong>g productivity and plant species diversity <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>se pasture areas (Fernandez-Gimenez,2006).2.4 DISCUSSIONS AND TRENDS FROM THE LITERATUREMany countries have reformed land and <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> s<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> 1960s. These efforts strove to improveaccess to and control <strong>of</strong> land by <strong>the</strong> landless and rural poor. Later, <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1980s and 1990s, land reformprograms sought to <strong>in</strong>crease tenure security <strong>of</strong> rural and urban populations alike. This latter trend aroselargely <strong>in</strong> response to highly centralized governance and <strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s under <strong>the</strong>colonial and post-colonial eras and <strong>the</strong> <strong>of</strong>ten progressively less secure <strong>rights</strong> derived from pre-colonial timesthat left rural populations <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly vulnerable to landlessness and eviction. 13 While many nationalgovernments <strong>in</strong> non-Western countries have attempted to redistribute lands and address issues <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>equity,donor assistance to land reform has largely focused attention on privatization <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong>, <strong>in</strong>dividuation <strong>of</strong><strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>, and formalization <strong>of</strong> tenure. More recently, <strong>the</strong>se trends have <strong>in</strong>cluded legal recognition <strong>of</strong>customary and <strong>in</strong>digenous <strong>rights</strong> with<strong>in</strong> statutory legal frameworks (FAO, 2002b). In some countries—forexample Botswana, Namibia and Malawi—national governments have created statutory enabl<strong>in</strong>g frameworksthat (i) provide <strong>in</strong>centives for generation <strong>of</strong> new <strong>rights</strong> (and <strong>in</strong>come streams) <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>digenous communities, or(ii) recognize and support <strong>in</strong>digenous <strong>in</strong>itiatives to establish use <strong>rights</strong> and limit harvest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> selected <strong>natural</strong><strong>resource</strong>s with <strong>the</strong> objectives <strong>of</strong> ensur<strong>in</strong>g susta<strong>in</strong>able use and proper stewardship <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se <strong>resource</strong>s.In addition to <strong>the</strong>se land reform <strong>in</strong>itiatives, <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> governance and <strong>management</strong> policies have <strong>of</strong>tenmodified <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, although <strong>the</strong> trends are mixed. Many wildlife conservationstrategies that persisted throughout much <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> twentieth century and <strong>in</strong>to <strong>the</strong> present century embrace <strong>the</strong>tradition <strong>of</strong> state <strong>property</strong> and strict <strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> use <strong>rights</strong> as tools for protection. Establish<strong>in</strong>g protectedareas has underm<strong>in</strong>ed customary <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> ei<strong>the</strong>r through evictions or elim<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> access <strong>rights</strong> to<strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s such as non-timber forest products (Dowie, 2005). This approach <strong>of</strong>ten ignored legitimatecustomary <strong>rights</strong>, lead<strong>in</strong>g to conflict between local communities and <strong>the</strong> state, and <strong>in</strong> many cases rapiddegradation <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>se protected areas.The 1980s brought with it clear realization that government <strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s and strictprotection models for biodiversity conservation present difficulties for a number <strong>of</strong> reasons:1. Governments began realiz<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>the</strong>y lack f<strong>in</strong>ancial and human <strong>resource</strong>s to manage susta<strong>in</strong>ably <strong>the</strong> vasttracts <strong>of</strong> lands and renewable <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s <strong>the</strong>re<strong>in</strong>. In particular, monitor<strong>in</strong>g, enforcement, anddispute resolution required extensive <strong>resource</strong>s that most governments lacked. Without adequate systemsfor monitor<strong>in</strong>g and enforcement, lands legally under state <strong>management</strong> have <strong>in</strong> practice exploited as openaccess <strong>resource</strong>s.2. Governments lacked transparency and accountability <strong>in</strong> governance and <strong>management</strong>, pos<strong>in</strong>g enormousthreats to state-held lands. State-held lands and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s <strong>in</strong> many <strong>in</strong>stances came under abuse bycorrupt government <strong>of</strong>ficials. This has taken <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> illegal logg<strong>in</strong>g, grant<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> m<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g or logg<strong>in</strong>gconcessions to private companies <strong>in</strong> critical ecosystems <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g protected areas, or <strong>in</strong> certa<strong>in</strong> casesexploitation <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s by governments (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g military) to extract revenues for personal13Similar experience can be noted <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Former Soviet Union and <strong>the</strong> Newly Independent States.ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 13


ends or to f<strong>in</strong>ance violent conflicts or both (e.g., Indonesia, Liberia, Myanmar, Cambodia, DemocraticRepublic <strong>of</strong> Congo, Sierra Leone) (Ross, 2004).3. Government agencies <strong>in</strong> many cases succumbed to <strong>in</strong>centives to address short-term economic prioritiesra<strong>the</strong>r than long-term environmental ga<strong>in</strong>s.4. Centralized policies and regulations were <strong>of</strong>ten poorly designed and did not reflect user concerns andneeds. At <strong>the</strong> same time, user groups failed to subscribe to <strong>the</strong> centralized policies, lead<strong>in</strong>g to lowcompliance.5. F<strong>in</strong>ally, diverse experiences revealed that government-imposed, protection-oriented models illegallyconfiscated <strong>rights</strong> <strong>of</strong> local communities <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>digenous groups.Thus, earlier emphasis <strong>of</strong> development programs on economic growth ra<strong>the</strong>r than meet<strong>in</strong>g livelihood needs,and government attempts to control <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s (typically to enrich <strong>the</strong>mselves) ra<strong>the</strong>r thanempower<strong>in</strong>g local <strong>in</strong>dividual, group and community owners to better govern and manage <strong>the</strong> lands and<strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> <strong>in</strong> question has caused significant harm, both to popular confidence <strong>in</strong> central government<strong>of</strong>ficials and to <strong>the</strong> possibilities for susta<strong>in</strong>able stewardship <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s.The past two decades have seen significant advances <strong>in</strong> decentralization and particularly devolution <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong><strong>resource</strong> governance and <strong>management</strong>. Decentralization (transfer <strong>of</strong> government functions from <strong>the</strong> center tolocal government) and devolution (transfer <strong>of</strong> authority to local level community <strong>in</strong>stitutions) are importantstrategies for susta<strong>in</strong>able <strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, ensur<strong>in</strong>g livelihood security andempowerment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rural poor.These policy changes are based on <strong>the</strong> recognition that effective governance <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> can takeplace through devolution <strong>of</strong> governance and <strong>management</strong> <strong>rights</strong> and responsibilities to those resid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>closest proximity to <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong>. Many <strong>of</strong> those <strong>in</strong>dividuals, families and user groups are keenly aware <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong>ir dependence on <strong>the</strong> land parcels and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> <strong>in</strong> question. This <strong>of</strong>ten biases <strong>the</strong>m aga<strong>in</strong>st shorttermextractive exploitation and <strong>in</strong> favor <strong>of</strong> long-term stewardship. There is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g recognition <strong>of</strong> localknowledge and governance capacities <strong>of</strong> local <strong>in</strong>stitutions. In case after case local knowledge <strong>of</strong> localconditions, particularly concern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> health <strong>of</strong> land and o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, turns out to be more f<strong>in</strong>egra<strong>in</strong>edand sophisticated than that <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficials and technicians <strong>in</strong> overlapp<strong>in</strong>g local, regional, and nationalregimes can muster. Indeed, people who live with <strong>resource</strong>s <strong>of</strong>ten have a clear “knowledge” advantage overthose who merely pass through an area from time to time.In many <strong>in</strong>stances, local <strong>in</strong>stitutions <strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong> governance can be more effective <strong>in</strong> monitor<strong>in</strong>g,enforcement, sanction<strong>in</strong>g and dispute resolution systems than government agencies. Here aga<strong>in</strong>, a large part<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> explanation lies <strong>in</strong> superior time and place knowledge, backed by far greater legitimacy.Decentralization and devolution, <strong>the</strong>refore, serve to provide enabl<strong>in</strong>g environments for effective governanceby local <strong>in</strong>stitutions, <strong>the</strong>reby elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g open access circumstances and associated mis<strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> landsand <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s. In addition, local <strong>in</strong>stitutions serve to <strong>in</strong>troduce important checks and balances on stategovernance and <strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> lands and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s. Management <strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s by local <strong>in</strong>stitutionsand user groups allows for greater cost-effectiveness <strong>in</strong> <strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, and is better adapted tochang<strong>in</strong>g ecological conditions and more responsive to complex and fluid needs <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> multiple user groupsthat may change <strong>in</strong> space and time. Decentralization and devolution policies allow policy makers to developsolutions that <strong>in</strong>tegrate socioeconomic, food security, and poverty alleviation concerns with improvedstewardship <strong>of</strong> land and <strong>resource</strong>s. Decentralization and devolution, and associated security <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong><strong>rights</strong>, have served as well to empower rural communities and create <strong>in</strong>centives for <strong>the</strong> k<strong>in</strong>d <strong>of</strong> stewardshipthat help ensure long-term susta<strong>in</strong>ability <strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s at <strong>the</strong> local level.Under decentralization and devolution efforts, customary <strong>rights</strong> to lands and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s are<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly be<strong>in</strong>g recognized under statutory law. For example, national land laws and policies <strong>in</strong> a number<strong>of</strong> African nations have begun legally recogniz<strong>in</strong>g customary <strong>rights</strong> to <strong>in</strong>dividual and communal lands. InMozambique, <strong>the</strong> land law grants communities <strong>management</strong> and decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g powers regard<strong>in</strong>g use <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>14 ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR


commons. Similarly, <strong>in</strong> Tanzania, <strong>the</strong> village Land Act recognizes customary occupation or use <strong>of</strong> land. InUganda, <strong>the</strong> Constitution and Land Act provide secure tenure to holders <strong>of</strong> customary land <strong>rights</strong>, andauthority <strong>of</strong> local land committees to adm<strong>in</strong>ister customary laws. The Act allows for communal ownershipand communal claims to <strong>the</strong>se <strong>resource</strong>s (FAO, 2002b). In neighbor<strong>in</strong>g Botswana, Namibia and Malawi,state-enabl<strong>in</strong>g frameworks similarly authorize local committees or user groups to govern and manage severaltypes <strong>of</strong> renewable <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s. Even though <strong>in</strong> certa<strong>in</strong> cases those are new <strong>in</strong>itiatives, <strong>the</strong>y draw <strong>the</strong>same power, legitimacy, and efficiency from <strong>the</strong>ir local foundations as do comparable local <strong>in</strong>itiatives <strong>of</strong>longer stand<strong>in</strong>g.In Lat<strong>in</strong> America and parts <strong>of</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>ast Asia over <strong>the</strong> past two decades, national laws have promoted legalrecognition <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>digenous peoples, giv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>alienable <strong>rights</strong> to customary claims. In South America,for example, <strong>in</strong>digenous <strong>rights</strong> are legally recognized <strong>in</strong> a number <strong>of</strong> countries <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g Brazil, Colombia,Peru, Bolivia, and Ecuador. In Bolivia, <strong>the</strong> 1996 Agrarian Reform Law legally recognizes <strong>the</strong> TierrasComunitarias de Orig<strong>in</strong> giv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>digenous groups collective <strong>in</strong>alienable <strong>rights</strong> over customary claims to land and<strong>resource</strong>s (FAO, 2002b). In Ecuador, <strong>the</strong> Constitution recognizes <strong>in</strong>alienable land claims <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>digenousgroups to customary claims. In <strong>the</strong> Philipp<strong>in</strong>es, <strong>the</strong> 1997 Indigenous Peoples Rights Act recognizes<strong>in</strong>digenous ownership and control <strong>of</strong> ancestral doma<strong>in</strong>s. Associated regulations prevent encroachment andexpropriation by outside groups. This trend <strong>in</strong> recognition <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>digenous <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> is also visible <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>west. For <strong>in</strong>stance, Canadian law recognizes <strong>rights</strong> <strong>of</strong> Canada’s First Nations (<strong>in</strong>digenous groups) and, <strong>in</strong> sodo<strong>in</strong>g, recognize a wide variety <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>digenous claims to <strong>resource</strong>s, e.g., extremely valuable timber, wildlife, fishand water <strong>rights</strong> (McNeil, 2001).Over <strong>the</strong> past two decades, co-<strong>management</strong> and community-based <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> <strong>management</strong> (CBNRM)approaches have recognized rural populations and <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> to <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s <strong>in</strong> variouscapacities. These hybrid <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> typically have implications for use or <strong>management</strong> <strong>rights</strong>, but rarelyfor transfer <strong>rights</strong>. Various forms <strong>of</strong> co-<strong>management</strong> and CBNRM models exist (Child, 2005). However, <strong>in</strong>general, both co-<strong>management</strong> and CBNRM <strong>in</strong>itiatives seek to work <strong>the</strong> diverse stakeholder groups (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>glocal user groups) l<strong>in</strong>ked with specific units <strong>of</strong> land and stocks <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, and attempt to reconcile<strong>the</strong>ir diverse <strong>in</strong>terests. Under such arrangements, stakeholder groups enjoy specific benefits and shareresponsibility for <strong>management</strong> or governance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> specific unit <strong>of</strong> land or associated <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>.Lynch (1999) makes a useful dist<strong>in</strong>ction between decentralization and devolution on <strong>the</strong> one hand andcommunity-based <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r; advocat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> latter for long-term occupants <strong>of</strong> specific areasand to <strong>the</strong> commons. As Lynch notes, <strong>the</strong> former mechanisms gives group <strong>rights</strong> to local communities foruse <strong>of</strong> public land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s conta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>the</strong>re<strong>in</strong>. In such cases, <strong>the</strong> government reta<strong>in</strong>s ownership<strong>of</strong> lands but grants leases or delegates <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> for a specific period <strong>of</strong> time to local user groups undercommunity forestry, or hybrid forms <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> such as CBRNM or co-<strong>management</strong> arrangements.Lynch advocates community-based <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>, or legal recognition <strong>of</strong> private group <strong>rights</strong>, given thatprivate <strong>rights</strong> provide greater security and are subject to fewer state controls than are use <strong>rights</strong> underdecentralized systems <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> <strong>management</strong>. Such private <strong>rights</strong> also allow local communities tonegotiate with governments and outside <strong>in</strong>terest groups on more equal terms than those associated with use<strong>rights</strong> on public lands.As decentralized and devolution approaches to <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> <strong>management</strong> become popular around <strong>the</strong>world, <strong>the</strong>re is also recognition that devolution <strong>in</strong> particular is not a panacea. As Larson (2004) notes,decentralization or devolution may not always lead to susta<strong>in</strong>able <strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, nor do allcustomary systems ensure equity <strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong> distribution and decision mak<strong>in</strong>g. Elite capture may lead topowerful groups dom<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g decision mak<strong>in</strong>g and <strong>resource</strong> use at <strong>the</strong> expense <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> poorer and marg<strong>in</strong>alizedgroup(s). In o<strong>the</strong>r cases, customary systems may be biased aga<strong>in</strong>st a specific gender (typically women).Devolution <strong>of</strong> some but not all powers is <strong>the</strong>refore recommended by some, hence ensur<strong>in</strong>g social equity andenvironmental susta<strong>in</strong>ability as def<strong>in</strong>ed by national governments (Ribot, 2004). In o<strong>the</strong>r cases, collaborative orco-<strong>management</strong> models may provide appropriate checks and balances to ensure equitable distribution <strong>of</strong><strong>rights</strong> and environmental susta<strong>in</strong>ability.ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 15


3.0 PROPERTY RIGHTS IN ACTION:ILLUSTRATIONS OF SOME KEYCHALLENGES ANDOPPORTUNITIES REGARDINGPROPERTY RIGHTS TONATURAL RESOURCESThis section beg<strong>in</strong>s with a summary <strong>of</strong> key observations regard<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> to <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s thathave emerged to this po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> discussion. These observations underlie <strong>the</strong> contemporary challenges thatare <strong>the</strong> focus <strong>of</strong> much <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> rema<strong>in</strong>der <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> section.3.1 PROPERTY RIGHTS TO LAND AND NATURAL RESOURCES: KEYOBSERVATIONS1. A <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> system and related <strong>in</strong>stitutions are nearly always present. Wherever stocks <strong>of</strong><strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s exist, some type <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> system that governs—or attempts to govern—access, use, <strong>management</strong>, and transfer <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s nearly always exists. A situation <strong>of</strong> openaccess to <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s occurs where <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> authority systems are <strong>in</strong>adequately equipped toenforce claimed authority or are excessively challenged; however, govern<strong>in</strong>g pr<strong>in</strong>ciples are very rarelyabsent. Information regard<strong>in</strong>g local <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> rules and <strong>the</strong>ir enforcement is usually fairly easy tocome by. Pos<strong>in</strong>g questions to observed <strong>resource</strong> users about access and use rules is a <strong>good</strong> place to start.2. More than one <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> system may operate at <strong>the</strong> same site. Often overlapp<strong>in</strong>g and perhapscompet<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems exist <strong>in</strong> relation to a given <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> set. A common occurrence <strong>of</strong>plural <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems <strong>in</strong>volves customary and statutory rules and policies. But <strong>property</strong> systemsmay also be def<strong>in</strong>ed and applied through vehicles as diverse as religion or development projects. Thepresence <strong>of</strong> multiple systems regulat<strong>in</strong>g, or claim<strong>in</strong>g authority to regulate, <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> has significantimpact on <strong>the</strong> contents and coherence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> bundles <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong> attached to <strong>the</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s <strong>of</strong> aparticular site.3. Whatever <strong>the</strong> orientation <strong>of</strong> national policies, customary practices rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> effect <strong>in</strong> manysett<strong>in</strong>gs. In non-Western countries, customary <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems frequently reta<strong>in</strong> de facto authorityand <strong>in</strong>stitutions that cont<strong>in</strong>ue to regulate and enforce <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>, although <strong>in</strong> many cases customarysystems are challenged and weakened. Customary systems react to, and may compete with, governmentpolicy and chang<strong>in</strong>g socioeconomic conditions. None<strong>the</strong>less, customary <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems <strong>of</strong>tenreta<strong>in</strong> much more coherence and legitimacy than compet<strong>in</strong>g systems and events. Indeed, it is importantto understand <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> situation <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> de jure versus de facto, and customary versus statutory.Often one f<strong>in</strong>ds that <strong>in</strong>itial perceptions <strong>of</strong> a <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regime turn out to be only part <strong>of</strong> a muchlarger picture.16 ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR


4. Customary <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems are durable. Property <strong>rights</strong> systems, particularly customarysystems, exhibit characteristics <strong>of</strong> flexibility as <strong>the</strong>y evolve <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> face <strong>of</strong> chang<strong>in</strong>g economic, social, andpolitical environments. This flexibility, along with long-stand<strong>in</strong>g local legitimacy, makes it difficult toreplace a customary system. Also, <strong>in</strong> many circumstances, it is not necessary to replace customary systems.If <strong>the</strong> goal is to improve stewardship <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, ra<strong>the</strong>r than promot<strong>in</strong>g or facilitat<strong>in</strong>g exploitation byoutsiders (with <strong>the</strong> latter arguably lead<strong>in</strong>g to fur<strong>the</strong>r marg<strong>in</strong>alization <strong>of</strong> already impoverishedpopulations), <strong>the</strong>n states can materially streng<strong>the</strong>n customary systems—particularly those that havedemonstrated <strong>the</strong>ir utility and robustness—simply by accord<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m <strong>of</strong>ficial recognition. Whenoutsiders challenge <strong>the</strong> authority <strong>of</strong> customary rules and <strong>in</strong>stitutions, an occasional state <strong>in</strong>terventionunderl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g state support for customary rules and <strong>in</strong>stitutions can enhance <strong>the</strong>ir credibility and re<strong>in</strong>force<strong>the</strong>ir legitimacy. Such rules and <strong>in</strong>stitutions ga<strong>in</strong> a new lease on life simply because <strong>the</strong> state or nationalgovernment has recognized <strong>the</strong>ir existence and utility.5. Customary <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> are not a panacea. As noted earlier, customary land and <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> arenot always equitable. Societal prejudices aga<strong>in</strong>st particular groups, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g women, are <strong>of</strong>ten reflected <strong>in</strong><strong>the</strong> associated <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> system. In some cases customary tenure systems may not promotesusta<strong>in</strong>able <strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, and <strong>in</strong>stead engage <strong>in</strong> exploitative use respond<strong>in</strong>g tochang<strong>in</strong>g economic <strong>in</strong>centives. In o<strong>the</strong>r cases yet, customary systems may f<strong>in</strong>d it difficult to adapt to <strong>the</strong>rapid pace <strong>of</strong> changes tak<strong>in</strong>g place <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> current context (Mathieu et al., 2003). It is useful to notehowever, that statutory <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems are equally susceptible to <strong>in</strong>equity aris<strong>in</strong>g from unfairprivileges granted to favored groups. Statutory <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> may also promote unsusta<strong>in</strong>able<strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s through unclear, contradictory or poor policies, or through <strong>the</strong> poorimplementation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se policies. Therefore, some comb<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> customary and statutory systemscould yield positive results.6. Form <strong>of</strong>ten follows function. Established practices <strong>of</strong>ten constitute <strong>the</strong> basis for establishment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>rules that govern <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems. This pr<strong>in</strong>ciple is articulated <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> well-known maxim: possessionis n<strong>in</strong>e-tenths <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> law. In many parts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> world, customary land tenure systems have to adapt todemographic pressure and changes <strong>in</strong> local economy. As a result, agriculture is com<strong>in</strong>g under directcompetition aga<strong>in</strong>st non-agricultural uses <strong>of</strong> land. As Mathieu et al. (2003) illustrate <strong>of</strong> Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso,customary rules and restrictions, such as restrictions regard<strong>in</strong>g alienation <strong>of</strong> land to outsiders is com<strong>in</strong>gunder pressure. As new practices become dom<strong>in</strong>ant, rules are <strong>of</strong>ten modified to reflect <strong>the</strong>se chang<strong>in</strong>gpractices. Conversely, regulation <strong>of</strong> practices through proclamation <strong>of</strong> new rules can be even morechalleng<strong>in</strong>g. This is evidenced <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>in</strong> many countries volumes <strong>of</strong> land tenure legislation havebeen produced but <strong>the</strong>y have never been effectively implemented.7. To be complete, a <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> system needs “sticks”. To enforce rules, a <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systemneeds teeth <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutions capable <strong>of</strong> monitor<strong>in</strong>g compliance with rules, impos<strong>in</strong>g penaltiesfor non-compliance and resolv<strong>in</strong>g disputes. Where such <strong>in</strong>stitutions are lack<strong>in</strong>g, exist<strong>in</strong>g rules govern<strong>in</strong>g<strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> will not necessarily shape practices. 14 Among <strong>the</strong> challenges to customary <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>systems is that legitimate authority to enforce rules may not be recognized beyond communityboundaries, whereas challenges to local rules are <strong>of</strong>ten non-local. As local authority weakens, it may alsobecome more feasible to challenge rules from <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>side. However, it is equally important to note thatmany statutory rules ostensibly govern<strong>in</strong>g access to and use <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s lack <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutionalsupports upon which <strong>the</strong>ir enforcement depends.8. To be complete, a <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> system also needs “carrots”. New or expand<strong>in</strong>g market <strong>in</strong>centivescan ei<strong>the</strong>r pose threats to exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>, or create opportunities for achievement <strong>of</strong>14The system <strong>of</strong> sanctions and rule enforcement can vary. Sanctions may take <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> imposed fees or penalties for rule violations.However, <strong>in</strong> many non-Western contexts, parallel or overlapp<strong>in</strong>g systems <strong>of</strong> sanctions may exist, as for <strong>in</strong>stance social sanctions and <strong>the</strong>fear <strong>of</strong> social exclusion, or super<strong>natural</strong> sanctions based on belief <strong>in</strong> div<strong>in</strong>e retribution.ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 17


environmental and development goals through a <strong>rights</strong>-based approach. Market <strong>in</strong>centives, wherecarefully managed, can complement and re<strong>in</strong>force exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems. Unmanaged market<strong>in</strong>centives can destroy exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>rights</strong> systems and lead to free-for-all competition favor<strong>in</strong>g those withprivileged means and access. Where <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> are ignored and not replaced, few constra<strong>in</strong>ts orguidel<strong>in</strong>es rema<strong>in</strong> regard<strong>in</strong>g environmental susta<strong>in</strong>ability. Usually <strong>the</strong> most appropriate approach to skirtthis problem is to channel <strong>in</strong>centives toward traditional and local <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> users.9. Duration <strong>of</strong> tenure has implications for security <strong>of</strong> tenure and productive <strong>in</strong>vestments. Individualsor groups with short-term use <strong>rights</strong> are unlikely to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> long-term susta<strong>in</strong>ability <strong>of</strong> land and <strong>natural</strong><strong>resource</strong>s. For <strong>in</strong>stance, five-year use <strong>rights</strong> are unlikely to provide adequate <strong>in</strong>centives for <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong>plant<strong>in</strong>g slow grow<strong>in</strong>g trees or <strong>in</strong> soil and water conservation works as <strong>the</strong> time period is too brief topermit short-termers to benefit from <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>in</strong>vestments. Long-term tenure security is fundamental forlong-term <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> susta<strong>in</strong>ability (FAO, 2002a).3.2 FIVE KEY CHALLENGES TO A RIGHTS-BASED APPROACH FOR BETTERNATURAL RESOURCE MANAGEMENTIn <strong>the</strong> follow<strong>in</strong>g section, <strong>the</strong> focus is on selected challenges <strong>in</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> reforms with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>natural</strong><strong>resource</strong> programm<strong>in</strong>g context. The follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>mes <strong>of</strong> contemporary importance are explored:1. Manag<strong>in</strong>g and channel<strong>in</strong>g chang<strong>in</strong>g market <strong>in</strong>centives,2. Harmoniz<strong>in</strong>g with government policies (with a focus on devolution/decentralization),3. Build<strong>in</strong>g on customary <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems,4. Balanc<strong>in</strong>g equity and efficiency, and5. Enforc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> <strong>in</strong> a chang<strong>in</strong>g world.To illustrate <strong>the</strong>se key challenges to <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> and how <strong>the</strong>y function <strong>in</strong> non-Western and transitionsocieties, <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> concepts and summary <strong>of</strong> trends <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> literature featured <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> previous sectionare transposed <strong>in</strong>to a practical and dynamic context—one that closely reflects <strong>the</strong> real world conditions <strong>in</strong>which <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> and development practitioners and managers operate.3.2.1 Manag<strong>in</strong>g and Channel<strong>in</strong>g Chang<strong>in</strong>g Market IncentivesSocieties everywhere are becom<strong>in</strong>g more dependent on participation <strong>in</strong> market activities to satisfy all manner<strong>of</strong> consumption needs and wants. Whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> result <strong>of</strong> population <strong>in</strong>creases, advertis<strong>in</strong>g, chang<strong>in</strong>g tastes orris<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>comes, markets for <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s—or for products that require <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s as <strong>in</strong>puts—aregrow<strong>in</strong>g. Grow<strong>in</strong>g markets may threaten susta<strong>in</strong>ability <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s as demand <strong>in</strong>creases; <strong>in</strong>troduce or<strong>in</strong>tensify <strong>the</strong> conflict between use <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s to satisfy subsistence needs (and as a livelihoodstrategy) and use <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s as <strong>in</strong>puts for commodity production; require new and more efficientorganizational configurations that can respond to <strong>management</strong> needs <strong>in</strong>herent <strong>in</strong> production for markets; or<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>the</strong> stra<strong>in</strong> on exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> rules and enforcement <strong>in</strong>stitutions that have yet to adapt<strong>the</strong>mselves to function<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a market environment.Markets require that actors are endowed with particular types and levels <strong>of</strong> organizational capacity. Capture <strong>of</strong>an <strong>in</strong>come stream provides <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>centive that motivates <strong>the</strong> would-be provider <strong>of</strong> a commodity to produceand market <strong>the</strong> commodity. Therefore, for markets to work effectively, clear channels must be established toshape <strong>in</strong>come flows <strong>in</strong> a predictable manner. Control over commodity <strong>in</strong>puts, such as <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, is anobvious benefit to <strong>the</strong> supplier <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> commodity. Two important potential developments may arise:• Exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> may be challenged s<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> economic actors motivated or positioned to takeadvantage <strong>of</strong> new market opportunities are not necessarily <strong>the</strong> same <strong>in</strong>dividuals and groups as exist<strong>in</strong>g<strong>rights</strong> holders. Frequently market operators take a short-term approach to <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, while thosewho depend on <strong>the</strong> same <strong>resource</strong>s for <strong>in</strong>puts to <strong>the</strong>ir production systems are structurally encouraged to takea long-term approach to those same <strong>resource</strong>s and prefer susta<strong>in</strong>able flows <strong>of</strong> <strong>good</strong>s and services to18 ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR


s<strong>in</strong>gle-round exploitation strategies. Thus <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> advocates will likely have strong <strong>in</strong>centives tosupport customary or long-endur<strong>in</strong>g user groups.• New or <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g market <strong>in</strong>centives encourage a tendency toward <strong>in</strong>dividualization and <strong>in</strong>creasedexclusivity <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>. This is because transaction costs related to commodity production andmarket<strong>in</strong>g can be reduced through concentration <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> bundle <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> and assign<strong>in</strong>g it to aspecific <strong>in</strong>dividual or corporation. This is especially true where exist<strong>in</strong>g organizational capacity is<strong>in</strong>sufficient to ensure susta<strong>in</strong>able commodity production and market<strong>in</strong>g.A case from Cameroon illustrates both <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> “potentialdevelopments” that arise when lucrative market<strong>in</strong>centives become available which significantly deviatefrom <strong>the</strong> conventional uses, or scale <strong>of</strong> use <strong>of</strong> a <strong>natural</strong><strong>resource</strong> stock, or both. First, forest dwell<strong>in</strong>gcommunities were not <strong>in</strong> a position to <strong>in</strong>vest and benefitfrom <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational market for timber. Given <strong>the</strong>powerful <strong>in</strong>centives aris<strong>in</strong>g from sizeable potentialpr<strong>of</strong>its, <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> to forest <strong>resource</strong>s werechallenged (or perhaps more accurately, ignored) by thosewith <strong>the</strong> means to fell trees and move <strong>the</strong>m <strong>in</strong>to lucrativedomestic and <strong>in</strong>ternational timber markets. Second, <strong>rights</strong>to trees exploited for marketable timber, and <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>comefrom <strong>the</strong> trees, became <strong>the</strong> exclusive right <strong>of</strong> those whowere will<strong>in</strong>g and able to make <strong>the</strong> necessary <strong>in</strong>vestments.In <strong>the</strong> process, <strong>the</strong> bundle <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> wasconsolidated as a s<strong>in</strong>gle strand with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> bundle—that toharvest trees to supply <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational market fortimber—came to dom<strong>in</strong>ate and dim<strong>in</strong>ished all o<strong>the</strong>r<strong>rights</strong>. The example illustrates a strik<strong>in</strong>g disconnectbetween exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>digenous forestdwellers and <strong>the</strong> usurpation <strong>of</strong> those <strong>rights</strong> necessary torespond to market <strong>in</strong>centives aris<strong>in</strong>g from a nontraditionalmarket. Disregard for exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>rights</strong> <strong>of</strong> forestdwell<strong>in</strong>g populations, motivated by powerful market<strong>in</strong>centives, has wrought damage both to livelihoods <strong>of</strong>local populations and to <strong>the</strong> environment.Box 5. Manag<strong>in</strong>g Market IncentivesIn Cameroon, forest-dwell<strong>in</strong>g communities areamong <strong>the</strong> most marg<strong>in</strong>alized groups <strong>in</strong> society,and massive timber exploitation has brought<strong>the</strong>m few benefits. Sixty-six percent <strong>of</strong>Cameroon’s population <strong>in</strong> forest areas livesbelow <strong>the</strong> poverty l<strong>in</strong>e. One option forcommunities to ga<strong>in</strong> greater benefit is tosubcontract commercial timber operators toexploit <strong>the</strong> forest but this exposes <strong>the</strong> enterpriseto elite capture, with negative environmentalconsequences (as logg<strong>in</strong>g operators may try torecoup <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>in</strong>vestments by rapidly cream<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong>fall <strong>the</strong> trees with marketable value). Isolated casestudies suggest that communities could earnsubstantial <strong>in</strong>comes from forests if <strong>the</strong>y tookcontrol <strong>of</strong> harvest<strong>in</strong>g and process<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>mselves.This, however, requires organizational andtechnical skills far beyond <strong>the</strong> usual capacity <strong>of</strong>local communities, and might also requiregovernments to provide safety nets forcommunities which get <strong>in</strong>to difficulties (ODI2002).The Cameroon case illustrates <strong>the</strong> challenge <strong>of</strong> manag<strong>in</strong>g and channel<strong>in</strong>g market <strong>in</strong>centives that, leftunchecked, can aggravate unequal distributions <strong>of</strong> wealth and impair <strong>the</strong> capacity <strong>of</strong> some actors to ga<strong>in</strong>livelihoods, as well as cause environmental degradation (see Box 5). While this example features forest<strong>resource</strong>s, similar examples <strong>of</strong> market <strong>in</strong>centives be<strong>in</strong>g allowed free re<strong>in</strong> have occurred <strong>in</strong> a variety <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong><strong>resource</strong> sett<strong>in</strong>gs rang<strong>in</strong>g from fisheries to watersheds, pastures, and agricultural lands. Efforts to alleviate <strong>the</strong>adverse impacts <strong>of</strong> unmanaged market <strong>in</strong>centives have focused on recogniz<strong>in</strong>g and streng<strong>the</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g local actors<strong>in</strong> relation to non-resident entrepreneurs who are considered to have less <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> address<strong>in</strong>g local welfareconcerns and ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>resource</strong>s over <strong>the</strong> long term. Closely allied sets <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>itiatives <strong>in</strong>clude those target<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>creased popular participation <strong>in</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> governance and <strong>management</strong>, decentralization anddevolution <strong>of</strong> power and authority <strong>the</strong>se <strong>resource</strong>s, and re<strong>in</strong>forcement <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> concept and practice <strong>of</strong>commonly held <strong>property</strong>.Although common <strong>property</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s is most <strong>of</strong>ten a prom<strong>in</strong>ent feature <strong>of</strong> customary tenuresystems, it has proven difficult to defend <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> face <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>tense market <strong>in</strong>centives coupled with governmentpolicies that are not supportive <strong>of</strong> common <strong>property</strong> regimes. The lead<strong>in</strong>g tool <strong>in</strong> mak<strong>in</strong>g exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>rights</strong>defensible is to channel <strong>the</strong> market <strong>in</strong>centives to <strong>the</strong> resident populations. Complementary tools <strong>in</strong>cludeROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 19


modification <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> policy environment to recognize local <strong>rights</strong>, and strength technical and organizationalcapabilities <strong>of</strong> local populations so that <strong>the</strong>y can participate <strong>in</strong> susta<strong>in</strong>able production, process<strong>in</strong>g, andmarket<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> based commodities.The retention and defense <strong>of</strong> common <strong>property</strong> hold<strong>in</strong>gs based on market uses <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s requiresanalysis and redef<strong>in</strong>ition <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> distribution <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> strands <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> bundle. Suchredef<strong>in</strong>ition is a prerogative <strong>of</strong> local authority structures, but a fur<strong>the</strong>r challenge arises from <strong>the</strong> fact that suchstructures are not monolithic. It is already difficult to secure coveted <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> to marketable <strong>resource</strong>sfor geographically def<strong>in</strong>ed populations, but even that is just <strong>the</strong> first stage. The second stage is for <strong>the</strong> def<strong>in</strong>edpopulations to work out distributions <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong> and benefits among <strong>the</strong>mselves, that both take account <strong>of</strong> allcategories <strong>of</strong> stakeholders as def<strong>in</strong>ed by gender, ethnicity, and age and foster stewardship <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>sand promote susta<strong>in</strong>able use practices.Box 6. The Struggle to Graduate from Stage OneIn 1989 a forest <strong>management</strong> cooperative was established <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Baban Rafi Forest, Niger, as part <strong>of</strong> an<strong>in</strong>ternationally funded forest <strong>management</strong> <strong>in</strong>itiative. In addition to <strong>the</strong> many uses <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> forest and forestproducts by local residents, <strong>the</strong> Baban Rafi Forest served as a large reserve <strong>of</strong> fuelwood marketed <strong>in</strong>neighbor<strong>in</strong>g urban centers, particularly <strong>the</strong> regional capital <strong>of</strong> Maradi. The fuelwood trade was at that timecontrolled by Maradi-based entrepreneurs who harvested wood through a mix <strong>of</strong> local and imported labor.The project design targeted transfer <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> to trees and o<strong>the</strong>r forest <strong>resource</strong>s to localcooperative. Dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> project this transfer succeeded partially, but mostly <strong>in</strong> de facto terms (that is, withsupport from <strong>the</strong> project and local government). The transfer never atta<strong>in</strong>ed a de jure status. Dur<strong>in</strong>g itsearly years, <strong>the</strong> project focused heavily on secur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> benefits <strong>of</strong> fuelwood trade for local populations.The experiment to transfer market <strong>in</strong>centives to <strong>the</strong> local populations <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> vic<strong>in</strong>ity <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Baban RafiForest turned out to be a more complicated task than a simple transfer <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> from state(which formally held de jure <strong>rights</strong> to most forests and trees <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> country) to local populations. Thecooperative was composed <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>habitants <strong>of</strong> seven villages with diverse histories, as well as severalherd<strong>in</strong>g/farm<strong>in</strong>g settlements <strong>in</strong>habited by a different ethnic group. Although a portion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> local populationwas <strong>in</strong>deed <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> secur<strong>in</strong>g revenues from <strong>the</strong> fuelwood trade, o<strong>the</strong>rs were more <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong>reta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g or expand<strong>in</strong>g access to pasture <strong>resource</strong>s, while still o<strong>the</strong>rs were primarily attracted by <strong>the</strong>prospect <strong>of</strong> tapp<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to reserves with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> forest <strong>of</strong> potentially productive lands for agriculture. Whileeach population segment enjoyed recognized sets <strong>of</strong> access and use <strong>rights</strong> regard<strong>in</strong>g specific forest<strong>resource</strong>s and zones, participation <strong>in</strong> cooperative <strong>management</strong> and activities came disproportionately fromspecific <strong>in</strong>terest blocs, with compet<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terest blocs rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g alo<strong>of</strong>. In addition, <strong>the</strong> exclusively malecooperative leadership struggled with <strong>the</strong> question <strong>of</strong> how revenues from fuelwood sales, still quite m<strong>in</strong>imal,would be utilized or distributed (from Elbow, 1994; and a subsequent visit to <strong>the</strong> site <strong>in</strong> 1995).The struggle to get past Stage One (a policy change) and truly arrive at Stage Two (a function<strong>in</strong>g and selfsufficientsystem for group <strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> to marketable <strong>resource</strong>s) as illustrated by BabanRafi Forest Cooperative (Box 6), is a struggle that has been repeated <strong>in</strong> countless <strong>in</strong>terventions seek<strong>in</strong>g tosecure market <strong>in</strong>centives for local populations <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>of</strong> enhanc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir revenues and improv<strong>in</strong>ggovernance and <strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s. In part <strong>the</strong> constra<strong>in</strong>t is <strong>the</strong> result <strong>of</strong> disconnect betweenlimited project cycles and a long-term need for consensus and <strong>in</strong>stitution build<strong>in</strong>g. But perhaps <strong>the</strong> constra<strong>in</strong>tcould also be alleviated through reduced complexity and less ambition. In <strong>the</strong> Souti Yanfou Forest <strong>of</strong> Gu<strong>in</strong>ea,<strong>the</strong> non-local market for game has motivated hunters from ano<strong>the</strong>r part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> country to overexploit localwildlife <strong>resource</strong>s. In response, with <strong>the</strong> aid <strong>of</strong> an <strong>in</strong>ternationally f<strong>in</strong>anced <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> <strong>management</strong>program, a local hunter’s association was established to assert <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> over forest wildlife, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong> right to exclude outsiders. Although new, <strong>the</strong> clear def<strong>in</strong>ition and targeted focus <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> association’smandate encourage optimism that Stage Two <strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong> will be consolidated (Carter, 2004;document and personal communications).20 ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR


See Child (2005) for examples <strong>of</strong> relatively successful cases <strong>of</strong> transition from Stage One to Stage Two <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>context <strong>of</strong> wildlife <strong>management</strong> <strong>in</strong> sou<strong>the</strong>rn Africa.3.2.2 Harmoniz<strong>in</strong>g with Government Policies—Focus on Devolution/DecentralizationDecentralization refers simply to a shift <strong>of</strong> (<strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> <strong>management</strong>) authority from central to localgovernments. However <strong>the</strong> implications <strong>of</strong> decentralization for <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> to <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s at <strong>the</strong>local level are crucial. First, decentralization <strong>in</strong>itiatives have led to clarification and secur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>for local users. Most cases <strong>of</strong> decentralization <strong>in</strong>volve identification and boundary del<strong>in</strong>eation <strong>of</strong> lands ando<strong>the</strong>r <strong>resource</strong>s used as collective properties (Oviedo, 2002). The physical extent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>rights</strong> can <strong>the</strong>n berecorded <strong>in</strong> government registers, and <strong>rights</strong> <strong>of</strong> use groups <strong>of</strong> def<strong>in</strong>ed common <strong>property</strong> legally recognized.Box 7. Clos<strong>in</strong>g Open Access AreasThrough DecentralizationIn <strong>the</strong> Philipp<strong>in</strong>es, a USAID-supported CoastalResource Management Program supportedrehabilitation <strong>of</strong> abandoned and underutilizedmangroves through fishpond lease agreementsprovided to local communities. The localgovernment units (prov<strong>in</strong>cial and municipallevel government agencies) signed leases withlocal communities, secur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>ir access <strong>rights</strong>to mangrove <strong>resource</strong>s <strong>the</strong>reby provid<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong>se communities <strong>in</strong>centives for effectivemonitor<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> this open access <strong>resource</strong>(CRMP 2003).Such clarification <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong> serves to reduce conflictsaris<strong>in</strong>g from unclear <strong>rights</strong>. Second, decentralizationprograms have re<strong>in</strong>forced <strong>management</strong> <strong>rights</strong>, and thus<strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> users. For example,under decentralization programs, local forest councils (<strong>in</strong>some cases newly formed) have been given authority tomanage commonly held land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s.While under most decentralization <strong>in</strong>itiatives local villagecouncils are expected to work with local governments <strong>in</strong>decision mak<strong>in</strong>g, creation <strong>of</strong> rules <strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong> use, or <strong>in</strong>o<strong>the</strong>r cases monitor<strong>in</strong>g and enforcement, <strong>in</strong> many casescritical use and decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>rights</strong> are formallydevolved to local communities. In o<strong>the</strong>r cases yet,decentralization programs have been designed to closeopen access situations, as for <strong>in</strong>stance <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> donorsupported Philipp<strong>in</strong>es Coastal Resources ManagementProgram (see Box 7). Third, decentralization programs have streng<strong>the</strong>ned <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> throughclarification <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong> characteristics, such as specification <strong>of</strong> a time frame. Although, <strong>the</strong> precise nature <strong>of</strong>newly def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>rights</strong> to <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> commons, specifically duration <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>, vary fromcountry to country. In some cases <strong>rights</strong> have been granted for an <strong>in</strong>def<strong>in</strong>ite period, as for <strong>in</strong>stance<strong>in</strong>digenous <strong>rights</strong> <strong>in</strong> Brazil (Oviedo, 2002). In o<strong>the</strong>r cases, decentralization and devolution efforts haveresulted <strong>in</strong> short (five year) or long-term leases. Ano<strong>the</strong>r important feature is that a def<strong>in</strong>ed process forrenewal generally accompanies <strong>the</strong> fixed time period. Despite variations, clarification <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>characteristics and processes that may accompany <strong>the</strong> process <strong>of</strong> decentralization or devolution have helpedto secure local level <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>, as expectations come to be standardized and shared between local andgovernment actors. Fourth, <strong>in</strong> most cases, decentralization has resulted <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> development <strong>of</strong> means foradjudicat<strong>in</strong>g disputes related to <strong>the</strong>se <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> where such mechanisms did not already exist.Decentralization <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, and <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>creased security afforded by <strong>the</strong>se <strong>rights</strong>, have providedcritical <strong>in</strong>centives for local communities to manage <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>resource</strong>s susta<strong>in</strong>ably and <strong>in</strong> many cases to enhance<strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir assets. As noted <strong>in</strong> previous section, a number <strong>of</strong> key challenges rema<strong>in</strong>. Marg<strong>in</strong>al groupsand (<strong>in</strong> many cases) women cont<strong>in</strong>ue to lack equitable use <strong>rights</strong> or decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g powers. This is ma<strong>in</strong>lybecause long-stand<strong>in</strong>g local <strong>in</strong>stitutions have been <strong>in</strong>ternally <strong>in</strong>equitable, leav<strong>in</strong>g women and specific ethnic oreconomic groups out <strong>of</strong> decision mak<strong>in</strong>g. 15 Decentralization and boundary demarcation br<strong>in</strong>gs concepts <strong>of</strong>15Me<strong>in</strong>zen-Dick et al. (1997) provide useful analysis on gender differences <strong>in</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> and control <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, and <strong>in</strong> particular,barriers that limit women’s <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>. These barriers <strong>in</strong> access<strong>in</strong>g land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s may be explicit (e.g., legislationprevent<strong>in</strong>g women’s ability to <strong>in</strong>herit or transfer land); however, numerous less explicit constra<strong>in</strong>ts limit women’s control and access toland and <strong>resource</strong>s. Some examples <strong>in</strong>clude restrictions on women’s participation <strong>in</strong> local <strong>in</strong>stitutions (such as village councils) responsiblefor governance <strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong> use, ei<strong>the</strong>r due to social norms that limit women’s place to private doma<strong>in</strong> or due to time constra<strong>in</strong>ts l<strong>in</strong>kedwith responsibilities for domestic chores; limited access to education and <strong>in</strong>formation; or limited access to money to acquire credit and<strong>in</strong>vestments.ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 21


exclusive <strong>rights</strong> to <strong>resource</strong>s, <strong>of</strong>ten giv<strong>in</strong>g preference to settled agriculturalists over pastoralists. These<strong>in</strong>itiatives have also given preference to primary right holders over secondary users that may reside far<strong>the</strong>raway from <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong>. In some cases, community leaders have participated <strong>in</strong> corrupt deals to advancepersonal <strong>in</strong>terests. In o<strong>the</strong>r cases decentralization has placed an <strong>in</strong>creased burden on local communitieswithout provid<strong>in</strong>g additional <strong>rights</strong> (such as requir<strong>in</strong>g regular forest <strong>management</strong> plans). F<strong>in</strong>ally, wherecustomary <strong>rights</strong> to a <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> spill across village boundaries, devolution target<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> village level canhave unanticipated consequences, as illustrated <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> proposed community forest for <strong>the</strong> village <strong>of</strong> Kw<strong>in</strong>ellaNya Kunda (Box 8).Box 8. Challenges Rema<strong>in</strong>In <strong>the</strong> 1990s Gambia’s forestry Department, with technical assistance from <strong>the</strong> German government,began a program to establish as series <strong>of</strong> community forests. When <strong>the</strong> village <strong>of</strong> Kw<strong>in</strong>ella Nya Kundaselected a five square kilometer area with<strong>in</strong> its territory as <strong>the</strong> location for a community forest, <strong>the</strong>neighbor<strong>in</strong>g villages <strong>of</strong> Taba Nani and Mad<strong>in</strong>a Anglais strongly objected. As stated by <strong>the</strong> Alkalo <strong>of</strong> TabaNani, we have more than 1,000 cattle which have traditionally grazed <strong>in</strong> this area. The borehole for our cattle is<strong>the</strong>re [<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> area <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> proposed community forest]. Our cattle track is <strong>the</strong>re. This is very serious. We arewill<strong>in</strong>g to fight to preserve our access to this graz<strong>in</strong>g area. We have no o<strong>the</strong>r choice because to our west is MutaroForest Park and to our south is <strong>the</strong> Casamance [Senegal] (M’Boge and Sheehan, 1995, p.63).3.2.3 Build<strong>in</strong>g on Customary Property Rights RegimesThroughout Africa and much <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> non-Western world, village-level customary <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regimesreveal sophisticated land and <strong>resource</strong> tenure systems. Local tenure regimes are <strong>of</strong>ten made to adapt ormodify <strong>the</strong>mselves <strong>in</strong> reaction to (or defend <strong>the</strong>mselves from) national policies, but by and large <strong>property</strong><strong>rights</strong> rema<strong>in</strong> based on, or derived from, customary practices.Examples <strong>of</strong> elaborate local <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems abound <strong>in</strong> Gu<strong>in</strong>ea and elsewhere. For <strong>in</strong>stance, <strong>in</strong>Sogoloou village <strong>of</strong> Gu<strong>in</strong>ea’s Forest Region, ownership <strong>of</strong> arable land for cultivation <strong>of</strong> upland rice is sharedamong three clans (Fischer, 1995). Yet production decisions, such as number and location <strong>of</strong> parcelscultivated <strong>in</strong> a given year (regardless <strong>of</strong> ownership), are <strong>the</strong> prerogative <strong>of</strong> a council <strong>of</strong> elders that isrepresentative <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> three clans <strong>in</strong> proportion to <strong>the</strong>ir respective populations and historical importance <strong>in</strong>establish<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> village. No village, clan, or member has <strong>the</strong> right to transfer ei<strong>the</strong>r use <strong>rights</strong> or ownership<strong>rights</strong> to an outside party without <strong>the</strong> consent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> council <strong>of</strong> elders (consent which researchers reportedwould not be considered <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> foreseeable future). Beyond <strong>the</strong> rice-produc<strong>in</strong>g agricultural lands is a r<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong>multipurpose <strong>resource</strong>s dom<strong>in</strong>ated by palm, fruit, and o<strong>the</strong>r species <strong>of</strong> trees. Here too, use <strong>rights</strong> are strictlydef<strong>in</strong>ed regard<strong>in</strong>g, for example, <strong>the</strong> exact date on which specified groups (sometimes def<strong>in</strong>ed by sex, age, orpr<strong>of</strong>ession such as blacksmith or healer) and <strong>in</strong>dividuals may beg<strong>in</strong> to harvest palm oil or w<strong>in</strong>e, or collectfruits or honey. Pastur<strong>in</strong>g livestock is also tightly regulated. Certa<strong>in</strong> forested areas are designated as <strong>of</strong>f-limitsto all but a select group <strong>of</strong> traditional healers and rites managers, except dur<strong>in</strong>g precisely timed and entrycontrolledrituals such as <strong>in</strong>itiation rites. Any deviation from exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>rights</strong> and uses must come from <strong>the</strong>council <strong>of</strong> elders that is entrusted with <strong>the</strong> governance <strong>of</strong> village land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s.Variations <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Sogoloou model, which features a cohesive and coherent local system <strong>of</strong> land and <strong>resource</strong>tenure, are found <strong>in</strong> rural areas <strong>of</strong> non-Western countries. However, <strong>the</strong> tenure system <strong>in</strong> Sogoloou is more<strong>in</strong>tact than most customary tenure systems fac<strong>in</strong>g challenges from <strong>in</strong>compatible national policies, oreconomic and market developments and trends. It is strik<strong>in</strong>g that Sogoloou is able to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>stitutions, consist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> customary authority systems such as <strong>the</strong> council <strong>of</strong> elders and extended familyheads, necessary for enforcement <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> rules. Ano<strong>the</strong>r strik<strong>in</strong>g feature at Sogoloou is <strong>the</strong>community’s control over non-land renewable <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s such as trees and pastures.22 ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR


It is precisely ownership and <strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> non-land <strong>resource</strong>s that have been <strong>the</strong> most challenged bygovernment policies <strong>in</strong> much <strong>of</strong> West Africa. France imposed laws <strong>in</strong> her West African colonies assert<strong>in</strong>gstate control <strong>of</strong> all <strong>resource</strong>s that did not lend <strong>the</strong>mselves to <strong>in</strong>dividual possession and control, such asstreams, aquifers, pastures, m<strong>in</strong>eral <strong>resource</strong>s, and forests. For example, France <strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>the</strong> first forestcode for West Africa <strong>in</strong> 1935 which established pr<strong>in</strong>ciples such as lists <strong>of</strong> protected species <strong>of</strong> trees, andforest reserves with<strong>in</strong> which preexist<strong>in</strong>g popular use <strong>rights</strong> are circumscribed and ownership <strong>rights</strong> become<strong>the</strong> exclusive reserve <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> state. Such policies, reta<strong>in</strong>ed and usually re<strong>in</strong>forced by most post-<strong>in</strong>dependencegovernments, make it difficult for customary-based common <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> and <strong>the</strong>ir enforcement<strong>in</strong>stitutions to successfully defend <strong>property</strong> claims and <strong>management</strong> prerogatives (Elbow and Rochegude,1990).Compound<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> challenge posed to customary common <strong>property</strong> is <strong>the</strong> French <strong>in</strong>stitutional tradition <strong>of</strong>land legislation, dat<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>the</strong> earliest years <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> twentieth century, which couples <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>ciples <strong>of</strong> vacanteet sans maître and mise en valeur. The former pr<strong>in</strong>ciple declares that un<strong>in</strong>habited and unused land belongs to <strong>the</strong>state (<strong>the</strong> vast majority <strong>of</strong> land dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> relatively underpopulated colonial period); and <strong>the</strong> latter pr<strong>in</strong>ciplestipulates <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> to land have validity only where <strong>the</strong> land is put to productive use. Given that <strong>the</strong>lead<strong>in</strong>g productive use (mise en valeur) <strong>of</strong> land <strong>in</strong> more humid areas <strong>of</strong> West Africa was crop cultivation, thisspecific use <strong>of</strong> land, which carried <strong>the</strong> benefits <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> claims recognized by customary and statutory<strong>rights</strong> systems alike, was fur<strong>the</strong>r enforced.As are many customary <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems concern<strong>in</strong>g both land and non-land <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s,Sogoloou’s tenure system reta<strong>in</strong>s a high priority on susta<strong>in</strong>able use <strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s. In Sogoloou, rice cultivationlocations are selected annually (rotated) with <strong>the</strong> goal <strong>of</strong> prevent<strong>in</strong>g overuse <strong>of</strong> fragile soils. Systems forrotation between rice and o<strong>the</strong>r crops, as well as fallow periods, are ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>ed to keep <strong>the</strong> soils fertile. Use<strong>of</strong> palm and fruit trees, pasture, and water sources all fall under <strong>the</strong> authority <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> same <strong>in</strong>stitutions, whichmanage <strong>the</strong>m to achieve <strong>the</strong> same susta<strong>in</strong>ability goals.The challenge is how to capitalize on <strong>the</strong> exist<strong>in</strong>g diverse customary <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> context <strong>of</strong>targeted <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> and developmental goals. The short answer is, with caution. This is becausecustomary systems are not only difficult for <strong>the</strong> outsider to grasp, but <strong>the</strong>y are also mov<strong>in</strong>g targets s<strong>in</strong>ce thoseresponsible for manag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m constantly f<strong>in</strong>e-tune <strong>the</strong>m to accommodate chang<strong>in</strong>g political, economic, andecological conditions. Customary <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems, moreover, <strong>of</strong>ten enjoy a near monopoly onlegitimacy <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> eyes <strong>of</strong> local users, and <strong>the</strong>refore should not be ignored. A productive strategy to supportvaluable local <strong>in</strong>stitutional capital <strong>in</strong>volves <strong>in</strong>corporat<strong>in</strong>g enabl<strong>in</strong>g frameworks <strong>in</strong>to statutory land tenuresystems that allow flexibility <strong>of</strong> customary systems.It is worth highlight<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> this regard that customary systems <strong>of</strong>ten <strong>in</strong>volve local-level decision makersaccustomed to ga<strong>the</strong>r<strong>in</strong>g and process<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation from <strong>the</strong>ir environments and <strong>the</strong>n apply<strong>in</strong>g it to adjustthose systems on an as-needed basis. Central governments can shed <strong>the</strong> burden <strong>of</strong> modify<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutionalarrangements to sets <strong>of</strong> local-level decision makers, most <strong>of</strong> whom have strong <strong>in</strong>centives (e.g., concern for<strong>the</strong> welfare <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir children and grandchildren) to keep customary systems “healthy.” This can free up central<strong>resource</strong>s to (i) provide extension support to actors <strong>in</strong> customary systems so that <strong>the</strong>y can cont<strong>in</strong>ue toenhance/preserve <strong>the</strong>ir production systems; and (ii) provide modest but regular supervision to countertemptations (to which local elites might succumb) to modify customary systems over time <strong>in</strong> ways thatpr<strong>in</strong>cipally benefit <strong>the</strong>ir children and grandchildren at <strong>the</strong> expense <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rs’ <strong>of</strong>fspr<strong>in</strong>g. Note that devolv<strong>in</strong>gauthority for adjust<strong>in</strong>g customary systems to local decision makers engaged <strong>in</strong> those systems radically reduces<strong>the</strong> transaction costs which o<strong>the</strong>rwise <strong>of</strong>ten serve as powerful impediments to timely adaptation.There are two general approaches to build<strong>in</strong>g on customary systems: wholesale formalization <strong>of</strong> exist<strong>in</strong>g<strong>rights</strong>; or a phased, monitored, and managed series <strong>of</strong> encounters between formal and <strong>in</strong>formal systems. Thelong-stand<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>itiative <strong>in</strong> Niger to elaborate a comprehensive Rural Code based on customary <strong>rights</strong>represents <strong>the</strong> former approach. Launched <strong>in</strong> 1985, <strong>the</strong> code’s framework was enacted <strong>in</strong>to law <strong>in</strong> 1993. In <strong>the</strong>meantime <strong>the</strong>re was much jockey<strong>in</strong>g for position among customary <strong>rights</strong> claimants once <strong>the</strong> word was outthat <strong>rights</strong> were to be frozen (Lund, 1995). Groups with privileged access to power, education, or <strong>in</strong>formationROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 23


positioned <strong>the</strong>mselves to prepare for formalization <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir <strong>property</strong> claims vis-à-vis compet<strong>in</strong>g groups. The<strong>in</strong>itiative has stalled several times <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> face <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> complex technological, f<strong>in</strong>ancial and o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>resource</strong>requirements to fully implement a system to formalize customary <strong>rights</strong>. At <strong>the</strong> same time conflicts surfacedbased on <strong>the</strong> multiple claims <strong>in</strong>herent <strong>in</strong> most customary systems. While potentially laudable undertak<strong>in</strong>g, itcould also be argued that Niger’s Rural Code process is both overly ambitious and somewhat misguided <strong>in</strong>attempt<strong>in</strong>g a wholesale formalization multiple, overlapp<strong>in</strong>g and diverse <strong>property</strong> claims. That <strong>in</strong>itiative runs<strong>the</strong> risk <strong>of</strong> petrify<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> exist<strong>in</strong>g (or manipulated) pattern <strong>of</strong> land and <strong>resource</strong> <strong>rights</strong> by perhaps <strong>in</strong>advertently,driv<strong>in</strong>g up <strong>the</strong> transactions costs <strong>of</strong> adaptation. 16 If <strong>the</strong> only way to modify exist<strong>in</strong>g allocations <strong>of</strong> <strong>rights</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> face <strong>of</strong>chang<strong>in</strong>g economic, political and sociological circumstances (e.g., <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> HIV/AIDS pandemic) isto redo <strong>the</strong> Rural Code, <strong>the</strong>n this <strong>in</strong>itiative will very likely reduce flexibility <strong>in</strong> land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> tenurearrangements that might arguably be characterized as a s<strong>in</strong>e qua non <strong>of</strong> survival <strong>in</strong> a very harsh desert-edgeenvironment. These aspects are both complex and non-trivial. Program designers are advised to bear <strong>the</strong>se <strong>in</strong>m<strong>in</strong>d because failure to do so can wreak havoc with <strong>in</strong>stitutional arrangements that have helped generations<strong>of</strong> people survive <strong>in</strong> bleak, apparently impoverished environments across <strong>the</strong> globe.In contrast to Niger’s <strong>in</strong>itiative to produce a comprehensive Rural Code, a project supported effort <strong>in</strong> Gu<strong>in</strong>ea<strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>the</strong> concept and tool <strong>of</strong> written tenure contracts as a first step toward formalization <strong>of</strong> exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>rights</strong>between landowners and land borrowers. 17 In a completely voluntary program, <strong>in</strong>troduction <strong>of</strong> tenurecontracts was proposed on <strong>the</strong> assumption that it was <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>of</strong> both borrower and owner to def<strong>in</strong>eand formalize a lend<strong>in</strong>g period and any o<strong>the</strong>r conditions perta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g to <strong>the</strong> land loan. Often a landownerlacked <strong>the</strong> labor to work a piece <strong>of</strong> land but hesitated to run <strong>the</strong> risk <strong>of</strong> los<strong>in</strong>g historical ownership claims bylend<strong>in</strong>g parcels to those who could mobilize <strong>the</strong> required labor. The land borrower, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, wasusually borrow<strong>in</strong>g for an undef<strong>in</strong>ed period, and <strong>the</strong>refore could lose access follow<strong>in</strong>g any given grow<strong>in</strong>gseason. This practice discouraged <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> land and <strong>management</strong> efforts that would promote andconsolidate susta<strong>in</strong>able use practices. Project-supported leases were designed to permit any time periodmutually agreed upon by owner and borrower. The first years follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>troduction <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> leases formalizedtime periods <strong>of</strong> as little as five years, or <strong>in</strong> a few cases, one year. But each year <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> project, as participantsbecame used to <strong>the</strong> arrangement, <strong>the</strong> time periods leng<strong>the</strong>ned, and <strong>in</strong> some cases were specified for as long as99 years. A few pieces <strong>of</strong> land were even transferred <strong>in</strong> perpetuity. Note that <strong>the</strong> Gu<strong>in</strong>ea flexible contract<strong>in</strong>gexperience, by contrast with <strong>the</strong> Niger Rural Code <strong>in</strong>itiative, encouraged experimentation. Given <strong>the</strong> m<strong>in</strong>imaltransactions costs <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> adapt<strong>in</strong>g leases to <strong>in</strong>corporate longer terms as both lenders and borrowersga<strong>in</strong>ed familiarity with and confidence <strong>in</strong> this contractual arrangement, both sets <strong>of</strong> parties adapted leases <strong>in</strong>an appropriate manner to leng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> period <strong>of</strong> contractual commitment. This outcome is highlyappropriate: land borrowers now have <strong>the</strong> confidence to make productivity ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g or enhanc<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> leased parcels because <strong>the</strong>y have, with<strong>in</strong> a flexible leas<strong>in</strong>g structure, <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment securityengendered by a negotiated and contractually fixed period <strong>of</strong> control over <strong>the</strong> leased parcel. Owners, on <strong>the</strong>o<strong>the</strong>r side <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> arrangement, establish written pro<strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> title and achieve greater assurance that borrowerswill not run down but ra<strong>the</strong>r improve leased parcels because <strong>the</strong>y have compell<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>centives to do so. These resultswill need evaluation <strong>in</strong> a decade; at <strong>the</strong> moment <strong>the</strong>y suggest that appropriately flexible enabl<strong>in</strong>g frameworksproduce positive results for <strong>the</strong> labor-poor landowners, <strong>the</strong> landless but labor-rich, and <strong>the</strong> biophysical16France dur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>ter-war period employed ethnographers and anthropologists to ga<strong>the</strong>r data on and describe land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>tenure arrangements throughout its West African colonies. Many colonial adm<strong>in</strong>istrators seized on those studies as ways to cut through<strong>the</strong> complexity <strong>of</strong> customary systems without realiz<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> damage <strong>the</strong>y were do<strong>in</strong>g to customary tenure systems by stamp<strong>in</strong>g outflexibility <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> name <strong>of</strong> “certa<strong>in</strong>ty.”17The Expanded Natural Resources Management Activity (ENRMA) was implemented from September 1999 to September 2005. ENRMAwas f<strong>in</strong>anced by USAID and implemented by <strong>the</strong> Government <strong>of</strong> Gu<strong>in</strong>ea and W<strong>in</strong>rock International. The land tenure contract component<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> ENRMA built on earlier research conducted by <strong>the</strong> Land Tenure Center, University <strong>of</strong> Wiscons<strong>in</strong>-Madison.24 ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR


environment. These are significant achievements. Landowners and users “w<strong>in</strong>” as <strong>in</strong>dividuals but also derivecollective benefits from productive <strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> land. 18There are numerous benefits <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land tenure contracts: (i) <strong>the</strong> terms are solely at <strong>the</strong> discretion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>contract<strong>in</strong>g parties and not imposed by central authorities who are ostensibly promot<strong>in</strong>g development orenvironmental goals; (ii) <strong>the</strong>y are simple and clear; (iii) <strong>the</strong>y represent a step toward enhanced security <strong>in</strong> landhold<strong>in</strong>g (for both owners, whose historical <strong>rights</strong> are acknowledged, and borrowers, who have access toarable land for at least a guaranteed m<strong>in</strong>imum time period); and (iv) <strong>the</strong>y open <strong>the</strong> door for similarformalization between private parties wish<strong>in</strong>g to identify, have recognized and secure <strong>rights</strong> to a variety <strong>of</strong>land and o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> transactions.3.2.4 Balanc<strong>in</strong>g Equity and EfficiencySometimes solutions to <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> concerns present trade<strong>of</strong>fs between efficiency (<strong>the</strong> greatest socialvalue for <strong>the</strong> least social cost) and equity (relative distribution <strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s among <strong>in</strong>dividuals and groups,particularly socially disadvantaged and marg<strong>in</strong>alized groups). However, <strong>the</strong>se two sets <strong>of</strong> issues are not<strong>in</strong>herently <strong>in</strong> opposition to one ano<strong>the</strong>r, and <strong>in</strong> many cases appropriate enabl<strong>in</strong>g arrangements enhanceefficiency <strong>in</strong> land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> use while simultaneously address<strong>in</strong>g equity issues effectively.A debate that has long dom<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> discussion focuses on <strong>the</strong> efficiency and equityoutcomes <strong>of</strong> private or state <strong>property</strong> versus common <strong>property</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s. Many commentators argue thatprivate <strong>property</strong> or state control and managed regimes are more efficient than common <strong>property</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s(Hard<strong>in</strong>, 1968). To that end, private (<strong>in</strong>dividually) alienable <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> and market exchange have beenpromoted <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> belief that <strong>the</strong>se will enhance decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g powers for <strong>the</strong> <strong>rights</strong> holders, and thusprovide critical <strong>in</strong>centives to avoid <strong>in</strong>efficiencies <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> system. Common <strong>property</strong> regimes on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r handare <strong>of</strong>ten characterized as <strong>in</strong>efficient; as not provid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dividuals proper <strong>in</strong>centives to <strong>in</strong>vest and act <strong>in</strong> asocially efficient manner. Three ma<strong>in</strong> sources <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>efficiencies associated with common <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> havebeen identified (Ostrom, 2002): (i) rent dissipation, that is, <strong>in</strong>ability to capture value from communal use; (ii)high transaction costs <strong>of</strong> controll<strong>in</strong>g and exclud<strong>in</strong>g non-members, as well as enforcement costs <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong>devis<strong>in</strong>g, monitor<strong>in</strong>g and apply<strong>in</strong>g rules that encourage susta<strong>in</strong>able use; and (iii) low productivity, that is, lack<strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>centive to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> a <strong>resource</strong> or even to benefit from that <strong>resource</strong>. Ostrom ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>s that <strong>the</strong>se areproblems that all common <strong>property</strong> arrangements have to overcome.Careful analysis <strong>of</strong> common <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> suggests that where associated <strong>in</strong>stitutional arrangements arestrong, such <strong>rights</strong> can help achieve very high degrees <strong>of</strong> efficiency <strong>in</strong> use <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s. Indeed, wellfunction<strong>in</strong>gcommon <strong>property</strong> regimes are <strong>of</strong>ten characterized by high legitimacy, high levels <strong>of</strong> voluntarycompliance, low levels <strong>of</strong> disputes, resilience and ability to adapt to chang<strong>in</strong>g socioeconomic contexts—particularly sudden shocks such as droughts (McKean, 1992), as well as greater sense <strong>of</strong> equity <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong>distribution <strong>of</strong> benefits derived from <strong>resource</strong> (Gibbs and Bromley, 1989). Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>resource</strong>s such aspastures, where costs <strong>of</strong> monitor<strong>in</strong>g and enforcement may require extensive <strong>in</strong>vestments, group governancemay be more cost-effective than governance by <strong>in</strong>dividuals. 19 Moreover, rural poor <strong>in</strong> particular are heavilydependent on common <strong>property</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s for <strong>the</strong>ir livelihood. For <strong>the</strong>se communities, governance and<strong>management</strong> costs are <strong>of</strong>ten outweighed by benefits derived from govern<strong>in</strong>g and manag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong>(Hanna, 1995). Given repeated failures <strong>in</strong> <strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> state-owned <strong>resource</strong>s and <strong>in</strong> many cases excessiveexploitation <strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s by states, common <strong>property</strong> regimes provide relatively effective systems for<strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s and prevention <strong>of</strong> ecological degradation <strong>in</strong> specific circumstances.18For a more detailed discussion <strong>of</strong> formal recognition <strong>of</strong> customary <strong>rights</strong>, see Fitzpatrick (2005), Toulm<strong>in</strong> et al. (2002), and Toulm<strong>in</strong> andQuan (2000).19In arid pastures, <strong>in</strong> particular, where ra<strong>in</strong>fall patterns are unpredictable, divid<strong>in</strong>g common <strong>property</strong> pastures <strong>in</strong>to <strong>in</strong>dividual parcels maywell be doomed to failure. Extensive pastoral systems are <strong>of</strong>ten <strong>the</strong> only efficient production systems <strong>in</strong> such circumstances.ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 25


No clear pattern emerges regard<strong>in</strong>g distributional equity <strong>of</strong> various <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regimes. Private <strong>property</strong><strong>rights</strong> have, however, tended to favor elites and relatively privileged segments <strong>of</strong> society, lead<strong>in</strong>g to exclusion<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> socially disadvantaged from adequate <strong>resource</strong> access. State <strong>property</strong> has typically tended to excluderural communities from <strong>resource</strong> access. In some cases, state-ownership and privatization <strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s has ledto conflict as local communities attempt to ga<strong>in</strong> control over a <strong>resource</strong>. Inefficiencies due to <strong>in</strong>equitable<strong>resource</strong> distribution can rise dramatically <strong>in</strong> such <strong>in</strong>stances. Common <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> <strong>in</strong> many <strong>in</strong>stancesprovide rural communities access and control over critical <strong>resource</strong>s; yet <strong>resource</strong> governance and<strong>management</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutions (councils and user committees) <strong>in</strong> many cases do not represent users adequately, nordo <strong>the</strong>y share decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g powers or distribute benefits among members appropriately. Rural elitesdom<strong>in</strong>ate many local <strong>in</strong>stitutions and have traditionally excluded <strong>the</strong> poor and marg<strong>in</strong>alized from decisionmak<strong>in</strong>g and prevented fair distribution <strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s. Indeed, s<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>in</strong>stitutions are a reflection <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> socialsystem <strong>in</strong> which <strong>the</strong>y are embedded, <strong>in</strong>equities <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutional arrangements reflect social <strong>in</strong>equities <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>particular social unit.Arriv<strong>in</strong>g at solutions to <strong>natural</strong><strong>resource</strong> governance and<strong>management</strong> that promote bo<strong>the</strong>quity and efficiency is rarelysimple or without risk. Indeed,efforts to secure <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>for rural populations frequentlyfeature cases <strong>of</strong> distortedtransaction costs andmisallocation <strong>of</strong> benefits thatbenefit one group <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>population while fur<strong>the</strong>rmarg<strong>in</strong>aliz<strong>in</strong>g o<strong>the</strong>rs. But roomfor hope exists. Examples from<strong>the</strong> Brazilian Amazon (Box 9) andSenegal and Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso (Box10) <strong>in</strong> West Africa, suggest thatsite-specific factors can be criticalto rais<strong>in</strong>g or lower<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>transaction costs <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong>defend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> customary <strong>property</strong><strong>rights</strong> <strong>of</strong> secondary <strong>rights</strong> holders,and can thus decisively affect <strong>the</strong>equity outcomes <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>itiativesBox 9. Achiev<strong>in</strong>g Equity and Efficiency <strong>in</strong> Brazilian AmazonUnder Brazilian law, <strong>in</strong>digenous reserves are owned by <strong>the</strong> state.However, statutory law recognizes <strong>in</strong>digenous claims <strong>of</strong> exclusive,<strong>in</strong>def<strong>in</strong>ite use <strong>rights</strong> over land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>se reserves <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> respective <strong>in</strong>digenous groups. The law also provides authority to<strong>in</strong>digenous groups for governance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> reserves(Oviedo, 2002). Efficiency and equity outcomes <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>digenous systems <strong>in</strong>conservation are evident <strong>in</strong> a study <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>habited <strong>in</strong>digenous reserves andun<strong>in</strong>habited government protected areas <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Brazilian Amazonconducted by Nepstad et al. (2006). Satellite imagery <strong>of</strong> 149 reserves(121 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se <strong>in</strong>digenous reserves) and 15 government protected areasshow that <strong>the</strong>re was no significant difference <strong>in</strong> deforestation and forestfire losses between <strong>the</strong> two sets <strong>of</strong> areas, despite <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong><strong>in</strong>digenous reserves face greater pressures from colonization by non<strong>in</strong>digenouspopulations and agricultural expansion from outside <strong>of</strong><strong>in</strong>digenous reserves than do state protected areas <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> region.Indigenous lands account for five times as much area as that conta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong>government protected reserves <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> study area, yet <strong>in</strong>digenous<strong>in</strong>stitutions are effective <strong>in</strong> monitor<strong>in</strong>g and prevent<strong>in</strong>g encroachment.Policy enabl<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>habited reserves also promotes equity by enabl<strong>in</strong>g<strong>the</strong>se o<strong>the</strong>rwise marg<strong>in</strong>alized communities to derive <strong>the</strong>ir livelihoodsfrom secured access and control <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se reserves.target<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>creased efficiency. Among <strong>the</strong>se factors are state policies that favor primary <strong>rights</strong> holders(Senegal), and <strong>the</strong> capacity <strong>of</strong> secondary <strong>rights</strong> holders to organize <strong>the</strong>mselves <strong>in</strong> defense <strong>of</strong> a cause esteemedto be legitimate based on customary practices (Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso). Increased attention and care <strong>in</strong> deal<strong>in</strong>g withsuch factors can lead to more equitable outcomes.26 ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR


Box 10. Seek<strong>in</strong>g Equity and Efficiency: a Tricky Quest with a Potential Pay<strong>of</strong>fMany countries implement<strong>in</strong>g land reform policies favor sedentary communities and primary <strong>rights</strong>holders at <strong>the</strong> expense <strong>of</strong> pastoralists and holders <strong>of</strong> secondary <strong>rights</strong>. It was believed that secur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>rights</strong><strong>of</strong> settled agriculturalists would provide <strong>in</strong>centive for <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> farm<strong>in</strong>g, as well as access to credit,and hence promote agriculture-based economic growth. In Senegal, such land policies have secured <strong>rights</strong><strong>of</strong> settled farmers, while disenfranchis<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> pastoralists. Customary practices that allowed forcoexistence and socioeconomic relations characterized by reciprocity are be<strong>in</strong>g replaced by exclusivity.Traditionally, pastoralist <strong>rights</strong> to fodder were recognized, while farmers benefited from <strong>the</strong> manurederived from <strong>the</strong> livestock. At <strong>the</strong> same time, land policies and result<strong>in</strong>g titl<strong>in</strong>g and registration effortshave not led directly to improved access to rural credit, <strong>in</strong>creased farm productivity or economic growth.Meanwhile unrecognized and <strong>in</strong>secure pastoralist <strong>rights</strong> to pastures and rangelands are deteriorat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>toopen access situations, <strong>in</strong> some cases be<strong>in</strong>g encroached upon by farm<strong>in</strong>g (Traore, 2002).A more positive trend is seen <strong>in</strong> efforts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Sour<strong>in</strong>dow-Mihity pastoralist community <strong>in</strong> northwestBurk<strong>in</strong>a Faso that is attempt<strong>in</strong>g to take back greater control over rangelands threatened by damconstruction and clear<strong>in</strong>g by migrant farmers. The community has sought legal recognition <strong>of</strong> pastoralistassociations, developed rules govern<strong>in</strong>g access to and use <strong>of</strong> pastoral <strong>resource</strong>s, ensured equity <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong>form <strong>of</strong> access to non-member herders and women, developed <strong>in</strong>stitutional arrangements for monitor<strong>in</strong>gand enforcement <strong>of</strong> rules, and has actively worked to establish co-<strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se areas with <strong>the</strong>state (Sanou, 2002).It is important to note that various economic characteristics and attributes <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong> have implicationsfor <strong>the</strong> appropriateness <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regimes. For <strong>in</strong>stance, as Thomson (1992) notes, whe<strong>the</strong>r particular<strong>resource</strong> such as trees are most effectively held as private, public, or common <strong>property</strong> depends on how wellaccess to <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong> is controlled, and whe<strong>the</strong>r consumption <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong> is separable (between users), ornot. Based on <strong>the</strong>se criteria, <strong>resource</strong>s that are easily managed as private do not benefit under common orpublic <strong>property</strong> regimes, creat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>management</strong> difficulties and unnecessarily rais<strong>in</strong>g transaction costs <strong>of</strong>collectively manag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong>. However, where trees produce a public <strong>good</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong>environmental services, private control and <strong>management</strong> may result <strong>in</strong> overharvest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong>, <strong>the</strong>rebyunderm<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g public benefit. In such cases, a common <strong>property</strong> regime and associated transaction costs maywell be cost-effective.3.2.5 Enforcement <strong>of</strong> Property Rights <strong>in</strong> a Chang<strong>in</strong>g WorldRegardless <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regime, robust monitor<strong>in</strong>g and enforcement arrangements <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g asystem <strong>of</strong> penalties, is crucial to susta<strong>in</strong>able governance <strong>of</strong> any land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>, and appropriateenforcement <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>. Also necessary are reliable systems <strong>of</strong> dispute resolution <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> event that<strong>rights</strong> are challenged. These <strong>of</strong>ten require an enormous commitment <strong>of</strong> time and labor. Moreover, <strong>in</strong> areas,such as those governed by customary <strong>rights</strong>, where rules are flexible and prone to changes <strong>in</strong> space and time,and areas where numerous multiple <strong>rights</strong> may be associated with a s<strong>in</strong>gle unit <strong>of</strong> land, enforcement <strong>of</strong><strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> becomes even more challeng<strong>in</strong>g.There are three issues related to enforcement <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> which merit consideration: (i) mak<strong>in</strong>g rulesand clarify<strong>in</strong>g discrepancies <strong>in</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>; (ii) identify<strong>in</strong>g appropriate <strong>in</strong>stitutions (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dividuals orgroups) who hold <strong>rights</strong> and (perhaps o<strong>the</strong>rs that) bear responsibility for enforc<strong>in</strong>g those <strong>rights</strong>; and (iii)identify<strong>in</strong>g and assess<strong>in</strong>g transaction costs <strong>of</strong> mak<strong>in</strong>g, monitor<strong>in</strong>g, and enforc<strong>in</strong>g rules. Enforcement systemsrequire adaptability and flexibility to enable <strong>the</strong>m to adapt and respond to chang<strong>in</strong>g rules, conditions, andlocal contexts.A key aspect <strong>of</strong> enforcement is rule mak<strong>in</strong>g and limit<strong>in</strong>g ambiguity by develop<strong>in</strong>g clearly stated rules thatusers can follow and designated authorities can enforce. In many cases, ambiguity and conflict<strong>in</strong>g claims to<strong>resource</strong>s arise as a result <strong>of</strong> discrepancies between <strong>the</strong> customary and statutory rules. Clarity <strong>in</strong> rules isROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 27


achieved by resolv<strong>in</strong>g discrepancies regard<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> statutory-customary divide <strong>in</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> <strong>management</strong>through adjustment <strong>of</strong> statutory policies. Resolv<strong>in</strong>g such discrepancies <strong>in</strong> favor <strong>of</strong> customary arrangementsthat <strong>resource</strong> users and <strong>rights</strong> holders support, and progressively clarify<strong>in</strong>g rules <strong>of</strong> access to and use <strong>of</strong> landand o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s will gradually narrow opportunities for serious disputes over <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>.Of particular concern <strong>in</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> enforcement are transaction costs, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g costs <strong>of</strong> labor and timeneeded for rule mak<strong>in</strong>g, monitor<strong>in</strong>g compliance and enforc<strong>in</strong>g rules <strong>in</strong> cases <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>fraction. As noted above,<strong>the</strong> characteristic <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong> and terra<strong>in</strong> is an important factor <strong>in</strong> assess<strong>in</strong>g transaction costs. For<strong>in</strong>stance, it is <strong>of</strong>ten easier to monitor harvest<strong>in</strong>g activity on a lake than <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> middle <strong>of</strong> a forest, s<strong>in</strong>ce a s<strong>in</strong>glemonitor can see far<strong>the</strong>r across open water than through forested terra<strong>in</strong>. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, stationary <strong>resource</strong>ssuch as <strong>in</strong>dividual trees, v<strong>in</strong>es, and pastures are easier to monitor than mobile <strong>resource</strong>s such as birds <strong>in</strong>forests, fish <strong>in</strong> lakes and streams, and wildlife <strong>in</strong> watersheds, particularly migratory wildlife populations thateasily move across more than one <strong>in</strong>ternational or <strong>resource</strong> border. The more difficult it is to monitor a<strong>resource</strong>, <strong>the</strong> greater <strong>the</strong> risk <strong>of</strong> unauthorized activity and <strong>the</strong> harder (more costly) it is to establish robust<strong>in</strong>stitutional arrangements for monitor<strong>in</strong>g.States with large land hold<strong>in</strong>gs, large expanses <strong>of</strong> privately held lands, open water <strong>resource</strong>s (typically openaccess), and commonly held lands and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s may be particularly challeng<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>the</strong>se reasons.Where states are responsible for monitor<strong>in</strong>g and enforcement, lack <strong>of</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ances for monitor<strong>in</strong>g and resolv<strong>in</strong>gdisputes is <strong>of</strong>ten a critical obstacle to effective governance. Moreover, such <strong>of</strong>ficial systems <strong>of</strong>ten lend<strong>the</strong>mselves to corruption. Hybrid user/<strong>of</strong>ficial monitor<strong>in</strong>g and enforcement systems frequently prove lesscorrupt and more effective <strong>in</strong> dissuad<strong>in</strong>g or sanction<strong>in</strong>g illicit uses. Individuals hold<strong>in</strong>g private <strong>rights</strong> mayexperience similar problems <strong>of</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ancial constra<strong>in</strong>ts where large extents <strong>of</strong> lands are <strong>in</strong>volved. In many cases,community-based systems for commons <strong>management</strong> have been particularly effective <strong>in</strong> rule enforcement <strong>of</strong>relatively larger land areas, and have proved more effective than state or <strong>in</strong> some cases <strong>in</strong>dividual privatesystems. In common <strong>property</strong> systems, customary practices <strong>of</strong> monitor<strong>in</strong>g and enforcement typically <strong>in</strong>volveshar<strong>in</strong>g responsibility among members. In customary systems, social relations and associated sanctionsprovide strong dis<strong>in</strong>centives to violation <strong>of</strong> rules if monitor<strong>in</strong>g is effective. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, perceived legitimacy<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> customary systems lend for greater voluntary compliance, and lower<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> enforcement costs. Manyprograms <strong>the</strong>refore look to streng<strong>the</strong>n local <strong>in</strong>stitutions <strong>of</strong> governance, and community-based participatoryapproaches to monitor and resolve land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> related disputes. Such local alternatives are notmore compatible with customary rules and more accessible for local communities, but <strong>the</strong>y ease burden on<strong>the</strong> judicial court systems (FAO, 2002a).Disputes over <strong>resource</strong> use are typically resolved by village <strong>in</strong>stitutions and elected or appo<strong>in</strong>ted authoritiesparticularly where customary rules are <strong>in</strong>volved, and by formal courts <strong>in</strong> cases <strong>of</strong> statutory rule enforcement.Many o<strong>the</strong>r cases <strong>of</strong> disputes over <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> use are not brought to court, and may l<strong>in</strong>ger on or beresolved by local councils. Given that <strong>in</strong> some countries, particularly <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> post-conflict contexts as <strong>in</strong>Burundi and Rwanda, disputes over land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> account for approximately 80-90 percent <strong>of</strong>cases received <strong>in</strong> courts (ACTS 2005), dispute resolution problems should not be taken lightly. In <strong>the</strong>secountries formal court systems are overburdened, with <strong>in</strong>sufficient capacity to handle <strong>the</strong> numerous cases <strong>of</strong>disputes related to land and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s. A weak enforcement system casts doubt on <strong>the</strong> security <strong>of</strong><strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> and hence engenders dis<strong>in</strong>centives that dissuade people from engag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> susta<strong>in</strong>ablepractices.Gambia provides an <strong>in</strong>structive example. This country has made efforts to uphold a comprehensiveenforcement and dispute resolution network that respects customary law throughout <strong>the</strong> country, while at <strong>the</strong>same time advanc<strong>in</strong>g cautiously toward more formal laws and <strong>in</strong>stitutions. The 1990 District Tribunals Actestablished a tribunal for each district <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> country. Each tribunal is presided over by <strong>the</strong> district chief,known as <strong>the</strong> Seyfo, assisted by six or seven local residents whom he nom<strong>in</strong>ates. The district tribunals areempowered to ensure proper application and enforcement <strong>of</strong> customary and religious laws (Marong, 1994,p.7, emphasis is ours). Despite its mandate to base its decisions on customary laws, <strong>the</strong> tribunal courts wouldquickly be overwhelmed if it were not for <strong>the</strong> government-sanctioned and cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>g existence <strong>of</strong> a network28 ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR


<strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal enforcement and dispute resolution <strong>in</strong>stitutions that provide <strong>the</strong> bulk <strong>of</strong> dispute resolutionservices <strong>in</strong> Gambia, thus alleviat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> workload <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> tribunals. As noted by Marong:Dispute resolution <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> customary sett<strong>in</strong>g is not <strong>the</strong> exclusive doma<strong>in</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> DistrictTribunal. Several <strong>in</strong>formal systems exist with<strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> traditional system which operatesignificantly to curtail <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> cases that o<strong>the</strong>rwise <strong>the</strong> tribunals would have had tocope with…. These systems are not established by any statute or o<strong>the</strong>r law and <strong>the</strong>reforelack <strong>the</strong> b<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g legal force that characterizes <strong>the</strong> operation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> District Tribunals, yet <strong>the</strong>yhave been so fully and completely accepted by <strong>the</strong> traditional people that <strong>the</strong> effect has beenthat adjudication by <strong>the</strong> more formal judicial system has become a matter <strong>of</strong> last resort andcomes ma<strong>in</strong>ly when <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal mechanisms discussed hereunder have failed to work(p.13).The <strong>in</strong>formal dispute resolution <strong>in</strong>stitutions <strong>in</strong>clude family elders, <strong>the</strong> village Alkalo (traditional chief) and <strong>the</strong>local Imam (religious leader). While most disputes are typically resolved at this <strong>in</strong>formal level, <strong>in</strong> cases wheredisputes go beyond <strong>the</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal level to <strong>the</strong> district tribunal, rul<strong>in</strong>gs cont<strong>in</strong>ue to uphold customary laws. Forexample, among <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>ciples followed by <strong>the</strong> tribunals is that whenever <strong>the</strong>re is a dispute over ownership <strong>of</strong> land and<strong>the</strong>re are elderly people who know <strong>the</strong> tenure history <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land, <strong>the</strong>y are called to give evidence before <strong>the</strong> tribunal as to <strong>the</strong>question <strong>of</strong> ownership (p.15), as illustrated <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> example provided <strong>in</strong> Box 11.Box 11. Giv<strong>in</strong>g Legitimacy to Historical EvidenceThe Court attached significant weight to <strong>the</strong> evidence <strong>of</strong> a 90 year old witness who deposed that <strong>the</strong>defendant’s family were <strong>the</strong> orig<strong>in</strong>al clearers <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land <strong>in</strong> dispute and that he knew that defendant’s fa<strong>the</strong>rcultivated <strong>the</strong> disputed land up to his death and <strong>the</strong>reafter <strong>the</strong> defendant himself farmed it for over 30 years.The Court gave judgment for <strong>the</strong> defendant. This case illustrates not only <strong>the</strong> approach <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> DistrictTribunals to <strong>the</strong> evidence <strong>of</strong> particularly knowledgeable witnesses, but also <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>ciple that orig<strong>in</strong>alclear<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> virg<strong>in</strong> forest confers customary ownership <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land (Marong, p.15).District tribunals <strong>in</strong> Gambia also have authority to resolve disputes <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g non-land <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s.Often <strong>the</strong> tribunals must weigh established customary rules aga<strong>in</strong>st pr<strong>in</strong>ciples <strong>of</strong> fairness and <strong>in</strong> favor <strong>of</strong>compromise, as illustrated <strong>in</strong> Box 12.Box 12. Disputes Over Ownership <strong>of</strong> Planted TreesDisputes <strong>of</strong>ten arise over ownership <strong>of</strong> planted trees. As <strong>the</strong> Imam <strong>of</strong> Dumbutu related, when a man whohas planted a tree subsequently dies, ano<strong>the</strong>r person (possibly <strong>the</strong> owner <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> land) can assume <strong>the</strong>responsibility <strong>of</strong> water<strong>in</strong>g and car<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>the</strong> tree. If, after some time passes, <strong>the</strong> son <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> man who planted<strong>the</strong> tree claims ownership <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> tree, a dispute may arise <strong>in</strong> which <strong>the</strong> caretaker claims ownership <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>tree. As <strong>the</strong> imam <strong>of</strong> Dumbutu stated, customary law would uphold <strong>the</strong> ownership claim <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> son. The act<strong>of</strong> water<strong>in</strong>g and car<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>the</strong> tree does not confer <strong>rights</strong> <strong>of</strong> ownership over <strong>the</strong> tree. The son <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> treeplanter would <strong>in</strong>herit <strong>the</strong> ownership <strong>rights</strong> to <strong>the</strong> tree (M’Boge and Sheehan, 1995, p. 43).Cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>g challenges rema<strong>in</strong> however as customary systems experience socioeconomic transitions. Thisweakens social relations (and hence social sanctions), gives rise to labor shortages occasioned by male labormigration, and <strong>in</strong> turn poses a serious challenge for many rural communities <strong>in</strong> govern<strong>in</strong>g commonly held<strong>resource</strong>s. Given that local governance systems are <strong>of</strong>ten more effective and efficient, and typically moreadapted to chang<strong>in</strong>g needs aris<strong>in</strong>g from emerg<strong>in</strong>g land and labor markets, <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s markets, andenvironmental <strong>in</strong>itiatives and <strong>in</strong>terventions than are state systems, customary <strong>in</strong>stitutions can be assisted toadjust to <strong>the</strong> scale and methods, and to adapt to <strong>the</strong>se changes. A f<strong>in</strong>al example <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> adaptability andflexibility <strong>of</strong> customary dispute resolution systems also is provided by Gambia (Box 13). This k<strong>in</strong>d <strong>of</strong> equityROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 29


jurisprudence is common <strong>in</strong> African moots where <strong>of</strong>ficials frequently try to structure reasonablecompromises, and unreasonable or wasteful demands are rejected.Box 13. “My Trees, Your Land”This dispute was settled by <strong>the</strong> Upper Baddibu District Tribunal. The dispute <strong>in</strong>volved a landlord and atenant over a question <strong>of</strong> tree ownership. A member <strong>of</strong> a compound planted mango trees <strong>in</strong> his backyardbath<strong>in</strong>g area. For reasons unrelated to <strong>the</strong> tree plant<strong>in</strong>gs, relations between <strong>the</strong> compound head and thisparticular member deteriorated, and <strong>the</strong> member was asked to leave <strong>the</strong> compound. Upon leav<strong>in</strong>g, hedemanded compensation for his trees, a demand to which his ex-landlord could not concede. The expelledmember took his claim directly to <strong>the</strong> district tribunal. [Based on customary rules], [t]he district tribunalruled <strong>in</strong> favour <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> member seek<strong>in</strong>g compensation. The tribunal brought <strong>in</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>essional tree appraisers toassign a value to <strong>the</strong> trees and <strong>the</strong>n ordered <strong>the</strong> compound head to buy <strong>the</strong> trees from <strong>the</strong> expelledmember. However, <strong>the</strong> expelled member decided that he did not want to sell <strong>the</strong> trees. Instead, hedemanded that <strong>the</strong> tribunal restrict his ex-landlord from pick<strong>in</strong>g fruit from <strong>the</strong> trees. The tribunalquestioned whe<strong>the</strong>r this would be an acceptable [i.e., reasonable] solution. [In a modified decision], [t]hetribunal advised <strong>the</strong> tree owner to share his use <strong>rights</strong> with his ex-landlord, much to his dismay (M’Boge andSheehan, p.55).30 ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR


4.0 GENERAL PRINCIPLES FORINTEGRATING ANDREINFORCING PROPERTYRIGHTS IN NATURALRESOURCES GOVERNANCEAND MANAGEMENTWherever human populations <strong>in</strong>teract with <strong>the</strong> <strong>natural</strong> world, <strong>the</strong>y develop systems to organize and regulateaccess to and use <strong>of</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ite renewable <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s. Such organizational and regulatory systems respond toand <strong>in</strong>ternalize external economic, political and <strong>in</strong>stitutional environments, and <strong>in</strong>ternal social structures andproduction systems. To <strong>the</strong> extent that it is <strong>in</strong>tact and function<strong>in</strong>g, a <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> system determ<strong>in</strong>es <strong>the</strong>identity <strong>of</strong> legitimate <strong>resource</strong> users, and <strong>the</strong> scope and parameters for <strong>resource</strong> use, <strong>management</strong>, andtransfer. But as societies evolve, <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems face challenges and may vary widely <strong>in</strong> performanceand function<strong>in</strong>g. Moreover, a system <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> to <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s is just one among <strong>the</strong> manyfactors that affect susta<strong>in</strong>ability <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, <strong>in</strong>centives for wealth creation and empowerment <strong>of</strong> ruralpopulations. Thus <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems <strong>in</strong>fluence, and are <strong>in</strong>fluenced by, market <strong>in</strong>centives, governmentand project policies, technological developments, and local organizational capacities, as well as o<strong>the</strong>r factors.The <strong>in</strong>terplay between <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> and trends or developments tak<strong>in</strong>g place <strong>in</strong> any <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se areas canresult <strong>in</strong> unanticipated outcomes regard<strong>in</strong>g environmental, wealth and governance objectives.Application <strong>of</strong> a number <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>ciples is recommended to m<strong>in</strong>imize undesirable andunexpected outcomes to <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> <strong>in</strong>itiatives. These pr<strong>in</strong>ciples are identified as follows:1. Understand exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems before launch<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> program.Wherever stocks <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s exist, some type <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> system that governs—orattempts to govern—access, use, <strong>management</strong>, and transfer <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s nearly always exists.Information regard<strong>in</strong>g local <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> rules and <strong>the</strong>ir enforcement is usually fairly easy to come by.Questions posed to <strong>in</strong>dividuals who are observed act<strong>in</strong>g as <strong>resource</strong> users are a <strong>good</strong> place to start. Morethan one <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> system may be <strong>in</strong> operation at <strong>the</strong> same site, which may <strong>in</strong>clude seasonal <strong>rights</strong>(e.g., pastoralists). Often overlapp<strong>in</strong>g and perhaps compet<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems exist <strong>in</strong> relation to given<strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> set. It is important to recognize <strong>the</strong>se overlapp<strong>in</strong>g claims to land for <strong>the</strong> different strands<strong>of</strong> a bundle <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>, as well as communal <strong>rights</strong> to <strong>resource</strong>s.2. Recognize and build on customary <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>. In non-Western countries customary <strong>property</strong><strong>rights</strong> systems frequently reta<strong>in</strong> de facto or some cases de jure authority and <strong>in</strong>stitutions that cont<strong>in</strong>ue toregulate and enforce <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> related to local <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s. Customary <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems<strong>of</strong>ten reta<strong>in</strong> more coherence and legitimacy than compet<strong>in</strong>g systems and events. Whatever <strong>the</strong> orientation<strong>of</strong> national policies, customary practices rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> effect <strong>in</strong> many sett<strong>in</strong>gs. In addition, customary<strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systems are durable, exhibit<strong>in</strong>g desirable characteristics <strong>of</strong> flexibility and adaptability as <strong>the</strong>yevolve <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> face <strong>of</strong> chang<strong>in</strong>g economic, social, and political environments.ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 31


3. Be aware <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> characteristic flexibility <strong>of</strong> customary systems. Customary <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> systemsare flexible <strong>in</strong> time and space, and generally feature <strong>the</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> system that is adapted andadaptable to local ecological, social, cultural, economic, and political contexts. While legal recognition <strong>of</strong>customary systems can <strong>in</strong> many cases re<strong>in</strong>force security <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> and reduction <strong>of</strong> legal “grayareas,” detailed codification <strong>of</strong> a customary system can oversimplify and freeze rules at a po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> time thatnormally change over time, thus undercutt<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> subtleties and dynamism <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> system.4. Provide <strong>in</strong>centives for susta<strong>in</strong>able <strong>management</strong> to user groups by secur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>. Anappropriate <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regulatory system channels and enhances positive <strong>in</strong>centives for susta<strong>in</strong>ablegovernance and <strong>management</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s. Access to and use <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s should be clearly def<strong>in</strong>edand <strong>rights</strong> based, but will most appropriately be derived from—ra<strong>the</strong>r than a replacement <strong>of</strong>—exist<strong>in</strong>g<strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> rules and <strong>in</strong>stitutions.5. Where possible, clarify <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>, reduc<strong>in</strong>g (potential) conflict over land and <strong>natural</strong><strong>resource</strong>s. Identify and address exist<strong>in</strong>g conflicts due to overlapp<strong>in</strong>g claims. Where possible identify andacknowledge users <strong>of</strong> various <strong>resource</strong>s, <strong>in</strong> particular secondary <strong>resource</strong>s that are <strong>of</strong>ten overlooked.Harmonize plural legal systems such that <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> emerg<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>the</strong> various legal systems lend forconsistent rules. In practice, any new statutory rules and laws that are designed take full consideration <strong>of</strong>customary rules already <strong>in</strong> place. Such harmonization is, and should be, an important aspect <strong>of</strong> clarify<strong>in</strong>gand secur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>.6. Pay particular attention to duration <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>. Secure long-term <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> are neededto create and consolidate local <strong>in</strong>centives for long-term <strong>in</strong>vestments. Short-term <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> are notconducive to long-term <strong>in</strong>vestments.7. Avoid displacement (reduction or elim<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong>) wherever possible. Reduction orelim<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> should be avoided. Reduction or elim<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> haveenormous potential for creat<strong>in</strong>g poverty, livelihood <strong>in</strong>security, and conflict. Where such changes <strong>in</strong> <strong>rights</strong>are necessary, assess current <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> <strong>of</strong> various primary and secondary users <strong>of</strong> land and <strong>natural</strong><strong>resource</strong>s <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> area and provide mean<strong>in</strong>gful compensation.8. Recognize diversity <strong>of</strong> solutions. No s<strong>in</strong>gle model is appropriate or applicable <strong>in</strong> all situations andplaces. Assess trade<strong>of</strong>fs <strong>of</strong> various <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regimes, and associated factors such as governmentcapacity for enforcement <strong>of</strong> laws (particularly <strong>in</strong> relation to private <strong>property</strong>), strength <strong>of</strong> local <strong>in</strong>stitutions(particularly <strong>in</strong> relation to communal lands and <strong>resource</strong>s), and <strong>in</strong>centives and dis<strong>in</strong>centives associatedwith various <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regimes.9. Streng<strong>the</strong>n local <strong>in</strong>stitutions. Where possible streng<strong>the</strong>n local <strong>in</strong>stitutions <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>governance. While efficient common <strong>property</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutions ensure high levels <strong>of</strong> equity and susta<strong>in</strong>ability<strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong> <strong>management</strong>, <strong>the</strong>ir effectiveness is <strong>in</strong>fluenced under certa<strong>in</strong> social and <strong>in</strong>stitutional sett<strong>in</strong>gs,and by specific attributes <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s and members <strong>in</strong>volved. Institutional arrangements arestreng<strong>the</strong>ned by mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>m more transparent, accountable, <strong>in</strong>clusive, and responsive to local needs.Local <strong>in</strong>stitutions should be assisted to become more equitable, particularly <strong>in</strong> heterogeneouscommunities (prevent capture <strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s by local elites). Where necessary, local <strong>in</strong>stitutions and usergroups should be provided necessary tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> monitor<strong>in</strong>g, conflict resolution, and consensus build<strong>in</strong>g.In addition, public oversight <strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong> exploitation may be necessary; however this will be moreeffective <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> support to local efforts than <strong>the</strong> traditional polic<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> land and <strong>resource</strong>s. One<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> least costly and most effective strategies available to central governments to streng<strong>the</strong>n local<strong>in</strong>stitutions is to promulgate enabl<strong>in</strong>g frameworks that formally recognize exist<strong>in</strong>g customary systems forland and renewable <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> and provide backup enforcement and dispute resolution services onan as-needed basis. Such measures quickly and effectively revive customary systems by underl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>irlegitimacy <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> eyes <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> formal legal system. Customary systems whose rules and monitor<strong>in</strong>g andenforcement activities are protected from unlimited contestation will have considerably greater <strong>resource</strong>s32 ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR


available to carry on <strong>the</strong>ir activities. In o<strong>the</strong>r cases, an ideal comb<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> state and community controlmay be explored to ensure social equity and environmental susta<strong>in</strong>ability. 2010. Promote <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regimes that allow for equity as well as efficiency. Equity, efficiency, andsusta<strong>in</strong>ability cannot be attributed to any particular regime by itself. Private, state, and common <strong>property</strong>regimes have <strong>the</strong>ir respective <strong>role</strong>s, and provide different benefits. When assess<strong>in</strong>g benefits <strong>of</strong> a <strong>rights</strong>regime, it is essential to take <strong>in</strong>to consideration <strong>the</strong> characteristics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>resource</strong>, range <strong>of</strong> right holders<strong>in</strong>volved, range <strong>of</strong> potential users, and <strong>the</strong> diversity <strong>of</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s derived from <strong>the</strong> region. Care must betaken to ensure that secur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>rights</strong> <strong>of</strong> one group does not serve to marg<strong>in</strong>alize o<strong>the</strong>rs. In addition,transaction costs <strong>of</strong> enforcement <strong>of</strong> rules should be seriously taken <strong>in</strong>to account as <strong>the</strong>y weigh veryheavily on <strong>the</strong> viability <strong>of</strong> customary renewable <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> and land tenure systems.11. Where possible promote solutions that go beyond efficiency and equity; empowerment <strong>of</strong> ruralpoor can br<strong>in</strong>g many long-term benefits. While efficiency and equity are important dimensions <strong>of</strong>ideal <strong>property</strong> <strong>rights</strong> regimes, regimes should consider concerns <strong>of</strong> rural empowerment and mov<strong>in</strong>gcommunities beyond dependency and a pervasive sense <strong>of</strong> helplessness. Such solutions br<strong>in</strong>g enormoussocial and economic benefits. In addition, long-term susta<strong>in</strong>ability (ra<strong>the</strong>r than short-term ga<strong>in</strong>s) shouldbe considered important variables <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> equation.Awareness <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> above pr<strong>in</strong>ciples and observations will enhance understand<strong>in</strong>g and facilitate <strong>the</strong>response <strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> managers as <strong>the</strong>y grapple with project or program implementation issuesacross a variety <strong>of</strong> contexts. While every situation is unique, <strong>the</strong>se pr<strong>in</strong>ciples shed light on exist<strong>in</strong>gpractices and constra<strong>in</strong>ts for which a practical response can be identified.20Some authors have explored <strong>the</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>ciple <strong>of</strong> subsidiarity <strong>in</strong> decision mak<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s, that is, decisions be made at <strong>the</strong> mostlocal level possible <strong>in</strong> order to m<strong>in</strong>imize costs at higher socio-political, and adm<strong>in</strong>istrative levels (Ribot, 2004). Accord<strong>in</strong>g to this pr<strong>in</strong>ciple,where <strong>the</strong>re is lack <strong>of</strong> skilled human <strong>resource</strong>s at <strong>the</strong> decentralized level, and where macroeconomic policies such as taxes and quotasneed to be considered, <strong>the</strong> central government may be a more appropriate <strong>management</strong> entity (FAO, 2005).ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 33


REFERENCES ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 35


African Centre for Technology Studies (ACTS). 2005. Land Tenure and Conflict <strong>in</strong> Africa: Prevention,Mitigation and Reconstruction Conference Proceed<strong>in</strong>gs, December 9 th – 10 th , 2004. Nairobi: African Centrefor Technology Studies (ACTS).Ashley, Carol<strong>in</strong>e and Christopher LaFranchi. 1997. Livelihood strategies <strong>of</strong> rural households <strong>in</strong> Caprivi:implications for conservancies and <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong> <strong>management</strong>. DEA Research Discussion Paper 20.W<strong>in</strong>dhoek: DEA.ARD, Inc. 2005. Land Tenure and Property Rights (LTPR) Framework and Tools, Burl<strong>in</strong>gton, Vermont.Documents may be requested from ard@ard<strong>in</strong>c.com.Bohrer, Kev<strong>in</strong>. 1996. Gu<strong>in</strong>ea Country Pr<strong>of</strong>ile. In Country Pr<strong>of</strong>iles <strong>of</strong> Land Tenure, West Africa. Madison,Wiscons<strong>in</strong>: Land Tenure Center.Bromley, Daniel W. 1989. Economic Interests and Institutions: The Conceptual Foundations <strong>of</strong> Public Policy. New York,NY: Basil Blackwell Inc., pp. 187-190.Bromley, Daniel. 2003. The Commons, Common Property, and Environmental Policy. In B. Larson (ed.)Property Rights and Environmental Problems, Volume I. Burl<strong>in</strong>gton: Ashgate Publish<strong>in</strong>g Company, pp. 83-99.Bruce, John W. 1988. A Perspective on Indigenous Land Tenure Systems and Land Concentration. In R.E. Downs andS.P. Reyna (eds.) Land and Society <strong>in</strong> Contemporary Africa. Hanover and London: University Press <strong>of</strong> NewEngland, pp. 23-52.Bruce, John W. 2004. Compar<strong>in</strong>g Communal and Individual Ownership: Pros, Cons and Pitfalls. In Roth,Michael, Vuyi Nxasana, Sipho Sibanda, and Teresa Yates (eds.) F<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g Solutions, Secur<strong>in</strong>g Rights: Papers andPerspectives from <strong>the</strong> National Land Tenure Conference, ICC, Durban, South Africa. Durban: LexisNexis Butterworths,pp. 127-137.Carter, Janis. 2004. Chimpanzee Protection <strong>in</strong> ENRMA Co-managed Forests Field Report for W<strong>in</strong>rock International.Conakry, Gu<strong>in</strong>ea: USAID. This report provides <strong>the</strong> rationale and orig<strong>in</strong>s <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Souti Yanfou Hunter’sAssociation, which was still <strong>in</strong> its <strong>in</strong>fancy at <strong>the</strong> close <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> ENRMA <strong>in</strong> September 2005.Cavendish, William. 1999. Empirical Regularities <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poverty-Environment Relationship <strong>of</strong> African RuralHouseholds, <strong>the</strong> Centre for <strong>the</strong> Study <strong>of</strong> African Economies Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper Series, Paper 105.Child, Brian. 2005. Pr<strong>in</strong>ciples, Practices, and Results <strong>of</strong> CBNRM <strong>in</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Africa. In Brian Child andMartha Lyman (eds.) Natural Resources as Community Assets: Lessons From Two Cont<strong>in</strong>ents. Madison: The SandCounty Foundation and Aspen Institute, pp 18-60.Coastal Resource Management Program (CRMP) 2003. Model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> Way: Lessons <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Capacities forCoastal Management <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Philipp<strong>in</strong>es. Special Report (1996-2004), Coastal Resource Management Project, CebuCity, Philipp<strong>in</strong>es.Coward, E. Walt Jr. 2006. Property Rights <strong>in</strong> Motion, Keynote Address International Association for <strong>the</strong>Study <strong>of</strong> Common Property, 11 th Biennial Global Conference, Bali, Indonesiahttp://dlc.dlib.<strong>in</strong>diana.edu/archive/00002072/00/Coward_Walt_Bali_Keynote.pdf.Dowie, Mark. 2005. Conservation Refugees: When Protect<strong>in</strong>g Nature Means Kick<strong>in</strong>g People Out, Orion,November/December Issue.Elbow, Kent M. 1994. Popular Participation <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Management <strong>of</strong> Natural Resources: Lessons from BabanRafi, Niger. LTC Research Paper 118, Madison, Wiscons<strong>in</strong>: Land Tenure Center, University <strong>of</strong> Wiscons<strong>in</strong>-Madison.Elbow, Kent and Ala<strong>in</strong> Rochegude. 1990. A Layperson’s Guide to <strong>the</strong> Forest Codes <strong>of</strong> Mali, Niger and Senegal, LTCPaper 139. Madison, Wiscons<strong>in</strong>: Land Tenure Center, University <strong>of</strong> Wiscons<strong>in</strong>-Madison.ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 37


Fernandez-Gimenez, Maria. 2006. Land Use and Land Tenure <strong>in</strong> Mongolia: A Brief History and CurrentIssues, USDA Forest Service Proceed<strong>in</strong>gs RMRS-P-39http://www.fs.fed.us/rm/pubs/rmrs_p039/rmrs_p039_030_036.pdf.Fischer, Julie E. et al. 1995. Atelier Régional de N’Zérékoré sur la Problématique Foncière et la Gestion des RessourcesNaturelles en Gu<strong>in</strong>ée Forestière, Workshop Report. Madison, Wiscons<strong>in</strong>: Land Tenure Center.Fitzpatrick, Daniel. 2005. ‘Best practice’ Option for <strong>the</strong> Legal Recognition <strong>of</strong> Customary Tenure. Developmentand change 36 (3): 449-475.Food and Agriculture Organization. 2002a. Land Tenure and Rural Development, FAO Land Tenure Series3. Rome: FAO.Food and Agriculture Organization. 2002b. Law and Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development s<strong>in</strong>ce Rio: Legal Trends <strong>in</strong>Agriculture and Natural Resource <strong>management</strong>, FAO Legislative Study 73. Rome: FAO.http://www.fao.org/DOCREP/005/Y3872E/Y3872E00.HTM.Food and Agriculture Organization. 2005. Environment <strong>in</strong> Decentralized Decision Mak<strong>in</strong>g, AgriculturalPolicy Support Service, Policy Assistance Division. Rome: FAO.http://www.fao.org/docs/up/easypol/346/en_decen_dec_mak<strong>in</strong>g_016EN.pdf.Fortmann, Louise. 1988. The Tree Tenure Factor <strong>in</strong> Agr<strong>of</strong>orestry with Particular Reference to Africa. InLouise Fortmann and John W. Bruce (eds.) Whose Trees? Proprietary Dimensions <strong>of</strong> Forestry. Boulder, CO:Westview Press, pp. 16-33.Fortmann, Louise, and John Bruce. 1988 (eds.) Whose Trees? Proprietary Dimensions <strong>of</strong> Forestry. Boulder, CO:Westview Press.Gibbs, Christopher and Daniel Bromley. 1989. Institutional Arrangements for Management <strong>of</strong> RuralResources: Common Property Regimes. In Fikret Berkes (ed.) Common Property Resources: Ecology andCommunity-Based Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development. London: Belhaven Press, pp. 22-32.Hanna, S. 1995. Efficiencies <strong>of</strong> User Participation <strong>in</strong> Natural Resource Management. In S. Hanna and M.Munas<strong>in</strong>ghe (eds.) Property Rights and <strong>the</strong> Environment: Social and Ecological Issues. The Beijer InternationalInstitute <strong>of</strong> Ecological Economics and The World Bank, pp. 59-68.Hard<strong>in</strong>, G. J. 1968. The Tragedy <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Commons. Science 1621: 243-8.Kerapeletswe, Charity and Jon Lovett. 2001. The Role <strong>of</strong> Common Pool Resources <strong>in</strong> Economic Welfare <strong>of</strong>Rural Households. Work<strong>in</strong>g paper. York, England: University <strong>of</strong> York.http://dlc.dlib.<strong>in</strong>diana.edu/archive/00000472/.Larson, Anne. 2004. Formal Decentralization and <strong>the</strong> Imperative <strong>of</strong> Decentralization ‘From Below’: A CaseStudy <strong>of</strong> Natural Resource Management <strong>in</strong> Nicaragua. In Ribot, Jesse and Anne Larson (eds.) Decentralization<strong>of</strong> <strong>natural</strong> <strong>resource</strong>s: Experiences <strong>in</strong> Africa, Asia and Lat<strong>in</strong> America. London: Frank Cass.Lawry, Steven W. 1990. Tenure Policy Toward Common Property Natural Resources <strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan Africa,Natural Resources Journal 30 (Spr<strong>in</strong>g): 403-422.Lund, Christian. 1995. Law, Power and Politics <strong>in</strong> Niger: Land Struggles and <strong>the</strong> Rural Code. Ph.D.Dissertation. Roskilde, Denmark: Roskilde University.Lynch, Owen 1999. Promot<strong>in</strong>g Legal Recognition <strong>of</strong> Community-Based Property Rights, Includ<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong>Commons: Some Theoretical Considerations. Paper presented at a Symposium <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> InternationalAssociation for <strong>the</strong> Study <strong>of</strong> Common Property and <strong>the</strong> Workshop <strong>in</strong> Political Theory and Policy Analysis,Indiana University, Bloom<strong>in</strong>gton, Indiana, June 7, 1999.38 ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR


M’Boge, Haddy and Nancy Sheehan. 1995. Les Différends et le Règlement des Différends en Gambie. Madison,Wiscons<strong>in</strong> : Land Tenure Center, University <strong>of</strong> Wiscons<strong>in</strong>-Madison. Draft paper f<strong>in</strong>anced by USAID andprepared for CILSS (Interstate Committee for Drought Control <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Sahel).Ma<strong>in</strong>e, Henry. 1861. Ancient Law: Its Connection With <strong>the</strong> Early History <strong>of</strong> Society, and Its Relation toModern Ideas, London: John Murray.Marong, Alhagi B.M. 1994. Land Tenure, Dispute Resolution and Customary Law: A Jo<strong>in</strong>t Research Project with <strong>the</strong>Land Tenure Centre <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> University <strong>of</strong> Wiscons<strong>in</strong>, Madison, USA. Banjul: The Law Reform Commission <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Gambia, Republic <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Gambia.Mathieu, Paul, Philippe Lavigne Delville, Lac<strong>in</strong>an Pare, Mahamadou Zongo, Hubert Ouedraogo with JulianneBaud, Eric Bologo, Nad<strong>in</strong>e Kone, Kar<strong>in</strong>e Triollet. 2003. Mak<strong>in</strong>g Land Transactions More Secure <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> West<strong>of</strong> Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso, IIED Drylands Program, Issue Paper No. 117, London: IIED.http://www.iied.org/pubs/pdf/full/9170IIED.pdf.Maxwell, Simon. 1999. What can we do with a Rights-Based Approach to Development? OverseasDevelopment Institute Brief<strong>in</strong>g Paper. http://www.odi.org.uk/publications/brief<strong>in</strong>g/3_99.html.McAuslan, Patrick. 1998. Mak<strong>in</strong>g Law Work: Restructur<strong>in</strong>g Land Relations <strong>in</strong> Africa. Development and Change29: 525-552.McKean, Margaret A. 1992. Management <strong>of</strong> Traditional Common Lands (Iriaichi) <strong>in</strong> Japan. In Daniel W.Bromley (ed.) Mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> Commons Work: Theory, Practice and Policy, Institute for Contemporary Studies Press:San Francisco, pp. 63-98.McNeill, Kent. 2001. Emerg<strong>in</strong>g Justice: Essays on Indigenous Rights <strong>in</strong> Canada and Australia, Boston: Houghton.Me<strong>in</strong>zen-Dick, Ruth, Rajendra Pradhan, and Monica Di Gregorio 2004. Understand<strong>in</strong>g Property Rights. InMe<strong>in</strong>zen-Dick, Ruth and Monica Di Gregorio (eds.) Collective Action and Property Rights for Susta<strong>in</strong>ableDevelopment, Focus 2020, Brief 3, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton DC: IFPRI.Me<strong>in</strong>zen-Dick, Ruth, Lynn Brown, Hilary Sims Feldste<strong>in</strong>, and Agnes Quisumb<strong>in</strong>g. 1997. Gender, PropertyRights, and Natural Resources, Food Consumption and Nutrition Division Discussion Paper No. 29,Wash<strong>in</strong>gton DC: IFPRI.Nepstad, D.C., S. Schwartzman, B. Bamberger, M. Santilli, D. Ray, P. Schles<strong>in</strong>ger, P. Lefebvre, A. Alencar, E.Pr<strong>in</strong>z, G. Fiske, and A. Rolla. 2006. Inhibition <strong>of</strong> Amazon Deforestation and Fire by Parks and IndigenousReserves. Conservation Biology 20 (1): 65-73.Norfolk, Simon. 2004. Exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Access to Natural Resources and L<strong>in</strong>kages to Susta<strong>in</strong>able Livelihoods: ACase Study <strong>of</strong> Mozambique, Livelihood Support Programme Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 17. Rome: FAO.Overseas Development Institute. 2002. Natural Resource Perspectives. Number 75 (February 2002).Ostrom, El<strong>in</strong>or. 1999. Private and Common Property Rights. In Boudewijn, Bouckaert and Gerrit DeGeest (eds) Encyclopedia <strong>of</strong> Law and Economics, Vol. 1 The History and Methodology <strong>of</strong> Law and Economics,Edward Elgar and The University <strong>of</strong> Ghent, pp 332-379. http://encyclo.f<strong>in</strong>dlaw.com/2000book.pdfOviedo, Gonzalo. 2002. Lessons Learned <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Establishment and Management <strong>of</strong> Protected Areas byIndigenous and Local Communities, South America: Enhanc<strong>in</strong>g Equity <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Relationship BetweenProtected Areas and Indigenous and Local Communities <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Context <strong>of</strong> Global Change, IUCN.www.iucn.org/<strong>the</strong>mes/ceesp/Publications/TILCEPA/CCA-GOviedo.pdfPlace, Frank, Michael Roth and Peter Hazell. 1994. Land Tenure Security and Agricultural Performance <strong>in</strong>Africa: Overview <strong>of</strong> Research Methodology. In Bruce, John W. and Shem E. Migot-Adholla (eds.) Search<strong>in</strong>g forLand Tenure Security <strong>in</strong> Africa. Dubuque, Iowa: Kendall/Hunt Publish<strong>in</strong>g Company, pp. 15-39.ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 39


Ribot, Jesse C. 2004. Wait<strong>in</strong>g for Democracy: The Politics <strong>of</strong> Choice <strong>in</strong> Natural Resource Decentralization. Wash<strong>in</strong>gtonDC: World Resources Institute.Ross, Michael. 2004. What Do We Know About Natural Resources and Civil War?, Journal <strong>of</strong> Peace Research 41:337-356.Sanou, Saidou. 2002. Land Tenure and Pastoral Resources <strong>in</strong> Nor<strong>the</strong>rn Yatenga, Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso. In Toulm<strong>in</strong>,Camilla, Philippe Lavigne Delville, Samba Traore (eds.) The Dynamics <strong>of</strong> Resource Tenure <strong>in</strong> West Africa. Oxford:International Institute for Environment and Development, pp. 180-187.Shackleton, Sheona, Charlie Shackleton and Ben Cous<strong>in</strong>s. 2000. Re-valu<strong>in</strong>g <strong>the</strong> Communal Lands <strong>of</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rnAfrica: New Understand<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>of</strong> Rural Livelihoods, ODI Natural Resource Perspectives Number 62,November 2000.Thomson, Jamie T. 1992. A Framework for Analyz<strong>in</strong>g Institutional Incentives <strong>in</strong> Community Forestry,Rome: FAO.Toulm<strong>in</strong>, Camilla. 2005-06. Secur<strong>in</strong>g Land and Property Rights <strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan Africa: The Role <strong>of</strong> LocalInstitutions. http://www.iied.org/Gov/mdgs/documents/mdg3/ch2_28pp.pdf.Toulm<strong>in</strong>, Camilla, Philippe Lavigne Delville and Samba Traore. 2002. Introduction. In Toulm<strong>in</strong>, Camilla,Philippe Lavigne Delville and Samba Traore (eds.) The Dynamics <strong>of</strong> Resource Tenure <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> West Africa. London:IIED, pp. 1-24.Toulm<strong>in</strong>, Camilla and Julian Quan. 2000. Register<strong>in</strong>g Customary Rights. In Toulm<strong>in</strong>, Camilla and Julian Quan(eds.) Evolv<strong>in</strong>g Land Rights, Policy and Tenure <strong>in</strong> Africa. London: DFID/IIED/NRI, pp. 207-28.Traore, Samba. 2002. Stray<strong>in</strong>g Fields: Tenure Problems for Pastoralists <strong>in</strong> <strong>the</strong> Ferlo, Senegal. In Toulm<strong>in</strong>,Camilla, Philippe Lavigne Delville, Samba Traore (eds.) The Dynamics <strong>of</strong> Resource Tenure <strong>in</strong> West Africa. London:IIED, pp. 145-156.Unruh, Jon, Lisa Cligget and Rod Hay. 2005. Migrant Land Rights Reception and 'Clear<strong>in</strong>g to Claim' <strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan Africa: A Deforestation Example from Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Zambia, Natural Resources Forum 29: 190-198.Wiber, Melanie G. 2005. The Voracious Appetites <strong>of</strong> Public versus Private Property: A View <strong>of</strong> Intellectual Property andBiodiversity from Legal Pluralism, CAPRi Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper # 40, July 2005.W<strong>in</strong>rock International Institute for Agricultural Development. 1999-2005. Various project reports <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Expanded Natural Resources Management Activity, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g F<strong>in</strong>al Program Report, September 2005.Conakry, Gu<strong>in</strong>ea: USAID.World Resources Institute. 2005. The Wealth <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Poor: Manag<strong>in</strong>g Ecosystems to Fight Poverty, WRI,Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, DC.40 ROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR


U.S. Agency for International Development1300 Pennsylvania Avenue, NWWash<strong>in</strong>gton, DC 20523 Tel: (202) 712-0000 Fax: (202) 216-3524 www.usaid.govROLE OF PROPERTY RIGHTS IN NRM: GOOD GOVERNANCE AND EMPOWERMENT OF THE RURAL POOR 41

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!