12.07.2015 Views

Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) in Land in developing countries

Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) in Land in developing countries

Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) in Land in developing countries

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Impr<strong>in</strong>tPublished by:Deutsche Gesellschaftfür Technische Zusammenarbeit(GTZ) GmbHP.O. Box 518065726 EschbornGermanyT +49 6196 79 - 0F +49 6196 79 - 1115E <strong>in</strong>fo@gtz.deI www.gtz.deWork of Division 45 - Agriculture, fisheries and food, GTZ, Eschborn:Sector Project “<strong>Land</strong> Management” (Dorith v. Behaim)Sector Project “Agricultural Policy and Food Security“ (Dr. Marlis L<strong>in</strong>decke)Future Initiative “AgroInvest” (Dr. Christian Henckes)Responsible, contact:Dorith v. Behaim, Mart<strong>in</strong>a Römer, Sector Project “<strong>Land</strong> Management”Dr. Thomas Breuer, Plann<strong>in</strong>g OfficerAuthors: Dr. Matthias Görgen, Dr. Bett<strong>in</strong>a Rudloff, Dr. Johannes Simons, Alfons ÜllenbergSusanne Väth, Lena WimmerSource & Copyright of pictures:© GTZ / Alfons Üllenberg, Dr. Babette Wehrmann, Oliver Schoenweger, Dr. Godihald Mush<strong>in</strong>zimanaContact to the Federal M<strong>in</strong>istry for Economic Cooperation and DevelopmentKar<strong>in</strong> FoljantyDesign:Jeanette Geppert,www.jeanette-geppert.deEschborn, December 2009


3ContentList of figures and tables 4List of abbreviations 5Preface 61. Introduction 82. Overview of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land and analysis of recent developments and trends 102.1. Global land resources: a short overview 102.2. Overview of the magnitude of large-scale <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land 112.3. Incentives for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land and relevant stakeholders 122.4. International frameworks and agreements concern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>FDI</strong> and <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land 163. Possible impacts of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land on target <strong>countries</strong> <strong>in</strong> terms of susta<strong>in</strong>abledevelopment 203.1. Possible economic impacts of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land on rural livelihoods 213.2. Possible socio-cultural impacts of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land on rural livelihoods 233.3. Possible environmental impacts of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land on rural livelihoods 244. Assessment of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land <strong>in</strong> four selected <strong>countries</strong>: Cambodia, Laos,Madagascar and Mali 254.1. General Overview 254.2. Country profile – Republic of Madagascar 284.3. Country Profile – Republic of Mali 344.4. Country Profile – Lao People’s Democratic Republic (Lao PDR) 404.5. Country profile – K<strong>in</strong>gdom of Cambodia 465. Conclusions and recommendations 52References 58Glossary 64Annex 66


4Acknowledgement:List of figures and tablesTable 1: Overview of the drivers of state-backed and private <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> landTable 2: Typology of target <strong>countries</strong>Table 3: Country profile MadagascarTable 4: Demand for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> Madagascar (2009)Table 5: Country profile Republic of MaliTable 6: Demand for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land <strong>in</strong> Mali (2009)Table 7: Country profile LaosTable 8: Authorities <strong>in</strong> charge depend<strong>in</strong>g on land sizeTable 9: Area of land lease/concession projects of two prov<strong>in</strong>ces (2009)Table 10: Country profile CambodiaTable 11: Official data on granted Economic <strong>Land</strong> Concessions to companies for Agricultureand Forestry <strong>in</strong> Cambodia


5List of abbreviationsAoA – Agreement on AgricultureASEAN – Association of Southeast AsianNationsBIT – Bi-lateral <strong>Investment</strong> TreatiesBMELV – Federal M<strong>in</strong>istry of Food,Agriculture and ConsumerProtectionBMZ – Federal M<strong>in</strong>istry for EconomicCooperation and DevelopmentBOD – Biological Oxygen DemandCDC – Council for the Development ofCambodiaCDF – Code Domanial et Foncier (Mali)CDM – Clean Development MechanismCPI – Corruption Perception IndexCSO – Civil Society OrganisationDAC – Development AssistanceCommitteeDDFI – Department of Domestic and<strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Investment</strong> (Laos)EIA – Environmental ImpactAssessmentELC – Economic <strong>Land</strong> Concession(Cambodia)ESAF – Enhanced StructuralAdjustment Facility (Mali)EU – European UnionFAO – Food and AgriculturalOrganisation<strong>FDI</strong> – <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Direct</strong> <strong>Investment</strong>FTA – Free Trade AgreementGATS – General Agreement on Trade <strong>in</strong>ServicesGATT – General Agreement on Tariffsand TradeGDP – Gross Domestic ProductGHI – Global Hunger IndexGIS – Geographic Information SystemGTZ – Gesellschaft für technischeZusammenarbeitIFAD – International Fund forAgricultural DevelopmentIFPRI – International Food PolicyResearch InstituteIIED – International Institute forEnvironment and DevelopmentIISD – International Institute forSusta<strong>in</strong>able DevelopmentIMF – International Monetary FundIPCC – Intergovernmental Panel onClimate ChangeLASED – <strong>Land</strong> Allocation for Social andEconomic Development(Cambodia)LLDC – Least Developed CountriesLOA – Loi d’Orientation Agricole(Mali)LPDP – Lao German <strong>Land</strong> PolicyDevelopment ProjectMAFF – M<strong>in</strong>istry of Agriculture, Forestryand Fisheries (Cambodia)MEF – M<strong>in</strong>istry of Economics andF<strong>in</strong>ance (Cambodia)MLMUPC – M<strong>in</strong>istry of <strong>Land</strong> Management,Urban Plann<strong>in</strong>g and Construction(Cambodia)NGO – Non-governmental OrganisationNTFP – Non-Timber Forest ProductsODA – Official Development AssistanceOECD – Organisation for EconomicCooperation and DevelopmentPPP – Public Private PartnershipQIA – Qatar <strong>Investment</strong> AuthorityRIT – Regional <strong>Investment</strong> TreatiesSIA – Social Impact AssessmentsSLC – Social <strong>Land</strong> Concession(Cambodia)SOE – State-owned EnterpriseSWF – Sovereign Welfare FundTNC – Transnational CorporationTRIMs – Trade Related Aspects of<strong>Investment</strong> MeasuresUNCTAD – United Nations Convention onTrade and DevelopmentUNDP – United Nations DevelopmentProgrammeWHO – World Health OrganisationWRI – World Resource InstituteWTO – World Trade Organisation


6Preface<strong>Land</strong> acquisitions by foreign private <strong>in</strong>vestorshave taken place on a small scale for decades.However, a changed economic and politicalenvironment seems to have accelerated thisprocess <strong>in</strong> the recent past. The current dramatic<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> sales and leas<strong>in</strong>g of land <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g<strong>countries</strong> makes clear that land is an <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>glyscarce resource <strong>in</strong> competition between variousland use <strong>in</strong>terests. Cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>g population growth,climate change and associated problems such asongo<strong>in</strong>g soil seal<strong>in</strong>g, erosion, desertification andurbanization are <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the pressure on landand other natural resources. At the same time,there is grow<strong>in</strong>g competition for a limited amountof agricultural land, due to ris<strong>in</strong>g demand for foodand fodder, as well as biomass for <strong>in</strong>dustrial andenergy use <strong>in</strong> national and <strong>in</strong>ternational markets.Aga<strong>in</strong>st this background, state actors and private<strong>in</strong>vestors from <strong>in</strong>dustrialised and emerg<strong>in</strong>g<strong>countries</strong> are us<strong>in</strong>g long-term leases or purchaseagreements to secure large areas of agriculturalland <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong> <strong>in</strong> order to grow foodor energy plants for export - a process described<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational news headl<strong>in</strong>es as “land grab”. Inthe current f<strong>in</strong>ancial crisis, land is also <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>glybecom<strong>in</strong>g a speculative asset for <strong>in</strong>vestors.The recent upsurge <strong>in</strong> <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land raises the hopeto bridge the gap of decades of under<strong>in</strong>vestment<strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong>’ agricultural sector, butit may also threaten host <strong>countries</strong>’ food securityand <strong>in</strong>crease the vulnerability of the rural population.However, keep<strong>in</strong>g FAO’s estimation <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>d,that at least an additional 30 billion US$ areannually required <strong>in</strong> the agricultural sector <strong>in</strong>order to half the world’s hungry until 2015, privatesector <strong>in</strong>vestment is <strong>in</strong>dispensable. Effects of <strong>FDI</strong><strong>in</strong> land strongly depend on their specific <strong>in</strong>stitutionalsett<strong>in</strong>g. This emphasises the need for actionof Development Cooperation to respond to thepolitical demands and come up with sound ideason how <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land should be shaped, whatthe policies should look like, which can trigger<strong>in</strong>vestments and which lead to susta<strong>in</strong>able andaccessible supply of food <strong>in</strong> the years to come.A coherent policy for improved land managementand secure land rights <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong> canlimit the possible risks and also contribute towardsbetter utilisation of the possible opportunities of<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land.This study by GTZ on behalf of BMZ focuseson these challenges and attempts to analyse the sofar exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land. It aims to broaden theunderstand<strong>in</strong>g of the complexity of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land<strong>in</strong> order to provide for better-targeted ways ofaddress<strong>in</strong>g those <strong>in</strong>vestments. Therefore the studypresents background <strong>in</strong>formation, causes andimpact cha<strong>in</strong>s as well as recent developmentsconcern<strong>in</strong>g large-scale land acquisition on thebasis of four case study <strong>countries</strong>. Cambodia, LaoPDR, Madagascar and Mali have been selectedout of many least developed <strong>countries</strong> which areamong the potential hosts for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land. Eventhough exact <strong>in</strong>formation on contractual detailsrema<strong>in</strong>s limited, exemplary <strong>in</strong>sights <strong>in</strong> land userights and land conflicts, <strong>in</strong>vestment climate andlegal requirements, current land deals, as well associal and environmental opportunities and risksare given. To <strong>in</strong>itiate developmental benefitsfrom private and/or public sector <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land,recommendations are given how to improve the<strong>in</strong>stitutional environment and the acceptance offoreign <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> land serv<strong>in</strong>g as an overviewof the result<strong>in</strong>g need for action for developmentcooperation.Eschborn, December 2009Albert EngelHead of DivisionAgriculture, Fisheries and FoodDorith von BehaimSector Project<strong>Land</strong> Management


81. IntroductionOfficial development assistance (ODA) for theagricultural sector has lost share of overall aidover time: it had been around 15% <strong>in</strong> the 1970s,but it decreased to around 5% <strong>in</strong> 2007. Thedom<strong>in</strong>ant spend<strong>in</strong>g areas supported adm<strong>in</strong>istration,water and forestry; food crops were not apriority (OXFAM, 2009). But, accord<strong>in</strong>g toFAO 2009, the agricultural sector <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g<strong>countries</strong> urgently needs capital. Decades of low<strong>in</strong>vestment have meant stagnat<strong>in</strong>g productivityand production levels. In order to halve the world’shungry by 2015, as targeted by the 1996 WorldFood Summit, FAO calculations show that at leastUS$ 30 billion of additional funds are requiredannually <strong>in</strong> the next ten years.Public <strong>in</strong>vestments can only address this requirementpartially and must be amended by private<strong>in</strong>vestments, which currently are approximatelyfive times higher than public aid (OXFAM,2009). Private <strong>in</strong>vestments, therefore, can play avery relevant role <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g agriculture’scapacity (FAO, 2009).Develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong> often face a lack of domestic– private and governmental – <strong>in</strong>vestmentcapacities. <strong>Foreign</strong> direct <strong>in</strong>vestments (<strong>FDI</strong>) <strong>in</strong>agriculture are, therefore, crucial for strengthen<strong>in</strong>gthe agricultural sector. These <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>agriculture are often closely l<strong>in</strong>ked to <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>arable land <strong>in</strong> order to secure and to control theaccess to commodities produced on the land.Recently, more and more <strong>in</strong>vestors from foreign<strong>countries</strong> are acquir<strong>in</strong>g arable land <strong>in</strong> less developedregions – ma<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>in</strong> Africa, South andCentral America and Southeast Asia. S<strong>in</strong>ce 2000,approximately 15-20 1 million ha of land worldwidehave been acquired or are under negotiation <strong>in</strong>the context of the recent surge of <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Direct</strong><strong>Investment</strong>s <strong>in</strong> land (<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land) (v. Braun andMe<strong>in</strong>zen-Dick (IFPRI) 2 , 2009). <strong>Land</strong> acquisitionsby foreign private <strong>in</strong>vestors have taken place on asmall scale for decades. However, a changedeconomic and political environment seems tohave accelerated this process <strong>in</strong> the recent past(v. Braun and Me<strong>in</strong>zen-Dick (IFPRI), 2009;Haralambous et al. (IFAD), 2009; Gra<strong>in</strong>, 2008;Cotula et al. (IIED, FAO, IFAD), 2009).1 For Comparison: Farmland Germany: 16.8 million ha (2005); EU 27: 160.7 million ha (2005), compare BMELV, 2008, p. 432.2 The papers referr<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land are often assigned to the organisations that the authors work <strong>in</strong>. Therefore the organisationsare mentioned <strong>in</strong> brackets.


9Def<strong>in</strong>ition of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land is a special form of <strong>FDI</strong>. But even for general <strong>FDI</strong>, def<strong>in</strong>itions only exist asguidel<strong>in</strong>es for statistics or as a reference with<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational agreements:“<strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong>volves a last<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> effective management control over anenterprise. <strong>Foreign</strong> direct <strong>in</strong>vestment can <strong>in</strong>clude buy<strong>in</strong>g shares of an enterprise <strong>in</strong> anothercountry, re<strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g earn<strong>in</strong>gs of a foreign owned enterprise <strong>in</strong> the country where it is located,and parent firms extend<strong>in</strong>g loans to their foreign affiliates. International Monetary Fund(IMF) guidel<strong>in</strong>es consider an <strong>in</strong>vestment to be a foreign direct <strong>in</strong>vestment if it accounts forat least 10 % of the foreign firm’s vot<strong>in</strong>g stock of shares” (WORLD BANK GLOSSARY).The impacts of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> general can be positive on the target country because the capital<strong>in</strong>-flow, tax <strong>in</strong>come and the subsequent transfer of know-how can be a kick-off for development.This perspective is shared widely <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational development cooperation. Increased accessto <strong>FDI</strong> is seen as one of the key benefits of globalization because it is thought to lead tocapital formation, technology and knowledge transfer, higher wages and greater job opportunities.No specific official def<strong>in</strong>ition for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land exists so far. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the above-mentionedgeneral def<strong>in</strong>ition of <strong>FDI</strong>, <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land can be characterised as follows:“<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land by a foreign company or state is based on a last<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> tak<strong>in</strong>g controlover land use rights. The transaction <strong>in</strong>cludes either rights of land-use or land-ownership.The land-use rights are generally valid for a limited period and can possibly be extended.”Objective of the studyThis study has a two-fold objective:(1) It summarises the recent discussion on <strong>FDI</strong><strong>in</strong> order to give an overview of the scope of<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land. Relevant criteria for evaluat<strong>in</strong>gthe positive and negative outcomes, the<strong>in</strong>fluence of the contract designs and the<strong>in</strong>stitutional framework are also presented.(2) As part of the evaluation criteria the resultsof the four case studies are given forCambodia, Laos, Madagascar and Mali.


102. Overview of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land and analysis ofrecent developments and trends2.1. Global land resources:a short overviewIn order to better understand <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land, a roughoverview about global land resources is necessary.This chapter <strong>in</strong>vestigates the potential availableland area for crop production and forecasts thedevelopment of arable land. The chapter reliesma<strong>in</strong>ly on a study by Bru<strong>in</strong>sma (2009).The worldwide land surface covers 13.4 billion ha.Of these 13.4 billion ha 12 % is currently used forthe cultivation of crops which translates <strong>in</strong>to anestimated area of 1.5 billion ha. Arable land has<strong>in</strong>creased over the last decades and higher demandfor agricultural commodities will lead to a further<strong>in</strong>crease of cultivated land area. The ma<strong>in</strong> driversof this development will be on one hand the<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g demand for food and on the other the<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g demand for agricultural raw materialsfor energy and other <strong>in</strong>dustrial purposes (e.g.rubber). From 1967 until 2005, the global areaused for crops <strong>in</strong>creased by 187 million ha. The<strong>in</strong>crease occurred ma<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong>(227 million ha), while <strong>in</strong> developed <strong>countries</strong> thecultivated area decreased by 40 million ha. Primaryreasons for this development <strong>in</strong> developed <strong>countries</strong>were the cont<strong>in</strong>ual growth of yields and thedeceleration of agricultural commodity demand.When discuss<strong>in</strong>g <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land, the central questionhas to be answered whether land is a scarceresource.Accord<strong>in</strong>g to calculations, a wider range of globalland surface for the cultivation of crops could beused. An estimation by Fischer et al. (2002)shows a potential of 4.5 billion ha which can beused for crop production. Consequently only 36%of potential land areas for crop production are <strong>in</strong>use and the rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g 2.7 billion ha could be used<strong>in</strong> the future to satisfy the <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g demand.These potentials are unequally distributed.Whereas great potentials ma<strong>in</strong>ly exist <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g<strong>countries</strong>, <strong>in</strong> developed <strong>countries</strong> potentials arerare. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to Fischer et al. (2002) potentialland area for crop production <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g<strong>countries</strong> is estimated at 2.8 billion ha. At themoment 970 million ha are <strong>in</strong> use which impliesthat 1.8 billion ha could be activated. However,this calculation is often overestimated and potentialsare <strong>in</strong> reality far lower due to a number ofrestrictions:First, this estimation ignores all other possibleland use opportunities besides crop production.The need for forest, protection areas as well assettlement and <strong>in</strong>dustrial areas is not considered.Accord<strong>in</strong>g to Alexandratos (2009) only 40%of the potential 2.7 billion ha available is underconsideration for forests (45%), protection areas(12%) as well as settlement and <strong>in</strong>dustrialareas (3%). Similar to Alexandratos (2009),Nachtergaele and George (2009) also restrictthe potential land use to crop production on 55%of potential available land.A further po<strong>in</strong>t of criticism exists <strong>in</strong> the vary<strong>in</strong>gland qualities. The estimated potential of 2.7billion ha does not consider that not on all of theseareas a wide variety of crops could be cultivated.For example, <strong>in</strong> this calculation land areas <strong>in</strong>North Africa are also considered, which could beonly used for the cultivation of olive trees.Rice Harvest


11The third restriction concentrates on the distributionof potential available land. The potentialavailable land for crop production ma<strong>in</strong>ly concentrateson South America and Sub-Saharan Africa.90% of potential available land is located <strong>in</strong> SouthAmerica and Sub-Saharan Africa and 50% of thepotential is spread among only seven <strong>countries</strong>(Brazil, Democratic Republic of the Congo,Angola, Sudan, Argent<strong>in</strong>a, Colombia and Bolivia).This estimated potential does not consider theimportant fact of ecological and economic constra<strong>in</strong>ts.Due to ecological fragility and <strong>in</strong> somecases toxicity of land, not all potential areas couldbe exploited for crop production. On the otherhand, <strong>in</strong> many cases the cultivation with crops onthese areas is not profitable, because <strong>in</strong>frastructureto these areas does not exist or the fertility isrelatively low and, therefore, the cost benefit ratiois too high. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to Fischer (2002) 70% ofpotential available lands <strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan Africa areaffected by at least one ecological or economicconstra<strong>in</strong>t. When consider<strong>in</strong>g preced<strong>in</strong>g reasons,it is forecasted that <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong> anadditional 120 million ha for crop productionwill be activated. The <strong>in</strong>crease of arable land willtake place ma<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan Africa (64million ha) and <strong>in</strong> South America (52 million ha).In contrast to Sub-Saharan Africa and SouthAmerica, it is forecasted that arable land <strong>in</strong> some<strong>countries</strong> <strong>in</strong> Asia (e.g. Ch<strong>in</strong>a, Rep. Korea) willdecrease until 2050. The ma<strong>in</strong> reasons for the<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g arable land will be the price <strong>in</strong>centivesfor the production of agricultural commodities.Accord<strong>in</strong>g to Lopez (1998) and De<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>ger andM<strong>in</strong>ten (1999), an expansion of crop cultivationareas correlates with agricultural commodityprices. Besides economic <strong>in</strong>centives, ecologicaleffects are also responsible for expansion of arableland. Regeneration of soil fertility with fertilizer isoften more expensive than the evasion on so farnot used land.Go<strong>in</strong>g over these facts, it could be that the potentialfor land expansion exists but the potentialsare often overestimated and land availability isconstra<strong>in</strong>ed due to ecological and economicrestrictions. The result<strong>in</strong>g amount of potentialavailable land area for crop production is, therefore,<strong>in</strong> some regions scarce and <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land couldlead to further scarcity of land.2.2. Overview of the magnitude oflarge-scale <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> landA comprehensive set of data allow<strong>in</strong>g for a preciseoverview of the extent and the contractual detailsof <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land is not available. Well-documentedexamples are scarce, details on the deals are oftenunclear and some reports are contradictory.However, some organisations gather <strong>in</strong>formationprovided by the media <strong>in</strong> order to outl<strong>in</strong>e themagnitude and the relevance of the emerg<strong>in</strong>gphenomenon. 3A table <strong>in</strong> the annex assembles currently available<strong>in</strong>formation about <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land exceed<strong>in</strong>g 5,000ha per project. It is ma<strong>in</strong>ly based on studiesconducted by Gra<strong>in</strong> (2008), by IFPRI (v. Braunand Me<strong>in</strong>zen-Dick, 2009), and the GTZ casestudies for Cambodia, Laos, Madagascar, Mali onbehalf of BMZ and a work<strong>in</strong>g group of IIED,3 For example see: http://farmlandgrab.org/ and http://www.landcoalition.org/cpl-blog/.


12Field work with ox ploughFAO and IFAD (Cotula et al, 2009). The tablecomprises <strong>in</strong>formation on size (<strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ance or ha),locations, actors and contract details such as thecurrent status of reported land deals. To whatextent these deals, not all f<strong>in</strong>ished yet, will beimplemented <strong>in</strong> the near future is not exactlyknown because of a lack of transparency. For<strong>in</strong>stance <strong>in</strong> the prom<strong>in</strong>ent Daewoo case <strong>in</strong>Madagascar the negotiations were formallysuspended after it <strong>in</strong>duced riots, but might beresumed.In spite of the above mentioned lack of completenessand reliability of data, the table <strong>in</strong> the annexdemonstrates:• Develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong> and especially leastdeveloped African and Southeast Asian<strong>countries</strong> are the ma<strong>in</strong> target regions for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>land.• The biggest deals are negotiated with <strong>in</strong>vestorsfrom Saudi Arabia, other Gulf States and someAsian <strong>countries</strong> (Ch<strong>in</strong>a, South Korea, India).These <strong>countries</strong> are characterised by a shortageof fertile land due to unfavourable climateconditions or population growth on the onehand and sufficient f<strong>in</strong>ancial means on the otherhand.• The scope of some of the envisaged <strong>in</strong>vestments(up to 1.3 million ha) demonstrates the dimensionof s<strong>in</strong>gle deals.2.3. Incentives for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land andrelevant stakeholdersThe World <strong>Investment</strong> Report as well as theWorld <strong>Investment</strong> Prospects Survey address <strong>FDI</strong><strong>in</strong> general but do not explicitly refer to <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>land (UNCTAD 2008a, UNCTAD 2008b).Nevertheless, presented figures give empiricalevidence of the grow<strong>in</strong>g relevance of <strong>FDI</strong>.Regard<strong>in</strong>g Africa, the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>FDI</strong> is explicitlyascribed to high commodity prices among otherth<strong>in</strong>gs. For Lat<strong>in</strong> America and the Caribbean, thesurge of <strong>FDI</strong> is said to be driven by the demandfor natural resources.It is commonly agreed that several developmentson the global markets for agricultural commoditiesenhanced the attractiveness of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land.Long-term developments refer to:• Expectation of a high and ris<strong>in</strong>g level of pricesfor agricultural commodities due to globallyreducedgrowth <strong>in</strong> production and ris<strong>in</strong>gdemand because of population and economicgrowth. As a result, food security may be agrow<strong>in</strong>g risk <strong>in</strong> the future. From a privateperspective, land <strong>in</strong>vestments may become moreattractive as high prices may lead to high landrents.• Food aid as a traditional source to ensure foodsecurity <strong>in</strong> times of unexpected shortages may<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly become <strong>in</strong>sufficient depend<strong>in</strong>g onthe design of aid: As long as a large part of aidstill is given <strong>in</strong> k<strong>in</strong>d, a countercyclical availabilityis system immanent: if price peaks symbolizeoverall scarcity, then aid <strong>in</strong> k<strong>in</strong>d will not beavailable or the loss <strong>in</strong> alternative high exportreturns are too high for donors.


13• Climate change (due to weather events likedroughts and flood<strong>in</strong>g) leads to a possible loss <strong>in</strong>overall productivity and raises the probability ofunexpected harvest losses.• Climate obligations. The Clean DevelopmentMechanism (CDM) allows <strong>in</strong>dustrializedsignatories of the Kyoto Protocol to buy certifiedemission reductions. Hereby, the actual emissionreductions are transferred to other – ma<strong>in</strong>lydevelop<strong>in</strong>g – <strong>countries</strong>, <strong>in</strong> order to cut the costsof reduction. The transfer can be implementedby forestation projects <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong>requir<strong>in</strong>g land resources.• Another advance <strong>in</strong> developed <strong>countries</strong> refers tothe political support of agro-fuels (US, Braziland the European Community). These <strong>countries</strong>have established compulsory rates for agro-fuelsfor energy used <strong>in</strong> the transportation sector.Hereby, competition between food and agrofuelsproduction for restricted land area <strong>in</strong>creasesand <strong>countries</strong> characterised by suitable soil andclimate conditions for agro-fuels are now on thetarget list of foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> thosealternative energies.• Trade Liberalisation. The ongo<strong>in</strong>g process <strong>in</strong>trade liberalisation and reforms of nationalagricultural policies of large agricultural exportershave <strong>in</strong>duced a general food price <strong>in</strong>creaseand adds to the reduced availability of foodsurpluses. 4The follow<strong>in</strong>g recent developments have aggravatedthis generally changed environment:• Food crisis <strong>in</strong> 2007 and 2008: the price peaksfor agricultural products led to a special focus onfood security <strong>in</strong> particular for food import<strong>in</strong>g<strong>countries</strong> and their dependency on the worldmarkets. In several of these <strong>countries</strong>, e.g. theMiddle East, food imports account for animportant part of the domestic consumptionand they had to cope with high expenditures forimports and a respective burden for their tradebalances <strong>in</strong> the period of high food prices. Onaccount of high costs for promot<strong>in</strong>g local foodproduction and due to the limited resources,these <strong>countries</strong> decided to produce food abroadand <strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> land <strong>in</strong> foreign <strong>countries</strong>. Bythat they aim to grow less dependent on foodimports and the volatility of global food prices.• F<strong>in</strong>ancial crisis <strong>in</strong> 2008: high prices for agriculturalproducts due to scarcity of land and waterresources on the one hand and ris<strong>in</strong>g demand foragricultural commodities on the other, may leadto two-fold profits from <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> land: (1)profit from rais<strong>in</strong>g land prices has <strong>in</strong>creased landrents and the attractiveness of land <strong>in</strong>vestmentsfor private <strong>in</strong>vestors, (2) <strong>in</strong>centives for agriculturalproduction. The rise of profits is of specificrelevance as the global f<strong>in</strong>ancial crisis has led toa collapse <strong>in</strong> equity and bond markets, andthereby strengthen<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>directly the competitivenessof <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land (Cotula et al. (IIED,FAO, IFAD), p. 57). Develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong> maynot be able to follow these <strong>in</strong>centives as they lackthe necessary capital.These developments have pushed <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong>the agricultural sector and especially <strong>in</strong> land <strong>in</strong>foreign <strong>countries</strong> <strong>in</strong>stead of buy<strong>in</strong>g products likefood or energy at the world markets.Empirically, the relevant time span to analyze andto collect data on <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land compromisesdifferent phases:• In 2000, the first Ch<strong>in</strong>ese <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> cashcrops and food production became an importantpart of Ch<strong>in</strong>ese <strong>in</strong>vestment policy, due to<strong>in</strong>dustrialization and economic development.• In 2005 and 2006, high prices for energy, an<strong>in</strong>tensified debate about climate change andpolitical promotion of agro-fuels resulted <strong>in</strong> an<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g demand for agricultural commodities<strong>in</strong> order to produce agro-fuels and <strong>in</strong>creased thedemand for land.• A further surge <strong>in</strong> <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land can be observed<strong>in</strong> 2007 and 2008 when food prices rose dramaticallydur<strong>in</strong>g the food crises.The <strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>in</strong> the field of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land can begovernmental and private actors:• Most of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> the land sector is conductedby private bodies <strong>in</strong> the form of private sector<strong>in</strong>vestments. Invest<strong>in</strong>g companies orig<strong>in</strong>atefrom different <strong>countries</strong> like the USA or the UKand Sweden, but Ch<strong>in</strong>a and Saudi Arabia appearon the list as well. The prom<strong>in</strong>ent deal of theSouth Korean company Daewoo Logistics <strong>in</strong>4 Trade liberalisation <strong>in</strong> the agricultural sector was connected with a considerable reduction of subsidies.


14Madagascar, which has received extensive mediacoverage, is an example of a private sector<strong>in</strong>vestment too.• Governments: Governments can act <strong>in</strong> differentways.(1) <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land may be negotiated on thehighest political level between the governmentsof the affected <strong>countries</strong>. 5 A prom<strong>in</strong>entexample for <strong>in</strong>tergovernmental negotiations isthe case of Malibya Agriculture where theLibyan and the Malian governments agreed ona Libyan <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> the Malian NigerOffice Area to produce food for the Libyanpopulation.(2) Even if the f<strong>in</strong>al actors sign<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>vestmentcontract are private, public actors play adom<strong>in</strong>ant role <strong>in</strong> the overall <strong>in</strong>vestmentenvironment laid down <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment law. Aswell, very often deficits <strong>in</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>al <strong>in</strong>vestmentarise from weak governance structures forenforc<strong>in</strong>g domestic law. Governments cancreate a favourable framework for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> landwith the help of Bilateral <strong>Investment</strong> Treaties(BIT) which provide legal protection to<strong>in</strong>vestments for citizens or enterprises outsideof the contract<strong>in</strong>g nations.(3) Moreover, governments <strong>in</strong> target <strong>countries</strong>can facilitate <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land by adjust<strong>in</strong>g thedomestic legal framework to the needs of<strong>in</strong>vestors, by provid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formational, technicalsupport or by direct or <strong>in</strong>direct subsidies.• Sovereign Wealth Funds (SWF): Those fundsare state-owned and serve the political objectivesof the respective country. In the last several yearsthey have been expand<strong>in</strong>g abroad as a result of arapid accumulation of reserves. By now, it is notcommon for SWF to <strong>in</strong>vest directly <strong>in</strong> foreignland, but SWF are engaged <strong>in</strong> the agriculturalsector (Cotula et al. (IIED, FAO, IFAD),2009, p. 30). For example, the Qatar <strong>Investment</strong>Authority (QIA) is reported to have establishedjo<strong>in</strong>t venture funds with the governments ofIndonesia and Vietnam and is negotiat<strong>in</strong>gsimilar deals with the government of Malaysiaand the Philipp<strong>in</strong>es. In addition, it is reportedthat the QIA was <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> the land deals <strong>in</strong>Sudan (Cotula et al. (IIED, FAO, IFAD),2009, p. 35; Gra<strong>in</strong>, 2008). The state-ownedSaudi Industrial Development Fund is currentlygrant<strong>in</strong>g f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g facilities to firms explor<strong>in</strong>gagricultural <strong>in</strong>vestments abroad.• State-owned enterprises: These companies arestate-controlled and, therefore, act accord<strong>in</strong>g tothe political objectives of the government too.Examples for state-owned enterprises are ZadHold<strong>in</strong>g Company from Qatar, Ch<strong>in</strong>a InternationalWater and Electric Corporation <strong>in</strong>Zimbabwe and other companies owned by theCh<strong>in</strong>ese state <strong>in</strong> Tanzania and the DemocraticRepublic of Congo. A huge amount of largescale<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> the context of national foodstrategies can be assigned to state-ownedenterprises.<strong>Foreign</strong> direct <strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>in</strong> land can be classifiedaccord<strong>in</strong>g to their different primary motives basedon the political goals and economic background oftheir domestic frame:• Investors from oil rich <strong>countries</strong> with poorresources of arable land, water scarcity and harshclimate conditions. They aim at improv<strong>in</strong>g foodsecurity and reduc<strong>in</strong>g the dependence on highand volatile food prices. These <strong>countries</strong> are rich<strong>in</strong> capital and able to <strong>in</strong>vest lots of moneyespecially through state funds that serve state<strong>in</strong>terests.• Investors from <strong>in</strong>dustrialized and emerg<strong>in</strong>g<strong>countries</strong> with large populations and rapideconomic growth. They face an <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gdemand for feed, fodder, fibre and for renewableresources and try to countervail it by <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>land. This strategy helps them to grow lessdependent on the world markets.Based on available <strong>in</strong>formation, it seems that the<strong>in</strong>vestors from oil rich and emerg<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong>ma<strong>in</strong>ly are governments or state enterprises orstate funds respectively. In contrast, <strong>in</strong>vestors from<strong>in</strong>dustrialised <strong>countries</strong> primarily are privatecompanies <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g ma<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>in</strong> agro-fuel projects.When governments try to follow their food orenergy strategies by <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> foreign lands,5 Several po<strong>in</strong>ts with<strong>in</strong> the land deal can rema<strong>in</strong> unclear and therefore conta<strong>in</strong> social, political and environmental risks as there is little transparency and possibilityfor public control. Even for some government-to-government deals, no official data but only media reports and governmental press releases are available. Very oftenthose reports are the only source on the content of the contract and the status of implementation.


15they usually set up <strong>in</strong>vestment contracts with thegovernments <strong>in</strong> the target <strong>countries</strong> themselvesor with companies through which they act.While private <strong>in</strong>vestments are ma<strong>in</strong>ly driven bythe goals of the companies (especially short andlong-term profit, susta<strong>in</strong>able development of thefirm), public <strong>in</strong>vestments can result from differentobjectives. Table 1 summarises the drivers for <strong>FDI</strong><strong>in</strong> land.Table 1: Overview of the drivers of state-backed and private <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> landIncentives State-backed <strong>in</strong>vestments Private <strong>in</strong>vestmentsEconomic drivers ••Reduc<strong>in</strong>g import costs for food••Increas<strong>in</strong>g shareholder value because of••Secur<strong>in</strong>g future energy securityris<strong>in</strong>g food prices due to population growth••Secur<strong>in</strong>g future food securityand climate change••Reduc<strong>in</strong>g dependence on (volatile global) ••Increas<strong>in</strong>g shareholder value because ofprice developmentemerg<strong>in</strong>g agro-fuel markets ma<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>in</strong> theUS and EU••Anticipat<strong>in</strong>g grow<strong>in</strong>g land prices(speculation)••Search<strong>in</strong>g for alternative <strong>in</strong>vestments as aresult of the f<strong>in</strong>ancial crisisPolitical andstrategic driversSource: own work.••Meet<strong>in</strong>g grow<strong>in</strong>g demand for agro-fuels(blend<strong>in</strong>g targets, etc.)••Comply<strong>in</strong>g with <strong>in</strong>ternational agreements(mitigation climate change, Kyoto protocol,etc.)••Reduc<strong>in</strong>g the dependency on theworld market for food and fuelThe target <strong>countries</strong> differ <strong>in</strong> terms of naturalresources, economic development or politicalstability. However, it seems feasible to divide them<strong>in</strong>to two groups accord<strong>in</strong>g to agricultural andeconomic resources. 1) Develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong> withlow world market <strong>in</strong>tegration 2) Export orienteddevelop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong> with established access toworld markets.Table 2: Typology of target <strong>countries</strong>Develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong> withlow world market <strong>in</strong>tegration••Favorable natural conditions (soils and climate) foragriculture: Underutilised land resources, waterresources for irrigation••Often weak <strong>in</strong>frastructure and world market access••Low productivity and smallholder agriculture (oftensubsistence farm<strong>in</strong>g)••Low <strong>in</strong>put costs (land and labour)••Little <strong>in</strong>formation about the availability of arable landand unclear land titles••Weak governance••Unclear land markets and tendency towards corruption••Political disturbancesMa<strong>in</strong> motivation••Potential for development <strong>in</strong> economy through <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>land/agricultureExamplesCountries ma<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan Africa or SouthEast-Asia (Sudan, Madagascar, Mali, Cambodia, Laos)Export oriented develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong> with establishedaccess to world markets••Availability of arable land resources which cannot beutilised due to enormous extent, production capacityand f<strong>in</strong>ancial resources••Appropriate <strong>in</strong>frastructure and world market access••Established or beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g development of a land market••High productivity and market-oriented agriculture••World market orientationMa<strong>in</strong> motivation••Secure capital flow <strong>in</strong>to a agriculture, an importantand grow<strong>in</strong>g sector of the economyExamplesBrazil, Argent<strong>in</strong>a, Russia, Ukra<strong>in</strong>e, IndonesiaSource: own work.


162.4. International frameworks andagreements concern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>FDI</strong> and<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> landThe legal framework for foreign direct <strong>in</strong>vestments,which have an impact on <strong>in</strong>vestments,encompasses all types of different legal sett<strong>in</strong>gs –from <strong>in</strong>ternational to domestic law, from publicto private commercial law and from explicit <strong>in</strong>vestment-relatedlaw to trade rules. Thereby, therelevant rules may affect both state and privateactors. Some specific provisions for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> landexist which differ from rules to other <strong>FDI</strong>.At a multilateral level the WTO addresses <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>different agreements: 6(1) Explicit <strong>in</strong>vestment rules are laid down <strong>in</strong> theAgreement on Trade Related Aspects of<strong>Investment</strong> Measures (TRIMs). It def<strong>in</strong>esgeneral rules for <strong>in</strong>vestment measures <strong>in</strong> orderto avoid trade restrictive and distort<strong>in</strong>g effects.It focuses on measures that have a possibleimpact on export and import quantities, but itrequires an equal treatment of national andforeign <strong>in</strong>vestors as well. In particular, exportrestrictions are prohibited.(2) The General Agreement on Trade <strong>in</strong> Services(GATS) <strong>in</strong>tegrates <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> the concept ofcommercial presence. Hereby, members give<strong>in</strong>dividual positive lists of those sub-sectors forwhich market access is offered for services.(3) The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade(GATT) and the Agreement on Agriculture(AoA) def<strong>in</strong>e rules that are of specific relevanceto <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land. These allow export restrictions<strong>in</strong> case of food shortages under GATT Art.XI, 2 a and c as well as under AoA Art. 12.The respective rules are specific to the agriculturalsector as export restrictions are forbiddenfor all other commodities.Trade-related provisions can affect <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong>the sense that trade options <strong>in</strong>fluence the overall<strong>in</strong>vestment climate. For example: Export restrictions<strong>in</strong> case of a food crisis enable target <strong>countries</strong>to ensure their food security. But for the <strong>in</strong>vestor itreduces <strong>FDI</strong> attractiveness if <strong>in</strong> phases of shortagehis own export flows may be limited.Bilateral <strong>Investment</strong> Treaties (BITs) andRegional <strong>Investment</strong> Treaties have <strong>in</strong>creasedconsiderably <strong>in</strong> numbers and <strong>countries</strong> concerned,either cover<strong>in</strong>g topics not regulated by the WTOframework or oblig<strong>in</strong>g the signatory states to ahigher level. 7Major rules important to <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land <strong>in</strong> BITs arethe follow<strong>in</strong>g (Smaller and Mann 2009):• The national treatment obligates the targetcountry to treat foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors no less favourablythan domestic <strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>in</strong> “like circumstances”.The def<strong>in</strong>ition of like circumstances iscontentious and will be elaborated by case law.Judgement so far summarises activities <strong>in</strong> onesector – like agricultural production – as a groupof <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> which like circumstances haveto be assumed. Other factors like the size of afarm are not considered to justify differenttreatment. This is why large-scale <strong>in</strong>ternational<strong>in</strong>vestors have to be treated equally to small-sizedomestic farmers <strong>in</strong> the target country.• The most-favoured nation treatment provisionextends the treatment of one foreign <strong>in</strong>vestor toall foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors. Hereby, any privilege forone <strong>in</strong>vestor has to be applied to others as well.This requirement makes BITs different toBilateral Trade Agreements, which can grantpreferential conditions for the partners underdef<strong>in</strong>ed circumstances.• The prohibition of expropriation without compensationis the most crucial element of BITs.Expropriation of the <strong>in</strong>vestor <strong>in</strong> the targetcountry is possible but not without compensation.The scope for apply<strong>in</strong>g expropriation hasnot been def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> a coherent manner e.g.whether a change <strong>in</strong> domestic law for stricterenvironmental standards requires compensation.• The right to export ensures the export of producedcommodities <strong>in</strong> the target country to theforeign <strong>in</strong>vestor’s country. In the case of food,this right can be limited by exceptions such asshortages under GATT and the AoA.6 <strong>FDI</strong> can function as substitutes for imports or <strong>in</strong>crease exports of the target country. In both cases trade flows and trade quantities and world marketprices are <strong>in</strong>fluenced (compare GOPINATH et al, 1999). This is why <strong>FDI</strong> have an impact for other <strong>countries</strong> and the WTO deals with trade distortions thatcan result from <strong>FDI</strong>.7 BITs have ga<strong>in</strong>ed explod<strong>in</strong>g relevance and the number of signed treaties has <strong>in</strong>creased tenfold s<strong>in</strong>ce the 1990s up to 2,676 signed treaties <strong>in</strong> 2008 (UNCTAD2009): recent key signatories are Germany and Ch<strong>in</strong>a, conclud<strong>in</strong>g most BITs <strong>in</strong> 2008. Among develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong> those from Asia and Oceania dom<strong>in</strong>ate,sign<strong>in</strong>g 31 new BITs <strong>in</strong> 2008 alone (UNCTAD 2009). African <strong>countries</strong> had signed 687 BIT by 2006, up from 193 <strong>in</strong> 1995 (UNCTAD, 2008a, p. 24 and 26).


17• The access to logistic <strong>in</strong>frastructure and <strong>in</strong>termediategoods. Hereby, the right is ensured thatthe <strong>in</strong>vestor can use all <strong>in</strong>termediates and thetarget country’s <strong>in</strong>frastructure for his production.This <strong>in</strong>cludes the access to water and energy.• Safeguards and protect<strong>in</strong>g clauses support thetarget country <strong>in</strong> times of balanc<strong>in</strong>g paymentsimbalances to restrict capital flows. Additionally,<strong>in</strong> phases of conflicts, public <strong>in</strong>terest can limitaccess to <strong>in</strong>ternal <strong>in</strong>frastructure.<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land <strong>in</strong> the context of TransnationalCorporations<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land is a specific form of TransnationalCorporations (TNC) along the value cha<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>agriculture. With<strong>in</strong> the World <strong>Investment</strong> Report(UNCTAD 2009b) three pr<strong>in</strong>cipal forms ofTransnational Corporation are identified:• “Indirect, non-equity participation throughimplementation of standards and other <strong>in</strong>formation-<strong>in</strong>tensiverelationships <strong>in</strong> which a targetcountry farmer/firm produces to the specificationsof a foreign TNC …”• “<strong>Direct</strong>, non-equity participation throughcontract farm<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong> which target-countryfarmers/firms are tightly coord<strong>in</strong>ated andcontrolled by the TNC, which may also provide<strong>in</strong>puts and assistance ….”• <strong>Direct</strong> equity participation through <strong>FDI</strong>,whereby coord<strong>in</strong>ation and control of transactionsare fully <strong>in</strong>ternalised with<strong>in</strong> the TNC.This classification highlights that contract farm<strong>in</strong>gis not covered by the term <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land. However,contract farm<strong>in</strong>g may lead to similar resultsbecause of an asymmetric distribution of power <strong>in</strong>the value cha<strong>in</strong>: The foreign buyers may exercisea high degree of control over the producers ofagricultural products which are usually lesspowerful and much smaller (UNCTAD 2009b).Those networks are called “Captive networks” 8 .Private <strong>in</strong>ternational contracts on <strong>in</strong>vestmentprojects <strong>in</strong> land identify “the key elements ofthe fiscal and economic barga<strong>in</strong> relat<strong>in</strong>g tothe <strong>in</strong>vestment” (Smaller and Mann 2009).Because of the private nature, <strong>in</strong>formation aboutthese contracts can hardly be obta<strong>in</strong>ed. Theyconta<strong>in</strong> the specifics of the transaction not only <strong>in</strong>terms of quantity, price and duration for purchaseor lease. They also may conta<strong>in</strong> treatment issueslike taxation, export and import requirements orrules on us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>termediate goods and <strong>in</strong>frastructure.Where no reference is found <strong>in</strong> the contract,the domestic law is applicable (Smaller andMann 2009).Private contracts have been sett<strong>in</strong>g legal standards,as their requirements often are transferred togeneral domestic legislation (Smaller and Mann2009). Individual <strong>in</strong>vestor <strong>countries</strong> and firmsmay take over a lead<strong>in</strong>g role by design<strong>in</strong>g theirspecific contracts and thereby <strong>in</strong>directly chang<strong>in</strong>gdomestic law <strong>in</strong> target <strong>countries</strong>.<strong>Investment</strong> rules and especially BITs are oftenblamed for protect<strong>in</strong>g only the <strong>in</strong>vestor’s <strong>in</strong>terests.Even though <strong>in</strong>ternational rules may arise fromthis objective, it must be stated that the overallscope rema<strong>in</strong>s for the target country to protectdomestic <strong>in</strong>terests.One dom<strong>in</strong>ant rule is that compensation forforeign <strong>in</strong>vestors – once they have entered themarket – has to be guaranteed <strong>in</strong> case of expropriation.But whether all changes <strong>in</strong> domesticlegislation must be def<strong>in</strong>ed as expropriation hasnot been def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> a coherent manner.But prior to enter<strong>in</strong>g the market, certa<strong>in</strong> sectorscan be excluded from access – which is often thecase due to domestic law e.g. land or water.Performance requirements such as environmentalobligations or ensur<strong>in</strong>g local employment can bedef<strong>in</strong>ed, protect<strong>in</strong>g clauses <strong>in</strong> phases of national<strong>in</strong>security can restrict exports and food exportscan be pr<strong>in</strong>cipally imposed <strong>in</strong> the WTO frame <strong>in</strong>case of shortages.<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land also has a very close l<strong>in</strong>k to thehuman right to food 9 because <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land canhave an impact on the access to land by the ruralpopulation. It is generally admitted that access toland plays a key role for rural livelihood and forreduc<strong>in</strong>g poverty. So large-scale land acquisitionsby foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors and the loss of access to landfor the local population can directly <strong>in</strong>fluencerural development and the possibilities to enhance8 For forms of global value cha<strong>in</strong> governance compare for example STURGEON and GEREFFI (2008).9 The right to food is part of the Universal Declaration of Human Rights (Art. 25) and of the International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights(Art.11).


18<strong>Land</strong> for SaleRice fieldit. The frequently used terms “land grab”, “landgrabb<strong>in</strong>g” or “the new neo-colonialism” <strong>in</strong>dicatethe negative attitude towards <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land.Regard<strong>in</strong>g the opportunities and risks of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>land, some specifics of agricultural productioncompared to other sectors have to be considered(De Schutter, 2009).The dom<strong>in</strong>ant negative attitude towards <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>land may lead to an ignorance of possible developmentperspectives. Major objective therefore,should be to enhance the positive potential byavoid<strong>in</strong>g negative effects. The human right to foodis not directly enforceable by law, but plays a role<strong>in</strong> shift<strong>in</strong>g more awareness to susta<strong>in</strong>able foodsecurity policies: The UN developed voluntaryguidel<strong>in</strong>es which may serve as a coherent tool boxby comb<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g different measures at differentpolitical levels and by comb<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g legal <strong>in</strong>strumentsand development strategies.Despite <strong>in</strong>ternational frameworks and agreements,the domestic law <strong>in</strong> the target country is themajor basis for access of a foreign <strong>in</strong>vestor and fortreat<strong>in</strong>g him once he <strong>in</strong>vested. Regard<strong>in</strong>g access toa target country, certa<strong>in</strong> sectors and activities canbe excluded from foreign property, which often isthe case for land acquisitions and lease. Aftergett<strong>in</strong>g market access, national treatment isrequired. This treatment refers to the overallbundle of national legal requirements like propertyrights <strong>in</strong> land and water, labour rights, humanhealth and safety, taxes or environmental standards.Rights stemm<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>vestmentagreements are layered over the domestic lawand domestic laws and government activity that is<strong>in</strong>consistent with the <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>vestmentagreement can be challenged by the <strong>in</strong>vestor(Smaller and Mann , 2009).


19In the context of land use rights, related domesticlaw is often characterised by legal pluralism with amixture of official and <strong>in</strong>formal land provisions.Informal land rights are based on tradition andmutual recognition with<strong>in</strong> the rural communities.A lack of recognition of these <strong>in</strong>formal land rightsby the state makes it difficult for landholders toenforce their traditional rights.This <strong>in</strong>dicates that the target country plays anactive part <strong>in</strong> weigh<strong>in</strong>g domestic <strong>in</strong>terests and hasthe potential to protect susta<strong>in</strong>ability and foodsecurity.But even if such protective aims are followed onpaper, very often the enforcement is lack<strong>in</strong>g: theright to compensate domestic owners for expropriationwith<strong>in</strong> the target country itself very oftenis laid down <strong>in</strong> domestic law. However, it oftenfails due to miss<strong>in</strong>g cadastre systems and propertydocumentation.


203. Possible impacts of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land ontarget <strong>countries</strong> <strong>in</strong> terms of susta<strong>in</strong>abledevelopmentThe recent foreign large-scale <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong>land have been strongly criticised especially bysome NGOs and <strong>in</strong>ternational developmentorganisations (E.G. Gra<strong>in</strong>, 2008, Oppeln andSchneider (Welthungerhilfe), 2009). Thoseorganisations h<strong>in</strong>t at possible negative impacts forthe target <strong>countries</strong> and especially for the localpoor. The expropriation of local landholders andthe loss of adequate accessto land supposedly result <strong>in</strong> negative consequencesfor local food supply (food security) and for theenvironment. On the other hand, some authorshighlight opportunities for economic developmentand poverty reduction <strong>in</strong> targeted areas throughe.g. job and <strong>in</strong>come creation, technologicaltransfers, know-how spill over effects and <strong>in</strong>frastructuralimprovements (e.g. v. Braun andMe<strong>in</strong>zen-Dick (IFPRI), 2009; Cotula et al.(IIED, FAO, IFAD), 2009, p. 5).Negative or positive, the consequences of <strong>FDI</strong><strong>in</strong> land for a particular target country and itspopulation strongly depend on the nationalspecific circumstances, both <strong>in</strong> overall economicand legal terms, the contractual framework andthe capability of national <strong>in</strong>stitutions <strong>in</strong> boththe <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g and target <strong>countries</strong> to controland assert compliance with the contracts. Internationalrules and <strong>in</strong>stitutions may support aneffective implementation. S<strong>in</strong>ce many of theactual negotiations about land deals lacktransparency, are characterised by powerasymmetries and do not encompass code ofconducts <strong>in</strong> favour of the poor (Smaller andMann , 2009, p. 3), it is <strong>in</strong> question whetherunder the current framework positive effects canoutweigh the negative.With this <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>d any <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> controll<strong>in</strong>g theeffects of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land should focus on thedef<strong>in</strong>ition of a code of conduct and the capabilitiesof national and <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>stitutions. Theyshould design and implement agreements <strong>in</strong> a waythat ensures susta<strong>in</strong>able development by benefitt<strong>in</strong>gthe local population and by address<strong>in</strong>gdevelop<strong>in</strong>g goals for the affected regions.To develop pr<strong>in</strong>ciples and an <strong>in</strong>ternational frameworkto promote responsible <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> agriculture,a roundtable was convened <strong>in</strong> New York on23 September 2009 concurrent with the 64thUnited Nations General Assembly (Governmentof Japan, World Bank, FAO, IFAD, UNCTAD2009). The roundtable was co-chaired by thegovernment of Japan, World Bank, FAO, IFADand UNCTAD. Representative stakeholders from31 governments and 13 organisations attended themeet<strong>in</strong>g. 10The roundtable can be regarded as a first steptowards a coord<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong>ternational response toresponsible <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> agriculture associatedwith acquisition of rights to land and relatedresources.In its World <strong>Investment</strong> Report 2009 theUNCTAD analyses the impact of TransnationalCorporations on the production <strong>in</strong> targeted10 The Roundtable was attended by over 70 people from 31 <strong>countries</strong> and 13 organizations. The participants <strong>in</strong>cluded representatives from the Governmentsof Australia, Belarus, Brazil, Bulgaria, Cameroon, Canada, Central African Republic, Comoros, Denmark, Egypt, France, Germany, Ghana, Holy See, India,Indonesia, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, Moldova, Pakistan, Papua New Gu<strong>in</strong>ea, Sao Tome and Pr<strong>in</strong>cipe, Saudi Arabia, South Africa, South Korea, Sweden,Switzerland, Tanzania, United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, United States of America, European Union, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO), InternationalFund for Agricultural Development (IFAD), International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI), Organisation for Economic Co-operation andDevelopment (OECD), The United Nation Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD), The World Bank, The United Nation World Food Programme (WFP),Global Donor Platform for Rural Development, International Institute for Susta<strong>in</strong>able Development, International <strong>Land</strong> Coalition, Rabobank International andYara International.


21develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong> as well as the impact on theenvironment, social effects and political implicationsand consequences for food security. Accord<strong>in</strong>gto this analysis it was concluded: “The actualimpacts of TNC participation vary greatly across<strong>countries</strong> and types of agricultural goods, and are<strong>in</strong>fluenced by a range of factors, especially themode of TNC <strong>in</strong>volvement and the target-country<strong>in</strong>stitutional environment.”So the follow<strong>in</strong>g chapter aims at summaris<strong>in</strong>gpossible effects of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land. It serves as aframework for a comprehensive evaluation of<strong>in</strong>vestments by systematis<strong>in</strong>g relevant areas ofimpacts to be considered. Furthermore, identify<strong>in</strong>gthe drawbacks of exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestments mayserve as a basis for improv<strong>in</strong>g future contracts andagreements that result <strong>in</strong> a w<strong>in</strong>-w<strong>in</strong> situation forthe <strong>in</strong>vestor and for the local economy.3.1. Possible economic impacts of<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land on rural livelihoodsIn general terms, <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land can enhanceeconomic development and contribute to povertyreduction by <strong>in</strong>itiat<strong>in</strong>g growth <strong>in</strong> the local economy.On the other hand it can have a negativeimpact on local economies by detract<strong>in</strong>g access toa production factor that is of outstand<strong>in</strong>g importancefor its development.A multitude of direct and <strong>in</strong>direct effects can arisefrom <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land.<strong>Direct</strong> positive socio-economic effects can besummarised as follows:• Increas<strong>in</strong>g productivity on agricultural land.This can be achieved if <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land is connectedto better access to agricultural <strong>in</strong>puts (e.g. seeds,fertiliser and capital) or by apply<strong>in</strong>g technologiesthat raise yields and reduce post-harvest lossesand by educat<strong>in</strong>g employees and farmers.<strong>Investment</strong>s <strong>in</strong> irrigation schemes can lead tomore efficient use of exist<strong>in</strong>g resources.• Valoris<strong>in</strong>g or augment<strong>in</strong>g of marg<strong>in</strong>al land bymelioration measures (i.e. irrigation schemes,dams, terraces, etc.).• Market access for farmers <strong>in</strong> rural areas ofdevelop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong>.• Generat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>come by leasehold.• Generat<strong>in</strong>g tax <strong>in</strong>come by levy land taxes orland transfer tax, the establishment of newfirms, by the <strong>in</strong>crease of employment and byraised consumption.• Improv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>frastructure by build<strong>in</strong>g roads, or<strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> transportation and communication.• Increas<strong>in</strong>g agricultural exports due to <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>goverall productivity and product quality.Some of these potential improvements can alsoeasily go <strong>in</strong> the other direction and dependstrongly on the design of <strong>FDI</strong>: whether exportsreally grow is determ<strong>in</strong>ed by the replacement offormer export flows. If land areas were formerlydedicated to export production then simply adisplac<strong>in</strong>g occurs. The tax <strong>in</strong>come may be evenlower than before if tax breaks are offered toattract <strong>in</strong>vestments. Consumption taxes cancollapse if <strong>in</strong>come losses appear due to a loss <strong>in</strong>rural livelihood.Indirect positive impacts affect not only thenarrow production of agricultural raw material.<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land can lead to a transfer of know-howand to a better <strong>in</strong>tegration of the local economy<strong>in</strong>to added value cha<strong>in</strong>s. Additionally, positiveeffects can occur by spill over impacts for thelocal economy. On-farm and off-farm bus<strong>in</strong>ess


22(process<strong>in</strong>g) may offer additional revenues, andthus stimulate economic growth. Increasedcommodity production for exports generatesforeign currencies and additional taxes and mayexpand the scope of national governments to<strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> projects that improve liv<strong>in</strong>g conditions.Negative effects of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land may affect thefollow<strong>in</strong>g areas:• Reduced food security <strong>in</strong> the target countrywhen food crops are not available for localconsumption (e.g. export or replacement with<strong>in</strong>dustrial crops). This is of outstand<strong>in</strong>g importance<strong>in</strong> light of the human right to food. Asa matter of fact, some of the relevant target<strong>countries</strong> for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land are dependent onfood aid e.g. Madagascar, Sudan or Cambodia(Haralambous et al., (IFAD), 2009).• Biased distribution of benefits <strong>in</strong> favour of the<strong>in</strong>vestor or just some parts of the local population,not alleviat<strong>in</strong>g poverty but fuel<strong>in</strong>g socialconflicts. Additionally, the states’ bureaucracymay appear <strong>in</strong> the barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g process due tocorruption or <strong>in</strong>effective governance controlmechanisms. This does not only reflect welfarelosses, but leads to less acceptance of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>land.• Competition <strong>in</strong> land use for food, animal feed,and agro-fuels with the poor suffer<strong>in</strong>g from highprices for land and water resources.• Increase of local and regional unemploymentwhen apply<strong>in</strong>g labour extensive mechanisation.As very often women are <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> cropproduction, they can be most affected by thisdevelopment.Specific problems may occur if water is a scareresource and <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land leads to a change <strong>in</strong> theavailability for local farmers. The above mentionednegative effects may be <strong>in</strong>tensified.It is often argued that <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land is related toland that is marg<strong>in</strong>al, “underutilised” or “abandoned”and, therefore, does not negatively affectthe local economy.Marg<strong>in</strong>al landMarg<strong>in</strong>al lands are lands with very low productivity and difficult to cultivate due to naturaland economic conditions (e.g. climate, soil properties, soil degradation, lack of marketaccess). Marg<strong>in</strong>ality does not imply that land cannot be used or improved. Marg<strong>in</strong>al landsare often used as pasture, for the production of fuel wood and for some food crops <strong>in</strong><strong>countries</strong> where land is rare.UnderutilisedUnderutilised lands are characterised by the fact that its production capacities and its rateof return are not fully exploited.Abandoned landAbandoned land is land that was used before and is now abandoned because of market and/or political developments.


23However, such lands are often important forthe livelihoods of poor rural communities. Forexample, they are used for graz<strong>in</strong>g, livestocktransit routes, as well as for collection of fuelwood, biomass, wild fruits and nuts, medic<strong>in</strong>alplants and natural products. Moreover, they grantaccess to water sources. Such lands can contributeup to a quarter of the <strong>in</strong>come of poor households,with the poorest households be<strong>in</strong>g most dependenton them. The role of this land becomes even morecrucial <strong>in</strong> times or conditions of shock (e.g. cropfailure, HIV/AIDS) and for the most vulnerablegroups. Furthermore, the tenure status of this landmay be very complex, with the state assert<strong>in</strong>g landownership but exercis<strong>in</strong>g little control at locallevel, and local groups claim<strong>in</strong>g rights based onlocal customary tenure systems that may lacklegally enforceable status. In such a context,demand from outside for land may further underm<strong>in</strong>ethe land rights of rural communities (seealso v. Braun and Me<strong>in</strong>zen-Dick, 2009).3.2. Possible socio-cultural impacts of<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land on rural livelihoodsSocio-cultural impacts of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land on rurallivelihoods and <strong>in</strong> terms of susta<strong>in</strong>able developmentare closely related to the above-mentionedeconomic effects.As positive effects, follow<strong>in</strong>g improvements arepossible:• Improv<strong>in</strong>g liv<strong>in</strong>g conditions and susta<strong>in</strong>abledevelopment by additional <strong>in</strong>come possibilities<strong>in</strong> rural areas which can be l<strong>in</strong>ked to the employmentoption with<strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>vestments projectdirectly or due to an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> other bus<strong>in</strong>essoptions like cater<strong>in</strong>g and others. Additionally,liv<strong>in</strong>g standards may be <strong>in</strong>creased if overallliv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>frastructures may be improved e.g. byestablish<strong>in</strong>g schools or health care organisations.• Reactivation of abandoned land and valueadd<strong>in</strong>g of underutilised land leads to <strong>in</strong>comegeneration <strong>in</strong> rural areas.• An <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> work<strong>in</strong>g standards is possible ifforeign <strong>in</strong>vestors apply their domestic standardsto the employees which may be higher thanthose <strong>in</strong> target <strong>countries</strong>.• Better <strong>in</strong>tegration of smallholder/family farmers,who may <strong>in</strong>tegrate <strong>in</strong> associations.• An <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> civil safety and political stabilitycan be the outcome of improved liv<strong>in</strong>g conditionsand a better <strong>in</strong>tegration of local small-sizefarmers.Depend<strong>in</strong>g on the specific design, these abovementionedadvantages may not be achieved but<strong>in</strong>stead turn <strong>in</strong>to a burden for the target countryif the follow<strong>in</strong>g possible negative effects occur:• A strong competition for rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g land can<strong>in</strong>voke land conflicts, lead<strong>in</strong>g to civil andpolitical <strong>in</strong>stability.• Reduc<strong>in</strong>g access of land and marg<strong>in</strong>alisation ofsmall-size land owners has negative effects onany development geared towards the needs ofthe poor. Reduced access to land can lead todisplacement of <strong>in</strong>digenous people or theexclusion of rural communities and <strong>in</strong>creaserural poverty, especially for women. Access touse of common lands can be restricted (collect<strong>in</strong>gfuel wood, wild fruits, medic<strong>in</strong>al plants, etc.or graz<strong>in</strong>g livestock). As a consequence, socioculturalcohabitation between different socioprofessionalgroups (e.g. livestock and cropfarmers, pastoralists, etc.) can be impeded.• Emigration of local farmers can <strong>in</strong>crease socialtensions and urban poverty. If former landownerslose their livelihood this may <strong>in</strong>duce amigration flow <strong>in</strong>to cities and <strong>in</strong>crease urbanburden or poverty. Plus, a loss of <strong>in</strong>herentcultural habits may occur.• Immigration of foreign employers can <strong>in</strong>vokesocial frictions. Income disparities <strong>in</strong> localcommunities may arise from the fact that oftenhighly educated management personnel will berecruited from the <strong>in</strong>vestor’s <strong>countries</strong> whereaslow-level work will probably be done by localpersonnel. Especially if the imported employersbenefit from better work<strong>in</strong>g standards or a firm’sbetter healthcare system, social frictions can<strong>in</strong>crease. Cultural and l<strong>in</strong>gual divergences canalso worsen social systems.


243.3. Possible environmental impacts of<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land on rural livelihoodsThe ecological susta<strong>in</strong>ability <strong>in</strong> agriculturalproduction is an important subject <strong>in</strong> the contextof large-scale foreign <strong>in</strong>vestments. Apply<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>tensive agricultural production has an impacton biodiversity, carbon stocks, and land, soil andwater resources.Positive effects can be:• An <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> environmental-friendly productionmethods can take place if foreign <strong>in</strong>vestorsimport practices which are more susta<strong>in</strong>ablecompared to local ones <strong>in</strong> the target country –due to a higher level of education and bettertechnical capacities. Plus, imported qualitystandards for food production may have apositive <strong>in</strong>fluence.• A reduction of erosion can be <strong>in</strong>voked byproduc<strong>in</strong>g on formerly abandoned land.These positive effects may spread to rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gareas for local producers: Tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g local farmers <strong>in</strong>environmentally sound production can strengthenawareness for the underly<strong>in</strong>g problems. In addition,it can have spill-over effects for other farmsand lead as a kick-off for a comprehensive naturalresource management.However, negative impacts may be the follow<strong>in</strong>g:• Increase <strong>in</strong> erosion and worsen climate changeby displac<strong>in</strong>g forest areas and other land usechanges, which result <strong>in</strong> high carbon stockreleases. Especially if fire clean<strong>in</strong>g takes place.• A loss <strong>in</strong> water availability and quality (sal<strong>in</strong>ity,water logg<strong>in</strong>g) may be <strong>in</strong>voked by large-scalewater use and use of pesticides and fertiliser.• A loss <strong>in</strong> soil quality can be caused as well by anunsusta<strong>in</strong>able use of chemicals.• A reduction of biodiversity may be caused bylarge-scale monoculture production systems.• Disruption of the local ecologic systems by<strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g plants or species that are not part ofthe local biodiversity (e.g. eucalyptus, palm treesand rubber <strong>in</strong> some areas).Regard<strong>in</strong>g possible impacts of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land, thereare a lot of possible positive as well as negativeconsequences. <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land can neither be fullycondemned nor supported without restrictions.The actual consequences depend on the design ofthe <strong>in</strong>dividual projects and the conditions <strong>in</strong> thetarget <strong>countries</strong>. Economic, societal and environmentalconsequences cannot be assessed <strong>in</strong> generaland detached from the <strong>in</strong>dividual projects. Inaddition, it seems to be necessary not to assume as<strong>in</strong>gle <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> the target country. Rather, itshould be differentiated between the <strong>in</strong>terests ofdifferent groups with<strong>in</strong> the society. So <strong>FDI</strong> maybr<strong>in</strong>g development to the region but peopleorig<strong>in</strong>ally liv<strong>in</strong>g here may experience a negativeimpact on their livelihood.Harvest


26scale, with 0 be<strong>in</strong>g the best score (no hunger) and100 be<strong>in</strong>g the worst, though neither of theseextremes is achieved <strong>in</strong> practice. Values less than4.9 reflect low hunger, values between 5 and 9.9reflect moderate hunger, values between 10 and19.9 <strong>in</strong>dicate a serious problem, values between 20and 29.9 are alarm<strong>in</strong>g, and values exceed<strong>in</strong>g 30are extremely alarm<strong>in</strong>g. Though the proportion ofpeople who are calorie deficient is <strong>in</strong>tegrated <strong>in</strong> theGHI, this <strong>in</strong>formation is also listed separately <strong>in</strong>the country profiles.Additionally, the relevance of agriculture isaddressed by its share of GDP and overall employment.The higher its relevance especially as anemployment option, the larger a potential burdento rural livelihood, if foreign <strong>in</strong>vestments displaceslocal employers.Moreover, food security is described by theamount of food aid, the food import bill and theclassification of the <strong>countries</strong> accord<strong>in</strong>g to theFAO as a country <strong>in</strong> crisis.Biodiversity and overall environmental conditionsare addressed with <strong>in</strong>dicators represent<strong>in</strong>g the area<strong>in</strong> each country that is protected area, the deforestationrate and overall share of forests <strong>in</strong> totalarea. The deforestation rate can only serve asproxy variable for loss of biodiversity as it primarily<strong>in</strong>dicates the annual loss of forest area and,therefore, the ongo<strong>in</strong>g loss of area relevant forclimate and soil and groundwater quality. The useof fire cultivation can give a h<strong>in</strong>t whether thispotential damage to the environment is an appliedcultivation habit with<strong>in</strong> a country. Additionally, it<strong>in</strong>dicates the already exist<strong>in</strong>g pressure to accedenew land.Overall economyAll case <strong>countries</strong> belong to the category of leastdeveloped <strong>countries</strong> (LDC), which have a GDPper capita below 900 US$ and/or are highlyeconomically vulnerable e.g. due to low diversificationand/or have weak human assets like education.The share of population liv<strong>in</strong>g below thepoverty l<strong>in</strong>e of 2 US$ lies <strong>in</strong> all <strong>countries</strong> higherthan 65% and is the highest <strong>in</strong> Madagascar withnearly 90% <strong>in</strong> 2000-2006. If economic developmentis a goal of the society, there is an urgentneed for <strong>in</strong>vestments. Especially Mali attracts alarge amount of ODA for agriculture with 72million US$ <strong>in</strong> 2007.Relevance of agricultureIn all cases, agriculture plays a very relevant rolefor the overall economy. Especially as regards toemployment, agriculture plays an important role<strong>in</strong> all of the <strong>countries</strong>. The share of agriculture<strong>in</strong> GDP reaches from about 30% <strong>in</strong> Cambodia,Madagascar and Mali to 45% <strong>in</strong> Lao PDR. Inlight of this, <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land affects a sector that isof outstand<strong>in</strong>g importance for employment <strong>in</strong> allof the four <strong>countries</strong> (<strong>in</strong> the EU it is 4%).Food securityData on food security reveals a need for improvement,even though the <strong>countries</strong> are not classifiedas “<strong>countries</strong> <strong>in</strong> crisis” accord<strong>in</strong>g to the FAO.However, all four <strong>countries</strong> can be seen as vulnerableto food <strong>in</strong>security. The GHI states an alarm<strong>in</strong>gstatus for all <strong>countries</strong>. All receive food aidand all except Mali paid large food bills <strong>in</strong> 2006,most <strong>in</strong> Cambodia (FAO 2009b). Tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>toaccount the percentage of people liv<strong>in</strong>g below thepoverty l<strong>in</strong>e, it is obvious that <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land mayworsen the situation of the poor if it does notcreate additional <strong>in</strong>come opportunities.Environment and BiodiversityWith respect to the environmental conditions andbiodiversity, the share of protected areas differsconsiderably between the Asian and the African<strong>countries</strong>. The forestry area is the highest <strong>in</strong> LaoPDR. Forests are an important source of <strong>in</strong>come.Official data from 2002 (MAFF) reported that42% of land area was covered with forest. A morecurrent estimate by the end of 2007 from theNational <strong>Land</strong> Management Authority reported35%. Even though a high protection rate canbe found for Cambodia, their deforestation rateis the largest with 2% per year. In Mali – forexample – fire cultivation destroy<strong>in</strong>g about 14million ha pasture per year.<strong>Investment</strong> climateSome <strong>in</strong>formation characteris<strong>in</strong>g the overallclimate for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> the case study <strong>countries</strong> issummarised <strong>in</strong> the country profiles. The <strong>in</strong>vestment<strong>in</strong>dicators of the World Bank reflect howattractive a target country is for foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors.They rank a s<strong>in</strong>gle country’s position with<strong>in</strong>an overall list of 181 evaluated <strong>countries</strong> – thelarger the position, the worse the <strong>in</strong>vestmentattractiveness.


27With respect to “ease of do<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess”, thefour <strong>countries</strong> are ranked <strong>in</strong>to the last quarter ofthe surveyed <strong>countries</strong>. Concern<strong>in</strong>g corruption,Madagascar and Mali are much less affected thanCambodia and Lao PDR.Regard<strong>in</strong>g the degree of how target <strong>countries</strong>protect foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors’ rights, there areremarkable differences between the <strong>countries</strong>:Madagascar and Cambodia are perceived asprotect<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestors much better compared toMali or Lao PDR. But Lao PDR is perceivedto be best <strong>in</strong> “enforc<strong>in</strong>g contracts”.The corruption perception <strong>in</strong>dex (CPI), puttogether by Transparency International, ranksmore than 180 <strong>countries</strong> by their perceived levelsof corruption, as determ<strong>in</strong>ed by expert assessmentsand op<strong>in</strong>ion surveys. Scores assigned rema<strong>in</strong>between 0 and 10 as best score. All case <strong>countries</strong>received bad scores. Madagascar ranks best amongthe case <strong>countries</strong>.In all <strong>countries</strong>, extract<strong>in</strong>g and m<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g play thedom<strong>in</strong>ant role <strong>in</strong> all <strong>FDI</strong>, but <strong>in</strong> Cambodia andLao PDR the share <strong>in</strong> agricultural <strong>FDI</strong> is veryhigh too.Regard<strong>in</strong>g the specific share of <strong>FDI</strong> for agriculture,here there is no comprehensive datasetprovided by the UNCTAD or by other organisations.More specific <strong>in</strong>formation on the <strong>FDI</strong> climate isprovided by the 2009 <strong>Investment</strong> Climate Statementsof the US Bureau of Economic, Energyand Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Affairs of the US State Department.It assesses the <strong>in</strong>vestment climate <strong>in</strong> about 150<strong>countries</strong>. 12Legal multi- and bilateral environmentThe four case <strong>countries</strong> differ greatly <strong>in</strong> their<strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>in</strong> legal arrangements at multi- andbilateral level. Cambodia, Madagascar and Maliare members of the WTO, so that the multilateralprovisions of WTO are applicable. This does nothold for Laos which is not a WTO member.All of the four <strong>countries</strong> have signed a largenumber of BITs. However, agreements do notcover all <strong>countries</strong> that <strong>in</strong>vestors come from. 13This lack of a bilateral frame may be a risk and achance: In the absence of a BIT, the risk for the<strong>in</strong>vestor <strong>in</strong>creases that no compensation is guaranteed<strong>in</strong> the case of expropriation. This leads to aloss <strong>in</strong> attractiveness <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the targetcountry. On the other hand it may raise thebarga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g power for the target country byoffer<strong>in</strong>g such provisions by requir<strong>in</strong>g own conditionsat the same time. In any case, the negotiationof new BITs should carefully balance the exist<strong>in</strong>goutlook for protect<strong>in</strong>g their own <strong>in</strong>terests.Legal domestic environmentThe description on the legal domestic frameworkfocuses on land law, because domestic land law isof special relevance for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land.Data on the size of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land and risks andopportunitiesThe lack of transparency <strong>in</strong> <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land affectsthe attempt to give a comprehensive overview ofthe amount and size of land devoted to foreign<strong>in</strong>vestors. However, some relevant <strong>in</strong>formationwas gathered.Rice harvest12 For general <strong>in</strong>formation compare U.S. State Dpartment, 2009a; for country specific <strong>in</strong>formation see U.S. State Dpartment, 2009b-d.13 The most relevant <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong> for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land <strong>in</strong> Cambodia, Laos, Mali and Madagascar are summarised <strong>in</strong> the tables of the respective country profiles.


28MADAGASCAR MADAGASCAR MADAGASCAR MADAGASCARMADAGASCAR MADAGASCAR MADAGASCAR MADAGASCAR MADAGASCAR MADAGASCARCOUNTRY PROFILEP<strong>in</strong>eapple cultivation Baobab Jatropha plantation Rice fields Intercropp<strong>in</strong>g Jatropha4.2. Country profile – Republic of MadagascarMadagascar lies <strong>in</strong> the Indian Ocean off the southeastern coast of Africa and is the world’s fourth largestisland with a surface of 587,040 km 2 . Table 3 provides an overview of the country profile regard<strong>in</strong>g:• Economy, agriculture, food security, poverty and environment• Overall <strong>in</strong>vestment climate• Legal frame• Pattern of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land


29Table 3: Country profile MadagascarOverall domestic background: Economy, Agriculture, Food security, Poverty and Environment(1) Economic situationGDP per capita, 2008, US$ (a) 457Official Development aid (ODA), 2007, US$ million (b) 892ODA <strong>in</strong> agriculture, forestry and fishery (b)Commitments 2007, US$ millionDisbursements 2007, US$ millionShare of population below poverty l<strong>in</strong>e (2 US$ per day, average 2000-2006) (c) 89.6%(2) Relevance of agricultureShare of <strong>in</strong> GDP (2007) (d) 26%Share of agriculture employment (e) 80% (2007)(3) Food securityGlobal Hunger Index (GHI), 2008 (f) 28.8GHI-Rank<strong>in</strong>g (out of 88 <strong>countries</strong>), 2008 (f) 76Share of undernourished population (f) 37%Food aid, 2008, ‘000 t, cereals <strong>in</strong> gra<strong>in</strong> equivalent (g) 29.6As country <strong>in</strong> crisis accord<strong>in</strong>g to FAO (2009) (h)NoValue of food import m<strong>in</strong>us export, 2006, US$ million (i) -92(4) Environment/ BiodiversityProtected area, % of total area 2003 (k) 3,1%Forestry area, % of total area 2005 (l) 22,1%Deforestation rate (annual change <strong>in</strong> forest covered area, with<strong>in</strong> 2000-05) (i) -0,3%Fire cultivationNo dataOverall <strong>in</strong>vestment climate(1) Climate for <strong>FDI</strong> (m)Ease of do<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess (rank of 181 <strong>countries</strong>) 144Protect<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestors (rank of 181 <strong>countries</strong>) 53Enforc<strong>in</strong>g contracts (rank of 181 <strong>countries</strong>) 153(2) Corruption (n)CPI rank<strong>in</strong>g (rank of 181 <strong>countries</strong>), 2008 (2007) 85 (94)(3) Share of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> agriculture <strong>in</strong> % of all <strong>FDI</strong> average (o)US State Department Climate Statements 2009 (o)No dataWorld <strong>Investment</strong> Report 2009 2005 – 2007 (p) 2% Average 2005-2007Legal Frame(1) Multi- and bilateral frame (q)WTO rules applicable?yesBITs <strong>in</strong> force with major <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land <strong>in</strong>vestor <strong>countries</strong>5 of all <strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>in</strong>cluded(2) Domestic frame (q)Major legal basis684LAW N° 2007-036 dated 14thJanuary 2008 relat<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>in</strong>vestmentlaw <strong>in</strong> Madagascar


30Table 3: Country profile MadagascarPattern of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land(1) Investor country (r)Major <strong>in</strong>vestors, <strong>in</strong> ha(2) Major purpose (r)FoodMa<strong>in</strong> cropsAgrofuelsMa<strong>in</strong> cropsOtherJapanSouth Korea (not yet signed)United K<strong>in</strong>gdomIndiaAustraliaLebanonSouth AfricaItalym<strong>in</strong>orrice, maize, beefdom<strong>in</strong>antjatropha, palm oil, sunflower oilm<strong>in</strong>orSource: (a) IMF, 2009; (b) OECD, 2009; (c) UNDP, 2008; (d) World Bank, 2007; (e) GTZ estimates, 2007; (f) Welthungerhilfe, 2008; (g) FAO2009b, (h) FAO, 2009e; (i) FAO, 2009b; (k) WRI,2009; (l) FAO 2007; (m) World Bank 2009, (n) Transparency International 2008 and2009 (o) U.S. State Department, 2009b-e (p) UNCTAD 2009b (q) UNCTAD, 2009c, GTZ case studies; (r) GTZ case studiesMadagascar is classified as LDC with a GDP percapita of US$ 457 per year with nearly 90% ofthe population hav<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>come below US$ 2per day (on average <strong>in</strong> 2000-2006). The relevanceof agriculture is po<strong>in</strong>ted out by the 26% share ofagriculture <strong>in</strong> GDP and especially by the highpercentage of employment <strong>in</strong> agriculture (80%).Regard<strong>in</strong>g the allocation of total <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> differentsectors, the 2009 <strong>Investment</strong> Climate Statementdoes not imply explicit <strong>in</strong>formation on <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>agriculture for Madagascar. Based on the datapresented <strong>in</strong> the statement, the share of agriculture<strong>in</strong> the overall 2007 <strong>FDI</strong> (777 million US$) is lessthan 3%.The government of Madagascar welcomes <strong>FDI</strong>and is develop<strong>in</strong>g the legal framework to becomemore <strong>in</strong>vestor friendly. A lack of fair competitiveconditions worsens the <strong>in</strong>vestment climate as wellas a lack of transparency <strong>in</strong> contract<strong>in</strong>g, corruptionand governmental regulations. This is viewedas a disadvantage for foreign <strong>in</strong>vestments. Privateentities both foreign and domestic are providedwith the right to establish and own bus<strong>in</strong>essenterprises. The government rema<strong>in</strong>s a m<strong>in</strong>orityshareholder <strong>in</strong> some privatised companies, such asTelma, 14 and cont<strong>in</strong>ues to own Air Madagascar.Competitive equality is officially granted to allprivate enterprises. But <strong>in</strong> practice politicallyconnectedcompanies are given preferential marketaccess. The private sector often compla<strong>in</strong>s aboutgovernment <strong>in</strong>terference <strong>in</strong> some sectors of theeconomy, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g flour and vegetable oil.Legal multi- and bilateral environmentMadagascar signed 9 BITs, but none with a major<strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g country of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land. One BIT withSouth Africa, a relevant <strong>in</strong>vestor, has not entered<strong>in</strong>to force yet. Compensation for expropriation isforeseen and the protect<strong>in</strong>g clauses are comparableto the other <strong>countries</strong>` BITs. One exception refersto the BITs with EU Member States (Germany,Belgium and Luxemburg, France, Sweden). Heretrade restrictions are explicitly excluded not onlyfor the f<strong>in</strong>al product relevant for the <strong>in</strong>vestor butalso for <strong>in</strong>termediate goods and <strong>in</strong>puts relevant totransport and logistics. This <strong>in</strong>dicates a strongpro-<strong>in</strong>vestor attitude.14 State-owned telecommunication company


31Legal domestic environmentAt a domestic level, a reform of the Madagasy<strong>in</strong>vestment law was undertaken <strong>in</strong> 2008 thatensures protection of ownership for <strong>in</strong>vestments,the free movement of capital and equal treatment.Additional rules aim at stabilisation and the fightaga<strong>in</strong>st AIDS (art. 6 and 7): thereby an <strong>in</strong>vestorfriendlyenvironment based on a stable tax systemand a public health programme is envisaged. 15Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the constitution, foreigners are notallowed to own land. In contrast, the <strong>in</strong>vestmentregulation (Loi 2007 du 14 Janvier 2008 sur les <strong>in</strong>vestissementsà Madagascar) allows foreigners accessto land via a company accord<strong>in</strong>g to Malagasy law.This company has the right to lease or to purchaseland. Although the legal situation is not clearlydef<strong>in</strong>ed, <strong>in</strong> fact foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors are generallydemand<strong>in</strong>g long leas<strong>in</strong>g contracts.Before 2005, non-titled land was presumed tobelong to the state. Different activities have beenundertaken ever s<strong>in</strong>ce for implement<strong>in</strong>g a landreform that <strong>in</strong>creases the security of land userights for local farmers and alleviates land accessfor foreigners. The so-called “territoire domanial”has been divided <strong>in</strong>to two parts: One part stillbelongs to the state for specific purposes, but thebiggest is now presumed to belong to communitiesand <strong>in</strong>dividuals. People who are us<strong>in</strong>g the land arenow regarded as owners (proprieté privée nontitrée),but these rights are not yet documentedand, thus, the situation is still <strong>in</strong>secure.In order to <strong>in</strong>crease security of land use rights,another part of the land reform is the <strong>in</strong>troductionof the so called “guichet fonciers”, agencies on acommunal level to document land use rights. Butstill only 22% of farmers have a documentedcertificate on their land ownership. Undocumentedtraditional access still dom<strong>in</strong>ates which oftenleads to conflicts about the ownership of land.Traditionally, land was owned by the family andreceived by heritage. S<strong>in</strong>ce land pressure was lowdur<strong>in</strong>g pre-colonial times, land conflicts occurredrarely and were solved by traditional authorities(raimand’reny). When Madagascar became aFrench colony, the French <strong>in</strong>troduced a cadastralsystem and started document<strong>in</strong>g landownership.But when the French left the country, the cadastralsystem was not used and updated anymore,lead<strong>in</strong>g to the current situation where no landrights are secured.The Malagasy land right system acknowledges alldifferent k<strong>in</strong>ds of land use rights as own<strong>in</strong>g, us<strong>in</strong>g,<strong>in</strong>herit<strong>in</strong>g, leas<strong>in</strong>g, purchas<strong>in</strong>g, as well as usufruct.In the high plateau, where land pressure is thehighest <strong>in</strong> the country, farmers have started to usefertiliser to <strong>in</strong>crease productivity of the land. Also,they use former uncultivated land to augment thequantity of agricultural land. That means that landresources <strong>in</strong> the high plateau are limited, and accessfor foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors is difficult. In the eastern partof the country, where the most natural forest canbe found, tribes still practice slash & burn to ga<strong>in</strong>fertile land. In this region, <strong>FDI</strong> is likely to <strong>in</strong>creaseconflicts between agricultural use and conservationof biodiversity.All <strong>in</strong>vestments over 1,000 ha formally require anenvironmental impact assessment which shouldensure ecological stability and <strong>in</strong>cludes socialaspects. Due to weak governance this obligation isnot always fulfilled. 16 In terms of social impacts,only a third of all documented projects explicitlyaim at local job opportunities or at support<strong>in</strong>g thelocal <strong>in</strong>frastructure. These firms which explicitlyemploy local population <strong>in</strong> the project contractsma<strong>in</strong>ly come from the EU.Data on the size of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land and risks andopportunitiesTable 4 summarises the demand for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land<strong>in</strong> Madagascar from 2005 until March 2009. Allmajor <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land projects are <strong>in</strong>cluded (with morethan 1,000 ha requested by foreign and/or national<strong>in</strong>vestors). This overview still conta<strong>in</strong>s the Daewoocase (1 million ha for food production and 0.3million ha for agro-fuel production), although thisproject has been recently cancelled by the newleader of the transition government <strong>in</strong> Madagascar.15 In compliance with the pr<strong>in</strong>ciples presented <strong>in</strong> Law 2005-040 dated 20th February 2006 relat<strong>in</strong>g to fight aga<strong>in</strong>st HIV/AIDS and protection of the rights ofthose <strong>in</strong>fected with HIV/AIDS, all companies must set up an awareness and education program for their staff as well as make it easy for those wish<strong>in</strong>gto undergo a screen<strong>in</strong>g test.16 The Daewoo case described <strong>in</strong> the country study supports this statement.


32Table 4: Demand for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> Madagascar (2009)Area, <strong>in</strong> ha without the Daewoo project Area, <strong>in</strong> ha <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the Daewoo project<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land (<strong>in</strong> total) 1,720,300 3,020,300<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land for food production 446,500 1,446,500<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land for agro-fuelproduction1,231,700 1,531,700<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land for cash cropproduction9,100 9,100<strong>FDI</strong> for other purposes 33,000 33,000Source: Own researchMost of these demands are still <strong>in</strong> the plann<strong>in</strong>gphase and land contract<strong>in</strong>g has not been f<strong>in</strong>alisedyet.The overall size of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land <strong>in</strong> Madagsacaris the highest of all selected target <strong>countries</strong>,represent<strong>in</strong>g an area equal to nearly 50% of thecurrently cultivated land area. So far the <strong>FDI</strong>`spurpose is dom<strong>in</strong>ated by agro-fuel.In Madagsacar, <strong>in</strong>vestors from European andAmerican <strong>countries</strong> are <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> the productionof agro-fuels, <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g especially <strong>in</strong> Jatropha,whereas Asian <strong>countries</strong> are ma<strong>in</strong>ly look<strong>in</strong>g for<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> food production. In most cases, all productionwill be exported. It is worth not<strong>in</strong>g that<strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>in</strong> agro-fuels are rarely agro-bus<strong>in</strong>esscompanies but either newly established companiesrais<strong>in</strong>g money at the stock exchanges, or from<strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>vestor companies or companieswork<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the petrochemical <strong>in</strong>dustry. This oftenresults <strong>in</strong> bad plantation management due to alack of experience <strong>in</strong> agriculture. Furthermore,Jatropha yields are often tremendously overestimated.The question still is what will happen withthe plantations and the farmers work<strong>in</strong>g on themwhen <strong>in</strong>vestors realise that the expected resultswill never be reached.This is different with <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> food production.In general, companies <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> this type ofproduct are work<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the agro-bus<strong>in</strong>ess sectorand are experienced <strong>in</strong> agricultural production.Social conflicts aris<strong>in</strong>g from the assignment ofland to foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors reveal the sensitivity ofthe citizens with respect to <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land. It is notonly the property rights that fuel the conflicts, butthe role land plays <strong>in</strong> the context of traditionalbeliefs. <strong>Land</strong> is holy and is still owned by theancestors, who play an important role <strong>in</strong> the life ofMalagasy people.After the world economic and f<strong>in</strong>ancial crisis, thedemand for land seemed to dim<strong>in</strong>ish and some ofthe projects have been stopped ma<strong>in</strong>ly due to alack of f<strong>in</strong>ancial resources. In addition, first experiences<strong>in</strong> large-scale and low-cost farm<strong>in</strong>g have leadto disillusionment about the possibilities ofrealis<strong>in</strong>g the envisaged profits.Most <strong>in</strong>vestors seem to be aware of the importanceof the unique biodiversity <strong>in</strong> Madagascar or fearpressure from the numerous <strong>in</strong>ternational NGOswork<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> biodiversity conservation. At least no<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land for agricultural production is knownthat is destroy<strong>in</strong>g bio diverse spots. This is nottrue for m<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g projects. The two big m<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gprojects of Sherritt (Ambatovy) and QMM bothare work<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> hotspot-areas destroy<strong>in</strong>g large areasof ra<strong>in</strong>forest.Impacts on food security differ from project toproject. Some projects might <strong>in</strong>crease food productionor augment revenue of farmers whichcould improve the supply of food for <strong>in</strong>dividualfarmers. Other projects implemented on fertileland produce food for export purposes and wouldonly reduce food security.


33Cocoa HarvestJatropha Nursery of Eco Flower InvestorRice Harvest


34MALI MALI MALI MALI MALI MALI MALIMAL MALI MALI MALI MALI MALI MALI MALI MALI MALI MALI MALI MALI MALICOUNTRY PROFILERural hous<strong>in</strong>g Transportation Harvest Water collection Fertile land4.3. Country Profile – Republic of MaliSituated <strong>in</strong> West Africa, the Republic of Mali covers an area of 1,241,238 km 2 . In 2002, 35.2 % of thisarea was designated arable land and 11.6 % cultivated land. Mali has large conservation areas (4.6 %),forests (26.1 %) and pastureland (24.2 %).Table 5 provides an overview of the country profile regard<strong>in</strong>g:• Economy, agriculture, food security, poverty and environment• Overall <strong>in</strong>vestment climate• Legal framework• Pattern of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land


35Table 5: Country profile Republic of MaliOverall domestic background: Economy, Agriculture, Food security, Poverty and Environment(1) Economic situationGDP per capita, 2008, US$ (a) 657Official Development aid (ODA), 2007, US$ million (b) 1017ODA <strong>in</strong> agriculture, forestry and fishery (b)Commitments 2007, US$ millionDisbursements 2007, US$ millionShare of population below poverty l<strong>in</strong>e (2 US$ per day, average 2000-2006) (c) 77,1%(2) Relevance of agricultureShare <strong>in</strong> GDP (2007) (d) 37%Share of agriculture employment (e) 76% (2004)(3) Food securityGlobal Hunger Index (GHI), 2008 (f) 26.9GHI-Rank<strong>in</strong>g (out of 88 <strong>countries</strong>), 2008 (f) 73Share of undernourished population (f) 11%Food aid, 2008, ‘000 t, cereals <strong>in</strong> gra<strong>in</strong> equivalent (g) 23.6As country <strong>in</strong> crisis accord<strong>in</strong>g to FAO (2009) (h)NoValue of food import m<strong>in</strong>us export, 2006, US$ million (i) 36(4) Environment/ BiodiversityProtected area, % of total area 2003 (k) 3,7%Forestry area, % of total area 2005 (l) 10,3%Deforestation rate (annual change <strong>in</strong> forest covered area, with<strong>in</strong> 2000-05) (i) -0,8%Fire cultivation3% of total areaOverall <strong>in</strong>vestment climate(1) Climate for <strong>FDI</strong> (m)Ease of do<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess (rank of 181 <strong>countries</strong>) 166Protect<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestors (rank of 181 <strong>countries</strong>) 150Enforc<strong>in</strong>g contracts (rank of 181 <strong>countries</strong>) 158(2) Corruption (n)CPI rank<strong>in</strong>g (rank of 181 <strong>countries</strong>), 2008 (2007) 96 (118)(3) Share of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> agriculture <strong>in</strong> % of all <strong>FDI</strong> average (o)US State Department Climate Statements 2009 (o)No dataWorld <strong>Investment</strong> Report 2009 2005 – 2007 (p)No dataLegal Frame(1) Multi- and bilateral frame (q)WTO rules applicable?yesNo relevant <strong>in</strong>vestor <strong>in</strong>cluded, butBITs <strong>in</strong> force with major <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land <strong>in</strong>vestor <strong>countries</strong>existence of a frame contractbetween Mali and Libya, which maynot be called a BIT(2) Domestic frame (q)Major legal basis28372<strong>Investment</strong> Code, National<strong>Investment</strong> Law (Loi 91-48/ANRM,March 1991)


36Table 5: Country profile Republic of MaliPattern of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land(1) Investor country (r)Major <strong>in</strong>vestors, <strong>in</strong> ha Lybia (86%)South AfricaCh<strong>in</strong>aUSA(2) Major purpose (r)Fooddom<strong>in</strong>antrice, millet, corn, sorgo, cotton,Ma<strong>in</strong> cropssugar, jatropha, mangoAgrofuelsMa<strong>in</strong> cropsOtherm<strong>in</strong>orjatrophaSource: (a) IMF, 2009; (b) OECD, 2009; (c) UNDP, 2008; (d) World Bank, 2007; (e) GTZ estimates, 2007; (f) Welthungerhilfe, 2008; (g) FAO2009b, (h) FAO, 2009e; (i) FAO, 2009b; (k) WRI,2009; (l) FAO 2007; (m) World Bank 2009, (n) Transparency International 2008 and2009 (o) U.S. State Department, 2009b-e (p) UNCTAD 2009b (q) UNCTAD, 2009c, GTZ case studies; (r) GTZ case studiesm<strong>in</strong>orAgriculture plays an important role <strong>in</strong> Mali´seconomy. Its share of GDP is about 37%. Maliattracts <strong>in</strong> particular a large amount of ODA foragriculture with 72 million US$ <strong>in</strong> 2007. 76% ofthe population is employed <strong>in</strong> agriculture. About77% of the population lives below the povertyl<strong>in</strong>e. Mali receives food aid. In 2008, the amountof food aid was estimated at 23.600 t cereals <strong>in</strong>gra<strong>in</strong> equivalent (g).As regards to the allocation of total <strong>FDI</strong> todifferent sectors, the 2009 <strong>Investment</strong> ClimateStatements <strong>in</strong>clude some <strong>in</strong>formation based onnational statistics. In 2004, South African<strong>in</strong>vestors and others pledged to <strong>in</strong>vest aboutUS$ 100 million <strong>in</strong> agro-bus<strong>in</strong>ess. The <strong>in</strong>vestmentwas later postponed to 2009. There is no evidencethese <strong>in</strong>vestments have taken placeso far.The Malian government succeeded <strong>in</strong> encourag<strong>in</strong>g<strong>FDI</strong> and foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors are not discrim<strong>in</strong>atedaga<strong>in</strong>st. Enhanced structural adjustment facility(ESAF) agreements signed by the IMF/WorldBank and Mali and are <strong>in</strong> force s<strong>in</strong>ce 1992. Theseagreements encourage the mobilisation of externalresources to boost <strong>in</strong>vestment. The government’snational strategy to fight poverty presented to theIMF/World Bank and other donors emphasisesthe role of the private sector <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g theeconomy.<strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestors can own 100% of any bus<strong>in</strong>essesthey create and purchase shares <strong>in</strong> privatisedparastatal companies. Access to land is providedon the basis of renewable long-term leases of up to50 years, respectively 99 years.The tax system is complicated even though someefforts have been made to improve it. <strong>Foreign</strong><strong>in</strong>vestors sometimes report that tax laws are<strong>in</strong>terpreted <strong>in</strong> a way that discrim<strong>in</strong>ates aga<strong>in</strong>stforeign <strong>in</strong>vestors.Legal multi- and bilateral environmentMali altogether signed 15 BITs, but the dom<strong>in</strong>ant<strong>in</strong>vestor country, Libya, which holds 85% of all<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land, is not <strong>in</strong>cluded as a partner countryof BITs. However, Mali and Libya signed acooperation agreement which serves as a frameworkfor all jo<strong>in</strong>t projects, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land.Aga<strong>in</strong>, the compensation and protective measuresare similar to the BITs <strong>in</strong> the other <strong>countries</strong>.


37Legal domestic environmentIn Mali, the land tenure system is based on theCode Domanial et Foncier (CDF, <strong>Land</strong> Act) 17 , theLoi d’Orientation Agricole (LOA, AgriculturalOrientation Law), the Code Forestier, (Forest Act)and the Charte Pastorale (Law on Pastoralism) aswell as its implement<strong>in</strong>g provisions. They providethe follow<strong>in</strong>g four property categories:• National Doma<strong>in</strong> (cover<strong>in</strong>g the entire Malianterritory),• State public land,• State private land, and• Private land.In accordance with the French system, state landis divided <strong>in</strong>to state public and state private land.While state public land comprises all lands withpublic functions (natural and artificial doma<strong>in</strong>s),state private land covers all other areas which arenot under private ownership. State private landcan be registered under the name of a legal entity(such as a state enterprise, a foreign <strong>in</strong>vestor etc.)or be unregistered.Neither communal nor <strong>in</strong>digenous land is knownas such <strong>in</strong> Mali. Areas where local people possesscustomary land rights are <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the stateprivate doma<strong>in</strong>, hence considered to be state privatelands. They are only recognised and partiallysecured if they are located <strong>in</strong> unregistered areas.They rema<strong>in</strong> secured as long as common public<strong>in</strong>terest does not call for a different use. In thiscase, however, customary rights need to becompensated. In practice, this is only done forcustomary owners who can present written proof.Although customary rights are recognised onunregistered lands, they are considered to be userights only. Officially, they cannot be sold. In caseof compensation, not the land, only the addedvalue <strong>in</strong> form of constructions, cultures etc. iscompensated. It is, however, possible for a holderof a customary right to change it <strong>in</strong>to a formalright – first a provisional concession and then atitle – if he or she follows a rather long, drawn outand expensive procedure.CDF and LOA provide for the follow<strong>in</strong>g landtenure arrangement: annual contract, cultivationpermission, rural concession, leasehold, land title –all allocated by the state on (former) state privateland. The land title can be held only by nationalfarmers. <strong>Foreign</strong> operators are entitled to leasesonly. Most <strong>FDI</strong> contracts are based on a renewablelease of up to 50 years, respectively 99 years <strong>in</strong>total. Similar to the situation <strong>in</strong> Laos, problemsand conflicts arise from the fact that local farmers’and pastoralists’ land (use) rights are not (sufficiently)respected by the national <strong>in</strong>stitutions/representatives sign<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>FDI</strong> contracts. Most ofthe land <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Mali has been given tothe Niger Office (a state enterprise irrigat<strong>in</strong>g amajor area along the river Niger, primarily for riceproduction) and has thus been registered as“registered land”. Hence, customary rights on thisland are not recognised although hundreds ofthousands of people live on these lands, farm theselands, graze their animals there, live from theforests and depend on the water available there.Additional national regulations oblige foreign<strong>in</strong>vestors to conduct an environmental and socialimpact assessment. In practice, however, these areoften not done or only after major constructionworks have already been started.Data on the size of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land and risks andopportunitiesCurrently <strong>in</strong> Mali, 173,605 ha are known to bedemanded for foreign <strong>in</strong>vestments. In addition,there is <strong>in</strong>formation about an <strong>in</strong>vestment ofanother 200,000 ha by a Saudi Arabian company<strong>in</strong> food <strong>in</strong> Mali (Gra<strong>in</strong>). This <strong>in</strong>formation couldnot been verified yet.Most of the <strong>in</strong>vestment is tak<strong>in</strong>g place <strong>in</strong> theNiger Office Area. This is the most fertile area ofMali with production depend<strong>in</strong>g on irrigationfrom the Niger River. But s<strong>in</strong>ce water availabilitydur<strong>in</strong>g the dry season is limited, only 250,000 haare irrigable. Therefore, further demand <strong>in</strong> landand water will create water conflicts. The case ofMalibya, currently <strong>in</strong> the implementation projectphase of build<strong>in</strong>g roads and dams, is alreadyresult<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> conflicts with cattle breeders, s<strong>in</strong>cetheir traditional routes and graz<strong>in</strong>g areas areignored. Whereas Malibya is exclusively produc<strong>in</strong>gfor the Libyan market with the objective to securefood security <strong>in</strong> Libya and to reduce dependencyon food imports and therefore on the food world17 Ord<strong>in</strong>ance n° 00-27/P-RM of Mars 22 2000, named “Code domanial et Foncier” (<strong>Land</strong> Act) modified by the Law n° 02-008 of February 12 2002.


38market, the other example presented <strong>in</strong> the casestudy, the Markala Sugar Project, produces sugarfor the domestic market to secure food security <strong>in</strong>Mali and to reduce dependency on sugar importsand therefore the world market. The reason forthis difference <strong>in</strong> philosophy is the different formof <strong>in</strong>vestment. Malibya is a classic <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land,while Markala Sugar Project is the first publicprivatepartnership project <strong>in</strong> Mali and the firstpublic private partnership (PPP) developmentproject <strong>in</strong> the agro-<strong>in</strong>dustrial sector submitted forf<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g to the African Development Bank.Accord<strong>in</strong>gly, Malibya is exclusively head<strong>in</strong>g forquality and profits us<strong>in</strong>g sophisticated technologiesrequir<strong>in</strong>g little and ma<strong>in</strong>ly skilled (thereforeforeign) manpower, while the Markala SugarProject will, accord<strong>in</strong>g to the Bank’s plans, amongother th<strong>in</strong>gs be accompanied by a poverty reductionprogram, a resettlement action plan andmeasures to mitigate the negative environmentalimpact.Table 6: Demand for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land <strong>in</strong> MaliInvestor Investor Country Surface (ha) CropsMalibya Agriculture Libya 100,000 rice and vegetablesUEMOA UEMOA 11,288 rice and vegetablesAgro Industries Developement France 2,605 rice and vegetablesMali Biocarburant Netherlands 2,112 jatropha curcasManuel Estepa Gonzalez Ivory Coast 5,000 jatropha curcasSUDAN Ivory Coast 5,000 jatropha curcasASSIL Ivory Coast 5,000 jatropha curcasCAMEX UK 20,000 rice and vegetablesBurk<strong>in</strong>a Faso Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso 2,500 rice and vegetablesFORAS Saudi Arabia 5,000 rice and vegetablesCO-ENTREPRISE West African Countries 1,000 rice and vegetablesTotal 159,505Source: own researchMost projects are still not yet implemented. Sofar, it is therefore too early to do an evaluation.Nevertheless, some observations show a violationof exist<strong>in</strong>g rights: Both the Malibya Agricultureproject as well as the Markala Sugar Projectstarted with their implementation work beforecarry<strong>in</strong>g out the environmental and social impactassessments and compensation for resettledfarmers does not meet the legal obligations.Despite all positive impacts, it is obvious that notall of the affected population will benefit fromthese projects. Both projects can also result <strong>in</strong>major environmental degradation.


39HarvestField work with ox ploughFishermen


40LAOS LAOS LAOS LAOS LAOS LAOS LAOS LAOS LAOS LAOS LAOSCOUNTRY PROFILELAOS LAOS LAOS LAOS LAOS LAOS LAOS LAOS LAOS LAOS LAOS LAOS LAOS LAOSRubber plantation <strong>in</strong> Luang Namtha Jatropha concession Jatropha concession Jatropha concession4.4. Country Profile – Lao People’s Democratic Republic (Lao PDR)Lao PDR is a small, landlocked country <strong>in</strong> Southeast Asia, bordered by Myanmar and Ch<strong>in</strong>a to thenorthwest, Vietnam to the east, Cambodia to the south and Thailand to the west with a total area of236,800 km 2 . The forested landscape consists mostly of rugged mounta<strong>in</strong>s with some pla<strong>in</strong>s andplateaus. The Mekong River forms a large part of the western boundary with Thailand, whereas themounta<strong>in</strong>s of the Annamite Cha<strong>in</strong> form most of the eastern border with Vietnam.Table 7 provides an overview of the country profile regard<strong>in</strong>g:• Economy, agriculture, food security, poverty and environment• Overall <strong>in</strong>vestment climate• Legal framework• Pattern of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land


41Table 7: Country profile - LaosOverall domestic background: Economy, Agriculture, Food security, Poverty and Environment(1) Economic situationGDP per capita, 2008, US$ (a) 858Official Development aid (ODA),2007, US$ million (b) 396ODA <strong>in</strong> agriculture, forestry and fishery (b)Commitments 2007, US$ millionDisbursements 2007, US$ millionShare of population below poverty l<strong>in</strong>e (2 US$ per day, average 2000-2006) (c) 76.8%(2) Relevance of agricultureShare <strong>in</strong> GDP (2007) (d) 42%Share of agriculture employment (e) 75% (2006)(3) Food securityGlobal Hunger Index (GHI), 2008 (f) 20.6GHI-Rank<strong>in</strong>g (out of 88 <strong>countries</strong>), 2008 (f) 57Share of undernourished population (f) 19%Food aid, 2008, ‘000 t, cereals <strong>in</strong> gra<strong>in</strong> equivalent (g) 16.8As country <strong>in</strong> crisis accord<strong>in</strong>g to FAO (2009) (h)NoValue of food import m<strong>in</strong>us export, 2006, US$ million (i) -163(4) Environment/ BiodiversityProtected area, % of total area 2003 (k) 18,8%Forestry area, % of total area 2005 (l) 69,9%Deforestation rate (annual change <strong>in</strong> forest covered area, with<strong>in</strong> 2000-05) (i) -0,5%Fire cultivationNo dataOverall <strong>in</strong>vestment climate(1) Climate for <strong>FDI</strong> (m)Ease of do<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess (rank of 181 <strong>countries</strong>) 165Protect<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestors (rank of 181 <strong>countries</strong>) 180Enforc<strong>in</strong>g contracts (rank of 181 <strong>countries</strong>) 111(2) Corruption (n)CPI rank<strong>in</strong>g (rank of 181 <strong>countries</strong>), 2008 (2007) 151 (168)(3) Share of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> agriculture <strong>in</strong> % of all <strong>FDI</strong> average (o)US State Department Climate Statements 2009 (o) 31% Average Jan 2000 - Sep 2008World <strong>Investment</strong> Report 2009 2005 – 2007 (p) 12% Average 2005-2007Legal Frame(1) Multi- and bilateral frame (q)WTO rules applicable?not, not memberBITs <strong>in</strong> force with major <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land <strong>in</strong>vestor <strong>countries</strong>All <strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>in</strong>cluded(2) Domestic frame (q)Major legal basis4936Law on the Promotion of <strong>Foreign</strong><strong>Investment</strong>s from 2004


42Table 7: Country profile LaosPattern of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> landInvestor country (r)Major <strong>in</strong>vestors, <strong>in</strong> haMajor purpose (r)FoodMa<strong>in</strong> cropsAgrofuelsMa<strong>in</strong> cropsOtherThailandCh<strong>in</strong>aAustraliaVietnamIndiaKoreaJapanFrancem<strong>in</strong>orCorn, cattle,m<strong>in</strong>orjatrophadom<strong>in</strong>ant (m<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g)Source: (a) IMF, 2009; (b) OECD, 2009; (c) UNDP, 2008; (d) World Bank, 2007; (e) GTZ estimates, 2007; (f) Welthungerhilfe, 2008; (g) FAO2009b, (h) FAO, 2009e; (i) FAO, 2009b; (k) WRI,2009; (l) FAO 2007; (m) World Bank 2009, (n) Transparency International 2008 and2009 (o) U.S. State Department, 2009b-e (p) UNCTAD 2009b (q) UNCTAD, 2009c, GTZ case studies; (r) GTZ case studiesAgriculture plays an important role <strong>in</strong> the Laoseconomy. Its share <strong>in</strong> GDP is about 42% and75% of the population is employed <strong>in</strong> agriculture.About 77% of the population lives <strong>in</strong> absolutepoverty and 19% is undernourished. Lao PDRreceives food aid. In 2008, the amount of foodaid was estimated at 16.800 t cereals <strong>in</strong> gra<strong>in</strong>equivalent.In Lao PDR, economic reforms dat<strong>in</strong>g back to thelate 1980s officially welcome and promote <strong>FDI</strong> asa means for enhanc<strong>in</strong>g development and economicgrowth. All sectors are open to <strong>in</strong>vestments unlessthey are regarded detrimental to national security,to health and national traditions, or have anegative impact on the environment.As regards to the allocation of total <strong>FDI</strong> todifferent sectors, the 2009 <strong>Investment</strong> ClimateStatements <strong>in</strong>clude some <strong>in</strong>formation based onnational statistics:• Licensed <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Investment</strong> <strong>in</strong> Lao PDRfrom 2000 through September 2008 add up to6,972 million US$ or 792 million US$ per year.Recent figures show the accelerat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>creaseof foreign <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> Lao PDR as 2008`sfigures almost quadrupled dur<strong>in</strong>g the first n<strong>in</strong>emonths of 2009 (be<strong>in</strong>g worth 4.3 billion US$)(Vientiane Times 2009).The data presented <strong>in</strong> the World <strong>Investment</strong>Report 2009 (UNCTAD 2009b) differ considerablyfrom those presented <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Investment</strong>Climate Statements. This may be due to thedifferent periods of time that the average wascalculated for, but it may also reflect the difficultiesof gett<strong>in</strong>g reliable data.<strong>Investment</strong> climate is assessed as “poor butimprov<strong>in</strong>g” due to the very low rates <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational<strong>in</strong>dices of transparency and ease of do<strong>in</strong>gbus<strong>in</strong>ess.Because Lao PDR is a communist one-party state,the sanctity of contracts is subject to political<strong>in</strong>terference and a number of socialist pr<strong>in</strong>ciples.Contracts can become void if it is disadvantageousto one party or conflicts with state or public<strong>in</strong>terests.Another obstacle for enforc<strong>in</strong>g the legal frameworkis the little tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g judges have <strong>in</strong> commercialdisputes as mentioned <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Investment</strong>Climate Report.


43Legal multi- and bilateral environmentLaos signed 24 BITs. All relevant <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land<strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong> are <strong>in</strong>cluded. Laos’ BITs<strong>in</strong>clude compensation for expropriation andmeasures to protect the domestic economy.Legal domestic environmentAccord<strong>in</strong>g to the constitution, land is completelyowned by the state and, therefore, land cannot besold de jure. Nevertheless, the assignment ofpermanent use rights allows the evolution of aland market. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the <strong>Land</strong> Law 2003,the Lao tenure system is de facto based on stateland and private land, whereas private property,as long as it is not collid<strong>in</strong>g with public <strong>in</strong>terests,is secured by article 16 of the constitution. Additionally,communal land is def<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> the Decree88 from 2008, but not yet <strong>in</strong>cluded with<strong>in</strong> the<strong>Land</strong> Law.In rural areas, generally no titles are issued, ma<strong>in</strong>lybecause 99% of the rural areas would not qualifyfor the current requirements that have to be metto receive a title. However, for local villagers atraditional system based on the knowledge of thevillage community can guarantee the use rights aslong as there are no conflict<strong>in</strong>g outside claims. Incases of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land, the traditional system is notappropriate for sav<strong>in</strong>g the rights of the traditionalowners as these rights are not recognised by thestate. Neither <strong>in</strong>dividual nor common/collectiveuse rights are registered. Hence, the state considersall rural land to be state land which it can allocate<strong>in</strong> form of concessions. S<strong>in</strong>ce 2002, when pressureon land resources <strong>in</strong>creased, caused by the emergenceof <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land and by resettlement programmes,tenure <strong>in</strong>security <strong>in</strong> rural areas hasgrown tremendously.S<strong>in</strong>ce 1997 the Lao government, supported by the<strong>Land</strong> Titl<strong>in</strong>g Project <strong>in</strong>itiated by the World Bank,has allocated roughly 540,000 land titles, butnearly exclusively <strong>in</strong> settlement areas. The <strong>Land</strong>Titl<strong>in</strong>g projects concentrated on settlement areasbecause the majority of people live there and landvalues are much higher.Domestic and foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors can obta<strong>in</strong> landvia long-term state land concessions. Concessionrefers to a type of <strong>in</strong>vestment whereby land istransferred to companies that are responsible forall its <strong>in</strong>vestment and cultivation/construction.Large concessions are usually the preferred formof <strong>in</strong>vestment s<strong>in</strong>ce it maximises company controlover the land. As mentioned above, a majorproblem for <strong>in</strong>vestors is the fact that local peoplemay have legitimated rights on these lands whichoften results <strong>in</strong> conflicts between the <strong>in</strong>vestor andthe local farmers whose farms become destroyedby the <strong>in</strong>vestor.To access land, foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors must submit theirproposals to the Department of Domestic and<strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Investment</strong> (DDFI) of the Committee forPlann<strong>in</strong>g and <strong>Investment</strong>. <strong>FDI</strong> worth less than 3million US$ can be approved at the prov<strong>in</strong>ciallevel, less than 10 million US$ gets signed by thepresident of the DDFI, and <strong>in</strong>vestment exceed<strong>in</strong>g20 million US$ has to be proved by the PrimeM<strong>in</strong>ister. 18 Besides the monetary triggers, responsibilityof the different levels is def<strong>in</strong>ed on the basisof the area of the <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land. This creates anambiguous framework that does not clearlyconf<strong>in</strong>e the responsibility of different authorities.Table 8: Authorities <strong>in</strong> charge depend<strong>in</strong>g on land size<strong>Land</strong> sizeAuthority< 3 ha District authorities3 – 100 ha Prov<strong>in</strong>ce authorities100 – 10,000 ha M<strong>in</strong>istry on Agriculture & Fisheries> 10,000 ha Approval by the National AssemblySource: GTZ, 2006.18 <strong>FDI</strong> exceed<strong>in</strong>g the limits can be approved by the National Assembly.


44The screen<strong>in</strong>g of the submitted proposals conductedby the Department of Domestic and<strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Investment</strong> (DDFI) takes <strong>in</strong>to accountthe f<strong>in</strong>ancial and technical feasibility of theproject. A lack of exact regulations concern<strong>in</strong>gsocial and environmental impact assessmenth<strong>in</strong>ders a socio-ecological feasibility surveysecur<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>terests of smallholders and <strong>in</strong>digenouspeople.Referr<strong>in</strong>g to the <strong>in</strong>vestment climate, the one-stopservice <strong>in</strong>tended by the Lao Law on Promotionof <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Investment</strong> does not apply for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>land, as a bundle of different permits granted byvarious state authorities is mandatory.It can be observed that rules and regulationsconcern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestment appraisal and concessionapproval are not always clearly def<strong>in</strong>ed, andadditionally guidel<strong>in</strong>es for the selection of landfor land concessions and its monitor<strong>in</strong>g are partlyunderdeveloped. For example, <strong>in</strong> VientianeProv<strong>in</strong>ce several concessions are <strong>in</strong> protected areas,some concessions are substantially larger thancontractually agreed upon, and district andprov<strong>in</strong>cial adm<strong>in</strong>istrations have granted concessionsthat were larger than the allowable size of3 and 100 hectare allotments. In many cases(89 out of 237 <strong>in</strong> Vientiane Prov<strong>in</strong>ce) writtenconcession agreements are lack<strong>in</strong>g, allow<strong>in</strong>g theblatant circumvention of statutory provisions.Consultations with local villagers are rare andrent-seek<strong>in</strong>g activities arise on all levels(National <strong>Land</strong> Management Authority 2009).The lack of a systematic overview detail<strong>in</strong>g thelocation, size, boundaries, etc. of the concessionsand the lease tracts makes regulat<strong>in</strong>g the grant<strong>in</strong>gof concessions difficult. With support from theLao-German <strong>Land</strong> Policy Development Project(LPDP/GTZ), <strong>in</strong> October of 2008, the <strong>Land</strong>and Natural Resources Research and InformationCenter of the National <strong>Land</strong> Management Authoritybegan a nationwide <strong>in</strong>ventory and surveyof all concession and lease tracts. However, itrema<strong>in</strong>s necessary to ensure the security of thecurrent use rights of the local population and their<strong>in</strong>clusion <strong>in</strong> the apportionment of concessiontracts. A first step to this end was taken <strong>in</strong> July of2009 when the LPDP/GTZ Project was given theauthorisation to extend the power to grant landtitles to rural regions as well.Due to many protests and conflicts aris<strong>in</strong>g fromthe allocation of land concessions without consultationof local villagers, a temporary memorandumon government concessions over 100 ha wasdeclared by Prime M<strong>in</strong>ister Bouasone Bouphavanhon 30 May 2007. In the Prime M<strong>in</strong>ister’s 2007memorandum, contract farm<strong>in</strong>g was emphasisedas a better approach to <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> the agriculturalsector that would ensure local level benefits. It hasbeen heavily promoted <strong>in</strong> northern Laos, wherereportedly over 10,000 ha have been planted undercontract schemes. Unfortunately, no <strong>in</strong>formationis available about impacts on the farmers’ livelihood.And still, most <strong>in</strong>vestors prefer <strong>in</strong>vestments<strong>in</strong> land <strong>in</strong>stead <strong>in</strong> contract farm<strong>in</strong>g.Data on the size of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land and risks andopportunitiesS<strong>in</strong>ce 1993 Lao PDR became <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly thefocus of <strong>FDI</strong> and a massive surge can be observeds<strong>in</strong>ce 2002. Lao PDR has one of the lowestconcession rates <strong>in</strong> Southeast Asia (2-9 US$/ha); itgrants long concession periods and is characterisedby unclear regulations and low enforcement.The ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestors are Ch<strong>in</strong>a, Vietnam andThailand and the ma<strong>in</strong> products are rice, rubber,cassava, sugar, and pulp wood. Whereas Ch<strong>in</strong>ama<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>in</strong>vests <strong>in</strong> rubber and rice, Thailand andVietnam together with Malaysia concentrate onrubber, sugar and cassava. Investors from Japan,India and the Scand<strong>in</strong>avian <strong>countries</strong> focus onpulp wood.A reliable data base is available for just two of the17 prov<strong>in</strong>ces of Lao PDR. GTZ supports the LaoPDR <strong>in</strong> carry<strong>in</strong>g out an <strong>in</strong>ventory to collect dataabout all the different <strong>in</strong>vestment projects <strong>in</strong> thecountry, not only <strong>in</strong> the agricultural sector.


45Table 9: Area of land lease/concession projects of two prov<strong>in</strong>ces (2009)Vientiane Prov<strong>in</strong>ce(total surface 1,852,600 ha)Luang Namtha(total surface 961,200 ha)Number of projects Surface (ha) Number of projects Surface (ha)Total 237 391,709 107 25,366Concessions 198 390,374 23 19,291Lease 34 177 61 126Contract Farm<strong>in</strong>g 5 546 23 5,949SectorAgriculture 114 62,551 43 18,140Rubber 46 25,104 36 18,110M<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g 55 326,944 5 5,502Industry 30 714 12 48Investors are 1. Lao (149) 1. Lao (58)2. Ch<strong>in</strong>ese (25) 2. Ch<strong>in</strong>ese (45)3. S-Korean (24) 3. Thai (1)Source: GTZ Lao PDR, 2009Collected data for the prov<strong>in</strong>ces Vientiane andLuang Namtha are already available. They coveronly active and implemented projects and areassembled <strong>in</strong> Table 9.• To get a comprehensive overview, a close cooperationwith local authorities is necessary.Hence projects not <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the <strong>in</strong>terests oflocal authorities will hardly f<strong>in</strong>d the requiredsupport.• It is not always clear where the <strong>in</strong>vestor comesfrom. To circumvent legal requirements, it seemsto be possible to make use of Lao citizens toconduct bus<strong>in</strong>ess on behalf of foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors.Therefore, <strong>in</strong>vestments cannot be allocated todomestic or foreign <strong>in</strong>vestments unambiguously.• For some <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land, there are no writtencontracts or documents. They are based on oralagreements.The <strong>in</strong>ventory has brought transparency to the<strong>in</strong>vestment projects of two prov<strong>in</strong>ces. The Laoparliament has recognised the efforts and agrees toa follow-up project extend<strong>in</strong>g the GTZ activitiesnationwide.S<strong>in</strong>ce data for the other prov<strong>in</strong>ces are not yetavailable it is difficult to estimate <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land forthe whole country. In a pre-study to the GTZproject, estimates amounted to approximately 2-3million ha of land that is already under concession(<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g concessions for m<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g). This is about10-15% of the whole Lao PDR territory.Additional demand for land orig<strong>in</strong>ates from Ch<strong>in</strong>a(about 1 million ha) and Kuwait (about 200,000ha) for food production. Apart from food, thereare many projects for the production of agro-fuel,ma<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Jatropha.Rubber plant<strong>in</strong>g on burned siteRubber plantation <strong>in</strong> Luang Namtha


46COOPERATIONS DRIVING FACTORS WEAKNESSES IMPACTSCAMBODIA CAMBODIA BODIA CAMBODIA CAMBODIA CAMBODIA CAM CAMBODIA CAMBODIA CAMBODIA CAMBODIA CAMBODIAKEYFACTS COUNTRY PROFILE CURRENT SITUATION INVESTMENTS OPPORTUNITIESRural hous<strong>in</strong>g Work<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> rice fields Sell<strong>in</strong>g on the streets <strong>Land</strong> for Sale Transportation4.5. Country profile – K<strong>in</strong>gdom of CambodiaCambodia is located <strong>in</strong> Southeast Asia, occupies a total area of 181.040 km 2 and has a population of 14.5million.Table 10 provides an overview of the country profile regard<strong>in</strong>g:• Economy, agriculture, food security, poverty and environment• Overall <strong>in</strong>vestment climate• Legal framework• Pattern of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land


47Table 10: Country profile CambodiaOverall domestic background: Economy, Agriculture, Food security, Poverty and Environment(1) Economic situationGDP per capita, 2008, US$ (a) 818Official Development aid (ODA),2007, US$ million (b) 672ODA <strong>in</strong> agriculture, forestry and fishery (b)Commitments 2007, US$ millionDisbursements 2007, US$ millionShare of population below poverty l<strong>in</strong>e (2 US$ per day, average 2000-2006) (c) 68.2%(2) Relevance of agricultureShare <strong>in</strong> GDP (2007) (d) 32%Share of agriculture employment (e) 71% (2007)(3) Food securityGlobal Hunger Index (GHI), 2008 (f) 23.2GHI-Rank<strong>in</strong>g (out of 88 <strong>countries</strong>), 2008 (f) 64Share of undernourished population (f) 26%Food aid, 2008, ‘000 t, cereals <strong>in</strong> gra<strong>in</strong> equivalent (g) 44.2As country <strong>in</strong> crisis accord<strong>in</strong>g to FAO (2009) (h)NoValue of food import m<strong>in</strong>us export, 2006, US$ million (i) -476(4) Environment/ BiodiversityProtected area, % of total area 2003 (k) 23,7%Forestry area, % of total area 2005 (l) 59,2%Deforestation rate (annual change <strong>in</strong> forest covered area, with<strong>in</strong> 2000-05) (i) -2,0%Fire cultivationNo dataOverall <strong>in</strong>vestment climate(1) Climate for <strong>FDI</strong> (m)Ease of do<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess (rank of 181 <strong>countries</strong>) 135Protect<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestors (rank of 181 <strong>countries</strong>) 70Enforc<strong>in</strong>g contracts (rank of 181 <strong>countries</strong>) 136(2) Corruption (n)CPI rank<strong>in</strong>g (rank of 181 <strong>countries</strong>), 2008 (2007) 166 (162)(3) Share of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> agriculture <strong>in</strong> % of all <strong>FDI</strong> average (o)10,5%US State Department Climate Statements 2009 (o)Average1998 – 2008World <strong>Investment</strong> Report 2009 2005 – 2007 (p)342415%Average2005 – 2007Legal Frame(1) Multi- and bilateral frame (q)WTO rules applicable?YesBITs <strong>in</strong> force with major <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land <strong>in</strong>vestor <strong>countries</strong>Only 3 of all <strong>in</strong>vestors <strong>in</strong>cluded(2) Domestic frame (q)Major legal basis <strong>Land</strong> Law 2001


48Table 10: Country profile CambodiaPattern of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land(1) Investor country (r)Major <strong>in</strong>vestors, <strong>in</strong> ha(2) Major purpose (r)FoodMa<strong>in</strong> cropsAgrofuelsMa<strong>in</strong> cropsOtherCh<strong>in</strong>aUSAThailandVietnamKoreaTaiwanSouth AfricaItalyM<strong>in</strong>orRiceDom<strong>in</strong>antPalm oilMediumSource: (a) IMF, 2009; (b) OECD, 2009; (c) UNDP, 2008; (d) World Bank, 2007; (e) GTZ estimates, 2007; (f) Welthungerhilfe, 2008; (g) FAO2009b, (h) FAO, 2009e; (i) FAO, 2009b; (k) WRI,2009; (l) FAO 2007; (m) World Bank 2009, (n) Transparency International 2008 and2009 (o) U.S. State Department, 2009b-e (p) UNCTAD 2009b (q) UNCTAD, 2009c, GTZ case studies; (r) GTZ case studiesAgriculture plays an important role <strong>in</strong> Cambodia´seconomy. The share of agriculture <strong>in</strong> GDP isabout 32% and 71% of population is employed <strong>in</strong>agriculture. 68.2 % of total population still lives<strong>in</strong> absolute poverty and 26% is undernourished.Cambodia receives food aid and paid large foodbills <strong>in</strong> 2006 (FAO 2009b). In 2008, the amountof food aid was estimated at 44 200 t cereals <strong>in</strong>gra<strong>in</strong> equivalent (g).The <strong>in</strong>vestment climate <strong>in</strong> Cambodia was rated bythe World Bank <strong>in</strong> 2008. Cambodia was ranked<strong>in</strong> two of three categories (ease of do<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess,enforc<strong>in</strong>g contracts) <strong>in</strong> the last quarter. Concern<strong>in</strong>gthe category “protect<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestors” a highprotection rate can be found for Cambodia.Cambodia is perceived as protect<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestorsmuch better compared to Mali or Lao PDR.After the Civil War, Cambodia started to transformto a free market economy <strong>in</strong> the late 1980sand is <strong>in</strong>tegrat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to the regional and worldtrad<strong>in</strong>g framework: It became a member of theAssociation of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN)<strong>in</strong> 1999 and of the World Trade Organisation(WTO) <strong>in</strong> 2004. In keep<strong>in</strong>g with its WTOcommitments, it is improv<strong>in</strong>g the climate forforeign and domestic <strong>in</strong>vestments. Based on thereforms, the economy has grown steadily and thereal GDP growth rates averaged 8.8% dur<strong>in</strong>g theperiod 1994-2008.With<strong>in</strong> the legal framework there is little or nodiscrim<strong>in</strong>ation aga<strong>in</strong>st foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors. However,there are some reports about acts of corruption,tax evasion or the poor enforcement of laws thatlead to disadvantages for foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors. TheCPI corruption <strong>in</strong>dex rates Cambodia 166 of 181.As regards to the allocation of total <strong>FDI</strong> todifferent sectors, the 2009 <strong>Investment</strong> ClimateStatements <strong>in</strong>clude some <strong>in</strong>formation based onnational statistics. Total cumulative registered<strong>in</strong>vestment capital from January 1998 to December2008 amounted to 2,432 million US$ whichaverages about 221 million US$ per year. <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>agriculture totaled 177 million US$ for the wholeperiod or 16 million US$ per year. Accord<strong>in</strong>g tothe data, the share of agriculture <strong>in</strong> overall <strong>FDI</strong> isabout 10%.Cambodia officially welcomes <strong>FDI</strong> and establishedan open and liberal regime by the Law on <strong>Investment</strong><strong>in</strong> 1994. In pr<strong>in</strong>ciple all sectors are open to<strong>FDI</strong>; a 100% ownership is permitted <strong>in</strong> mostsectors. However, <strong>in</strong> some sectors <strong>FDI</strong> are subjectto conditions (manufacture of cigarettes, movieproduction, rice mill<strong>in</strong>g, exploitation ofgemstones, publish<strong>in</strong>g and pr<strong>in</strong>t<strong>in</strong>g, radio and


49television, manufactur<strong>in</strong>g wood and stone carv<strong>in</strong>gs,silk weav<strong>in</strong>g, and hospitals and cl<strong>in</strong>ics).Additionally, the Cambodian Constitution onlyprovides Cambodian citizens and Cambodianlegal entities with the right to own land. <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>land can only be undertaken <strong>in</strong> jo<strong>in</strong>t ventures.Legal multi- and bilateral environmentCambodia signed altogether 21 BITs of whichonly three cover relevant <strong>in</strong>vestor <strong>countries</strong> for<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land (Ch<strong>in</strong>a, Thailand and Taiwan). 19In these agreements, a compensation for expropriationfor the <strong>in</strong>vestor is foreseen, based on anappraised market value. Additionally, protectivetrade measures like import restrictions to stabilisethe balance of payments are possible from bothcontract<strong>in</strong>g partners and specific rules for disputesettlements are <strong>in</strong>tegrated.Legal domestic environmentDomestic law follows a very restrictive land policy:ownership of land is restricted to Cambodianpersons and legal entities only. A company isdef<strong>in</strong>ed as Cambodian if 51% is nationally held.Concessions are limited to 10,000 ha and rulesfor exceptions exist. An environmental impactassessment (EIA) is required and a national planto ensure food security has been adopted <strong>in</strong> 2008.Cambodia ranks worst of all case <strong>countries</strong> regard<strong>in</strong>gcorruption which h<strong>in</strong>ders the effective implementationof exist<strong>in</strong>g legal rules.Until 1989, all land <strong>in</strong> Cambodia was state ownedand land markets did not exist. After the end ofKhmer Rouge, land distribution took place basedon size of families, and possession rights weregranted for resid<strong>in</strong>g and subsistence farm<strong>in</strong>g.Temporary possession was established, whichallows tenants who had occupied the land for am<strong>in</strong>imum of five years the acquisition of a landtitle.Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the new constitution of 1993 and the<strong>Land</strong> Law of 2001, five ma<strong>in</strong> categories of landproperty can be dist<strong>in</strong>guished:• Private land,• State public land (all areas needed for publicservices such as roads, river banks, etc.),• State private land (all other areas owned by thestate),• Communal land, and• Indigenous land.The first <strong>Land</strong> Law of 1991 was established toprovide the opportunity to register traditionalland use rights, but the government was not ableto manage the huge demand. As land pressure<strong>in</strong>creased dramatically, ma<strong>in</strong>ly caused by populationgrowth, social conflicts about land grewsteadily and were enhanced by miss<strong>in</strong>g land titlesand an unsatisfied cadastral system. In 2001, anew <strong>Land</strong> Law entered <strong>in</strong>to force to accelerate theprocess of land registration and improve tenuresecurity. Temporary possession was removed.With the help of development organisations, anew cadastral system was implemented and about1.15 million plots have been registered.Private state land can be used for Social <strong>Land</strong>Concessions (SLC) and Economic <strong>Land</strong> Concessions(ELC). The M<strong>in</strong>istry of <strong>Land</strong> Management,Urban Plann<strong>in</strong>g and Construction (MLMUPC)is responsible for grant<strong>in</strong>g these land concessions.A sub-decree of SLC was established <strong>in</strong> 2003 toaccompany the implementation of the <strong>Land</strong>Allocation Project (LASED). It offers the poor anopportunity to apply for land for hous<strong>in</strong>g andsubsistence farm<strong>in</strong>g.In 2005, the land act degree was amended by theELC sub-decree, a mechanism established to grantstate private land not exceed<strong>in</strong>g 10,000 ha toconcessionaires for agricultural exploitation up toa maximum of 99 years.Village workshop19 No data of entry available; no reasons available why this or that agreement has not entered <strong>in</strong>to force yet.


50To acquire land use rights, foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors mustsubmit their proposals to the Council for theDevelopment of Cambodia (CDC) and a clearprocedure is def<strong>in</strong>ed, as for <strong>in</strong>stance mandatoryenvironmental and social impact assessments.The MLMUPC is entitled to assign the ELC to<strong>in</strong>vestors.Even though a clear procedure for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land isdef<strong>in</strong>ed, the process often does not comply withthe regulations. Some public authorities, especiallythe M<strong>in</strong>istry of Economy and F<strong>in</strong>ance (MEF) andthe M<strong>in</strong>istry of Agriculture, Forest and Fishery(MAFF), act as legal entities and lease, sell orexchange land even though they are not authorised.Moreover, it can be observed that the capacitiesto enforce the rule of law are partially weakand the lack of transparency enhances rent-seek<strong>in</strong>gactivities. Furthermore, the governments of theprov<strong>in</strong>ces are difficult to control by the Cambodiangovernment. Obviously, there are weaknesses<strong>in</strong> enforc<strong>in</strong>g the legal framework. In addition, thelow level of land registration and the lack of landtitles make way for the <strong>in</strong>terpretation and allocationof property rights. As a consequence, thenumber of overlapp<strong>in</strong>g land use rights for certa<strong>in</strong>plots <strong>in</strong>creases dramatically, which augment socialconflicts and endanger the rights of smallholdersand <strong>in</strong>digenous groups. Despite the 10,000 halimit, it is reported that land concessions exceed<strong>in</strong>gthe 10,000 ha are granted. One way to circumventthe official limit is by grant<strong>in</strong>g concessions oncontiguous tracks of land for the same purpose(compare UN, 2007).Data on the size of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land and risks andopportunitiesAn official database for <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land exceed<strong>in</strong>g thesize of 1,000 ha is provided by the M<strong>in</strong>istry ofAgriculture, Forestry and Fisheries (MAFF, 2009).Accord<strong>in</strong>g to this database, 58 Economic <strong>Land</strong>Concessions (ELC) for about 1 million ha weregranted for grow<strong>in</strong>g agricultural and forestryproducts between 1998 and 2006. Companiesfrom abroad account for 26 of the overall ELCwith an area of about 300,000 ha.Table 11: Official data on granted ELCS to companies for Agriculture and Forestry <strong>in</strong> CambodiaOrig<strong>in</strong> of <strong>in</strong>vestorGranted Economic <strong>Land</strong> Concessions (ha)Cambodia 656,047Ch<strong>in</strong>a 189,070USA 28,597Thailand 25,700Vietnam 24,540Korea 14,886Taiwan 4,900Source: MAFF, 2009More than two thirds of the ELC were grantedto Cambodian companies. Regard<strong>in</strong>g the orig<strong>in</strong>of <strong>in</strong>vestors from abroad, Ch<strong>in</strong>a leads with about200,000 ha, followed by other <strong>countries</strong> with anarea between 5,000 and 30,000 ha.The database is not always specific with respect tothe crops grown on the land. Some concessionsjust refer to one crop, others refer to several cropsor to agro-<strong>in</strong>dustrial crops <strong>in</strong> general. Regard<strong>in</strong>gEconomic <strong>Land</strong> Concessions granted to companiesfrom abroad, about 60,000 ha are devoted tooil palms, another 60,000 to agro-<strong>in</strong>dustrial crops<strong>in</strong> general, the rest to corn, bean, soya bean, rice,cassava & peanut (28,500 ha), cassava & agro<strong>in</strong>dustrialcrops (16,000), cassava (8,000 ha),cassava, rubber, cashew (15,200 ha), sugar cane(9,700 ha), crops (8,000 ha) rubber (6,900 ha).Forestry products encompass 10,000 ha of acacia,tr<strong>in</strong>comali wood, and other plantation crops,10,000 ha merkusii plantation & process<strong>in</strong>g,26,400 ha pistacia ch<strong>in</strong>ensis bunge and othertrees, and about 30,000 ha tectona plantation &process<strong>in</strong>g.


51The official database is not supposed to be comprehensiveand the extent of land concessions issupposed to exceed the officially reported amountby far. But there is no reliable estimation on theadditional land concessions granted by otherentities.Regard<strong>in</strong>g the economic, socio-cultural andenvironmental impact of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land, the casestudy reveals the follow<strong>in</strong>g positive po<strong>in</strong>ts:• The recent upsurge <strong>in</strong> private sector <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>Cambodia (<strong>FDI</strong> is estimated to reachUS$ 8.9 billion <strong>in</strong> the first eight months of 2008(Royal Embassy of Cambodia <strong>in</strong> Wash<strong>in</strong>gtonD.C (2008) is considerably larger than thevolume of Official Development Aid be<strong>in</strong>gprovided by the donor community (see table10). When a conflict arises between privatesector and donor projects, it is likelythat the larger project will be given precedence,and this may pose a threat to some donorprojects.• There is significant <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> local employmentopportunities with rais<strong>in</strong>g wages (up to US$ 100per month) which is more or less equal to theurban wage rate.• Improved local roads for mov<strong>in</strong>g companygoods and products means local villagers alsobenefit from better road conditions. But also theeffects of damaged roads were seen due to heavyloaded trucks, especially <strong>in</strong> the ra<strong>in</strong>y season.• Export to foreign <strong>countries</strong> has tremendously<strong>in</strong>creased, especially to Ch<strong>in</strong>a (ma<strong>in</strong>ly wood andrubber) go<strong>in</strong>g along with an <strong>in</strong>crease of exportrevenues. Also, it is expected that the localproduction of agro-fuel will benefit the countryby reduc<strong>in</strong>g imports of fossils fuels (but thisheavily depends on the development of jatrophayields which often are overestimated).• There is a hope that <strong>FDI</strong> will result <strong>in</strong> thecreation of job opportunities and thus contributeto the development of the country.On the other hand, unfavourable developments forthe rural people could be detected:• But many people are already negatively affectedby <strong>FDI</strong> by los<strong>in</strong>g their agricultural land or accessto forests which is an important source ofrevenue especially for <strong>in</strong>digenous communities(NTFP).• Large-scale land <strong>in</strong>vestments granted toforeign companies have already led to dom<strong>in</strong>antcontrol of fertile land by foreigners, more landconcentration, <strong>in</strong>equitable land distribution andcauses an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> landless people. Manylocal villagers migrated to urban areas fornon-agriculture jobs.• S<strong>in</strong>ce there is no basel<strong>in</strong>e data available atnational level on patterns of changes of naturalresources, especially of biodiversity, impacts canonly be estimated:• A large part of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> landconcern establish<strong>in</strong>g tree plantations likeeucalyptus, palm trees and rubber. All theseexotic species are not part of the local biodiversityresult<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a disruption of the localecologic system. They are not part of thenatural local food cha<strong>in</strong>s.• These trees are generally cultivated <strong>in</strong> largescalemonocultures go<strong>in</strong>g along with <strong>in</strong>tensiveuse of chemical fertiliser and pesticides andthus show<strong>in</strong>g a high risk of water pollution.• Eucalyptus plantations are form<strong>in</strong>g a seriousfire risk.• Palm oil production with its high biologicaloxygen demand (BOD) presents a seriousdanger to nearby rivers and lakes.• Monocultures of tree plantations with clearcut at short <strong>in</strong>tervals and without a stableforest cover are likely to <strong>in</strong>crease the risk ofsoil erosion, especially dur<strong>in</strong>g the establishmentphase.• Ongo<strong>in</strong>g illegal logg<strong>in</strong>g activities are detrimentalto natural environment result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> aloss of biodiversity. Even national conservationareas are threatened by human activities.Village workshop


525. Conclusions and recommendationsThe case studies give some evidence of the benefitsand threats that <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land present to the targetcountry as regards to the domestic economy,people’s livelihoods and ecological susta<strong>in</strong>ability.As most of the <strong>in</strong>vestment projects are not yetfully implemented <strong>in</strong> the case <strong>countries</strong>, a comprehensiveevaluation is not possible at present.The effects of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land are dependent on thecontractual design and on the opportunities toimplement and enforce the provisions that theparties agree on.v. Braun and Me<strong>in</strong>zen-Dick (IFPRI, 2009)recommend a dual approach to addressthe threats and opportunities related to <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>agricultural land: “First, the threats need to becontrolled through a code of conduct for hostgovernments and foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors. Second, theopportunities need to be facilitated by appropriatepolicies <strong>in</strong> the <strong>countries</strong> that are the targets ofthese foreign direct <strong>in</strong>vestments”.It is important to stress - foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors and thetarget country can and should contribute tom<strong>in</strong>imise the negative and <strong>in</strong>crease the positiveimpacts. It is the nature of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land that<strong>in</strong>terests may differ between these actors. However,<strong>in</strong> the end w<strong>in</strong>-w<strong>in</strong> situations should bepossible if the right bus<strong>in</strong>ess model is <strong>in</strong> place.Elements to optimise <strong>FDI</strong> can be applied atdifferent levels of the process of negotiat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>FDI</strong><strong>in</strong> land:A priori elements refer to the negotiation processof planned <strong>in</strong>vestment, i.e. how to <strong>in</strong>volve allaffected stakeholders <strong>in</strong> a transparent manner.Also all provisions relevant for consider<strong>in</strong>g localneeds fall <strong>in</strong>to this category, start<strong>in</strong>g with landproperty rights. Some of these elements are onlythe responsibility of the target country, likedomestic law on land property and all monitor<strong>in</strong>gand enforc<strong>in</strong>g mechanisms. Others are the jo<strong>in</strong>tresponsibility of both actors like all proceduralissues:• Generation of an accurate and reliable <strong>in</strong>formation(data) base. Most <strong>in</strong>formation comesfrom ‘grey’ literature, newspapers and <strong>in</strong>ternetblogs. To verify these sources, local <strong>in</strong>formationand stakeholder op<strong>in</strong>ions are necessary (s<strong>in</strong>ceobta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g accurate <strong>in</strong>formation about landdeals is quite a sensitive topic). Information onthe volume, conditions and possible effects of<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land on a global level as well as on theground <strong>in</strong> the target <strong>countries</strong> should be availablebeforehand <strong>in</strong> order to assess threats andopportunities adequately.• Transparency of the negotiations and participationof all relevant stakeholders. In order to beable to support their <strong>in</strong>terests, local landholdersmust be granted access to all relevant <strong>in</strong>formationand be <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> negotiations. “Free,prior, and <strong>in</strong>formed consent is the standard to beupheld” (v. Braun and Me<strong>in</strong>zen-Dick, (IFPRI),2009). In particular, the rights of <strong>in</strong>digenouspeople and other marg<strong>in</strong>alised groups are to beprotected. It is the media as well as civil societythat can make <strong>in</strong>formation available especially ifthere is no official announcement of negotiations.Obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation on large-scale land<strong>in</strong>vestments is the first step to ensure susta<strong>in</strong>abilityof <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land. The essential elements are:• Participation of all affected communities at thedifferent stages of an <strong>in</strong>vestment project (fromplann<strong>in</strong>g to evaluation), and• Implementation of an effective system for theredistribution of benefits and provision of publicgoods.• Policy dialogue between <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g and target<strong>countries</strong> and private <strong>in</strong>vestors. Public presentationsand discussions on the risks andchances of large-scale <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> land canhelp <strong>in</strong> reach<strong>in</strong>g an agreement on rules to f<strong>in</strong>d asusta<strong>in</strong>able approach which encompasses


53pro-poor-growth. Internationally acceptedstandards like “social- and ecological guidel<strong>in</strong>es”<strong>in</strong> which access to land and secur<strong>in</strong>g of land userights are stipulated should be considered.• Integration of smallholder production andshar<strong>in</strong>g of benefits. The ma<strong>in</strong> managementpr<strong>in</strong>ciple could be the <strong>in</strong>tegration of smallholderproduction <strong>in</strong>to the value-added cha<strong>in</strong>s of largeagribus<strong>in</strong>esses. Therefore, it is necessary togenerate a proper <strong>in</strong>centive system to stimulatesuch collaboration (Bickel and Breuer, 2009).The local community should benefit, not lose,from foreign <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> agriculture. Leasesare preferable to lump-sum compensationbecause they provide an ongo<strong>in</strong>g revenue streamwhen land is taken away for other uses. Contractfarm<strong>in</strong>g or out-grower schemes give moreopportunities because they leave smallholders <strong>in</strong>control of their land but still deliver output tothe outside <strong>in</strong>vestor. Explicit measures areneeded for enforcement if agreed-upon <strong>in</strong>vestmentor compensation is not forthcom<strong>in</strong>g.• Enforcement and Capacity development ofCivil Society Organisations (CSO), NGOs(especially rural ones) and farmer groups. CSOand NGOs and local stakeholder organisationsshould be formed through public support tocontrol <strong>in</strong>vestments and guarantee the participationof all stakeholder groups, especially therural communities which normally generatehigh transaction costs.• Capacity development <strong>in</strong> government <strong>in</strong>stitutions<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong> and <strong>in</strong>vestmentagencies of target <strong>countries</strong>. Members of<strong>in</strong>vestment agencies should be qualified tonegotiate <strong>in</strong>dividual bus<strong>in</strong>ess plans and modelsfor <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land. Therefore, it is necessary thatthey have <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>d the complexity of the subject<strong>in</strong> order to design and barga<strong>in</strong> contracts thatresult <strong>in</strong> a w<strong>in</strong>-w<strong>in</strong> situation for the foreign<strong>in</strong>vestor and the rural population. Key elementsof a susta<strong>in</strong>able <strong>in</strong>vestment concept are situationanalysis, multi-stakeholder process, def<strong>in</strong>ition ofa bus<strong>in</strong>ess model, capacity development alongthe value cha<strong>in</strong>, monitor<strong>in</strong>g and evaluation.• Respect of land rights. If people have to give uptheir land, there should be an adequate compensationthat enables for an equivalent livelihood.This requires def<strong>in</strong>ed and certified propertyrights which lie fully <strong>in</strong> the target country’sresponsibility. Respect<strong>in</strong>g land rights <strong>in</strong>cludescustomary and common property rights. Onenecessary precondition for enforc<strong>in</strong>g landproperty is the registration of land use rights asan <strong>in</strong>tegral part of a comprehensive land reformpolicy. In this context, recognised land rights(or cadastre) on community (village) level,<strong>in</strong>dividual or communal title deeds and certificatesas well as local conventions on land useand regulations could be elaborated and tested.Through clarification, documentation of landuse rights on the local, regional (decentralised)and national level, the legal protection andsecurity of smallholder families will be improved.• Environmental and social susta<strong>in</strong>ability. Toensure agricultural production practices are <strong>in</strong>l<strong>in</strong>e with the goals of environmental susta<strong>in</strong>ability,environmental impact assessment (EIA) andsocial impact assessments (SIA) are requireddur<strong>in</strong>g the negotiation process. If deals aref<strong>in</strong>alised, implementation has to be monitoredaga<strong>in</strong>st depletion of soils, loss of critical biodiversity,<strong>in</strong>creased greenhouse gas emissions orsignificant diversion of water from other humanor environmental uses.• Build<strong>in</strong>g up and implementation of susta<strong>in</strong>ableland use management systems. Throughparticipative land use plann<strong>in</strong>g processes basedon an appropriate <strong>in</strong>formation system which<strong>in</strong>cludes availability of land, exist<strong>in</strong>g land use,quality of land (soil, climate conditions), andtenure systems, transparency on national anddecentralised levels will be <strong>in</strong>creased. Transparencyis an important prerequisite for any furtherplann<strong>in</strong>g and responsible decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g on


54distribution of land and on eventual permitt<strong>in</strong>gland concessions.Ex post elements address mechanism to solveproblems that appear after <strong>FDI</strong> are implemented.• Compensation for expropriation can addresseither local farmers and depend then on respectivedomestic legal provisions <strong>in</strong> the targetcountry or foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors and will then bepart of a BIT.• Macroeconomic protection clauses can addresschanges <strong>in</strong> the macroeconomic situation <strong>in</strong> thetarget country. Trade restrictions can then beallowed which may affect the <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g countrynegatively but support the target country’seconomy. They should be restricted to a limitedperiod of time and are usually part of a BIT.• Food security protection clauses. Domesticfood security should have priority over thesupply of export markets. If national foodsecurity is at risk (for <strong>in</strong>stance, <strong>in</strong> case of anacute drought), export restrictions can supportdomestic food availability for the target country.As they may be counterproductive <strong>in</strong> the longrun, they have to be limited <strong>in</strong> time. They areallowed accord<strong>in</strong>g to the WTO and could becovered as well by BITs. Additionally, suchprovisions can be part of the private contract.More general provisions refer to the <strong>in</strong>ternationalcommunity:• Development of <strong>in</strong>ternational guidel<strong>in</strong>es for<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> land and natural resourcesabroad. The <strong>in</strong>stitutional arrangements could bemodelled after the <strong>in</strong>ternational bus<strong>in</strong>ess lawsadopted dur<strong>in</strong>g the past 10 years to preventcorrupt practices <strong>in</strong> the context of <strong>FDI</strong>. Thefollow<strong>in</strong>g policies and guidel<strong>in</strong>es could berelevant <strong>in</strong> this context: FAO Voluntary Guidel<strong>in</strong>esfor the Right to Food, EU <strong>Land</strong> PolicyGuidel<strong>in</strong>es, FAO Voluntary Guidel<strong>in</strong>es forResponsible Governance of Tenure of <strong>Land</strong> andother Natural Resources and the African <strong>Land</strong>Policy Initiative.• Enforcement of scientific research. Focusshould be on food security issues and theeconomic, social and ecological impacts of<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land <strong>in</strong> the target <strong>countries</strong>.All recommendations are <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with those ofother organisations deal<strong>in</strong>g with problems causedby <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land. The case studies reveal thenecessity of act<strong>in</strong>g accord<strong>in</strong>g to these recommendations,but they give evidence of some obstacles<strong>in</strong> implement<strong>in</strong>g them. Transparency is difficultto achieve as long as a lack of transparency is <strong>in</strong>the <strong>in</strong>terest of powerful groups <strong>in</strong> the society.The GTZ project <strong>in</strong> Lao PDR reveals that it takesextensive field research to generate reliable <strong>in</strong>formationabout the extent of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land and thatit requires the will<strong>in</strong>gness by national and localauthorities to co-operate. Moreover, it takes yearsto implement a system of land registration and toregister land titles. So regard<strong>in</strong>g the conditions <strong>in</strong>develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong>, it may be difficult to enforcethe rights of poor people and to implement an<strong>in</strong>stitutional framework that takes <strong>in</strong>to accounttheir needs.Moreover, recommendations given by several<strong>in</strong>stitutions suggest that there is a common sense<strong>in</strong> the target <strong>countries</strong> regard<strong>in</strong>g strategies ofdevelopment and the distribution of benefits. Theydo not deal with the difficulties of different groupsseek<strong>in</strong>g rent with<strong>in</strong> the target country. So theoverall problem cannot be reduced to an imbalanceof power between the foreign direct <strong>in</strong>vestoron the one side and the target country on theother. A comprehensive approach must considerthe political and societal environment with<strong>in</strong> thetarget country <strong>in</strong> order to develop a strategy thatis <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with <strong>in</strong>ternationally agreed developmentobjectives.Another opportunity is to address the <strong>in</strong>vestorsexplicitly. Regard<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestments done by governmentsor governmental organisations like SovereignWealth Funds and state-owned enterprises, acode of conduct could be established and enforcedby political agreements. Regard<strong>in</strong>g private enterprises,the code of conduct could be <strong>in</strong>tegrated<strong>in</strong>to guidel<strong>in</strong>es for corporate social responsibility.Given the fact that corporate social responsibilityis becom<strong>in</strong>g more and more important for at leastsome of the global players on the food and agrofuelsmarkets, this may be an opportunity toachieve some improvements.


55The second element of a dual approach recommendedby v. Braun and Me<strong>in</strong>zen-Dick (IFPRI,2009) consists of facilitat<strong>in</strong>g opportunities <strong>in</strong> thetarget <strong>countries</strong> by strengthen<strong>in</strong>g the policyenvironment and implementation capabilities.These target <strong>countries</strong> should improve <strong>in</strong>vestmentclimate through the rule of law and contractsecurity; pursue evidence-based agriculturalpolicies related to <strong>in</strong>centives, markets, technologies,and rural <strong>in</strong>frastructure; facilitate out-growerschemes and contract farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the smallholdersector; enhance market <strong>in</strong>formation systems thatcan po<strong>in</strong>t to opportunities for farm<strong>in</strong>g communities;and build extension systems that facilitateaccess to knowledge and services, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g ruralbank<strong>in</strong>g.To sum up: Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the results of the casestudies, the problems aris<strong>in</strong>g with <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land arenot so much a deficit <strong>in</strong> the legal environment ofthe target <strong>countries</strong>. There seem to be deficits <strong>in</strong>enforc<strong>in</strong>g the laws and <strong>in</strong> (the will<strong>in</strong>gness <strong>in</strong>)controll<strong>in</strong>g that give room for assign<strong>in</strong>g landconcessions not <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the <strong>in</strong>terests of thepoor. A lack of a comprehensive cadastral systemand the deficit of land titles aggravate transparencyand controll<strong>in</strong>g.Another approach to deal with the problemsaris<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land is to strengthen thecompetitiveness of contract farm<strong>in</strong>g. UNCTADconcludes <strong>in</strong> the World <strong>Investment</strong> Report 2009:”With regard to the mode of TNC <strong>in</strong>volvement,evidence from many develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong> showsthat through contract farm<strong>in</strong>g target <strong>countries</strong> canreceive most of the benefits related to TNCparticipation, while avoid<strong>in</strong>g a number of negativeconsequences.” But contract farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the frameof Transnational Corporations requires appropriatecapabilities of the farmers and appropriatetechnology and expertise to deliver quality andquantity of the products. A suitable organisationof local farmers may help to fulfil these requirements.In light of this, educat<strong>in</strong>g local farmers accord<strong>in</strong>gto the requirements of contract farm<strong>in</strong>g andassistance <strong>in</strong> organis<strong>in</strong>g contract farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> globalvalue cha<strong>in</strong>s can be a means to strengthen thecompetitiveness of relevant alternatives to <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong>terms of TNC participation.Referr<strong>in</strong>g to the Roundtable “Promot<strong>in</strong>g ResponsibleInternational <strong>Investment</strong> <strong>in</strong> Agriculture”mentioned <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>troduction, a first step towardsa coord<strong>in</strong>ated <strong>in</strong>ternational response to theacquisition of rights to land and related resourceshas been done (compare Government of Japan,World Bank, FAO, IFAD, UNCTAD 2009).At the roundtable it was generally agreed that<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> agriculture are vital for improv<strong>in</strong>gfood security and economic growth. On the otherhand many participants expressed an urgent needfor action to alleviate possible negative impactsassociated with large-scale <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>vestments<strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong>.Some analyses propose elements of a “code ofconduct”, general guidel<strong>in</strong>es and measures toovercome probable negative impacts. Importantrecommendations are outl<strong>in</strong>ed hereafter (comparee.g. v. Braun and Me<strong>in</strong>zen-Dick, (IFPRI), 2009;Cotula et al, (IIED, FAO, IFAD), 2009;Bickel and Breuer, 2009; Smaller and Mann ,(IISD), 2009 De Schutter, 2009).A code of conduct as a first element <strong>in</strong> a dualapproach for foreign land acquisition requires<strong>in</strong>ternational arrangements and laws that applyeverywhere, not only <strong>in</strong> the <strong>countries</strong> that aretargets of <strong>in</strong>vestments, which often have <strong>in</strong>sufficientlydeveloped legal <strong>in</strong>stitutions and enforcementmechanisms, but also <strong>in</strong> the <strong>countries</strong>where the <strong>in</strong>vestments orig<strong>in</strong>ate.


56Regard<strong>in</strong>g the pr<strong>in</strong>ciples of <strong>in</strong>ternational code ofconduct, the overwhelm<strong>in</strong>g view was that thesepr<strong>in</strong>ciples should have a flexible mechanism formonitor<strong>in</strong>g and consider country-specific circumstances.Fundamental pr<strong>in</strong>ciples should cover:• “<strong>Land</strong> and Resource Rights: Exist<strong>in</strong>g rights toland and natural resources are recognised andrespected.• Food Security: <strong>Investment</strong>s do not jeopardisefood security, but rather strengthen it.• Transparency, Good Governance and Enabl<strong>in</strong>gEnvironment: Processes for access<strong>in</strong>g land andmak<strong>in</strong>g associated <strong>in</strong>vestments are transparent,monitored and ensure accountability.• Consultation and Participation: Those materiallyaffected are consulted and agreements fromconsultations are recorded and enforced.• Economic viability and responsible agro-enterprise<strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g: Projects are viable economically,respect the rule of law, reflect <strong>in</strong>dustry bestpractice, and result <strong>in</strong> durable shared value.• Social Susta<strong>in</strong>ability: <strong>Investment</strong>s generatedesirable social and distributional impacts anddo not <strong>in</strong>crease vulnerability.• Environmental Susta<strong>in</strong>ability: Environmentalimpacts are quantified and measures taken toencourage susta<strong>in</strong>able resource use, whilem<strong>in</strong>imis<strong>in</strong>g and mitigat<strong>in</strong>g them negativeimpact.” (Government of Japan, World Bank,FAO, IFAD, UNCTAD 2009).Furthermore, the need for additional research andanalysis on the extent, nature and impact oflarge-scale <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> agriculture is underl<strong>in</strong>ed.Likewise the Federal M<strong>in</strong>istry for EconomicCooperation and Development (2009) has designedsix basic pr<strong>in</strong>ciples <strong>in</strong> order to be able tomake use of the possible opportunities andpotential of foreign <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> land.While the analysis of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land reveals risks andopportunities, the case studies conducted for thisreport also disclose the difficulties <strong>in</strong> achiev<strong>in</strong>g anempirical, comprehensive overview of the actualimpacts. The lack of transparency as well as thecomplexity of the subject aggravates the analysis.There is need to further gather and distribute<strong>in</strong>formation cover<strong>in</strong>g the general conditions andthe <strong>in</strong>terests of the <strong>in</strong>volved actors as well as on thenegotiation process and the impact on localsusta<strong>in</strong>able development. The impacts (economic,social and environmental) of <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land – eitherpositive or negative – need to be monitored andpublished, so that <strong>in</strong>terventions can take place ifnegative impacts are observed. Furthermore,capacity development <strong>in</strong> target <strong>countries</strong> may helpthose <strong>countries</strong> negotiate more favourable contractsthat br<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e the <strong>in</strong>terests of the <strong>in</strong>vestorwith the needs of the target country.


57Work<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> rice fieldsSlashed and burned old growthforest areaWater collection


58ReferencesAlexandratos, N. (2009):World food and agriculture to 2030/2050: Highlights and views from mid-2009. Contribution to FAOExpert Meet<strong>in</strong>g on How to Feed the World <strong>in</strong> 2050 24-26 June 2009, RomeAvailable at: ftp://ftp.fao.org/docrep/fao/012/ak542e/ak542e04.pdf, last visit 27/10/2009Bickel, M. and Breuer, T (2009):<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g <strong>countries</strong>. In Rural 21 – The <strong>in</strong>ternational Journal for Rural Development,Vol. 43, No. 2.Bru<strong>in</strong>sma, J. (2009):The Resource Outlook to 2050: By how much do land, water and crop yields need to <strong>in</strong>crease by 2050.Contribution to FAO Expert Meet<strong>in</strong>g on How to Feed the World <strong>in</strong> 2050 24-26 June 2009, RomeAvailable at: http://www.fao.org/fileadm<strong>in</strong>/templates/wsfs/docs/expert_paper/05-Bru<strong>in</strong>sma_ResourceOutlookto2050.pdf,last visit 27/10/09Cotula, L.; Vermeulen, S.; Leonard, R. and Keeley, J. (2009):<strong>Land</strong> Grab or development opportunity? Agricultural <strong>Investment</strong>s and <strong>in</strong>ternational deals <strong>in</strong> Africa,IIED, FAO, IFAD, London/Rome.Available at: ftp://ftp.fao.org/docrep/fao/011/ak241e/ak241e.pdf, last visit 07/07/2009.Cruz, R.V., H. Harasawa, M. Lal, S. Wu, Y. Anokh<strong>in</strong>, B. Punsalmaa, Y. Honda, M. Jafari, C. Liand N. Huu N<strong>in</strong>h (2007):Asia. Climate Change 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Work<strong>in</strong>g Group IIto the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. In: M.L. PARRY,O.F. CANZIANI, J.P. PALUTIKOF, P.J. VAN DER LINDEN AND C.E. HANSON (Eds.), CambridgeUniversity Press, Cambridge, UK, 469-506.)Available at: http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_ipcc_fourth_assessment_report_wg2_report_impacts_adaptation_and_vulnerability.htm, last vist 10/10/09De<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>ger, K. and M<strong>in</strong>ten, B. (1999):Poverty, Policies and Deforestation: the Case of Mexico, Economic Development and Cultural Change,1999, JanuaryDe Schutter, O. (2009):Large-scale land acquisition and leases: A set of core pr<strong>in</strong>ciples and measures to address human rightschallenges. Available at: http://www.srfood.org/images/stories/pdf/otherdocuments/22-srrtflarge-scalelandacquisitions-hrpr<strong>in</strong>ciples-9.6.09-2.pdf,last visit 07/07/2009.European Commission(2009a):Energy Statistics of Cambodia. Available at: http://ec.europa.eu/external_relations/energy/events/asem_energy_2009/docs/cambodia_en.pdf,last visit 09/03/09.


59European Commission (2009b):Energy Statistics of Lao PDR. Available at: http://ec.europa.eu/external_relations/energy/events/asem_energy_2009/docs/lao_en.pdf,last visit 09/03/09.FAO (2007):State of the World’s Forests 2007, Rome, 2007. Available at http://www.fao.org/docrep/009/a0773e/a0773e00.htm, last visit 09/30/09FAO (2008):The right to food and access to natural resources, Us<strong>in</strong>g Human Rights Arguments and Mechanisms toImprove Resource Access for the Rural Poor, Rome, 2008.FAO (2009a):Statistic Division – AquaStat. Available at: http://www.fao.org/nr/water/aquastat/<strong>countries</strong>/<strong>in</strong>dex.stm, lastvisit 09/03/09.FAO (2009b):Statistical Yearbook 2007-2008. Value of agricultural imports and exports are available at: http://www.fao.org/fileadm<strong>in</strong>/templates/ess/documents/publications_studies/statistical_yearbook/FAO_statistical_yearbook_2007-2008/c01.xls,last visit 09/03/09.FAO (2009c):From <strong>Land</strong> Grab to W<strong>in</strong>-W<strong>in</strong>. Seiz<strong>in</strong>g the Opportunities of International <strong>Investment</strong>s <strong>in</strong> Agriculture.Available at: ftp://ftp.fao.org/docrep/fao/011/ak357e/ak357e00.pdf, last visit 07/07/2009.FAO (2009d):Crop Prospects and Food Situation, No. 2, April. Available at: http://www.fao.org/docrep/011/ai481e/ai481e02.htm, last visit 09/08/09.FAO (2009e):Global Information and Early Warn<strong>in</strong>g System – Countries <strong>in</strong> Crisis Requir<strong>in</strong>g External Assistance.Available at: http://www.fao.org/Giews/english/hotspots/<strong>in</strong>dex.htm, last visit 09/09/09.Federal M<strong>in</strong>istry for Economic Cooperation and and Development (2009):Development Policy Stance on the Topic of <strong>Land</strong> Grabb<strong>in</strong>g – the Purchase and Leas<strong>in</strong>g of Large Areasof <strong>Land</strong> <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries: Discourse 015, BonnFischer, G., van Velthuizen, H., Shah, M. and F. Nachtergaele (2002):Global Agro-ecological Assessment for Agriculture <strong>in</strong> the 21st Century: Methodology and results,RR-02-002, IIASA, Laxenburg.


60Gop<strong>in</strong>ath, M., Pick, D., and Vasavada, U. (1999):The Economics of <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Direct</strong> <strong>Investment</strong> and Trade with an Application to the U.S. Food Process<strong>in</strong>gIndustry, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 1999, 81(2), pp. 442-452.Government of Japan, World Bank, FAO, IFAD, UNCTAD (2009):“Promot<strong>in</strong>g Responsible International <strong>Investment</strong> <strong>in</strong> Agriculture” Chair’s Summary of the Roundtableconcurrent with the 64th United Nations General Assembly. Available at: http://www.mofa.go.jp/policy/economy/fishery/agriculture/summary0909.pdf, last visit 10/01/09.GRAIN (2008):Seized! The 2008 <strong>Land</strong> Grab for Food and F<strong>in</strong>ancial Security, Gra<strong>in</strong> Brief<strong>in</strong>g. Available at: http://www.gra<strong>in</strong>.org/brief<strong>in</strong>gs_files/landgrab-2008-en.pdf, annex available at: http://www.gra<strong>in</strong>.org/front_files/landgrab-2008-en-annex.pdf, last visit 07/07/2009.GTZ (2006):Study on State <strong>Land</strong> Leases and Concessions <strong>in</strong> Lao PDR. <strong>Land</strong> Policy Study No. 4 under LLTP II.Vientiane, Lao-German <strong>Land</strong> Policy Development Project.GTZ (2009):The Food Price Crisis and the Right to Food Results of a symposium held <strong>in</strong> Eschborn <strong>in</strong> November 2008.Haralambous, S.; Liversage, H. and Romano, M. (2009):The Grow<strong>in</strong>g Demand for <strong>Land</strong> – Risks and Opportunities for Smallholder Farmers. Rome, IFAD,Discussion paper prepared for the Round Table organised dur<strong>in</strong>g the Thirty-second session of IFAD’sGovern<strong>in</strong>g Council, 18 February. Available at: www.ifad.org/events/gc/32/roundtables/2.pdf, last visit07/07/2009.IMF (2009):World Economic Outlook 2009. Available at: http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2009/01/weodata/<strong>in</strong>dex.aspx, last visit 09/03/09.Lopez, R. (1998):The Tragedy of the Commons <strong>in</strong> Côte d’Ivoire Agriculture: Empirical Evidence and Implications forEvaluat<strong>in</strong>g Trade Policies, The World Bank Economic Review, 12, 1, pp. 105-31.MAFF (2009):Economic <strong>Land</strong> Concessions. Available at: http://www.maff.gov.kh/elc/profiles.html, last visit 09/07/09.Nachtergaele, F. and George, H. (2009):How much land is available for agriculture, (unpublished paper), FAO, Rome.OXFAM (2009):Invest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> poor-farmers pays. Reth<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g how to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> agriculture. Oxfam Breif<strong>in</strong>g Paper 129, June2009.OECD (2009):Aid for trade at a glance 2009. Available at: http://www.oecd.org/document/56/0,3343,en_2649_34665_42835064_1_1_1_1,00.html, last visit 09/07/09.


61Royal Embassy of Cambodia <strong>in</strong> Wash<strong>in</strong>gton D.C (2008):Information Bullet<strong>in</strong> November 2008 - Volume 34. Available at http://www.embassyofcambodia.org/<strong>in</strong>formation_bullet<strong>in</strong>_vol_34.pdf, last visit 10/10/09.Smaller, C. and Mann, H. (2009):A Thirst for Distant <strong>Land</strong>s: <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> agricultural land and water. International Institute forSusta<strong>in</strong>able Development (IISD). Available at: http://www.iisd.org/pdf/2009/thirst_for_distant_lands.pdf,last visit 07/07/2009.Songwe, V. and K. De<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>ger, K. (2009):<strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Investment</strong>s <strong>in</strong> Agricultural Production: Opportunities and Challenges. World Bank Agricultural& Rural Development Notes, Issue 45. Available at: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/EXTARD/Resources/336681-1231508336979/Note45a.pdf, last visit 07/07/2009.Sturgeon, T.J. and G. Gereffi (2008):The Challenge of Global Value Cha<strong>in</strong>s: Why Integrative Trade Requires New Th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g and New Data.http://www.cggc.duke.edu/pdfs/GVCmetrics_Nov202008.pdf, last visit 09/30/09Transparency International (2008):Global Corruption Report 2008. Available at: http://www.transparency.org/publications/gcr/gcr_2008,last visit 08/31/09.Transparency International (2009):Persistently high corruption <strong>in</strong> low-<strong>in</strong>come <strong>countries</strong> amounts to an “ongo<strong>in</strong>g humanitarian disaster”.Available at: http://www.transparency.org/news_room/latest_news/press_releases/2008/2008_09_23_cpi_2008_en, last visit 08/31/09.Tucker, H.G. (2009):<strong>Foreign</strong> Large Scale <strong>Investment</strong>s <strong>in</strong> Agriculture, Hydropower and M<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g: Challenges and Opportunitiesfor Development Cooperation <strong>in</strong> Laos and Cambodia. Report prepared for GTZ Lao and theMekong River Commission (MRC), May 2009, draft version.U.S. Department of State (2009a):<strong>Investment</strong> Climate Statements 2009. Available at: http://www.state.gov/e/eeb/rls/othr/ics/2009/<strong>in</strong>dex.htm, last visit 09/07/09.U.S. Department of State (2009b):<strong>Investment</strong> Climate Statement – Cambodia, February. Available at: http://www.state.gov/e/eeb/rls/othr/ics/2009/117418.htm, last visit 09/07/09.U.S. Department of State (2009c):<strong>Investment</strong> Climate Statement – Laos, February. Available at: http://www.state.gov/e/eeb/rls/othr/ics/2009/117377.htm, last visit 09/07/09.U.S. Department of State (2009d):<strong>Investment</strong> Climate Statement – Madagascar, February. Available at: http://www.state.gov/e/eeb/rls/othr/ics/2009/117354.htm, last visit 09/07/09.


62U.S. Department of State (2009e):<strong>Investment</strong> Climate Statement – Mali, February. Available at: http://www.state.gov/e/eeb/rls/othr/ics/2009/117844.htm, last visit 09/07/09.United Nations (2007): Economic land concessions <strong>in</strong> Cambodia. A human rights perspective.Available at: http://cambodia.ohchr.org/webdocuments/reports/Thematic_rpt/Thematic%20Report%20on%20ELC_12-Jun-07_eng.pdf, last visit 09/09/09UNCTAD (2008a):World <strong>Investment</strong> Prospects Survey 2008-2010. New York and Geneva. Available at: http://www.unctad.org/en/docs/wips2008_en.pdf, last visit 07/07/2009.UNCTAD (2008b):World <strong>Investment</strong> Report 2008, Transnational Corporations and the Infrastructure Challenge. NewYork and Geneva. Available at: http://www.unctad.org/en/docs/wir2008_en.pdf, last visit 07/07/2009.UNCTAD (2009a):Recent Developments <strong>in</strong> International <strong>Investment</strong> Agreements (2008–June 2009), IIA MONITOR No.3 (2009). Available at: http://www.unctad.org/en/docs/webdiaeia20098_en.pdf, last visit 09/23/2009.UNCTAD (2009b):World <strong>Investment</strong> Report 2009, Transnational Corporations, Agriculture and Development. New Yorkand Geneva. Available at: http://www.unctad.org/en/docs/wir2009_en.pdf, last visit 09/30/2009.UNDP (2008):Human Development Report - Statistic Division. Available at: http://hdr.undp.org/en/media/HDI_2008_EN_Tables.pdf, last visit 09/03/09.v. Braun, J. and Meizen-Dick, R. (2009):„<strong>Land</strong> Grabb<strong>in</strong>g“ by <strong>Foreign</strong> Investors <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries: Risk and Opportunities. IFPRI PolicyBrief 13. Available at: http://www.ifpri.org/pubs/bp/bp013.pdf, last visit 07/07/2009.Vientiane Times (2009):“<strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> Laos jumps nearly fourfold this year”, 27/10/2009.Welthungerhilfe (2008):Global Hunger Index – The Challenge of Hunger 2008. Available at: http://www.welthungerhilfe.de/fileadm<strong>in</strong>/media/pdf/WHI/GHI_2008.pdf, last visit 09/09/09.World Bank (2007):Quick Query – World Development Indicators. Available at: http://ddp-ext. worldbank.org/ext/DDPQQ/member.do?method=getMembers&userid=1&queryId=135, last visit 09/09/09.World Bank (2009)Do<strong>in</strong>g Bus<strong>in</strong>ess 2009. Available at: http://www.do<strong>in</strong>gbus<strong>in</strong>ess.org/documents/DB09Easeofdo<strong>in</strong>gbus<strong>in</strong>essrankmethod.pdf,last visit 31/08/09.World Resource Institute (2005):Earth trends: Global Forest Assessment. Available at: http://earthtrends.wri.org/country_profiles/<strong>in</strong>dex.php?theme=7, last visit 09/03/09.


63Onl<strong>in</strong>e Sources:Farmland Grab:http://farmlandgrab.org/.The <strong>Land</strong> Coalition:http://www.landcoalition.org/cpl-blog/.World Bank (Glossary):http://www.worldbank.org/depweb/english/beyond/global/glossary.html.UNCTAD (2009c), Database on Bilateral <strong>Investment</strong> Agreements, :HTTP://WWW.UNCTADXI.ORG/TEMPLATES/DOCSEARCH. ASPX?ID=779/.Poll<strong>in</strong>ation of vanilla


64GlossaryAgro-fuelsAgro-fuels are def<strong>in</strong>ed as liquid energy sourcesproduced from agricultural commodities (e.g.from sugar, starch and oil crops), which are used<strong>in</strong> the transport sector as well as for thermalenergy generation (heat and power). Fuels fromagricultural waste and residues are less controversialand not <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> this def<strong>in</strong>ition.Source: GTZ.<strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Direct</strong> <strong>Investment</strong> (<strong>FDI</strong>)<strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong>volves a last<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong>effective management control over an enterprise.<strong>Foreign</strong> direct <strong>in</strong>vestment can <strong>in</strong>clude buy<strong>in</strong>gshares of an enterprise <strong>in</strong> another country, re<strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>gearn<strong>in</strong>gs of a foreign owned enterprise <strong>in</strong>the country where it is located, and parent firmsextend<strong>in</strong>g loans to their foreign affiliates. InternationalMonetary Fund (IMF) guidel<strong>in</strong>es consideran <strong>in</strong>vestment to be a foreign direct <strong>in</strong>vestment ifit accounts for at least 10 % of the foreign firm’svot<strong>in</strong>g stock of shares. However, many <strong>countries</strong>set a higher threshold because 10 % is often notenough to establish effective management controlof a company or demonstrate an <strong>in</strong>vestor’s last<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>terest.Source: World Bank.Contract farm<strong>in</strong>gContractual partnership between small farmersand a process<strong>in</strong>g and/or market<strong>in</strong>g firm for thepurpose of commercial production, frequently atpredeterm<strong>in</strong>ed prices. Depend<strong>in</strong>g on the termsof contract, small farmers may receive technicalassistance, seeds, agro-chemicals and some creditfrom their contract-partners, and are ensured ofguaranteed markets, secure <strong>in</strong>come and employment.Source: HU Berl<strong>in</strong>; SLE.<strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>Land</strong><strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land by a foreign company or state that isbased on a last<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> tak<strong>in</strong>g control overland use rights. The transaction <strong>in</strong>cludes eitherrights of land use or land-ownership. The landuse rights are generally valid for a limited periodand can possibly be extended. Source: (Owndef<strong>in</strong>ition follow<strong>in</strong>g the general def<strong>in</strong>ition of <strong>FDI</strong>).Increased access to <strong>FDI</strong> is seen as one of the keybenefits of globalization because it is thoughtto lead to capital formation, technology andknowledge transfer, higher wages and greater jobopportunities. The UN Conference on F<strong>in</strong>ancefor Development argues that <strong>FDI</strong>, along with<strong>in</strong>ternational f<strong>in</strong>ancial stability, are vital componentsto national and <strong>in</strong>ternational developmentefforts. Many other <strong>in</strong>ternational policy documentsstress the value of <strong>FDI</strong> but critics areconcerned that its benefits are very unequallydistributed, both globally and with<strong>in</strong> societies.Source: WHO.Forest AreaForest area is the land spann<strong>in</strong>g more than 0.5 hawith trees higher than 5 metres and a canopycover of more than 10 %, or trees able to reachthese thresholds <strong>in</strong> situ. It does not <strong>in</strong>clude landthat is predom<strong>in</strong>antly under agricultural or urbanland use. Forest is determ<strong>in</strong>ed both by the presenceof trees and the absence of other predom<strong>in</strong>antland uses. The trees should be able to reach am<strong>in</strong>imum height of 5 metres (m) <strong>in</strong> situ. Areasunder reforestation that have not yet reached butare expected to reach a canopy cover of 10 % anda tree height of 5 m are <strong>in</strong>cluded, as are temporarilyunstocked areas, result<strong>in</strong>g from human <strong>in</strong>terventionor natural causes, which are expected toregenerate. It <strong>in</strong>cludes: areas with bamboo andpalms provided that height and canopy covercriteria are met; forest roads, firebreaks and othersmall open areas; forest <strong>in</strong> national parks, naturereserves and other protected areas such as those ofspecific scientific, historical, cultural or spiritual


65<strong>in</strong>terest; w<strong>in</strong>dbreaks, shelterbelts and corridorsof trees with an area of more than 0.5 ha andwidth of more than 20 m; plantations primarilyused for forestry or protective purposes, such as:rubber-wood plantations and cork, oak stands.It excludes: tree stands <strong>in</strong> agricultural productionsystems, for example <strong>in</strong> fruit plantations andagroforestry systems. The term also excludes trees<strong>in</strong> urban parks and gardens.Source: FAO.Sovereign Wealth Funds (SWFs)Sovereign wealth funds are government <strong>in</strong>vestmentvehicles that are funded by foreign currencyreserves but managed separately from officialcurrency reserves. Basically, they are pools ofmoney governments <strong>in</strong>vest for profit.Source: U.S. Department of the Treasury.Susta<strong>in</strong>able DevelopmentAccord<strong>in</strong>g to the United Nations World Commissionon Environment and Development (1987),susta<strong>in</strong>able development is “development thatmeets the needs of the present without compromis<strong>in</strong>gthe ability of future generations to meettheir own needs.” Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the more operational(practice-oriented) def<strong>in</strong>ition used by theWorld Bank, susta<strong>in</strong>able development is “a processof manag<strong>in</strong>g a portfolio of assets to preserve andenhance the opportunities people face.” Susta<strong>in</strong>abledevelopment <strong>in</strong>cludes economic, environmental,and social susta<strong>in</strong>ability, which can beachieved by rationally manag<strong>in</strong>g physical, natural,and human capital.Source: World Bank.Susta<strong>in</strong>able land use<strong>Land</strong> use that achieves production sufficient tomeet the needs of present and future populationswhile conserv<strong>in</strong>g or enhanc<strong>in</strong>g the land resourceson which that production depends.Source:World Agroforestry CentreTransnational corporations (TNCs)Transnational corporations are <strong>in</strong>corporated orun<strong>in</strong>corporated enterprises compris<strong>in</strong>g parententerprises and their foreign affiliates. A parententerprise is def<strong>in</strong>ed as an enterprise that controlsassets of other entities <strong>in</strong> <strong>countries</strong> other than itshome country, usually by own<strong>in</strong>g a certa<strong>in</strong> equitycapital stake. An equity capital stake of 10% ormore of the ord<strong>in</strong>ary shares or vot<strong>in</strong>g power for an<strong>in</strong>corporated enterprise, or its equivalent for anun<strong>in</strong>corporated enterprise, is normally consideredas the threshold for the control of assets. A foreignaffiliate is an <strong>in</strong>corporated or un<strong>in</strong>corporatedenterprise <strong>in</strong> which an <strong>in</strong>vestor, who is a resident<strong>in</strong> another economy, owns a stake that permits alast<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> the management of that enterprise(an equity stake of 10% for an <strong>in</strong>corporatedenterprise, or its equivalent for an un<strong>in</strong>corporatedenterprise).Source: World <strong>Investment</strong> report 2009


66Reported <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land (2000-2009) exceed<strong>in</strong>g 5,000 haAfricaTarget Country Investor Dimension Type of <strong>Land</strong> Use Bus<strong>in</strong>ess StatusAngola Lonrho (UK) 25,000 ha leased(Lonrho is negotiat<strong>in</strong>gfor a further 125,000ha <strong>in</strong> Mali andMalawi)RiceSignedCameroon IKO (Ch<strong>in</strong>a) 10,000 ha Rice ImplementedDemocratic Rep.of the CongoSOCAPALM (Belgium) 58,063 ha for 60yearsPalm oilCh<strong>in</strong>a (ZTE International) 2.8 million ha Agrofuel oil palmplantationEni (Italy) 180,000 ha Palm oilSignedSignedMagIndustries (Canada) 68,000 ha Eucalyptus SignedEgyptJenat; Jo<strong>in</strong>t venture of Tadco,Almara<strong>in</strong> and Al-Jouf (SaudiArabia)10,000 haUS$ 100 millionBarley, wheat, andlivestock feedUnknownJanan (UAE) 42,000 ha Wheat (no exportplanned)Ethiopia Flora EcoPower (Germany) 56,000 ha Agrofuel crops;contract farm<strong>in</strong>garrangementIndia US$ 4 billion Agriculture, flowergrow<strong>in</strong>g, and sugarestatesKaruturi (India) 40,000ha Maize, rice andvegetablesSigned; right of usefor 50 yearsUnknownFri-El Green Power (Italy) 30,000 ha Agrofuels SignedArdent Energy Group (USA) 15,000 ha Agrofuels SignedAgriNexus (Malaysia) withMohammed al-Amoudi (based<strong>in</strong> Saudi Arabia and Ethiopia)Ethio Agri-CEFT (SaudiArabia)30,000ha Sugar cane; 100,000ha for agrofuelsplannedSigned, Ethiopia hasagreed to grant <strong>in</strong>total 300,000 haSigned19,200 ha Coffee, tea, crops SignedSun Biofuels (UK) 80,000 ha Jatropha ImplementedDjibouti 5,000 ha Unknown SignedDubai World Trad<strong>in</strong>gCompany (UAE)5,000 ha Jo<strong>in</strong>t venture forteaSignedBecco Biofuels (UK) 35,000 ha Agrofuels Signed or undernegotiationHovev Agriculture Ltd.(Israel)The National BiodiselCorporation (NBC) (Isreal,Germany, USA)UAE40,000 ha grantedexpand<strong>in</strong>g to400,000 haAgrofuels190,000 ha Jatropha and otheragrofuels5,000 ha;US$ 300 millionTeaSignedSigned or undernegotiationSignedIDC <strong>Investment</strong> (Denmark) 15,000 ha Jatropha ImplementedLHB (Israel) 100,000 ha Jatropha


67AfricaTarget Country Investor Dimension Type of <strong>Land</strong> Use Bus<strong>in</strong>ess StatusKenya Qatar 40,000 ha leased <strong>in</strong>exchange for fund<strong>in</strong>g US$2.3billion portBioenergy International(Switzerland)Fruit and vegetablecultivationSigned93,000 ha Jatropha PlannedLiberia Dom<strong>in</strong>ion Farms (USA) 17,000 ha Rice and othercropsEquatorial Biofuels Limited(EBF), wholly owend by EquatorialPalm Oil (EPO) (UK)Madagascar Sime Darby Bhd (Malaysia) 220,000ha;US$ 800 million169,000 ha Palm oil SignedPalm oil and RubberVarun (India) 230,000 ha Rice, maize andlentilsDAEWOO Logistics (SouthKorea) / Madagascar FutureEnterprise (MFE)MadabeefMalagasy company,f<strong>in</strong>anced and owned bybritish <strong>in</strong>vestors1.3 million ha Maize and 300,00 hapalm oil200,000 ha;US$ 480 millionLivestockSUCOCOMA (Ch<strong>in</strong>a) 10,000 ha Sugar caneAvana Group (UnitedK<strong>in</strong>gdom)Implemented s<strong>in</strong>ce2003 planned to beexpandedSignedPlannedDiscont<strong>in</strong>ued10,000 ha Jatropha PlannedGlobal Agro-fuel (Lebanon) 100,000 ha JatrophaDelta Petroli (Italy); <strong>in</strong>vestmentof nearly EUR 50 million50,000 ha JatrophaER Company 80,000 ha Jatropha UnknownBio Energy Limited (Malagasycompany with Australian<strong>in</strong>terests)120,000 ha JatrophaGEM Biofuels (UK) 452,500 ha JatrophaJ-Oils (France) 10,000 ha JatrophaJSL Agro-fuels (Germany) 30,000 ha Jatropha PlannedNew Ecology Oils (NEO)(France) <strong>in</strong>vestment of EUR8.4 million <strong>in</strong> the first twoyearsNOTS Renewable Energy (TheNetherlands)35,000 ha Jatropha15,000 ha JatrophaOji Paper (Japan) 30,000 ha Eucalyptus andAcaciaOSHO Group (South Africa) 100,000 ha Sugar caneproduction forethanolSithe Global (USA) 60,000 ha Palm oil productionfor ethanolSOPREMAD (France) 15,000 ha Sugar cane productionfor ethanol


68Reported <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land (2000-2009) exceed<strong>in</strong>g 5,000 haAfricaTarget Country Investor Dimension Type of <strong>Land</strong> Use Bus<strong>in</strong>ess StatusMadagascarMaliTozzi Renewable Energy(Italy)Unitech and United TechnologiesGroup(USA)Les Cultures du Cap Est;Malagasy company, f<strong>in</strong>ancedby an Indian GroupDEKO SA(South Africa); <strong>in</strong>Madagascar represented byDEKOMADProject Malibya; LibyanAfrican <strong>Investment</strong>Portfolio (LAP) (Lybia)Millenium Challenge Account(MCA) (USA)100,000 ha;US$ 300 millionJatropha150,000 ha Sunflower for oilproduction9,100 ha Palm oil for<strong>in</strong>dustrial purposes33,000 ha Agroforestry (p<strong>in</strong>e)100,000 ha Rice Signed16,000 ha Rice and vegetables SignedAl-Korayev (Saudi Arabia) 100,000 ha Unknown PlannedSouth Africa and Ch<strong>in</strong>a 55,000 ha Sugar cane PlannedLibya Projet de SOSUMAR US$ 170 million Sugar cane Planned butproblems concern<strong>in</strong>gcompensation of thefarmersMalawi Djibouti 55,000 ha Unknown SignedMozambique Ch<strong>in</strong>a US$ 800 million Rice Discont<strong>in</strong>ued(political opposition)NigeriaAgric-tech Ltd(UK)Republic of theCongoSekab (Sweden) 100,000 ha Agrofuel crops Under negotiationTrans4mationAgric-tech Ltd (UK)10,000 ha Unknown SignedAgri SA (South Africa) 10 million ha Maiz, soya, poultryand diaryProcana, owned by BioEnergy Africa (British<strong>in</strong>terests)24,500 ha Sugar cane SignedExpected to beimplemented soonSun Biofuels (UK) Unknown Jatropa ImplementedAgriterra (Agricultural<strong>Investment</strong>fund with a<strong>in</strong>shareholders <strong>in</strong> US andEurope)20,000 ha Livestock ImplementatedCAMEC (UK) 30,000 ha Sugar cane foragrufuelsTrans4mation10,000 ha Unknown SignedViscount Energy (Ch<strong>in</strong>a) US$ 80,000 Sugar cane,CassavaVietnam Africa AgriculturalDevelopment Company(VAADC) (Vietnam)Agri SA (South Africa)Implemented10,000 ha Rice Planned200,000 ha offered tofarmers’ unionIn negotioation withthe governmentUnknown Planned but delayed


69AfricaTarget Country Investor Dimension Type of <strong>Land</strong> Use Bus<strong>in</strong>ess StatusSudanTanzaniaSaudi Arabia (Hail AgriculturalDevelopment Co)9,200-10,117 haleased (60% f<strong>in</strong>ancedby Saudi government)Wheat, vegetables,and animal feedSignedSouth Korea 690,000 ha Wheat SignedUnited Arab Emirates (UAE) 378,000 ha Unknown ImplementedUAE (Abu Dhabi Fund forDevelopment)30,000 ha Corn, alfalfa, andpossibly wheat,potatoes, and beansEgypt Unknown 2 million tons ofwheat annuallyCitadel Capital (Egypt)210,000 ha; right ofuse for 99 yearsSugar cane, corn,wheatSignedSignedSignedJarch Capital (USA) 400,000 ha Unknown SignedSaudi Arabia 500,000 ha Unknown RequestedJordan 25,000 ha Livestock and cropsSun Biofuels (UK) withTanzania <strong>Investment</strong> Center(TIC)Ch<strong>in</strong>a (Int. Water and ElectricCorp.)5,500 ha Jatropha Signed101,000 ha Corn Rights of usereceivedTadco (Saudi Arabia) US$ 40 million Wheat PlannedD1 Oils (UK) 60,000 ha Jatropha SignedSouth Corea ca. 100,000 ha Food production andprocess<strong>in</strong>gUnder negotiationCAMS Group (UK) 45,000 ha Sweet sorghum ImplementedUganda Heibei Company (Ch<strong>in</strong>a) 40,500 ha Poulty, cattle, maiz,rice wheatEgypt 840,000 ha Unknown PlannedZambia Marli <strong>Investment</strong>s Ltd. US$ 69 million Agrofuels PlannedZimbabweEgypt, Ethiopiaand SudanRepublic of theCongoSigned for first 1000ha; further operationsplannedCh<strong>in</strong>a 2 million ha Jatropha RequestedD1 Oils (UK) 45,000 ha Agrofuels SignedCh<strong>in</strong>a (Int. Water and ElectricCorp.)101,000 ha Corn Right of use receivedTadco (Saudi Arabia) US$ 40 million Wheat PlannedVietnam Africa AgriculturalDevelopment Company(VAADC) (Vietnam)Agri SA (South Africa)10,000 ha Rice Planned200,000 ha offered tofarmers’ unionUnknown Planned but delayed


70Reported <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land (2000-2009) exceed<strong>in</strong>g 5,000 haAsiaTarget Country Investor Dimension Type of <strong>Land</strong> Use Bus<strong>in</strong>ess StatusCambodia Vietnam Rubber Group 100,000 ha Rubber UnknownCh<strong>in</strong>ese Farm Cooperation –Pheapimex GroupMarubeni CorporationRethy <strong>Investment</strong> CambodiaOil Palm Co., Ltd. (MRICOP);jo<strong>in</strong>t venture owned by MongRethy of Cambodia (60%),Borim Universal of Korea(30%) and Lavanaland ofMalaysia (10%)Jo<strong>in</strong>t venture betweenMittapheap-Men Sarun andRama Khmer International ofCambodia, and GlobaltechSdn. Bhd. Of MalaysiaKuwaitright of use for 70years; 300,000 ha2004: feasibility studyfor 11,231 ha concessionarea; 7,600ha rubber plantations“develop spareforest”Signed (2000)Rubber Planned (s<strong>in</strong>ce 2004)11,000 ha Palm oil <strong>Land</strong> concessionseceived 199620,000 ha Palm oil land concessionseceived 1995300,000 ha;US$ 200 millionAgricultural production;riceQatar Unknown Hydropower,agriculturalproductionCh<strong>in</strong>a Unknown 20-30 years landlease; rice, gra<strong>in</strong>sand livestock feedfor export to KoreaPlanned (May 2008)UnknownCh<strong>in</strong>a 130,000 ha rice SignedSouth Korea 200,000 ha “w<strong>in</strong>-w<strong>in</strong> to restoreforestry andproduce Agrofuels”Green Rich Co. Ltd.(Ch<strong>in</strong>a)Ch<strong>in</strong>a National Corporationfor Oversea EconomicCooperation Loadstars DevelopmentCo., Ltd.60,200 ha nowreduced toCh<strong>in</strong>a Goldman Sachs (USA) US$ 450 – 500millionIndonesiaSaudi Arabia (B<strong>in</strong> LadenGroup)Palm oil and acacia8,000 ha Agricultural and<strong>in</strong>dustrial crops500,000 ha;US$ 4.3 billionPoultry and pigfarmsRicePlanned (2008)Signed (October2009)Implemented s<strong>in</strong>ce1998; right fo usefor 70 yearsImplemented s<strong>in</strong>ce2000ImplementedDiscont<strong>in</strong>uedIndia 56,000 ha Palm oil ImplementedSime Darby Bhd (Malaysia) 195,856 ha Palm oil Implemented


71AsiaTarget Country Investor Dimension Type of <strong>Land</strong> Use Bus<strong>in</strong>ess StatusLaos Vietnam Rubber Group 100,000 ha Rubber UnknownKuwait 200,000 ha Crop production forexportJapan 34,000 ha Food, energy, cashcropsCh<strong>in</strong>a,ZTE International(Ch<strong>in</strong>ese) <strong>in</strong> partnership withDynasty Company, a LaotianfirmThailand,Mitr Lao Sugar, asubsidisary of Mitr PholGroup Co. Ltd.Memorandom ofcooperation Signed;deals PlannedUnknown10,000 ha Cassava Unknown10,000 ha Sugar cane <strong>Land</strong> concession <strong>in</strong>2006 (8,000ha areplanted); request forfurther 10,000(2009) and 24,000(<strong>in</strong> 3-5 years)Malaysia Sime Darby Bhd 329,470 ha Palm oil ImplementatedPakistanSaudi Arabia and other GulfStates405 000 ha Food Under negotiationUAE (Abraaj Capital) 324,000 ha Unknown ImplementedPhilipp<strong>in</strong>es Bahra<strong>in</strong> 10,000 ha Agro-fishery SignedVietnamCh<strong>in</strong>a 1.24 million ha Unknown Discont<strong>in</strong>uedQatar 100,000 ha Unknown PlannedSaudi Arabia 20,000 ha banana p<strong>in</strong>eapples PlannedSouth Korea 20,000 ha Jatropha and sugarcane for ethanolQatar <strong>Investment</strong>Authority (Qatar)US$ 1 billion jo<strong>in</strong>tfundAgriculturalproductionUnknown


72Reported <strong>FDI</strong> <strong>in</strong> land (2000-2009) exceed<strong>in</strong>g 5,000 haEastern Europe and Central AsiaTarget Country Investor Dimension Type of <strong>Land</strong> Use Bus<strong>in</strong>ess StatusLithuania,Estonia andLatviaLithuania 35,000 ha AgriculturalproductionFund raised 2003Ukra<strong>in</strong>e Morgan Stanley (USA) 40,000 ha Unknown Implemented<strong>Land</strong>kom (UK) 100,000 ha Unknown ImplementedRenaissance Capital (Russia) 331,000 ha Unknown ImplementedLibya 100,000 ha Unknown SignedRussia Alpcot Agro (Sweden) 128,000 ha Unknown ImplementedTrigon (Denmark) 100,000 ha Unknown ImplementedBlack Earth Farm<strong>in</strong>g(Sweden)Khorol Zerno LLC (SouthKorea major stakeholder)331,000 ha Unknown Implemented10,000 ha Unknown SignedRussian Gra<strong>in</strong> (Russia) 87,000 ha Wheat, barley Fund raisedLat<strong>in</strong> AmericaTarget Country Investor Dimension Type of <strong>Land</strong> Use Bus<strong>in</strong>ess StatusArgent<strong>in</strong>a Olam International (Indian 12,000 ha Soybeans, corn Signedowned))Arumugam (Malaysia) 600,000 ha Agrofuels SignedSouth Korea 21,000 ha Unknown SignedBrazil Mitsui (Japan) 100,000 ha Soybeans ImplementedCalyxAgro 28,000 ha Soybeans, cotton,sugar caneFund raisedCosan (Brazil) and 128,000 ha Unknown Implemented


73OtherTarget Country Investor Dimension Type of <strong>Land</strong> Use Bus<strong>in</strong>ess StatusSouth Africaand otherSub-saharan<strong>countries</strong>WorldAfricaAfrican <strong>Land</strong> Fund (ALF)Emergent Asset Managementand Gra<strong>in</strong>vestSaudi Company for Agricultural<strong>Investment</strong> and AnimalProduction (Saudi Arabia)Qatar <strong>Investment</strong> Authority(Qatar)Agricapital (Bahra<strong>in</strong>)Agri-Vie (South Africa'sDevelopment Bank, KelloggFoundation, etc.)150,000 ha AgriculturalproductionUS$ 800 millioncompany to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong>agricultural projectsabroadUS$ 60 billionsovereign wealthfund to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> foodand energyUS$ 1 billion<strong>in</strong>vestment vehicleformed by Abu Dhabi<strong>Investment</strong> House,Ithmaar Bank, andGulf F<strong>in</strong>ance Houseto <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> agriculturePrivate equity fund israis<strong>in</strong>g up to US$ 100million to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong>agricultural projects<strong>in</strong> Ghana, Kenya,Nigeria, South Africa,Tanzania, and UgandaTurkey Bahra<strong>in</strong> (Agricapital) US$ 500 millionmay rise toUS$ 3 - 6 billionGeorgia, Egypt,PakistanBahra<strong>in</strong> MAP (Market AccessPromotion) Services GroupUS$ 2.7 millionUnknownMAP has jo<strong>in</strong>edother Gulf partnersto form a MiddleEast Food Fund thatwill collectively<strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> foodproduction <strong>in</strong> nearby<strong>countries</strong> for theGulf marketEUR 2 billion raised,total of EUR 3billion plannedUnknownUnknownUnknownUnknownSignedImplementedSources: Own compilation based on GRAIN, 2008; V. BRAUN AND MEINZEN-DICK (IFPRI), 2009; Cotula et al. (IIED, FAO, IFAD), 2009.


Deutsche Gesellschaft fürTechnische Zusammenarbeit (GTZ) GmbHDag-Hammarskjöld - Weg 1 – 565760 Eschborn / GermanyT + 49 61 96 79 - 0F + 49 61 96 79 - 11 15E <strong>in</strong>fo@gtz.deI www.gtz.de

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!