12.07.2015 Views

no. 51 | january 2009

no. 51 | january 2009

no. 51 | january 2009

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>no</strong>. <strong>51</strong> | <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong>Postneoliberalism – A beginning debatePreface ................................................................................................................................................ 3Postneoliberalism : catch-all word or valuable analytical and political concept?– Aims of a beginning debate Ulrich Brand and Nicola Sekler .............................................................. 5Ways out of the crisis of neoliberalism Michael Brie ..........................................................................15Postneoliberalism and its bifurcations Ana Esther Ceceña ..................................................................33Postneoliberalism and post-Fordism– Is there a new period in the capitalist mode of production? Alex Demirovic ...................................45Postneoliberalism from and as a counter-hegemonic perspective Nicola Sekler ................................ 59Postneoliberalism or postcapitalism?The failure of neoliberalism in the financial market crisis Elmar Altvater......................................... 73‘Neoliberalism’ and development policy – Dogma or progress? Kurt Bayer ..................................... 89Environmental crises and the ambiguous postneoliberalising of nature Ulrich Brand ......................103The crisis of neoliberalism and the impasse of the union movement Gregory Albo .........................119Women peasants, food security and biodiversity in the crisis of neoliberalism Christa Wichterich ........133On recent projects and experiences of the sufficiency eco<strong>no</strong>my: a critiqueChanida Chanyapate and Alec Bamford ................................................................................................143Struggles against Wal-Martisation and neoliberal competitiveness in (southern) China– Towards postneoliberalism as an alternative? Ngai-Ling Sum .......................................................157Postneoliberalism in Latin America Emir Sader ..............................................................................171Notes on postneoliberalism in Argentina Verónica Gago and Diego Sztulwark ..................................181Realistic postneoliberalism – A view from South Africa Patrick Bond ............................................193Notes on contributors ......................................................................................................................212


development dialogue<strong>no</strong>. <strong>51</strong> <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong>Postneoliberalism – A beginning debateAck<strong>no</strong>wledgements ..................................................................................................... 2Preface ........................................................................................................................3Postneoliberalism : catch-all word or valuable analytical and political concept?– Aims of a beginning debate...................................................................................... 5Ulrich Brand and Nicola SeklerWays out of the crisis of neoliberalism ....................................................................... 15Michael BriePostneoliberalism and its bifurcations .........................................................................33Ana Esther CeceñaPostneoliberalism and post-Fordism– Is there a new period of capitalist mode of production? ...........................................45Alex DemirovicPostneoliberalism from and as a counter-hegemonic perspective ...............................59Nicola SeklerPostneoliberalism or postcapitalism?The failure of neoliberalism in the financial market crisis ..........................................73Elmar Altvater‘Neoliberalism’ and development policy – Dogma or progress? .................................89Kurt BayerEnvironmental crises and the ambiguous postneoliberalising of nature .................... 103Ulrich BrandThe crisis of neoliberalism and the impasse of the union movement ........................ 119Gregory AlboWomen peasants, food security and biodiversity in the crisis of neoliberalism ......... 133Christa WichterichOn recent projects and experiences of the sufficiency eco<strong>no</strong>my: a critique ..............143Chanida Chanyapate and Alec BamfordStruggles against Wal-Martisation and neoliberal competitiveness in (southern) China– Towards postneoliberalism as an alternative? ......................................................... 157Ngai-Ling SumPostneoliberalism in Latin America..........................................................................171Emir SaderNotes on postneoliberalism in Argentina ................................................................. 181Verónica Gago and Diego SztulwarkRealistic postneoliberalism – A view from South Africa .......................................... 193Patrick BondNotes on contributors .............................................................................................. 212


Ack<strong>no</strong>wledgementsWe would like to thank all the contributors for their willingness toparticipate actively in this – with regard to the authors’ provenance– truly international(ist) project. We are happy and proud to havesuch a broad range of critical thinkers represented in this volume ofDevelopment Dialogue. Special thanks go to the Dag-HammarskjöldFoundation in Uppsala and here to Henning Melber and MattiasLasson who supported this project from the very beginning. We arealso indebted to Stefan Armborst, Wendy Davies, Alison Entrekin,Marisa García Mareco and Peter Thomas for the translation ofseveral texts from German, Spanish and Portuguese into English. Thetranslations were made possible financially by the Rosa LuxemburgFoundation (Germany/Berlin). Last but <strong>no</strong>t least, we are deeplygrateful to Wendy Davies who edited the texts under e<strong>no</strong>rmous timepressure but in an excellent way and gave this issue its final form.Thank you very much.We hope that this volume will contribute to and further inspirean important debate on alternative ways of organising society andconcrete possibilities of achieving this.Vienna, December 2008Ulrich Brand and Nicola Sekler


PrefaceThe Dag Hammarskjöld Foundation has a long tradition of engagementrelated to global governance issues. It has therefore also activelyparticipated in World Social Forum (WSF) events ever since thesebegan. As a result of its presence at the WSF in January 2007 in Nairobi,the Foundation published its Development Dialogue <strong>no</strong>. 49 in November2007 on Global civil society – More or less democracy? The volumegathered a variety of approaches, voices and views within the widepa<strong>no</strong>rama of actors related to the WSF. Some of the contributionswere originally presented and discussed at a panel in Nairobi.The current volume is further evidence of the Foundation’s interactionwith scholars and activists who are pursuing an analytically basedadvocacy role for and within social movements dealing with governanceissues. It is produced in time for the WSF in Belém in January<strong>2009</strong> and is presented there at a panel organised by the guest editors. Itbrings together a range of views from different regions in the world,from thinkers engaged in critical assessments of neoliberal policies,their failures and resulting perspectives.These analyses seek ways extricating ourselves from the current developmentalimpasse, and explore the scope of postneoliberal governance.Their authors share the view of so many others engagedin the WSF movement that a<strong>no</strong>ther world is possible. Supportingsuch a vision, the Dag Hammarskjöld Foundation will continue toseek opportunities to create a space where a variety of stakeholderswith different views can meet and discuss. This will include initiativesto facilitate interaction, exchange and dialogue <strong>no</strong>t only amongthe like-minded but also across the political-ideological spectrum ofan alter-global movement.The Foundation would like to thank the two guest editors and all thecontributors for the time and work invested in this result. We trustthat it will be welcomed as an attempt to encourage reflection bothin seeking to come to terms with existing social realities and in thesearch for a better future – if <strong>no</strong>t for all, then at least for the majorityof people living on this planet.Uppsala, December 2008Henning Melber


Postneoliberalism: catch-all wordor valuable analytical and politicalconcept? – Aims of a beginningdebateUlrich Brand and Nicola SeklerAt first glance the globalisation of the real estate, banking and financialcrisis which started in the United States has led to a questioningof the ideology of ‘neoliberalism’ and at least given the word ‘neoliberalism’negative con<strong>no</strong>tations. Whether new political and eco<strong>no</strong>micpolicies will emerge from this crisis, and what forms they maytake, are among the most important political and social questions ofour times. In the last months of 2008, in relation to the visible crisis,many were swift to proclaim ‘the end of neoliberalism’. In this regardwe could <strong>no</strong>t have chosen a better moment, with this already plannedspecial issue of Development Dialogue, to probe what lies beyond neoliberalism– or what ‘postneoliberalism’ might consist of. We explorea number of questions. How do we understand the actual constellationand dynamics? How is the financial crisis articulated analyticallyand politically with other crises, and what are political consequencesfor emancipatory politics? What are the continuities and discontinuitieswith respect to the specific neoliberal context in quite differentcircumstances, in countries such as China, Thailand, Brazil, Argentina,South Africa, Germany or Canada? And with respect to issueareas like the financial crisis itself, the environmental crisis, the organisingof wage earners, feminist demands or occupied factories?The starting point of postneoliberal reflections represents the actualsocial, political and eco<strong>no</strong>mic constellation. Over the last 30 years,neoliberal policies have been implemented in almost every societyon the globe. This took place in different forms – under conditionsof military dictatorship as in Chile, imposed as so-called structuraladjustment in line with the Washington Consensus, articulated withconservative policies as in the US and UK, implemented in post-socialistcountries in Eastern Europe or in more social-democratic waysas in Germany or the Scandinavian societies – resulting in fairly specific‘neoliberal’ configurations.


6 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateDealing with ‘neoliberalism’ requires differentiating between at leasttwo dimensions – an analytical and a political one. Despite all thedifferences, analytically we can distinguish between, firstly, consideringneoliberalism as a theory and an intellectual movement (FriedrichHayek, Milton Friedman, the Mont Pelèrin Society, the dominanceof neoclassical thinking in universities and beyond) and, secondly,focusing on neoliberalism as a broad strategy on the part of eco<strong>no</strong>mic,political and cultural (and sometimes military) elites to destroythe (peripheral) Fordist compromises and to restructure power relations,institutions, overall orientations and truths, in particular societiesand at the international level, even more towards capitalist interests.A third analytical perspective is to view neoliberalism as a socialpractice, implying the assumption that theoretical considerations andstrategies to implement theory are <strong>no</strong>t always and everywhere comprehensivelysuccessful and functional as such. Accordingly, the contradictoryand confl ictive aspects of (neoliberal) social practices in aglobal perspective – global North and South, East and West – andwithin societies are examined.It is precisely this third analytical perspective that leads us to the politicaldimension of ‘neoliberalism’ – that is, concrete neoliberal policies,practices and political discourses representing the compromisesarising from the struggles of different social forces. In times of crises,neoliberal politics and these compromises come under pressure. Delegitimatio<strong>no</strong>f neoliberalism takes place <strong>no</strong>t only via visible crisis – likethe ecological and the financial one – or by means of the e<strong>no</strong>rmoussocial polarisation in many countries but in addition through the continuingconceptual and practical criticism undertaken by intellectuals,scientists and critical media, social movements and NGOs.This is the starting point for our considerations of the term postneoliberalism,the intention being to discuss different responses to the (negative)impacts of neoliberalism and its growing inability to deal withthe upcoming contradictions and crises. Thus the focus is <strong>no</strong>t on thequestion of whether a new, postneoliberal era in general has begun andwhat might be the criteria supporting or contesting such an assessment.Rather, we propose to consider postneoliberalism as a perspective onsocial, political and/or eco<strong>no</strong>mic transformations, on shifting terrainsof social struggles and compromises, taking place on different scales, invarious contexts and by different actors. All postneoliberal approacheshave in common that they break with some specific aspect of ‘neoliberalism’and embrace different aspects of a possible postneoliberalism, butthese approaches vary in depth, complexity and scope, as well as everydaypractices and comprehensive concepts.


postneoliberalism – aims of a beginning debate 7With the help of the term postneoliberalism we aim to create a spacefor shared reflection on questions like: Where are the stabilities ofneoliberal configurations? Where does active consent or at least passiveconsent to neoliberal politics and practices remain, when thereare <strong>no</strong> viable alternatives or alternatives have been silenced? How,and in what historical, political, cultural, social, eco<strong>no</strong>mic contexts,have postneoliberal practices, strategies and concepts emerged? Whatare their main objectives and how do they try to achieve them? Whatare the main obstacles, limitations and contradictions they have todeal with? Which aspects are questioned and tend to be addressed ina ‘postneoliberal’ manner? What tends still to be ‘neoliberal’ or unquestionedand why?Accounting for these manifold facets allows us to overcome someimportant shortcomings of current discussions, as the example of therole of the state might show. Many of the contributions to actual debateshighlight that confidence in ‘self-regulating market forces’ hasdisappeared and therefore that reregulation by the state is necessary.Here there is a risk of confusing neoliberalism with the market andof constructing a dichotomy of ‘the market’ versus ‘the state’. In fact,starting from an understanding of the state as a condensation of socialrelations, neoliberalism can be seen as a specific form of state interventioninto societal, eco<strong>no</strong>mic and other relations. The specific neoliberalcharacteristic of the state is that it became more repressive insocial, labour market and military policies, and less interventionist inthe movement of different forms of capital.In this volume we bring together very different approaches to the actualconstellation – often in a historical perspective – which gives a broadand complex picture. There are general reflections on the crisis of neoliberalismand possible ways out (Michael Brie and Alex Demirovic),while some contributions focus on different policy and confl ict fieldssuch as the regulation of financial markets (Elmar Altvater), developmentpolicies (Kurt Bayer) or environmental politics (Ulrich Brand).From an emancipatory perspective it is important to <strong>no</strong>te that althoughthe struggles ‘against neoliberalism’ represent a common starting pointor framework, the specific conditions of struggle – in other words thespecific neoliberal context or perception of neoliberalism – vary. Inthis volume, the examples of feminist struggles against the erosio<strong>no</strong>f biodiversity or the ambiguities of a state-led sufficiency eco<strong>no</strong>my(Christa Wichterich; Alec Bumford and Chanida Chanyapate) showthis clearly. Some postneoliberal struggles and approaches start as radicallyanti-capitalist (Verónica Gago and Diego Sztulwark) or with theaim of reforming capitalism (Kurt Bayer), they may focus on single is-


8 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatesues, or involve various fields, or operate through parties, grassrootsmovements or alternative thinktanks (Ngai-Ling Sum, Patrick Bond).As Ana Esther Ceceña and Nicola Sekler argue, the plurality of approaches,movements for change and alternative practices is crucial ifwe want to envision emancipatory forms of societalisation on a globalscale. Or, as the Mexican Zapatistas propose, we need a ‘world in whichmany worlds fi t’. This might lead to other problems, such as a weaknessin their capacity to change dominant power relations and orientations(Emir Sader and Greg Albo), but in principle this is a major advance.Below we give a brief sketch ofthe argument of the particular authors.The crisis of 19th century liberalism led in some countries to fascism.Referring to Hannah Arendt’s analysis of national socialism as a <strong>no</strong>rmalisedeveryday system Michael Brie argues that, by recombining formerlyexisting elements, there are different ways out of the manifoldcrises of neoliberalism. He outlines five crises of neoliberalism – relatingto (overaccumulation, ecological reproduction, social integration,the political system, and increasing violence – out of which four scenariosof very different postneoliberal alternatives can be condensed:an even more deregulated capitalism, a conservative-authoritarian aswell as a social democratic version of finance-led capitalism, and theemergence of a mode of development based on solidarity. From anemancipatory perspective the last scenario is the most desirable one;it includes new forms of property and organisation of the eco<strong>no</strong>my, anew way of living and participatory democracy.At the centre of Ana Esther Ceceña´s analysis is the concept of bifurcations.She argues that the concept of postneoliberalism can be graspedmost of all as a general naming of a dramatically changing constellationand that it needs to be clarified whether it is a capitalist and domination-drivenway of restructuring or a mode of living which pointstowards a post-capitalist society. Among others, three processes werecrucial during the neoliberal phase: the integration of formerly ‘excluded’people, the commodification of parts of nature, and the redefinitionand valorisation of territory and territorial power. Accordingto Ceceña this phase reached crisis point and led to the growthof institutional and discursive practices around ‘national security’ andthe militarisation of societal relations: this is the ‘postneoliberalismof capital’. A<strong>no</strong>ther version is a ‘national postneoliberalism’ whichemerged in various Latin American countries and which places a crucialemphasis on the nationalisation of companies and on new constitutions.A third postneoliberalism emphasises much more the creatio<strong>no</strong>f common spaces from below, the transformation of everydayrelations into more emancipatory ones, and self-determination.


postneoliberalism – aims of a beginning debate 9Alex Demirovic outlines central elements of neoliberalism in OECDcountries and claims that neoliberalism was never an enhancement ofthe market at the cost of the state but involved a shifting of marketand state logics and of the relationships of forces – that is, paradigms ofaccumulation, domination and everyday life. Referring to Germany,he shows that social domination became domination by and throughcontingency. Neoliberalism understood as a politics of destruction(through liberalisation, deregulation and privatisation) turned into acrisis before 2008 and remains such. In the current situation mainlyneoliberal policies are being implemented to deal with the crisis, rearrangingthe relationship between financial and industrial capital.Theoretical concepts might help to clarify the complexity of the currentcrisis, its recent history and its dynamics. Nicola Sekler introducesAntonio Gramsci´s concept of hegemony, that is a consensus-basedform of social domination, and complements it with the concept ofcounter-hegemony. Postneoliberalism as a counter-hegemonic perspectivemeans considering that different impacts of neoliberalismand ‘neoliberalised’ social contexts create – from the point of viewof actors – a starting point for various postneoliberal approaches. Bydiscussing the examples of Piquetero organisations and recovered enterprisesshe shows how this perspective raises our awareness of continuitiesand discontinuities with respect to the existing neoliberalcontext. Because of the unifying momentum of ‘postneoliberalism’,and in order to ack<strong>no</strong>wledge the plurality of postneoliberal approaches,she argues that the term is <strong>no</strong>t useful for orientating emancipatorystruggles politically.The current banking and financial crisis, Elmar Altvater argues, has itshistorical origins in the 1970s when the former Bretton Woods systemcollapsed and the liberalisation of financial markets became thecrucial lever for restructuring capitalism. Monetarism was the hegemonicideology of the ‘neoliberal counter-revolution’ and had severenegative repercussions all over the world. This is shown with respectto many aspects, especially in the way that the dominance of financialmarkets relates to the ecological crisis. Altvater argues that neoliberalismcame to an end in August 2008 because the crisis <strong>no</strong>w is muchdeeper than the previous ones. Nevertheless, postneoliberal strategiescan still lead to a restructuring of capitalism and the horizon of a postcapitalistworld has therefore to be opened up by social movements.Recent changes in development policy are the topic of Kurt Bayer’scontribution. He argues that the Washington Consensus is underpressure because its policies evidently cause more problems thanthey solve. Successful eco<strong>no</strong>mic development in countries like Chinatook place because neoliberal policies were <strong>no</strong>t implemented and


10 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debate‘shock therapies’ were avoided. Bayer argues that in recent years it hasbecome quite clear that political institutions (as well as a functioninginfrastructure) matter for stable eco<strong>no</strong>mic growth. Open financialmarkets have proved ineffective and the actual financial crisis hasled to massive refinancing problems for many countries in the globalSouth. As a consequence the International Financial Institutions andthe governments of powerful states are changing their strategies, resultingin a new pragmatic approach of development.The field of environmental politics is paradigmatic for a shift towardspostneoliberalism. Ulrich Brand argues that in recent years it has becomeobvious that the neoliberal or post-Fordist forms of the appropriatio<strong>no</strong>f nature have <strong>no</strong>t been successful but have led to a deepeningof the ecological crisis. There are different ways of dealing withthe crisis of societal relationships with nature and the failed attemptsof the management of global resources and problems (the ‘Rio typeof politics’): a business-as-usual version, an openly coercive variantof postneoliberal strategies with regard to the societal appropriatio<strong>no</strong>f nature, and a version linked to the emergence of developmentalistand state-led strategies in some countries. A fourth type points toemancipatory forms of societal relationships with nature. Differentelements of this version, strategies to realise it and problems to betackled are all sketched out.Gregory Albo focuses on the historical and actual situation of the unionmovement. Its weakening was a centre-piece of neoliberalism, widelypromoted by capital and the state, and brought the movement an organisational,eco<strong>no</strong>mic and political impasse.. Although in 2008 theeco<strong>no</strong>mic situation in most countries started to worsen and the ideologicalcrisis of neoliberalism has become obvious, there are strongneoliberal continuities: the state is still heavily oriented towards neoliberalpolicies and the societal relationships of forces is <strong>no</strong>t shifting infavour of progressive actors. Albo outlines four major challenges theunion movement and describes new approaches in relation to labourdemands like the ‘living wage’ or the strengthening of the public sector,alliances between the global justice and the labour movements, andorganisational changes of the unions themselves towards a social justiceunionism. He argues that the labour movement can only be strengthenedwhen it becomes part of a wider reconstitution of the left.Feminist perspectives on neoliberalism highlight aspects which are oftenforgotten, that is especially care work and subsistence eco<strong>no</strong>mies(private households, unpaid labour and nature) which are the necessaryprecondition for the functioning of the capitalist eco<strong>no</strong>my. ChristaWichterich shows that the crisis of neoliberalism is most of all a crisis of


postneoliberalism – aims of a beginning debate 11social reproduction. Describing the practices of women peasants withrespect to the maintenance of biodiversity and local k<strong>no</strong>wledge, sheshows how, as a result of neoliberal policies, these practices are evenmore undermined by industrial agriculture and the commodificatio<strong>no</strong>f nature. Global environmental governance through, for example, theUN Convention on Biological Diversity, is fostering these processes.Alternatives come from below, like the seed movements in India andSouth Africa, and through transnational networks.After the severe crisis in 1997, the king of Thailand proposed an alternative,<strong>no</strong>n-neoliberal development path under the heading of a ‘SufficiencyEco<strong>no</strong>my’, receiving strong international endorsement. This<strong>no</strong>w well-k<strong>no</strong>wn concept is critically evaluated by Chanida Chanyapateand Alec Bamford. They show in detail the core issues involved init and argue that in practice the Sufficiency Eco<strong>no</strong>my is <strong>no</strong> alternativeto free-market capitalism and neoliberal globalisation, but its optimisation.The rules of the game, as well as the export oriention of theeco<strong>no</strong>my and especially of agriculture, remain uncontested. However,community-based alternatives raise very different issues underthis heading and propose radical changes so as to promote the developmentof people through a sufficiency eco<strong>no</strong>my. ‘from below’.The rapid changes taking place in China are creating new dynamicsworldwide. Ngai-Ling Sum shows how world market integrationtakes place through the creation of local neoliberal competitivenessand related discourses. Those internationally developed discourses aretransferred to the ‘eco<strong>no</strong>mic powerhouse’ of southern China (HongKong/Pearl River Delta). However, as Sum shows, ‘Wal-Martisation’is contested by a ‘new left’, and well-organised resistance is takingplace. These processes from below articulate in contradictory wayswith the official state strategy of ‘socialism with Chinese characteristics’.Indeed, since 2008 the Chinese government has more actively promoteda social agenda under the heading of a ‘harmonious society’, whichmight according to Sum resonate with strategies in Venezuela.Emir Sader shows that it is <strong>no</strong>t by chance that Latin America is neoliberalism’sweakestlink, because the system was imposed there quiteearly, radically and brutally. With the rebellion in Chiapas (Mexico)and the election of Hugo Chavez in Venezuela in 1999, a new periodof contestation and resistance to neoliberalism began. Postneoliberalismindicates the inability of neoliberal capitalism – with the dominanceof financial capital – and its related social forces to create theconditions for sustained growth. Sader argues that an emancipatorypostneoliberal project has four core issues to be dealt with: oppositionto deregulation, opposition to financialisation, opposition to the


12 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateweakening of labour relations and opposition to ‘free trade’. The majorchallenge today is to reconstruct an anti-capitalist left under conditionswhere many oppositional forces, including the labour movement,have been integrated into capitalist social relations.Taking up recent experiences in Argentina, Verónica Gago and DiegoSztulwark ask whether we can understand the situation in this countryunder the heading of postneoliberalism. They show that the radicallyemancipatory experiences following the 2001 crisis have been marginalised.A crucial element of the restoration of the country was the fearthat neoliberalism could return. Neodevelopmentalism and a new governmentalityarose and caused an impasse: the blocking of the most in<strong>no</strong>vativedynamics of the last decade. The demands of the movementsthat emerged after 2001 have been weakened, but at the same time statepolicies to deal with the crisis are ineffective. Gago and Sztulwark showthat the actual anti-imperialist rhetoric of some Latin American governments,with its focus on national development, is closing spaces foralternatives rather than opening them up. The possibilities of a new andcollective protagonism of emancipatory forces are outlined.That neoliberalism has <strong>no</strong>t come to its end. because the dominant institutionalframework is still largely neoliberal. becomes particularlyclear – so the central argument of Patrick Bond goes – when experiencesin African societies are taken into account. Policies to deal withthe financial crisis are as neoliberal as the system of international politicalinstitutions that hinders particular national approaches to dealwith problems. Moreover, the next US administration under president-electBarack Obama is seen critically because it is probably goingto relegitimise neoliberal and imperial politics. Alternatives haveto be developed from below through, among other things, a reorganisatio<strong>no</strong>f the financial system, a decommodification of social relationsand the creation of a space for specific development strategies. Oneprecondition for Bond is the further delegitimation of US politicaland military strategies, designed by ‘Obama’s neoliberals’.The term postneoliberalism is intentionally used in a vague way. Weare aware of this relative nebulosity, the range of meanings that theterm could have and the tension between an emancipatory content/interpretation on the one hand and a dominant or even a reactionaryone on the other hand. The latter possibility has become clear recently,in that elites have started referring to ‘neoliberalism’ as a code forall the errors that have occurred and need to be solved, but withoutquestioning the existing power relations and general orientations towardsthe unquestioned role of capital, competitiveness and eco<strong>no</strong>m-


postneoliberalism – aims of a beginning debate 13ic efficiency. Concerning the latter, we have to ack<strong>no</strong>wledge that inmost places the societal relations of forces are <strong>no</strong>t <strong>no</strong>ticeably shiftingto the left. On the contrary, in Western Europe the criticism of neoliberalismis mainly coming from the extreme right, which promotesa racist eco<strong>no</strong>mic nationalism without questioning hierarchical classand gender relations and the imperial structure of the world market.Moreover, the welcomed victory of Barack Obama in the UnitedStates is <strong>no</strong>t an outcome of shifting power relations but – until <strong>no</strong>w– an excellent campaign with a promised alternative to an exhaustedconservative, belligerent and anti-popular project (cf. Bond, this volume),which shows us that it is worth taking a closer view of socialand power relations and how they really change.As we have already stated, the analytical-strategic point of the debateis to highlight from different perspectives the problem of neoliberalpolitics so as to deal with the contradictions and crises arising fromit. We do <strong>no</strong>t assume that this is – in any way – a first step. As wesee in this volume and so many other publications and experiences,there are many existing alternatives which are indeed anti-neoliberal.However, we are convinced that we can contribute to a shared processof reflection on these alternative practices and strategies by highlightingthe diversity of societal contexts, meanings of crises and possiblesolutions, as well as the strategies of different actors.


Ways out of the crisis of neoliberalismMichael Brie‘Crisis is a productive condition. One must only takeaway from it the aftertaste of catastrophe.’Max FrischA historical experience: the crisis of liberalism and fascismThe Soviet troops were just liberating the last survivors of the concentrationcamp in Auschwitz in January 1945 and the American-ledtroops in the West were fighting the Ardennes Offensive of Hitler’sWehrmacht. The war was coming back to Germany, its point of departure.Precisely at this point, the 38-year-old Hannah Arendt, Jewishrefugee in the USA, sketched out a book entitled ‘Elements ofShame: Anti-Semitism, Imperialism, Racism’, or even ‘The ThreePillars of Hell’. Later, during the Cold War, it was appropriated in ananticommunist fashion under the title The Origins of Totalitarianism. 1What, however, was the real concern of this famous and almost alwaysmisread book?Hannah Arendt was a stateless displaced German Jewess, robbed ofany protection, threatened with death by gassing if Hitler’s murderershad been able to get hold of her. She was a witness of a war that costover 50 million humans their lives. And like her contemporaries, ifshe didn’t hold ‘evil’, ‘capitalism’, ‘the Germans’, ‘anti-Communism’responsible, she was confronted with a puzzle: how could the ‘thinand ephemeral veil’ (Ador<strong>no</strong> 2006: 113) of civilisation so often, sobrutally, so limitlessly be blown apart in the first half of the 20th century?How could the commandment ‘thou shalt <strong>no</strong>t kill!’ be turnedwith so little effort and on a massive scale into ‘you should kill!’?When Hannah Arendt later spoke of the ‘banality of evil’ duringher observation of the trial of Adolf Eichmann, the organiser of theNazi extermination of the Jews, many were hurt – above all, thevictims. Didn’t the awful ‘atrocity…that <strong>no</strong> penance, <strong>no</strong> pardon, <strong>no</strong>atonement of the guilty, that is, <strong>no</strong>thing human, could ever againmake good’ (Levi 1992: 156) also need to have a ‘great cause’? HannahArendt disagreed: ‘a World War was needed to get rid of Hitler,1 The German title was Elemente und Ursprünge totaler Herrschaft.


16 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatewhich was shameful precisely because it was also comic. Contemporaryhistorians, understandably e<strong>no</strong>ugh, have repeatedly attemptedto cover up this element of the bloody fool’s game, to erase it, and togive the events a grandeur that they do <strong>no</strong>t have, but which wouldmake them humanly more bearable’ (Arendt 1976: 132 [trans. modified]).She ascertained a ‘disastrous disparity between cause and effect’(ibid.). One can indeed reconstruct ‘which actions [followed on]which actions’, and at the same time the quality of the action and itsresults fundamentally changed if ‘<strong>no</strong>rmal imperialism’ became a systemof total domination. It is the discrepancy between the nullity ofthe causes and the ‘radical evil’ of a system in which ‘all men have…been made equally superfluous’ (Arendt 1996: 457). And these causes,so insignificant in themselves, according to Hannah Arendt, are ‘tobe found everywhere in the contemporary world’ (ibid.). Bertolt Brechtwill say: ‘The womb is fertile still, from which that crawled’.The epoch-making experience of those who went through the hellsof National Socialism and that of their affected contemporaries mustbe remembered. The bearable <strong>no</strong>rmality of the present in which welive, we who write about it differently from many about whom muchis written, covers over the abysses that have opened up. The crisis ofneoliberalism is <strong>no</strong> promisingly good news, but rather means immediatelythe threatening of the <strong>no</strong>rmal life of millions of humans. Itcan be transformed into an opportunity to stop the menacing accumulatio<strong>no</strong>f elements of a new catastrophe of global civilisation andthus to make sure that it does <strong>no</strong>t become the origins of an unleashedbarbarism. The probability of 21st century barbarism is <strong>no</strong>w muchgreater than that of a 21st century society based on solidarity.For Hannah Arendt, it was the crisis of the long century between1789 and 1914 in which liberalism rose to hegemony and asserted itselfthat brought forward the elements of total domination. For her,this capitalism thus fell into crisis because liberalism found <strong>no</strong> civilisinganswers to the central questions of its time and thus set free tendenciesthat offered solutions through decivilisation, promised certaingroups advancement and power or at least a good income, appearedto have clear simple answers in the face of growing uncertainty and,instead of a demoralising degeneration of the social and political situation,proclaimed a great glorious uprising. 2Hannah ArendtOctober 14, 1906– December 4, 1975.2 She shares this conviction with Karl Polanyi, even if his diag<strong>no</strong>sis is of a differenttype. For him, ‘the origins of the cataclysm lay in the utopian endeavor of eco<strong>no</strong>micliberalism to set up a self-regulating market system’ (Polanyi 1944: 29).


ways out of the crisis of neoliberalism 17Two points in Hannah Arendt’s chosen approach are to be <strong>no</strong>ted. Onthe one hand, it is often forgotten that social systems are indeed oftendominated by a paradigm of reproduction (in the sense of a superstructure),but can<strong>no</strong>t be reduced to this. Thus the reproductio<strong>no</strong>f contemporary finance capital, as we are currently experiencing,is dependent on statal-imperial support, closely linked to real estateownership and the pension guarantees of many hundreds of millionsof humans, strengthened and at the same time weakened by imperialwars, linked into strategies of state funds of global competitors, whichcan<strong>no</strong>t be separated from the ecological contradictions, and so forth.Reproduction is always mediated via ‘others’; it lives only by subjugatingthe other without, however, destroying it at the same time,making it its own without completely robbing it of its own power,using it without exhausting it. In order to endure this contradiction,capital must resort to crutches (Marx), to forms of socialisation thatcontradict it. It regularly brings forward in its reproduction elementsthat put it in question. Stability and fluidity belong together. Modernsocieties are societies on the edge of chaos. In this, there are the possibilitiesof regular changes but also the dangers of self-destruction.‘From the beginning of modernity it has been a case of forcing theworld to be different from what it is’ (Baumann 1996: 36). Its vanishingpoint is the future.Thus, however, the space is open in which new things – different,strangely, confl icting forms – are constituted. This occurs <strong>no</strong>t only inthe intermediate spaces and intermediate worlds, but also in the eyeof the storm itself. The peaceful liberalism oriented to free trade gavebirth to the robber imperialism out of which fascism grew, just as didthe social state that is pregnant with the dominance of the social andsocialism. Unleashed barbarism and humane civilisation were formedas elements, as seeds, as origins in the processing contradictions ofcapitalism. In times of crisis these elements could immediately be puttogether into entirely new totalities – into totalitarian fascisms, butmaybe also into societies based on solidarity.Through transformations of conditions, through social, political andintellectual struggles, through wars and global competition, the contradictionsof capitalist societies can be pushed in one or the otherdirection. They thus fall into disequilibrium. The search for solutionsto the accumulating problems then becomes increasingly hectic.Ever more robbery, ever more privatisation, ever more armamentsand wars, ever more subjugation of the state to the interests of financialmarket capitalism, or even the attempt to create a new stabilitythrough more social justice, renewal of the public sphere, commonpeaceful development, a politics of sustainability – both are possible.


18 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateNatural as well as social systems fall time and again out of equilibrium;alternative situations become possible that promise new but verydifferent equilibria. This creates points of bifurcation (Lorenz 1993),which can lead to new relatively stable situations or could flow intochaos (socially: into barbarism). The new either emerges out of the<strong>no</strong>vel recombination of existing elements that emerged in the old,or it does <strong>no</strong>t emerge at all. The transformation of parts leads to thetransformation of the system. As the chaos theorist John Holland hasformulated it, ‘in evolution it is <strong>no</strong>t a case simply of creating a goodanimal, but rather of finding good building blocks that can be composedinto good animals’ (cited in Waldrop 1993: 212). Allow us totranslate these thoughts into the terms of the history of the 20th century:German National Socialism was the worst possible combinatio<strong>no</strong>f the worst elements of the crisis of liberal capitalist societies that waspossible before the invention of the atom bomb. The path of the socialstate under the leadership of Swedish social democracy was, on theother hand, one of the most humane and social attempts at the reorganisatio<strong>no</strong>f capitalist societies.The fi ve crises of neoliberal capitalismNational Socialism led bourgeois societies to the edge of self-destruction.The principle of appropriation, of conquest, of destruction, brokethrough all limits. The spirits that were called up in order to banishcommunism raised themselves up to masters that wanted to subjugatethe world as a racist gang of thieves. This existential experience andthe challenge by Soviet socialism as well as a strong left and workers’movement were the elements above all that brought the ruling circlein the West to put strong fetters on capitalism after 1945. The rulingcircle declared peace, full employment and social security to betheir goal. Institutions were created that were supposed to secure theunity of eco<strong>no</strong>mic and social as well as democratic parliamentary developmentunder the domination of liberal elites. Among these werecapital controls, rules for investments, fixed exchange rates, a strongpublic sector and strict labour legislation.This strategy for managing the crisis created in its turn, however,fundamental contradictions between, on the one hand, elements ofsocial counter-power, planning and regulation, and expansion ofpublic sectors; and, on the other, strong capital accumulation, whichhad made possible this Fordist welfare-state capitalism. Elements ofvery opposed directions of development amassed.The spirits that were calledup in order to banishcommunism raised themselvesup to masters that wanted tosubjugate the world as a racistgang of thieves.


ways out of the crisis of neoliberalism 19The welfare state repressed the commodity character of labour power.Labour <strong>no</strong> longer needed to be sold for any price. New alternativeversions of life appeared possible. The patriarchal nuclear family <strong>no</strong>ticeablydisintegrated, though without a replacement being found forthe reproduction work that had been done by women up until then.The wage-centred society was at risk. The expansion of the publicsector went in opposition to the dominance of private business; Keynesianglobal regulation opposed the freedom of capital circulation.In the wake of redistribution, in response to the private demands ofwageworkers and the demands of the public purse, the profit ratewent down. Democratisation posed the question of how the eco<strong>no</strong>mycould be brought under the control of the interests of the great majorityThe expansion of the material wealth of wageworkers as wellwould lead to an environmentally destructive consumer society. Thegrowth boom pushed human civilisation to the ecological limits ofgrowth. Decolonisation created independent states, many of which,however, did <strong>no</strong>t prove to be capable of endoge<strong>no</strong>us development orbecame development dictatorships.A glaring problem arose in the centres of capitalism: the e<strong>no</strong>rmousadvances in productivity would have made it necessary to redistributea share of the profits in favour of wages and public services. Ifan exorbitantly high growth reached its limits, then it required a redistributionat the expense of capital or there would be ‘overaccumulation,long term growth weaknesses and stagnation’ (Huffschmid2002: 122), or an expansion to the world markets. Capital would haveneeded to give up its predominance or to create new investment possibilitiesand to reduce the power of wageworkers and the welfarestate. It went on the attack.Since the 1970s, the restictions on capital have been progressivelylifted and a transformed institutional arrangement has been created.Its cornerstones are free currency exchange, free world trade and freecapital circulation, a new division of labour (including within companies),extensive privatisation and weakening of the negotiation powerof wage labour through flexibilisation, part-time labour, lower wagesectors as well as the dominance of short-term shareholder values. Financefunds with a short-term valorisation orientation, greater flexibilityand e<strong>no</strong>rmous pressure potential have become the dominantcontrolling force (Windolf 2005: 20-57). The predominance of theUSA gained a new foundation: global finance market capitalism hasits institutional foundation in the US empire (Panitch; Gindin 2008:17-47). This neoliberal developmental path is <strong>no</strong>w in its turn in avery deep crisis. The question is whether it stays with the reparative


20 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatemeasures of this new finance market capitalism or whether there haveemerged forces to introduce fundamental transformations – in one orthe other direction.First, the overaccumulation crisis has grown more acute. Only a partof capital could be invested productively, particularly in the new productioncapacities of the East Asian ‘tigers’ and China. On the otherside of the destroyed levees, significant finance and debt bubbleswere built up through the indebtedness of developing countries, inthe hype of the so-called new eco<strong>no</strong>my, in the real estate market, inthe life insurance sector, in the debt of the USA itself. There was anexplosion of finance claims in property ownership that is <strong>no</strong>t accompaniedby by any real eco<strong>no</strong>mic development. In 1980 the relation ofglobal gross social product and financial assets was 1 : 1.2. By 2006, ithad risen to 1 : 3.5. The realisation expectations and entitlements toreturns linked to it became a threat to the real eco<strong>no</strong>my. Public fundswill have to put in 2000 billion dollars in the USA alone in order tostop (perhaps) the latest crisis. Capital valorisation has grown to anextent never seen before in history through the institutional revolutio<strong>no</strong>f neoliberalism. It has created disproportions with real developmentthat have <strong>no</strong>t been seen on such a scale since 1928. Valorisationinterests and developmental necessities are fundamentally opposed.There is a new overaccumulation crisis.Second, the ecological reproduction crisis that Fordism had alreadyconjured up is deepening. The primary fixation on accumulation ofmaterial wealth and the expansion of the use of resources as well asthe emission of dangerous materials into the environment has furtherspeeded up. While the highly developed countries have <strong>no</strong>t changedtheir development model, other countries with large populations arewaiting to take on this outdated development model. Worldwide, thenumber of cars will double by the year 2030, from currently almost 1billion to 2 billion, if there is <strong>no</strong> reversal of policies. The attempt tofind a tech<strong>no</strong>logical solution to the rapid destruction of the naturalfoundations of human life without a revolution in the mode of productionand way of life is completely impossible.Furthermore, finance market capitalism shortens the already shorttime horizon of capital valorisation to two years. Projects that goon longer than that are increasingly financed less. ‘Slimmed down’states have had the possibilities of long-term comprehensive investmentprojects taken from them, while at the same time they stillhave to step into the breach opened up by the crisis and come upwith answers. This leads to a general underinvestment in the renewal


ways out of the crisis of neoliberalism 21Crises of neoliberal finance market capitalismFinancemarketcapitalismand development of the most important fields of social reproduction,particularly in education, culture, environment and heath. There is areproduction crisis.Third, the dissolution of the patriarchal nuclear family was compensatedfor, for those with a high income, above all by the inflowof cheap migrant labour, with low wages and part-time jobsMany Western societies were deeply split. The necessary support is<strong>no</strong> longer provided for many children and old people among thepoor groups of society. Flexibilisation destroys, even for people witha higher income, the possibilities of a genuinely self-determined life.Lack of meaning, criminality, drug addiction and dissolution of socialcohesion are the consequences.Worldwide, the decay of the state has already reached a quarter ofall countries. The number of refugees is <strong>no</strong>w over 20 million. Thenumber of humans without basic essentials including sufficient nutrition,fresh water, minimal sanitary conditions, medical help andeducation is around 3 billion. In many states, only a mi<strong>no</strong>rity is involvedin formal work. In many countries, either the social state orthe traditional institutions of social integration are being destroyed.There is an integration crisis.Fourth, democratisation after 1945 was based on the fact that the citizens,the overwhelming mass of the population, shared in the welfarestate. The contradiction between the eco<strong>no</strong>mic system and democracywas supposed to be at least defused. Thissocial pact – at any rate only valid in a smallmi<strong>no</strong>rity of countries – was thrown away. Thehopes of many people in the new national statesfreed from colonialism were often <strong>no</strong>t realised.Even governments of the left have implementedeco<strong>no</strong>mic programmes that are subjugatedto the primacy of the global investors. Neverbefore have there been so many free electionsas today while at the same time the expectationsattached to them of a social and eco<strong>no</strong>micdevelopment that corresponds to these interestshave increasingly been followed by disappointment.This is also precisely the case in the EuropeanUnion. There is a legitimation crisis of thepolitical system, of representative democracy.Overaccumulation crisisReproduction crisisIntegration crisisDemocracy crisisSecurity crisis


22 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateFifth, the four already <strong>no</strong>ted crises create such great eco<strong>no</strong>mic, social,cultural and political tensions in and between states and groups of statesthat violence necessarily increases. The answer to this at the momenthas been a new armaments spiral and the growth of a preventative securitystate (Braml 2004). Armament expenditures have grown by around50 per cent in the last decade, above all in the USA. They have <strong>no</strong>t onlycreated a latent civil war domestically (with the highest share of prisonersworldwide – 2.3 million in 2005, every tenth black man between 21and 29 incarcerated at some point in his life) 3 , but have also transformedthe Cold War against the Soviet Union into a global civil war ‘againstterror’, using military bases in 130 countries. They have built a networkof illegal prisons and concentration camps, similar to what occurred inthe heyday of the old imperialism. Worldwide, there are estimated tobe many thousands of people who are held and tortured in such prisons.At the same time, an asymmetrical terrorist war against the dominanceof the USA and the West has begun.Water, raw materials, access to the sea, migration, k<strong>no</strong>wledge, capital,cultural identity – in neoliberalism, everything and anythingbecomes <strong>no</strong>t only a commodity, but also cause of violent confrontations.With the globalisation of capital, violence has also been globalised.There is a security crisis.Postneoliberal scenariosThe five crises mentioned create high pressure to find alternatives. Thefive named crises of neoliberal finance market capitalism are the unstablefoundation on which politics is undertaken. It is the relations offorce between organised social movements, parties, elites and counterelites,states and interest groups, and their strategies, that determineon this basis the real development that takes place. The social costs ofmaintaining the stability of the system are growing. Resistance is increasingand the profits of neoliberal politics are going down. Alongwith this, the possibilities of deploying increased resources for crisismanagement are reduced as well. Feverishly, people are looking forways out. The USA is confronted by the question of whether it is ableto maintain the eco<strong>no</strong>mic and political foundations of its global leadingrole or whether it will sink to the level of primus inter pares.Postneoliberalism can have many faces. Analytically, four possiblepostneoliberal scenarios can be distinguished. 4 First, the temptation3 Cf.: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Prisons_in_the_United_States4 Cf.: Klein (2003). The real possibilities that they have of pursuing their own goals willdepend, on the one hand, on the general international conditions; on the other hand,on the domestic balance of forces.


ways out of the crisis of neoliberalism 23Alternative scenarios in the crisis of neoliberalismCrisis ofneoliberalismis great for the USA to want to react to the crises described with anaggressive extension of its dominance, if it is <strong>no</strong>t too late. Nevertheless,it comes up against tight constraints: it could try to extend onceagain the speculative capital investment possibilities, but the currentfinancial crisis and its own structural weaknesses and debts showthe danger of such policies even for the Wall Street-FED complex.It could continue its policy of securing the shrinking raw materialsources by military means, but the costs – as the Iraq war shows –are very high and weaken the claim of an empire to be acting in thename of global wellbeing. Furthermore, this only intensifies the globalecological crisis. 5 The ruling elites are tempted to promote thede-integration of the world, to mortgage allof Africa’s raw materials, to seal off furtherits own borders, just as the European Unionis doing. At the same time, the destructio<strong>no</strong>f American society itself continues, sincethe middle classes will become weaker andare threatened with collapse (hence also thefrantic state-led actions to rescue the banks).Imperial dictate externally and free electionsdomestically in the context of a type of developmentthat is viewed as a threat by themajority in their own land exhaust the institutionalconfiguration of the USA. Additionally,the ‘war against terror’ has onlyheightened the threats and promoted the riseof competitors like China or India.Totalitarian domination of anunleashed capitalismNeoconservative organisatio<strong>no</strong>f fi nance market capitalismSocial democratic organisatio<strong>no</strong>f fi nance market capitalismTransition to a mode of developmentbased on solidarityIf the former politics of the USA is continued, it will mean an acceleratedaccumulation of elements of barbarism in the USA itselfand worldwide. The unleashing of capitalism will give rise to a furtherdecivilisation. Already ‘terror suspects’, ‘poverty refugees’ onthe high seas, the victims of ecological and social catastrophes as wellas of state failures in the Third World have <strong>no</strong> human rights. Theyare similar to those who were made ‘stateless’ by National Socialism.These victims are still ‘collateral damage’ and there are <strong>no</strong> exterminationcamps. But there have been many steps taken in the directio<strong>no</strong>f lawlessness. If this development is <strong>no</strong>t stopped, there will be abarbarisation of unleashed imperialist capitalism, which will tip overinto ge<strong>no</strong>cide.5 The armed forces of the USA use in one day (!) more oil than Bangladesh, with 150million inhabitants, uses in an entire year.


24 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateFundamentally more probable is that at least at the moment this voyageinto barbarism will once again be stopped, just as it was stoppedin the decades before 1914 or before 1933. But precisely in order tostop this tendency, one must be conscious of its real possibility, forneither WWI in its true dimensions, to say <strong>no</strong>thing of Auschwitz,was thought possible by large sections of the elites. It was precisely forthis reason that they could happen. There was <strong>no</strong> linear causal connectionbetween the elements of barbarism that emerged in ‘<strong>no</strong>rmal’liberal capitalism and the system of barbarism of German NationalSocialism. This system was in <strong>no</strong> way inevitable. The capitalist classescould have managed the crisis differently in Germany, too, if largesections of the eco<strong>no</strong>mic and political elites had <strong>no</strong>t been convincedof the advantage of a temporary ‘alliance’ with Hitler’s National Socialistsas a way out of the crisis. Even more importantly: neither before1914 <strong>no</strong>r after 1933 was a real way out found; the imminent fallinto the abyss was prevented in a way that only made possible an evenworse future. Even if it did <strong>no</strong>t immediately fall into catastrophe, elementsof barbarism nevertheless accumulated under the surface of anincreasingly endangered civilisation.More probable actually is the second scenario – that is, that barbarismwill be stopped. The dominant strategy is currently the continuatio<strong>no</strong>f neoliberalism by other means. So long as neoliberalismin the highly developed countries was able to live on the constellationdeveloped after World War II, had access to cheap raw materials,and experienced <strong>no</strong> threat to its mo<strong>no</strong>poly of violence, the politics ofprivatisation, deregulation, appropriation, weakening or even disempoweringof all oppositional forces, as well as of social and culturalpolarisation, could be realised in a pure form. This era is <strong>no</strong>w over.Structural problems have emerged and forces of resistance are forming.In order to guarantee the ‘achievements’ of this period for thecapitalist class, the global domination complex and the upper middleclasses, the ruling elites are looking for a new balance. Here are twoexamples from the European Union.The balance between the protection of the achievements of neoliberalismfor the rulers and the threats from the five named crises canconsist of a neoconservative strategy of ‘sympathetic conservatism’within the nation state and ‘enlightened’ imperialism abroad. Thisis the second option of postneoliberal politics. The centres of powerwill seek an alliance with the ‘little people’; these centres will continueto be open only selectively for ‘useful’ and cheap labour-power;the market chances for the insiders will be heightened through activestate support (above all in the educational sector) and repressive exclusio<strong>no</strong>f ‘excess’ people of all types and a welfare state policy that forces


ways out of the crisis of neoliberalism 25The balance betweenprotecting achievements andavoiding threats can consistof a neoconservative strategyof ‘sympathetic conservatism’within the nation state and‘enlightened’ imperialismabroad.the individual to transform him- or herself into the ‘entrepreneur ofhis or her own labour power and affective labour’ (Meinhard Miegel).A ‘common foreign and security politics’ should fl ank this with amixture of partial integration and build-up of military interventionpower, division of spheres of influence and coordinated security ofWestern hegemony. Foreign politics will be subordinated to globalcompetition. The Lisbon strategy of the European Union aims in thisdirection. European leaders of this process are currently the Frenchpresident, Sarkozy, and Italy’s’ prime minister, Berlusconi.A third possibility is the revitalisation of new social democracy, whichaccepts finance market capitalism as the basis for negotiation and strivesafter the ‘social organisation’ of neoliberal globalisation. Tony Blair,Gerhard Schröder, Lionel Jospin and José Luis Rodríguez Zapaterohave outlined the limits of such a politics. Finance market capitalismobjectively sets much narrower limits for a politics of social equality,wageworkers’ participation in growth and social integration than thewelfare state capitalism of the period after WWII did. It therefore islargely associated with a libertarian politics for the upper middle classes.This was and is also the reason why the neoconservatives or even theparties of the Right were able to win majorities among wageworkers inan increasing number of states of the European Union.There is a fourth scenario for postneoliberalism – the transition to amode of development of societies based on solidarity. Its foundationwould be a solidarity eco<strong>no</strong>my and property order with four sectors,beyond the old dichotomy of private business versus state eco<strong>no</strong>my. Anew mode of life and development based on solidarity and participa-


26 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatetory democracy are inseparable component parts of such a scenario. Ioffer some comments on this in the following section.The transition to development based on solidarityA new eco<strong>no</strong>mic and property orderThe tech<strong>no</strong>logical revolution of the last 30 years has transformed scienceand culture into the most important productive forces. The privatisatio<strong>no</strong>f these public goods goes against their character as productsthat only increase their value through unlimited use. It therefore requiresa strong education, culture and science sector, supported by publicfinancing and to a large extent self-organising, and <strong>no</strong>urishing itselfin <strong>no</strong> small measure on the freely chosen engagement of the many wholive in genuine social security. The number of these goods regularly increases.If at all, then it is here that anarchy and a cultural communismhave their future. They require, however, a comprehensive foundation.It is this in sector that the free development of the individual and thefree development of all can in reality immediately coincide. Free publicaccess would predominate in this sector. There would be <strong>no</strong> owner, butrather, only supervisors of universal accessibility.There is a second sector that has increased e<strong>no</strong>rmously in significancethrough the clearly increasing life expectancy (which in Central Europein the last 160 years has risen from approximately 40 to almost80 years) and modernisation and urbanisation as well as the extensiveA possible scenario forpostneoliberalism? Thetransition to a mode ofdevelopment of societiesbased on solidarity.


ways out of the crisis of neoliberalism 27development of a global exchange society: the field of common goodslike health care, public infrastructure in transportation and communicationand so forth. The protection of the natural and human environmentis similarly a common good. Even the banking system andthe credit institutes as well as the legal system belong to this field.The recent financial crisis shows that these are privately useful but in<strong>no</strong> sense private goods – although they were treated as if they were.Neoliberalism has developed a game of communalising costs and privatisingprofits. The demarcation of public goods consists above all inthe fact that common goods can be destroyed by excessive and falseuse. The modern welfare and legal state that has fallen into crisis dueto neoliberalism is the backbone of these sectors. The democratic institutionsof the state, of communities and of universal security organisations,carry out the most important eco<strong>no</strong>mic functions on thebasis of the enforceable securing of the social and ecological fundamentalrights of all.The sustainable mixedeco<strong>no</strong>my of a societybased upon solidarityPublic goodsCommunal goodsIndividual goodsGainful employmentA four-in-oneperspective for anemancipated wayof lifeCitizens'involvmentAssociated goodsPersonal'self-realisationReproductive labourA third sector is the social sector of the production of material andimmaterial goods, which are neither public <strong>no</strong>r common, or are <strong>no</strong>tsupposed to be such. This sector is today above all in private and onlyvery partially in statal or cooperative hands. It is based on credit-financedentrepreneurial activity. This then takes on a capitalist formif the combination of the means of production and labour power is


28 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatesubordinated to the imperatives of capital valorisation. An eco<strong>no</strong>mybased on solidarity, on the basis of needs-oriented fundamental security,regional business cycles, control of capital circulation and strongco-determination, must succeed in breaking up and overcoming thissubordination of social and ecological governance and public investmentprogrammes. In this sector there must be established a formof associative property of different actors with different property interests(‘good work’, regional development, in<strong>no</strong>vative and efficientgoods for the user, ecological sustainability, and so forth). This postcapitalistentrepreneurial sector is based on the cooperation of a pluralityof owners of the same assets (Brie 1990).A fourth sector is the production of individual goods in the intimatesphere of partnership, living with the old and children, of friendshipand love as well as free personal development. The time spent in thissector today in the developed countries is very considerable and <strong>no</strong>wexceeds that spent on wage-earning activities in the course of a lifetime,if we include childhood, adolescence and old age in this calculation.It will be crucial to free this time from subjugation to the forcesof self- marketing and to strip it of the passively consumerist characterthat it often has today.Universal publicsphereCo-determinationSocial securityand peaceMain featuresof participatorydemocracySolidarity of commondevelopmentA new way of lifeThe transition from an eco<strong>no</strong>my dominated by capital to a mixedeco<strong>no</strong>my based on solidarity makes possible a fundamentally new lifebalance, which the Marxist-feminist Frigga Haug calls the ‘four-i<strong>no</strong>ne-perspective’.Wage labour, reproduction labour in the care of theself and others, the leisure of free self-development and public engagementshould be generalised as the part-time activities of all, sothat each and every person can dedicate around four hours of his orher day to each of these activities (Haug 2008: 20ff.). Wage activityclose to home must go down to below 30 hours a week. The ‘oppressivesubjugation to the division of labour’ (Karl Marx in the traditio<strong>no</strong>f Charles Fourier and Robert Owen) would finally be brought to


ways out of the crisis of neoliberalism 29an end. Only such a new organisation of life allows liberation from apsychology of ‘wanting to have’, out of which grew, together with theinfinite desire for self-valorisation of capital, the transformation of theworld into an accumulation of dead things (‘commodities’), destroyingnature as much as the human and the soul – precisely the situationthat dominates us today. 6Participatory democracyThe decisive condition for the emergence of a new eco<strong>no</strong>mic orderand way of life is the struggle for the democratisation of democracy.Today, democracy, this great achievement of the 20th century, hasbeen debased to a mere facade of imperial claims to power, of theimplementation of the imperative of an unleashed capital valorisationand of the protection of egotistical property claims. It has been transformedinto an oligarchy of globally acting elites. The alternative tothis is participatory democracy, in particular as it is developed in thecontext of the World Social Forum.The main features of a new participatory democracy are above allfour directions of development: first, it involves the production ofa universal public sphere, the assurance that all decisions are accessibleto those who are affected by them, that there is the obligationto listen to them, to confront their criteria and their critiques. Second,democracy is only possible if it contributes to the developmentof the other in a way based on solidarity. This is the case above all forthose who today have been touched by war, environmental destruction,failure of the state and lack of fundamental conditions for a selfdeterminedlife. Third, democracy requires immediately communal,regional and firm-based codetermination with a right to veto if one’sown essential needs are at stake. Fourth, democracy is only possiblewhen people are <strong>no</strong>t threatened by a lack of jobs, poverty in old age,lack of basic goods for a self-determined life, or war. Only when thesefour conditions are met is the delegation of power to others in anyway responsible, for it is only then that it is <strong>no</strong>t transformed into one’sown lack of power.Many elements of this new solidarity development have emerged inthe existing society dominated by capital. The old welfare state andall the other attempts to control capitalism since the latter half of the6 ‘The new society and the new human will only become reality when the oldmotivations – profi t and power – are replaced by new ones: being, sharing,understanding; when the market character is dissolved by the productive charactercapable of love and a new radical humanist spirit takes the place of cyberneticreligion.’ (Fromm 2000: 192).


30 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debate19th century have already contributed to this. These kinds of postneoliberalismapproaches based on solidarity have also emerged inconfrontation with neoliberalism. The social and political strugglesagainst capitalist globalisation on the local as well as the global levelhave also helped the nuclei of a participatory democracy to emerge.People have begun once again to engage politically; against all formsof resistance, they have developed elements for a mode of life basedon solidarity.The other world comes into being <strong>no</strong>t in the beyond, but rather fromand in the struggles of today. The seeds of the new are formed in infinitemultiplicity. The forces of solidarity in the European Union havea particular responsibility. Nowhere else were the experiences of fascistbarbarism so awful and the forces opposed to capital historically sostrong. Nowhere else were such comprehensive institutions of the welfarestate developed. On the basis of very high tech<strong>no</strong>logical development,it is here that turning to sustainability is most possible. The desirefor peace domestically represents a strong brake on imperial politics.Neoliberal policies have met increasingly strong resistance in recentyears. The example of Latin America can be instructive and strengthened.However, this will <strong>no</strong>t occur automatically. The defensive phaseof the left in Europe has still <strong>no</strong>t been overcome. However, the consciousnessthat it will be a catastrophe (Walter Benjamin) if it continuesthis way has become general. This is a chance to be seized.Many elements of this newsolidarity development haveemerged in the existing societydominated by capital.


ways out of the crisis of neoliberalism 31ReferencesAdor<strong>no</strong>, Theodor W. (2006 [19<strong>51</strong>]), Minima Moralia:Refl exionen aus dem beschädigten Leben, Frankfurtam Main: Suhrkamp Verlag.Baumann, Zygmunt (1996), ‚Gewalt – modern undpostmodern’, in Miller, Max and Soeffner, Hans-Georg,Modernität und Barbarei: Soziologische Zeitdiag<strong>no</strong>seam Ende des 20. Jahrhunderts, Frankfurt:Suhrkamp Verlag.Braml, Josef (2004), ‚Vom Rechtsstaat zum Sicherheitsstaat?Die Einschränkung persönlicher Freiheitsrechtedurch die Bush-Administration’, in AusPolitik und Zeitgeschichte, <strong>no</strong>. 45 (http://www.bpb.de/publikationen/S61VJJ,0,0,Vom_Rechtsstaat_zum_Sicherheitsstaat.html#art0)Eigen, Manfred (1987), Stufen zum Leben, München:Piper Verlag.Fromm, Erich (2000), Haben oder Sein: Die seelischenGrundlagen einer neuen Gesellschaft, München:Deutscher Taschenbuch Verlag.Huffschmid, Jörg (2002), Politische Öko<strong>no</strong>mie der Finanzmärkte,Hamburg: VSA Verlag.Klein, Dieter (ed.) (2003), Leben statt gelebt zu werden:Selbstbestimmung und soziale Sicherheit, Berlin:Karl Dietz Verlag.Lorenz, Hans-Walter (1993), Nonlinear Dynamical Eco<strong>no</strong>micsand Chaotic Motion, Berlin: Springer Verlag.Panitch, Leo and Gindin, Sam (2008), ‘Finance andAmerica Empire’, in Panitch, Leo and Konings, Martijn(eds), American Empire and the Political Eco<strong>no</strong>myof Global Finance, New York: Monthly Review Press,pp. 17-47.Polanyi, Karl (1944), The Great Transformation, Boston:Beacon Press.Young-Bruehl, Elisabeth (2004), Hannah Arendt: Leben,Werk und Zeit, Frankfurt am Main: Fischer TaschenbuchVerlag.Waldrop, M. Mitchell (1993), Inseln im Chaos: Die Erforschungkomplexer Systeme, Reinbek bei Hamburg:Rowohlt Verlag.Wieser, Wolfgang (1998), Die Erfi ndung der Individualitätoder Die zwei Gesichert der Evolution, Heidelbergand Berlin: Spektrum Akademischer Verlag.Windolf, Paul (2005), ‚Was ist Finanzmarktkapitalismus?’,in Windolf, P. (ed.), Finanzmarkt-Kapitalismus,Special Issue of the Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologieund Sozialpsychologie, Wiesbaden, pp. 20-57.


Postneoliberalism and its bifurcationsAna Esther CeceñaThe end of neoliberalismNeoliberalism met its definitive end with the crisis that erupted in2008. There is <strong>no</strong> going back. By itself, the market is self-destructive.It has to be supported and contained. Capitalist society, arbitrated bythe market, either plunders itself or becomes uncontained. It lackslong-term perspectives.Both things have happened after 30 years of neoliberalism. The voraciousnessof the market took the appropriation of nature and the dispossessio<strong>no</strong>f human beings to the extreme. Territories were ravagedby desertification and their inhabitants driven out. People revolted,and ecological catastrophe, which had reached an extreme point of irreversibility,started to manifest itself in a violent way.People rebelled against the advance of capitalism, blocking the waysthat were taking it towards even greater appropriation. Armed insurgenciesimpeded access to the rainforest; civil revolts put an endto the building of dams, to intensive mining, to the construction ofheavy-load roads, to the privatisation of oil and gas, and to the mo<strong>no</strong>polisatio<strong>no</strong>f water. The market, by itself, was <strong>no</strong>t able to defeatthose people who were already out of its reach because they had beenexpelled; and from there, from the <strong>no</strong>n-market, they were strugglingfor human and natural life, for life’s essential elements, for a<strong>no</strong>ther relationshipwith nature, for an end to the pillaging.The end of neoliberalism begins when the extent of dispossession arousesthe fury of the people and compels them to burst onto the scene.Phase shiftsContemporary capitalist society has reached a level of complexity thathas made it extremely unstable. In the same way as happens with biologicalsystems (Prigogine 2006), complex social systems possess aninfinite and, to a great extent, unpredictable capacity for reaction inthe face of stimuli or changes. The diversity on which this societyhas been built, and which comes from the subsuming, rather thaneliminating, different societies with other ways of understanding theuniverse, other customs and histories, results in a multiplicity of so-


34 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatecial behaviours and political perceptions and practices throughout theworld, and thus opens up an immense spectrum of perceptions of realityand possibilities for social organisation.The cohesive power of capitalism has allowed the establishment ofdifferent moments of what physicists call equilibrium, where, despitethe deep contradictions of this system, as well as the e<strong>no</strong>rmous variationsit implies, wasteful tendencies are decreasing. Nevertheless, itsduration is limited. Between equilibrium and dissipation there areconstant opportunities for bifurcation, which require capitalism tofind those opportune cohesive elements with which to construct anew equilibrium, or, in other words, to re-establish the conditions requiredfor capital valorisation. But the risk of rupture, which points topossible epistemological and systemic dislocations, is always present.The system’s internal equilibria, understood as patterns of accumulation– in eco<strong>no</strong>mic termi<strong>no</strong>logy – are forms of social articulation sustainedaround a dynamising and ordering axis. This is an axis of complex rationalitywhich, according to circumstances, embraces different forms:in the Fordist phase it was clearly the assembly-line for large-scale productionas well as the state in its role as social organiser; under neoliberalism,it was the market; and under postneoliberalism, it is simultaneouslythe state, as controller of global territory – that is, under the commandof its military aspect – and private enterprise as a form of directself-expression used by the system of power, subverting the limits of theliberal right established during the former stages of capitalism.Between equilibrium anddissipation, there are constantopportunities for bifurcation.The postneoliberalisms and its bifurcationsThe uncertainty concerning the future leads us to characterise it moreas the negation of a stage that is being exceeded. If the capitalist modalitythat stems from the crisis of the 1970s – involving a profoundtransformation of the mode of production and of organising productionand the market – was called post-Fordist by many scholars, todaythe same thing is happening with the transition from neoliberalismto something different, which, although it has already been sketchedout, still leaves a broad margin for things to be overlooked.Post-Fordism formulates itself from the perspective of the changes inthe system of work and in the way the state carries out its social function,while neoliberalism operates from the perspective of the marketand the relative abandonment of the socialising function of the state.In both cases, there is <strong>no</strong> definite name; it is either a post, and in thissense a completely undefined field, or a neo, which delimits without


postneoliberalism and its bifurcations 35being very creative. Both are currently giving way to a<strong>no</strong>ther – muchmore sophisticated – post, which brings the two qualities together:postneoliberalism. We are dealing here with a category that has littlelife of its own in the heuristic sense, although it is polysemous at thesame time. Its virtue may be that it leaves open a whole range of possiblealternatives to neoliberalism – from neofascism to the civilisatorybifurcation – but its explanatory strength and qualities are uncertainand insufficient.Under these circumstances, in order to make progress with refiningor modifying the concept, it is indispensable to stop and look at thenature of the different scenarios, and to be aware that such a spectrumof possibilities includes some alternatives for reinforcing capitalism –even though it may be a capitalism with greater difficulties of legitimacy;for creating new ways out of capitalism, starting from its owninstitutions; and for collective modes of conceiving and putting intopractice <strong>no</strong>n-capitalist social organisations. It is necessary to work onall levels of abstraction and reality, where this term occupies the placeof an alternative without a name of its own, or the place of diversealternatives in a situation of coexistence without hegemonies, whichprevents any one of these alternatives from giving a specific contentto the process of going beyond neoliberalism.The postneoliberalism of capitalEven before the eruption of the current crisis it was evident that neoliberalismhad reached the limits of its power. The bonanza of thegolden years of the free market allowed the expansion of capitalismin all aspects on a global scale; it guaranteed e<strong>no</strong>rmous benefits forsome and the strengthening of large-scale capital; it eliminated nearlyall barriers to private appropriation; it created a more ‘flexibile’,more precarious and cheaper labour market; and it placed nature in asituation of defencelessness. But after its in<strong>no</strong>vative moment, whichimposed new rhythms <strong>no</strong>t only on production and communication,but also on social struggle, the limits of its own potential started toemerge.Among these limits, it is important to point out at least three that referto the immanent contradictions of capitalist production and theirspecific expression at this point in its development, and to the correspondingcontradictions in the process of appropriation and the socialrelations it constructs.


36 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateNeoliberalism’s achievements in extending the margins of expropriationled it to corrode the social consensus created by the so-calledwelfare state, but also to reduce markets. The general decrease inwages, and in the cost of labour force reproduction in a wider sense,gradually broke down the more sophisticated consumption patternsthat had emerged under Fordism. The capitalist answer consistedof reincorporating this ever-growing population into the marketthrough the producation of precarious goods on a large scale. However,this reincorporation does <strong>no</strong>t compensate, even remotely, foran increase in the production capacities generated by contemporarytech<strong>no</strong>logies; <strong>no</strong>r does it return the expected benefits. The extentof appropriation and concentration, tech<strong>no</strong>logical development, theglobalisation of production and of commercialisation – that is, thenetwork of objectivised power constructed by capital – does <strong>no</strong>t correspondto the dimensions and characteristics of social networks. It isa form of power that is starting to show serious problems in terms ofthe capacity for dialogue. These huge capacities for transforming natureinto a commodity, into a useful object for capital, as well as theaccumulated capability of eco<strong>no</strong>mic management, strengthened bychanges in both the <strong>no</strong>rms of land use and the concept of sovereignty,led to a wild race to appropriate all organic and i<strong>no</strong>rganic matter onthe planet. To get to k<strong>no</strong>w the jungles, to subdue them, to gain mo<strong>no</strong>polyover them, to isolate them, dividing them into their simplestelements, and returning them to the world converted into varioustypes of commodity: this process was – and is – one of the ways tosecure eco<strong>no</strong>mic supremacy; the occupation of territories in order toturn them into material for valorisation. Paradoxically, free-marketcapitalism promoted deep enclosures and wide exclusions. But withone danger: to objectivise life means to destroy it.Capitalism’s struggle todominate nature, and even tocreate artifi cial substitutes forit, has already resulted in theelimination of a huge numberof species, in the creation ofmajor ecological and climaticdisequilibria, and in puttinghumanity itself, and capitalismwith it, at risk of extinction.With the introduction of industrial sequencing tech<strong>no</strong>logies, withthe detailed k<strong>no</strong>wledge of complex ge<strong>no</strong>mes for the purpose of manipulatingthem, with the methods of na<strong>no</strong>-exploration and transformation,with climatic manipulation and many other tech<strong>no</strong>logicaldevelopments in the last 30 years, we have crossed the thresholdinto the largest ecological catastrophe ever experienced on this planet.Capitalism’s struggle to dominate nature, and even to create artificialsubstitutes for it, has already resulted in the elimination of a hugenumber of species, in the creation of major ecological and climaticdisequilibria, and in putting humanity itself, and capitalism with it,at risk of extinction.But perhaps the most obvious limits here are manifesting themselvesin the critical scarcity of fundamental elements sustaining the process


postneoliberalism and its bifurcations 37of production and of generating value, like oil, or of those sustainingthe production of life, like water, to a great extent squanderedthrough the ill-use to which it has been put during the capitalistprocess itself. Once again, the paradox is that, in order to avoid or tocompensate for scarcity, strategies are designed that worsen the catastrophe,such as the transformation of forests into transgenic soy ormaize plantations for the production of biofuel, which is much lessproductive and just as pollutting and destructive as oil.Capitalism has been shown to have an exceptional ability to overcomeobstacles and find new ways of operating; however, the levels ofdevastation reached, and the logic with which it is advancing towardsthe future, allow us to realise that the solutions are going up a blind alley,where even the conditions for capital valorisation are decreasing.Although neoliberalism has been characterised as a time of the preeminenceof financial capital, and this has led to the <strong>no</strong>tion of deterritorialisedcapitalism, in fact neoliberalism was characterised by afierce dispute over the redefinition of the use and ownership of territories.This redefinition has led to the rediscovery of societies hiddenin the shelter of jungles, forests, deserts or glaciers that modernitywas <strong>no</strong>t interested in penetrating. Giving these territories a monetaryvalue has brought about an offensive of expulsion, displacement ora recolonisation of those communities that, unsurprisingly, rose upagainst such a process.This, together with the protests and revolts caused by structural adjustmentpolicies or by privatisation of resources, rights and servicespromoted by neoliberalism, has charactersied the political landscapesince the 1990s. The conditions of impunity in which the first freetrade agreements were made, the first deregulations, the stripping ofland and so many other measures promoted since the capitalist crisisand reorganisation of the 1970s and 1980s, changed with the uprisingsof the 1990s, in which a shift of social dynamics took place thatstarted to pull back the free reins of neoliberalism.It was <strong>no</strong>t e<strong>no</strong>ugh to give the market freedom. The market acts as adisciplining and cohesive force in that it maintains a capacity for disarticulation,while the social forces are reorganising in response tothe new forms and contents of the domination process. Nor was themarket able to be a long-term alternative, since the voraciousness ofthe market provokes the destruction of the conditions for the reproductio<strong>no</strong>f society.


38 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateThe same system saw itself obliged to go beyond neoliberalism, movingits ordering axis from individual freedom (and private property),promoted by the market, towards social and territorial control, as away to re-establish its possibility of future prospect. The ideologicalslogan of ‘the free market’ was replaced by that of ‘national security’,and a new phase of capitalism starts to open up, with the followingcharacteristics:First, if neoliberalism places the market in the situation of using theplanet for its goals of maintaining capitalist hegemony, in this caseunder the rule of the United States, in this new phase which hascome into being with the start of the millennium the task is left inthe hands of the military authorities, which are undertaking a processof internal realignment, both organisational and conceptual, and alsoof global realignment.The modified situation in the former so-called socialist world had alreadyrequired a change of geopolitical vision, which corresponds toa new strategical design of penetration and control of the territories,resources and social dynamics of the Central Asian region. The e<strong>no</strong>rmousinfluence of this region in the defining of the internal eco<strong>no</strong>micsupremacy of the system meant that from the outset the area could<strong>no</strong>t just be left in the hands of a market which, given the confusedand disordered circumstances in the aftermath of the fall of the BerlinWall and the collapse of the Soviet Union, had good opportunitiesfor business but lacked favourable conditions for reordering theregion in accordance with the criteria of the United States’ hegemonyover capitalism. In this region we see the beginnings of what wouldafterwards become global policies: the militarised command over theprocess of production, reproduction and spacialisation of capitalism atthe dawn of the 21st century.The ideological slogan of ‘thefree market’ was replaced bythat of ‘national security’, anda new phase of capitalismstarts to open up.Second, this militarisation is alert both to the potential threat of otherhegemonic coalitions challenging the United States’ leadership, andto the systemic risk due to the questionings and to the construction ofalternatives by <strong>no</strong>n-capitalist social organisations. Its purposes are themaintenance of power hierarchies, the safeguarding of those conditionssustaining hegemony and counter-insurgency. It implies maintaininga situation of latent war, very similar to a state of emergency,and the permanent persecution of dissidents.These features would rapidly lead us to think of a return to fascism,were they <strong>no</strong>t combined with others that contradict them and indicatea characterisation that goes beyond neos and posts.


postneoliberalism and its bifurcations 39Wars, and military policies in general, are <strong>no</strong> longer a public affair.This is <strong>no</strong>t just because many wars in our time have focused on socalled‘failed states’ and, in this sense, do <strong>no</strong>t take place between‘states’, but between a state and the society of a particular nation. Itis also because, although it may be the state that initially becomesinvolved in armed confl ict, it does so through an external structurewhich, once contracted, is driven by its own rules and does <strong>no</strong>t respondto the criteria of the public administration.This kind of outsourcing, which has become common in today’s capitalism,has very deep implications for the case we are concerned with.It is <strong>no</strong>t a matter simply of the privatising of certain components ofstate activities, but of a rupture with any real sense of the state. Transferringthe use of violence from the state to the <strong>no</strong>n-public sphereputs justice in private hands and annuls the rule of law. It is <strong>no</strong>t evena state of emergency. The state is emptied of all authority and, bybreaking with the <strong>no</strong>tion of the mo<strong>no</strong>poly of violence. it has establishedviolence within society.Under fascism, a strong state existed, capable of organising societyand generating consensus. The state was centralised and disciplined.Today, appealing to law and to <strong>no</strong>rms established collectivelyis becoming a <strong>no</strong>nsense, and the institutions responsible for ensuringtheir execution are militating against them. Consider, for example,Guantánamo or the occupation of Iraq.With the recent crisis, the most important capitalist institutions havecollapsed. The IMF and the World Bank are repudiated even by theirfounders. We are going into a form of capitalism without rights, withoutcollective <strong>no</strong>rms, with an openly factious state. In other words,mercenary capitalism.Alternative national postneoliberalismA<strong>no</strong>ther variant on overcoming neoliberalism is the one enacted byseveral Latin American states today which proclaim themselves socialistor in transition towards socialism, and which have begun tocontravene, or even reverse, the neoliberal policies imposed by theIMF and the World Bank. Despite the differences between them,all these experiences, which involved an electoral challenge to thepresidency are sharing and creating, in collaboration, ways of distancingthemselves from the dominant orthodoxy. Bolivia, Ecuador andVenezuela, each following its own particular rhythm, are pushingthrough policies aimed at the recovery of sovereignty and participa-


40 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatetory power, which have taken shape in the new constitutions elaboratedby their respective societies. 1The dispute with the IMF and the World Bank has created a certaindistance from these institutions and their policies, while the creatio<strong>no</strong>f an alternative institutionality – as yet embryonic – is underwaythrough, for example, ALBA, the Banco del Sur, Petrocaribe 2and others. However, these initiatives do <strong>no</strong>t in themselves indicateguidelines for an anti-capitalist endeavour, but, for the moment, theyopen up a space of greater independence with regard to the worldeco<strong>no</strong>my, which is more propitious for the building of socialism.First, to advance the processes of restoring sovereignty, indispensablein terms of their relation with the major global powers – whetherthese arise from matters of state or business – and to embark on largescalesocial projects of a socialist conception, the strengthening of thestate and its leadership are required. The paradox lies in the fact thatthe state represents an institution created by capitalism to secure privateproperty and social control.The paradox lies in the factthat the state representsan institution created bycapitalism to secure privateproperty and social control.1 A very different case – but one where there is open confrontation with the dominantscheme – is that of Iran. Even though there is <strong>no</strong> pretension here to a transition tosocialism, it would be necessary to study carefully its elements of discord in order tounderstand its particular way out of neoliberalism, if such is possible.2 Translators’ <strong>no</strong>te: ALBA (‘alba’ means ‘dawn’) is the abbreviation for ‘AlternativaBolivariana para las Américas’, a new leftist movement along the Andean–Caribbeanaxis inspired by Simón Bolívar’s dream of a unifi ed American continent. The Bancodel Sur (Bank of the South) will devote fi nancial resources to the accomplishment ofindependent development objectives. Through Petrocaribe’s programme, Venezuela isusing its oil revenues to build a space for solidarity exchanges.


postneoliberalism and its bifurcations 41Second, the processes of nationalisation undertaken, or the limits imposedon transnational capital, changing its role from owner to servicesupplier or to mi<strong>no</strong>r shareholder, marks a substantial differenceconcerning the capacity to dispose of the strategic resources of everynation. In this case, sovereignty is held and exercised by the state, butthis still does <strong>no</strong>t transform the conception of the way these resourcesare used, to the extent that intensive mining projects are still encouraged,albeit under other property <strong>no</strong>rms. This is <strong>no</strong>t e<strong>no</strong>ugh for a‘change of model’; it is a first step –the follow-up to which is uncertain– but it indeed represents a historic popular claim.Third, the reinforcement of the national interest vis-à-vis the globalor transnational powers is accompanied by a centralisation of thestate, which does <strong>no</strong>t turn out to be easily compatible, either with the<strong>no</strong>tion of plural nationality postulated by indige<strong>no</strong>us peoples, or withthe idea of a participatory democracy which brings the processes ofdeliberation and decision-making nearer to the community level.Lastly, the constitutions have outlined the construction of a new society.In Bolivia and Equador, there have been proposals to changethe aims of ‘development’ to those of ‘good living’, 3 marking a fundamentaldifference between development’s rush forward and the horizontal,or even circular, march of good living, which reminds us ofthe Zapatist metaphor of ‘walking at the pace of the slowest’. Theepistemological dislocation implied by emergence of the idea of goodliving takes the process towards a societal bifurcation. Therefore, thedebate is <strong>no</strong> longer about neoliberalism or postneoliberalism, butabout something else, which is <strong>no</strong> longer capitalist and which bringstogether the millenia-long experiences of communities and the radicalcriticism of capitalism. Various names have been given to this:communitarian socialism; socialism of the 21st century; socialism inthe 21st century; or <strong>no</strong>t even socialism, only good living, auto<strong>no</strong>myof communities or emancipatory horizons.So, the construction of this other way of being, to which we can givethe generic name of good living, necessarily has to leave capitalismbehind, but at the same time it has to transform capitalism, with theconstant risk of being trapped in the attempt, because, among otherreasons, such a search process is undertaken from within the institutionalityof the (still capitalist) state, with all the historical and politicalburden it entails.3 On this matter, consult the texts of the new constitutions of Bolivia (2007; still <strong>no</strong>tpromulgated in late 2008) and Equador (2008), as well as the article by AlbertoAcosta (2008), president of the Constituent Assembly of Equador.


42 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateThe postneoliberalism of the peopleA<strong>no</strong>ther process of transcending neoliberalism is that undertaken bypeoples who have <strong>no</strong>t opted for the electoral struggle, essentially becausefrom the very beginning they have decided to distance themselvesfrom the dominant institutionality. Many indige<strong>no</strong>us peoplesin America have been concerned with this process, or variations of it.Their rejection of institutionality, is based on a combination of bifurcationswith respect to colonial domination – that is, the latent rebellionsover more than 500 years, as well as the corresponding rebellionsagainst capitalist domination. Actually, the nations that came into beingat the time of independence from Spain and Portugal reproducedthe relations of internal colonialism and are therefore <strong>no</strong>t recognisedas retrievable spaces.Sometimes, resistance and rebellions arise that admit the nation, but<strong>no</strong>t the state, as a transitory space of resistance, while other rebellionsleap over this stage in order to launch themselves into a struggle thatis anticapitalist and anticolonial and dedicated to constructing/reconstructingentirely new forms of social organisation.From this perspective, the process is carried out in community spaces,transforming everyday networks and creating the conditions for selfdeterminationand self-support, always conceived in an open manner,through discussion and through the sharing, in solidarity, of similarexperiences.To recover and to recreate people’s own ways of life, which are human,based on respect of all other living beings and the environment,with a free politicality deivoid of hegemonisms. Decentralised democracies.This is the other way out of neoliberalism, and it wouldbe very impoverishing to call it postneoliberalism, because it is evendifficult to locate it in the same semantic field. We all k<strong>no</strong>w that semanticsare also politics, and that here too it is essential to subvert oursenses to make them correspond to the new air of emancipation.What is coming after neoliberalism is a wide range of multiple possibilities.Let us <strong>no</strong>t narrow the horizon, fencing it in with conceptsthat reduce its complexity and belittle its creative and emancipatorycapacities. The world is full of many different worlds, with infiniteroutes of bifurcation. It is up to the peoples in struggle to show theways forward.


postneoliberalism and its bifurcations 43What is coming afterneoliberalism is a wide rangeof multiple possibilities. Letus <strong>no</strong>t narrow the horizon,fencing it in with conceptsthat reduce its complexityand belittle its creative andemancipatory capacities.ReferencesAcosta, Alberto (2008), ‘La compleja tareade construir democráticamente una sociedaddemocrática’ (The complex task of building ademocratic society democratically), in TendenciaI <strong>no</strong>.8, Quito.Prigogine, Ilya (2006 [1988]), El nacimiento del tiempo(The Birth of Time), Argentina: Tusquets.Constitución de la República del Ecuador(Constitution of the Equatorian Republic of Ecuador),2008.


Postneoliberalism and Post-Fordism– Is there a new period in thecapitalist mode of production?Alex DemirovicFor the last two decades materialist theory has been trying to answerthe question of whether, after the long period of Fordism, thereis <strong>no</strong>w a new period of capitalist social formation (cf. the contributionsin Brand and Raza 2003). This new phase has been tentativelycharacterised as post-Fordism (Hirsch 1995) or as high-tech capitalism(Candeias 2008). In the 1980s, the political programme accompanyingit was characterised as neoconservative; since the mid-1990s ithas been called neoliberal. This period had its prelude in 1973 withthe military coup in Chile. In the 1980s it was characterised by thegovernments of Reagan, Thatcher and Kohl; the rise of rightwingpopulist and racist movements; the dissolution of socialist states andRussia’s loss of position as a hegemonic country; the rise of the Infocomindustry and the new eco<strong>no</strong>my; the transformation of social democracyinto new parties of the electoral centre, which re-organisedtheir classical connection with the unions in a looser way; and therise of the eco<strong>no</strong>mies of South East Asia, China, India and Brazil (cf.Rilling 2008). There are indications that this period is <strong>no</strong>w drawingto a close. In Latin and Central America, resistance has been formingsince the mid-1990s. There have been social movements against theneoliberal-dominated mode of globalisation, social resistance movementsforming in China, unremitting protests against the West in Islamiccountries, and numerous attacks; along with increasing migrations;all these could be taken as evidence that the neoliberal strategyof capitalist reshaping of social relations has encountered rejectionworldwide.When the question comes up of whether or <strong>no</strong>t the period of neoliberalismis coming to its end or is already at an end, it is sensiblefirst to get a sense of the characteristics of this phase in the OECDstates themselves. In my view, the period was marked by a tendencytowards destruction of the well-rehearsed organisation of relationsbetween the social classes, thus the dissolution of the compromisewith the waged working class and the dissolution of alliances withthe middle classes. I understand neoliberalism as a practical ideology,as a strategy that allows the ruling classes to govern the state through


46 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatethe market (cf. Foucault 2004, Demirovic 2008). It is therefore <strong>no</strong>tthe case that that neoliberalism is exclusively promoting the market.On the contrary, neoliberalism does <strong>no</strong>t aim programmatically to doaway with all differentiation; rather, all social relations are subjectedto reorganisation in a way that makes markets and competition work– and that is why it aims to introduce market-like forms of governanceinto the different social fields. Thus there is a new paradigm ofaccumulation and domination.For the bourgeoisie, it is a case of dissolving previous compromises –that is, the institutions necessary for agreements, negotiations and (atleast according to the claims) relatively egalitarian ways of life – andof acting independently of these compromises. An essential characteristicof the neoliberal-dominated accumulation strategy is correspondinglythe abandonment of consensus and hegemony, insofar ashegemony means that the bourgeois class makes concessions. The neoliberal-orientedsections of the bourgeois class aim to pursue, alone,corporate interests of appropriation of the means of production, thesubjugation of life relations to capital valorisation and the class’s immediateaccumulation of wealth. Concessions, negotiations and compromisesare <strong>no</strong>t considered. Correspondingly, the form of politicspursued is one of reducing taxes for entrepreneurs on assets or stockexchange transactions, and raising mass taxes (that is, value added taxor income tax). Correspondingly, the state budget is borne to an evergreater extent by the subaltern classes. Additionally, the decreasingstate budget is deployed in the interests of the upper classes (armaments,increasing the size of the police force, subsidies, family support,health policies that serve the medical-technical and pharmacyindustry more than the patient), while the share of state expenditurethat aims at consensus – social expenditure, education, culture – isshrinking. One could indeed say that members of the middle classeswere drawn into the accumulation dynamic through share ownership,through higher returns on savings, through real estate ownershipor through consumer credit. Yet it inverts the concept of hegemonyif these practices of eco<strong>no</strong>mically determined dominationare characterised as hegemony, for it is <strong>no</strong>t a case of a politics that hasalliances and compromise between the many classes as its foundationand which, by means of the state, is generalised as a way of life that iscomparatively homoge<strong>no</strong>us and keeps the distance between the socialclasses relatively small. Rather, the neoliberal strategy promotes thepolarisation of society in terms of education, access to privileged professionalpositions, income or assets. Individuals are individualised;they are forced to enter into a relationship of competition with eachother. Even in relation to themselves the individuals fall into a <strong>no</strong>vel


postneoliberalism and post-fordism – is there a new period in the capitalist mode of production? 47type of contradiction: value increase in share ownership or higher interestin private old-age pensions are linked in a way mediated by themarket, with increasing exploitation, the creation of a global labourmarket and the risk of becoming a victim of relocation, outsourcingor rationalisation. Individuals are required to think of themselves inan entrepreneurial way and rationalise themselves in relation to employability.Individuals are required tothink of themselves in anentrepreneurial way andrationalise themselves inrelation to employability.This form of domination is domination by and through contingency(cf. Demirovic 2001). By that, I mean a <strong>no</strong>vel technique of dominationthat systematically produces the ‘dull compulsion’ of social relationsand uses it in order to liberate the state from a responsibility experiencedas a political burden. This goes back to the crisis diag<strong>no</strong>sis ofthe Trilateral Commission, which had repercussions in the differentleading capitalist states and meant that the welfare state was <strong>no</strong> longercapable of acting, due to increasing obligations to the ruled. It isthereafter a case of cutting through the many networks that emergedduring the welfare state phase between politics and administration onthe one side and associations (above all the unions) on the other. Thestate apparatuses should be re-organised for their particular functionfor the ruling class. They are dissolved or weakened as access to thestate apparatuses is made strategically more selective – that is, determinedby the rulers – and dynamic. In particular, <strong>no</strong>n-governmentalorganisations corresponded to these changed claims of the state apparatuses,since they depend in part on state funding and could drawon high informational and advisory competence. Their connection tothe membership and their democratic legitimacy is low, which makesthem flexible and entirely suitable as dialogue partners in negotiationswith state administrations. At the same time, NGOs, on the basis oftheir engagement with particular themes of groups of people, couldclaim to represent general interests as advocates. This gives the possibilityof playing them off against the unions, which the rulers claimedwould only represent particular interests.Domination through contingency can be illustrated with the exampleof insurance. With insurance based upon solidarity, the solidaritycommunity would take over the damages experienced by a member,such as illnesses, inability to work, need for care and so forth.The coverage occurs across the board, even if the way expenditureon medical care provision is conducted is still contested and in needof regulation. With reorganisation to a model of insurance based onmathematical distinction of risk groups, individual behaviour is assessedaccording to statistically <strong>no</strong>rmal distributions. What is calculatedis the probability of a person belonging to a particular risk group.


48 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateCorrespondingly, these groups – young male drivers, smokers, individualswith a specific genetic disposition, and so on – have to acceptthat their insurance premiums will go up or down. In a similar way,this is the case with the introduction of market prices for transport infrastructure.This is <strong>no</strong> longer regarded as public, and available to allcitizens at any time – which actually was never the case, because individualmotorised travel was in many ways <strong>no</strong>t based on solidarity, asit had destructive consequences for the public space; instead, the publictransport system is <strong>no</strong>w much more understood as a limited good,for the use of which market prices are to be paid, higher according tothe demand. In all these cases, individuals can <strong>no</strong> longer calculate exante what consequences certain actions will have for them. It is oneof the paradoxical consequences that the increase in uncertainty goestogether at the same time with the externally imposed fixing of individualsto a determinate identity. On the basis of statistically determinatesocial or biological characteristics, individuals become membersof a risk group and are thus defined according to particular quasi-naturalcharacteristics. Social inequality increases, since the availabilityof money makes one independent of such market-type restrictions.The calculated statistical risk expectations finally lead to the impositio<strong>no</strong>f disclosure of private data, provision for the goal of risk minimisation,and increased individual contributions.Domination through contingency does <strong>no</strong>t see society as a space thatarises from homoge<strong>no</strong>us life relations. On the contrary, heterogeneityand chance are its basis. Nevertheless, these result in statistically comprehensibledistributions. Clusters can be formed that correspond tospecific <strong>no</strong>rmality expectations. If deviations occur (protests, illnesses,infections, dependency, migration, armed confl ict), state apparatusestransnationally become active and form networks (transnationalprisoner and migrant camps, military operations, police, informationand monitoring systems, medical controls, hygiene measures). Withtechnical control and regulation of deviations, even authoritarian solutionsare accepted.The public transport system is<strong>no</strong>w much more understoodas a limited good, for the useof which market prices are tobe paid, higher according tothe demand.This pattern of domination by and through contingency is associatedwith a new regime of accumulation that views stable practices as alimitation of the dynamic of valorisation. It is based on the dynamisatio<strong>no</strong>f consumer demand and a correspondingly flexible and specialisedform of production in commercial enterprises, based on marketlogic. To this belong the establishment of profit centres, the introductio<strong>no</strong>f benchmarks and so-called best practices, flexibilisation andlonger working hours, the division of the workforce into core labourand those in precarious employment (temp work, part-time, ‘mini


postneoliberalism and post-fordism – is there a new period in the capitalist mode of production? 49jobs’). Information techniques, a new logistics, low transport costsand the politically driven liberalisation of markets allow the transnationalisatio<strong>no</strong>f value chains. This makes it possible to exploit differencesin taxation, wages, productivity and social and environmentalstandards. A worldwide labour market opens up for capital, for theappropriation of surplus labour. An already skilled workforce can beexploited without the companies having to bear the costs that ensuringa suitably qualified labour capacity would imply. The global labourmarket itself develops dynamically, because in many regions thepopulation is about to be proletarianised and is migrating from thecountry to the cities. This includes internal migration in countrieslike Turkey, China, India, Thailand and Brazil as well as migrationfrom the periphery to the centres of the world eco<strong>no</strong>my (from Africato Europe, from Central America to the US).This dynamic, however, does <strong>no</strong>t tie up the money capital circulatingto a sufficient extent. For the goal of capital valorisation, new realmsof nature and society are also given a monetary value – that is, theyare subjected to capital valorisation. This includes very different processes.Services that were previously in the hands of the state are privatised.This involves public infrastructure such as water, roads, telecommunications,energy and public transport, as well as public careservices such as childcare, education, health, and care of the elderly.The arguments are always the same: state money represents subsidies;these discourage institutions from confronting competition, preventingefficient organisation, blocking in<strong>no</strong>vations and crippling the initiativeof individuals, who have <strong>no</strong> stimulus to orient themselves differently.Correspondingly, public services are downsized and largenumbers of employees are fired from the public sector or subjectedto the capitalist labour market through privatisation (precarious employment,achievement-oriented rewards, longer working hours, reducedquality).But it is <strong>no</strong>t only what previously was under public control and removedfrom the market that is <strong>no</strong>w commodified. Capital also takesover the pioneer function by opening up entirely new organisationalspheres of valorisation. Think, for example, of genetic resources forpharmaceutical, medical and agricultural purposes, of reproductivehealth, of the development of renewable energy, of the developmentof the seas.The large amount of money capital circulating (petrodollars, savings,pension funds), as well as the decline in the productivity rate and lowerprofitability, have led to a search for new spheres of investment. Lib-


50 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateeralisation and deregulation were introduced in order to achieve this,thus making currency speculation, stock market transactions or derivativemarkets possible to a great extent. The paradoxical effect is thateven more money capital is <strong>no</strong>w available and looking for profitableinvestment opportunities. The decline in corporate and asset taxes reducesthe state’s possibilities of linking financial resources in the longterm to public infrastructure. Private households are required to investin health and old age care. Savings and other provisions, above all inpensions, as well as the financial assets of private individuals and moneycapital, are concentrated in institutional investors and funds that haveto invest this money in order to earn interest. At the same time, however,in trying to achieve this goal, they encounter worsened conditionsfor real eco<strong>no</strong>mic production and reproduction, since long-terminvestments are less rewarding. They thus invest money in shares anddrive prices up, speculating in foreign currency and dealing in high-interestcredit. A casi<strong>no</strong>-esque type of activity emerges. National eco<strong>no</strong>miessuch as Germany’s show a reduction in the investment quota. Allthe way to the middle-sized enterprises, there is an attempt to increaseprofit through the investment of money capital in the form of interest.Enterprises and their individual component parts are assessed accordingto the perspective of shareholder value. This means that the company’sestimated profits are based on expectation of interest. The enterprise isitself valorised and becomes an object of transactions on the financialmarket: it is broken up into value-related component parts (real estate,production branches, k<strong>no</strong>whow, patents) and sold, according to marketdynamics. In individual cases this type of accumulation can en-Savings and pensions, fi nancialassets of private individualsand money capital, areconcentrated in institutionalinvestors and funds thathave to invest this moneyin order to earn interest.They encounter worsenedconditions for real eco<strong>no</strong>micproduction and reproduction,since long-term investmentsare less rewarding. They thusinvest money in shares anddrive prices up, speculating inforeign currency and dealingin high-interest credit. Acasi<strong>no</strong>-esque type of activityemerges.


postneoliberalism and post-fordism – is there a new period in the capitalist mode of production? <strong>51</strong>able a tenfold or hundredfold increase in the value of the company’scapital; since, however, the total eco<strong>no</strong>my on average only grows a fewpercent, this means that this growth can only be achieved at the costof other market participants (that is, a devalorisation of capital and itsclaim to a share of the total profits).Since the 1990s, the money form – that is, credit and interest – hasbecome predominant over industrial and trade capital; finance capitalis taking hold as the dominant sector in the power bloc on a transnationallevel. The expectation was <strong>no</strong>urished that there could be anew finance-dominated regime of accumulation, with self-supportinggrowth and new forms of participation and compromise. Therehas been accumulation through dispossession, but there has neverthelessbeen <strong>no</strong> coherent regulation pattern. For the assumption thatdiffusion of share ownership stimulates consumption, that consumptionin its turn leads to fiscal surplus and growth of industry, whoseprofits in their turn are invested and increase the value of the enterprises,has <strong>no</strong>t been confirmed. The enterprises have invested less intech<strong>no</strong>logies, research and development, because long-term capitalinvestment appeared less lucrative than short-term operations on thefinancial markets. Lower- and middle-income households, which arethe driver of mass consumption, clearly owned fewer shares than thesmall number of wealthy households. Consumerism, above all amongthe American population, was financed by credit. The demand forshares, by institutional investors in particular, led to their overvaluationand to the formation of a speculative bubble at the beginningof the millennium. With the dotcom crisis, the crisis process touchedfor the first time the centres that had managed up until then to shiftthe devalorisation of capital by means of speculation to other regions(South East Asia, Central and Latin America, or Russia). Money capital,still searching for valorisation even after the crisis, saw a solutionin giving more credit to consumers. Between 2000 and 2004, UShousehold mortgages increased in value by us$ 3 trillion. The expectationwas that workers’ budgets would satisfy the profit expectationsof the finance industry through paying back interest. When this did<strong>no</strong>t occur to the desired extent, low-risk and high-risk mortgageswere mixed together and sold as an investment product. Forty percent of these credits are tendentially <strong>no</strong> longer worth as much as supposed.Nevertheless, it is <strong>no</strong>t only a question of these debts, worth anestimated us$ 1.5 trillion. House owners used the rising value of theirhouse and mortages in order to get other credits for consumption (andthe bank had the asset of a presumably valuable house).


52 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateAdditionally, there are credit card risks. Moreover, it is unclear howmany structured financial market products with less value than expectedare still in circulation. Credit default swaps alone, with whichcompanies secured themselves against speculation risks, are estimatedat a volume of us$ 62 trillion – a much more extensive property titlethan could ever be ho<strong>no</strong>ured. Thus were laid the foundations for thecrisis in the housing market and the reduction of consumer spendingthat since the summer of 2008 has been convulsing the eco<strong>no</strong>my,even in the centre, and whose consequences in the face of the propertytitles still in circulation are <strong>no</strong>t yet foreseeable. Trillions of dollarsand euros have already been written off; the probability that an evengreater amount of capital will be destroyed is <strong>no</strong>t small. The leadingcapitalist states are attempting to guarantee the property titles of theaccumulated capital in its totality. Thus, trust between banks shouldbe created so that they lend each other money; equally, trust is neededto discourage people who have money assets from withdrawing alltheir savings in a panic and thus further reducing liquidity; finally,also to be avoided is a credit squeeze which would make refinancingdifficult or even impossible for many companies, forcing them to filefor bankruptcy. The leading states together granted two to three trilliondollars and euros for the direct rescue of banks and for the supportof financial institutions in the autumn of 2008. They reduced interestrates in order to provide liquidity and implemented eco<strong>no</strong>micrecovery programmes. In some states, these political support actionswere linked to partial state takeovers of the banks; in others, the stateonly imposed conditions (regarding the size of management salaries,or dividends). Altogether, the states have obliged themselves to takeover financial market risks that could force even eco<strong>no</strong>mically strongstates into bankruptcy.The crisis interventions by the state, which signify a break with neoliberaldogmas, were <strong>no</strong>t welcomed by neoliberals in the eco<strong>no</strong>my,politics or the press. The bourgeois camp has <strong>no</strong>t been in agreementabout how to interpret the situation. The refusal of any state guarantee,coherent with the ruling order, and the demand to allow evenbanks and funds to go bankrupt does <strong>no</strong>t have a majority. The attitudeprevails that states should help, once there is a crisis, in a similarway to how medicine is administered during sickness. But when thecrisis is over, they should then withdraw. Thus the position of theFrench President Sarkozy is rejected: he demanded the state takeoverof commercial enterprises in order to protect them from – foreign –financial market actors, and would like to see the financial marketstrongly regulated. But even beneath such strong declarations we canclearly recognise the tendency to regulate the financial market. What


postneoliberalism and post-fordism – is there a new period in the capitalist mode of production? 53The attitude prevails thatstates should help, once thereis a crisis, in a similar way tohow medicine is administeredduring sickness. But when thecrisis is over, they should thenwithdraw.is unclear is the extent. Does this mean that the state is back and neoliberalismis <strong>no</strong>w over? Finished due to its own dynamic, <strong>no</strong>t due toexternal left-wing opposing forces. Will the bourgeois camp followa new postneoliberal politics? Has the neoliberal phase of capitalistaccumulation reached its end and is capitalism <strong>no</strong>w entering a newphase? Is it such a fundamental crisis of capital, the capitalist mode ofproduction in its totality, that the task could fall to the left – for whichit is in <strong>no</strong> way prepared at the moment – of organising the transitionto a new mode of production? It would be somewhat paradoxical: theleft, which has so often talked about how the final collapse of capitalism,is hesitating to place this current crisis alongside the crisis of1929 or even to see it as a final crisis (cf. Rilling 2008). But a series ofcrisis factors come together: the financial market crisis, which containsthe risk of state bankruptcy and contributes to a deep and enduringrecession of the world eco<strong>no</strong>my; collapse of industrial sectors,unemployment, deteriorating living standards of the wage workers– with all of the consequences also for the countries of the South:increase in poverty, less revenue, increased migration and so forth;military entanglements that turn out to be unsolvable; an energy crisisthat has become deeper because, although the the need for actionwas k<strong>no</strong>wn, valuable time was lost in the last decade for developingnew sustainable energy systems; environmental catastrophe; crisis ofresearch, in<strong>no</strong>vation and education; collapse of public infrastructures.The neoliberal propaganda of wanting to produce justice for the futuregeneration by <strong>no</strong>t burdening it with state debts <strong>no</strong>w turns into itsopposite – the future of many people is gambled away.The bourgeois camp is irritated and insecure. That is obvious. However,what the states have undertaken up until <strong>no</strong>w occurs in thecontext of neoliberalism itself. What are supported are the banks andfunds, <strong>no</strong>t the consumers, <strong>no</strong>t those who take credit. In Germany,


54 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateChancellor Merkel guaranteed all deposits. No upper limit was drawnand <strong>no</strong> progression was introduced, which allows a certain amountof losses to be taken on that were actually capital losses, which wouldonly affect a few rich and very rich people. This crisis was immediatelyexploited by cold-blooded actors for the appropriation of publicmoney, for the destruction of capital and for the mo<strong>no</strong>polisation ofbusinesses and banks. There is thus much to be said for the assumptionthat financial market actors have used the crisis as a further formof plundering of the public budgets, of the taxpayer and consumer.Should we therefore say that the state has returned to the role ofstrong regulator because it has to take over the role of the ideal totalcapitalist in the crisis? That would be mistaken. The state was in <strong>no</strong>way absent (cf. Rilling 2008). Rather, the state was much more involvedin the implementation of the politics that were pursued by thedominant sector – finance capital – and led to a multiplicity of legalchanges and measures that have successively increased the eco<strong>no</strong>micpower of this sector since the beginning of the 1990s: deregulation,privatisation, reduction of administration, strengthening of enforcementdeficits, extension of repressive mechanisms. In the current crisisit is emphasised that the state will continue to govern <strong>no</strong>t againstbut rather with the market laws. Nevertheless it is to be supposedthat forces within the state will be moved and the state must be governedin a<strong>no</strong>ther way. For the bourgeois camp in Germany had to admitthat, despite all the early an<strong>no</strong>uncements that Germany was <strong>no</strong>ttouched by the crisis, it can<strong>no</strong>t protect itself from the crisis dynamicon a national basis. The dynamic of the financial market obliged thegovernment, like other states’ governments, to develop means of crisiscontrol or to take them over from other states – because it requiredadequate instruments or because competition made it necessary, forthe rescue programmes and reduction of interest rates work de factolike state subsidies. The tendencies towards new international andtransnational solutions are unmistakable when states guarantee thesecurities of companies and banks of other states or jump in with directmeasures of support. The looming recession is also cause of muchconcern to German business, which is strongly oriented to exportsand attaches little significance to internal demand (even though with55 per cent it has a higher share in internal demand than exports). Atany rate, the state takes up the interests of industry only partially. Itcan<strong>no</strong>t be said that the state is the ideal total capitalist that supposedlyconsiders the interests of all parties. The predominance of financialcapital remains. Broad eco<strong>no</strong>mic growth programmes have <strong>no</strong>t yetbeen proposed.


postneoliberalism and post-fordism – is there a new period in the capitalist mode of production? 55What happens is thatincentives are given even inthe crisis for superannuatedforms of individualconsumption, which at besthave a short-term effect andbarely take money away fromthe fi nancial markets.Neoliberalism had already arrived long before the renewed increasedin the dynamic of crisis in the summer months of 2008 at a pointwhere it was <strong>no</strong> longer able to pursue alone a politics of destruction– that is, of liberalisation, deregulation and privatisation. There wereefforts at new alliances but such efforts were <strong>no</strong>t successful. Too manycrisis elements came together: negative investment development,unemployment, impoverishment that reaches from the level of theworking class to the level of parts of the middle class, worsening ofthe life situation of workers due to low wages, longer working hours,and intensified pressure to improve performance at work; the cutbackof expenditure on education and professional training contributed toa lack of qualified labour-power – there were problems in researchand in<strong>no</strong>vation. In Germany, against all expectations, this was thebasis for the formation, with the party of the left (the Linkspartei), ofa politically influential actor that currently (still) gains much supportfrom the social movements. This makes it possible for the first timein a long while to speak even in public, outside of small leftwing circles,of alternatives to capitalism. The bourgeois parties are to a certainextent making efforts to pay attention to interests from below,through a series of individual measures. The financial crisis furtherincreased the pressure to pursue a politics of concessions; at the sametime, however, any demand for the production and guarantee of publicgoods for all can be rejected <strong>no</strong>w with reference to the crisis. Theburden for future generations is even greater. The substance of politicshas <strong>no</strong>t changed at all. Efforts to change the social laws put inplace under the so-called red-green government of the social democratGerhard Schröder have <strong>no</strong>t yet been successful. Despite all therhetoric of securing education and training, despite the defeats at thepolls that to a large extent are due to the unequal developments in thefield of education, neoliberal education politics remain in force. Unemploymentand precarious work conditions continue to be unmentioned,the facts of poverty are denied. The tendency for employmentrelations to be ever more precarious has <strong>no</strong>t changed. Energy politicsis <strong>no</strong>t undergoing the radical transformation towards the constructio<strong>no</strong>f a decentralised provision of solar energy that would be necessaryto stop the dynamic of global warming and disempower the classicalenergy companies. Worldwide poverty, which is increasing in thecrisis, is <strong>no</strong>t being combated with greater efforts. What is needed isregulation of the financial markets (introduction of taxes for stock exchangetransactions, capital gains tax, progressive taxation of large assets,currency regulation), extending the field of education and stimulatinglong-term demand with a public investment programme todeal with the crisis and bind capital. Instead, what happens is that incentivesare given even in the crisis for superannuated forms of indi-


56 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatevidual consumption, which at best have a short-term effect and barelytake money away from the financial markets.These are provisional indications that the phase of neoliberal structuraltransformation of capitalist social formation is <strong>no</strong>t yet over. Nevertheless,a change of strategy is occurring, even though the bourgeoisactors do <strong>no</strong>t ack<strong>no</strong>wledge the meaning of the crisis and believe thatit will be over in a few months. They want to begin again, as soonas possible, the profitable speculative financial transactions enabledand supported by the state. The dominant capital sectors and groupssee the necessity of a certain degree of regulation of accumulatio<strong>no</strong>n the financial markets, since the increased frequency of crises andtheir depths are just as little unrecognised as the fact that there is <strong>no</strong>longer eco<strong>no</strong>mic restoration after crises due to their quick rhythm (cf.Candeias 2008). Domination by and through contingency is modifiedand extended, and the crisis itself takes on a new meaning: it becomesa governmental tech<strong>no</strong>logy that is implemented in order to destroycapital strategically and to appropriate public spending by financecapital. This also determines the future political struggles, for it willbe a matter of determining who decides which money capital is destroyedin what way: infl ation, small savings, assets of the rich, speculationagainst developing countries. The relation between capital sectors,between productive and financial capital, is being rebalanced.For companies in the productive field, the financial crisis has a seriesof negative consequences: the buying power of consumers sinks, exportsfall, extending credit becomes more difficult. How productiveand financial capital should be newly arranged is certainly <strong>no</strong>t clear;crisis-ridden de-industrialisation processes are probable. In relationto the subaltern classes, there will be a stark polarisation – that is, aneven stronger denial of reality and an energetic claim of <strong>no</strong>rmality bythe ruling classes. This means that the possibilities of politics of consensuswill become weaker and that politics of compulsion, combinedwith domination of contingency, will increase. For the subalterns,this means, alongside a deterioration of their life situation, the possibilityof perceiving themselves as an auto<strong>no</strong>mous social force whoclaim their own view of things and must define the order of thingsaccording to their own power. That isn’t a bad precondition for fundamentaltransformations of the dominant mode of production.


postneoliberalism and post-fordism – is there a new period in the capitalist mode of production? 57ReferencesBrand, Ulrich and Werner, Raza, (eds) (2003), Fitfür den Postfordismus?, Münster: WestfälischesDampfboot.Candeias, Mario (2004), Neoliberalismus.Hochtech<strong>no</strong>logie. Hegemonie. Grundrisse einertransnationalen kapitalistischen Produktions- undLebensweise, Berlin-Hamburg: Argument.Candeias, Mario (2008), ‘Finanzkrise und neuerStaatsinterventionismus’, Rosa-Luxemburg-Stiftungstandpunkte, <strong>no</strong>. 24, Berlin.Demirovic, Alex (2001), ‘Herrschaft durch Kontingenz’,in Bieling, Hans-Jürgen; Dörre, Klaus; Steinhilber,Jochen; and Urban, Hans-Jürgen (eds), FlexiblerKapitalismus, Hamburg: VSA, pp. 208-224.Demirovic, Alex (2008), ‘Neoliberalismus undHegemonie’, in Butterwegge, Christoph; Lösch,Bettina; and Ptak, Ralf (eds), Neoliberalismus.Analysen und Alternativen, Wiesbaden: VS Verlag fürSozialwissenschaften, pp. 17-33.Foucault, Michel (2004), Die Geburt der Biopolitik.Geschichte der Gouvernementalität II, Frankfurt amMain: Suhrkamp.Hirsch, Joachim (1995), Der nationaleWettbewerbsstaat. Staat, Demokratie und Politik imglobalen Kapitalismus, Berlin: ID-Verlag.Rilling, Rainer (2008), ‘Finanzmarktkrise – Ende desNeoliberalismus? Und die Linke?’, Rosa-Luxemburg-Stiftung standpunkte, <strong>no</strong>. 23, Berlin.


Postneoliberalism from and as acounter-hegemonic perspective 1Nicola SeklerThe Exhibition Centre of the City ofBue<strong>no</strong>s Aires, November 2007. Morethan a hundred so-called empresas recuperadas(recovered enterprises 1 ) are displaying theirproducts in an exhibition organised incooperation with the ministry of labour,employment and social security. Theoccasion could be described as a mixture ofa political event and a trade fair. In additionto the market stands, where the enterprisesshow their products and give informationabout their struggles to finally and legallytake over the assets, there is an auditoriumwith lectures on quality management,tech<strong>no</strong>logical and managerial k<strong>no</strong>whow,‘best practices’ and other themes, a cinemashowing movies about specific takeoverstruggles, and a business zone – onlyaccessible to those who have an appointment– where business people can organiseround-tables in order to agree on further(eco<strong>no</strong>mic) cooperation.Greater Bue<strong>no</strong>s Aires, December2007, in one of the many settlementslacking basic infrastructure and services.Members of one of the so-called piquetero 2organisations (unemployment organisations)are constructing a new centro de salud (healthcentre), the old one having closed a fewyears ago. However, the aim of this centreis <strong>no</strong>t to take on the activities of the formerhealth centre, for which state agencies wereresponsible, but – pursuing an integratedapproach – to provide an advisory servicefor neighbourhood communities withrespect to nutrition, prevention programmes,environmental damage and how to deal withit, and courses on alternative medicine. It islunchtime: José and Rodriguez are servinglunch, Carla stops doing the plastering work,Marina switches off the cement mixer,and so on. After lunch the next steps arediscussed – all group members are keen oncompleting construction works as soon aspossible in order to start the activities.1 I would like to thank Ulrich Brand and Thomas Heine for helpful comments on this contribution. Specialthanks go to all the ghost thinkers – mainly living in (Greater) Bue<strong>no</strong>s Aires – who shared their ideas,interpretations and experiences with me.2 The phe<strong>no</strong>me<strong>no</strong>n of empresas recuperadas (or fabricas recuperadas) encompasses a wide range of quitedifferent business facilities from all sectors of the eco<strong>no</strong>my including gastro<strong>no</strong>my, supermarkets, hotels,the metalworking industry, transportation, and so forth. In the following I will use ‘enterprise’ as a generalexpression.3 From the word piquete, meaning ‘road block’ – the typical type of action used by these organisations.Along with the political positioning and identity struggles of the different piquetero organisations a hugediscussion took place about whether their members could be characterised as unemployed people,unemployed workers, in the sense of referring to a worker’s identity, and about working relations andtheir implications in general. Moreover it is important to add that parts of ‘the’ movement never identifi edthemselves with the term piquetero – given to it from outside – because of the unifying moment for sucha heterogeneous group. In order to take account of the heterogeneity and plurality within the piqueteromovement – as it is often called – I decided to use the terms ‘unemployment organisations’ and ‘piqueteroorganisations’.


60 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateWhat do these two scenes have in common? Are there any linkagesbetween recovered enterprises and piquetero organisations? What aretheir respective approaches? Where do they come from and what aretheir objectives or ambitions?To answer these questions I will introduce some theoretical reflections.Starting with Antonio Gramsci`s concept of hegemony andan elaboration on a Gramsci-inspired counter-hegemonic perspectivethis contribution will deal with the question of whether, how and inwhat sense ‘postneoliberalism’ could be a worthwhile analytical perspectiveon counter-hegemonic struggles. The idea is to approach thesubject of ‘alternatives’ through postneoliberal lenses and show thecontinuities and discontinuities. The two examples mentioned illustratehow different these postneoliberal approaches can be, althoughborn out of the same national context and taking a similar startingpoint. This heterogeneity represents one reason why I will concludeby arguing against the use of the term postneoliberalism, politically andstrategically.Postneoliberalism as a counter-hegemonic perspectiveIn a Gramscian tradition, hegemony is <strong>no</strong>t merely based on classdomination, repressive forces and institutions or – at the internationallevel – exercised by one nation; <strong>no</strong>r is it only constituted and consolidatedwithin traditional political institutions and at the national level.Instead, hegemony can be characterised as procedural and consensusbasedas well as established and questioned at multiple levels and eventhrough everyday practices (see, for example, Gef 4: 499, 6: 783, 13:1560ff.).Antonio GramsciJanuary 22, 1891 – April 27, 1937.Often, and even in a Gramscian tradition, the <strong>no</strong>tion of hegemonyhas been used mechanically or descriptively to determine the solidityof a given hegemony, or analogically to question the effectivenessof hegemony. Instead, I would like to stress the procedural aspects ofcreating and negotiating hegemony.Hegemony should be understood as being deeply anchored in civilsociety, which in turn can be identified as the socially determined‘sites’ for disputes over hegemony, social struggles over interpretationsand ‘truths’, and institutionalised political, eco<strong>no</strong>mic and culturalforms of social structures and processes – in short, sites for thestabilisation and the questioning of hegemony. However, Gramcsi’sunderstanding of civil society as a concept as well as the ‘consensual’character of hegemony neither suggests – as <strong>no</strong>rmative or liberal civil


postneoliberalism from and as a counter-hegemonic perspective 61society concepts do – that civil society is something without powerstructures, <strong>no</strong>r that civil society or civil society organisations are‘progressive’ as such. A central insight and an added value of a Gramscianperspective is precisely that civil society actors are seen as sociallyconstituted and embedded, contributing through various practicesand strategies – at the same time – to either stabilising or destabilisingaspects of hegemony.Now, being more explicitly about the consent-based character of hegemony,two aspects have to be stressed. First, hegemony based onconsent does <strong>no</strong>t mean that social groups or individual subjects generallyand actively agree on everything. Forms of acceptance could beactive or passive, and even apparent coercion could be exercised onthe basis of social consent (for example the politics of ‘democratic security’in Columbia, or forms of sexual and domestic violence againstwomen).Second, the idea is <strong>no</strong>t that every ‘negotiation’, agreement or disagreementis performed consciously. Rather, hegemony must be thoughtof as ‘practices which are immanent to the living and working conditions’(Adolphs and Karakayali 2007: 123). Thus, (parts of) hegemonyor hegemonic rules are reproduced – consciously or <strong>no</strong>t – in everydaypractices, in seemingly private or public relations. The most ‘plausible’,‘<strong>no</strong>rmal’ and thus unquestioned relations and interpretationscorrespond to the structural or most prevailing aspects of hegemony.The multifaceted relationship between the existing hegemony and attemptedcounter-hegemony can be described through a reconceptualisatio<strong>no</strong>f Gramsci’s <strong>no</strong>tion of a war of positions, entailing the assumptionthat profound social transformation is <strong>no</strong>t possible via a suddenbreakdown but rather by a complex process (Gef 8: 10<strong>51</strong>):That means ‘other worlds’ (Zibechi 2006: 124) are shaped over a longperiod of time, in sometimes contradictory, molecular search processesleading to changes in everyday consciousness and engendering abreeding-ground for ‘a different view of things’. Restrictions on theseexperiences and struggles arise <strong>no</strong>t only from obvious limitations orcooptation attempts from those defending existing hegemony but alsofrom structural aspects of hegemony anchored in everyday consciousnessas ‘<strong>no</strong>rmality’.


62 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateAs a result of these reflections, postneoliberalism proposed as a counter-hegemonicperspective 4 can be described as highlighting the followingaspects:First, neoliberalism – or any other social formation – can be regardedas a specific setting of social relations – racial, gender, eco<strong>no</strong>micand family – and practices shaped by a particular logic, which in thecase of neoliberalism is a market-driven one. Both the social relationsthemselves and the way of organising these relations can be questionedand challenged at many sites and in different ways.Second, although counter-hegemonic practices, strategies andprojects, whether limited in scope or far-reaching, often uniformlytake neoliberalism as their point of reference for developing alternatives,they in fact address very specific problems or impacts. The degreeof rupture with ‘the old’ varies greatly, and alternatives do <strong>no</strong>tbreak with all aspects of neoliberalism at once. In the end, even ifthey are intended to, <strong>no</strong>t all counter-hegemonic practices challengeinstitutional and state policies (Zibechi 2006: 125) or all aspects of<strong>no</strong>rmality; more generally, such practices may only partly challengethe structural and consolidated moments of hegemony.Third, from the actor’s point of view, looking through postneoliberallenses means asking: where do they break with hegemonic relations,and where <strong>no</strong>t? What are the alternatives? Where are the contradictionsin everyday practices and struggles? Which contradictions dothey consciously work on, and which remain unquestioned becauseof the degree of <strong>no</strong>rmality? And so on. Considering the continuitiesand discontinuities with ‘neoliberalism’ also means asking about thelimitations of ‘post’ elements which can be found either in what I call‘<strong>no</strong>rmality’ or – more generally – in the structural moments of thesocial context, including juridical limitations as well as settled valuesand interpretation patterns.Fourth, the reconstitution of hegemony and the establishment ofcounter-hegemonies in the sense of alternative institutional and everydaypractices occur at the same time, on multiple levels, and atcountless points, thereby creating a plurality of political spaces andstruggles. Just as neoliberalism can<strong>no</strong>t be regarded as a mo<strong>no</strong>lithicblock, but as (re)constituted in different contexts, postneoliberalismor the respective counter-hegemony has to be considered as ‘under4 In a<strong>no</strong>ther contribution (together with Ulrich Brand) we tried to grasp the process ofdestructing hegemonic relations and constructing counter-hegemonic relations withthe help of a so-called deconstructive perspective (Brand and Sekler <strong>2009</strong>).


postneoliberalism from and as a counter-hegemonic perspective 63construction’ (Borón 1999: 135), as constructed by many postneoliberalisms.Postneoliberalism(s) from a counter-hegemonic perspectiveIn the following I will expound in more detail and from the proposedcounter-hegemonic perspective on the two examples described at thebeginning of this article. Both piquetero organisations and the movementof recovered enterprises emerged in the mid-1990s in a neoliberal,Argentinean context which can be characterised by a highdegree of deindustrialisation due to deregulation and internationalcompetition, resulting high unemployment rates and state institutionsprivileging international credibility rather then measures of social redistribution,which in turn resulted in a striking shrinkage of themiddle class and an impoverishment of the masses (for a general discussionsee Sader and Gentili 1999, Svampa 2005). Nevertheless, thepostneoliberal experiences and practices of these two groups of actorsare very different because of the very specific ‘neoliberal’ contextsand experiences they address.The workers broke with the<strong>no</strong>rmality of hierarchicalworking relations, starting‘to think again’ and to organiseproduction themselves.Occupying and taking over production sites – at this time – was primarilya spontaneous direct action aiming at saving the workplaceand justified by fundamental breaches of labour laws by owners andmanagement (who were <strong>no</strong>t paying salaries or overtime). In most ofthe cases, initially, this was neither necessarily politically motivated<strong>no</strong>r fundamentally orientated against property or capitalist productionrelations. Instead the intention was simply to enforce the paymentof salaries, thereby defending decent working relations whereboth parties fulfil their responsibilities. At the point when they recognisedthat a negotiation with the (former) management was <strong>no</strong>tpossible any more they started to question aspects of the ‘<strong>no</strong>rmality’of working relations. Step by step and with the help of externals 5 theworkers broke with the <strong>no</strong>rmality of hierarchical working relations,starting ‘to think again’ (Zibechi 2006: 144) and to organise productionthemselves, thus demonstrating their own abilities (generally seeRebón 2007; Ruggieri 2007; Magnani 2003).Today almost 200 6 enterprises from different sectors can be subsumedunder the heading of recovered enterprises, all with different experi-5 Elaborated in Rebón 2007: 75ff.6 Figures vary e<strong>no</strong>rmously, depending on whether the self-organised enterprises, whichhave <strong>no</strong>t been directly taken over by the employees, are included or <strong>no</strong>t.


64 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateences in terms of take-over struggles, state policies, 7 resulting financialand legal situations, competition and market experiences, organisatio<strong>no</strong>f the working process, and so forth. Despite these different,individual experiences some general characteristics can be identified:all recovered enterprises are legally organised as cooperatives 8 – a formalcondition to start the process of expropriation; most of the workersreach fundamental decisions in plenum and have special delegatesfor special tasks, which are accountable to the plenum and can bevoted out at any time; and in most of the enterprises workers drawthe same salary, with additional payments for those undertaking specialtasks.In addition, one part of the recovered enterprises from the outsetformed part of a wider social context. These solidarity structureswere born out of the positive experiences of the take-over strugglesand the support received from the neighbourhood assemblies, andare still in place in most cases. In particular, recovered enterprisesprovide space – free of charge – for societal projects like culturalevents, popular education, exhibitions and evening school (for childrenand adults) and participate in neighbourhood activities (Rebón2007; Ruggeri 2005).One of the most urgent problems identified by recovered enterprisestoday is market competition in a continuing capitalist market. Oneway of coping with this challenge is broadening cooperative ties –politically and eco<strong>no</strong>mically. Besides the aim of showing the contributio<strong>no</strong>f the enterprises to the ‘national’ eco<strong>no</strong>my one of the goals ofthe exhibition, Empresas Recuperadas por los trabajadores, was to networkwith others. This was <strong>no</strong>t without tension: there was a huge discussionin the run-up to the exhibition about whether cooperating withthe government in this case ran the risk of being coopted by stateinstitutions, although most of the recovered enterprises have pragmaticrelations with state institutions, public funding bodies, 9 and soon. A<strong>no</strong>ther expression of the attempt to find new associates in orderto cope better with the requirements of the capitalist market isThe phe<strong>no</strong>me<strong>no</strong>n of empresasrecuperadas (or fabricasrecuperadas) encompasses awide range of quite differentbusiness facilities from allsectors of the eco<strong>no</strong>my.7 Provincial governments are responsible for legal and fi nancial aspects; this iselaborated in Magnani 2003: 88ff.8 Even Za<strong>no</strong>n, the most determined example of workers trying to obtain nationalisatio<strong>no</strong>f their factory, had to agree to form a cooperative in order to start the process ofexpropriation.9 It is diffi cult to refer to the question of fi nancing in general, because different factorsare crucial in each individual case: local governments, public funding, donations,private credits between already-established recovered enterprises (as aimed for inRosario).


postneoliberalism from and as a counter-hegemonic perspective 65the recently established FACTA (Federación Argentina de Cooperativasde Trabajadores Autogestionados – Argentinean Federation ofSelf-Managing Workers’ Cooperatives). 10 Besides campaigning for anational law of expropriation to replace individual and precarious solutionsthis federation aims to improve networks between recoveredenterprises and other self-organised companies.I will <strong>no</strong>w give a short overview of the second experience in order toreflect the counter-hegemonic postneoliberal content:Piquetero organisations also emerged in the mid-1990s in Argentinaout of a shared experience of being ‘out of work’ and socially disintegrated.At least from the outside, one of the most visible similaritiesbetween these organisations was their typical form of action – that ofusing road blocks (piquetes) – as a result of which they achieved statesubsidies in many cases. Despite these commonalities the backgroundof piquetero organisations differs considerably and – with referenceto their origin – can be divided into two strands. The first strand –chronically – emerged in 1996/97, out of the struggles against privatisatio<strong>no</strong>f the oil industry, and the consequent dismissals of formerlyprivileged workers with long-term stable and <strong>no</strong>rmal working relationsin the inner regions of Argentina (the states of Neuquén andCutral-Co). In contrast, the second strand, in the Bue<strong>no</strong>s Aires region,built on territorial organisational structures born of land strugglesof the 1980s. Here, workers have in common a long history ofunemployment – because of a former deindustrialisation process inthe 1970s – impoverishment, and thus continuing marginality. Later,other strands of piquetero organisation developed out of various existingterritorial and political structures (see, generally, Oviedo 2004,Svampa and Pereyra 2005).Thus, what is often described today as a serious fragmentation ofpiquetero organisations was caused only partly by the successful cooptatio<strong>no</strong>f relevant leaders of some of the piquetero organisations by thegovernment of Néstor Kirchner in 2003. Partly it is also the differencesin the ideological and political-strategic orientations, includingorganisational and decision-making structures of piquetero organisationsthat demonstrated a plurality from the outset.A small part of the second strand – sometimes characterised as ‘auto<strong>no</strong>mous’– had aspirations that went well beyond the goal of securingwage labour and integration into the ‘<strong>no</strong>rmal’ system. Start-10 www.facta.org.ar


66 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateing by questioning labour relations as hierarchical and alienated, statesubsidies are consequently used to establish alternative, co-operativeand self-organised forms of enterprises as well as basic supply withinthe neighbourhood. Besides obvious political interventions like usingpiquetes, political practice for them was also always their own processof re- and self-organisation. This was accompanied by fundamentalquestioning of social relations like the patriarchal division of labour,which aimed to change society and social structures from belowvia basic democracy and horizontal forms of organisation (see MTDSola<strong>no</strong> and Colectivo Situaciónes 2002) .As a consequence, moving back to local activities in the neighbourhoodsafter 2003/2004 does <strong>no</strong>t in this sense signify a ‘withdrawal’from politics, or even resignation, as some interpret it in the contextof the fragmentation argument. Rather, it was the ack<strong>no</strong>wledgementthat the fast growth of their organisations was preventing themfrom realising their own principals and that reconstructing social relationsneeded more time as well as a deepening of their own socialstructures and experiences. As the episode described at the beginningshows, this group of 8-10 people has, besides the concreteproject of constructing a health care centre, a<strong>no</strong>ther, more ‘radical’and long-standing project: reflecting and deconstructing gender relations.Moreover, other relations like family relations and responsibilitiesare questioned; for example, they care for and support autisticchildren collectively in a ‘working group’.What does it <strong>no</strong>w mean to consider these postneoliberal approachesfrom a counter-hegemonic perspective? Concerning their specificneoliberal context: what are the continuities and discontinuities inthe two illustrated approaches? What are the limitations of these postneoliberalismsor which kinds of relations remain unquestioned? Insort of a conclusion I will briefly sketch some of the relevant aspects.A considerable limitation of the postneoliberal approach of recoveredenterprises has often been seen in the fact that these enterprisesare largely integrated into the production and distribution chains ofcapitalist markets (Geiger 2006). Being in the midst of capitalism,exposed to the capitalists’ logic and market constraints, often leads –so the further argumentation goes – to self-exploitation rather than‘self’-determination vis-à-vis working conditions. This is certainlytrue. However, such a general view on recovered enterprises movementneglects, first, that there are attempts to escape the market logicat least partly by establishing forms of solidarity networks. In Rosario(Santa Fe), for example, the recovered enterprises joined forces in an


postneoliberalism from and as a counter-hegemonic perspective 67institutionalised round table where future projects are planned. Theseare: a foundation where new recovered enterprises can get credit undermore favourable conditions; an area specially reserved for recoveredenterprises within the newly planned industrial park in Rosario;a special study programme to be established at the University of Rosarioon the issue of solidary eco<strong>no</strong>my, special supermarkets wheremainly products from cooperatives hall be distributed; and so on.Second, the capitalist logic argument overlooks the fact that workingrelations – including former existing hierarchies, and with thesea certain kind of ‘<strong>no</strong>rmality’ –were questioned and reorganised. Thisis especially worth mentioning because – as Magnani shows in a detailedanalysis of everyday changes initiated by the process of takeover– even if workers of self-organised enterprises spend a lot of timeat the workplace, most of their further social relations and their surroundingsare (still) deeply shaped by a different, unchanged reality/<strong>no</strong>rmality. As shown by discussions about the rights of new membersof the cooperatives and the amount of salary they should receive, it isdifficult to broaden the newly adopted ‘<strong>no</strong>rmality’ and transfer it tothe outside. Solidarity and reorganisation of social relations seem tobe strongly linked to those who participated in the take-over struggles.Gender relations are mostly part of <strong>no</strong>rmality and are still onlyreflected in special circumstances. In addition, in a fairly comprehensivesurvey Rebón discovered that racist attitudes remained mainlyunquestioned by workers of recovered enterprises when nearly half ofthe interviewees indicated that foreign workers were responsible forthe bad working situation in Argentina (Rebón 2007: 85).Piquetero: from the wordpiquete, meaning ‘road block’.The example of the cited piquetero organisation shows that the membersquestion many facets of social relations and try to overcome hierarchiesand inequalities by consciously working on their everydaysocial practices and relations. As such, the way of questioning socialrelations in depth goes far beyond neoliberalism in a restricted sense.Besides the health care centre that the working group is buildingthere are other projects following the same ‘principles’, such as a communitygarden and working groups with young people. Thus, ‘goingback to one’s roots’ allows those participating in the activitiesto deepen their ‘emancipatory’ experiences. Restrictions can be observedon the one hand in the fact that this social transformation frombelow takes place in quite a limited space (socially and territorially),involving only a small number of people. However, and by means ofstate subsidies, the structural moments of state institutions and policiesare always present as a dependent variable. Drawing on the discussionsof how political social or territorial work is, they have evenstarted to ask themselves whether this is still working politically or


68 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debate<strong>no</strong>t. However, participation in new projects and new, issue-specificforms of networks outside the realm of piquetero organisations and beyondinternational reach are already under way.Postneoliberalism as ‘many <strong>no</strong>’s, many yeses’? 11Using the term postneoliberalism as a counter-hegemonic analyticalperspective allows us firstly to raise our awareness of the referencesystem of alternatives. Postneoliberal alternatives are <strong>no</strong>t detached fromtheir context. When negotiating alternative approaches actors haveto refer to their concrete experiences, which – assuming a neoliberalhegemony – are in one way or a<strong>no</strong>ther shaped by neoliberal characteristics.This is even true for alternative emancipatory approachesand practices that existed before neoliberalism’s road to success or forthose struggling from the outset against a neoliberalisation of theircontext. This means, even if one detaches oneself from certain aspectsof neoliberalism the reference system represents neoliberalism – in allits varieties and contradictory facets.Against this background postneoliberalism as a counter-hegemonicanalytical perspective constitutes a category in order to shed light on‘post’ elements and neoliberal ones. Secondly, this encourgages us tohave a closer look at the continuities – which aspects are <strong>no</strong>t questionedand thus reproduced – and the discontinuities – that is, thoseelements that the alternatives refer to and try to overcome. A postneoliberalanalytical perspective does <strong>no</strong>t limit alternatives to challenging‘typical’ neoliberal relations. Instead, and as the example ofthe ‘piquetero approach’ shows, some sort of crisis can be the startingpointfor questioning social relations much more deeply, more generally,going far beyond social relations shaped by neoliberalism.Thirdly, and as a consequence, postneoliberal approaches face a necessaryimperfection. Challenging former social relations and practicessignifies a process, in which – step by step – old elements have to bedisarticulated and new ones established. Accordingly, and as discussedabove, ‘postneoliberalism’ consists of many different postneoliberalisms– that is, multiplicity rather than unity characterises the term asproposed.11 Referring to Kings<strong>no</strong>rth’s ‘one <strong>no</strong>, many yeses’ (2004) and the idea of Louise Amoorethat the ‘<strong>no</strong>’ also has to be differentiated and problematised because ‘the certaintyand lack of contingency present in the claiming of an absolute “<strong>no</strong>” will necessarilyforeclose the possibility of multiple and contradictory “yeses”’ (2006: 258).


postneoliberalism from and as a counter-hegemonic perspective 69Out of these considerations I will briefly discuss the question ofwhether it would be worth promoting progressive debates under theheading of ‘postneoliberalism’. To my mind there are at least threereasons against using ‘postneoliberalism’ strategically and politically,from (what aspires to be) an emancipatory point of view.First, and most generally, there is the problem of a discursive and<strong>no</strong>n-emancipatory co-optation of the term postneoliberalism. As experiencedrecently, in times of serious crises of neoliberal financialpolicies, everybody is calling on the state power to take on its responsibilityand ‘domesticate’ neoliberalism. Beside the fact that only veryspecific parts and relations of neoliberalism are questioned, and thereregulation will in the end result in a neoliberalism with a human,sustainable, face, I would like to stress a<strong>no</strong>ther aspect. Through anappeal to the state and the corresponding political leaders the wholeproblem-solution ‘structure’ is cemented. Official politics and policiesare responsible for the crisis are and they have the power to changeit. In this discourse – even if assignments are radical – neither on theproblem <strong>no</strong>r on the solution side is the anchoring of neoliberal ideasin (everyday) relations, practices and consciousness taken into accountadequately.Secondly, using postneoliberalism politically and strategically runsthe risk that discussions always centre on the question of whethersomething can be considered as ‘post’ or <strong>no</strong>t. On the one hand thisrefers to a <strong>no</strong>rmative background on which a judgement is made as towhat is already good and revolutionary e<strong>no</strong>ugh to really oppose neoliberalismand what is still too much in the neoliberal logic, which– as the case of recovered factories shows– often implies a strong tendencyto simplification. On the other hand it always results in a focuson the differences of approaches and perceives those differences asshortcomings and weakness.Thirdly, promoting alternative approaches under the heading of postneoliberalismruns the risk of homogenisation – <strong>no</strong>w homogeneousneoliberalism, then (aspired-to) homogeneous postneoliberalims– which entails the <strong>no</strong>rmative assumption of (a possible) unity anduniversality. Discussions about fragmentations as in the case of thepiquetero phe<strong>no</strong>me<strong>no</strong>n as well as in the case of recovered enterprisesalways start with the conviction that first of all there was a commonstarting point and then – determined by ever-existing historical certaintiesabout how different political/strategic approaches develop –the fragmentation process will start.


70 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateIn contrast, and from the viewpoint of the proposed postneoliberalismas a counter-hegemonic perspective, a ‘realistic’ view would be toaccept from the beginning a plurality without having unity and unificationand also catch-all approaches as the underlying assumption.Drawing on Kingsworth and Amoore I will try to grasp this pluralitywith the slogan of ‘many <strong>no</strong>, many yeses’. Even if there seemsto be a common <strong>no</strong> – as, for instance, the common saying ‘Que sevayan todos’ (‘They all must go’) in Argentina 2001/2002 suggested– this <strong>no</strong> could represent a reference to different impacts of neoliberalism,to different ‘neoliberalised’ social contexts and ‘<strong>no</strong>rmalities’and the starting point for varying postneoliberal approaches. Lookingthrough postneoliberal lenses raises our awareness of continuities anddiscontinuities with respect to the existing social context of challengedand unquestioned ‘<strong>no</strong>rmalities’ in the many postneoliberalismsunder construction.Even if there seems to be a common <strong>no</strong> – as, for instance, the common saying ‘Que se vayan todos’ (‘They all must go’) inArgentina 2001/2002 suggested – this <strong>no</strong> could represent a reference to different impacts of neoliberalism, to different‘neoliberalised’ social contexts and ‘<strong>no</strong>rmalities’ and the starting point for varying postneoliberal approaches.


postneoliberalism from and as a counter-hegemonic perspective 71SourcesAdolphs, Stephan and Karakayali, Serhat (2007), ‘DieAktivierung der Subalternen. Gegenhegemonie undpassive Revolution’, in Buckel, Sonja and Fischer-Lesca<strong>no</strong>, Andreas (eds.), Hegemonie gepanzertmit Zwang. Zivilgesellschaft und Politik imStaatsverständnis Antonio Gramscis, Baden-Baden:Nomos, pp. 121-140.Amoore, Louise (2006), ‘“There is No Great Refusal“:The Ambivalent Politics of Resistance’, in de Goede,Marieke (eds), International Political Eco<strong>no</strong>my andPoststructural Politics, New York: Palgrave, pp. 255-274.Borón, Atilio (1999), ‘El pos-neoliberalismo: unproyecto en construcción’, in Sader, Emir andGentili, Pablo (eds), La trama del neoliberalismo,Bue<strong>no</strong>s Aires: Eudeba, pp. 135-142.Brand, Ulrich and Sekler, Nicola (<strong>2009</strong>,forthcoming), ‘Struggling between Auto<strong>no</strong>my andInstitutional Transformations. Social Movementsin Latin America and the Move towards Post-Neoliberalism’, in Macdonald, Laura and Ruckert,Arne (eds), Post-Neoliberalism in the Americas, NewYork: Palgrave.Geiger, Margot (2006), ‘Betriebsbesetzungen inArgentinien’, in Altvater, Elmar and Sekler, Nicola(eds), Solidarische Öko<strong>no</strong>mie, Hamburg: VSA, pp.92-111.Gramsci, Antonio (1991ff.), Gefängnishefte – KritischeGesamtausgabe (Prison Notebooks) , editedby Bochmann, Klaus and Haug, Wolfgang-Fritz,Hamburg/Berlin: Argument-Verlag (cited as Gef,number of volume).Kings<strong>no</strong>rth, Paul (2004), One No, Many Yeses:A Journey to the Heart of the Global ResistanceMovement, London: Simon and Schuster.Magnani, Esteban (2003), El cambio silencioso.Empresas y fábricas recuperadas por lostrabajadores en la Argentina, Bue<strong>no</strong>s Aires:prometeo.MTD Sola<strong>no</strong> and Colectivo Situaciónes (2002), LaHipótesis 891 – Más allá de los piquetes, Bue<strong>no</strong>sAires: De ma<strong>no</strong> a ma<strong>no</strong>.Oviedo, Luis (2004), Una historia del movimientopiquetero. De las primeras Coordinadoras alArgentinazo, Bue<strong>no</strong>s Aires: Ediciones Rumbos.Rebón, Julián (2007), La empresa de la auto<strong>no</strong>mía.Trabajadores recuperando la producción, Bue<strong>no</strong>sAires: Ediciones Picaso.Ruggieri, Andrés (2007), ‘Las empresasrecuperadas en la Argentina: desafi os politicos ysocioeconómicos de la autogestión’. http://www.recuperadasdoc.com.ar/encuentro/ponencias/recuruggeri.pdfSader, Emir and Gentili, Pablo (eds) (1999), La tramadel neoliberalismo. Mercado, crisis y exclusiónsocial, Bue<strong>no</strong>s Aires: Eudeba.Svampa, Maristella (2005), La sociedad excluyente.La Argentina bajo el sig<strong>no</strong> neoliberalismo, Bue<strong>no</strong>sAires: Taurus.Svampa, Maristella and Sebastián Pereyra (2004),Entre la ruta y el barrio. La experiencia de lasorganizaciones piqueteras, Bue<strong>no</strong>s Aires: EditorialBiblos (second edition).Wolff, Jonas (2007), ‘(De-)Mobilising theMarginalised: A Comparison of the ArgentinePiqueteros and Ecuador’s Indige<strong>no</strong>us Movement’,Journal of Latin American Studies, <strong>no</strong>. 39, pp. 1-29.Zibechi, Raúl (2006), ‘La emancipación comoproducción de vínculos’, in Ceceña, Ana Esther(Hrsg.), Los desafíos de las emancipaciones enun contexto militarizado, Bue<strong>no</strong>s Aires: ConsejoLati<strong>no</strong>america<strong>no</strong> de Ciencias Sociales, pp. 123-149.


72 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debate


Postneoliberalism or postcapitalism?The failure of neoliberalism in thefinancial market crisisElmar AltvaterThe rise of neoliberalism that began in the 1970s was first and foremosta consequence of deep, even ‘revolutionary’ changes in the worldeco<strong>no</strong>my. The ‘revolution’, however was a ‘passive’ one, ‘transformism’in the sense of Antonio Gramsci’s term: it strengthened capitalisthegemony by means of an all-encompassing transformation of thesocial, political and eco<strong>no</strong>mic system from ‘above’ – that is, steeredby the dominant social and political forces. Market liberalisation wasaccompanied by a far-reaching deregulation of politics. Milton Friedmancalled it a ‘neoliberal counterrevolution’ against Keynesianism.It was a success and started its triumphal march around the world. Inthe 1970s the ‘Keynesian environment’ of the era after World War IIliterally broke into pieces and the new ‘neoliberal’ epoch took off.It began with the end of the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchangerates in March 1973 and the following liberalisation of financial marketsin Margaret Thatcher’s Great Britain. The formation of crucialprices in the world eco<strong>no</strong>my, such as exchange rates and interest rates,were <strong>no</strong> longer based on official decisions and the state with its democraticlegitimation. Instead, the decisions on exchange and interestrates were up to private actors – that is, multinational banks, speculativeinvestment and other funds, and transnational corporations.Thus, the first acts of privatisation concerned the manner by whichprices on global financial markets have been formed. This triggereda wave of wild privatisation of public goods and services which sweptover the entire world. The new private actors immediately used theirnew freedom to create financial in<strong>no</strong>vations: new institutions andnew instruments to increase the returns on financial investments.Countries with still regulated markets were induced or forced to giveup their techniques of what neoliberals called ‘financial repression’:exchange controls, fixed interest rates, credit control, prescribed assets,and so forth. Since then, financial markets have exerted theirown repression of the real eco<strong>no</strong>my, of social systems and of the naturalenvironment.


74 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateThe liberalisation, deregulation and privatisation mania of neoliberalismtriggered radical repercussions in the relationship betweenthe countries of the Global North and the Global South. Liberalisedfinancial markets, above all Wall Street, supported by the BrettonWoods institutions and the US government, helped to recycle socalled‘petrodollars’ after the oil-price shock of 1973 from the MiddleEast back into oil-importing Third World countries. They wereenabled to accumulate vast debts over the course of a few years whenreal interest rates were low (even negative) prior to 1979. They slidinto the debt crisis of the 1980s after the US Federal Reserve tripledinterest rates (the so-called ‘Volcker shock’ – that is, the politics ofhigh interests to attract capital to the US), leading to what was laterdescribed as the ‘lost decade’ for the developing world.The other side of the coin was a strengthening of the US dollar: firstof all, because oil producers sold oil for US dollars despite the obviouseco<strong>no</strong>mic weakness of the dollar vis-à-vis other competing, strongcurrencies. Secondly, the recycling of petrodollars and then the debtservicinghave been managed by the US financial system which occupiedthe strategic heights of global finance. This was of utmost importancefor restructuring US hegemony after the debacle in Vietnamand for restoring its eco<strong>no</strong>mic and political hegemony in the moreand more globalised world. Globalisation is mostly understood as aprocess of spatial expansion, of world trade, investment and migrationflows. This is <strong>no</strong>t wrong; however, it is quite a onesided perspectivebecause globalisation also means the globalisation of a certain developmentmodel, of political concepts and standards of global governance,of rules, <strong>no</strong>rms and a global language. Therefore, the ‘Washingtonconsensus’, the financial policy package that indebted countrieshad to accept under the conditionality of the International MonetaryFund has been one of the most efficient globalising forces after theliberalisation of global financial markets.Globalisation is mostlyunderstood as a processof spatial expansion, ofworld trade, investment andmigration fl ows. This is <strong>no</strong>twrong; however, it is quite aonesided perspective becauseglobalisation also means theglobalisation of a certaindevelopment model, of politicalconcepts and standards ofglobal governance, of rules,<strong>no</strong>rms and a global language.Monetarism emerged as the hegemonic eco<strong>no</strong>mic policy concept ofthe neoliberal counter-revolution. The monetary base provided bythe ‘independent’ central bank should react to market conditions and<strong>no</strong>t be used as a political tool of governmental institutions to realiseother objectives than that of monetary stability. Policies of full employmenthave been most frowned on by neoliberals. Consequently,the independence of the central bank is understood as an insulationagainst democratic political institutions and civil society organisations,in order to be free to formulate monetary policy according tothe necessities of globalised financial markets. The rule of independencewas inscribed into the statute of the European Central Bankat the end of 1990s. The independent central bank must control the


postneoliberalism or postcapitalism? the failure of neoliberalism in the financial market crisis 75amount of money circulating and <strong>no</strong>thing else. Fiscal policy in thelong run has <strong>no</strong> influence on the growth rate of the eco<strong>no</strong>my and onemployment and should therefore follow the rules of monetary stabilityand <strong>no</strong>t the policy target of full employment.The result of policy programmes based on these rules is by <strong>no</strong> meansconvincing: a rise in unemployment since neoliberalism has been theideological basis of eco<strong>no</strong>mic policy concepts in nearly all countries– and, if this did <strong>no</strong>t happen, it was due to the expansion of the informaleco<strong>no</strong>my, of precarious labour; distribution of income andwealth became more unequal in most countries and in the world as awhole; the number of millionaires increased as well as the number ofpoor peoples; the future expectations of the working classes are direunder neoliberal capitalism; many eco<strong>no</strong>mies are in crisis, and the effectson social systems, political stability and the natural environmentare extremely negative. The balance of the neoliberal epoch is disastrousfor the majority of people; temporarily it was a golden age forfinancial asset owners, but it was bad for labour.The neoliberal era lasted until August 2008 when the liberalised systemof global financial markets imploded, causing huge losses of morethan us$ 1.4 trillion, as the IMF complained at the beginning of October2008; however, these losses had in the meantime considerablyincreased. In the last days of neoliberalism even the most hard-<strong>no</strong>sedneoliberals, managers of big banks as well as representatives of the Bushadministration were urgently asking for state help and even for a nationalisatio<strong>no</strong>f big private banks in order to avoid the final meltdow<strong>no</strong>f the whole capitalist system. After fewer than four decades the neoliberalcycle seems to be over. However, this only means that capitalism aswe k<strong>no</strong>w it has reached an end, <strong>no</strong>t the capitalist system in general.The hierarchy of disembedded markets– linkage between fi nancial and real marketsIf Karl Polanyi’s concept of ‘disembedded markets’ is meaningful atall, then it is with regard to financial markets. Markets have been disembeddedfrom society and nature since the West’s ‘great transformation’into a market eco<strong>no</strong>my in the 18th and 19th centuries. Financialmarkets have moreover been disembedded from markets for realgoods, services and labour: the monetary eco<strong>no</strong>my is ‘auto<strong>no</strong>mised’(‘verselbständigt’) vis-à-vis the real eco<strong>no</strong>my. Financial markets areself-referential; they follow their own logic of development. As a consequenceof the all-embracing liberalisation of markets in general andparticularly of finance since the end of the Bretton Woods regime in


76 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatethe 1970s the relations between social reproduction and the accumulationdynamics of the real eco<strong>no</strong>my on the one side and the workingof financial markets on the other have been widely dissolved.Neoliberalism was the theoretical background of liberalised and selfreferentialfinancial markets. The necessity of disembedding financialmarkets was justified by the concept of market equilibrium and potentialefficiency gains. In the neoliberal understanding, an equilibriumis possible in each individual market so long as decision makersare free to follow market signals. There are <strong>no</strong> interrelations andinterferences between markets. Unemployment above the level thatNAIRU (the ‘<strong>no</strong>n-accelerating infl ation rate of unemployment’) permitsis interpreted as the result of inefficient allocation of labour andof eco<strong>no</strong>mically unjustified wage levels. The dogma of auto<strong>no</strong>mousmarkets is an explicit argument against the Keynesian (and also theMarxist) theory of a hierarchy of markets and their connectedness:labour markets depend on the investment decisions of capital ownerson commodity markets. The investment decisions in their turndepend on future expectations concerning prices of products – thatis, on the performance of product markets, as well as on the developmentof interest rates – that is, on financial markets. The prices on thelatter determine prices (the wage level) and volumes (employment) onthe labour market. Consequently, in Keynesian as well as in Marxistapproaches an equilibrium in labour markets depends on the performanceof financial markets.However, the implied auto<strong>no</strong>my and self-reliance of financial marketsis by <strong>no</strong> means a guarantee against financial crisis tendencies. On theone side, crises have their origins in the ‘real eco<strong>no</strong>my’ in the case thatreal flows of income are <strong>no</strong>t sufficient to service the claims of financialinvestors. On the other side the crisis tendencies spill over from financeto the real eco<strong>no</strong>my and to society and nature, as the recent crises atthe end of the first decade of the 21st century have demonstrated sodramatically. The concept of ‘disembedded markets’ therefore does <strong>no</strong>tmean that they are really auto<strong>no</strong>mous and independent of each other.On the contrary, markets are highly interrelated and interdependent.Keynes and Marx are right, and neoliberalism is wrong.Contrary to some neoliberal simplifications the interest rates and ratesof return on financial investments have to be produced in the real eco<strong>no</strong>my.A virtual eco<strong>no</strong>my without a real basis is a nice but stupid idea. If<strong>no</strong>t, high yields on financial assets of 20 per cent and more can<strong>no</strong>t bepaid in real terms; the financial pressures on the real eco<strong>no</strong>my producean inflationary bubble: asset inflation rather than price inflation. Whenprices of products and services are stable or even declining, and simul-


postneoliberalism or postcapitalism? the failure of neoliberalism in the financial market crisis 77taneously asset prices soaring, a radical distribution of real flows of incomesin favour of the financial sector is going on. This tendency, then,is responsible for new speculative attacks on the real eco<strong>no</strong>my becauseof the high liquidity of financial investors (funds and banks). They tryto reap as much as possible of the surplus produced in the real eco<strong>no</strong>my;and by doing so they are pushing it into a crisis. This mechanism, basically,is driving the most recent financial crisis.When prices of productsand services are stableor even declining, andsimultaneously asset pricessoaring, a radical distributio<strong>no</strong>f real fl ows of incomes infavour of the fi nancial sectoris going on. This tendency,then, is responsible for newspeculative attacks on the realeco<strong>no</strong>my because of the highliquidity of fi nancial investors.Karl Polanyi described disembedded markets in general as ‘satanicmills’, pushing labour into misery, nature into environmental destruction,and the monetary system into a bad running order. Disembeddedfinancial markets work even more than product and labourmarkets as satanic mills, because their horizon is <strong>no</strong>t the nationaleco<strong>no</strong>my with its institutional settings and social and political regulationsbut the unfettered world market – that is, the poorly regulatedeco<strong>no</strong>my on a global scale. In terms of time they are characterised byan endemic ‘myopia’. Financial actors only have a very short-term horizon.The higher the interest rate and the financial yield, the shorterthe perspective of actors within the financial markets. Therefore the‘counter-movements’, a<strong>no</strong>ther crucial concept introduced by Polanyi– against the destructive functioning of the satanic mill so as to protectlabour (through the emergence/defence of the welfare state), nature(through environmental regulations) and money (through measuresto control monetary and financial authorities such as central banks,national and international supervisory authorities and so forth) – alsohave to develop a global and long-term perspectiveVery often, the tendency of market-disembedding is described as a ‘mechanism’;however, neither the processes of disembedding <strong>no</strong>r the countertendenciesfor protection against the effects of disembedding work likemechanisms. They are the outcome of hegemonic confl icts and strugglesin the political sphere (the state in a wide sense) and the social system(performed by social movements and political organisations).Financial crises shake the neoliberal belief systemGlobal crisis tendencies during the last quarter of the 20th centuryregularly appeared as crises of the financial sector: the best-k<strong>no</strong>wnhallmarks of the crisis cycle after the liberalisation of financial marketsin the 1970s are the debt crisis of the Third World in the 1980s,then the financial and banking crisis of the 1990s (the Peso crisis of1994 and the devastating Asian crisis in 1997 with repercussions inRussia in 1998, and Turkey and Brazil in 1999), the Argentinean crisisof 2001, which affected all aspects of eco<strong>no</strong>mic and social life in thecountry, leaving much of its industry in ashes, the bursting of the new


78 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateeco<strong>no</strong>my bubble in the US in 2000, and finally the ‘subprime crisis’ inthe US in 2007 and the metastases that followed in many other marketsegments (credit cards, investment banks, insurance, credit defaultswaps and so forth.) and countries of the world. The end is (in autumn2008) is <strong>no</strong>t foreseeable. The last decades of the 20th and the first decadesof the 21st century will enter history as the era of the neoliberalfinancial disaster.At all events, neoliberal promises of growth and stability, of employmentand wealth have proved to be insincere ideology, grossly falseand responsible for the sufferings of hundreds of millions of peoplearound the world. No wonder that neoliberal ideology has lost muchof its former attractiveness and thus much of its hegemonic power.The neoliberal crisis tendencies together with the loss of hegemonicattractiveness are the soil in which new eco<strong>no</strong>mic policy concepts beyondneoliberalism are beginning to grow.In view of the financial disaster of 2008 and the series of recent financialcrises since the ‘big-bang’ liberalisation of financial markets atthe end of the 1970s it seems as if neoliberals themselves have changedtheir mind, the neoliberal belief system is breaking into pieces. Firstof all, one of the lessons learnt was that financial stability can only beachieved by means of political regulation and <strong>no</strong>t by the working ofthe market mechanism or by deploying the mechanisms of self-regulatio<strong>no</strong>f the financial industry. This was why, after the Asian crisis,the Financial Stability Forum (FSF) was established in 1998. Immediatelyafter having being set up it began to elaborate on rules ofimproved transparency, prudence, surveillance – <strong>no</strong>t least in order toavoid more radical proposals by global civil society movements suchas ATTAC 1 to control the capital account and even to outlaw certainfinancial activities (those of offshore financial centres, hedge- andprivate equity funds, short-term speculation, and so forth.). It was <strong>no</strong>accident that ATTAC was founded in the same year in which the FSFwas set up – the one as a civil society response to the financial disasterthat was affecting so many millions of people, the other as an officialresponse in order to re-establish financial stability for financial actorsagainst the recent market turbulences.In the subprime crisis alone 5million homeowners in the USlost their houses.The extent of the contemporary crisis, however, goes much beyond theharmless reform proposals of the FSF and other bodies after the financialcrises of developing and newly industrialising countries. In contrastto the latter the present-day crisis hit the metropolitan countries of theworld system and therefore neoliberals discovered anew the state as an1 Association pour la taxation des transactions pour l’aide aux citoyens (Association forthe Taxation of Financial Transactions for the Aid of Citizens).


postneoliberalism or postcapitalism? the failure of neoliberalism in the financial market crisis 79important and indispensable institution of eco<strong>no</strong>mic (fiscal and monetary)stabilisation, as a market actor of last resort. Even the most neoliberalgovernments like that of the UK and of the US did <strong>no</strong>t hesitate tonationalise banks because of obvious market failures, the obvious shortcomingsof neoliberal eco<strong>no</strong>mic policy concepts (in the fields of fiscaland monetary policy) and the systemic risk that threatened the wholecapitalist eco<strong>no</strong>my. This is the reason why even <strong>no</strong>torious neoliberalsare joining the herd that is requesting less market self-regulation andmore state intervention. Masses of peoples are affected by the recent financialcrises. To mention only a few of the destructive consequencesof financial crises: in the subprime crisis alone 5 million homeowners inthe US lost their houses – swelling the army of homeless peoples; tensof million peoples suffered under the crisis in Asia, many of them beingpushed into dire poverty or even into abject misery; the debt crisis ofthe Third World in the 1980s can<strong>no</strong>t be forgotten, for it was responsiblefor a ‘lost decade’ of development in Latin America and elsewhere. As aresult popular resistance built up in many parts of the world, forming agrowing alliance against neoliberal ideology and the subsequent policyconcepts that were based on it. Today, however, neoliberals themselvesare abandonning their untenable positions and trying to find refugein the camp of their despised adversaries: those calling for less marketand more regulation. Although they might prefer self-regulation bythe banking industry itself and <strong>no</strong>t by the state, they are <strong>no</strong>t hesitatingto ‘bring the state back in’, in an even more radical way than in Keynesiantimes. They are transforming the crisis-ridden neoliberal capitalismbased on financial markets into a kind of a ‘financial socialism’(Richard Sennett in The Financial Times, 8 October 2008).This is a step beyond the neoliberal mind-map; but is this tendencyalready the first sign of the emergence of a postneoliberal order ofglobal finance?The software and hardware of neoliberal fi nancial marketsIn order to answer this question it is necessary to take the physicalpreconditions of neoliberal finance into account. While the profitrate on capital in the real eco<strong>no</strong>my underlies a tendency to decline,the rates of return on financial assets soar – at least for a certain periodof time. Financial in<strong>no</strong>vations and the creation of ever-new vehiclesof financial investment pushed the yields of the financial sectors abovethe profits to be obtained in other industries. Since the liberalisatio<strong>no</strong>f financial markets statistical evidence in most OECD countries hasshown interest rates much above the real growth rate of GNP. Thisrelation is even more articulated in developing and newly industrialisingcountries because of higher risks and thus high spreads (higher


80 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debaterisk charges) on the prime rate. Since financial claims in the last instancehave to be serviced out of real flows of income a redistributio<strong>no</strong>f incomes and of wealth from the real to the financial eco<strong>no</strong>my isan inevitable outcome. Financial liberalisation and the subsequent financialin<strong>no</strong>vations work as a mechanism of increasing the yields offinancial assets and of repression of the real eco<strong>no</strong>my.This constellation is inevitably crisis-prone. Extremely high yields onfinancial claims require high real growth rates. But growth meets social,natural and even eco<strong>no</strong>mic limits. Growth is an obsession whichonly can be transformed into reality by an acceleration of the processof production and reproduction and by extending its spatial reach –that is, by creating a typically capitalist time-space regime. It requiresand fosters at the same time high speed, high mobility and massiveuse of resources (mass production and mass consumption). It thus alsoexerts massively negative effects on the environment and on sociallife, which follow other rhythms than those imposed by the neoliberaltime-space regime.Neoliberalism’s disdain of nature and society is a consequence of theconcept of the world as populated by men (and women) who are simplyfollowing the utilitarian rationality of profit maximisation andthus acting as homines oeco<strong>no</strong>mici. These rational constructs operatein a spaceless and timeless world, thus lacking the coordinates of nature.The ‘annihilation of time by space and of space by time’, whichMarx mentions in the ‘Grundrisse’ is inscribed into the neoliberalbelief system. It takes <strong>no</strong> <strong>no</strong>tice of the specific characteristics of timeand history, of space and territories. Only because of this reduction isit possible to develop and then apply an eco<strong>no</strong>mic policy menu likethat of the ‘Washington Consensus’: an eco<strong>no</strong>mic policy recipe for allGrowth meets social, naturaland even eco<strong>no</strong>mic limits.Growth is an obsession whichonly can be transformed intoreality by an acceleration ofthe process of productionand reproduction and byextending its spatial reach.


postneoliberalism or postcapitalism? the failure of neoliberalism in the financial market crisis 81countries in all times which only have one characteristic in common– that they are highly indebted and that they therefore have to followthe rules of global financial markets and their regulating institutions(in the first place the IMF).The system can only obey the rules of physical expansion and acceleration– that is, transforming the annihilation of time and spaceinto reality – insofar as it has a specific ‘hardware’ at its disposal. Thishardware consists first of all of fossil energy sources, especially oil, andthe (industrial) technical and organisational (social) systems of theirtransformation into working energy. Oil has fuelled growth since thebeginning of the 20th century and thus turned an apparent obsessioninto a real political concept for the eco<strong>no</strong>my over a long period oftime. Eco<strong>no</strong>mic growth since then has been the mania of eco<strong>no</strong>mists,even of so-called alternative, <strong>no</strong>n-neoliberal eco<strong>no</strong>mists. They do <strong>no</strong>ttake into consideration that growth of the real eco<strong>no</strong>my and even theworking of the ‘virtual’ financial sphere are dependent on the secureprovision of fossil fuel for production and consumption, for transportand communication, and most of them are blind to the contradictionbetween growth as a geometrically extensive process and itsfuels which are a finite resource, and to the fact that its supply curveis <strong>no</strong>t going up, but down. Oil is running out, the ‘hardware’ of theneoliberal system is fl awed. The production of oil is peaking so thatin the foreseeable future it will be less available than today, if availableat all, and at increasing prices. The limits of oil supply turn outto become a physical hindrance to further growth and consequentlyto the high yields on financial assets. The financial sector in the lastneoliberal decades has learned to claim the yields. Now, it must learnto change the programme of the ‘driver software’. The neoliberalbonanza is over, the comfortable times of plentiful oil are gone. Thegrowth rates of the past can<strong>no</strong>t be achieved in the future unless a newparadigm of production, a<strong>no</strong>ther time-space regime, emerges.Financial markets are providing the driver software of this time-spaceregime of acceleration and expansion: time is money, the shorter thecycles of financial investment the faster the returns and the higher therevenues to obtain. The software is permanently improved by makinguse of financial in<strong>no</strong>vations with the overarching objective to increasethe financial yields. The software is ruthlessly applied and veryoften predatory and fraudulent. The drivers are designed to exploit allpossible spaces for making money even when law and moral rules areobstacles to such an endeavour. In these cases rules and laws have tobe broken. The liberalisation of financial markets opened the door tothe criminal eco<strong>no</strong>my; it was a method of issuing the licence to ‘print’money. No wonder that even ‘reputable’ financial institutions and big


82 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatetransnational corporations are involved in money laundering, grandcorruption, illegal transfers, assistance to tax evasion, risky speculation,and so forth.. It is said that financial institutions are prudent andtherefore avoid risks (risk aversion). But when the driver software allowsfor hiding the risks and selling risky assets as secure ones thespeculation bubble can get ever bigger – until it bursts. This is exactlywhat happened in the most recent financial crisis, since 2007. This isan important reason why even official institutions of the global financialsystem triggered a debate on new regulations of financial markets– that is, on a new software of the time-space regime. The criteria forthe quality of the driver software are disputed. The speculators wantit to be as loose as possible, perhaps with some safeguards against acrash and with huge amounts of public money at their disposal, if possiblewithout public control. Some political regulators are arguing infavour of control; social movements are even asking for full nationalisatio<strong>no</strong>f the financial system and for submitting it to democraticcontrol in a democratic society. They also want the prohibition ofcertain financial vehicles, of highly speculative institutions and businesses,and they pose the question whether it is e<strong>no</strong>ugh to exchangethe software without also changing the hardware – that is, the energyregime and the mode of production, the social formation.The resilient real eco<strong>no</strong>myMany observers have thought that the real eco<strong>no</strong>my is <strong>no</strong>t affected bythe crises of disembedded financial markets. However, capital followsa cyclical movement: Financial capital buys and invests in productivecapital. Real means of production and labour together produce commoditiesto be sold on the market for money, so that at the end of thecycle capital appears as a financial stock (increased by a surplus) whichagain can be invested into real means of production and labour – orThe accumulation cycle ofcapital encompasses the ‘real’and the ‘fi nancial’ eco<strong>no</strong>my;they are aggregates of theactually existing capitalistsystem and thus linked to thereal world.


postneoliberalism or postcapitalism? the failure of neoliberalism in the financial market crisis 83it can be used for speculation and investments in financial assets onfinancial markets. The accumulation cycle of capital thus encompassesthe ‘real’ and the ‘financial’ eco<strong>no</strong>my; they are aggregates of theactually existing capitalist system and thus linked to the real world.Consequently, the financial crisis is also an expression of the contradictionsof the real accumulation process as it has repercussions onthe real world. Here it is necessary also to take into account time lagsbetween fast-reacting financial flows and the inertia of the real eco<strong>no</strong>my.The consequences of financial turmoil for the real eco<strong>no</strong>my areextremely bitter, as the history of the debt crisis of the 1980s, of thefinancial crises of the 1990s and of the ‘subprime crisis’ and its aftereffectsshow: debtors can<strong>no</strong>t afford to service the debts, and thus theirsecurities – the ‘collateral’ of the debts – is taken away. In the caseof the current financial crisis this means that workers are losing <strong>no</strong>tonly their jobs but also their houses. Moreover, they are cut off fromaccess to new mortgage credits so that their real disposable income isbecoming dramatically reduced. This might be interpreted as a ‘<strong>no</strong>rmalisation’.The question, however, is why this <strong>no</strong>rmalisation has <strong>no</strong>tbeen realised without pushing many people into eco<strong>no</strong>mic distress.‘Contagion’ also has to be taken into account. This should <strong>no</strong>t onlybe understood as the spread of financial crises over national boundaries,as in the case of the Asian crisis which spilled over from Thailandto its South-East Asian and East Asian neighbours. Financial crisesalso have a serious impact on labour markets – that is, on the quantityand quality of employment, on the environment, and on the provisio<strong>no</strong>f food. Financial crises have been the most effective vehiclesfor transforming formal labour into informal labour and thus infl atingthe informal eco<strong>no</strong>my of precarious work. In some structuralistinterpretations the informal eco<strong>no</strong>my is <strong>no</strong>t understood as a consequenceof financial distress, but as a remedy against the most negativeconsequences of the crisis. In many parts of the world the informaleco<strong>no</strong>my is the only sector offering precarious jobs to otherwise unemployedpeoples. This is the reason why the informal sector and itsaccompanying ideology of self-help and individual responsibility paradoxicallyare presented as a solution to the crisis of neoliberalism, asa ‘neoliberalism from below’. It reconstructs the legitimacy of the systemby organising popular consent from below. It is a telling exampleof the collusions of the neoliberal governments (from above) and thementality from below – that is, the internalisation of neoliberal conditionsinto the thinking and action of people.The spillover of financial crises on nature are also serious. As we havealready seen, the fossil resources essential for fuelling the neoliberal


84 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateorder are running out, <strong>no</strong>t to speak about the harm done to the environmentby actions which follow only the individual logic of selfishmarket actors. But neoliberalism would <strong>no</strong>t be as successful as ithas been if it did <strong>no</strong>t offer an answer to the ecological challenge. ForF.A. von Hayek markets are a powerful device for discovering newand in<strong>no</strong>vative solutions to problems arising in the course of eco<strong>no</strong>micand social development. Therefore the creation of a marketfor tradable CO 2 emissions rights is viewed as an adequate means ofovercoming the climate crisis. At the same time the new certificatesoffer new areas of profitable financial investments. After the recentcrash of financial markets this is good news for financial investorssearching for new areas of profitable investment. The market is consideredto be very dynamic and able to create a future tur<strong>no</strong>ver (afterthe extension of the Kyoto treaty to the whole world) of up to us$2000 billion. The food crisis as well as the price hike of commoditiesalso offer new opportunities for financial speculation. These developmentsmay stabilise the neoliberal financial system for a while, untilthe bubble bursts again.This time the real world of the daily life of people all around theworld, and <strong>no</strong>t just the ‘real eco<strong>no</strong>my’, is involved and affected by thecrisis. Neoliberal finance more and more is undermining the livingconditions of mankind.Postneoliberalism versus postcapitalismThe inherent tendency of disembedding markets from society andnature has halted. It is necessary to rethink the relationship of financeto the real eco<strong>no</strong>my on a global scale. The scale matters and the taskrequires regulatory measures which go beyond traditional (nationstate)Keynesianism, although, paradoxically, national solutions in toovercome the financial turmoil are being offered, <strong>no</strong>t European oreven global ones. The nation state has come back in, market solutionsto the deep crisis are <strong>no</strong>t in the policy basket. Regulation on a globalscale – how is it possible? The question can only be answered by posinga<strong>no</strong>ther question: is the recent crisis a crisis of neoliberalism or isit a crisis of neoliberal capitalism? Is a postneoliberal financial systempossible under capitalism or is it necessary to go beyond capitalism aswe k<strong>no</strong>w it? Is a financial socialism already emerging and could it bean answer to the challenges of the crisis?Financial socialism is <strong>no</strong>t thesocialism of the workers or ofbroad popular masses. It is theexpression of the expectationsof managers of banks andfunds which are threatenedwith drowning in the whirlpoolof the fi nancial crisis.The crisis of neoliberal concepts is <strong>no</strong>t necessarily resulting in a postneoliberalorder which aims at social forms beyond capitalism. Onthe contrary, postneoliberalism in finance can result in new forms of


postneoliberalism or postcapitalism? the failure of neoliberalism in the financial market crisis 85capitalist hegemony which again include a stronger role for the state.Contrary to ‘old Keynesian’ state interventionism, this is <strong>no</strong>t designedin the interests of workers’, but in undisguised political support of financialinterests. Financial socialism is <strong>no</strong>t the socialism of the workersor of broad popular masses. It is the expression of the expectationsof managers of banks and funds which are threatened with drowningin the whirlpool of the financial crisis. They need the legitimatepower of the state to tap into the incomes of taxpayers in order todivert income flows from the real eco<strong>no</strong>my to the financial sector.Otherwise many other claims and thus assets would lose their value.In following the project of diverting income flows to the financialsector they are seeking and finding support from governments andcentral banks. Trust in the working of free markets has gone. Manyneoliberals are asking for the nationalisation of bankrupt or defaultingfinancial institutions: Fanny Mae and Freddy Mac, AIG (AmericanInternational Group) and other institutions in the US, Alitalia inItaly, Northern Rock in Great Britain, IKB (Deutsche Industriebank)and Hypo-RealEstate in Germany, the whole banking system in Icelandand many more. Not self-regulation of the market, but state actionis required – and a lot of money must be spent out of the statebudget. This is set to increase the tax burden of citizens, the publicdebt, and may also increase the infl ation rate and thus reduce the purchasingpower of citizens in order to save the financial institutions.It is necessary, therefore, to ask for more state control over financialinstitutions. The financial institutions survive eco<strong>no</strong>mically by givingup some of the most predatory and excessive neoliberal practices.Postneoliberalism in financial markets is <strong>no</strong>thing less than a bundle ofmethods to save capitalist finance from the overshooting irrationalityof financial neoliberalism. It might be postneoliberal, but it is <strong>no</strong>t inthe same instance a postcapitalist order.The neoliberal ‘counterrevolution’ was, as we have seen, a Gramscianpassive revolution whose outcome has been a further strengtheningof capitalist hegemony – for about four decades. In the final days ofneoliberalism there is a new passive revolution in the making, bringingthe state back in as a stabilising institution of a postneoliberal, butcapitalist world order.Or are social movements intellectually and politically strong e<strong>no</strong>ughto bring their postneoliberal and postcapitalist agenda forcefully andsuccessfully into the social process of restructuring the financial systemof 21st century capitalism?


86 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateReferencesBaba, Naohiko, McGuire, Patrick and von Peter,Goetz (2008), ‘Highlights of international bankingand fi nancial market activity, Bank for internationalsettlement’, BIS Quarterly Review, June.www.bis.org/publ/qtrpdf/r_qt0806b.pdfAltvater, Elmar (2005), Das Ende des Kapitalismus,wie wir ihn kennen. Eine radikale Kapitalismuskritik(The end of capitalism as we k<strong>no</strong>w it. A radical critiqueof capitalism), Münster: Westfälisches Dampfboot.Bank of England (2008), ‘Financial Stability Report],No. 24, October. http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/fsr/2008/fsrfull0810.pdfEuromemorandum Group (2008), ‘Democratictransformation of European fi nance, a full employmentregime, and ecological restrcturing – Alternativesto fi nance-driven capitalism: Euromemorandum2008/<strong>2009</strong>’. http://www.memo-europe.uni-bremen.de/euromemo/indexmem.htmEuropean Central Bank, Monthly Report, November2008 http://www.bundesbank.de/download/ezb/monatsberichte/2008/200811.mb_ezb.pdfFoster, John Bellamy and Magdoff, Fred (<strong>2009</strong>,forthcoming), The Great Financial Crisis – Causesand Consequences, New York: Monthly ReviewPress.Harvey, David (2003), The New Imperialism, Oxford:Oxford University Press.IMF (International Monetary Fund) (2007), ‘WorldEco<strong>no</strong>mic Outlook: Spillovers and Cycles in the GlobalEco<strong>no</strong>my’, April. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2007/01/pdf/text.pdf.IPCC (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change)(2007), ‘Fourth Assessment Report of the IPCC(2007) on Climate Change’.http://ipcc-wg1.ucar.edu/wg1/wg1-report.html.MEW 23–25, Marx, Karl: Das Kapital, Band 1 bis 3,Berlin: Dietz-Verlag.Polanyi, Karl (1978), The Great Transformation,Frankfurt: Suhrkamp Verlag.Stern, Nicholas (2006), ‘Stern Review on the Eco<strong>no</strong>micsof Climate Change’, Her Majesty’s Treasury,Government of the United Kingdom. http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/independent_reviews/stern_review_eco<strong>no</strong>mics_climate_change/sternreview_index.cfmWorld Eco<strong>no</strong>mic Forum (2008), ‘Global Risks 2008:A Global Risk Network Report’, January. http://www.weforum.orgWorld Bank (2008), ‘Global Eco<strong>no</strong>mic Prospects<strong>2009</strong>’, Washington, DC: World Bank.


postneoliberalism or postcapitalism? the failure of neoliberalism in the financial market crisis 87


‘Neoliberalism’ and developmentpolicy – Dogma or progress?Kurt BayerThere are many ideas around that can result in better developmentpolicies and hence improve the living conditions of millions of peopleEmmerij 2006There will be <strong>no</strong> ‘glad confi dent morning’ forfree-market principles for a long time to comeS. Brittan, Financial Times, 12 September 2008International Financial Institutions (IFIs) are the main institutionalactors in development assistance and policy advice. They are alsoprotagonists of (mainstream) development thinking. Since the end ofWorld War II several development paradigmata have consecutivelyformed this mainstream. The lack of success of development assistance,characterised by the persistent large number of very poor in developingand emerging countries (DCs) is a result of both faulty contentand lack of adequate representation of DCs in IFIs and other internationalfora. 1 As a result of the latter, industrial countries’ thinkinghas dominated development practice. Variously, this latest versio<strong>no</strong>f mainstream thinking, the ‘Washington Consensus’ (WC) has beenlabelled neoliberal. Recently, this ‘consensus’ has begun to crumbleand fray at the edges. It will only be successfully replaced by moreeffective development practice, if and when the influence of developingcountries’ participation in the IFIs is increased in a way whichleads to a more open market place for development ideas, permittingand promoting also <strong>no</strong>n-conventional tailor-made solutions gearedtowards the poor and taking account of their specific needs and environments.‘Form and function’ of IFIs require change to make developmentpolicy and assistance more effective. Whether this can becalled ‘postneoliberal’ will be more important for future historians ofeco<strong>no</strong>mic thought than for the poor of the world.1 This still holds true in spite of adding an additional board seat for sub-Saharan Africancountries at the 2008 Annual Meeting of the Development Committee of the WorldBank.


90 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateThe Washington Consensus: neoclassical or neoliberal?The WC has become the bogeyman of the critics of ‘neoliberal’/mainstreamdevelopment policy (see, for example, Klein 2000, 2008). Theterm Washington Consensus was first coined by John Williamsonin a 1990 book on Latin American eco<strong>no</strong>mic policies (Williamson1990). It lists budget discipline, growth-enhancing shifts in public expenditures,tax reform (towards lower marginal tax rates and a broadenedtax base), liberalisation of interest rates, competitive exchangerates, trade and foreign direct investment liberalisation, privatisation,deregulation (to reduce entry and exit barriers) and safeguardingproperty rights as ingredients for successful development in LatinAmerica. These are essentially policy ingredients following neoclassicalthinking. During the 1990s, both Washington-based BrettonWoods Institutions, the World Bank Group and the InternationalMonetary Fund, adopted many of these policies. But like Williamsonhimself, the Bretton Woods Institutions never saw themselves as strictadherents to a Washington Consensus. Critics of mainstream developmentpolicy adopted this term as a catch-all moniker encompassingall they deemed detrimental and negative in development policy.Seen in the context of the evolution of development thinking, thetenets of the so-called WC belong to the ‘catching up’ theories whichhave dominated development thinking during the past 70 years (Küblböck2008). According to this theory developing and emergingcountries should follow in the industrial countries’ footsteps, andthus also adopt policies essentially gleaned from developed countries’mainstream thinking.Unravelling the Washington ConsensusJoseph Stiglitz is arguably the most prominent critic of neoliberalmainstream development policy. His most scathing attacks havebeen directed at the Bretton Woods Institutions, in which he himselfplayed a leading role as chief eco<strong>no</strong>mist and senior Vice President ofthe World Bank. While always a proponent of globalisation and of lessdeveloped countries’ involvement in the global eco<strong>no</strong>my, he has criticisedthe neoliberal, state and institution-de<strong>no</strong>uncing shock therapyfor developing and transition countries and has extolled the pragmaticgradualism and sequential approach as, for example, applied by theChinese (see Stiglitz 2002). He sees a strong role for the state and forstrong institutions in general and regulatory institutions in particularfor guiding the build-up towards a market eco<strong>no</strong>my (Stiglitz 2008).In addition, numerous efforts have been made by analysts during thelast 20 years to criticise (see, for example, Easterly 2006), augment


‘neoliberalism’ and development policy – dogma or progress? 91(Birdsall 2001) and complement the Washington Consensus, <strong>no</strong>t leastby the originator of the term, John Williamson himself (Kuczynskiand Williamson 2003). The effects of this debate within the BrettonWoods Institutions have been mixed: while it has largely been ig<strong>no</strong>redby the International Monetary Fund (IMF), within the WorldBank a re-thinking process has set in with varying results.To see is to believe – evidence beats ideologyWhen Teng Hsiao Ping visited Malaysia and Hong Kong in 1979 andsaw – instead of impoverished states like China at that time – glitteringfinancial centres and fast-emerging eco<strong>no</strong>mies, he decided againstthe policy of a<strong>no</strong>ther ‘great leap forward’. Instead, he proposed tocross the river ‘by feeling the pebbles with his foot’ – that is, a gradualistapproach for China – <strong>no</strong>t destroying its (communist) institutionsbut, rather, reforming them to enable markets to work. Thesuccess of China and 12 other ‘sustainable growth countries’, each ofwhich sustained growth rates of more than 7 per cent over 25 years,has recently been the subject of an intensive study, The Growth Report(Spence 2008). This report does <strong>no</strong>t come up with a strategy; rather,it debunks the illusion of one (dominant) growth and developmentrecipe for all countries.In summing up the 13 case studies (Botswana, Brazil, China, HongKong, Indonesia, Japan, Korea, Malaysia, Malta, Oman, Singapore,Taiwan and Thailand), the authors conclude that sustained growth oc-Instead of suggesting thatsome ‘grand scheme’ exists forcountries’ development, theGrowth Report emphasisesthe need to identify importantbottlenecks and constraints togrowth.


92 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatecurs <strong>no</strong>t by luck, but by the ‘right mix of ingredients’. The report does<strong>no</strong>t extol the benefits of liberalisation, privatisation and deregulation: itrecognises that all these countries have gone different ways to achievegrowth. But they see some common experiences: all countries haveengaged in the global eco<strong>no</strong>my, they have pursued macroeco<strong>no</strong>micstabilisation, but <strong>no</strong>t singlemindedly as anti-inflation policy; they haverecognised that savings and investment must be stimulated; and theyhave accepted the need for (various forms of) good governance and theneed to establish the right incentives in the eco<strong>no</strong>my. But apart fromthat they have employed very different instruments to achieve the sameend: higher growth plus poverty alleviation.Instead of suggesting that some ‘grand scheme’ exists for countries’development, the Growth Report emphasises the need to identifyimportant bottlenecks and constraints to growth. Instead of comprehensivereform, narrow policy solutions and policy experiments areproposed, including local, <strong>no</strong>n-conventional solutions. By looking toremedy country-specific constraints to growth by adopting individualpolicies and spurning comprehensive reform, sequencing and experimentsbecome important. To that end, the realisation that policyspillovers exist can help to build upon previous reform steps, in orderto find ways to overcome spatial, political and eco<strong>no</strong>mic impedimentsto growth. The report points out that all available instruments mustbe activated in order for countries to be successful: market and government,domestic and foreign, social and eco<strong>no</strong>mic. But solutionsneed to be local, inclusive, accepted and perceived as equitable. Whilethe authors see a role for foreign development assistance, this can onlybe complementary. ‘The rule book must be written at home, <strong>no</strong>t inWashington’ (Rodrik 2008).This report is surely <strong>no</strong>t the last word on development eco<strong>no</strong>micsand politics, but it leaves much room for local contributions, for <strong>no</strong>nconventionalsolutions, for eclectic learning-by-doing – and for local,regional, national participation of the citizens of DCs) in findingsolutions. The report does <strong>no</strong>t directly attack the mainstream. Its authorsare academics, World Bank staff, UN functionaries and the like.But it clearly shows that the age of the Washington Consensus – if itever consisted – is over, even among many who were supposed to beits major proponents.


‘neoliberalism’ and development policy – dogma or progress? 93Eco<strong>no</strong>mic growth by itself,even if successful, does <strong>no</strong>tensure development, defi nedas broad-based, sustainableimprovement in the livingstandards of the affectedpopulations, especially thepoor.Pro-poor growth?The realisation that eco<strong>no</strong>mic growth by itself, even if successful,does <strong>no</strong>t ensure development, defined as broad-based, sustainable improvementin the living standards of the affected populations, especiallythe poor, has led some analysts to add a number of policy objectivesto the Washington Consensus, especially with respect to distributionalissues and institution-building (see for example Birdsall,in Bayer 2008: 70). One outflow was the UN-originated ‘basic needs’approach which puts improvement in social indicators at the heart ofdevelopment policy. More recently, the concept of ‘pro-poor growth’has come into discussion, namely a growth process which focuses onpoverty alleviation. But also this concept incorporates diverse ideasof how to achieve its objectives. Most widespread is the one that seeseco<strong>no</strong>mic growth as ‘poverty-neutral’ (my term, KB), but as a meansto generate e<strong>no</strong>ugh public and private resources to redistribute tothe poor via tax revenue and social systems. This is a kind of trickle-downapproach to poverty alleviation. A less accepted, but morepromising avenue would be to see a country’s growth process as <strong>no</strong>nneutralwith respect to poverty alleviation.At the extremes, one can distinguish between growth policy inducedby foreign direct investment (FDI) which generates profits for the(relatively large and often regionally concentrated) firms (which frequentlywould be repatriated to the source country or an offshoretax-saving location) and employment and thus wages for local workers.In this case, growth would generate local pockets of poverty alleviationthrough the wage component in the regions (often exportprocessingzones) in which FDI is located. On the other side of thespectrum would be a growth policy focused on indige<strong>no</strong>us labour-intensivesmall and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) and rural development,where the growth proceeds are spread wider and thus reachmore poor. Such a process could also be more evenly spread across thewhole country, since it is less premised on agglomeration advantagesand transport links for exports and, moreover, generates both profitand wage components for the eco<strong>no</strong>my. The promotion of this typeof ‘pro-poor’ growth can also be supplemented with tax and expenditureredistributive elements in public spending.Both approaches, but especially the SME-related one, require stronggovernment intervention: while in the former this focuses on FDI acquisitionand tax and expenditure policy, in the latter it requires additionallysome kind of ‘industrial’ policy designed to promote broadbasedrural and SME-related growth by means of a variety of instruments,among them providing micro financing, simplifying regis-


94 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatetration procedures, business training, promoting supply chains andclusters, apprenticeship systems to train skilled workers, maybe evencooperatives promotion, farm supply logistics, and so on.Recognising the role of institutionsThe experiences of the break-up of the Soviet empire and the demiseof the state-run systems of the former communist countries have putnew emphasis on the role of institutions for the functioning of marketeco<strong>no</strong>mies. A similar experience extends to all less developed countrieswhere the removal of former colonial structures also left institutionalvoids behind. This development process has been less visible,because it did <strong>no</strong>t coincide with the (sudden) implosion of a singlewidespread socio-eco<strong>no</strong>mic system. Rather, it took place country bycountry, each under its specific circumstances.The extreme market-friendly approach epitomised by the cases of Poland’sand Russia’s ‘shock therapy’, which consisted in the radical eliminatio<strong>no</strong>f the old institutional structures, gave rise to extremely lopsidedprivatisation processes and massive grabs of former governmentassets. The lack of effective regulatory authorities, implementing concessionrules, property rights, the lack of a judiciary able and willing toenforce titles and grievances in a fair way led to extreme displacementsof workers, destruction of capital, mass emigration of skilled persons,poverty and inequality. The role of government in eco<strong>no</strong>my and societywas vilified, <strong>no</strong>n-regulation the accepted <strong>no</strong>rm, and privatisationand a significantly reduced state were seen as ends in themselves.Also, in developing countries the lack of adequate institutions provesextremely harmful for development. Public social sector expenditureswere judged by the IMF and others as mainly market-distorting, expensiveand thus harmful. As a result, too little attention was givento the development of an adequate tax base with which to pay skilledcivil servants: to install an independent judiciary; to develop regulatoryauthorities to prevent public mo<strong>no</strong>polies from being turned intoprivate ones, especially in the utilities sector; and also to develop socialsafety nets supporting the transformation and development processes,helping the losers in these severe change processes.This practice has been recognised as an important barrier to development.As a result, recently increasing emphasis has been placed bythe development institutions on institution-building, a new field forthem, requiring grant money. As a result, all development banks have


‘neoliberalism’ and development policy – dogma or progress? 95installed different forms of do<strong>no</strong>r trust funds, where (bilateral) grantmoney for technical assistance is in many cases combined with loans.Also with respect to institutions, the ‘catching up’ model, fashioninginstitutions after those in developed countries, may <strong>no</strong>t be advisable.Since governmental institutions can play their role in democraciesonly if they are accepted and trusted by the population, thought mustbe given to developing institutions which fit both the cultural contextof the country and the requirements of a globalising national eco<strong>no</strong>my.Thus, <strong>no</strong>n-conventional solutions need to be considered, too.The market is <strong>no</strong>t willing orable to provide adequateinfrastructure outside thecapitals and business centresand is frequently <strong>no</strong>t able tofi nance long-term investment.At the same time, publicinfrastructure investment haslagged, for lack of an adequatetax base, but also because‘infrastructure does <strong>no</strong>t havea lobby’ to exert politicalpressure.Within this context, the demonisation of the state as an essential developmentactor for society and eco<strong>no</strong>my has begun to be reversed. This isalso a result of empirical evidence. World Bank studies have shown, forexample, that the wholesale privatisation of the energy sector in LatinAmerica has <strong>no</strong>t yielded the intended goals (more efficient high-qualityprovision of energy services to the whole population); <strong>no</strong>r can privateoutside investors be found any longer. The increased attention paid toaffordability considerations with respect to utility tariffs (partially a resultof the recent acceptance of income (and welfare) distribution problemsas legitimate development concerns has deterred profit- and rentseekingforeign investors. In addition, attention to deficiencies withrespect to ‘business climate’, a concern of all development institutionsinterested in promoting private sector activity, has shown significantregulatory deficiencies in most countries (see various issues of the annualWorld Bank’s ‘Doing Business’ reports).The recognition that a functioning physical infrastructure is essentialboth for private sector activity and for social development hasbrought to light significant gaps in infrastructure investment. Thisled to the realisation also by mainstream development practitionersthat the market is <strong>no</strong>t willing or able to provide adequate infrastructureoutside the capitals and business centres and is frequently <strong>no</strong>t ableto finance long-term investment. At the same time, public infrastructureinvestment has lagged, for lack of an adequate tax base, but alsobecause ‘infrastructure does <strong>no</strong>t have a lobby’ to exert political pressure.Since most developing and emerging countries can<strong>no</strong>t obtainloans with 40-year or even 25-year te<strong>no</strong>r from private capital markets(neither private firms, <strong>no</strong>r governments), it falls upon developmentbanks to provide and activate this long-term capital, frequently inthe form of sovereign loans. Recently, there has been a rush towards‘public-private partnerships’ (PPPs), in order to combine sovereignguarantees and capital with private funds and k<strong>no</strong>w-how in a newpartnership between state and private sector. While PPPs are ‘every-


96 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatebody’s darling’, few in DCs k<strong>no</strong>w about how to design such projectsproperly, to distribute benefits and risks proportionately to the publicand private participants and to draw up the necessary contracts andconcepts in order to make this idea work. A significant number ofPPP projects has been abandoned, been restructured or aborted early.State authorities have to beware of getting into situations where thedistribution of risks and the concomitant benefits turns out to be a‘privatisation of profits and a socialisation of risks’.Open fi nancial markets: benefi t or curse?One of the strong tenets of International Financial Institutions activityduring the past years was that of the beneficial effects of the liberalisatio<strong>no</strong>f capital flows. Given the lack of capital in developing andtransition countries due to low earnings and savings (and also capitalfl ight, rarely mentioned), attracting both real and financial capital toDCs was seen as overridingly beneficial. The financial crises of LatinAmerica and Asia, which led to the collapse of many eco<strong>no</strong>mies andthe impoverishment of millions of people, have led to some rethinking.For a while IFI development specialists saw the causes of thesecollapses mainly in insufficient structural change within these countries,which induced a loss of confidence among foreign investors andthus their sudden withdrawal of funds. More recently, emphasis wasput on the correct sequencing of the liberalisation of capital flows.FDI was seen to have mainly positive effects on the DCs (bringingcapital, organisation methods, technical k<strong>no</strong>w-how, marketing networks,and so on) and also as being less volatile than financial flows.The latter could easily lead to destabilisation of small open eco<strong>no</strong>mieswith insufficiently deep domestic capital markets. The positiveexperiences of, for example, Chile and Malaysia, both going differentbut u<strong>no</strong>rthodox (and, at the time of their installation, criticised)ways with respect to liberalising capital flows also led to (grudging)acceptance, for example by the IMF, of some capital market restrictions.Following Chile’s successful example, the IMF became betterdisposed towards barriers to incoming flows, but <strong>no</strong>t to outflows.There is <strong>no</strong> doubt that a redimensioningof the globalfi nancial system is in processwhich might redirect fi nanceto its original role of fi nancing‘real transactions’ and avoidthe pyramid schemes whichmove fi nancial fl ows severalhundred times larger than theunderlying transactions.The current financial crisis, which up to fall 2008 has mainly hitbanks in industrial countries, but led to massive refinancing problemsfor a number of DCs, in late 2007 and 2008 has drastically reducedcapital inflows to DCs. Since mid-2008, some of the most prominentadvocates of liberalised markets, for example the The Eco<strong>no</strong>mist andThe Financial Times, started to muse about the fact that deregulatio<strong>no</strong>f financial markets had, maybe, gone too far and a ‘measured re-regulation’was in order, especially with respect to removing incentives


‘neoliberalism’ and development policy – dogma or progress? 97for channelling ever-increasing amounts of capital flows around theregulated areas.Several schemes are being proposed to reduce volatility, to regulatehedge funds, to de-incentivise investments in highly leveraged funds,to reduce regulatory arbitrage. Suddenly, one of the most glaring institutionaldeficiencies –that is, the lack of unified supervisory authorityof the unified, global financial markets – is being recognised.The fact that recently the US, UK and German governments – alluntil recently adherents to free-market ideology – have re-nationalisedlarge financial institutions which had invested in assets of doubtfulvalue is the most glaring proof that the neoliberal dogma has cometo an end and that a re-evaluation of the limits of unregulated marketsmight be in order.There is <strong>no</strong> doubt that a re-dimensioning of the global financial systemis in process which might redirect finance to its original role offinancing ‘real transactions’ and avoid the pyramid schemes whichmove financial flows several hundred times larger than the underlyingtransactions.Some of the described functional failures implied by the impositio<strong>no</strong>f orthodox neoclassical thinking on the eco<strong>no</strong>mies of less developedcountries, whose institutional, legal, cultural preconditions in manycases differ from those presupposed by the fathers of neoclassical eco<strong>no</strong>micssignificantly, have also led to a crisis of legitimacy of orthodoxdevelopment theory. Development success is restricted to too fewcountries. This reality has imposed huge costs on the poor. It hasalso led to a delegitimisation of development assistance in industrialcountries, as signified by the fact that with the exception of the Nordiccountries <strong>no</strong> industrial country seems likely to achieve and fulfilthe promises and obligations which they undertook at G-7 meetings(double help to Africa), in the EU (reach at least 0.<strong>51</strong> per cent of GDPby 2010 and 0.7 per cent by 2015 for the EU-15) or at the MillenniumSummit (reach the Millennium Development Goals by 2015).Process co-determines substanceWhat became k<strong>no</strong>wn as the Washington Consensus, a neoclassicalconcept, has begun to crumble. This concept has been dubbed neoliberal.While the importance of both macro-eco<strong>no</strong>mic stabilisationand institutional and legal change for development commands overwhelmingconsensus, the instruments used and the prioritisation of


98 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateindividual steps have begun to be much more differentiated. Few todaystill believe in a Grand Design Strategy, where all (most) developmenttargets are to be achieved simultaneously. Rather, impedimentsto growth and development are analysed and attacked sequentially,depending on their respective power to hinder growth. I personallyfind the value of naming this crumbling of some old certainties byany name, be it postneoliberalism, pragmatism or trial-and-error approach,rather futile. Any –ism would give the appearance of a newtheoretical superstructure being in place – which is <strong>no</strong>t the case.The most recent crises in the global eco<strong>no</strong>my point to policy, institutionaland conceptual failures in the development practice of the lastdecades. This should lead to the recognition that the era of WWE(White Western Eco<strong>no</strong>mists) imposing their thinking (gleaned fromthe experience of their own industrial societies) on less developedcountries has been largely unsuccessful. This is a result of gaps bothof substance and the process of decision-making in the developmentinstitutions. Improvements would point to the need for a much largerrole of specialists from developing and emerging countries – academics,policy experts and NGOs – together with government elites, inshaping the directions and strategies of development IFIs. While I believethat the objectives of development might command widespreadconsensus among traditional, orthodox and ‘other’ development specialists,much more room would have to be given to each country/region to go its own way towards commonly agreed goals, dependingon specific historical, cultural, geographic, climatic, demographic,eco<strong>no</strong>mic and societal contexts. This would require a radical re-shapingof the institutional development architecture.While in such a newly organised development structure there wouldstill be a large role for top-down strategies, the development and especiallythe implementation of such strategies would have to leave muchmore room for bottom-up activities: by including <strong>no</strong>n-governmentalorganisations and individual citizens both in strategy-setting and in implementation.In such a world global eco<strong>no</strong>mic and development strategieswould <strong>no</strong>t be run by the G-7/8, but rather by a much more inclusivegroup of countries (‘G-20 plus’), consisting of industrial, emergingand developing countries. As a kind of steering group such a groupingwould supervise those areas which are most in need of global regulation(macro-stability, resources and environment, development, socialwelfare and labour and overarching public goods). They would proposepragmatic solutions to global problems devised by worldwide networksof government officials, academic experts and NGOs (see Bayer 2007).The existing IFIs would play an executive and consultative and secre-The emergence of ‘newdo<strong>no</strong>rs’ – as exemplifi ed bythe massive interventionsby China in Africa – whodo <strong>no</strong>t feel bound by theexisting rules of developmentassistance (such as thepainstakingly worked-out ‘debtsustainability framework’)is driving a wedge into thedominance of developmentactivity by existing institutions.


‘neoliberalism’ and development policy – dogma or progress? 99tariat role in this structure, with a revised voting structure, giving DCsa much larger share in decision-making than <strong>no</strong>w.The emergence of ‘new do<strong>no</strong>rs’ – as exemplified by the massive interventionsby China in Africa – who do <strong>no</strong>t feel bound by the existingrules of development assistance (such as the painstakingly worked-out‘debt sustainability framework’) is driving a wedge into the dominanceof development activity by existing institutions. While the activitiesof such new do<strong>no</strong>rs may be driven more by the wish to secureraw materials and global political influence than by (altruistic) developmentassistance, they have contributed to new thinking whichis making inroads into the existing institutions. As an example, traditionalIFIs have started to think about the role of Islamic banking,about <strong>no</strong>n-traditional quasi-property rights, about cooperativesas entrepreneurial organisations in Africa, about the role of religionin development, the special role of women – and many others, unheardof 10 years ago. More participation by the poor, by poor andsmall countries in the development dialogue would lead to a moreopen approach to development assistance. There are signs on the wall:orthodox, neoliberal dogmatism has failed to deliver, a new pragmaticapproach is starting to appear. Progress in reforming the IFIshas so far been limited and inadequate. However, this is the time toreform them and give small and poor countries adequate representation,lest they ‘vote with their feet’ and leave these global institutionsby forming their own. 2 This, together with the breakdown of theDoha Round, would be a<strong>no</strong>ther step back from a mutually beneficialglobal governance of eco<strong>no</strong>mic and development institutions.It is open to speculation which developments would drive such a reorganisatio<strong>no</strong>f the global development architecture. So far, the dominantindustrial countries have shown remarkable resistance to significantchange. In a recent speech on the occasion of the World Bank’s2008 annual meeting, World Bank President Zoellick’s proposal fora ‘new multilateralism’ engages only seven large emerging countriesin a ‘new steering group’ in addition to the G-7 countries, but oncemore leaves out the poorest countries from his considerations.2 See, for example, the increasing number of signatories to the new Banco del Sur,initiated by President Chavez in 2007.


100 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateReferencesBayer, Kurt (2007), ‘How to Run the GlobalEco<strong>no</strong>my’, BMF Working Paper <strong>no</strong>. 2, Vienna,www.bmf.gv.atBayer, Kurt (2008), ‘Does Globalization Make theWorld More Equitable?’, in Intervention vol. 5, <strong>no</strong>. 1,pp. 45-53.Birdsall, Nancy et al. (2001), WashingtonContentious. Commission on Eco<strong>no</strong>mic Reform inUnequal Latin American Societies, Washington, DC:Carnegie Foundation. www.policyin<strong>no</strong>vations.org/ideas/policy_library/data/01226.Buira, Ariel (ed.) (2003), Challenges to the WorldBank and IMF, Developing Country Perspectives,London: Anthem.Chang, Ha-Jong (ed.) (2004), RethinkingDevelopment Eco<strong>no</strong>mics, London: Anthem.Cornia, Andrea (2004), ‘Globalization and theDistribution of Income between and withinCountries’, in Chang (ed.), pp. 425-452.Easterly, William (2006), The White Man’s Burden,Oxford: Oxford University Press.Emmerij, L. (2006), ‘Turning Points in DevelopmentThinking and Practice’, UNU-WIDER Research Paper<strong>no</strong>. 8, www.wider.unu.edu/publications/workingpapers/research-papers/2006/en_GB/rp2006-08/- 12kFreudenschuss-Reichl, Irene and Bayer,Kurt (eds.) (2008), Entwicklungspolitik undEntwicklungszusammenarbeit, Vienna: Manz.Jomo, K.S. with Baudot, Jacques (2007), Flat World,Big Gaps. Eco<strong>no</strong>mic Liberalization, Globalization,Poverty and Inequality, London: United Nations.Katseli, Louka (2008), ‘Historischer Überblick zurGeschichte der EZA’, in Freudenschuss-Reichl andBayer (eds), pp. 9-22.Kaul, Inge and Griffi th-Jones, S. (2003), Proposalfor increasing DC participation in global fi nancialgovernance. UNDP, G-77 <strong>no</strong>te, New York, www.undp.orgKlein, Naomi (2000), No Logo, New York: Picador.Klein, Naomi (2008), The Shock Doctrine, New York:Metropolitan Books.Kuczynski, Pedro-Paolo, Williamson, John (eds)(2003), After the Washington Consensus. RestartingGrowth and Reform in Latin America, Washington,DC: Institute for International Eco<strong>no</strong>mics.Küblböck, Karin (2008), ‘Kontroversen in derEntwicklungsdiskussion’, in Freudenschuss-Reichland Bayer (eds), pp. 23-37.Matzner, Egon (ed.) (1992), The Market Shock, AnnArbor: University of Michigan Press.Rodrik, Dani (2008), ‘Is there a New WashingtonConsensus?’, Project Syndicate, www.projectsyndicate.org.commentary/rodrikRodrik, Dani (2008), ‘The Death of the GlobalizationConsensus’, Project Syndicate. www.projectsyndicate.org,2008.Spence, Michael (ed.) (2008), The Growth Report.Strategies for Sustained Growth and InclusiveDevelopment, Washington, DC: World Bank.Stiglitz, Joseph (2002), Globalization and ItsDiscontents, New York: Penguin.Stiglitz, Joseph (2006), Making Globalization Work,New York: W. W. Norton.Stiglitz, Joseph (2008), ‘The End of Neo-liberalism?’,www.project-syndicate.org.commentary/stiglitz101Williamson, John (ed.) (1990), Latin AmericanAdjustment: How Much Has Happened?Washington, DC: Institute for InternationalEco<strong>no</strong>mics.World Bank, Doing Business Report, annual issues,Washington, DC: World Bank.Zoellick, Robert (2008), ‘Modernizing Multilateralimsand Markets’, Speech at the Peterson Institute forInternational Eco<strong>no</strong>mics, Washington, DC,6 October.


‘neoliberalism’ and development policy – dogma or progress? 101


Environmental crises and theambiguous postneoliberalisingof nature 1Ulrich BrandDuring the last few decades of the neoliberal-imperial globalisationprocess, social relations have been fundamentally transformed. Neoliberalismwas never a purely market-driven process but also a shapingof other social relations and institutions, especially of the state. Thestate, private corporations, public discourses but also many aspects ofeveryday life were reoriented towards eco<strong>no</strong>mic efficiency and internationalcompetitiveness. Aspects such as (re-) distribution or socialand/or international solidarity played scarcely any role. As thesesocietal changes have occurred, the appropriation of nature has alsobeen transformed. Dimensions of nature that were previously of littleinterest were <strong>no</strong>w becoming (potentially) valuable resources to beassessed for their value and incorporated into the capitalist accumulationprocess. Neoliberalism was and is also an ecological project – thatis, a project to transform societal appropriation of nature or societalrelationships with nature. 2The argument in this article is set against the following background.There was a first phase of neoliberalism – starting in Chile 1973 andgaining power in the 1980s – which consisted mainly of the destructio<strong>no</strong>f the post-war (Fordist and peripheral-Fordist) institutional settingsand (asymmetric) social compromises, and a second phase inthe 1990s, after the fall of the Berlin wall, when neoliberal politicswas largely uncontested, institutionalised in many spheres of the socialand constitutionalised (in national legal systems as well as internationally,for example, in the WTO). For some years a third phase hasbeen underway, consisting of attempts to deal with the contradictions and crisesof neoliberalism itself. Neoliberal politics has produced highly unstablerelations which can <strong>no</strong> longer be controlled: the most obvious examplesare the financial crisis and the social crisis of integration, butthere is also a deepening of the environmental crisis. These strategies1 I would like to thank Achim Brunnengräber, Dieter Klein, Bettina Köhler, Nicola Seklerand Markus Wissen for their comments.2 Cf. Altvater 1993, Goldman 1998, the overview in Castree 2008; on the concept of societalrelationships with nature see Görg 2004, Brand et al. 2008, Brand and Görg 2008.


104 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatecan be called postneoliberal and they aim to deal with the several crisesof functioning and to avoid a crisis of legitimation of neoliberaland especially of capitalist societal relations – or to deal with such acrisis if it occurs.I give a very short sketch of the development of the environmentalcrisis since the 1970s and present some reflections on the relationshipbetween capitalism, its neoliberal and neoimperial phase and the societalappropriation of nature. The current environmental debate andthe crisis of societal relationships with nature underlying it are putinto the context of postneoliberal developments and strategies.My argument is enshrined in a real – that is, historical – contradiction:there is a widely generalised consciousness that capitalist societalrelationships with nature require radical transformation becauseof the destructive consequences of capitalist-neoliberal and imperialforms of the appropriation of nature. In principle this opens up spacefor a critique of and a practical change in the dominant forms of societalrelationships with nature. However, there are few really alternativepractices beyond the important local experiences of subsistence.Therefore, and despite all mi<strong>no</strong>r changes, I would call the currentconstellation a widely recognised crisis of the dominant socio-eco<strong>no</strong>mic, politicaland cultural forms of the appropriation of nature with, at the same time,strong passive consent – as there are <strong>no</strong> visible and accepted alternatives on alarge scale – for those crisis-driven forms. Environmental politics aims todeal with this contradiction and this is the terrain where postneoliberalstrategies and politics emerge. 3Environmental crisis and neoliberal natureThe destructive tendency of the appropriation of nature is inherentin capitalist development, its forms of production, distribution andconsumption – all shaped by domination – its instrumental rationalityand its raison d´être in the valorisation of capital. 4 Capitalist developmentis necessarily irrational – that is, in principle, there is <strong>no</strong>conscious and democratic shaping of societal relations – and this becomesespecially clear with respect to societal relationships with nature.Moreover, the use of the resources and sinks of the particularcountries and social groups correlates – according to form – with thelevel of material development (cf. Altvater, this volume).The destructive tendency ofthe appropriation of natureis inherent in capitalistdevelopment, its forms ofproduction, distribution andconsumption – all shaped bydomination – its instrumentalrationality and its raisond´être in the valorisation ofcapital.3 Of course, this rather general argument has to be adapted to particular societies andhistorical conjunctures.4 With respect to the appropriation of nature, countries practising socialism as well ascountries practising peripheral Fordism pursued the same patterns.


environmental crises and the ambiguous postneoliberalising of nature 105In order to understand the link between neoliberalism and societalrelationships with nature, it makes sense to see capitalist developmentand the use of its energy basis as happening in (uneven) historicalphases. To give an example: liberal capitalism in the 19th century hada particular energy basis (coal), and particular tech<strong>no</strong>logical, productionand consumption <strong>no</strong>rms. After the beginning of the 20th century,we saw a new energy basis (oil and gas), new tech<strong>no</strong>logies – asthe assembly line, (mass) production and (mass) consumption patternsemerged in the US and were more or less generalised after World WarII (of course, in very different ways) – and a new international divisio<strong>no</strong>f labour and resource flows.In the 1970s, an accumulation crisis and a related crisis of the developmentstate and of the Western welfare state undermined the (peripheral)Fordist mode of development. Through a confl ictive search process,neoliberal politics was strengthened in many countries, and tradeunions and the labour movement, in particular, were weakened (cf.Albo, this volume, on trade unions). The state should create the conditionsfor a new phase of capital accumulation with legal, discursive andcoercive means. This is the underlying grammar of the dominant wayof dealing with the environmental crisis. It was <strong>no</strong>t by chance that thesocio-eco<strong>no</strong>mic and political crisis of the post-war mode of developmentwent hand in hand with the politicisation of the environmentalcrisis (cf. Brand and Görg 2008). The crisis became obvious in the 1970swhen public debate and social movements put the problems of societalappropriation of nature on the political agenda.At the beginning, the environmental crisis was dealt with symbolicallyand by more or less tech<strong>no</strong>cratic state policies. After the mid-1980s some ‘solutions’ became more and more obvious. After the RioConference on sustainable development in 1992, the road towards institutionalin<strong>no</strong>vations seemed to be opened and ways of dealing withthe most fundamental environmental problems established: new internationalinstitutions like the Framework Convention on ClimateChange, private companies which understood the profound and in<strong>no</strong>vativechanges that were necessary – certain sectors such as the automobileand chemical industries promoted their strategies under the labelof sustainability – and an increasing public awareness. A new socialgroup of tech<strong>no</strong>crats emerged, the so called ‘earth brokers’ (Chatterjeeand Finger 1994). However, the aforementioned grammar of societaldynamics was <strong>no</strong>t evident for many years: in fact, in the course of the1990s, the Rio Conventions on Climate Change and Biodiversity werethemselves articulated through neoliberal politics – that is, they becameone institutional dimension of the neoliberalising of nature (Brunnen-


106 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debategräber 2007, Brand and Görg 2008). Not by chance, we can observe astrong institutional selectivity towards market-based instruments in thevery constitution of international climate and biodiversity politics. Butmore generally, a neoliberalising of nature took place: its privatisation,marketisation, de-regulation but also re-regulation (that is, state policiesin order to facilitate privatisation and marketisation), market proxiesin the residual public sector and respective fl anking mechanisms incivil society (Castree 2008).Since the end of the 1990s and especially around the ‘Rio +10’ conferencein Johannesburg in 2002 it became clear that the strategies of thecorporations consisted much more of a ‘greenwashing’ than real changesand that the public awareness reached among the global elites andmiddle classes was only translated into institutional changes as long astheir own production and consumption <strong>no</strong>rms were <strong>no</strong>t questioned.To sum up this first argument: environmental policies were and stillare formulated in line with dominant politics and related interests.From the 1980s on, the dominant politics were neoliberal and neoimperial,orientated towards competitiveness and maintaining and enhancingthe power of Northern governments, corporations and societies.The ico<strong>no</strong>graphic sites of the 1990s were, <strong>no</strong>t Rio de Janeiro, butBaghdad – because of the second Gulf War in 1991 – and Marakesh– with the end of the so-called Uruguay round where the foundatio<strong>no</strong>f the World Trade Organization was agreed upon. Neoliberal andneoimperial politics were much more dynamic than politics of sustainabledevelopment and were able to determine the dominant developmentpath (cf. Park et al. 2008, Leff 2008). 5 Policies were and arein the interest of the owners of assets and of the global middle classes– including the middle classes in eco<strong>no</strong>mically emerging countriessuch as China, India or Brazil. The Western way of life still promotesits attractiveness worldwide. Human wellbeing and social security arestill equated with eco<strong>no</strong>mic growth and this means the resource-intensivegrowth of car production, of airports, of industrialised farming,projects of ocean fertilisation, and so on. It is therefore possibleto speak of an imperial way of living in Northern/Western countriesand also in the nations of the Global South with their growing middle5 These developments show that we need to distinguish between explicit and implicitforms of environmental politics. The former are intended forms in a specifi c ‘policy fi eld’with specifi ed apparatuses and policies. Implicit environmental politics refers to thosemanifold societal structures and processes that lead to dominant and dominated formsof the societal appropriation of nature – that is, land use, infrastructure (e.g. the expansio<strong>no</strong>f airports), science, tech<strong>no</strong>logies, <strong>no</strong>rms of production and consumption, state policiesincluding fi nancial, trade and eco<strong>no</strong>mic policies. From a critical and emancipatoryperspective it is <strong>no</strong>t e<strong>no</strong>ugh to focus on explicit politics but to see the broader picture.


environmental crises and the ambiguous postneoliberalising of nature 107class. That means that quite a large portion of the world’s populationlives by exploiting nature and exploiting other people(s); this is alsoone crucial element that despite the obvious crisis in the dominantrelationships with nature remains largely uncontested.Recent re-politicisationsSurprisingly, since the end of the year 2006 a re-politicisation of theenvironmental crisis has taken place on a global scale and, from anemancipatory perspective, it is of utmost importance to understandthis. Obviously, it was a ‘catalytic mixture’ which caused the recentre-politicisation: the assumed peak oil – that is, the definitive exhaustio<strong>no</strong>f the global oil and gas reserves within the next few decades, thegrowing political power of Russia on grounds of its energy resources,the ongoing war in Iraq, the energy demands of the emerging eco<strong>no</strong>miesof countries like China and India, the strategies to produceagrofuels for the world market in countries like Brazil or Indonesia,the Stern Report (2006) to the British government and the 4thReport of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC2007; for a critical overview see Brunnengräber 2007).The dominant forms of globalenvironmental governance– for example, at theinternational level, the KyotoProtocol – are more and moreconsidered inadequate byscientists as well as the widerpublic.These recent developments articulate themselves with a certain societalsensitivity for environmental issues in some countries – Germany,for example. This was created in recent decades by social movementsand NGOs as well as some scientists and intellectuals, mediaand state officials. In other countries, like Bolivia or Brazil, confl ictsover resources intensified due to degradation and scarcity, price increasesand problems of access to the means of subsistence for millionsof people as well as the lack of distributional policies.But there is an additional aspect. The dominant forms of global environmentalgovernance – for example, at the international level, theKyoto Protocol of the Framework Convention on Climate Changeor the Convention on Biological Diversity, environmental politicalinstitutions and processes at the regional, national and local levels –are more and more considered inadequate by scientists as well as thewider public (cf. MASR 2005, Park et al. 2008, Brand et al. 2008).And finally, environmental politics seem to be an integral part of theattempts to re-legitimise neoliberal politics which came under pressuredue to manifold protests and problems of social polarisation, impoverishment,environmental problems themselves, and so on. Governmentsand business intend to create in this situation a win-winwin-winsituation through dominant political and eco<strong>no</strong>mic institu-


108 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatetions: the proposed sustainable strategies are considered to be goodfor business, good for consumers, good for society as a whole andgood for nature – and, therefore, justify state and intergovernmentalpolicies. Because of the politicisation of the environmental crisis, onthe one hand, and the implicit consensus that the dominant ways ofproduction, consumption and relationships with nature should <strong>no</strong>tbe changed fundamentally, on the other hand, symbolic politics canpredominate, fl anked by some political and eco<strong>no</strong>mic institutionalin<strong>no</strong>vations.Postneoliberal societal relationships with natureAlongside neoliberal-imperial political, eco<strong>no</strong>mic and cultural dynamics,the many ruptures, crises and criticisms must also be givengreater attention. Because the fact is that some dimensions of post-Fordist and mainly neoliberal relationships with nature are coming incrisis. At a general level we can distinguish between crises of legitimation– that is, through social struggles and criticism which delegitimisethe existing forms of the appropriation of nature – and crises offunctioning – that is, problems for the dominant forces themselves andof societal reproduction which, according to form, affect the weakerand more vulnerable social groups and regions most.In view of the growing consciousness that the existing ways of dealingwith the environmental crisis are inadequate and that the neoliberalisingof nature produces severe problems, we can identify differentpostneoliberal strategies and politics concerning the appropriatio<strong>no</strong>f nature (politics in the sense of strategies that became socially important).The emerging terrain and related politics upon which emancipatory,liberal social democratic, (market) liberal, conservative, reactionaryand other actors are performing with their respective strategiescould well be described as postneoliberal. The mentioned ‘types’ do<strong>no</strong>t exist in a pure form but we have to ack<strong>no</strong>wledge the unevennessand the contradictory character of specific developments in the areasof, for example, land use, the production of food and wood, the useof water, ways of dealing with the consequences of climate change,the erosion of biodiversity, the creation of environmental refugees,institutional settings, and so on. 6 Postneoliberal strategies do <strong>no</strong>t necessarilyconstitute a rupture with neoliberal politics. On the contrary,the term helps us to understand the continuities and discontinuities of thesocietal forms used to appropriate nature (and we should <strong>no</strong>t mix up6 At the methodological level, there is <strong>no</strong>t a clear criterion to distinguish the differentvariants of postneoliberal strategies. The distinctions are rather heuristic and shouldbe developed further in a coherent research programme.


environmental crises and the ambiguous postneoliberalising of nature 109strategies with outcomes – that is, the real shaping of societal relationshipswith nature in concrete constellations which are often productsof compromises). Moreover, the different variants should <strong>no</strong>t be understoodin a voluntaristic way – that is, that dominant forces canchoose to employ this or that strategy. Usually they are forced to usea specific strategy or several different ones, according the existing experiences,power relations and socio-ecological conditions.The rationale behind thedevelopment of ‘greenmarkets’ and ‘greeninvestment’, is ecologicalmodernisation and thejustifi cation as a socialmarket eco<strong>no</strong>my – that is,environmental politics withoutquestioning the basis ofsocietal structures and power.A certain individualisation ofresponsibility takes place andthe leitmotifs are enlightenedconsumers and new lifestyles.A fi rst and important strategy is one that is part of the postneoliberalstruggle – in that it deals with the many contradictions, but is in itselfneoliberal. I call it a business-as-usual version – that is, the way of dealingwith the contradictions of neoliberalism is a more or less reflexiveor even a completely ig<strong>no</strong>rant deepening of those strategies. A mainfeature of modern societies is what Marx called the ‘silent coercio<strong>no</strong>f societal relations’. The production of commodities and surplus valuethrough wage labour and the valorisation of capital through theseemingly equal exchange on the market reproduce highly unequalsocietal relations in an opaque way. Neoliberal strategies were successfulin the strengthening of this dynamics (whereas, before, thepartial de-commodification of wage labour was important) and therelated policies had strong impacts on various relations: gender relations,the racialised structure of societies, the international divisio<strong>no</strong>f labour, relations between the younger and older generations (forexample, through the capital-market orientation of pension funds)and, as we saw, societal relationships with nature. The business-asusualversion of postneoliberalism aims to maintain the same kind ofdevelopment as in the recent past, with some slight changes, integratinglessons from the worst experiences of neoliberal politics and/orresponding to critiques. Here, the continuities of neoliberal policiesconcerning societal relationships with nature prevail: privatisation,marketisation, deregulation and related issues (see above).The specific operation of the neoliberal form to deal with neoliberalcontradictions and crises is the ‘Rio type’ of politics – that is, a form ofdealing with socio-ecological problems through some institutionalin<strong>no</strong>vations, much more efficiency in the spheres of production andconsumption, the development of ‘green markets’ and ‘green investment’,and reliance on modern Western expertise. The rationale behindit is ecological modernisation and the justification as a socialmarket eco<strong>no</strong>my – that is, environmental politics without questioningthe basis of societal structures and power. A certain individualisatio<strong>no</strong>f responsibility takes place and the leitmotifs are enlightenedconsumers and new lifestyles. The Western and – according toform – universalising model of production and consumption is hardly


110 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatequestioned. This strategy is quite prominent in some countries inWestern Europe, of course with differences between Germany andthe Scandinavian countries because the latter were and still partly areresponsible for the most progressive attempts to regulate capitalism.However, the institutionalised logic of the Rio type does <strong>no</strong>t questionneoliberal dynamics.A second and openly coercive variant of postneoliberal strategies comes intoforce when confl icts about resources or sinks intensify and/or whenprotest against the predominant structures might involve questioningtheir very existence. The appropriation of nature and the related formsof social power are <strong>no</strong>t mainly exercised through the market and itspolitical embeddedness but through the military, police and/or privatearmies, which might lead to open or hidden wars (Ceceña 2006).The coercive variant might also emerge as an imperial strategy whenresource-rich societies and their governments are <strong>no</strong>t willing to integrateinto the world market or when the political-eco<strong>no</strong>mic orientatio<strong>no</strong>f a country is questioned by a major power. At the internationaland the national level, the rationale behind it is the maintenance ofexisting power relations. The extreme political right resorts more andmore to openly coercive means. Concerning the political shaping ofsocietal relationships with nature, this version is oriented towards ecoauthoritarianpolitics, which it justifies by referring to resource scarcity,overpopulation, the ‘inability of the poor’ to help themselves and theprofl igate lifestyles of the masses, which destroy nature.Thirdly, a roll-back version of postneoliberalism – which is an attemptto redynamise state-led capitalist development and to strengthen regionalintegration – is strong in some Latin American countries suchas Venezuela, Bolivia and Ecuador. Here we experience very dynamicsocial changes through movements, parties, intellectuals and evenstate apparatuses in the light of the obvious disaster of neoliberal politics.It is a kind of neo-developmentalism (neo-desarrollismo) whichaims to regulate capital movement, foster the development of infrastructure,and link growth and distribution. However, this does <strong>no</strong>tmean automatically that the damaging societal relationships with natureare subject to change. It is <strong>no</strong>t by chance that the distributionaland anti-colonial political project, especially in Venezuela, is oftencalled ‘oil socialism’ because it is based on the exploitation of oil anddoes <strong>no</strong>t question the societal relationship with nature, which is mediatedthrough domination. A<strong>no</strong>ther aspect of the roll-back versionconsiders that some dimensions of the neoliberalising of nature aredysfunctional for private capital itself. Actually, this becomes clearin water privatisation where the expected profits can<strong>no</strong>t be realised.


environmental crises and the ambiguous postneoliberalising of nature 111Additionally, here we can learn that social protest – as in the Boliviancity of Cochabamba – is important to make capital privatisationprocesses unattractive.Emancipatory postneoliberal strategiesA fourth variant –often combined with dimensions of the third one– can be called emancipatory postneoliberal strategies. Emancipatory postneoliberalstrategies might open up a way of thinking and acting thatgo beyond the capitalist mode of societalisation, beyond the mediatio<strong>no</strong>f the appropriation of nature through patriarchal, imperial andracist social relations. This would require conscious ways of appropriatingnature that go beyond valorisation or management that is mediatedthrough domination in the interest of powerful social forces,and deeply rooted in capitalist, imperial, patriarchal and racist formsof living.Essential for emancipatorystrategies is to reject the‘false alternative’ betweenthe domination of nature– inherent in most of thestrategies outlined – and thesubordination of society to theassumed ‘laws of nature’.It implies a critical understanding of precisely these societal relationshipswith nature. One element here is a critique of the dominantframing of the environmental crisis as a crisis of ‘humankind’ or ofoverstretched ‘carrying capacity’ or as still too weak management ofresources (which is common in the Rio type of environmental politics).In contrast, the appropriation of nature is materially – especiallythrough tech<strong>no</strong>logies and labour – and symbolically –through, forexample, scientific understandings of nature – mediated, and theseeco<strong>no</strong>mic, political and cultural forms of mediation have to be transformed.A<strong>no</strong>ther dimension of emancipatory relationships with natureis the ack<strong>no</strong>wledgement that there is an irreducible plurality ofthem, despite the fact that some forms become dominant or evenhegemonic – that is, widely accepted, and embedded in institutionaland everyday practices.A<strong>no</strong>ther essential for emancipatory strategies is to reject the ‘false alternative’between the domination of nature – inherent in most of thestrategies outlined – and the subordination of society to the assumed‘laws of nature’ (Horkheimer and Ador<strong>no</strong> 1982). Both orientationsstrengthen a dichotomist view of nature as something outside of society.An adequate perspective lies in the conscious and democraticshaping of societal relationships with nature (Görg 2004). This alsoimplies a critique of any unilinear understanding of progress whichalways implied and still implies a deepening of the domination anddestruction of nature.


112 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateWhat, against this background, are the important aspects that mightstrengthen an emancipatory postneoliberal perspective? The followingoutline is by <strong>no</strong> means comprehensive but emphasises some importantpoints for general discussion.Taking experiences seriously: First of all, there needs to be ack<strong>no</strong>wledgementof the manifold experiences of <strong>no</strong>n-capitalist relationships withnature as well as the e<strong>no</strong>rmous variety of types of resistance to formsof appropriation that are shaped by domination – and their productiveand problematic dimensions. In many parts of the world, societalrelationships with nature have never been completely modern andcapitalist. However since the 1960s, neoliberal dynamics has tried tomodernise those regions of the world which were forgotten by the‘Green Revolution’. One major example is the South of Mexico andlarge parts of the states of Chiapas and Oaxaca. In other places, resistanceemerged from the local level and moved to the internationaland transnational level – examples include campaigns against genetically-modifiedorganisms or against free trade at the expense of localfarming. Alternative and attractive forms of producing and living, ofexchange, and of social divisions of labour and alternative identitiesare necessary – and they are possible: the protection of the naturalcommons (water, biodiversity, air, and so on) against their commodificationis in many cases a very concrete struggle. Collective consumption,the accompanying infrastructures, more energy efficiencyand sustainable goods are <strong>no</strong>t only linked to learning processes butmight also question the power of certain producers and the speed of‘throwaway’ globalisation.Alternative and attractiveforms of producing andliving, of exchange, and ofsocial divisions of labourand alternative identitiesare necessary – and they arepossible.Questioning the forms and contents of eco<strong>no</strong>mic growth: Social dominationis, among other things, codified in the concrete forms and characteristicsof eco<strong>no</strong>mic growth – that is, world market and politicalcompetition and the private appropriation of socially produced surplus,resource-intensive production and consumption. Under capitalistconditions, the wellbeing of societies and individuals is linked tothose forms of eco<strong>no</strong>mic growth that involve degradation of nature.Social domination also occurs through access to the means of socialreproduction (including k<strong>no</strong>wledge) and through distribution. Thealternative is <strong>no</strong>t just a shrinking of the eco<strong>no</strong>my but a transformatio<strong>no</strong>f the rationality linked to the capitalist mode of developmentwhich is inscribed into science and tech<strong>no</strong>logy, political institutions,subjectivities (the famous figure of the homo eco<strong>no</strong>micus) and so on(Leff 2008). Therefore, from an emancipatory perspective, the concreteforms and characteristics of growth and its societal preconditionsneed to be questioned and practically changed.


environmental crises and the ambiguous postneoliberalising of nature 113Creating linkages: Of utmost importance for emancipatory strategiesis the linking of different political and social issues. Their separationinto different ‘policy fields’ (including the competences of specificministries) is part of the technique of capitalist-bourgeois domination.One major example is the current separation of dominant policiesof ‘energy security’ in a context of growing competition for energyresources and control of the energy infrastructure. This is largelydelinked from policies to combat climate change. Dominant politicalactors often claim ‘policy coherence’ and ‘comprehensive approaches’but in fact coherence mirrors – according to form – existing powerrelations. From an emancipatory perspective, in many cases coherenceand integrated policies to deal with problems seriously are onlypossible if these power relations are changed.State politics matter: Politics in times of deep socio-ecological crisesmust be designed differently – that is, as a democratic and informedtransformative process that takes into consideration the many ambiguitiesthat exist, but with a view to creating a more just world basedon solidarity – beyond the dogma of competitiveness and profitability.Therefore, state and intergovernmental policies tend to be part ofthe problem rather than the solution. The state is <strong>no</strong>t a neutral entitycommitted to the general interest of society and wellbeing but firstand foremost an institutional condensation of societal relationships –that is, the main rationale of the state is to reproduce capitalist, patriarchaland racist relations as well as specific, socially constituted relationshipswith nature under which powerful as well as dominated socialgroups and individuals live. However, recent experiences in LatinAmerica show that emancipatory strategies also require forms of universalisation,legal codification and the backing of financial, discursiveand physical means. Moreover, the contribution of state policyto international environmental policy primarily lies in transformingit into more of a ‘domestic political’ matter. As important as internationalcooperation and so-called political regimes are, changes mustnevertheless be promoted within the particular societies and aboveall ‘on the ground’. This is where powerful <strong>no</strong>n-sustainable interestsand everyday orientations hold sway. Many studies on internationalenvironmental policy have shown that while international cooperationis important, what is decisive is securing implementation at thenation-state level. ‘Globalisation’ is often <strong>no</strong>thing more than an excuse.Governments, parliamentarians, parties and individuals in thestate apparatus have considerable room for ma<strong>no</strong>euvre.


114 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateSocio-ecological confl icts as starting point: We need to ask whether thehighly politicised topic of the environmental crisis and especially ofclimate change can open up a way for more transformative thinkingand action. Socio-ecological confl icts reveal that much more isat stake than symbolic policies to slow down climate change throughglobal resource management: questions of democracy and decisionmaking,power over social k<strong>no</strong>wledge and the means of production,the necessary reduction in working-hours, the valorising of reproductiveactivities concerning caring, health, food production, and soon. Environmental issues are profoundly linked to social issues. Exploitativework, especially of ‘illegal’ immigrants and many workersin the Global South, obeys the same logic of profit and accumulationwhich precipitates the destruction of nature. It is necessary to politiciseworkers about the cheap food, energy and other goods in whichthey have an immediate – that is, short-term – interest and which areproduced under unsustainable and unsocial conditions. However, thisalso represents a problem that needs to be solved. Emancipatory socio-ecologicalorientations and practices need to be linked to a morefundamental critique of the organisation of social life and of alienation,and to a redistribution of social wealth.Environmental justice: In many emancipatory struggles we can detectan orientation towards environmental justice. In contrast to the rathertech<strong>no</strong>cratic concept of sustainable development, this refers, to thecontested character of societal relationships with nature. Many environmentalproblems are <strong>no</strong>t socially neutral but affect different socialgroups, regions and societies differently. This was the analysis of theenvironmental justice movement which emerged in the US in the1980s. 7 They saw that, as usual, environmentally damaging activitieslike industrial production took place disproportionately in poorer, oftenblack communities. It is important to address the issue of the distributio<strong>no</strong>f environmental problems – spatially, at the local, regional,national and international level, and socially, in relation to class, genderand race. The political challenge is <strong>no</strong>t just to ‘distribute’ negativeenvironmental impacts equally but to question the dominant formsof production, distribution and consumption. The forms of accessto the material means of social and individual reproduction, and thepower-mediated framing of environmental problems or ‘the’ ecologicalcrisis, are both at stake. However, the concept of environmental7 The famous report ‘Toxic Waste and Race’ (United Church of Christ 1987) showedthat toxic waste in the US is concentrated.in those urban areas where poor peopleand people of colour live. The authors of this report invented the concept ofenvironmental justice, which became more and more important for groups contestingdominant destructive forms of the appropriation of nature (Bradley and Roberts 2006,Kaiser and Wullweber 2007).


environmental crises and the ambiguous postneoliberalising of nature 115It is important to addressthe issue of the distributio<strong>no</strong>f environmental problems –spatially, at the local, regional,national and internationallevel, and socially, in relation toclass, gender and race.justice is contested because governments and other actors intend tointegrate it into the strategy of ecological modernisation. At the sametime, critical perspectives need to reflect an awareness that the <strong>no</strong>tio<strong>no</strong>f justice itself is culturally bound (Bradley and Roberts 2006, Kaiserand Wullweber 2007).Radical demands and proposals: It might be useful to develop radical demandsand proposals through debates and the exchange of views andexperiences. These should be articulated in relation to specific problemsand alter the ways in which they are interpreted, thus offeringpossibilities for action. One major debate was initiated by WaldenBello’s quest for ‘deglobalisation’ of the international political eco<strong>no</strong>my(2002): he argues, among other things, for a need to reject Westernconsumerism and a focus on resources from outside via foreigndirect investment and proposes the promotion of environmentallysoundand local tech<strong>no</strong>logies, distributional justice, self-determinationand an important role for the democratic state. A major confl ictfield consists of the struggles against privatisation in response to theoverall negative experiences of the last 20 years. These are still rarelylinked to environmental issues and a debate about democratic andsustainable forms of the appropriation of nature. A similar debate isneeded in the light of the current financial and banking crisis.Learning processes and democracy: We should <strong>no</strong>t overlook the fact thatthe current problems are also caused by the relative material wellbeingof many people. Especially the middle-classes in Western coun-


116 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatetries but also the ‘new consumers’ in the Global South seemed andmany still seem to profit from current developments (Myers and Kent2004). A deeply rooted imperial subjectivity, involving a problematicrelationship with nature – where a subjectively more-or-less goodlife in some regions of the world or among certain groups can concealthe ecological and social consequences of that lifestyle elsewhere– has to be replaced by a new attitude. Therefore, it is <strong>no</strong>t e<strong>no</strong>ughto bargain over emissions targets; a broad and – since different interestsprevail – confl ictive learning process has to take place in order topromote alternative but attractive ways of living, producing and consuming,based on a relationship with ‘nature’ that goes beyond oneof domination. Emancipatory politics seeks to strengthen alternativestrategies and forms of living through cooperative learning processesand where necessary through confl ict. Next, questions of democracyarise. Who decides about production and investment? Who controlsaccess to k<strong>no</strong>wledge? To give one illustration: tech<strong>no</strong>logical development,with its profound consequences for societal relationships withnature (as, for example, in the case of genetic and na<strong>no</strong> tech<strong>no</strong>logies),and driven by intercapitalist competition, needs to be subjectto democratic discussion and decision-making. The existing forms ofrepresentative democracy are <strong>no</strong>t adequate. Here again it is clear thatthe solution to the problem should <strong>no</strong>t be seen as residing in Westernscientific k<strong>no</strong>wledge, intergovernmental processes and ecologicalmodernisation for the Western middle classes at the expense of manyothers, especially the poor and the earth’s resources.A brief outlook. The postneoliberal terrain is <strong>no</strong>t completely openbut relatively structured due to historical developments and currentpower relations. As we have seen, environmental issues are questionsof power and domination – though this is <strong>no</strong>t to simplify them asabove equals bad and below equals good. Unless linked to a practicalcritique of societal and socio-ecological domination, environmentalpolitics runs the risk of remaining a nice wellbeing programmefor the enlightened middle-classes. But in contrast to the 1970s, inmost countries there seem to be <strong>no</strong> relevant social forces that mightbe capable of changing the overall dynamics and orientation towardsthe exploitation of nature. However, the terrain is full of contingenciesand this might give critical thinking and emancipatory actiona chance. Therefore, we need a reflection of different strategies tomaintain and shape societal relationships with nature.


environmental crises and the ambiguous postneoliberalising of nature 117ReferencesAltvater, Elmar (1993), The Future of the Market,London and New York: Verso.Bello, Walden (2002), Deglobalization: Ideas for anew world eco<strong>no</strong>my, London: Zed.Parks, Bradley C. and Roberts, J. Timmons (2006),‘Environmental and ecological justice’, in Betsill,Michele M.; Hochstetler, Kathryn; and Stevis,Dimitris (eds), International environmental politics,Houndmills and New York: Palgrave, pp. 329-360.Brand, Ulrich and Görg, Christoph (2008), ‘Sustainabilityand Globalisation: A Theoretical Perspective’,in Park, Jacob;, Finger, Mathias; and Conca, Ken(eds), The Crisis of Global Environmental Governance:Towards a new political eco<strong>no</strong>my of sustainability,London and New York: Routledge, pp. 13-33.Brand, Ulrich; Görg, Christoph; Hirsch, Joachim; andWissen, Markus (2008), Confl icts in EnvironmentalRegulation and the Internationalisation of theState: Contested Terrains, London and New York:Routledge.Brand, Ulrich and Sekler, Nicola (<strong>2009</strong>, forthcoming),‘Struggling between Auto<strong>no</strong>my and InstitutionalTransformations. Social Movements in Latin Americaand the Move towards Post-Neoliberalism’, in Macdonald,Laura and Ruckert, Arne (eds), Post-Neoliberalismin the Americas: New York: Palgrave.Brunnengräber, Achim (2007), ‘Energiesicherheit vorKlimaschutz’, in Melber, Henning and Wilß, Cornelia(eds) (2007), G8 Macht Politik: Wie die Welt beherrschtwird, Frankfurt am Main: Brandes & Apsel,pp. 113-123.BUKO – Federal Coordination of Internationalism,Working Group on Social Ecology (2008), ‘VergesstKyoto! Die Katastrophe ist schon da’, in Widerspruch<strong>no</strong>. 54, pp. 149-159. Castree, Noel (2008), ‘Neoliberalising nature: Thelogics of deregulation and reregulation’, in Environmentand Planning, vol. 40, <strong>no</strong>. 2, pp. 131-152.Ceceña, Ana Esther (ed.), (2006), Los desafíos delas emancipaciones en un contexto militarizado,Bue<strong>no</strong>s Aires: CLACSO.Chatterjee, Pratap and Finger, Mathias (1994), Theearth brokers: Power, politics and world development,London: Routledge.Görg, Christoph (2004), ‘The construction of socialrelationships with nature’, in Poiesis & Praxis (SpecialVolume: ‘Focus on Biodiversity’), vol. 3, <strong>no</strong>. 1, pp22-36.Goldman, Michael (ed.) (1998), Privatizing Nature:Political struggles for the global commons, London:Routledge.Horkheimer, Max and Ador<strong>no</strong>, Theodor W. (1982),Dialectic of enlightenment, New York: Continuum.IPCC – Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change(2007), ‘Climate Change 2007: The Physical ScienceBasis’, Contribution of Working Group I to theFourth Assessment Report of the IntergovernmentalPanel on Climate Change, Paris (Summary for Policymakers,www.ipcc.ch).Kaiser, Gregor and Wullweber, Joscha (2007), ‘ÖkologischeGerechtigkeit’, in Brand, Ulrich;, Lösch, Bettina;and Thimmel, Stefan (eds), ABC der Alternativen,Hamburg: VSA, pp. 146-147.Leff, Enrique (2008), ‘Decrecimiento o Deconstrucciónden la Eco<strong>no</strong>mía: Hacia un Mundo Sustentable’,paper presented at ‘The Energetic Transitio<strong>no</strong>f Mexico: Towards the Postoil Era’, the 5th Colloquiumorganised by the Red Ecologista Autó<strong>no</strong>made la Cuenca de México, July 2008.MASR (2005), ‘Millennium Ecosystem AssessmentSynthesis Report’, Washington, DC: Island Press.http://www.millenniumassessment.org/Myers, Norman and Kent, Jenniffer (2004), TheNew Consumers: The Infl uence of Affl uence on theEnvironment, Washington: Island Press.Park, Jacob; Finger, Matthias; and Conca, Ken(2008), ‘The Death of Rio Environmentalism’, in Park,Jacob; Finger, Matthias; and Conca, Ken (eds), TheCrisis of Global Environmental Governance: Towardsa New Political Eco<strong>no</strong>my of Sustainability,London: Routledge.Stern, Nicholas (2006), ‘Stern Review on the Eco<strong>no</strong>micsof Climate Change’: www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/independent_reviews/stern_review_eco<strong>no</strong>mics_climate_change/sternreview_index.cfm


The crisis of neoliberalism and theimpasse of the union movementGregory AlboIt is impossible to separate analytically or politically the emergenceof neoliberalism as a set of policy proposals of the New Right in theearly 1980s from the defeat of working class politics and unions afterthe radicalisations of the 1960s and 1970s. From the outset, a centralthrust of neoliberal policies was wage and social austerity for workersto restore the profitability of capitalist firms and the capacity ofthe state to assist in eco<strong>no</strong>mic restructuring. These income policieswere supplemented by labour market policies for ‘flexibility’ and labourpolicies, especially in North America, targeted at weakeningunions in the workplace, in collective bargaining and as political actors(Albo 2008).The consolidation of neoliberalism across the 1990s saw its policyagenda expand in ambition and scope, particularly as social democraticparties (and the American Democratic Party) – the so-calledpolitical arm of the labour movement – began to incorporate neoliberalpolicies into their programmes and rule as neoliberals in power.Indeed, as new production tech<strong>no</strong>logies, in both manufacturing andservice sectors, intensified workplaces, extended management controlover labour processes and increased global competition between firmsand states over market shares and employment, the balance of powershifted decisively toward the capitalist classes. Unions became decidedlyweaker in making gains in collective bargaining, organising anddefending new members, especially in new service sector employmentand for migrant workers, and advancing their traditional redistributivepolicy agenda for social justice.The political climate since September 2001, particularly in NorthAmerica, has been especially hostile as slower eco<strong>no</strong>mic growth, militaryinterventions by the NATO countries and hard right governmentsbroke initial efforts by unions to form alliances with a fledglinganti-globalisation movement. The period of neoliberalism hasdepended upon – and meant – the organisational, eco<strong>no</strong>mic and politicalimpasse of the union movement. It exposed the limits of theunion movement in the core capitalist countries: the ideological failureto grasp the nature of neoliberal globalisation and union strategicand organisational capacity to respond to it.


120 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateIt is possible to see in the political conjuncture that has opened upsince the financial turbulence of 2007 began to grip the world market,however, an emerging crisis of neoliberalism. The overaccumulatio<strong>no</strong>f capital in key sectors in the US and Europe, particularly in commercialand residential real estate markets, auto production and financialservices, has led an eco<strong>no</strong>mic contraction that has been spreadingacross the world market. This crisis of global capitalism has been aggravatedby unprecedented turmoil in the financial sector due to theoverextension of credit, and the tax-cutting excesses and liberalisationpolicies of national governments and the international financialinstitutions. The credit expansion and crisis is <strong>no</strong>t the result of problemsof corporate governance or lax regulatory measures over thecapital leveraging of financial institutions, whatever role these mayhave in fact played. They are the consequences of structural imbalancesin the world market between trade surplus and deficit countries,and the undermining of working class incomes that were then compensatedby resort to credit markets to maintain relative living standards.Together, these global eco<strong>no</strong>mic trends have ended the exportled– particularly driven by high demand and prices for commodityexports in metals and fossil fuels – mini-boom over the last six yearsin many parts of the world, as well as the consumption-led upswingin the US that supported the exports.Over the first half of 2008, eco<strong>no</strong>mic growth in the advanced capitalistcountries has stalled to under 1 per cent on an annual basis, and furtherdeclines are expected for the second half of the year and beyond that.Growth forecasts across the world market are continuing to be lowered.These developments have meant that consumption-sensitive sectors,such as housing and retail, are suffering sharp declines in activity. Asspeculative financial and asset bubbles continue to burst – in mortgage,personal and commercial credit, in commodity markets, in hedge fundcapitalisation, and in the Yen-carry trade – financial chaos is deepeningin the core states and spreading globally. Bank credit and loan capitalof all kinds are tightening and even locking up. Radically looser monetarypolicies in the G20 countries, and a range of desperate measuresof state intervention into financial markets to restore confidence for investorsand bankers, have yet to yield any signs of eco<strong>no</strong>mic stability as2008 comes to a close. The spectres of deflation and a bout of stagnationare <strong>no</strong>w haunting the world market.As a consequence of the eco<strong>no</strong>mic slowdown and crisis, job losses aremounting in the labour market, and unemployment is beginning toclimb upward. This is intensifying a number of negative longer-termtrends in the labour market in the capitalist countries over the pe-


the crisis of neoliberalism and the impasse of the union movement 121riod of neoliberalism: downward pressures on real wages, an increasein precarious and marginal work, the undermining of public sectorservices and employment, increasing reliance on migrant workerswith restricted rights, and mounting global inequalities. It has furtherencouraged employers to step up their political struggles againstunions in favour of further policies of labour flexibilisation. Thereis developing, moreover, major employer efforts across the advancedcapitalist bloc to undermine (at the state level) and redefine or evenscrap (at the company level) workers’ pension plans, and to cut healthcareprovisions (private health plans in the US and public healthcareprovision in other countries). These calls from employers, despite thehardships they entail for working class people, have so far receiveda sympathetic hearing in the eco<strong>no</strong>mic policy-making branches ofstates. The initial policy efforts of governments have been an attemptto reconstruct the existing policy regime and political relations, despitethe severity of the recession limiting the possibility of doing so.It has become impossible tocontend that fl exible labourmarkets and de-unionisedworkplaces improved jobsecurity and pay.The eco<strong>no</strong>mic turmoil has produced, however, an ideological crisisof neoliberalism: the free market ideology that has been virtuallyuncontested at the level of political power for almost two decades is<strong>no</strong>w totally discredited. It has become impossible to contend thatsmaller states and liberalised markets will lead to prosperity for all (thetrickle-down thesis); that public services could be protected and improvedby increased reliance on markets (the theses of self-regulationand marketisation); that new financial instruments were spreadingrisk and increasing eco<strong>no</strong>mic stability (the theses of transparency andshareholder value as central to efficient capital allocation); that flexiblelabour markets and de-unionised workplaces improved job securityand pay (the thesis of all employment and unemployment as voluntaryindividual decisions); and that increased market dependence meant aparallel increase in freedom and equality (the thesis that all collectiveaction is coercive and anti-democratic). These theoretical claims byneoliberal ideologues have <strong>no</strong>w proven to be unmitigated failures aspolicy frameworks, and a social disaster for whole societies and workerswhere they have been adopted.What remains of neoliberalism, it needs to be underlined, is its politicalembeddedness in state structures, policy instruments and the politicalfield of social forces. The disorganisation of working class organisation,in unions and political parties, was one of the central objectivesof neoliberalism. It remains, at this point, the most formidable obstacleto both thinking about and establishing a postneoliberal political order.This is why it is necessary to make a deeper assessment of the impactof neoliberalism on the labour movement and the prospects for a newunion politics in the context of the renewal of the left.


122 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateUnion movement challengesUnions have been one of the most effective social movements for theadvancement of democracy and social justice in capitalist societies.Unions have been the first means by which workers, who to earn theirliving have only their labour to sell, struggle to equalise the advantagesthat the owners of capital assets have in bargaining over wagesand the distribution of new value-added activities in workplaces. Unionshave also continually campaigned, in conjunction with socialistparties, for the extension of democracy through advocacy of universalparticipation in politics, civil rights such as freedoms of association,assembly and dissent, and the universalisation of social programmesto meet the basic social needs of all. These struggles for social justicewere opposed historically by the capitalist classes, and the advent ofneoliberalism as the policy response of employers and conservativeparties renewed their anti-democratic efforts (Moody 1997).Neoliberalism sought to roll back the gains of unions and workers inthe workplace, and put an end to the push by unions and leftist partiesfor greater worker control in enterprises and democratic determinatio<strong>no</strong>f eco<strong>no</strong>mic priorities at the level of the state. Their policy responsewas measures to weaken unions in workplace representation, deregulatio<strong>no</strong>f labour markets, increased corporate property rights and freetrade in capital and goods. After a long period after the war in whichexpansionary state policies and high employment strengthened the bargainingpower of union, this was the first challenge unions faced.Restructuring led to the socalled‘new eco<strong>no</strong>my’: a risein service sector employment,lean production-intensifyingwork processes, fl exiblemanufacturing systems, <strong>no</strong>nstandardwork arrangementsand extensive resort tocheap migrant labour poolsand temporary workerprogrammes.Beginning with the eco<strong>no</strong>mic slowdown of the 1970s, and particularlyafter the ‘Volcker shock’ in the US in 1981-82 radically drove upUS and thus world interest rates to force an eco<strong>no</strong>mic restructuringto break workers’ wage expectations and power, an ‘employers’ offensive’ensued across the advanced capitalist countries. Employers begana series of labour-saving plant shutdowns and a major shift of productionto locales with lower union density, for example the southernUS and <strong>no</strong>rthern Mexico in the case of North America. Furtherworkplace restructuring continued through the 1990s. It took theform of the so-called ‘new eco<strong>no</strong>my’: a rise in service sector employment(especially linked to ICT – information and communicationstech<strong>no</strong>logies – and the mass growth of various kinds of low-paidservant work), lean production-intensifying work processes, flexiblemanufacturing systems, <strong>no</strong>n-standard work arrangements and extensiveresort to cheap migrant labour pools and temporary worker programmes.The ‘employers’ offensive’ and much higher levels of labourreserves meant that inter-worker competition increased as well, particularlyas migration and increased female participation changed the


the crisis of neoliberalism and the impasse of the union movement 123character of the working classes. Indeed, the entire period of neoliberalismhas seen a remarkable degree of wage compression and wideninggaps between the share of new value-added activity taken bycapital and that taken by workers.The pressure on wages and workplace controls has posed, in turn, achallenge for collective bargaining. This has often entailed extensiveefforts to overhaul union agreements to give management increasedflexibility in employment, deployment of workers and over wagestructures. This has been quite diverse in the forms it has taken acrossthe capitalist countries. In Europe, for example, this has been a formof ‘competitive corporatism’ where unions form social pacts withcompanies to increase competitiveness through wage restraint, newwork arrangements and long-term contracts; while in North Americaflexibilisation agreements have been a more common pattern in unionisedworkplaces, along with sustained efforts at de-unionisation.In traditional manufacturing strongholds in North America, this hasmeant that unions like the United Steelworkers have often engaged in‘partnership’ and co-management schemes introducing flexible workarrangements as a trade-off for some job protection and union security.And unions like the Canadian Autoworkers have been willingto forego the right to strike to gain union recognition to bargainwith auto parts companies, <strong>no</strong>tably Magna. The latter is a variatio<strong>no</strong>f the ‘voluntary recognition agreements’ of unions by managementoccurring in the service sector, often after long unsuccessful organisingcampaigns but extensive losses to corporate image and time,with unions accepting certain workplace and bargaining concessionsin the process. There have also been similar adjustments, again withsignificant national variations, to national and sectoral collective bargaininginstitutions. This has given variation to a common pattern ofwage compression and bargaining setbacks: the ‘shared austerity’ ofSweden, the ‘co-managed austerity’ of Germany, and the ‘punitiveausterity’ of Canada and the US.A third challenge has come in the form of flexible labour market policies.Neoliberal governments explicitly abandoned Keynesian eco<strong>no</strong>micpolicies geared towards full employment for monetarist policiesof ‘infl ation-targeting’. The latter has meant targeting low infl a-tion rates <strong>no</strong>rmed so that wage increases largely do <strong>no</strong>t surpass the rateof infl ation and thus all productivity gains are claimed by employers.It has also meant a preference for maintaining a ready pool of labour,available – because of a ‘natural rate of unemployment’ – to take upnew work, particularly in the service sector, as it becomes available.A<strong>no</strong>ther component of flexible policies has been restricting access to,


124 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateand reducing benefits for, programmes such as unemployment insuranceor social assistance. These are seen to cause disincentives towork and labour market rigidities which hamper eco<strong>no</strong>mic stability.Finally, flexible labour market policy has entailed a series of continualrestrictions on union organising and free collective bargaining, <strong>no</strong>tablythe increasing invocation of back-to-work and right-to-worklegislation across all North American jurisdictions.The internationalisation of capital and the global re-organisation oflabour processes has been a fourth challenge for unions. Multinationalcorporations have chosen expansion of international production networks,in particular distributing repetitive and ecologically damaginglabour process in poorer countries where low wages can be paid. Butthey also shifted higher value-added activities to places where unionstrength is much weaker to allow the introduction of new labourprocesses. This reorganisation has increased the leverage for employersthrough the threat of capital fl ight and the relative immobilityof labour. The World Trade Organiztion (WTO) and internationaltrade agreements such as the North American Free Trade Agreement(NAFTA), as well as the political arrangements of the European Union,all have rules restricting the ability of governments to impedecapital mobility. Moreover, they often contain clauses blocking moreactive industrial policies. Workers in Mexico, for example, earn aboutone-tenth or less of the wages of workers in Canada and the US forsimilar work; the initial period of NAFTA saw some 2 million lessskilled jobs move to Mexico, particularly in the maquilas free tradezones in the <strong>no</strong>rthern border states. Parallel global pressures have hitMexican workers, and indeed all workers, by the massive shift of somuch of the world’s manufacturing capacity to China and other lowwageAsian countries. The internationalisation of capitalism, aided bytrade liberalisation and new trade rules, further compels employers todrive down unit labour costs and hold back wage gains.Indeed, the weakening of unions, in turn, fuels competition betweenworkers and further shifts the balance of power in favour of employers,In the most recent phase of neoliberalism, this has lead tothe embrace of ‘competitive unionism’. The inequalities and divisionsbetween workers as a consequence become <strong>no</strong>t only greater,but embedded in the very logic of union organisation and strategy.With competitive unionism, union democracy, mobilisational capacityand ideological independence from employers all become strainedor even atrophy.


the crisis of neoliberalism and the impasse of the union movement 125Union density in the US, forinstance, has declined to justover one in 10 workers beingin a union today, and morethan a dozen core capitalisteco<strong>no</strong>mies have seen anabsolute decline in unionmembership.New struggles, new movement?The challenges that emerged with neoliberalism put union movementsin the advanced capitalist countries on the defensive and, inmore than a few cases, meant a decisive defeat. Union density in theUS, for instance, has declined to just over one in 10 workers being ina union today, and more than a dozen core capitalist eco<strong>no</strong>mies haveseen an absolute decline in union membership. This reflects, in part,the difficulty of organising the service sector. But the inability of collectivebargaining to deliver systematic real wage gains and to blockwelfare state reforms also tells of the broader impasse of the labourmovement over the period of neoliberalism.Still, despite the major challenges, it is necessary to <strong>no</strong>te that keystruggles and signs of political resistance keep surfacing, from bothinside the labour movement and also associated social forces andmovements (Schenk and Kumar 2006). In North America, some ofthis has come from ‘living wage’ struggles led by local labour councilsin major cities, in alliance with community groups, to reach outto the low-waged and u<strong>no</strong>rganised, who are predominantly womenand people of colour. The mass immigrants’ rights May Day protests,as well as the day-to-day campaigns for the protection of <strong>no</strong>n-statusworkers, have taken place outside the main union movements, butalso led to new linkages and alliances. Similar types of struggles arehelping to rebuild local labour movements in many countries. Despiteoften defensive and weak leadership beaten down by neoliberalattacks, central labour organisations are also developing a new senseof urgency, at least in the sense of convention resolutions on organising,mobilising and political issues. If there is still great distance togo in translating sentiment into political action, it does suggest somesignificant openings for rebuilding the labour movement.The eco<strong>no</strong>mic recession, in the most pressing example of an openingfor new union activism, is leading to a major decline in employment.The weekly an<strong>no</strong>uncements of workplace layoffs and closures in themanufacturing sector suggest an even further undermining of ‘goodjobs’ in core union strongholds. The layoffs are spreading across theservice sector as well, with the often female and mi<strong>no</strong>rity workforcesthere moving from precarious work to <strong>no</strong> work at all. In early 2008,employer pressures on collective bargaining were already visible, andthe long period of neoliberalism has encouraged employers in crisisto adopt all kinds of abuses of severance and overtime pay, pensio<strong>no</strong>bligations and so forth. At a time when governments are also bailingout banks and financial institutions, the building of an anti-concessionsmovement is <strong>no</strong>t only a necessity for the union movement,


126 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatebut it will have broad popular appeal. This can begin with oppositionto contract concessions on worktime and wages, but more militantworkplace tactics such as plant occupations and community confiscatio<strong>no</strong>f assets will have to be explored. In reaching out to u<strong>no</strong>rganisedsectors with vulnerable workers facing abusive employers, ‘flyingsquads’ of union militants need to be actively built up as part of ananti-concessions movement. Indeed, ‘organising the u<strong>no</strong>rganised’ hasto be a central component of an anti-concessions campaign. It wouldhave to include a campaign for a new legal framework favouring unio<strong>no</strong>rganising to overturn neoliberal policies of deunionisation. In amoment of eco<strong>no</strong>mic crisis and political transition, such a movementhas to extend beyond the defence of particular plants and workers tobe framed as a class and community demand.A second opening is in the public sector where workers have confrontedboth limits on their rights and deteriorating working conditions aspublic services have declined as a result of neoliberal policies. It is possibleto envision new kinds of union campaigns linking public sectorworkers and communities, producers and users, in opposition to neoliberalism.It can also be insisted that responses to the eco<strong>no</strong>mic slowdownbegin with restoring the public sector, since so many years of financialsector-led growth has ended in the current debacle. A numberof campaigns – <strong>no</strong>tably some of the anti-privatisation struggles aroundhealthcare, universities and municipal services – have had successesacross several countries. These community-union alliances have oftenlacked full union support, even when major campaigns and demonstrationssuggest e<strong>no</strong>rmous potential. This is, however, also a reflectionthat social democratic parties have moved to a ‘post-class’, ‘post-partisan’,and ‘post-campaigning’ managerial culture. Unions and communitygroups have been fighting without organising support at the politicallevel of forces that these campaigns engage. But whatever the limits,new organisational capacities of the unions and the left, in both connectionsand political consciousness, keep being built in the process.It is possible to envision newkinds of union campaignslinking public sector workersand communities, producersand users, in opposition toneoliberalism.The closing of the gap between international solidarity and socialjustice movements and the union movement is a third opening thatneeds to become central to union strategy and struggle (Waterman2001). The formation of international production networks has partlymade this a central need for collective bargaining. Works councilsand campaigns are needed across companies and sectors as a basicmechanism to reduce competition between workers (rather thanserve as a mechanism, as works councils have sometimes been, toincrease company competitiveness) and to form a capacity to coordinatestruggles. There have been interesting examples of these ef-


the crisis of neoliberalism and the impasse of the union movement 127forts in the steel, auto and healthcare sectors extending from NorthAmerica to both Europe and Latin America, with perhaps some of themost interesting campaigns forming in the fight against the militantlyanti-union Wal-Mart. But the common interest of different unionmovements in class struggle against international corporations has yetto form at the strategic and organisational levels. With union movementson the defensive on a national basis from neoliberalism, it hasbeen hard to forge new international solidarities. But union and socialjustice struggles between one country and a<strong>no</strong>ther are more linked<strong>no</strong>w than ever as a part of global production systems.Such an orientation also puts on the union agenda other internationalsolidarity campaigns: <strong>no</strong>tably against the intolerable conditions ofPalestinian workers in the Occupied Territories and inside apartheidIsrael; against the continued assaults on unionists in Columbia; for therights of migrant workers; for the rights of workers in countries likeVenezuela to nationalise industry and experiment in workers’ control;and against the NATO alliance wars of intervention and occupation.These internationalist campaigns require a significant re-orientationby union centrals and affi liates, but they could play a disproportionaterole in union renewal.The very defeat of the union movement in the advanced capitalistcountries at the hands of neoliberalism provides a fourth opening.It requires unions to fundamentally assess and transform their owninstitutions and practices in the struggle for a postneoliberal – evenpostcapitalist – order. This is partly about looking at the organisationaldivisions of unions as they <strong>no</strong>w exist. It is especially about a processthat sees unions as developing workers’ capacities and contributingto building a different society – social justice unionism (Fletcher andGaspasin 2008). This entails democratising the internal practices ofunions, expanding education of members, encouraging rank and fileactivism in leading strategic orientations and struggles, and examiningunion practices on gender and race and incorporating a diversemembership into an equally diverse leadership.These are steps of internal organisational renewal. But it is also necessaryto re-insert unions as a central component of wider strugglesabout work and production. One way is through extending unionmembership into workplaces even where a majority membership has<strong>no</strong>t been attained as a means to break through employers’ hostility orto amalgamate workers dispersed across small service-sector worksites.A<strong>no</strong>ther is to make local labour councils key centres of workingclass political activism. This has been an aspect behind ‘union city’


128 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateorganising campaigns and also campaigns for living wages and immigrantworkers’ rights. It is possible to see this approach extendinginto other activities, from issues of local development and ‘jobs andjustice’ campaigns to assemblies of working class organisations. Organisationalrenewal in both its internal and outreach dimensions iscrucial to forging a new form of postneoliberal ‘common sense’ in theday-to-day activities of union members.If these openings lead to new political struggles that create wider tractionacross the union movement, a reversal of the way neoliberalismhas damaged working class organisation will have begun. In such acontext, it is possible to envision an outline of an alternative uniondevelopment model emerging. In collective bargaining, for example,new ways to address wage improvements and employment expansioncould be adopted. Solidaristic work policies that radically redistributework through work-time reduction, overtime caps, and sabbatical andparental leave might be vigorously pursued. Bargaining might put anannual work-time reduction factor alongside an annual wage improvementfactor (set to reduce social and wage inequalities) for sharing-outof productivity gains. Work-time reduction could also be put towardseducation and skills that expand the capacity for self-management atwork and leadership in the community. And alternative workers’ plansfor quality, ecologically responsible production – an imperative, giventhe need to make a ‘green’ transition to a carbon emissions-neutralenergy eco<strong>no</strong>my – could begin to build the foundation for expandingworkers’ control over enterprises. An expansionary fiscal policy torespond to the eco<strong>no</strong>mic crisis might <strong>no</strong>t only rebuild the public sector,but also be linked to unionisation and a longer-term strategy tore-establish a redistributional tax system. Such a postneoliberal agendaemerging from the unions movement will, of course, be equally aboutthe renewal of the left.Organisational renewal inboth its internal and outreachdimensions is crucial to forginga new form of postneoliberal‘common sense’ in the dayto-dayactivities of unionmembers.Renewal of the leftThe impasse of the union movement is, in this sense, also reflectiveof a wider decline of the left, in North America and, indeed,globally (Panitch and Leys 2001). Working class political organisation,in unions and parties, achieved a great deal in the course of the20th century: leading de-colonisation and self-determination struggles;struggling for liberal freedoms and democracy; improving wagesand benefits; and advancing welfare states and social citizenship. Butthe social forces that achieved these gains are <strong>no</strong>w quite different: thecommunist parties have, for good and ill, all but disappeared even inplaces where they once held power (or they have made their peace


the crisis of neoliberalism and the impasse of the union movement 129with capitalism as in China); the social democratic parties have politicallyre-aligned to chart a ‘Third Way’ that <strong>no</strong> longer even poses areform agenda to neoliberalism; unions are in retreat; and many civilsociety movements have evolved into professionalised NGOs navigatingthe grant eco<strong>no</strong>my. The central political coordinates for labourmovements over the last century – being for or against the Russianrevolution; attempting a vanguard seizure of the existing state apparatusor reforming it piecemeal; conceiving unions as primarily theindustrial wing of this or that political party – vanished almost at thesame pace as neoliberalism consolidated as the all-encompassing socialform of rule.From both the neoliberal assault on unions and the decline of socialistparties, there emerged the sense across the left of ‘starting over’in mapping out the organisational and strategic agendas for socialjustice and socialism, to the extent that the latter was still seen as adesirable objective at all. This meant initially, especially in Canadabut soon spreading to the US and other parts of the world, an effortto work through social coalitions apart from political parties. In thisschema, unions are only one <strong>no</strong>de in a network of oppositional power.This strategic outlook became incorporated into the anti-globalisationmovement at the end of the 1990s as a clustering of dissidentgroupings, with unions cautiously making linkages to the movementthrough so-called ‘Teamster-Turtle Alliances’.This political ‘movement’ has had, more or less, three predominantclusters. One has been remnants of the radical left, and certain strandsof Trotskyism in particular, that emphasise global resistance ‘frombelow’, and that in the revolutionary juncture near at hand that a‘Leninist’ organisation is still the necessary vanguard for a deepeninganti-capitalist movement. A second has been an uneasy mix of anarchist,libertarian and indige<strong>no</strong>us groups with the view that a combinatio<strong>no</strong>f spontaneous rebellion and alternative direct practices coulddirectly confront – and also bypass – existing capitalist states. And,third, a more encompassing ‘anti-power’ politics standpoint that hascontended that neither party <strong>no</strong>r programme is necessary as the leftcan ‘change the world without taking power’. These views have all,in certain ways, made a contribution to a revitalised anti-capitalistpolitics. They have continued on in the loose organisation form ofthe World Social Forum, with its national and local offshoots. Most ofthese decentralised forums have floundered, however, and exist onlyas occasional regionalised social justice fairs with little or <strong>no</strong> capacityto engage in organised political struggle.


130 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateIt is often claimed that the anti-globalisation movement was ‘cutshort’ when US President Bush began his ‘war on terror’ after September11, 2001. This requires a sober assessment of the organisationalstate of the movement and its seeming eclipse over the last years. Itseems clear that its ‘network’ vision of power has <strong>no</strong>t been adequatelygrounded in working class politics – a renewal of unions, day-to-daycommunity struggles, and the contestation of the class power crystallisedin state power and institutions. The movement of the Westernpowers towards the policy of a ‘long war’ across the Middle East, forinstance, did <strong>no</strong>t give added vitality to the anti-globalisation movement.This is especially surprising given the strengths of the globalpeace movements in fighting the Second Cold War of the 1980s andthe first Iraq War. Similarly, the lack of grounded organisation has leftunions and the left as a whole floundering in both protest and strategicresponse to the financial crisis and the largest single blow to neoliberalhegemony yet struck.It is hard <strong>no</strong>t to conclude that the political thinking and organisationalforms that emerged with the anti-globalisation movement havebeen quite limited in capacity and tentative in strategy. It has <strong>no</strong>tyielded a viable means to contest political hegemony and power ina period of neoliberal globalisation, and the spread of liberal democraticpolitical institutions. The ‘national-popular’ framing of the issuesof the day by neoliberalism, discredited as it has become, has <strong>no</strong>tyet been displaced by a socialist version of ‘common sense’ that wouldseem fundamental to charting a path out of a neoliberal social order.If the anti-globalisation movement was quite right to insist on the necessityof moving beyond political frameworks formed in quite differenthistorical moments and contexts, it has failed to supply the political,ideological, organisational and working-class resources essentialto building a postneoliberal order, let alone the capacity to contestcapitalism at the political level of social forces.The sudden setback of a movement that seemed so compelling, vibrantand globally engaged has been politically unsettling. It has necessarilygiven way to a period of experimentation in new left politicalformations and organisational creativity. This can be seen inthe important political struggles in Latin America under the bannerof building 21st century socialism. Significant political realignmentsand breakthroughs appear also to be unfolding in Greece, Germany,France, Portugal and other places. This can hardly be said to be thecase in North America: from once leading some of the most <strong>no</strong>teworthyfightbacks against neoliberalism and globalisation in the 1990s,against NAFTA and in Seattle and Quebec City, the North American


the crisis of neoliberalism and the impasse of the union movement 131left is deeply fractured, at an organisational dead-end and only beginningto pose the question of how to build anti-neoliberal political alliancesand a new politics of a pluralist left (Aro<strong>no</strong>witz 2006).There is, then, profound unevenness in the renewal of the left in differentparts of the world. In all cases there are only fragile linkages tounion movements and only the beginnings of the remaking of workingclass political organisation. But a new dynamic of struggle seemsto be unfolding. As neoliberalism enters a phase of crisis, importantstruggles are being waged in workplaces, communities and states.These struggles have quickly been coming up against the obstaclesput in place by neoliberalism and the limits of existing working classorganisational capacities. Even the best union campaigns and mostsignificant struggles soon reach these limits and have had to makeevery effort to push beyond them.In the first instance, the fights to preserve jobs and pensions, publichealthcare and community spaces for women, to improve the statusof immigrant workers, or against imperialist wars in the Middle andFar East, has led to efforts to connect anti-neoliberal struggles acrossunions and communities. Increasingly, such struggles are pushing unionactivists and movements in the direction of anti-capitalist politicsto oppose the barbarism that is neoliberalism in crisis. This wave ofstruggle is only in its earliest stages, and still needs to be set against thebackdrop of neoliberal power structures and union impasse, particularlyin North America, where the labour movements are just beginningthe long process of renewal. Yet, glimmers of hope are breakingthrough the structures of neoliberalism: the possibility for remakingworking class organisations, and the active rediscovering of a 21stcentury socialism that is the necessary condition for imagining andmaking actual a postneoliberal social order.ReferencesAlbo, G. (2008), ‘Neoliberalism and the Discontented’in Panitch L.and Leys C. (eds), Socialist Register:Global Flashpoints: Reactions to Imperialism andNeoliberalism (London: Merlin Press).Aro<strong>no</strong>witz, S. (2006), Left Turn: Forging a NewPolitical Future, Boulder: Paradigm.Fletcher, B. and Gaspasin, F. (2008), SolidarityDivided: The Crisis in Organized Labor and a NewPath Toward Social Justice, Berkeley: University ofCalifornia Press.Kumar, P. and Schenk, C. (eds) (2006), Paths toUnion Renewal, Toronto: Garamond.Moody, K. (1997), Workers in a Lean World, London:Verso.Panitch, L. and Leys, C. (eds) (2001), SocialistRegister: Working Classes, Global Realities, London:Merlin Press.Waterman, P. (2001), Globalization, SocialMovements, and the New Internationalisms, NewYork: Continuum.


Women peasants, food securityand biodiversity in the crisis ofneoliberalismChrista WichterichFrom the perspective of feminist eco<strong>no</strong>mics, the neoliberal systemwith its functional principles of efficiency, competition and orientationto profits goes against the operative rationality of provision andco-operation in the care and subsistence eco<strong>no</strong>mies with which socialreproduction and food security is guaranteed, above all by womenand their unpaid labour. Certainly, capitalist markets have overarched,penetrated and functionalised such traditional moral survivaleco<strong>no</strong>mies for a long time. However, neoliberalisation is <strong>no</strong>t acomprehensive and definitively closed process, but rather, consists inincomplete and <strong>no</strong>n-contemporaneous phases of integration, interlinkingand subjugation. After every crisis, political and eco<strong>no</strong>micforces set about organising new neoliberal projects and conquer newfields and terrains that were previously only partially or marginallyintegrated.In a complex contradictory relationship, neoliberal politics and eco<strong>no</strong>micsdefine care and subsistence eco<strong>no</strong>mies – private households,unpaid labour and nature – as extra-eco<strong>no</strong>mic and unproductive.At the same time, however, they presuppose care work as infinitelyflexible, extendable and indispensable base and social security net forthe monetarised eco<strong>no</strong>my. Without them, the market sphere can<strong>no</strong>twork (Elson 1991). Furthermore, neoliberal politics and eco<strong>no</strong>micsfunctionalise and eco<strong>no</strong>mise selective elements of these sectors. Capitalistintervention places natural, human and intellectual resourcesin the sphere of eco<strong>no</strong>mic value, integrating them according to requirementsinto its valorisation processes and, in cases of diminishedprofitability, throwing them back into the care and subsistenceeco<strong>no</strong>mies.At the same time, these markets seek to increase their efficiency byexternalising ecological and social costs and pushing them into thespheres defined as extra-eco<strong>no</strong>mic. Crises are softened and administeredby a downloading of costs, burdens and risks into the kitchens,onto the peasants’ fields, onto the women performing unpaid carework and into the environment (Elson 2002). Market integration and


134 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatecost externalisation are thus entwined processes and modes of functioningof the neoliberal system.It is <strong>no</strong>t only that markets – and this is shown once again by the currentfood supply crisis – fail in relation to securing social reproductionand food. Even more: they represent, in their tendency to crisis,a threat both to social and food security and to the functional logicof social reproduction, of production and use of local experientialk<strong>no</strong>wledge, as well as of agriculture based on natural processes ratherthan on industrialised methods and inputs.In the wake of intensified growth and competition, women have beenincreasingly integrated in recent years into the markets as self-responsibleand independent actors, while gender has been integrated intopolitical programmes. Precisely because this construction of womenas fully fledged, self-responsible market subjects latches on to emancipatorykey images of feminism such as self-determination, individualfreedom, independent securing of existence, liberation from patriarchalcontrol and public participation, it is historically an advance ingender equity. On the other hand, we are dealing here with an integrationthat has been instrumentally established in line with neoliberalgoals, and with steps towards equal opportunity that obey therules of the game of the system instead of changing them – as initiallyaimed at by feminism.Women peasants, biodiversity and local k<strong>no</strong>wledgeWith their kitchen gardens in local communities, women are responsiblefor the food crops that secure the food supply. Cash crops andmonetary income are, on the other hand, defined as masculine. Theconstruction of women’s roles as food providers, as guarantors of thebiodiversity of food plants and of seeds, continues, even though manywomen peasants also perform a great part of the ongoing work onmen’s cash crop fields or produce fruit, vegetable or flowers for exportas contract farmers and daily labourers: that is, they are integratedinto transnational agricultural valorisation processes and contexts(Wichterich 2004).With their kitchen gardens inlocal communities, women areresponsible for the food cropsthat secure the food supply.Cash crops and monetaryincome are, on the other hand,defi ned as masculine.Masculine and feminine roles in agriculture are constructed withinthe gender-specific division of labour and in the context of the dualagricultural production system – commercial, chemical-intensive mo<strong>no</strong>cultures,on the one hand, and mixed cultures geared towards localmarkets and self-sufficiency, on the other. Under the influence of localregional and global market forces and in the socio-cultural allocation of


women peasants, food security and biodiversity in the crisis of neoliberalism 135gender-specific tasks and capacities, traditional responsibilities and socialascription of masculinity and femininity are entangled in ever-newways and transform power relations (Krishna 2004; Rupp 2007).The Guatemalan peasant women who design their kitchen gardenlike many spirals turning into each other of corn, sweet potatoes andother vegetables are tied by a mixture of survival pragmatism, ancestorworship and natural philosophy to their land and biodiversity.They treat both as an inheritance from their ancestors, from whichthey are <strong>no</strong>t allowed <strong>no</strong>r want to separate themselves through sale.The plots should remain in the clan or in the ethnic community, i<strong>no</strong>rder to ensure their survival and well-being.The peasant women have had their own understanding of biodiversityand of the seed as their own means of production ‘for centuries’.They see their work self-consciously as value-creating activity andtheir k<strong>no</strong>wledge as productive capacity, with the help of which theyhave <strong>no</strong>t only maintained the genetic stock, but have productivelyfurther developed it. Furthermore, they have accumulated detailedk<strong>no</strong>wledge of the nutritional value and healing powers of local species.Traditional k<strong>no</strong>wledge in these reproduction contexts is a constitutiveelement of survival spaces and a central livelihood resource(Kuppe 2002). The women peasants therefore understand themselvesas investors: they give value to the plants and develop their productivity,which in its turn ensures that the women enjoy esteem in thecommunity.Their practical and strategic interest in biodiversity and in food securityoften brings the women peasants into confl ict with their men.Official government agricultural advisors offer the men commercialseeds and praise the advantages and earning possibilities of mo<strong>no</strong>cultures,recently above all those of organic fuel. In Burkina Faso,many peasants followed the desire of the government and plantedcotton, reducing the fields of the women, in order to have moreland available for the allegedly lucrative cotton. The women neverthelesscontinued to foster and care for biodiversity in the kitchengardens. It was precisely that which ensured their food supply whenthe cotton prices on the world market fell into the basement. Peasantwomen in Tanzania had a similar experience. In a subversiveaction, they planted banana trees and cabbage between the coffeetrees, even though the government had forbidden mixed farmingon the export fields.


136 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateProtection of species diversity and market mainstreamingWhen COP9 1 , the ninth conference of the signatory countries of theConvention on Biological Diversity (CBD) and the fourth conferenceof the members of the Cartagena Protocol on Biological Security(MOP4) 2 met in Bonn in May 2008, there was a <strong>no</strong>table confrontationin the parallel civil society forum Planet Diversity in a women’sworkshop. An official of the secretariat of the CBD proudly presentedthe CBD Gender Plan of Action to the workshop participants, predominantlyactivists with a peasant or environmental NGO background.3The CBD Gender Plan of Action was accepted, after a year of lobbyingand of overcoming of some resistance, as a reference documentfor the COP9. Reference documents should inform the signatorypartners, but they nevertheless are <strong>no</strong>t objects of negotiation andhave <strong>no</strong> binding character. Gender experts celebrate the action planas successful ack<strong>no</strong>wledgement of their concern to direct politicalattention in the field of biodiversity to the goal of general equal opportunity.It repeats the dictum of many UN documents, namely,that gender equality and the empowerment of women are importantpreconditions for the protection of the environment and sustainabledevelopment, and recognises women’s k<strong>no</strong>wledge of biodiversity andtheir role in the management and protection of resources.The main goal of the action plan is to integrate a gender-responsiveperspective into the framework of the CBD with the help of gendermainstreaming, and to allow women to participate in the governancemechanisms, the negotiations and implementation. In opposition tothe technical procedure, however, questions of content regardingthe relation of gender and biodiversity nevertheless remain ig<strong>no</strong>red.What, then, does a gender perspective mean in relation to biodiversity?Does it mean the goal of gender equality? Is it an instrumentfor the recognition of gender-specific needs and interests? Or againstthe discrimination of women in the CBD process? And is a genderperspective on biodiversity related to the perspective of peasant agri-1 COP stands for Conference of the Parties, the meeting of the delegates of 190signatory countries of the CBD (Convention on Biological Diversity).2 Meeting of the Parties, meeting of the member states of the member states of theCartagena Protocol, which is a supplement to the CBD regulating dealings withgenetically modifi ed organisms (GMOs) in international trade.3 UNEP/CBD/COP/9/INF/12, Convention on Biological Diversity: The Gender Plan ofAction under the Convention on Biological Diversity, 11 March 2008, http://www.cbd.int/cop9/doc/


women peasants, food security and biodiversity in the crisis of neoliberalism 137culture or to the perspective of the large landowners, the perspectiveof indige<strong>no</strong>us ethnic groups or of agribusinesses? These questions alreadysuggest that the action plan as an instrument that aims only atthe integration of gender and the participation of women disregardsboth the production relations as well as the micro-eco<strong>no</strong>mic level ofresource usage of different actors in their dealings with biodiversity(see also Wichterich 2007).The representatives of women peasants and activists at Planet Diversitycorrespondingly reacted indignantly to this Gender Plan ofAction that claimed to represent their interests. 4 It is neither in theirstrategic <strong>no</strong>r their existential interest that their agricultural biodiversityis put into terms of eco<strong>no</strong>mic value on the world market or takenaway from their usage and preserved in nature reserves. The womendon’t want to be mainstreamed or to engage in negotiations that presupposetheir expropriation. They don’t want to share in profits thatbusinesses make with their resources. Rather, they want to preventthe transformation of their agricultural biodiversity and their k<strong>no</strong>wledgeinto trade commodities. Instead of the freedom of businessesand trade, they demand the freedom of self-determined productionindependent of the world market and the exchange of seed amongthemselves. As women peasants they are afraid of a double depreciation:the lack of the food sovereignty based upon biodiversity and thelack of the appreciation that they enjoy as the food suppliers of thelocal communities.Women peasants are afraid ofa double depreciation: the lackof the food sovereignty basedupon biodiversity and the lackof the appreciation that theyenjoy as the food suppliers ofthe local communities.4 http://www.planet-diversity.org, http://www.wloe.org/Women-of-Planet-Diversity.539.0.html


138 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateIndustrialisation of agriculture and thecommodifi cation of biodiversityIn the phase of agroindustrial modernisation in the name of the ‘greenrevolution’, the locally generated, resource-specific experientialk<strong>no</strong>wledge of peasants was initially overlooked and deemed uselessin the new contexts of production and valorisation. Under the sig<strong>no</strong>f neoliberal globalisation, however, even this in situ k<strong>no</strong>wledge andthe local biodiversity become an object of strategies of selective marketisationand exploitation. Free trade is supposed to create access forthe market and entrepreneurs even to the last ‘unexploited’ resourcesand to squeeze them along with the local usage k<strong>no</strong>wledge connectedwith it into the commodity form in transnational markets.The biodiversity convention that was set in motion by the UN Conferenceon Environment and Development in Rio de Janeiro in 1992links the market logic with the necessity of protection. On the onehand, biological diversity should be included in global commoditycompetition and the profit cycle; on the other hand, it should be protectedby being zoned as nature protection parks –excluding the indige<strong>no</strong>usowners. With the offer of benefit-sharing, the CBD tries tomediate between the long-established proprietors of biodiversity andthe private eco<strong>no</strong>my, which wants to appropriate genetic resourceswith patents and commercialise them. Sharing in profits here servesas stimulus for the communities, which collectively own biodiversity,to agree to the commercialisation. Flanking the UN convention, freetrade agreements codify the protection of biodiversity as environmentalservices and as a liberalised sector with rules for intellectualproperty rights (TRIPS) 5 .The appropriation and patenting of genetic material and traditionalk<strong>no</strong>w-how about food resources by agribusinesses and pharmaceuticalcompanies disembeds these from their spatio-temporal and socialpractice of usage and tries to treat them in a decontextualised form asa commodity. This privatisation of the collective survival capital ofbiodiversity and k<strong>no</strong>wledge is in opposition to the concept of propertyand survival of the women peasants. For them, the biodiversitybuilt into and further developed in the logic of their provision eco<strong>no</strong>myis a model opposed to the dominant concept of development,5 Trade Related Intellectual Property Rights. The agreement on trade related rightsof intellectual property was added to the General Agreement on Trade and Tariffs(GATT), under pressure from US industry. It obliges all members of the World TradeOrganization (WTO) to implement the strong regulations of the patent rights ofindustrial countries in national law.


women peasants, food security and biodiversity in the crisis of neoliberalism 139which, with the dogmas of the market and of growth, advocates mo<strong>no</strong>culturesin the fields and in the mind, and which wants to integratelocal species, seed and indige<strong>no</strong>us k<strong>no</strong>wledge into the business logicof the global markets. Whether or <strong>no</strong>t preceded by a scientific inventoryof profitable genetic resources (bioprospection), biopiracy or acontract of sale – for the women the transformation of genetic materialinto patents and commodities, is appropriation of resources and athreat to their mode of existence and production.The current supply crisis in the world agromarkets shows that foodsecurity can<strong>no</strong>t be guaranteed by industrial mass production and freetrade, but rather, on the contrary, is massively threatened by it. Forpeasant women, this is confirmation that food supply can be best securedthrough cultivation on the basis of local biodiversity and forlocal markets. Capitalism, as <strong>no</strong>ted by Marina Meneses Velazquez,corn farmer and city councillor for ecology in Juchitan in Mexico,proposes false solutions for peasant agriculture: commercialisation ofresources and integration into the world market, on the one hand;nature protection zones for the conservation of biodiversity, on theother hand. Both expropriate the women.Alternative banks and stock exchangesAs the diversity of local species and k<strong>no</strong>wledge was lost with theintroduction of mo<strong>no</strong>cultures, peasant women from Zimbabwe toBangladesh began to set up, or to reanimate, their own banks andexchange systems for seeds (Akhter 2001). Their orientation to theAgainst the annihilationand theft of traditionalk<strong>no</strong>wledge, peasant womenand grassroots movementsorganise capacity-building inlocal communities, in order tomaintain traditional k<strong>no</strong>wledgeand passed-down skills thatrisk being forgotten.


140 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateneeds of producers went against the valorisation interests of the agribusinessesand the world market. In seed movements in India andin Southern Africa, peasant women collect seed, themselves conductbiological classification, research and qualitatively high-value seedpropagation, set up collective seed banks and organise seed festivalswith exchanges for k<strong>no</strong>wledge and seed. Thus they cross, cultivateand develop the crop, always adapting it to local necessities. Thesepractices form and prove their k<strong>no</strong>wledge and abilities of maintainingbiological diversity and of proliferating in forms independent of themarket (eed and Hoering 2002).Against the annihilation and theft of traditional k<strong>no</strong>wledge, peasantwomen and grassroots movements therefore organise capacity-buildingin local communities as memory-building, in order to maintaintraditional k<strong>no</strong>wledge and passed-down skills that risk being forgotten:for example, k<strong>no</strong>wledge about indige<strong>no</strong>us plant and tree speciesand methods of seed proliferation. The reactivation and passing on ofindige<strong>no</strong>us k<strong>no</strong>wledge systems implies an upgrading of this k<strong>no</strong>wledgein comparison with modern k<strong>no</strong>w-how and an empowermentin order to secure one’s own survival and food supply.Networks like that around the NGO Community Tech<strong>no</strong>logy DevelopmentTrust (CTDT) in Southern Africa, the Coalition in Defenceof Diversity in India or the South Asia Network on Food, Ecologyand Culture (SANFEC) demand from governments and multilateralinstitutions the conservation of seed and k<strong>no</strong>wledge diversity, so thatthe right to food, health and self-regulated survival eco<strong>no</strong>mies are <strong>no</strong>tsacrificed to commercial interests. At the same time, these grassrootsmovements are also articulate opponents of the adoption of geneticallymodified organisms (GMOs) and campaign forcefully againstthe politics of agrimultinationals like Monsanto. The struggles for theconservation of biological and cultural diversity as a fundamental resourcefor the diversity of survival practices and local eco<strong>no</strong>mic cyclesare <strong>no</strong>t only defensive struggles against the formation of mo<strong>no</strong>poliesof hybrid or genetically modified seeds, of patented and universalisedexpert k<strong>no</strong>wledge, but also struggles against the free trade model asthe universalised mode of the eco<strong>no</strong>my and of survival. The peasantwomen want to ‘live’ biodiversity and refuse expropriation by themarket system as well as by gender mainstreaming. Neither the CBD<strong>no</strong>r the Gender Plan of Action offer them answers to their questionsregarding food sovereignty, regarding indige<strong>no</strong>us intellectual propertyand survival.


women peasants, food security and biodiversity in the crisis of neoliberalism 141These social confrontations over biodiversity provide evidence thatthe neoliberalisation of social nature relations was never a processwithout resistance. Certainly, the defensive struggles of local resourceowners could <strong>no</strong>t prevent the neoliberal appropriation of nature, butthey cause breaks in the global consistency and contradictions in thecoherence of the system. Even if the resistance is locally limited and<strong>no</strong>t to be generalised, it conserves, first, niches and peripheries thatare <strong>no</strong>t yet fully integrated, while, second, it opens up possibilities ofdeveloping postneoliberal alternatives out of these enclaves.ReferencesAkhter, Farida (2001), ‘Die Nayakrishi Kampagne:Saatgut in die Hände der Frauen!’, in Klaffenböck,Gertrude; Lachkovics, Eva and Südwind, Agentur(eds), Biologische Vielfalt. Wer kontrolliert dieglobalen genetischen Ressourcen?,Frankfurt: Brandes & Apsel/Südwind, pp. 81-99.eed (Protestant Development Service) and Hoering,Uwe (2002), Fruits of Diversity. Global Justice andTraditional K<strong>no</strong>wledge, Bonn: eed.Elson, Diane (2002), ‘International FinancialArchitecture: A View from the Kitchen’, in:femina politica, <strong>no</strong>. 1, pp. 26-38.Elson, Diane (1991) (ed.), Male Bias in theDevelopment Process, Manchester: ManchesterUniversity Press.Krishna, Sumi (ed.) (2004), Livelihood and Gender:Gender in Community Resource Management, NewDelhi: Sage Publications India.Kuppe, Rene (2002), ‘Indigene Völker, Ressourcenund traditionelles Wissen’, in Brand, Ulrich andKalcsics, Monika (ed.), Wem gehört die Natur?Konfl ikte um genetische Ressourcen in Lateinamerika,Frankfurt: Brandes & Apsel, pp. 112-134.Rupp, Helen (2007), ‘Von “Ernährerinnen derWelt“ und fl exiblen Arbeitskräften im Agro-Exportsektor’, in Reader des Aktionsbündnissesglobale Landwirtschaft zu G8, Frankfurt: eben dasAktionsbündnis, pp. 42-45.Wichterich, Christa (2007), ‘Globalisierungund Geschlecht: Über neoliberale Strategienzur Gleichstellung’, in Blätter für deutsche undinternationale Politik, <strong>no</strong>. 6, pp. 686-695.Wichterich, Christa (2004), ‘Überlebenssicherung,Gender und Globalisierung: Soziale Reproduktionund Livelihood-Rechte in der neoliberalenGlobalisierung’, Wuppertal Papers zurGlobalisierung, Wuppertal.


On recent projects and experiencesof the Sufficiency Eco<strong>no</strong>my– A critiqueChanida Chanyapate and Alec BamfordOn 2 July 1997, after repeated speculative attacks by currency tradershad exhausted the national foreign exchange reserves, the Bank ofThailand an<strong>no</strong>unced that it was abandoning its defence of the Thaibaht in favour of a ‘managed float’. The baht promptly sank, losingmore than half its value in six months. The IMF was called in, financecompanies were closed, insolvent banks (at least the politically unprotectedones) were merged or sold off to foreign houses, thousands ofcompanies went bankrupt, and hundreds of thousands lost their jobs.Thailand’s attempts to follow IMF prescriptions – liberalisation ofcapital controls, deregulation of finance companies, reliance of foreigninvestment, and export-led growth based on exploitation ofcheap labour – had ended in disaster. The country’s administratorsblamed predatory hedge funds (George Soros cheerfully admitted hisrole) and charged a handful of officials with mismanagement. TheIMF claimed the correct policies had been corrupted by an Asian traditio<strong>no</strong>f ‘crony capitalism’. But a number of analysts pointed insteadat neoliberal policies themselves as the cause of the crisis.In his birthday speech from the throne in December that year, HMKing Bhumibol Adulyadej recommended the Sufficiency Eco<strong>no</strong>my(SE) as a way out of Thailand’s eco<strong>no</strong>mic problems. 1What is the Suffi ciency Eco<strong>no</strong>my?And is it really an alternative to neoliberalism?Royal birthday speeches are long, largely anecdotal and unscripted,and although Sufficiency Eco<strong>no</strong>my was supposedly based on the experiencegained from Royal Projects 2 dating back to 1974, there was1 English translation available at http://kanchanapisek.or.th/speeches/1997/1204.en.html2 ‘Throughout his reign, HM has initiated over 3000 projects because he has a goal thegood health of the Thai people. His projects benefi ted millions of people; there werenew tech<strong>no</strong>logy, sustainable access to water, and reduction of fl oods.’ Dr ChirayuIsrangkun na Ayuthya, Matichon, Education Section, 25 July 2006.


144 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatefrom the outset e<strong>no</strong>ugh uncertainty about the exact meaning of SEfor the king to return to the same topic the following year. 3Part of the reason for this lack of clarity stems from the reverencegranted to the monarchy in Thailand, buttressed by some of the mostrestrictive lèse majesté laws in the world. 4 Initiatives with the royalimprimatur like the Sufficiency Eco<strong>no</strong>my have to be taken seriously,even when poorly understood. Critical commentary on SE, whichmight both define and refine the concept, has been deliberately limited.5 But SE provides the official framework for the 9th and 10th NationalEco<strong>no</strong>mic and Social Development Plans 2002-11, and is enshrinedin the constitution. It has acquired its own bureaucracy, andinnumerable projects, both government and NGO, are cloaked in SEtermi<strong>no</strong>logy, even when the relevance seems strained. The governmenteven commissioned an SE song, which is played to captive audiencesfrom time to time.The goals of Suffi ciencyEco<strong>no</strong>my are balance andsustainability, often re-cast byeco<strong>no</strong>mists as ‘optimisation’ asopposed to the ‘maximisation’of traditional capitalistsystems.The officially approved explanation of SE uses a discourse resemblingBuddhist philosophy more than eco<strong>no</strong>mic theory. SE is founded onthree principles: moderation (akin to the Buddhist concept of the‘middle path’); reasonableness (or an understanding of cause and effect,also fundamental to Buddhist teaching); and self-immunisation.These principles require the use of, firstly, k<strong>no</strong>wledge or wisdom, andsecondly, morality or virtue. The goals are balance and sustainability,often re-cast by eco<strong>no</strong>mists as ‘optimisation’ as opposed to the ‘maximisation’of traditional capitalist systems. Importantly, while the SEdiscourse was from the outset focused on examples at the individualor community level, SE is explicitly promoted as a policy for privatebusinesses of any size and for national eco<strong>no</strong>mic management.3 English translation available at http://kanchanapisek.or.th/speeches/1998/1204.en.html4 Article 112 of the Thai Criminal Code makes it an offence to make defamatory,insulting or threatening comments about the king, queen, heir apparent or regent,punishable by a minimum of three to a maximum of 15 years in prison. Unlike thelaws on defamation, lèse majesté charges can be brought <strong>no</strong>t only by the injuredparty, but by anyone. Furthermore, it is <strong>no</strong> defence to prove that the statements aretrue or constitute fair comment. The law therefore invites exaggerated or maliciousprosecutions; an MP is currently facing a lèse majesté charge for allegedly insultingthe administrators of a school with which he is in dispute and the lèse majesté chargearises from the fact that the school in question was given its name by the king.5 The 10th International Thai Studies Conference held in Bangkok in January 2008staged two sessions on SE. However, as with the sessions dealing with the lèsemajesté laws, it was thought too controversial to include the papers in the publishedconference proceedings.


on recent projects and experiences of the sufficiency eco<strong>no</strong>my – a critique 145The outsider may wonder at the apparent confl ict between SE andthe neoliberal free-market ideologies previously dominant in Thailand.Mainstream eco<strong>no</strong>mics posits enlightened self-interest, unencumberedby any sense of altruism, 6 morality 7 or natural limits, as themainspring of the eco<strong>no</strong>my, which, mediated solely by the ‘invisiblehand’ of the market, will lead to greatest efficiency in the productionand distribution of goods and services and the greatest commongood. The idea of ‘e<strong>no</strong>ugh’, inherent in SE, is largely ig<strong>no</strong>red.Can the Suffi ciency Eco<strong>no</strong>my co-exist withcapitalism and globalisation?Those who were closest to, and benefiting from, positions of eco<strong>no</strong>micpower quickly answered ‘yes’. Although in the drafting of the 2007constitution, there was apparently an initial debate about ‘whetherwe want our eco<strong>no</strong>mic system to be based on capitalism, on marketforces, or on the concept of sufficiency eco<strong>no</strong>mics’, 8 the questionwas quickly decided. SE and free-market capitalism are compatible.Section 83 of the constitution mandates SE as the guiding eco<strong>no</strong>micphilosophy; immediately following that, Section 84 stipulates that thestate must support ‘a free and fair eco<strong>no</strong>my based on market forces’. 9Almost as soon as it became clear that the Sufficiency Eco<strong>no</strong>my was aserious proposition, private businesses, banks and government agenciesbegan ‘auditing’ their operations and discovering, without fail,that they were compliant with SE. In 1999, a gathering of academic6 ‘It is <strong>no</strong>t from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker that we expectour dinner, but from their regard to their own interest. We address ourselves, <strong>no</strong>t totheir humanity, but to their self-love, and never talk to them of our own necessities, butof their advantages.’ Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealthof Nations, Book 1, Ch 2.7 Ronald Coase, in ‘The Problem of Social Cost’, published in the Journal of Law andEco<strong>no</strong>mics in 1960, argues that when fi rms are faced with the choice of breaking thelaw and making a profi t from it, and keeping to the law and forgoing this profi t, thenthe decision on what choice to make should weigh the expected profi ts against thechances of getting caught and the attendant costs. Coase earned a Nobel Eco<strong>no</strong>micsPrize for this kind of amorality.8 Somyos Somviwatanachai, member of the constitutional drafting committee, quoted inthe Bangkok Post of 23 February 2007.9 Offi cial translation stored at the National Assembly of Thailand (NAT), accessible athttp://en.wikisource.org/wiki/2007_Constitution_of_Thailand. However, the translationavailable from the Election Commission of Thailand (http://www.ect.go.th/english/fi les/2007-constitution-english%5B1%5D.pdf) and other u<strong>no</strong>ffi cial translations haveinstead ‘a free eco<strong>no</strong>my based on market forces’, without the word ‘fair’. The Thaioriginal (see http://www.krisdika.go.th/lawHeadContent.jsp?fromPage=lawHeadContent&formatFile=htm&hID=0) clearly supports the NAT translation.


146 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateeco<strong>no</strong>mists happily concluded that SE was compatible with eco<strong>no</strong>micsas they knew it.However, SE did <strong>no</strong>t sit well with the administration of Prime MinisterThaksin Shinawatra (2001-2006). His ‘populist’ policies – theNational Universal Health Care Scheme (popularly k<strong>no</strong>wn as the 30-baht healthcare system), Village Funds, each of 1 million baht, andrural debt relief – did <strong>no</strong>t use the SE framework or termi<strong>no</strong>logy, andwere criticised by the SE establishment (UNDP 2007). The overthrowof the Thaksin government in the September 2006 coup led tothe appointment of former Privy Councillor General Surayud Chula<strong>no</strong>ntas Prime Minister with the task of drafting a new constitution.With Thaksin out of the way and royalists in power, SE was <strong>no</strong>w u<strong>no</strong>pposed.Endorsement of the Sufficiency Eco<strong>no</strong>my went international with theUNDP 2007 Human Development Report for Thailand. Under anAdvisory Panel made up of numerous establishment figures closelyassociated with SE, the report repeatedly asserts, though with scantsupporting argument, that SE ‘can co-exist within a framework ofcapitalist eco<strong>no</strong>mic principles’ (35), and that ‘the Sufficiency approachwas compatible with mainstream eco<strong>no</strong>mics because it accepted tradeand globalization’ (59).Each person, business orcountry can use wisdomand morality in order to bemoderate and reasonableregardless of the actionsof any other player in theeco<strong>no</strong>my.


on recent projects and experiences of the sufficiency eco<strong>no</strong>my – a critique 147And SE was declared a success in 2006 by Chirayu Israngkun naAyuthya: 10 ‘Thailand faced an eco<strong>no</strong>mic crisis in 1997 but was able torecover quickly because HM the King has bestowed the SE philosophyto the Thai people.’ 11The ease with which SE could be co-opted to support mainstreamas-you-were eco<strong>no</strong>mics perhaps derives from its lack of interest inhow eco<strong>no</strong>mic relations are structured. With the possible exceptio<strong>no</strong>f self-immunisation, the principles of SE apply to the individualplayer, <strong>no</strong>t to the rules of the game. Each person, business or countrycan use wisdom and morality in order to be moderate and reasonableregardless of the actions of any other player in the eco<strong>no</strong>my. Ratherthan trying to achieve a balanced, sustainable eco<strong>no</strong>my by means ofsocietal measures such as progressive taxation, laws banning usury, orlimits on the exploitation of natural resources, SE looks to individualsto police their own eco<strong>no</strong>mic activity.Even in the area of self-immunisation, where effective risk managementwould seem to benefit from collective action, the SufficiencyEco<strong>no</strong>my speaks in terms of individual prudence and parsimony ratherthan of risk-sharing mechanisms like social welfare systems.Because it never addresses structural issues, SE also avoids dealingwith issues of power. There is <strong>no</strong> sanction against those who are immoderate,who are unreasonable, or who take too many risks, andconsequently <strong>no</strong> protection for others from the repercussions of theiractions (other than whatever ‘self-immunity’ measures they may beable to implement by themselves). In this, the goals of SE again resembleBuddhist philosophy; <strong>no</strong>body can make you enlightened, justas <strong>no</strong>body can prevent you from achieving enlightenment. It’s all upto you.In the years since it has become the received wisdom in eco<strong>no</strong>micpolicy, the effect of SE on national policy and businesses has beenhard to trace. For example, the UNDP 2007 report lists five macroeco<strong>no</strong>micmeasures undertaken by the Thai authorities supposedlyas a result of application of the principles of SE in the decade followingthe 1997 crisis (59). Two of these (high levels of foreign reservesand conservative levels of public debt) were government practice beforethe crisis and were obviously insufficient in providing immu-10 Dr Chirayu is Director-General of the Crown Property Bureau (of which more below)and was co-Chair of the Advisory Panel to the UNDP Thailand Human DevelopmentReport 2007.11 Matichon, Education Section, 25 July 2006.


148 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatenity against it. Two others (flexible exchange rates and infl ation targeting)are standard neoliberal measures, and flexible exchange ratescould be argued to increase the vulnerability, or reduce the immunity,of a heavily export-oriented eco<strong>no</strong>my. The fifth measure ‘researchwork…begun on the creation of a national risk management scheme’(59) does <strong>no</strong>t yet appear to have been implemented, more than 10years after the king advocated SE. This is <strong>no</strong>t an impressive record ofmacroeco<strong>no</strong>mic reform to be attributed SE principles.Continuing exposure to foreign markets through a high level of dependenceon exports and the opening of the previously protectedbanking and insurance sectors to foreign competition are also hard toreconcile with the principle of self-immunity.Some outspoken proponents of SE at the corporate level, such asthe Crown Property Bureau (CPB), have unashamedly undertakenprojects that seem to bear <strong>no</strong> relation to SE principles. Since the eco<strong>no</strong>miccrisis of 1997, the CPB has been involved in numerous developmentprojects, including the upmarket Bangkok shopping mallsof Siam Paragon and Central World Tower, as well as plans for a‘Champs Élysées’ of shopping and for Bangkok’s tallest skyscraper.When returns on its property investments slumped after the 1997 crisis,the CPB instituted a more aggressive approach, evicting low-renttenants in favour of transnational retailers. 12 It is hard to find muchmoderation in promoting and profiting from the conspicuous consumptio<strong>no</strong>f luxuries, and the newly-evicted tenants are unlikely tofind CPB’s policies reasonable.At the community level, however, the SE establishment points towhat appear to be significant alternatives. The UNDP report devotesmuch space (UNDP 2007: 38-47) to the Inpaeng Network inthe rural Northeast, for example, which does seem to incorporateSE principles. Numerous other community-based initiatives are <strong>no</strong>wclaimed to be examples of the Sufficiency Eco<strong>no</strong>my. Governmentofficials in agriculture, community development and other areas ofwork in the field, <strong>no</strong>w act as agents instructing villagers to implementSE, in word if <strong>no</strong>t in deed.To understand how these community-based initiatives are alternatives,it is necessary to k<strong>no</strong>w what they are alternatives to.12 ‘How Thailand’s Royals Manage to Own All the Good Stuff’, Asia Sentinel, 1 March 2007.


on recent projects and experiences of the sufficiency eco<strong>no</strong>my – a critique 149‘We k<strong>no</strong>w that the thing whichhas made us poor is <strong>no</strong>t thatwe’re idle and don’t want towork. We’re poor because of“development”.’The dominant eco<strong>no</strong>my of the rural areas of Thailand today is theresult of ‘development’. Supported for almost half a century by Bangkokministries and foreign aid programmes and implemented by ahuge intrusive bureaucracy of government officials, development isseen by many Thais as an imposition, like taxes or military conscription,rather than as a benefit. ‘We k<strong>no</strong>w that the thing which hasmade us poor is <strong>no</strong>t that we’re idle and don’t want to work. We’repoor because of “development”, says a Northeast villager from theAssembly of the Poor’ (UNDP 2003).Thailand had for centuries been a food-exporting country and thefirst wave of industrialisation was financed on the export earningsof agriculture. When national development plans began in earnestin the 1960s, the strategy was to run agriculture as if it was an industry:maximise output by expansion of production (turning forestsinto farmland) and by increased efficiency achieved by ‘higher quality’inputs (synthetic pesticides and fertilisers); exploit eco<strong>no</strong>mies ofscale (mo<strong>no</strong>cropping); and monetise the rural eco<strong>no</strong>my by productionfor the market rather than home consumption. At the same time,measures such as the rice premium (effectively a tax on rice exports)ensured that the wealth generated from agriculture did <strong>no</strong>t percolateback down to the farm gate, which in turn ensured a ready supply ofcheap labour for the embryonic manufacturing sector.The results have been environmental degradation, rural debt and socialbreakdown as the eco<strong>no</strong>mically active sector of the population fled thecountryside for unskilled wage labour in the factories around Bangkok,leaving behind ghost villages of grandparents and children.In communities lucky e<strong>no</strong>ugh to have retained competent and farsightedleadership – local practitioners of alternatives, such as the‘guru’ farmers – or the assistance of NGOs offering a different visionfrom that of government, the motivation for developing alternativeshas been multi-faceted.Despoliation of natural resources as a result of capitalist agriculturetook the form of pollution of the soil and water from agro-chemicals,and deforestation or conversion of natural forest to plantations of eucalyptusand other environmentally damaging crops.The answers were alternative agriculture in a variety of forms withlow external inputs, and reforestation through community forestry.


150 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateThe debt problem is often simplistically blamed on villagers’ profl i-gacy in buying consumer goods like mobile phones, motorcycles andTV sets and in maintaining social prestige through over-lavish funeral,wedding and ordination ceremonies – in SE terms, a lack of moderation.In fact, most farmers became trapped in the debt cycle by followingthe prescriptions of government agricultural extension officerswho advised buying external inputs and arranged credit (aka debt) tomake this possible. The cost of inputs rose inexorably as diminishingeffectiveness required increasing quantities, while prices earned fromproduce were subject to high levels of volatility. Rice-growing becameone of the easiest ways of losing money in the Thai eco<strong>no</strong>my.The answer, found by some farmers themselves, has been to reduceexposure to the market. Production is focused firstly on self-reliance,at both the individual and community level, with only the surplusbeing traded. The abandonment of market-oriented mo<strong>no</strong>-croppingin favour of mixed farming also reduces the need for synthetic inputs.Although income from sales is reduced, expenditure is also reduced,since food is grown, <strong>no</strong>t bought, and there is <strong>no</strong> need to buy pesticidesand fertilisers. If debt can also be eliminated, crippling interestpayments are also avoided. 13Phuyai (Headman) Wiboon Khemchaloem of Chachoengsao is a nationallyrecognised example of many farmers driven to near bankruptcyby ‘modern’ agriculture, who have returned to solvency andhigh levels of productivity by switching to debt-free alternatives. TheInpaeng Network featured in the UNDP 2007 report was also startedas a reaction to increasing debt caused by capitalist agriculture andconsumerism.The debt problem is oftensimplistically blamed onvillagers’ profl igacy in buyingconsumer goods like mobilephones, motorcycles andTV sets and in maintainingsocial prestige through overlavishfuneral, wedding andordination ceremonies.Loans required for capital improvements or to meet life’s emergenciescan be supplied from community savings groups and credit unions.These activities serve as excellent stimuli for further community development.Regular deposits require ongoing participation; women’sinvolvement is very high; success depends on fostering and strengtheningintra-community trust; and successful capital formation can,apart from providing loans to individuals, form the basis of a communitywelfare system and finance community enterprises such asrice mills.13 Farmers are <strong>no</strong>rmally considered poor risks by commercial banks but can arrange lowinterestloans from the government Bank for Agriculture and Agricultural Cooperatives(BAAC). However, these loans are <strong>no</strong>rmally for one production cycle only. One poorharvest which yields insufficient cash income to repay the BAAC loan will send the farmerto the informal credit market where interest rates of 5-6 per cent per month are <strong>no</strong>rmal.


on recent projects and experiences of the sufficiency eco<strong>no</strong>my – a critique 1<strong>51</strong>Examples of what were previously thought of as community selfreliancedevelopment alternatives, but which <strong>no</strong>w often carry an SElabel, show characteristics that are <strong>no</strong>t made explicit in the <strong>no</strong>rmativeSE ca<strong>no</strong>n.One of these is participatory democracy and collective action. 14 Theimportance of these, especially to achieve self-immunity, is repeatedby many community leaders. Amphon Duangpan of Khlong Piasavings group, Chana District, Songkhla, says: ‘Community capitalbuilds national immunity’. 15For example, the first collective activity for self-reliance in BanThuem Tong, Muang District, Nan, involved setting up a ‘communitywelfare fund’ in 1974 through communal growing of red beanson temple land for sale, the sale of fish from a community pond,and a savings group. The welfare provided includes funeral payments,scholarships and emergency loans without interest. The village <strong>no</strong>wmanages 3.7 million baht 16 in various funds for a population of 84households (264 people), and is <strong>no</strong>w publicised as a prize-winningexample of successful SE practice. 17Collective marketing is also valuable in offsetting the market powerof middlemen, and numerous groups, such as the villagers of MaeTha, Chiang Mai, practise this.Collective community cohesion is also helpful in tackling problemsarising when some individuals fail to adhere to SE principles and engagein drug and alcohol abuse, gambling, and corruption at the localgovernment level.A<strong>no</strong>ther issue about which the Sufficiency Eco<strong>no</strong>my is silent is equity,perhaps because its chief proponents enjoy such obviously unequalstatus. SE explicitly accepts differences in levels of personal wealth.‘Some things may seem to be extravagant, but if it brings happiness,14 While the account of the Inpaeng Network in the UNDP Thailand Human DevelopmentReport 2007 clearly includes a description of its participatory structure, there is <strong>no</strong>conclusion that such a structure is a defi ning or even facilitative aspect of SE.15 Public Policy Development Programme, National Health Foundation, ‘Local PublicPolicy: Strong Communities Edition’, October 2005.16 Approximately US$ 105,000.17 Cited in www.rakbankerd.com (in Thai).


152 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateit is permissible as long as it is within the means of the individual.’ 18So what is immoderate for a person on a low income can be moderatefor someone better off. The poor man sufficiently walks; the <strong>no</strong>t-sopoorwoman sufficiently rides a motorcycle; the billionaire sufficientlychooses which of a fleet of luxury cars to use.This acceptance of, or at best apparent unconcern about the gross andgrowing inequities in Thai society in the SE philosophy have led manycivil society leaders to question whether it is simply a mechanism forpersuading people to maintain the eco<strong>no</strong>mic status quo. 19The ability to decide whether one’s consumption is moderate dependson having sufficient means to choose. The middle path between <strong>no</strong>ttoo little and <strong>no</strong>t too much is <strong>no</strong>t open to those who have less thane<strong>no</strong>ugh. It is also argued by many 20 that globalisation, which is supposedto be compatible with SE (see above), is itself a cause of growinginequity.Community-based alternatives are <strong>no</strong>rmally restricted to withincommunities or networks of communities where disparities of wealthare <strong>no</strong>t high. However, many operate welfare systems that help alleviatethe worst poverty. Thai civil society has campaigned for mechanismsthat would reduce eco<strong>no</strong>mic inequity, such as inheritancestaxes, taxes on large land-holdings and unused land, a shift from regressivetaxes, such as VAT, towards more progressive taxes, and theestablishment of welfare systems to cover cases of sickness, old ageand unemployment. None of these feature as part of SE doctrine.There are longstanding, sustainable and serious local communitybasedalternatives to mainstream development in Thailand. Manyhave used the momentum of SE in order to further these initiatives.‘We k<strong>no</strong>w we’ve been working for community self-reliance long beforethe king an<strong>no</strong>unced his SE philosophy, but the SE buzz wordcoming from the king has helped made our work with communities18 HM the King, Royal Speech on the Occasion of the Royal Birthday Anniversary,4 December 1998.19 Suspicions are <strong>no</strong>t allayed by publications such as ‘Suffi ciency Eco<strong>no</strong>my: A NewPhilosophy in the Global World: 100 Interviews with Business Professionals’, publishedby the Thai Chamber of Commerce. A review comments: ‘the main aim of the volumewas to enable the good businessmen and businesswomen…to demonstrate theirunwavering royal loyalty [in] 100 statements of corporate platitude and uncriticalloyalty.’ (A. Walker ‘Business Professionals Prostrating’, 23 April 2008; available athttp://rspas.anu.edu.au/rmap/newmandala/2008/04/23/business-professionalsprostrating/).20 Such as the UN ‘The World Social Situation: The Inequality Predicament,’ 2005.


on recent projects and experiences of the sufficiency eco<strong>no</strong>my – a critique 153easier.’ 21 They find <strong>no</strong> difficulty with the principles of SE, but alsosee the importance of participatory democratic action as a surer guaranteeof immunity. They are also far more interested in questions ofredistribution and equity.Nor are they fooled by the paradoxes in SE. ‘The problem is that thegovernment seems to prescribe SE for communities, while at the nationallevel, they continue to negotiate for free trade and propose newmega projects. It is hypocritical.’ 22For the SE philosophy to support community-based alternatives thatare broadly in line with its principles and objectives, certain thingsmust happen.First, more recognition must be given to the need for cooperative,collective, democratically-decided action and the political space requiredfor this to happen. A Community Forest Bill was submitted toparliament via a constitutional mechanism that allows citizen initiatives.It was rejected in favour of a competing version from the bureaucracythat effectively removes communities’ rights to manage thelocal environment.The ability to decide whetherone’s consumption ismoderate depends on havingsuffi cient means to choose.The middle path between <strong>no</strong>ttoo little and <strong>no</strong>t too much is<strong>no</strong>t open to those who haveless than e<strong>no</strong>ugh.21 Interview with Wichitra Chusakul, Deputy Manager, NET Foundation, Surin,9 October 2008.22 Interview with Bamrung Kayota, Chair of a Tambon (subdistrict) administrativeorganisation, Kalasin, and farmer-activist, 9 October 2008.


154 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateGovernment resources, currently directed overwhelmingly to theprivate sector, must be diverted to support community-based SE alternatives.The government also has the responsibility to see that naturalresources of land, water, seeds and local wisdom are protectedfrom degradation, commodification and privatisation.The bureaucracy must be made to realise that SE is <strong>no</strong>t a philosophythat can be imposed by diktat as previous development policies inThailand have been forced onto communities. ‘Some communitieshave implemented [SE], some only put up signs,’ <strong>no</strong>tes Bamrung. 23The danger is that the essence of SE will become so diluted as to bemeaningless.And finally, since SE as genuinely practised at the community levelrepresents an important contribution to reducing consumption andharm to the natural environment, it is imperative that communitybasedmodels are scaled up so that they have a genuine impact at thelevel of private businesses and government policy.The Sufficiency Eco<strong>no</strong>my came to prominence after the 1997 crisis ofthe Thai eco<strong>no</strong>my. If the crisis was the result of neoliberal policies,does SE therefore represent a postneoliberal alternative?It should be recognised that the Thai eco<strong>no</strong>my before the crisis did<strong>no</strong>t altogether conform to the classic neoliberal pattern. At the macrolevel, it is true, liberalisation of markets, especially of the capital marketin 1992, was very much work in progress. However Thailand hadnever been required to undergo a structural adjustment process andmany areas of the eco<strong>no</strong>my (such as electricity generation and distribution,public water supplies, and the postal service) had <strong>no</strong>t beenprivatised as had occurred in other countries, and remained undergovernment control.Also, government intervention was much more visible at the microlevel, especially in the rural eco<strong>no</strong>my, with centrally-driven policiesimposed, with greater or lesser success, by a large and intrusive bureaucracy.The freedom of eco<strong>no</strong>mic action for all players in classicneoliberalism was therefore circumscribed.Since the Sufficiency Eco<strong>no</strong>my became the accepted discourse, theconcept has been co-opted at two levels.23 Ibid.


on recent projects and experiences of the sufficiency eco<strong>no</strong>my – a critique 155We have seen that at the national and corporate level, SE has degeneratedinto little more than pietistic declarations of royalist obedience,while business carries on more or less as usual. Since SE at this leveldoes <strong>no</strong>t in fact represent an alternative to the status quo ante, it canhardly be described as postneoliberal.SE has also been co-opted at the community level, where genuineeco<strong>no</strong>mic alternatives, many pre-dating the official launch of SE, andoften incorporating ideals that are missing from the SE ideology, are<strong>no</strong>w routinely couched in the SE discourse. It is quite usual for thesecommunity initiatives to have been conceived, and to see themselves,as a reaction to the mainstream rural eco<strong>no</strong>my. However this mainstreameco<strong>no</strong>my was <strong>no</strong>t analysed as ‘neoliberalism’, but simply as‘capitalism’ and ‘development’.Importantly, these community-based alternatives, often inspired bythe teachings of Buddhism, rejected the importance of greed (or enlightenedself-interest) as the motivational mainspring of capitalism;and at the same time communities demanded, or simply wrested,democratic decision-making power, which was absent from the government-directeddevelopment process. The label of ‘postneoliberal’,while containing an element of truth, would in this case also be misleading.So does the Sufficiency Eco<strong>no</strong>my represent a postneoliberal alternative?Well, only partly, and then <strong>no</strong>t really.ReferencesUNDP (2003), Human Development Report for Thailand,Bangkok: UNDP.UNDP (2007), Human Development Report for Thailand,Bangkok: UNDP.


Struggles against Wal-Martisationand neoliberal competitivenessin (southern) China – Towardspostneoliberalism as an alternative?Ngai-Ling SumThe rise of neoliberalism has prompted adaptations, resistance and asearch for alternatives. This article concentrates on the case of (southern)China, especially the close relation between local states and globalcapital and its implications for a socialist and/or postneoliberal future.The first section briefly sketches the rise of glocal (global-local)‘competitiveness’ discourses and practices related to neoliberalism andits justification in terms of the metaphor of ‘clusters’. The second sectionfocuses on Hong Kong/Pearl River Delta and illustrates howthis body of competitiveness k<strong>no</strong>wledge is being recontextualised interms of the discourses and practices of ‘cluster-building’, ‘foreigndirect investment’, and ‘global sourcing’ from ‘China as a global factory’.Together these discourses and practices contribute towards thedisciplining of time and space of the region as an ‘eco<strong>no</strong>mic powerhouse’.Global giant supply/retail chains such as Wal-Mart source fromthe region, thereby assisting their practice of selling at ‘Always LowPrices’ around the world. The third section explores how the trendtowards ‘Wal-Martisation’ has prompted diverse anti-neoliberal challengesfrom transnational and trans-local anti-globalisation groups.They criticise this kind of price-value competitiveness especially interms of its impact upon land use, labour problems, gender inequalitiesand local communities. This article discusses the case of a HongKong-based NGO called Students and Academics Against CorporateMisbehaviour (SACOM) and its efforts to challenge labour issues inthe region. This kind of bottom-up approach is complicated by a topdownapproach from the Chinese central government to ‘persuade’Wal-Mart to form unions, especially in face of a fall in union membershipand general social unrest. The fourth section discusses the socialunrest and a related policy turn towards a social agenda under theHu/Wen leadership. This partly coincided with the 2008 neoliberalfinancial crisis that renders the discussions on the future of socialismmore relevant, if <strong>no</strong>t more urgent, amongst ‘new left’ intellectuals.These discussions in China also resonate elsewhere. For example,in certain circles of the transnational left, Chavez’s project in Latin


158 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateAmerica is narrated as ‘21st century socialism’ (or postneoliberalism).Does the development of Chavez’s project in Venezuela and of similarones in Bolivia and Ecuador shed light on the search for a potentiallycounter-hegemonic alternative to neoliberalism? Drawing on Jessopand Gramsci, this section ends with two cautionary <strong>no</strong>tes.The rise of glocal neoliberal competitivenessOne prominent discourse related to the rise of neoliberalism concernsthe glocal cultures of ‘competitiveness’. In the main, this bodyof k<strong>no</strong>wledge is constructed and coordinated by academic gurus/entrepreneurs,consultancy firms, policy thinktanks, and international/regional organisations (for example, Harvard Business School, MonitorGroup, the Competitiveness Institute, World Eco<strong>no</strong>mic Forum,the United Nations Industrial Development Organization – UNIDO– and Asian Development Bank). An exemplary case is Michael Porter,a Harvard Business School professor and consultant with a backgroundin competitiveness analysis of firms, industries, nations andregions (1980, 1985 and 1990). His work won early attention in thepolicy field; he was, for example, a member of Reagan’s first Commissio<strong>no</strong>n Industrial Competitiveness. He constructed the ‘diamondmodel’ based on four factors: demand conditions, factor conditions,firm strategy, structure and rivalry, and related and supporting industries,whose interaction is also shaped by the nature of ‘government’and its interventions as well as by ‘chance’ factors. Porter added thatthese micro-foundations would be strongest when they formed ’clusters’,a metaphor that de<strong>no</strong>tes ‘a geographic concentration of competingand cooperating companies, suppliers, service providers, and associatedinstitutions’ (Porter 1990). 1Porter’s model has been criticised and debated 2 but remains popularand is sold in the form of re-engineering solutions by related Harvardinstitutions (for example, the Institute for Competitiveness andInstitute for Competitiveness and Strategy) and associated strategyfirms (such as the Monitor Group and ontheFRONTIER Group.).Through its joint claims to expertise and efforts, Porter’s clusterbasedcompetitiveness concept was applied to different countries (e.g.Canada, Denmark, New Zealand, Portugal, Sweden, and Switzerland)and regions (e.g. Atlanta, Central European Region-Vienna,and Hong Kong/PRD). Several strategy firms (e.g. ontheFRON-1 Clusters are made visible via the technique of ‘cluster charts’ which identify localindustries based on export statistics and use the diamond model to test selected casesto establish a pool of unique clusters.2 For a summary of this debate, see Martin and Sunley (2003).


struggles against wal-martisation and neoliberal competitiveness in (southern) china 159TIER Group) have adapted this model to emerging markets (e.g.Mexico and Rwanda). The discourse of competitiveness has also beenadopted/adapted/recontextualised on different scales by internationalorganisations (e.g. World Eco<strong>no</strong>mic Forum and UNIDO), regionalbanks (e.g. Asian Development Bank), national agencies (e.g. UnitedStates Agency for International Development) and city governmentsand organisations (see Table 1).Table 1Some examples of institutionsand discourses related to‘competitiveness’ acrossdifferent scalesScalesExamples of institutionsInvolvedWorld Eco<strong>no</strong>mic ForumExamples of competitivenessdiscourses/instruments• GlobalCompetitiveness IndexInternationalThe Competitiveness Institute• The Cluster InitiativeDatabase• The Cluster InitiativeGreenbook 2003United Nations IndustrialDevelopment Organization(UNIDO)• Clusters and NetworksDevelopmentProgramme 2005Asian Development Bank• Asian DevelopmentOutlook 2003: IIICompetitiveness inDeveloping CountriesRegionalAfrican Union• Pan AfricanCompetitivenessForum 2008Inter-American DevelopmentBank• Competitiveness ofSmall Enterprises:Cluster and LocalDevelopment 2007Local/CityNumerous (inter-)citycompetitiveness projects andplans• OECD’s InternationalConference on CityCompetitiveness 2005• The Hong KongAdvantage 1997• Blue Book of CityCompetitiveness inChina 2008(Source: Author’s own compilation)


160 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateFrom a power-political perspective, Foucault argues that metaphors(like ‘cluster’) function as key parts of the various tech<strong>no</strong>logies ofpower that constitute and govern human society. Such discursivetech<strong>no</strong>logies organise a field of power-k<strong>no</strong>wledge that governs waysof seeing and representing eco<strong>no</strong>mic realities and of disciplining eco<strong>no</strong>micagents. In these terms, Porter’s ‘cluster’ metaphor has becomepart of a tech<strong>no</strong>logy of power that <strong>no</strong>t only <strong>no</strong>rmalises competitiveness/developmentbut also shapes and disciplines the organisation ofspace, policies and population. It naturalises ‘clusters’ as drivers andpillars for national or regional eco<strong>no</strong>mic competitiveness and disciplinesactors to treat these spaces as (potential) clusters in which therespective actors interact to optimise performance. It also targets policies,budgets and training to support cluster initiatives and steers nationsand/or regions (and their population) towards building platformsand schemes to assist the formation of clusters (Sum <strong>2009</strong>a).Recontextualing neoliberal competitiveness in the PearlRiver DeltaThis transnational body of k<strong>no</strong>wledge was transferred to Hong Kong/Pearl River Delta and recontextualised in two stages from the mid-1990s onwards. Deploying the ‘cluster’ metaphor, local policy makers(e.g. the then Financial Secretary, Donald Tsang), service-orientedbusinessmen (e.g. Victor Fung) and thinktanks (e.g. Hong KongCoalition of Service Industries) sponsored Harvard-related academics(e.g. Michael Enright) and related consultancy firms (e.g. Enright andScott) transferred the model to Hong Kong just before the 1997 transitionfrom a British colony into a Special Administrative Region ofChina. Their report, The Hong Kong Advantage, emphasised the problemof manufacturing decline in Hong Kong and narrated it in termsof the shift from a ‘manual’/’enclave’ to a ‘k<strong>no</strong>wledge’/‘metropolitaneco<strong>no</strong>my’ (Enright et al. 1997: 13). Hong Kong was portrayed as a‘metropolitan service eco<strong>no</strong>my’ which served as ‘packagers and integratorsof activities for the global eco<strong>no</strong>my, a leading source of foreigninvestment, a centre for overseas firms, the capital for the overseasfirms, and driver of the Mainland eco<strong>no</strong>my’ (Enright et al. 1997:80). This enframing highlighted its role as a functional space for ‘foreigndirect investment’. This space is occupied by five linked clusters(i.e. business and financial services, transport and logistics, light manufacturingand trading, property and construction, and tourism) thatare reinforced by localised laissez-faire practices of ‘government asreferee’ supported by the ‘hustle and commitment strategies’ of HongKong’s merchant manufacturers and the societal ethos of ‘hard-workingpeople’ (see especially 1997: 34-40, 45-6 and 85).Hong Kong was portrayedas a ‘metropolitan serviceeco<strong>no</strong>my’ which served as‘packagers and integratorsof activities for the globaleco<strong>no</strong>my, a leading sourceof foreign investment, acentre for overseas fi rms, thecapital for the overseas fi rms,and driver of the Mainlandeco<strong>no</strong>my’.


struggles against wal-martisation and neoliberal competitiveness in (southern) china 161This narration of Hong Kong as a global-oriented service site hasbeen reinforced and extended since 2000 in a series of studies linkedto the second report. In anticipation of China’s WTO entry, the Harvardimaginary crossed borders via the joint efforts of service actorssuch as the Hong Kong Chamber of Commerce, the Hong Kong Coalitio<strong>no</strong>f Service Industries and a<strong>no</strong>ther <strong>no</strong>n-profit thinktank chairedby Victor Fung (the 2022 Foundation). Together they deployed thespatial metaphor of ‘service metropolis’, 3 and this was later made moreconcrete by Enright and Scott in their June 2003 report, which introducedthe spatial imaginary of ‘Greater Pearl River Delta (PRD)’. Itenvisaged Hong Kong playing its service role and the PRD serving asa manufacturing site, thereby enabling the PRD to become a regional‘eco<strong>no</strong>mic powerhouse’. A government quango called InvestHKcommissioned Enright and Scott to study the investment potential ofeach subregion in the ‘Greater PRD’. Their results, plus the earlierreport, appeared as a book sponsored once more by the 2022 Foundation(Enright, Scott and Chang 2005). The strong cooperation reiteratedthe <strong>no</strong>rmality of ‘competitiveness’ and the ‘cluster’ metaphor.Thus the ‘Greater PRD’ is mapped as a new service-manufacturing‘regional powerhouse’ occupied by diverse export-oriented clusters(e.g. toys, plastic, kitchen tools, lamps) (see Map 1) offering opportunitiesfor ‘foreign direct investment’ and ‘global sourcing’ in China.This vision is also backed by other organisations (e.g. the Trade DevelopmentCouncil).The Hong Kong Advantageemphasised the problemof manufacturing declinein Hong Kong and narratedit in terms of the shift froma ‘manual’/’enclave’ to a‘k<strong>no</strong>wledge’/‘metropolitaneco<strong>no</strong>my’.3 The 2022 Foundation publication on the PRD is available onhttp://www.2022foundation.com/index.asp?party=reports, last accessed 11 June 2007.


162 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateMap 1: Mapping of production clusters in the Pearl River DeltaExhibit: Localised Industries in the Pearl River Delta RegionFoshanIndustrial ceramicsCeramic artworkNeedleworkTextilesChildren's garmentsShundeElectrical appliancesWoodworkingShipping containersFurnitureMachineryBicyclesJiangmenTextilesGarmentsPaperBatteriesNanhaiTextilesAluminium prodsMotorcyclesUnderwearKaipingWater-heating EquipmentSanitary wareZhongshanLighting fi xturesLampsMetal productsMotorcyclesCasual wearLocksAudio equipmentChencunFlower farmingOrnamental fi shTurf farmingPanyuSports goodsTextilesGarmentsJewelleryToysElectric supply equipShipping containersSource: "Hong Kong and the Pearl River Delta: the Eco<strong>no</strong>micInteraction", M. Enright et al., 2003.GuangzhouAutos and partsTransport equipElectrical prodsElectronicsChemicalsGarmentsTextilesBusiness servicesSoftwareToysHumenGarmentsElectronicsShenzhenElectronicsComputer prodsTelecom prodsICsToysPlasticsWatchesClocksOil paintingsPort servicesLogisticsFinancePrintingArtifi cial treesHuizhouLaser diodesDigital electronicsCD-RomsTelephonesBatteriesCircuit boardsPrecision machineryPlasticsChemicalsDongguanElectronicsComputersComponentsPeripheralsGarmentsFurnitureShoesToysWatchesClocksCutleryKitchen toolsSoldering machineryAngling equipmentWal-Martisation and related struggles/negotiationsGlobal giant supply/retail chains, such as Wal-Mart, source from, andalso retail in, the region. In 1995, Wal-Mart China formed a 65:35joint venture with the state-owned Shenzhen International Trustsand Investment Company (SZITIC) in China. The latter has strongties to local and central governments, which enables related firms tosecure land deals at favourable prices. Wal-Mart China also set upits global procurement centre in Shenzhen and regional headquarterin Hong Kong in 2002 and 2007 respectively. Seventy per cent of all


struggles against wal-martisation and neoliberal competitiveness in (southern) china 163products sold by Wal-Mart in 2005 were made in China and 80 percent of the 6,000 factories that supply it were Chinese. 4 Between 2001and 2006, Wal-Mart accounted for approximately 9.6 per cent of totalUS imports from China (Scott 2007). These data indicate the importanceof Chinese suppliers to Wal-Mart especially in its businessstrategy of ‘Always Low Prices’. The use of a special software programmeRetail Link (since 1991) facilitates the search for price-valuecompetitiveness because it connects its retailing with the global supplychains to create what the mainstream eco<strong>no</strong>mic and managementliterature would call a ‘just-in-time’ supply system linking all stores,distribution centres and suppliers, giving firms big cost advantages(Holmes 2001; Basker 2007). However, such lean practices can alsobe employed coercively (Free 2006: 14-16; 2007: 900) in the everydayoperations of discount-based mega-retailers.Their accounting practices require all suppliers to open their accountsto the mega-retailer (called ‘open book accounting). Armed with informationabout suppliers’ costs and margins, Wal-Mart managerscan routinely evaluate changes in each supplier’s costs and marginsas well as require it to match its lowest price or even cut it. It also introducesa form of coordinated competition among suppliers, for exampleby asking a specific supplier to match the lower prices of competingsuppliers. This firm grip over suppliers-manufacturers and theunrelenting push for cost and price-value competitiveness means thatmanufacturers, in turn, must pass on their costs and production insecurity(e.g. stopping orders) to their workers. The resulting trend toWal-Martisation modifies the social relations of production such thatpower shifts from suppliers-manufacturers to giant retailers with theformer trickling insecurity and poverty down to their flexible workforcein pursuing this low-cost disciplinary strategy.This change has prompted (trans)national and local concern amongunions, NGOs and community groups such as AFL-CIO’s Eye onWalMart, CorpWatch, Wal-Mart Watch, Wake-Up Wal-Mart,Sprawl-Busters, Frontline, Wal-Mart Class Website, and Studentsand Scholars Against Corporate Misbehaviour (SACOM) targetingthe land use and labour problems of the corporation. More specifically,SACOM, a Hong Kong-based NGO, adopts strategies to: (a)monitor multinational corporations such as Wal-Mart through pub-4 The fi rst statistics come from PriceWaterHouseCooper, Redefi ning IntellectualProperty Value: the Case of China, 2005, p. 63, http://www.pwc.com/techforecast/pdfs/IPR-web_x.pdf, accessed on 6 September 2007; and the second from AFL-CIO, Paying the Price of Wal-Mart, http://www.afl cio.org/corporatewatch/walmart/walmart_1.cfm, accessed on 6 September 2007.


164 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatelic campaigns; (b) enhance global-local networking activities amongworkers, NGOs, student groups, trade unions, human rights activists,lawyers, academics, environmentalists and ethical consumers inefforts to regulate corporate power; and (c) empower the labour forceas active agents in promoting rights in the workplace. Such local andtransnational groups have had sporadic successes, especially on casespecificbases, in launching critical reports, 5 redressing unfair dismissalsand setting up workers’ training courses and committees (seealso Sum <strong>2009</strong>b). However, such transnational bottom-up attemptsface constant struggles over funding, issue drift as NGOs of this kindmove from one specific issue to the next, and the difficulties of selectingpartners with whom to form counter-hegemonic alliances withoutbeing co-opted into the neoliberal game.In China, this bottom-up strategy has been complicated by a topdow<strong>no</strong>ne pursued by the Chinese government, which still claims tooperate under the banner of ‘socialism with Chinese characteristics’.There are difficulties and contradictions faced by the central government,the Chinese Communist Party, and the official union (All-China Federation of Trade Unions) (ACFTU) concerning how to resolvethe tensions and contradictions between neoliberalisation, priorsocialist values and social stability. The spread of ‘Wal-Martisation’and of marketisation more generally has intensified these tensions,which include the competitive drive of local states to attract foreigndirect investment, the close relationship between these states and globalcapital, the existence of sweatshop labour, the rise of labour andcivil unrest, the expropriation of farmers’ land by local authorities toconstruct factories/shopping malls, increasing unemployment and the‘floating population’ crowded into city slums, and the pervasivenessof environmental degradation.There are diffi culties andcontradictions faced by thecentral government, theChinese Communist Party,and the offi cial union (All-China Federation of TradeUnions) (ACFTU) concerninghow to resolve the tensionsand contradictions betweenneoliberalisation, priorsocialist values and socialstability.One strategy to maintain social stability is for the central governmentand the ACFTU to require large foreign corporations, such as Wal-Mart, to establish unions. Wal-Mart was the first to be targeted on 145 SACOM published a report entitled Wal-Mart’s Sweatshop Monitoring Fails to CatchViolations in 2007 on three toy factories in southern China. It revealed problemsrelated to the implementation of corporate social responsibility of Wal-Mart. Theseincluded factory inspections which were an<strong>no</strong>unced in advance and managerscoaching workers to give the ‘correct answers’ about their working conditions. Workerswere also encouraged to become ‘voluntary liars’ through a material incentive of RMB50 Yuan (approximately US$ 8 at prevailing exchange rate) and were also told the littlecapitalist tale that a factory’s loss of orders would translate directly into workers’ lossof future employment opportunities. In addition, factory owners manufactured ‘wagedocuments’ and ‘time cards’ that indicated that workers were suffi ciently paid in termsof base and overtime wages without exceeding the maximum working hours. In reality,workers’ monthly wages shrank signifi cantly and overtime was <strong>no</strong>t recorded (2007: 15).


struggles against wal-martisation and neoliberal competitiveness in (southern) china 165March 2006 when President Hu ordered the ACFTU to do a betterjob in establishing trade unions in foreign-invested enterprises. Thisenabled the ACFTU, which had experienced a fall in membership,to negotiate with Wal-Mart on setting up branch unions. Despiteinitial resistance, unions were set up in 77 out of 84 stores by July2007. Some question whether these localised entities guided by theACFTU actually promote workers’ rights or merely boost its decliningmembership (Chan 2007); and to undermine the threats from u<strong>no</strong>fficialand underground union movements, according to one report,six months after their introduction, ‘Wal-Mart union branches havedone little more than organize social events and run employee clubs’(Ruwitch 2007: 4).Towards postneoliberalism as an alternative?Concurrent with this top-down response to emerging problems, the‘new left’ in China criticised marketisation and global engagement,especially after China’s entry into the WTO. Some call for less AdamSmith and more Friedrich List in terms of building state capacitiesand eco<strong>no</strong>mic security (He 2000; Wang 2006). In this more criticalclimate, the Chinese central government (then led by PresidentHu and Premier Wen) embarked on the political tasks of promotingsocial justice, regaining control over local excesses (e.g. corruptionand land appropriation by bureaucrats), and ‘building a new socialistcountryside’ since 2004. The 11th Five-Year Plan (2006-2010) reflectedthese trends by emphasising the building of a ‘harmonious socialistsociety’ with a ‘people-first’ and ‘poverty-reduction’ agenda. Thesepolicies aimed to tackle social instability coincided with the 2008 globalfinancial crisis. Despite an initial view that China would <strong>no</strong>t beaffected, the ‘financial tsunami’ is causing a stock market crash, lossof foreign direct investment, declining exports, manufacturing slowdown,rising unemployment, and so on.Despite these problems, China is relatively cushioned by foreign reservesof some us$ 1.8 trillion and by the fact that its financial sectoris <strong>no</strong>t fully open. However, the crisis is hitting its export competitivenessand related clusters fast. It is estimated that one quarter ofthe 70,000 Hong Kong-owned firms in the PRD will shut by early<strong>2009</strong>. This has stimulated measures such as tax relief and increasedgovernment spending as well as discussions on national protectionismand whether China should deploy part of its reserves to underwriteAmerican/European debts or use them for social purposes athome (e.g. development of health and education, especially in ruralareas). Until September 2008, the social agenda still ranked high, as


166 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateevidenced in Wen’s speech in the State Council reception to celebratethe 59th anniversary of the founding of the People’s Republic. Thisproclaimed that China would continue to ‘stick to reform and openingup, promote social harmony and strive for new achievements inbuilding a moderately prosperous society’ (People’s Daily 2008).Notwithstanding this official positioning, it is unclear what these objectivesimply for the building of Chinese socialism. For example,will the social agenda act merely as a fl anking mechanism that cushionsthe impact of further privatisation (e.g., rural land rights) andmarket-opening in the roll-out stage of neoliberalism? Will it reinventConfucianism so that it is articulated to social-capitalist openingwith a datong (great harmony) nationalist imagination or couldit help to restore the sovereign place of the people/subaltern groupswithin the self-proclaimed system of ‘socialism with a Chinese characteristics’that might then seek a selective relinking with world capitalism?These discussions resonate with the more general questio<strong>no</strong>f the future of socialism elsewhere, especially during the period ofneoliberal financial crisis and eco<strong>no</strong>mic recession. The current revivalof (transnational) state interventions and (global) Keynesianismmay be hyped by some as a return to some kind of democratic socialism;whilst other members of the transnational left may regard postneoliberaldevelopments in Latin America (e.g., Chavez’s project inVenezuela) as ‘21st century socialism’. The latter involves grassroots/popular forces and classes gaining a foothold in the state and utilisingit to transform policies, especially at local levels. Do the Chavezproject and similar movements in Bolivia and Ecuador illuminate thesearch for a postneoliberal future? Drawing on Jessop and Gramsci,two cautions are necessary before this is accepted as a leftwing articleof faith.First, the case of China and its gradual integration with global capitalismmay illustrate Jessop’s idea of the variegated nature of the worldmarket – that is, the co-existence, complementarity and structuralcoupling of different types of capitalism and other eco<strong>no</strong>mic formationsin the global eco<strong>no</strong>my. 6 This can be seen in the couplingThe case of China and itsgradual integration with globalcapitalism may illustrateJessop’s idea of the variegatednature of the world market.6 While varieties of capitalism are often analysed in isolation from each other as if eachwere viable without other varieties, variegated capitalism explores the links amongvarieties of capitalism within the world market – whether due to their respectivespecialisations in the international division of labour, their respective modes ofregulation and forms of state, their respective temporalities, or their respectivepositions as creditors and debtors. This perspective excludes the generalisation ofone variety to the whole world market as well as simplistic forms of regime shopping,in which social forces seek to combine features of different varieties of capitalism toseek the optimum balance among them (personal communication from Bob Jessop, 25September 2008).


struggles against wal-martisation and neoliberal competitiveness in (southern) china 167of southern Chinese coastal exportism with the close ties betweenlocal authorities and global capital embedded in a central governmentpushing for a social agenda. Likewise, in Venezuela, we fi nd anexport-oriented rentier eco<strong>no</strong>my that currently supports a temporarycohabitation of neoliberal capitalism and domestic pragmatic leftpopulism that cuts across class lines. China and Venezuela, each in itsown way, combines statism, populism and market-oriented elements;and both contribute, in a path-dependent and path-shaping manner,to the ongoing struggles around the future of a (post-) WashingtonConsensus world (dis-)order.Second, are Hu/Wen’s ‘social agenda’ and Chavez’s ‘postneoliberal’project good alternatives? Crucial here, from a Gramscian perspective,is the distinction between ‘integral state’ (political society +civil society) and ‘(self-)regulated society’ (state without a state). Theformer characterises capitalist societies and involves the interpenetrationand reinforcement of ‘political society’ and ‘civil society’ inwhich the ruling class(es) compete for hegemony. The latter is morerelevant to the socialist project and alludes to the progressive re-absorptio<strong>no</strong>f political society into civil society with the state as tendentiallycapable of withering away and subsumed into the ‘(self-) regulatedsociety’. In this context, the task of subaltern classes and stratacan<strong>no</strong>t be confined to participating in the ‘integral state’ (with theattendant risk of being subsumed into a continuing statist politics) orto escaping integration into the profit-oriented eco<strong>no</strong>my by engagingin forms of state-led ‘building of new socialist countryside’ in Chinaor worker self-management and/or cooperatives in Venezuela. In thisregard, the Hu/Wen and Chavez strategies need further scrutiny. Thecoexistence of capitalist-socialist ways of managing social relationsdoes <strong>no</strong>t mean socialist elements will eventually displace capitalistones. Furthermore, the prevailing balance among capitalist and socialiststakeholders means that pro-capitalist/neoliberal factions couldstill swing power (e.g. the 2007 ‘No’ vote on Chavez’s constitutionalchanges in Venezuela). This battle for hegemony can<strong>no</strong>t rely on ‘personalcharisma’ (whether of a Chavez or Hu/Wen), vanguard partyand radical rhetoric/practices (e.g. ‘building of new socialist countryside’in China or the creation of community councils in Venezuela)to manage the many capitalist-socialist contradictions and state-civilsociety dialectics. Surely something more is required (e.g. the developmentof ‘organic relation’ between the subaltern and the civilsociety and the deepening of the philosophy of praxis) to deliver onGramsci’s vision of a (self-)regulated society based on justice and there-absorption of political society into civil society.


168 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateReferencesBasker, E. (2007), ‘The Causes and Consequencesof Wal-Mart’s Growth’, Journal of Eco<strong>no</strong>micPerspectives, vol. 21, <strong>no</strong>. 3, pp.177-198.Chan, A. (2007), ‘Organizing Wal-Mart: Two StepsForward, One Step Backward for China’s Unions’,New Labour Forum, vol. 16, <strong>no</strong>. 2, pp. 87-96.Enright, M., Scott, E. and Dodwell, D. (1997), TheHong Kong Advantage, Hong Kong: OxfordUniversity Press.Enright, M., Scott, E. and Ng, K-M. (2005), RegionalPowerhouse: The Greater Pearl River Delta and theRise of China, London: John Wiley & Sons.Free, C. (2006), ‘Walking the Talk? Supply ChainAccounting and Trust Among UK Supermarketsand Supplies’, Social Science Research Network,29 November. http://www.papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=948245, accessed 10 May2008.Free, C. (2007), ‘Supply-Chain Accounting Practicesin the UK Retail Sector: Enabling or CoercingCollaboration?’, Contemporary AccountingResearch, vol. 24, <strong>no</strong>. 2, pp. 897-933.He, D-H. (2000), Collision: the Globalization Trapand China’s Real Choice, Beijng: Eco<strong>no</strong>mic ManagementPress (in Chinese).Holmes, T. (2001), ‘Bar Codes Lead to Frequent Deliveriesand Superstores’, RAND Journal of Eco<strong>no</strong>mics,vol. 34, <strong>no</strong>. 4, pp. 708-725.Martin, R. and Sunley, P. (2003), ‘DeconstructingClusters: Chaotic Concept or Policy Panacea?’ Journalof Eco<strong>no</strong>mic Geography, <strong>no</strong>. 3, pp. 5-35.People’s Daily Newspaper (2008), ‘Premier Wen:China to stick to reform, opening-up’. http://english.people.com.cn/90001/90776/90785/6508633.html,accessed 30 October 2008.Porter, M. (1980), Competitive Strategy: Techniquesfor Analyzing Industries and Competitors, NewYork: Free Press.Porter, M. (1985), Competitive Advantage: Creatingand Sustaining Superior Performance, New York:Free Press.Porter, M. (1990), Competitive Advantage ofNations, Basingstoke: Macmillan.Ruwitch, J. (2007), ‘With Wal-Mart Unionized in China,Now What?’, Reuter, 26 March. http://www.reuters.com/article/featuresNews/idUKHKG27104620070326?pageNumber=4, accessed 6 September 2007.SACOM (2007), ‘Wal-Mart’s Sweatshop MonitoringFails to Catch Violations: The Story of Toys Made inChina for Wal-Mart’, June. http://www.sacom.hk/Uploads/WalMart%20Report(SACOM)Jun2007.pdf, accessed 15 December 2007.Scott, Robert E. (2007), ‘The Wal-Mart Effect: ItsChinese Imports Have Displaced Nearly 200 000US Jobs’, Eco<strong>no</strong>mic Policy Institute, 27 June. http://www.epi.org/content.cfm/ib235, accessed 13 June2008.Sum, N-L. (<strong>2009</strong>a), ‘A Cultural PoliticalEco<strong>no</strong>my of Transnational K<strong>no</strong>wledge Brands:Porterian ‘Competitiveness’: Discourse and itsRecontextualization in Hong Kong/Pearl RiverDelta’, in Tian, H., Chilton, P. and Wodak, R. (eds),Discourses of Globalization in China, Hong Kong:Hong Kong University Press (in press).Sum, N-L. (<strong>2009</strong>b), ‘Articulation of “New Constitutionalism”with “New Ethicalism”: Wal-Martizationand CSR-ization in Developing Countries’ in Utting,P. and Marquez, J. (eds), Business Politics and SocialPolicy: Competitiveness, Infl uence and Inclusive Development,London: Palgrave <strong>2009</strong> (in press).Wang, C-H. (ed.) (2006), One China, Many Paths,London: Verso.


Postneoliberalism in Latin AmericaEmir SaderLatin America has been a laboratory for neoliberal experiments parexcellence. It is <strong>no</strong> accident that it has become the weakest link in theworld’s neoliberal chain.It was the privileged birthplace of neoliberalism (in Pi<strong>no</strong>chet’s Chileand Paz Estensoro’s Bolivia) for very specific reasons. In Chile, it wastouted as an antidote – prescribed by the Chicago School – to the‘statisation’ of the eco<strong>no</strong>my by Salvador Allende’s government. InBolivia, it was treated as a remedy for hyperinfl ation – prescribed byJeffrey Sachs – in such large doses that it killed the patient, exterminatingBolivia’s mining eco<strong>no</strong>my.In both cases, the diag<strong>no</strong>sis had a target: the state and its regulations,expressed in restrictions on the unlimited circulation of capital, instate-owned companies, in the protection of domestic markets, andin workers’ rights. Its aim was to deregulate in order to allow theunlimited circulation of capital, which would supposedly promote areturn to eco<strong>no</strong>mic development, tech<strong>no</strong>logical renewal, distributio<strong>no</strong>f income and a new wave of eco<strong>no</strong>mic modernisation.This new model depended on the prior weakening of the populistmovements’ ability to resist and to defend their rights through politicalparties, social movements and all democratic forms of expressionand organisation. It was, thus, dictatorial processes that made it possibleto create a new neoliberal consensus. This established a new politicalplaying field, based on the polarisation of state and market (eco<strong>no</strong>mically-speaking)and state and civil society (socially-speaking). Anumber of displacements took place in the passage from one model tothe next: the state was displaced by the market, workers and citizensby consumers, rights by competition, work and electoral documentsby credit cards, public squares by shopping centres, human companionshipby television, social policies by private corporate welfare, thenational by the global, social integration by social exclusion, equalityby discrimination, justice by inequality, solidarity by selfishness,humanism by consumerism, social parties and movements by NGOsand volunteer organisations.Initiated by a military dictatorship and a party that had led a nationalistrevolution (the Bolivian revolution of 1952, whose main leader


172 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatewas the very same Paz Estensoro), the neoliberal model revealed itspotential for organising a new hegemony. It spread quickly from thefar right to other essentially nationalist movements (such as Peronismand the Mexican PRI) and social-democratic forces (Chile, Venezuela,Brazil), such that Latin America became the region of the world inwhich it was most prevalent and where it took its most radical forms.Using as a pretext the risk of infl ation and state debt, accentuated bythe debt crisis of the late 1980s and early 1990s, the countries successivelyapplied the same model of fiscal adjustment prescribed by theIMF, successively signing letters of intent that committed their governmentsto minimal state intervention, privatisation, open eco<strong>no</strong>mies andweakened labour relations. Never had the continent been so forcefullyhomogenised by an artificially imported and applied model; never hadnational governments been so weakened; never had inequality and povertydeepened so much in such a short period of time.These same characteristics made the new model reveal its limits andcontradictions with the same speed with which it had been implanted.The first neoliberal crisis exploded in Mexico in 1994, followedby the Brazilian crisis in 1999, and the Argentinean crisis in 2001-2002, affecting the three biggest eco<strong>no</strong>mies in the region. While themodel was still being implanted in Brazil, it was already showingsigns of fragility in the Mexican crisis.The neoliberal model spreadquickly from the far right toother essentially nationalistmovements and socialdemocraticforces, such thatLatin America became theregion of the world in which itwas most prevalent and whereit took its most radical forms.The Chiapas revolution of 1994 in Mexico was the first big expressio<strong>no</strong>f popular resistance, followed by the struggles and protests of Brazil’sLandless Workers’ Movement, indige<strong>no</strong>us movements, especiallyin Bolivia and Ecuador, and the unemployed picketers’ movement inArgentina. The election of Hugo Chavez (contemporary with crisesin the continent’s three biggest eco<strong>no</strong>mies) heralded a new period,moving from a phase of resistance to one of hegemonic dispute,which saw the successive election of new governments in Brazil, Argentina,Uruguay, Bolivia, Ecuador, Nicaragua and Paraguay – andnew perspectives in El Salvador.These governments, to differing degrees, were elected as a reaction toorthodox neoliberal governments, and on the strength of their promisesto reinstate social rights, reduce market power and restore the roleof the state. Lula spoke of social priorities. Hugo Chavez emerged inpolitical life in opposition to Carlos Andrés Perez’s neoliberal package.Kirchner was elected in Argentina after an attempted return byMenem, who had personified one of the most radical forms of neoliberalismon the continent.


postneoliberalism in latin america 173The new governments worked to restore social policies, to end privatisationprocesses and others that weakened the state, and were evenstrengthened to a degree. Processes of integration were a new dimensionand gained importance with time.It fell to the United States and Brazil to finish negotiating the FTAA(Free Trade Area of the Americas); however, the change of governmentin Brazil brought these negotiations to a halt and they wereshelved due to mobilisations against the FTAA. The United Statesstarted to seek bilateral free trade treaties. Mercosur, on the otherhand, was strengthened, as were other forms of regional integration,among which ALBA (Bolivarian Alternative for the Americas) andUSAN (Union of South American Nations).PostneoliberalismWhat is postneoliberalism and why use this expression?Capitalism has gone through various stages in the course of its history.After the initial process of accumulation, which included theso-called ‘commercial revolution’ and the whole process of colonisingthe periphery of the system (including slavery), the building of nationstates was marked by systems of political transition – constitutionalmonarchies, hybrid regimes between absolutism and the emergenceof parliamentary forms of political representation for the new emergingclasses. This period saw a succession of distinct hegemonies: fromthe cities of <strong>no</strong>rthern Italy and Holland, always related to their abilityto control maritime traffic, to the rise of the English hegemony.This brought about a transition from the commercial to the industrialrevolution, establishing a hegemony of capitalist relations of productionand circulation. The historical period of English hegemonycorresponded to the promotion of liberalism as a dominant ideology,which appeared to be the final stage of capitalist development – whenthere was greater consensus regarding its ideology.The 1929 crisis, however, laid the groundwork for the depletion ofthis model. All diag<strong>no</strong>ses of the crisis blame liberal policies, whichreceded in the following decades. After the confl icts exacerbated byWorld War II, the Keynesian model (of regulation and social welfare)became the hegemony, such that Richard Nixon, at the end of histime in office, once said: ‘We are all Keynesians.’After the long post-World War II eco<strong>no</strong>mic boom, capitalism returnedto a more liberal model based on deregulation and ‘free trade’.This didn’t mean returning to a path natural to capitalism; it was


174 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatesimply a different kind of hegemony ushered in by the depletion ofthe last, in the historical conditions of late 20th century capitalism.Through deregulation, it represented the promotion of the hegemonyof financial capital, both nationally and globally. ‘Free trade’ was <strong>no</strong>trestored and high levels of national protectionism remained, especiallyin central capitalist powers.In these circumstances, what might postneoliberalism represent? Itwas <strong>no</strong>t present in the transition from the historical period of worldbipolarity to unipolarity, under the hegemony of the American empire;or the previously mentioned transition from a regular to a neoliberalmodel.Postneoliberalism is based on the conditions generated by liberalism,among whose consequences are the inability to return to long cyclesof eco<strong>no</strong>mic growth. This impossibility has its roots in the hegemonyof financial capital – in its speculative form – over real capital. Theexcess is transferred to the financial arena instead of being channelledinto productive spheres, concentrating income even further in eachcountry and on a world scale.Postneoliberalism represented, among other things, the unprecedentedextension of commercial relations, as deregulation removed impedimentsto the growth of capital in all spheres and territories. Thisgrowth accompanied ideologies that preached market centrality.The excess is transferredto the fi nancial arenainstead of being channelledinto productive spheres,concentrating income evenfurther in each country and ona world scale.Commercialisation and its ideologies are widespread in the countries,especially on the periphery, where financialisation is deeply entrenched.Ideologically speaking, this has promoted a polarisation ofstate and private sector, disqualifying the former and valuing the latter,as well as abolishing the public sphere.A postneoliberal alternative must begin with anti-neoliberalism,which means:- opposition to deregulation;- opposition to financialisation;- opposition to the weakening of labour relations; and- opposition to ‘free trade’.Opposition means both ‘to reject and to move beyond’ – Aufhebung,to use the succinct German expression. It is about discussing what itmeans to reject or move beyond deregulation, financialisation, weakening,and free trade. It is <strong>no</strong>t about its opposite, because historicalconditions filter out concrete possibilities, preventing a game of abstractlogic from being directly transposed into concrete reality.


postneoliberalism in latin america 175A careful analysis of the Bolivian, Ecuadorian and Venezuelan modelsenables us to see the extent to which neoliberal policies in these countries(in addition to Cuba) represent a postneoliberal model or containelements of one. This hypothesis requires a detailed analysis of thesecountries and any others that adopt a postneoliberal logic. It requiresan analysis of the social nature of postneoliberal models, their limitations,contradictions, potentialities and concrete perspectives.Postneoliberalism and anti-capitalismThe left was born, in modern times, in the anti-capitalist struggle,rejecting it and seeking to move beyond it with socialism. Bringingprogress and emancipation to labour relations and the working class,it became the standard-bearer for a classless, stateless society.Long-lasting internal schisms in the labour movement and the leftgave rise to two schools of thought (social democracy and communism),in which the former went from anti-capitalism to the democratisatio<strong>no</strong>f capitalism, and the latter stayed true to the eco<strong>no</strong>mistbase of the Soviet model, but proposed prior transitional stages to theanti-capitalist struggle in other countries. This struggle was increasinglytempered by other historical moments.Capitalism’s passage to its neoliberal era extended commercial relationsto an unprecedented degree, as if realising capitalism’s originalpromises. In the process, however, power relations between socialclasses were radically transformed, for the worst as far as anti-capitalistforces were concerned. A gulf grew between the conditions for thedepletion of capitalism and those required in order to move beyond it– which sums up the greatest historical drama of our day.One response to the crisis of depletion of the neoliberal model privilegesthe first element of this equation and points to the identificationbetween anti-neoliberalism and anti-capitalism, causing this struggleto lead to socialism or to only find direct resolution in socialism.This conception is based on the understanding that the neoliberal erawould be the last stage of capitalism – according to Giovanni Arrighi’sanalyses of the final stages of each cycle of hegemony on a historicalscale. 1 He predicted that they would end precisely with moments ofhegemony of financial capital, revealing the depletion of the model’scapacity for production and redistribution. That was what happenedat the end of the Dutch and British hegemonies and Arrighi believedit would be repeated with the decline of the US hegemony.1 Arrighi, Giovanni (1994), The Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power, and the Origins ofOur Times, London/New York: Verso.


176 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateOn the other hand, the deregulation fostered by neoliberal policiesfavoured the hegemony of financial capital in its speculative mode. I<strong>no</strong>rder to instate a different model, it would be necessary to introducenew forms of eco<strong>no</strong>mic regulation, which would be very difficult,even in the current crisis, once deregulation had a foothold. It could<strong>no</strong>t come from a single country, <strong>no</strong> matter what its importance, becauseothers would benefit from the flow of capital rejected in thiscountry. At the same time, it would be hard to come to a large-scaleinternational agreement, due to the different interests of the biggestpowers and international corporations.The end of international bipolarity, however, has shrunk the internationalhorizon (previously restricted to the capitalist arena), withChina reconverting its eco<strong>no</strong>my to market relations and Cuba havinga hard time moving beyond the end of its socialist arena.Arrighi saw the axes for overcoming the US hegemony in the rise ofAsia. First, in Japan, whose prolonged recession stopped it from playinga greater role in the hegemonic crisis; then in the ‘Asian tigers’,which were hit by one of the biggest international financial crises inthe late 1990s; and, finally, China, which is rapidly transitioning to amarket eco<strong>no</strong>my. As such, the possibilities for revealing the declineof the United States are all located in capitalist eco<strong>no</strong>mies and do <strong>no</strong>tlend themselves to a process of postcapitalist transition.The same dilemma occurs at a national level: while neoliberalism haspointed to the limits of capitalism (whether to promote eco<strong>no</strong>micdevelopment or distribution of wealth), it has simultaneously underminedsolutions for moving beyond it, whether these be neoliberal or,even more so, capitalist. It has corroded social bases by forcing mostworkers out of formal work relations, leaving them in a precarioussituation in which it is very difficult for them to organise themselves,to obtain political and legal representation, to assume a social identity,to build a collective culture and to fight for their rights. It has alsobeen corrosive by consolidating the hegemony of liberal ideologies,especially through the spreading influence of the ‘American way oflife’ – from the proliferation of shopping centres to publicity and thecommercial nature of the media.This combination of factors has made the essential drama of today’sworld, as stated earlier, the abyss between the depletion of capitalism– <strong>no</strong>w in its neoliberal phase – and a delay in the subjective conditionsfor generating possibilities for moving beyond it. This gulf explains,in short, the contemporary world’s crisis of hegemony and the dilemmasof postneoliberalism.


postneoliberalism in latin america 177Latin America was the first region to adopt neoliberalism as its hegemonicmodel, as well as the earliest to try to implant alternatives. Itwent from being a region in which the model was dominant to a territoryof hegemonic instability in which alternatives were sought.Resistance to neoliberalism in countries like Brazil, Uruguay andMexico, among others, has fostered the constitution of a significantopposing force, which in many cases has halted the full realisation ofneoliberal projects. However, while some political powers with theirroots in these movements have begun to express resistance to neoliberalismin the political arena, they have <strong>no</strong>t put postneoliberal policiesinto practice. They have remained within the model, temperingit with compensatory social policies.Four governments seek to locate themselves outside of this model:Cuba, Venezuela, Bolivia and Ecuador. They are developing differentpolitical models with distinct socio-eco<strong>no</strong>mic structures, but theyshare a tendency <strong>no</strong>t to make eco<strong>no</strong>mic-financial objectives centraland favour policies with social objectives. They seek a strategy inwhich eco<strong>no</strong>mic concerns are subordinate to social concerns, breakingthe hegemony of financial capital and market mechanisms.The anti-neoliberal struggle: from resistance to hegemonyAs mentioned earlier, in forging a new path the Latin American lefthas gone from a defensive phase, when the hegemony of neoliberalismwas almost unquestionable during the 1990s, to hegemonic dispute. Assuch, social movements, which had been fundamental protagonists inthe phase of resistance, have had to face some difficult dilemmas.During the phase of resistance the left was harshly critical of politicalparties, governments, the state, and the political sphere itself, developingthe expression ‘auto<strong>no</strong>my of social movements’ as a sphere of‘civil society,’ important in the struggle against neoliberalism. Thisallowed them to regroup for resistance in the social arena.The neoliberal model began to show signs of depletion with the crisesin Mexico, Brazil and Argentina, making room for forms of political regroupingin opposition to neoliberalism. The election of Hugo Chavezin 1998 marked the beginning of this process, which had already beenin the making for 10 years, with the multiplication of governments ofa new kind, some of which were openly anti-neoliberal, while otherssought to make the model more flexible. It is safe to say, however, thatthe golden age of neoliberalism is over and that this is a new period ofdisputes over the kind of government that should succeed it.


178 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateThe movements that fell under the umbrella of the ‘auto<strong>no</strong>my of socialmovements’, declined to participate in national political disputesand ended up confined to limited spaces or even disappearing fromthe national arena. The former is what happened with the Zapatistas,who were isolated in Chiapas, Mexico, lost their capacity for nationalpresence and found themselves without proposals that allowed themto rally support at a national level and emerge as an alternative for thecountry as a whole. The latter is what happened with the picketersin Argentina, who, after the country’s biggest political crisis, whichsaw the succession of three presidents in one week, when presidentialelections were called, did <strong>no</strong>t participate, taking refuge in the motto‘Everybody out!’ As a result, Nestor Kirchner occupied the space ofopposition to the return of Carlos Menem and capitalised on the energyof the popular movements. A few years later, the picketers hadpractically disappeared, except the sector that had aligned itself withthe government.The Bolivian example, on the other hand, was paradigmatic. Thenew cycle of popular movements and uprisings that began with the‘water war’ in 2000 led to the foundation of the Movement for Socialism(MAS) in order to dispute the political direction of the state.Through a critique of Bolivia’s traditional left (which reduced theindige<strong>no</strong>us to peasants, small landowners, and supposed secondaryallies of working-class miners, erasing all of their secular identitiesas Aymaras, Quechuas and Guaranis), it was possible to reconstructa political subject from the original peoples, which led to the firstindige<strong>no</strong>us leader being elected president and the beginning of thebuilding of a new state in the country.In other ways, this is also the path taken by the Ecuadorian and Venezuelanpopular social movements. In Ecuador, indige<strong>no</strong>us movementshave shown great resistance and removed two presidents (thethird, Lucio Gutierrez, was ousted more by urban social movements),without, however, assuming direction of the state, delegating it toothers, until they felt betrayed, which caused rifts and weakened themovement. The election of Rafael Correa marked a return to the cycleof mobilisations in the dispute for control of the state and its refoundation.Similarly, the Venezuelan process, where nationalist militarymen were initially the protagonists, is heading in a similar direction,in this case supporting the emergence of a new movement of themasses, which did <strong>no</strong>t previously exist in the country.In countries with moderate governments, which have <strong>no</strong>t openly abandonedthe model but have given it more flexibility (in Brazil, for exam-


postneoliberalism in latin america 179ple, financial policies have remained the same, but within a new eco<strong>no</strong>micscenario), such as Argentina, Uruguay, Brazil, and probably Paraguay,relations between social movements and political powers are stillfairly traditional, although with forms of support that are critical of thegovernments. In these countries the dilemmas of the social movementsare <strong>no</strong>t easily solved, because there are only two positions in the politicalarena: those who break with these governments (whom they believeto be following directly in their predecessors’ footsteps and, thus, meremanagers of neoliberal models) and who become the main enemies ofthese movements (a position characteristic of the extreme left in thesecountries); or those who align themselves with the left-wing sectors ofthese governments, reflecting their contradictory nature, in the struggleagainst their conservative sectors.In countries with moderategovernments, which have<strong>no</strong>t openly abandoned themodel but have given it morefl exibility, such as Argentina,Uruguay, Brazil, and probablyParaguay, relations betweensocial movements andpolitical powers are still fairlytraditional.The Latin American populist arena is made up of these moderate governmentsand others which have in common <strong>no</strong>t only social policiesthat restore the rights expropriated by neoliberalism, but also foreignpolicies that privilege regional integration in detriment to the signingof free trade treaties with the Unites States. Many fail to understandthat this is the fundamental dividing line on the continent today, ratherthan one between a so-called ‘good left’ and ‘bad left,’ as preachedby right-wing theoreticians (such as Jorge Castañeda, among others),who seek to divide the left, co-opting the moderate sector and isolatingmore radical elements.After a beginning with relatively fast progress, the new governmentsbegan to suffer strong attacks from a relatively recomposed right.That was what happened in the attempted coup in April 2002 inVenezuela, and later in the harsh attacks on Lula, Nestor and CristinaKirchner, and Evo Morales. These did <strong>no</strong>t represent a new rightwingplatform, but attempts to weaken these governments, underminingtheir ability to continue to seek alternatives to the model andto make progress in regional integration. The future of the region inthe first half of the new century will be at stake in elections to determinethe successors of the current presidents (Lula, Tabaré Vazques,Cristina Kirchner, Hugo Chavez, Evo Morales, Rafael Correa). Itwill be decided whether these current governments will be able tocontinue and advance toward postneoliberalism, or be replaced bygovernments that, albeit with a different face, will restore the neoliberalmodel. It is this struggle between the new (which seeks, with difficulty,to forge new paths) and the old (which seeks to resist, with <strong>no</strong>less difficulty) that marks the current instability on the continent: theexpression of a great crisis of hegemony that characterises its presenthistorical moment.


Notes on postneoliberalism inArgentinaVerónica Gago and Diego SztulwarkCan we consider the Argentine situation under the concept of postneoliberalism?After the crisis of 2001, seen in the whole region as thefailure and the deepest delegitimisation of cold hard neoliberalism, aperiod of great changes began, in terms of the social significance ofthe state, the political capacity of social movements and the reorganisatio<strong>no</strong>f general labour conditions. Here, we shall try to analyse thesetransformations, starting with some sequences that we consider keyto comprehending both the dynamics of the process leading to thepresent-day global crisis and the new space of intervention that can beforeseen, from the Argentine debate, for nation states.From crisis to impasseWe propose classifying at least three phases in recent Argentine politics.The political and social crisis at the end of 2001, which we call‘de-stituent’, 1 can be described as the ‘end of fear’, the ‘end of neoliberallegitimacy’, and the ‘end of the party system’ (phase 1). From 2003onwards, these variables turned into new fears (the issue of insecurity),a neodevelopmental and nation-state intervention scheme (helpedby the exchange rate and a re-proletarianisation of the labour forcein the face of massive unemployment), and a new governmentality 2(complex dynamics including partial recognition of the elements thatwere emerging during the crisis, and the modification of the regionalscenario) (phase 2). At the present time, it is <strong>no</strong>t at all impossible toenvisage a ‘restoring’ kind of dynamics that tries to arouse ‘old fears’,to force a return to neoliberalism, although new-styled, and appeal tothe old bipartisanship (phase 3).1 Translators’ <strong>no</strong>te: We have chosen to use the expression ‘de-stituent’ as a translatio<strong>no</strong>f the Spanish word ‘destituyente’, which makes reference to the power that unseatsa regime, in order to preserve the resonances that indicate a power opposite to thatwhich institutes or that which is part of a constitutive process. We use the hyphento avoid confusion with the English word ‘destitute’, which carries con<strong>no</strong>tations ofimpoverishment.2 From the French ‘gouvernementalité’, a term coined by Foucauld to emphasise theclose link between forms of power and processes of subjectifi cation.


182 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateSo if the crisis of 2000/2001 was one of opening-up and in<strong>no</strong>vation,what soon become clearly visible were the social movements’ ownimaginative and political limitations, which act as constraints on thepolicies intended to replace the old neoliberal model. In this sense,the lack of imagination is <strong>no</strong>t abstract, but implies successive barriersto social in<strong>no</strong>vations. It is what we call the current impasse: theblocking of the most in<strong>no</strong>vative dynamics of the last decade. In turn,neodevelopmentalism, the new governmentality and the recyclingof social fears have limits set on them by the revival of imaginarieslinked to the decades prior to the consolidation of neoliberalism .The 2001 crisis made evident what we have described as a new socialprotagonism 3 : a succession of struggles and experiences of self-mobilisation,which reorganised political practices through direct action andthe rejection of the institutional representation of collective dynamics.The movements of the unemployed, as well as the factories takingoverof factories by their workers, the neighbourhood assemblies andthe escraches, 4 as a practical form of popular justice, of social condemnatio<strong>no</strong>f the ge<strong>no</strong>cides of the last dictatorship, can be distinguished as themost original and powerful expressions of that protagonism.The period that immediately followed the 2001 crisis was characterised,after a dizzy succession of five presidents, by the arrival of a Peronistgovernment: Eduardo Duhalde was then elected president byparliamentary agreement and <strong>no</strong>t through a general election. His administrationproposed stabilising the crisis through devaluation of thecurrency (the end of the one peso one dollar exchange rate, which hadguaranteed infl ationary stability during the 1990s) and a multiplicityof social programmes for the unemployed. However, the repression ofsocial movements, culminating in the killing of two piqueteros, 5 DaríoSantillán and Maximilia<strong>no</strong> Kosteki, forced a call for elections and atthe same time demonstrated the government’s inability to stabilisethe political confl ict. Thus in 2003 the first national election since thecrisis was held. Both majority parties became fragmented. Three candidatesfrom the Unión Cívica Radical competed against three Peronistcandidates. In first place was ex-President Carlos Menem, with lessthan 30 per cent of the vote, and in second place, with less than 25 perThe movements ofthe unemployed, theneighbourhood assembliesand the escraches, as apractical form of popularjustice, of social condemnatio<strong>no</strong>f the ge<strong>no</strong>cides of thelast dictatorship, can bedistinguished as the mostoriginal and powerfulexpressions of the new socialprotagonism.3 Colectivo Situaciones (2002), Apuntes para el nuevo protagonismo social, <strong>no</strong>. 19/20,Bue<strong>no</strong>s Aires: Ediciones de ma<strong>no</strong> en ma<strong>no</strong>.4 The Spanish slang word ‘escrache’ refers to a particular kind of demonstration ofteninvolving public shaming.5 Members of organisations of unemployed workers whose main form of protest was thepiquete, or road block.


<strong>no</strong>tes on postneoliberalism in argentina 183cent, was Néstor Kirchner, supported at that time by President Duhalde.Called to a second round, Carlos Menem gave up his candidature,and Kirchner had to take charge with <strong>no</strong> real electoral support.The Kirchner administration coincided with a rapid macroeco<strong>no</strong>micrecovery based on international grain prices (particularly of soyabeans, already developed on the basis of direct planting, with thewhole ‘tech<strong>no</strong>logical package’ associated with this method), and thedelayed internal consumer demand. Its efforts were directed towardsrenewing – mainly on the symbolic basis of debate – ways of perceivingthe relationship between government and social movements aspart of an overall move to restore the authority of state institutionsin the context of the crisis of legitimacy vis-à-vis political parties andneoliberal debate. This kind of gesture politics was consolidated particularlythrough the use of the language of the struggles of the 1970sand, in the area of human rights, the abolition of the ‘impunity laws’,the consequent reopening of trials on the effects of repression and afull ack<strong>no</strong>wledgment of human rights organisms.In a less complete manner, the government promoted, in its particularway, an active relationship with different social movements of theunemployed, refraining, at the same time, from using repression todeal with movements that had placed themselves at a distance fromthe government, or opposed it. But these in<strong>no</strong>vations, in terms ofgovernmentality, were never pure or complete; rather, they were developedin parallel to a greater effort to revive, under its dominance,the old trade unionist and political scheme of Peronism, the basis ofits territorial, parliamentary and electoral power. It is <strong>no</strong>t possible toconsider the record of this period complete without at least mentioningthe achievement, in the Latin American context, of a completelynew geopolitical auto<strong>no</strong>my and of a renewal of forms of regionalgovernment, determined by the social movements’ resistance to theneoliberal consensus. In this context, the Argentine government accomplisheda famous renegotiation of its external debt.In December 2007, CristinaFernández de Kirchnerassumed the presidency afterwinning the fi rst electoralround with almost 50 per centof the vote.In December 2007, Cristina Fernández de Kirchner assumed the presidencyafter winning the first electoral round with almost 50 per centof the vote. Shortly before, in the city of Bue<strong>no</strong>s Aires the candidateof the neoliberal right had won at the polls, taking more than 60 percent in the second round against the government-backed candidate.The explicit programme set out by the present government rests onthe concept of an (unspecified ) new social and political pact vis-à-visthe bicentenary of the nation state (2010), with a view to stabilisingthe governmentality in respect of social and eco<strong>no</strong>mic actors, based


184 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateon a neodevelopmental orientation, on continental integration andthe recovery of the nation state, on the construction of an export-ledindustrial eco<strong>no</strong>my, on the fight against poverty, and on the continuatio<strong>no</strong>f the achievements in the field of human rights, <strong>no</strong>t to mentionthe protagonism of social movements.On 11 March 2008, the new finance minister an<strong>no</strong>unced a new schemeof export taxes on grain, introducing a sliding-scale taxation systemand quotas. The radical opposition to the measure from the four farmers’organisations (from the traditional and oligarchic Sociedad Rural tothe historically small farmers’ organisation Federación Agraria) organiseda four-month-long protest against the tax measure. The extensive socialmobilisation was finally resolved in parliament – after a presidentialdecree calling for legislative debate – with the defeat of the governmentin the Senate.This was <strong>no</strong> longer merely a confl ict, owing to its magnitude, its implicationsand its effect. A brief description of some of its aspects maybe necessary. The basic reasoning underlying the export tax policyis shared by all the actors: the growth of the Argentine eco<strong>no</strong>my,backed up, among other things, by the e<strong>no</strong>rmous agrarian revenues,mostly based on the direct planting of soya beans. The principal argumentthe government held up for modifying the export taxationscheme was that the international rise of production prices exportedby Argentine agricultural tech<strong>no</strong>logy required regulation so that reasonabledomestic food prices could be maintained.The basic reasoningunderlying the export taxpolicy is shared by all theactors: the growth of theArgentine eco<strong>no</strong>my, backedup, among other things, by thee<strong>no</strong>rmous agrarian revenues,mostly based on the directplanting of soya beans.


<strong>no</strong>tes on postneoliberalism in argentina 185The main objections of the exporting sectors, who opposed the measure,were: (a) that it was necessary to divide the levies according tosmall, medium-sized and big producers; (b) that it was also indispensableto create an integrated agricultural policy; (c) that the governmentwas seeking to obtain financial resources in order to sustain its legitimacybased on the expansion of public expenditure and the subsidisingof other capital sectors. During the confl ict the agricultural sector organisations,which consist of small, medium-sized and large landownersinvolved in the soya bean business, opposed the increase in exporttaxes by developing forms of struggle inherited from the phase prior to2003: rallies, road blocks and picket lines, banging pots and pans duringdemonstrations in the towns, escraches de<strong>no</strong>uncing government legislators,and the rhetoric of self-mobilisation against the state.The government and its supporters, together with the intellectualswho organised themselves to underpin the government’s arguments,put forward in its defence three fundamental lines of reasoning : theidea that the tax increases were redistributive and designed to combatthe concentration of income; that the struggle against raising exportduties stemmed from a coup d’état plan; and that it was necessaryto confront a right-wing faction, in the media and the soya beanbusiness, by recovering the imaginaries and discourses of the popularstruggles of the previous decades. 6It is in this context of an impasse that we believe the possibility of reflectingon postneoliberalism in Argentina has to be put to the test.There are two areas to explore. On the one hand, there is the weakeningof the complex variety of certain social questions that formulatedthe struggles, as much when they made their sudden appearanceas during their phases of withdrawal or persistence: questions concerningwage labour, self-management, the taking-over of factoriesand companies, political representation, forms of deliberation and decision-making,urban ways of living, communication, food distribution, and the struggle against impunity and repression. On the otherhand, and parallel to it, there is the crisis caused by the government’sway of responding to those questions – namely, in restorative terms;that is, as demands to be met – while, in many respects, the same actorsand dynamics present during the period of the introduction anddiffusion of neoliberalism are still there.6 See, for a fuller analysis, Colectivo Situaciones, ‘¿La vuelta de la política?’,www.situaciones.org


186 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateSome defi nitions of neoliberalismWe start from the following thesis (which reflects the thinking ofGramsci and Foucault): the aspects concerned with power and freedom– in other words, those that have been the subject of politicalphilosophy for centuries – refer to the relationship between the governedand the gover<strong>no</strong>rs. We perceive neoliberalism as a configurationbelonging to a certain form of relationship between power(relation between truth and law) and resistance (creation of counterbehaviour).If we start from the relation between neoliberalism andbiopolitics, 7 we can understand why it is <strong>no</strong>t worth insisting on a perspectiveof ‘auto<strong>no</strong>my of politics’. Rather we adopt the perspective –that is active today on this continent – of bio-resistances (or biopoliticsin the precise sense given to the concept by Negri and Hardt).One of the most obvious limits in Argentina to understanding thechallenge facing us as a result of the crisis of neoliberalism consists ofig<strong>no</strong>ring the difference between ‘liberalism’ and ‘neoliberalism’. Hereare some reflections on this issue:1. If neoliberalism, unlike its antecedent, depends on an infinite numberof institutions and regulations (to such an extent that Foucault defines itas an active policy without state control, and therefore an object of directinterventions) the crisis of neoliberalism is <strong>no</strong>t the crisis of the freemarket, but a crisis concerning the legitimacy of those policies. Therefore,we should cast some light on the field of resistant subjectivities thathave taken this regulation system into crisis.2. Neoliberalism is <strong>no</strong>t a matter of the realm of eco<strong>no</strong>my suppressingthat of politics, but of the formation of a political world (system ofgovernmentality) that arises as a ‘projection’ of the rules and requirementsof the competitive market.3. The total lack of clarity and subtlety of thinking at the present timein Argentine can be seen in the theoretical separating of the two sequences‘liberalism-market-eco<strong>no</strong>my’ and ‘developmentalism-statepolitics’,and of supposing that the latter is able, step by step, to correct7 We use the concept of biopolitics in a broader sense and without discriminatinghere between the interpretations that have emerged since the work of Foucault(particularly, in current Italian political philosophy: Agamben, Espósito, Hardt andNegri, Vir<strong>no</strong>, etc.). We propose instead a conceptual image that we take from LópezPetit and that could be useful for our purpose: the fact that capital has becomeindistinguishable from existence, from life itself, and that to undertake a reconquestof emancipatory activity it is impossible to think from an external space about capitaland its power mechanisms. In this context, all resistance, all counter-actions areimmediately political, bioresistant.


<strong>no</strong>tes on postneoliberalism in argentina 187and replace the former. But this way of thinking implies the risk of animmediate and general repositioning and relegitimisation of a ‘political’neoliberalism, owing to the absence of any critical reflection onthe modes of articulation between institution and competition (betweenliberalism and neoliberalism). Any diag<strong>no</strong>sis that re<strong>no</strong>uncessingularity, correlates with policies devoid of singularity with respectto the present challenge.4. In a sense, all over the continent the same problem is at stake: arethe repositioning of the state and the new anti-liberal leadership ableto overcome neoliberalism? Our thesis is that it is only the energy displayedin the movements and revolts of the last decades on the continentthat anticipates new subjects and rationalities, which, again andagain, are undermined with the reintroduction of an authenticallyliberal rationality starting with the ‘recuperation of the state’. 85. What is under discussion <strong>no</strong>w is neoliberalism. And what will existafter neoliberalism is the substitution of some institutions by others,if we define institutions as something more profound and active thanthe political-institutional scaffolding we have k<strong>no</strong>wn.6. Let us (with Vir<strong>no</strong>) describe the ‘institution’ of post-capitalism asthe projection of a space for the development of a new rationality, asbriefly glimpsed in the rebellions and new subjectivities in America’sSouthern Cone during the last decade.7. Finally, these distinctions would permit us to distinguish betweenpostneoliberalism and a neoliberalism of the left 9 which integrates thedelegitimisation of neoliberalism only in terms of political debate .Neo-developmentalism?We k<strong>no</strong>w that the global crisis is <strong>no</strong>t merely an eco<strong>no</strong>mic crisis, becausecapitalism is <strong>no</strong>t merely eco<strong>no</strong>mic, but the subsuming of life bycapital, into the language of accountancy and monetary codification.Neither is it an exclusively local crisis. Even the Argentine government,which, at the beginning, thought what was happening was aWe k<strong>no</strong>w that the global crisisis <strong>no</strong>t merely an eco<strong>no</strong>miccrisis, because capitalism is<strong>no</strong>t merely eco<strong>no</strong>mic, butthe subsuming of life bycapital, into the language ofaccountancy and monetarycodifi cation.8 A different thesis is the one Negri proposes concerning the power of movements thatare ‘passing through at a distance’ (atravesamiento con distanciamiento). See interviewwith Toni Negri,‘Cambio de paradigmas’, by Verónica Gago, Página/12, Bue<strong>no</strong>s Aires, 4December 2007.9 This idea of a ‘neoliberalism of the left’ is elborated on by Raúl Zibechi. See interviewwith him by M. Laura Carpinetta: ‘Seguimos bajo un modelo neoliberal’, Página/12,Bue<strong>no</strong>s Aires, 23 September 2008.


188 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatenational crisis in the United States, without any consequences for ourcountry, is <strong>no</strong>w realising the immediately transnational dimensionsof the disaster. A world is becoming evident in which the markettends to become second nature, constantly underpinned by institutionswhich, at the moment, situate themselves at the centre of thescene: states, international regulators and diverse attempts at globallegality.Is it possible that so much sincerity confirms the ideological certaintiesof the anti-imperialist left? The global crisis is revealing the relativeloss of influence of the United States and of their claim to be theonly superpower (a position they have wanted to maintain since theend of the Cold War). Quite clearly, new strategies of regional developmentare emerging which, in one way or a<strong>no</strong>ther, form part of thegovernment of social exchanges. Is it possible (and convenient) to beig<strong>no</strong>rant of the fluid and confl icting dynamic that is developing onthat level? Are <strong>no</strong>t the still timid plans for regional integration in theSouthern Cone Region precisely a sign of the extent to which a newspace for these initiatives exists? Should we <strong>no</strong>t discuss instead theneo developmental nature with which it is intended to characterise thesenew forms of governmentality?These oversimplified concepts of the crisis serve only to legitimatepowers, <strong>no</strong>t to open up political spaces. It is what happens when onesimply confronts national integration and the global market, withoutthinking about the nature of the new forms of global regulation, ofhierarchies and of the exploitative relations preserved in the nationalspace itself. The anti-imperialist rhetoric runs the risk of losing itsprevious antagonistic efficiency and of being put at the service of thenational development plans to codify the in<strong>no</strong>vations introduced bythe social movements of South America during the last decade (removalof neoliberal institutionality and legitimacy, elimination of repressiveagendas, and so on).Moreover, such confrontation hinders understanding of the apparentlyindirect connections between the militaristic ideas elaboratedin the United States, as the predominant way of managing the globalorder, and the frontiers of ‘dangerousness’ (government through fear),which are being developed in the Latin American countries as a strategyto control the population (in particular migrant workers).The simple identification of more regulation and democratic management,which is being proposed, could, especially <strong>no</strong>wadays, bea destructive path for social movements. Especially if the agenda for


<strong>no</strong>tes on postneoliberalism in argentina 189this ‘return to the state’ is undertaken without fundamental discussionson the nature of those ‘regulations’, as well as on the type ofinstitutions that would be necessary to overcome the state’s role asguarantor and supporter of neoliberal accumulation based on the directexploitation of life, of the product of social cooperation and ofnatural resources.Who in our time is in a betterposition to capitalise on thesymbols of the nation, aswell as to exploit its meagreremains, than the supportersof capitalist globalisation?The Latin American perspectiveThe idea of the nation is again in dispute. And its positive agenda canbe taken up again if it is opened up right across the continent (andthe rest of the Third World), and if it is renewed on the basis of socialin<strong>no</strong>vation created through new and old forms of popular action.Otherwise, who in our time is in a better position to capitalise on thesymbols of the nation, as well as to exploit its meagre remains, thanthe supporters of capitalist globalisation (see the recent change of theRepsol-YPF logo into YPF with the Argentine fl ag as background)?The nation is one of the viable symbolic grounds for the re-buildingof an (always global) capitalism in search of reinventing its power oftotal command over the crisis.The crisis of capital (which is profound and affects civilisation itself)anticipates its attempt to reorganise a political institutionality and,accordingly, the instruments of social domination (the world of newregulations to come). The task <strong>no</strong>w is to create and strengthen areasof identification and production of common signs, in order to exchangeand strengthen forms of resistance and critical perspectives,and institutions capable of understanding and acting at the level ofantagonism; which requires – whether as open confrontations or asa series of agreements – communication and independent thinkingwith regard to those institutions dedicated to the re-establishment ofcapital.In Latin America, as we k<strong>no</strong>w, we live in a different situation fromthe rest of the Western world. The crisis of neoliberalism explodedbefore, and the new actors divided their forces to continue with theirown development and to take part in a series of new governments(very dissimilar from each other, with differing means of discussingand perceiving the global-capitalist world, and of creating a new dynamicsas the foundation), which have included these actos in variousways and in various proportions. Still today we are involved inthe ambivalences of this dual process, in which, on the one side, themovements are confronted with the necessity of seeking auto<strong>no</strong>myfor their spaces of development, organisation and politicisation of new


190 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatedynamics, and, on the other hand, according to circumstances, theybecome more or less involved in some governmental dynamics whichthey do <strong>no</strong>t always control.Postneoliberalism: a hypothesis for ArgentinaTo talk about postneoliberalism means, for us, the possibility of aquestion: shall we be able to confront these new scenarios critically,based on a renewed polarity between collective protagonists and therestored/reformed institutions of capital?In our country, the discussion is complex, because the identificatio<strong>no</strong>f state intervention with democracy and social distribution hassometimes been useful to make room for policies with a progressive(distributive) agenda. However the rhetoric with which those policiesis invoked <strong>no</strong>wadays is too often associated with evoking a pastto which we should return. This underestimation of the new logicsof production and of the contemporary social and political subjectivitiesgives scope for reactionary (expropriating) understandings of thatpast and of those categories, enabling the repositioning of state interventionaccording to the requirements of capitalist accumulation anddenying the implicit potential of the present.The deficient powers of neoliberal institutionality (which, in its time,gave place to countless organised social movements) continue beingan indispensable argument for an authentic postneoliberal policy.


<strong>no</strong>tes on postneoliberalism in argentina 191


192 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debate


Realistic postneoliberalism– A view from South AfricaPatrick Bond 1Those who declare that the Great Crash of late 2008 heralds the endof neoliberalism are <strong>no</strong>t paying close e<strong>no</strong>ugh attention, includingeven the Swedish Bank’s ‘Eco<strong>no</strong>mic Nobel Prize’ laureate for 2008,Paul Krugman (2008):Everyone’s talking about a new New Deal, for obvious reasons. In2008, as in 1932, a long era of Republican political dominance cameto an end in the face of an eco<strong>no</strong>mic and financial crisis that, in voters’minds, both discredited the [Republican] free-market ideologyand undermined its claims of competence. And for those on theprogressive side of the political spectrum, these are hopeful times.I disagree. It is <strong>no</strong>t time to go ‘postneoliberal’ in policy argumentationwithin the existing institutional framework, given the adverse balance offorces in the world today, even accounting for the November 2008 USelection. Instead, a more realistic – and also radical – approach requiresus first to humbly ack<strong>no</strong>wledge that a more dangerous and painful periodlies immediately ahead, because of at least three factors:• public policy will suffer from the financial sector crisis via intenseausterity, pressures associated with extreme eco<strong>no</strong>mic volatility (suchas privatisation), and a renewed lobby for micro-neoliberal strategies;• there remains unjustified faith in the multilateral system (from Kyototo Bretton Woods revivalism), which distracts us from the national-scalesolutions that are both feasible and radical; and• a new threat arises, in the form of relegitimised neoliberalism and imperialism,via the election of Barack Obama as US president.South Africa and Africa offer myriad illustrations of these problems.The view I have from Durban leads me to conclude that until wechange the power balance, a new era of global-scale postneoliberalismimposed from the top down is a fantasy, whether envisaged from1 Some of these ideas were debated at the Gyeongsang University Institute for SocialStudies (supported by the Korea Research Foundation’s grant KRF-2005-005-J00201).Thanks are also due to numerous collaborators in other institutions and justicemovements, especially Dennis Brutus at CCS.


194 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatePretoria, Beijing, Caracas, Washington, New York or European capitals.Moving forward requires hard work, <strong>no</strong>t just a capitalist crisis.What kind of work will be needed to achieve a postneoliberal politicaleco<strong>no</strong>my, or at least the conditions that would make such possible?In two articles for the Dag Hammarskjold Foundation – ‘Perilsof elite pacting’ in Critical Currents <strong>no</strong>. 1 Bond 2007a) and in ‘Linkingbelow, across and against’ in the Development Dialogue Global CivilSociety special issue (Bond 2007b) – I raised two dilemmas, respectively:first, uncoordinated, dysfunctional global intra-capitalist cohesio<strong>no</strong>n major policy problems; and second, the potentials but alsoserious weaknesses in the countervailing World Social Forum andglobal justice movements. But if many would share my skepticismabout global-scale solutions to problems, then what <strong>no</strong>w requires elaboration(in this article) is the variety of national-scale opportunities andaccomplishments on the left. This is a particularly acute time to refocusour attention on sites of genuine power, given the misleading hypeabout a new Bretton Woods conference under G20 (or even UnitedNations Financing for Development) mandates, or a <strong>2009</strong> Copenhagensolution to the Kyoto Protocol’s malaise.To transcend fruitless callsfor United Nations solutionsto environmental, eco<strong>no</strong>micand geopolitical problems,we need to reconsidernational state powerssuch as exchange controls,defaults on unrepayble debts,fi nancial nationalisation andenvironmental reregulation.In addressing the core problems identified above, the view from South Africais revealing, if combined with other examples from around the world:• to counteract the austerity, volatility and micro-neoliberalism, weneed to immediately recall and reorganise campaigning associatedwith defence against fi nancial degradation (cf. Altvater, this volume);• to transcend fruitless calls for United Nations solutions to environmental,eco<strong>no</strong>mic and geopolitical problems, we need to reconsider nationalstate powers such as exchange controls, defaults on unrepayble debts, fi -nancial nationalisation and environmental reregulation, and the deglobalisation/decommodification strategy for basic needs goods; and• to assist the re-delegitimisation of US power, we need to insist on aworld <strong>no</strong>t addicted to the US dollar and all that it represents eco<strong>no</strong>mically,and also to provide critical (<strong>no</strong>t dogmatic) support to risinganti-imperialist potentials.These are some of the crucial strategic orientations that are requiredto move from an illusory postneoliberal hubris, claimed by progressivesin many sites around the world, to a more durable terrain uponwhich firm foundations are laid for human and environmental rightsas political determinants, instead of markets and profits. The rest ofthe article lays out the problem and pilots for the solutions (due toconstraints of space, focusing on financial degradation and the rel-


ealistic postneoliberalism – a view from south africa 195egitimation of neoliberalism and imperialism), drawing especiallyupon national (South African) political processes that are realistic incoming months/years.Our <strong>no</strong>t-yet-postneoliberal reality: fi nancial degradationAs this issue of Development Dialogue went to press, the G20 had justmet to discuss the way forward for global financial regulation. In their15 November 2008 statement, the G20 (2008:1) clumsily conjoineddisparate ideologies:We must lay the foundation for reform to help to ensure that a globalcrisis, such as this one, does <strong>no</strong>t happen again. Our work will beguided by a shared belief that market principles, open trade and investmentregimes, and effectively regulated financial markets fosterthe dynamism, in<strong>no</strong>vation, and entrepreneurship that are essentialfor eco<strong>no</strong>mic growth, employment, and poverty reduction.That essentially pro-market approach was balanced, however, by Europeanvoices at the G20 (as reported by Parker, Ward and Hall, 2008):Spain’s governing Socialist party summed up the heady mood in someparts of Europe in an internal document, seen by El Mundo, that identifiedthe summit as a moment of historic change. ‘The origins of thiscrisis lie in neoliberal and neoconservative ideology,’ it said.At the summit press conference, International Monetary Fund managingdirector Dominique Strauss-Kahncalled for nations to approve a fiscal stimulus equal to 2 per centof gross domestic product. Such a move, he said, would result in a2 per cent increase in growth. When asked where fiscal stimuluswas need, he said, ‘everywhere, everywhere where it is possible’(Grice and Foley, 2008).But for Strauss-Kahn, such Keynesian <strong>no</strong>ises are easily uttered in settingslike the G20 crisis conference, at which the Bretton Woodsinstitutions must be seen to be acting forcefully (and after all, theIMF director’s personal sponsor, French premier Nicolas Sarkozy, hasrailed against ‘American capitalism’). In reality, though, the IMF wassimultaneously treating South Africa like a typical Third World debtordeserving of a full neoliberal work-out. For on 22 October, theIMF filed several lengthy reports which made the following six pointsconcerning South Africa:• the SA government should run a budget surplus;• the SA government should adopt privatisation for ‘infrastructureand social needs’ including electricity and transport;


196 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debate• the SA Reserve Bank should maintain existing inflation-targeting;• the SA Reserve Bank should raise interest rates;• the SA Treasury and Trade Ministry should remove protectionsagainst international eco<strong>no</strong>mic volatility, especially financial andtrade rules; and• the SA Labour Ministry should remove worker rights in labourmarkets, including ‘backward-looking wage indexation’ to protectagainst infl ation (Bond, 2008a).Instead of conceding the need for exchange controls and import controlson luxury goods so as to restore payments and trade account balances,the IMF (2008) had one solution, contrary to Strauss-Kahn’srhetoric: ‘Tighter fiscal policy to avoid exacerbating current accountpressures.’The point is that the global crisis may conjure up triumphant centreleftrhetorics of postneoliberalism in a European neo-Keynesian (andappropriately anti-American) context. But where the real power relationscan be revealed, in the devalorisation of overaccumulated capital,it is instead much more appropriate to prepare a defence againstausterity. The coming austerity was articulated by the most sophisticatedSouth African neoliberal, finance minister Trevor Manuel (whohas long been groomed for a top IMF job). He was asked by The FinancialTimes (2008) in October about the impact of the financial crisison South Africa, and told his constituents to tighten their belts:The huge bubble incommodities – petroleum,minerals, cash crops, land –disguised how much countrieslike South Africa stoodexposed.


ealistic postneoliberalism – a view from south africa 197We need to disabuse people of the <strong>no</strong>tion that we will have amighty powerful developmental state capable of planning and creatingall manner of employment. It may have been on the horizonin 1994 [when the governing African National Congress firstcame to office] but it could <strong>no</strong>t be delivered <strong>no</strong>w. The next periodis likely to see a lot more competitiveness in the global eco<strong>no</strong>my.As consumer demand falls off there will be a huge battle betweenfirms and countries to secure access to markets.Securing access to markets is indeed the core problem for nationalcapitalist elites and for the system as a whole. ‘Overaccumulation ofcapital’ at the global scale is the root problem of the recent crisis,coming on the heels of a period of 35 years of world capitalist stagnation,extreme financial volatility and internecine competition that hashad rui<strong>no</strong>us impacts. The huge bubble in commodities – petroleum,minerals, cash crops, land – disguised how much countries like SouthAfrica stood exposed, and indeed the early 2000s witnessed increasingoptimism that the late 1990s emerging markets currency crises could beovercome within the context of the system. Moreover, even before theresources boom, by 2001 the rate of profit for large South African capitalwas restored from an earlier downturn from the 1970s-90s, to ninthhighest amongst the world’s major national eco<strong>no</strong>mies (far ahead of theUS and China), according to one British government study (Citron andWalton 2002).The reality, though, was that high corporate profits were <strong>no</strong>t a harbingerof sustainable eco<strong>no</strong>mic development in South Africa, as a resultof persistent deep-rooted contradictions:• with respect to stability, the value of the rand in fact crashed (againsta basket of trading currencies) by more than a quarter in 1996, 1998,2001, 2006 and 2008, the worst record of any major eco<strong>no</strong>my, whichin turn reflects how vulnerable SA became to international financialmarkets thanks to steady exchange control liberalisation (26 separateloosenings of currency controls) starting in 1995;• SA witnessed GDP growth during the 2000s, but this does <strong>no</strong>ttake into account the depletion of <strong>no</strong>n-renewable resources – ifthis factor plus pollution were considered, SA would have a netnegative per person rate of national wealth accumulation (of at leastus$ 2 per year), according to even the World Bank (2006, 66);• SA’s eco<strong>no</strong>my has become much more oriented to profit-takingfrom financial markets than production of real products, in part becauseof extremely high real interest rates, for from March 1995(when the financial rand exchange control was relaxed), the after-


198 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateinflation interest rate rose to a record high for a decade’s experiencein SA eco<strong>no</strong>mic history, often reaching double digits (after a recent3.5 per cent spike during the mid-2000s, consumer and housingcredit markets are badly strained by serious arrears and defaults);• the two most successful major sectors from 1994-2004 were communications(12.2 per cent growth per year) and finance (7.6 percent) while labour-intensive sectors such as textiles, footwear andgold mining shrunk by 1-5 per cent per year, and overall, manufacturingas a percentage of GDP also declined;• the SA government admits that overall employment growth was-0.2 per cent per year from 1994-2004 – but -0.2 per cent is a vastunderestimate of the problem, given that the official definition ofemployment includes such work as ‘begging’ and ‘hunting wildanimals for food’ and ‘growing own food’;• the problem of excessive capital intensity in production – too manymachines per worker – will probably get worse, for the IndustrialDevelopment Corporation (a state agency) forecasts that the sectorwith the most investment in the period 2006-10 will be iron andsteel, with a massive 24 per cent rise in fixed investment per year,but sectoral employment expected to fall 1.3 per cent per year, inspite of – or indeed because of – all the new investment;• overall, the problem of ‘capital strike’ – large-scale firms’ failure toinvest – continues, as gross fixed capital formation hovered around15-17 per cent from 1994-2004, hardly e<strong>no</strong>ugh to cover wear-andtearon equipment; and• businesses did invest their SA profits, but <strong>no</strong>t mainly in SA: datingfrom the time of political and eco<strong>no</strong>mic liberalisation, most of thelargest Johannesburg Stock Exchange firms – Anglo American,DeBeers, Old Mutual, SA Breweries, Liberty Life, Gencor (<strong>no</strong>wthe core of BHP Billiton), Didata, Mondi and others – shiftedtheir funding flows and even their primary share listings to overseasstock markets;• the outflow of profits and dividends due these firms is one of twocrucial reasons SA’s ‘current account deficit’ has soared to amongstthe highest in the world (in mid-2008 exceeded only by New Zealand)and is hence a major danger in the event of currency instability,as was Thailand’s (around 5 per cent) in mid-1997;• the other cause of the current account deficit is the negative tradebalance, which can be blamed upon a vast inflow of imports aftertrade liberalisation, which export growth could <strong>no</strong>t keep up with;


ealistic postneoliberalism – a view from south africa 199Stated employment growth of-0.2 per cent per year is a vastunderestimate of the problem,given that the offi cial defi nitio<strong>no</strong>f employment includes suchwork as ‘begging’ and ‘huntingwild animals for food’ and‘growing own food’.• a<strong>no</strong>ther reason for capital strike is SA’s sustained overproductionproblem in existing (highly-mo<strong>no</strong>polised) industry, as manufacturingcapacity utilisation fell substantially from the 1970s to theearly 2000s;• corporate profits avoided reinvestment in plant, equipment andfactories, and instead sought returns from speculative real estateand the Johannesburg Stock Exchange: there was a 50 per centincrease in share prices during the first half of the 2000s, and theproperty boom which began in 1999 had by 2004 sent house pricesup by 200 per cent (in comparison to just 60 per cent in the USmarket prior to the burst bubble, according to the InternationalMonetary Fund).With this sort of neoliberal preparation, it is <strong>no</strong> surprise that in the secondweek of October 2008, South Africa’s stock market crashed 10 percent (on the worst day, shares worth us$ 35 billion went up in smoke) andthe currency declined by 9 per cent, while the second week witnessed afurther 10 per cent crash. The speculative real estate market had alreadybegun a decline that might yet reach those of other hard-hit propertysectors like the US, Denmark and Ireland, because South Africa’s early2000s housing price rise far outstripped even these casi<strong>no</strong> markets (200per cent from 1997-2004, compared to 60 per cent in the US).Even the apparent death of South Africa’s neoliberal project in September2008, personified by former president Thabo Mbeki, whose


200 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatepro-corporate managerialism was one reason for an unceremoniousremoval from power, is misleading. The ‘populist’ ruling party leaderJacob Zuma appears intent on <strong>no</strong>t only retaining Manuel as long aspossible but preparing a collision course with his primary internalsupport base, trade unionists and communists, in the run-up to theMarch <strong>2009</strong> general election. As Zuma put it to the American Chamberof Commerce in November 2008, ‘We are proud of the fiscaldiscipline, sound macroeco<strong>no</strong>mic management and general mannerin which the eco<strong>no</strong>my has been managed. That calls for continuity’(Chilwane 2008).What this means in South African and similar sites is that the 2000seco<strong>no</strong>mic expansion (in SA’s case around 5 per cent through mostof the decade until 2008) was untenable, as growth was based uponunsustainable eco<strong>no</strong>mic practices associated with a last-gasp neoliberalspeculative and credit-based consumption spree. Given the durablepower of neoliberal eco<strong>no</strong>mic managers, extreme austerity – <strong>no</strong>tpostneoliberalism – looms.Obama’s neoliberalsRegrettably, this appears the case in the site of greatest hope, or at minimumrelief – the US. Unfortunately, a<strong>no</strong>ther false solution to the worldeco<strong>no</strong>mic crisis arose in November 2008, with Obama’s election as USpresident. Although he an<strong>no</strong>unced a stimulus package aimed at creating2.5 million jobs through public works by January 2011, Obama’s teamof eco<strong>no</strong>mic policy managers is decidedly neoliberal and has the orientationand capacity to undermine postneoliberal state intervention.A central figure in the current crisis is the deregulatory yet pro-bailoutfinancial manager, Tim Geithner, chosen as Treasury secretary. Head ofthe Council of Eco<strong>no</strong>mic Advisors is neoliberal University of Chicagoprofessor Austan Goolsbee. Similarly, Lawrence Summers was <strong>no</strong>tonly the main force in Washington responsible for the most disastrousrecent financial deregulation, in 2000 as Bill Clinton’s Treasury secretary,he was also the central figure in the prior world financial crisis, in1997-99, when he pushed Asia to open its doors to foreign financiersin exchange for bailout loans. And the prior eco<strong>no</strong>mic crisis featuredPaul Volcker. Judging by their record and ideology, these three leadingeco<strong>no</strong>mic advisors will do yet more intense damage to the rest of theworld, and they will do so with far greater power – thanks to undeservedcredibility associated with Obama’s election – than did Bush’sfinancial managers.Head of the Council ofObama's Eco<strong>no</strong>mic Advisorsis neoliberal University ofChicago professor AustanGoolsbee.


ealistic postneoliberalism – a view from south africa 201New York Federal Reserve Bank president Geithner served underHenry Kissinger in his consultancy firm during the mid-1980s, joinedthe Reagan-Bush administration in 1988, and then worked for Summersand Robert Rubin in the Clinton Treasury Department duringthe 1990s. As New York Fed president, he was implicated in bothderegulation and the first round of ineffectual Wall Street bailouts in2008, in which he failed to foresee the devastating impact of the LehmanBrothers investment bank’s failure on world finance.Issuing from the comfort of University of Chicago Business School,Goolsbee’s (2007) advocacy of increased subprime mortgage lendingin the New York Times just a few weeks before the real estate crisisburst upon the world eco<strong>no</strong>my, in 2007, appeared entirely ideological:‘[S]omeone with a low income <strong>no</strong>w but who stands to earn muchmore in the future would, in a perfect market, be able to borrow froma bank to buy a house… the mortgage market has become more perfect,<strong>no</strong>t more irresponsible.’Summers, too, was incompetent in his consistent advocacy of financialderegulation, though he is best k<strong>no</strong>wn in US political circles forthe sexism controversy that cost him the presidency of Harvard Universityin 2006 (following huge confl icts with his leading African-American scholars). During the late 1990s he took advantage of Asia’seco<strong>no</strong>mic woes to force further dogmatic liberalisation along withbailouts of US creditors that ran into the hundreds of billions of dollars,starting with Mexico in 1995. A few years earlier Summers (1991)gained infamy as an advocate of African ge<strong>no</strong>cide and environmentalracism, thanks to a confidential World Bank memo he signed whenhe was the institution’s senior vice-president and chief eco<strong>no</strong>mist:I think the eco<strong>no</strong>mic logic behind dumping a load of toxic wastein the lowest-wage country is impeccable and we should face upto that… I’ve always thought that underpopulated countries inAfrica are vastly underpolluted, their air quality is vastly inefficientlylow…After all, Summers continued, inhabitants of low-income countriestypically die before the age at which they would begin suffering prostatecancer associated with toxic dumping. And in any event, usingmarginal productivity of labour as a measure, low-income Africansare <strong>no</strong>t worth very much anyhow. Nor are African’s aesthetic concernswith air pollution likely to be as substantive as they are for wealthyNortherners. Such arguments were said by Summers to be made inan ‘ironic’ way. Yet their internal logic was pursued with a vengeance


202 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateby the World Bank and IMF long after Summers moved over to theClinton Treasury Department, where in 1999 he insisted that JosephStiglitz be fired by Bank president James Wolfensohn for speaking outconsistently against the impeccable eco<strong>no</strong>mic logic of the WashingtonConsensus.One of Obama’s other leading advisors has done more damage to Africa,its eco<strong>no</strong>mies and its people than anyone in recent history. Volckeris an 82 year old banker. Even the International Monetary Fund’sofficial history (2001) can<strong>no</strong>t avoid using the famous phrase most associatedwith the Fed chair’s name:The origins of the debt crisis of the 1980s may be traced back toand through the lurching efforts of the world’s governments to copewith the eco<strong>no</strong>mic instabilities of the 1970s…[including the] monetarycontraction in the United States (the ‘Volcker Shock’) thatbrought a sharp rise in world interest rates and a sustained appreciatio<strong>no</strong>f the dollar.Volcker’s decision to raise rates so high to rid the US eco<strong>no</strong>my of inflation and strengthen the fast-falling dollar had special significancein Africa. The numbers involved were daunting for a typical Africancountry. According to University of California eco<strong>no</strong>mic geographerGillian Hart (2004), ‘Medium and long-term public debt [of lowincomecountries] shot up from us$ 75.1 billion in 1970 to us$ 634.4billion in 1983. It was the so-called Volcker Shock…that ushered inthe debt crisis, the neoliberal counterrevolution, and vastly changedroles of the World Bank and IMF in Latin America, Africa, and partsof Asia.’ A<strong>no</strong>ther leading political eco<strong>no</strong>mist, Elmar Altvater (thisvolume) of Berlin’s Free University, recalls how the world ‘slid intothe debt crisis of the 1980s after the US Federal Reserve tripled interestrates (the so-called “Volcker Shock”. . .) leading to what later hasbeen described as the “lost decade” for the developing world’.Meanwhile, the Bank’s sister institution, the International MonetaryFund, was described by Tanzanian president Julius Nyerere as ‘a neocolonialinstitution which exploits the poor to make them poorerand serves the rich to become richer’ (cited in Bond 1998). Volckerhad, ironically, played a central role in the destruction of the BrettonWoods system’s dollar-gold convertibility arrangement, effectively aus$ 80 billion default on holders of dollars abroad, when in 1971 heserved Richard Nixon as under-secretary of the Treasury (deputy financeminister). Eight years later, even though then-president JimmyCarter did <strong>no</strong>t k<strong>no</strong>w him, he was chosen to chair the Federal Re-


ealistic postneoliberalism – a view from south africa 203serve, which sets US (and by extension world) interest rates, and <strong>no</strong>wVolcker is back again at Obama’s side.Geithner, Summers, Volcker and similar capitalist eco<strong>no</strong>mists whisperedfor a resurgent US based on national self-interest, including arestored financial system again capable of colonising world markets.A renewed commitment to multilateral institutions would be crucialfor this gambit. Going into <strong>2009</strong>, these men and the institutions theyhave managed need Obama to relegitimate shock-doctrinaire neoliberalism– and in turn, they need Obama’s Africa advisors (like WitneySchneidman) to promote military imperialism in the form of theAfrica Command. Obama himself has explained that his ‘fundamentalobjective’ for the continent is ‘to accelerate Africa’s integrationinto the global eco<strong>no</strong>my’ – <strong>no</strong> matter the vast damage that has beendone in history and in recent years (Rodney 1972, Bond 2006). Insum, we can only expect more neoliberalism. What about the prospectsfrom below?A realistic postneoliberal projectIf, as argued above, neoliberalism may have a<strong>no</strong>ther breath of life,with mouth-to-mouth resuscitation applied from above by BarackObama or the International Monetary Fund, much stronger pressureis needed from below to resist. Some forms have been well tested insocial struggle, including three ‘pilot projects’ in genuine postneoliberalism:defending against financial degradation; restoring nationalpower without the distraction of global governance; and re-establishinganti-imperialism so as to take advantage of unprecedented UnitedStates weakness. I focus here on some dimensions.If, as argued above,neoliberalism may havea<strong>no</strong>ther breath of life, withmouth-to-mouth resuscitationapplied from above by BarackObama or the InternationalMonetary Fund, much strongerpressure is needed frombelow to resist.First, facing myriad forms of financial crisis, we might consider quiterecent examples of community and citizens’ groups generating impressivedefence against fi nancial degradation. Consider two micro examples- the 1990s housing ‘bonds boycotts’ in South Africa’s black townshipsand Mexico’s mid-1990s ‘El Barzon’ (the yoke) movement againstbanks – as well as a stronger form of IMF riot than is <strong>no</strong>rmal: the Argentinerevolt against malgovernance and international debt/bankingcontrol in 2001-02 that led to a debt default of us$ 140 billion.South Africa’s bond boycotts began in the wake of the 200,000 mortgagesgranted in townships during the late 1980s. The long 1989-93recession left 500,000 freshly unemployed workers and their familiesunable to pay for housing. This in turn helped generate a collectiverefusal to repay housing bonds until certain conditions were


204 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatemet. The tactic moved from the site of the Uitenhage Volkswagenauto strike in the Eastern Cape to the Johannesburg area in 1990, as aconsequence of two factors: shoddy housing construction (for whichthe homebuyers had <strong>no</strong> other means of recourse than boycotting thehousing bond) and the rise in interest rates from 12.5 per cent (-6 percent in real terms) in 1988 to 21 per cent (+7 per cent in real terms) inlate 1989, which in most cases doubled monthly bond repayments.As a result of the resistance, township housing foreclosures whichcould <strong>no</strong>t be consummated due to refusal of the defaulting borrowers(supported by the community) to vacate their houses, and the leadingfinancier’s us$ 700 million black housing bond exposure in September1992 was the reason that its holding company (Nedcor) lost 20per cent of its Johannesburg Stock Exchange share value (in excess ofus$ 150 million lost) in a single week, following a threat of a nationalbond boycott from the national civic organisation. Locally, if a bankdid bring in a sheriff to foreclose and evict defaulters, it was <strong>no</strong>t uncommonfor a street committee of activists to burn the house downbefore the new owners completed the purchase and moved in. Suchpower, in turn, allowed both the national and local civic associationsto negotiate concessions from the banks.Similarly, a much larger movement – probably 1 million formal membersat its peak – joined ‘El Barzon’ in 1995-96. Mexican presidentsCarlos Salina and Ernesto Zedillo maintained neoliberal eco<strong>no</strong>micpolicies which led to a crash in December 1994. By mid-1995, <strong>no</strong>tlong after Zedillo’s inauguration, 2 millionworkers had lost the ir jobsand much of Mexico’s middle class sank directly into poverty. Thecurrency fell by 65 per cent, the stock market crashed, and interestrates soared from 14 per cent to more than 100 per cent. As 200,000small businesses were declared bankrupt, a million Mexicans joined abond boycott of consumer, farmer and petty-bourgeois debtors whocollectively refused to ho<strong>no</strong>ur loans that had become unrepayable.Their slogan was ‘I don’t deny I owe – but I’ll pay what is just!’ Inmany cases, the El Barzon strategy and solidarity foiled foreclosureproceedings, and generated major concessions from the creditors.‘I don’t deny I owe– but I’ll pay what is just!’In Argentina, protests in 2001-02 by piqueteros against the government’syear-long freeze of bank accounts initially took the form ofthe cacerolazo (banging of pots and pans in the cities’ main squares)and then massive street demonstrations. During December 2001, oneof the four presidents who lost their job due to the intensity of demonstrations,Rodríguez Saá, defaulted on us$ 132 billion in foreigndebts. Although disputes remain about whether the subsequent gov-


ealistic postneoliberalism – a view from south africa 205ernment of Nestor Kirchner could have done more to press home theadvantage (Jubilee South’s Argentina chapter remains furious aboutpayment of illegitimate debt), in 2003, Kirchner at least showed Argentina’scapacity to operate in the world eco<strong>no</strong>my even after spurningWashington. According to a surprised Eco<strong>no</strong>mist (2003) magazine,‘After missing a $2.9 billion payment to the International MonetaryFund on September 9th, it distinguished itself with the single largest<strong>no</strong>n-payment of a loan in the Fund’s history. The next day, it clincheda deal that may be the speediest and kindest the IMF has ever agreedto.’ Private creditors were forced to take a 70 per cent ‘haircut’ onArgentine bonds.The same approach to unrepayable debt – national default – was advocatedby then-leading UN eco<strong>no</strong>mic adviser Jeffrey Sachs. He told headsof state at a July 2004 African Union meeting in Addis Ababa, ‘Africancountries should refuse to repay their foreign debts’ and insteaduse the funds to invest in health and education. (At the time, the IMFwas controversially prohibiting expenditure of health funds donated toAfrica, especially for HIV/AIDS mitigation, on grounds that civil servicepay would rise to above 7 per cent of GDP.)Also in 2004, a Cape Town meeting of Jubilee Africa members fromAngola, Cameroon, Cote d’Ivoire, the Democratic Republic of Congo,Kenya, Mozambique, South Africa, Swaziland, Zambia, Tanzaniaand Zimbabwe, and partners from Brazil, Argentina and the Philippinesworking on a comprehensive Illegitimate Debt Audit demanded thattheir national governments pursue this postneoliberal agenda:• full unconditional cancellation of Africa’s total debt;• reparations for damage caused by debt devastation;• immediate halt to the Highly Indebted Poor Country initiativeand Poverty Reducation Strategy Papers and the disguised structuraladjustment programme through the New Partnership for Africa’sDevelopment and any other agreements that do <strong>no</strong>t addressthe fundamental interests of the impoverished majority and thebuilding of a sustainable and sovereign Africa; and• a comprehensive audit to determine the full extent and real natureof Africa’s illegitimate debt, the total payments made to date andthe amount owed to Africa.Such national-scale challenges to global financial power are the only waysforward, given the adverse global-scale power relations. From a nationalpower base, several other financial sector reforms can be pursued: imposition


206 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateof exchange controls (such as were applied by Malaysia in 1998 and Venezuela in2003), bank nationalisation (as many Northern countries are doing by way ofbailouts), and fi scal stimulation (as national states are generally being encouragedto do at present, in order to avoid global depression).The contemporary form of this approach takes shape in the deglobalisationand decommodifi cation strategies for basic needs goods, as exemplifiedin South Africa by the national Treatment Action Campaign andJohannesburg Anti-Privatisation Forum which have won, respectively,antiretroviral medicines needed to fight AIDS and publicly-providedwater (Bond 2006). The drugs are <strong>no</strong>w made locally in Africa– in Johannesburg, Kampala, Harare, and so on – and on a generic <strong>no</strong>ta branded basis, and generally provided free of charge, a great advanceupon the us$ 15,000/patient/year cost of branded AIDS medicines adecade earlier (in South Africa, half a million people receive them).The water in Johannesburg is <strong>no</strong>w produced and distributed by publicagencies (Suez was sent back to Paris after its controversial 2001-06protest-ridden management of municipal water); and in April 2008 amajor constitutional lawsuit in the High Court resulted in a doublingof free water to 50 litres per person per day and the prohibition of prepaymentwater meters (Bond and Dugard 2008).Similarly, a deglobalised, decommodified alternative is needed tooft-feted micro-credit schemes financed by international financiersand foundations at the expense of local impoverished women whoare expected to pay exorbitant interest rates. For anyone believingthat micro-credit is a postneoliberal project, consider the extremistviewpoint of Grameen Bank’s Muhammad Yunus (1998, 214): ‘Ibelieve that “government,” as we k<strong>no</strong>w it today, should pull out ofmost things except for law enforcement and justice, national defenseand foreign policy, and let the private sector, a “Grameenised privatesector,” a social-consciousness-driven private sector, take over theirother functions’ (see Bond 2007c for a full critique).In contrast, the Venezuelan government of Hugo Chavez has begunproviding large grants to 3,500 ‘communal banks’ (Pearson 2008):Communal banks are social organisations that administer the financialand <strong>no</strong>n-financial resources of the communal councils, theorganising mechanism of communities. Through the communalbanks, organised communities can finance social projects, assistmembers in cases of emergency, and make social investments. Inthe <strong>2009</strong> budget, Chavez explained, us$ 1.6 billion has been assignedto the communal banks. Chavez <strong>no</strong>ted the irony that while


ealistic postneoliberalism – a view from south africa 207Without a leadership fi gureof Chavez’s capacity, thecrucial ingredient for Africais heightened pressurefrom below. This means thestrengthening, coordinationand increased militancy of civilsociety.large, small and medium sized banks are collapsing around theworld as a result of the financial crisis, Venezuela is ‘giving birthto thousands of banks that are banks of the people, the communalbanks, the banks for popular power…and [this] popular power isvital for the future of the revolution…so this…can’t fail.’… Chavezis also encouraging the communal councils and the national governmentbodies to create networks of social distribution of theproducts that are made in the socialist companies and collectives.The idea of such a network would be to counteract the capitalistnetworks of production, which have been generating speculationin the price of products.Without a leadership figure of Chavez’s capacity, the crucial ingredientfor Africa is heightened pressure from below. This means thestrengthening, coordination and increased militancy of two kinds ofcivil society: those forces devoted to the debt relief cause, which haveoften come from what might be termed an excessively polite, civilisedsociety based in internationally-linked NGOs which rarely ifever used ‘tree-shaking’ in order to do ‘jam-making’; and those forceswhich react via short-term ‘IMF riots’ against the system, in a mannerbest understood as uncivilised society. The IMF riots that shook Africancountries during the 1980s and 1990s often, unfortunately, roseup in fury and even shook loose some governments’ hold on power.When these, however, contributed to the fall of Kenneth Kaunda inZambia (one of many examples), the man who replaced him as presidentin 1991, former trade unionist Frederick Chiluba, imposed evenmore decisive IMF policies. Most anti-IMF protest simply could <strong>no</strong>tbe sustained (Seddon 2002).In contrast, the former organisations are increasingly networked, especiallyin the wake of 2005 activities associated with the Global Callto Action Against Poverty (GCAP), which generated (failed) strategiesto support the Millennium Developmental Goals partly throughwhite-headband consciousness-raising, through appealing to nationalAfrican elites and through joining a naïve appeal to the G8 Gleneaglesmeeting (Bond 2006). Since then, networks have tightened andbecome more substantive through two Nairobi events: the January2007 World Social Forum and August 2008 launch of Jubilee South’sAfrica network. Moreover, Jubilee Africa also added ecological debtto its agenda, insisting that the free environmental space that Africanrainforests provide the North for acting as a carbon sink be compensatedin future financial and aid negotiations. Such calculations, asdone for example by Joan Martinez-Alier (2002), would show that theNorth owes the South, <strong>no</strong>t the other way around.


208 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateRegrettably, a necessary prerequisite to make all the above strategiesmore feasible is the re-delegitimisation of US power. Most obviously, aworld addicted to the US dollar as the reserve currency will be at themercy of the US state, as one example. The insane mutually-assureddestructive system of US Treasury Bill purchases by East Asian investors– so as to ensure a market for their consumer goods – began runninginto the contradiction of huge declines in Chinese, Japanese, Taiwaneseand Korean dollar reserves wealth, as the US currency fell substantiallyin recent years. A multi-currency exchange system is inevitable,and to the extent it is conjoined with national exchange controlsand hence less extreme volatility in financial trading, will be advantageousfor eco<strong>no</strong>mic development, compared to the current currencyanarchy. Ideally something like Keynes’ International Currency Union– which would penalise balance of trade surpluses – would be ideal, butgiven the neoliberal and neoconservative forces in multilateral institutions,is probably out of the question in our lifetimes.The big problem remains the US state, because to counteract US eco<strong>no</strong>micand cultural decline, two strategies are <strong>no</strong>w in play: politicalrevitalisation via Barack Obama’s carefully-crafted image as a <strong>no</strong>nimperialistpolitician with roots in African-American, Kenyan andeven Indonesian traditions; and the activism anticipated through hissecretary of state, Hillary Clinton, a strong supporter of the US waragainst Iraq. Obama may <strong>no</strong>t run as extreme a militarist regime asBush/Cheney did or as McCain/Palin would have done. Yet as JeremyScahill points out, there is an awful precedent from Washington’simperialist habits during Bill Clinton’s administration:The prospect of Obama’s foreign policy being, at least in part,an extension of the Clinton Doctrine is real. Even more disturbing,several of the individuals at the center of Obama’s transitionand emerging foreign policy teams were top players in creatingand implementing foreign policies that would pave the way forprojects eventually carried out under the Bush/Cheney administration.With their assistance, Obama has already charted out severalhawkish stances. Among them:• his plan to escalate the war in Afghanistan;• an Iraq plan that could turn into a downsized and rebranded occupationthat keeps US forces in Iraq for the foreseeable future;• his labelling of Iran’s Revolutionary Guard as a ‘terrorist organisation’;• his pledge to use unilateral force inside of Pakistan to defendUS interests;


ealistic postneoliberalism – a view from south africa 209• his position, presented before the American Israel Public AffairsCommittee that Jerusalem ‘must remain undivided’ - aremark that infuriated Palestinian officials and which he laterattempted to reframe;• his plan to continue the War on Drugs, a backdoor US counterinsurgencycampaign in Central and Latin America;• his refusal to ‘rule out’ using Blackwater and other armed privateforces in US war zones, despite previously introducinglegislation to regulate these companies and bring them underUS law (Scahill 2008).In addition to Hillary Clinton and the reappointment of Bush’s defensesecretary Robert Gates, Scahill (2008) warns of the following imperialistinfluences: vice president Joe Biden, chief of staff Rahm Emanuel,former secretaries of state Madeleine Albright and Warren Christopher,former defense secretary William Perry, former UN ambassadorRichard Holbrooke, and other key Clinton-era figures (Dennis Ross,Martin Indyk, Anthony Lake, Lee Hamilton, Susan Rice, John Brennan,Jami Miscik, John Kerry, Bill Richardson, Ivo H. Daalder, SarahSewall, Michele Flour<strong>no</strong>y, Wendy Sherman, Tom Donilon, Denis Mc-Do<strong>no</strong>ugh and Mark Lippert). As Scahill concludes,‘I don’t want to just end thewar,’ Obama said early thisyear. ‘I want to end the mindsetthat got us into war.’ That isgoing to be very diffi cult ifObama employs a foreignpolicy team that was central tocreating that mindset, beforeand during the presidency ofGeorge W. Bush.Barack Obama campaigned on a pledge to bring change to Washington.‘I don’t want to just end the war,’ he said early this year.‘I want to end the mindset that got us into war.’ That is going tobe very difficult if Obama employs a foreign policy team that wascentral to creating that mindset, before and during the presidencyof George W. Bush.What is most crucial, then, for a realistic postneoliberal project, is ongoingdelegitimisation of the US in its political and military modes.One danger zone is Africa, where the Bush/Cheney/Gates geopoliticaland military machinery ground to a halt in the form of the AfricaCommand. No state aside from Liberia would entertain the idea ofhosting the headquarters (which remained in Stuttgard), <strong>no</strong>twithstandingan endorsement of Africom from even Obama’s main Africaadvisor, Witney Schneidman.More importantly, even if Obama restores a degree of US credibilityat the level of international politics, US military decline will continueto be hastened by failed Pentagon strategies against urban Islamistguerilla movements in Baghdad, rural Islamist fighters in Afghanistanand Pakistan, and the belligerent nuclear-toting state of NorthKorea. None of these forces represent social progress, of course, but


210 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debatethey probably are responsible for such despondency in Washingtonthat other targets of US imperial hostility, such as the governmentsof Cuba, Venezuela, Bolivia and Ecuador, remain safe from blatantoverthrow in the near term.In turn, those four Latin American countries have the best opportunityin the world, today, to build postneoliberal eco<strong>no</strong>mic, socialand environmental projects. The latter eco-socialist project is vitallyimportant, because to counter the objectionable idea of ‘petro-socialism’,as practiced in Venezuela, there are some inspiring examplesin Cuba’s post-carbon in<strong>no</strong>vations, in Bolivia’s indige<strong>no</strong>us people’spower and in Ecuador’s official commitment – <strong>no</strong> matter how itwavers in practice – to a ‘keep the oil in the soil’ policy in the YasuniNational Park. The social and eco<strong>no</strong>mic advances in postneoliberalVenezuela are important, as are Keynesian strategies being implementedin China (the world’s most expansive public works projects –with ecological disasters ) and Argentina, as key examples.From South Africa, our window on this new world shows quite cleardangers of both Pretoria government officials and NGOs (for example,Civicus, headquartered in Johannesburg) being coopted into renewedneoliberal (and even neoconservative) US imperial projects,especially if Obama draws upon his African roots for socio-politicalpower. Antidotes remain, of course, and are expressed through antiimperialistsentiments emerging in both the centre-left political actors(the trade unions and SA Communist Party) and the independentleft social movements (especially those acting in solidarity with Zimbabweans,Swazis, Palestinians and Burmese).But the most powerful South African example is <strong>no</strong>t the negation ofneoliberalism and imperialism, but rather the grassroots activist initiatives– such as acquiring generic AIDS medicines and free publicwater supplies – against the forces of micro-commodification andmacro-neoliberalism. These are indeed the most useful signals thata<strong>no</strong>ther world – realistically postneoliberal – is <strong>no</strong>t only possible, butis being constructed even <strong>no</strong>w.


ealistic postneoliberalism – a view from south africa 211ReferencesAltvater, E. (2008), ‘Postneoliberalism orPostcapitalism? The Failure of Neoliberalism in theFinancial Market Crisis’, Development Dialogue (thisvolume).Bond, P. (1998), Uneven Zimbabwe, Trenton: AfricaWorld Press.Bond, P. (2006), Looting Africa, London: Zed Books.Bond, P. (2007a), ‘Perils of elite pacting’,Critical Currents <strong>no</strong>. 1, Uppsala: Dag HammarskjöldFoundation.Bond, P. (2007b), ‘Linking below, across and against’,Development Dialogue, <strong>no</strong>. 49, on Global CivilSociety, Uppsala: Dag Hammarskjöld Foundation.Bond, P. (2007c), ‘Microcredit evangelism, healthand social policy’, International Journal of HealthServices, vol. 37, <strong>no</strong>. 2, pp. 229-249.Bond, P. (2008a), ‘Strauss-Kahn strikes again’,Counterpunch, 29 October.Bond, P. and Dugard, J. (2008), ‘The case ofJohannesburg Water’, Law, Democracy andDevelopment, vol. 12, <strong>no</strong>. 1.Chilwane, L. (2008), ‘Eco<strong>no</strong>mic policies to remain,Zuma tells US business’, Business Day, 27 November.Citron, L. and Walton, R. (2002), ‘Internationalcomparisons of company profi tability’, Bank ofEngland Monetary and Financial Statistics Division,London, http://www.statistics.gov.uk/articles/eco<strong>no</strong>mic_trends/ET587_Walton.pdf (accessed 1December 2008).The Eco<strong>no</strong>mist (2003), ‘Nestor Kirchner’s nimblecookery’, 13 September.Goolsbee, A. (2007), ‘“Irresponsible” mortgageshave opened doors to many of the excluded’, NewYork Times, 29 March.Grice, A. and Foley, S. (2008), ‘Brown claims worldbacking for plan to tax less, spend more,’ TheGuardian, 17 November.International Monetary Fund (2001), SilentRevolution: The International Monetary Fund 1979-1989, www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/history/2001/index.htmInternational Monetary Fund (2008), ‘IMF ExecutiveBoard Concludes Article IV Consultation withSouth Africa: Public Information Notice (PIN) No.08/137,’ Washington, 22 October.Krugman, P. (2008), ‘The Lame Duck Eco<strong>no</strong>my’, NewYork Times, 21 November.Lapper, R. and Burgis, T. (2008), ‘S Africans urged tobeware left turn’, Financial Times, 27 October.Lough, R. (2008), ‘IMF agrees Seychelles $26mrescue package’, Mail & Guardian, 15 November.Martinez-Alier, J. (2002), ‘External debt andecological debt’, ftp://ftp.cordis.europa.eu/pub/improving/docs/g_ser_glob_martinezalier.pdf(accessed December 2008).Parker, G., Ward, A. and Hall, B. (2008), ‘Dreamsof taming Anglo-Saxon capitalism fade’, FinancialTimes, 15 November.Pearson, T. (2008), ‘Communal banks of Venezuelareceive big boost’, Venezuelanalysis.com, 15November.Rodney, W. (1972), How Europe UnderdevelopedAfrica, Dar es Salaam: Tanzania Publishing Houseand London: Bogle L’Ouverture Publications.Scahill, J. (2008), ‘This is change? 20 hawks,Clintonites and neocons to watch for in Obama’sWhite House’, AlterNet http://www.alternet.org/story/107666/, (accessed 20 November 2008).Seddon, D. (2002), ‘Popular protest and classstruggle in Africa’, in Zeilig, L. (ed.) Class Struggleand Resistance in Africa, Bristol: New Clarion Press.Summers, L. (1991), ‘The memo’, World Bank Offi ceof the Chief Eco<strong>no</strong>mist, http://www.whirledbank.org/ourwords/summers.html (accessed 1 December2008).World Bank (2006), Where is the Wealth ofNations?, Washington, DC.Yunus, M. (1998), Banker to the Poor, Dhaka:University of Bangladesh Press.


212 development dialogue <strong>january</strong> <strong>2009</strong> | postneoliberalism – a beginning debateNotes on the contributorsGreg Albo, Department of Political Science,York University, Director of the Centrefor Social Justice and active in Labour forPalestine. albo@yorku.caElmar Altvater, retired Professor at the FreeUniversity of Berlin; member of the scientificcouncil of Attac, Germany; Vice-president ofthe International Lelio Basso Foundation forthe Rights of People.altvater@zedat.fu-berlin.deAlec Bamford, retired development worker,Bangkok, chanida.alec@gmail.comChanida Chanyapate Bamford, Coordinator,Focus on the Global South, Bangkok.c.bamford@focusweb.orgKurt Bayer, Board Director of EuropeanBank for Reconstruction and Development,London; previously Austrian Ministry ofFinance and World Bank Board.Patrick Bond, Director, University ofKwaZulu-Natal Centre for Civil Society,http://www.ukzn.ac.za (pbond@mail.ngo.za).Ulrich Brand, University of Vienna,active in BUKO (BundeskoordinationInternationalismus) and member of thescientific advisory council of Attac Germany,ulrich.brand@univie.ac.atMichael Brie, Rosa Luxemburg FoundationBerlin, member of the scientific advisorycouncil of Attac Germany. brie@rosalux.deAna Esther Ceceña, National Auto<strong>no</strong>mousUniversity of Mexico; Director of theObservatorio Lati<strong>no</strong>america<strong>no</strong> de Geopolíticaand active in the Americas DemilitarisationCampaign.Alex Demirovic, Technical University Berlin,member of the scientific advisory councilof Attac Germany, member of the editorialboard of Prokla.demirovic@em.uni-frankfurt.deVerónica Gago and Diego Sztulwark,Colectivo Situaciones (Argentina). www.situaciones.org / www.tintalimonediciones.com.arNgai-Ling Sum, Senior Lecturer in theDepartment of Politics and InternationalRelations in Lancaster University.n.sum@lancaster.ac.ukEmir Sader, Federal University of Rio deJaneiro, General Secretary of CLACSO(Consejo Lati<strong>no</strong>america<strong>no</strong> de CienciasSociales). emirsader@uol.com.brNicola Sekler, University of Vienna,active in BUKO (BundeskoordinationInternationalismus).nicola.sekler@univie.ac.atChrista Wichterich, Bonn, active in WIDE(Women in Development Europe) andmember of the scientific advisory council ofAttac Germany.


Image creditsDavid Ritter p.5, Wally Gobetz p.14,Ben Northern p.16, Nicholas Theinp.18, Claudia A. De La Garza p.25,Grant Neufeld p.26, Lorena p.30, LarsSundström p.34, Claudia Meyer p.36,Bob Smith p.38, Steve Woods p.40,72, 98 & 121, Jan Flaska p.43, MarkusBiehal p.44, Fotocromo p.47, PauloOliveira Santos p.48, G & A Scholiersp.50 Sanja Gjenero p.53 & 55, JessicaBrowne p.58, Sebastian Da<strong>no</strong>n p.63,Diego Herrera p.64, Tracy Lee Carrollp.67, Sergio Pili p.70, Flávio Takemotop.74, Gaston Thauvin p.77, SvilenMushkatov p.78, John Siebert p.82,Robert Linder p.84, Guilherme Silvap.91, Sufi Nawaz p.93, Marcelo Mourap.95, Thomas Picard p.96, Asif Akbarp.104, jaylopez p.107, Samuel Rosap.109, Tracey Perry p.111, Ove Tøpferp.112, Jack Horst p.115, Aschwin Preinp.122, Craig Jewell p.125,Ruben Joye p.126, Nick Benjaminszp.128, Rodolfo Clix p.132, VasantDave p.134, Mark Schweizer p.137,Wasan Markjang p.139, SteveKnight p.142, John Grech p.144,Gavin Mills p.146, Jon Ng p.149,Michal Zacharzewski p.150, BartoszWacawski p.153, Andrew Turnerp.156, Mike Hardisty p.160, TreyRatcliff p.161, Gi<strong>no</strong> Zahnd p.164,David Thiel p.166, M Nota p.170,Vjeran Lisjak p.172, Mike Johnsonp.174, Paula Rupolo p.179, HernanHerrero p.180, Zurimar Campos –Copyright-Agencia Bolivariana deNoticias p.183, Fernando Weberichp.184, Jessica Shan<strong>no</strong>n p.187, Diago A.Mari<strong>no</strong> p.189, Aldon Scott Mc Leodp.192, Lynne Lancaster p.196, ValeriaObregon p.199, Angela Radulescup.200, Davide Guglielmo p.203, JanKratěna p.204


In the last 30 years, neoliberal policieshave been implemented in almost everysociety on the globe, resulting in fairlyspecific ‘neoliberal’ configurations.This volume has been compiled in timefor the World Social Forum in January<strong>2009</strong> in Belém in order to initiate a newdebate. It offers various responses to thenegative impacts of neoliberalism andits growing inability to deal with theupcoming contradictions and crises. Thecontributors are mainly scholar-activistsfrom different parts of the world, whopresent perspectives on social, politicaland/or eco<strong>no</strong>mic transformations. Theydeal with shifting terrains of socialstruggles and compromises, takingplace on different scales, in variouscontexts and by different actors. Allpostneoliberal approaches have incommon that they constitute a rupturewith specific aspects of ‘neoliberalism’.The contributors explore different aspectsof a possible postneoliberalism, focusingon continuities and discontinuities, whichvary in depth, complexity and scope,and relate to everyday practices as well ascomprehensive concepts.development dialogueis addressed to individualsand organisations in boththe South and the North,including policy makers,international institutions,members of civil society,the media and the researchcommunity.development dialogueis intended to providea free forum for criticaldiscussion of internationaldevelopment priorities forthe 21st century.development dialogueis published by theDag HammarskjöldFoundation. Copies maybe downloaded orobtained from theDag Hammarskjöld Centre,Övre Slottsgatan 2,se-753 10 Uppsala, Sweden,fax: +46-18-12 20 72,email: secretariat@dhf.uu.sewebsite: www.dhf.uu.se

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!