12.07.2015 Views

Water-Quality Trading: Can We Get the Price of Pollution Right?

Water-Quality Trading: Can We Get the Price of Pollution Right?

Water-Quality Trading: Can We Get the Price of Pollution Right?

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Water</strong>-<strong>Quality</strong> <strong>Trading</strong>:<strong>Can</strong> <strong>We</strong> <strong>Get</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Price</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Pollution</strong> <strong>Right</strong>? 1Yoshifumi KonishiFaculty <strong>of</strong> Liberal ArtsSophia UniversityJay S. CogginsDepartment <strong>of</strong> Applied EconomicsUniversity <strong>of</strong> MinnesotaBin WangDepartment <strong>of</strong> Public HealthPennsylvania State UniversityDraft: September 24, 2011AbstractA substantial challenge has loomed in designing water-quality trading (WQT) mechanisms:getting <strong>the</strong> prices right. By this we mean providing participants with price signals that accountproperly for spatially explicit damage relationships in a watershed. This paper extends recent workby Hung and Shaw (2005) and Farrow et al. (2005) by incorporating two important features that arecharacteristic <strong>of</strong> many watersheds: (i) branching rivers; and (ii) nonlinear pollution damages. Evenunder first-best conditions, <strong>the</strong> mechanism <strong>of</strong> Hung and Shaw fails to achieve <strong>the</strong> social optimumwhen <strong>the</strong>re are critical zones in a branching river. It is robust to nonlinear damages. The mechanism<strong>of</strong> Farrow et al. fails when damages are nonlinear, but is robust to branching. Under <strong>the</strong> second-bestcondition in which <strong>the</strong> initial distribution <strong>of</strong> permits is not optimal, nei<strong>the</strong>r mechanism dominates.The former precludes efficient trades across branches while <strong>the</strong> latter encourages inefficient trades.<strong>We</strong> also find, however, that <strong>the</strong> efficiency loss due to not getting <strong>the</strong> total supply <strong>of</strong> permits rightis substantially larger than that from not getting prices right.Keywords: <strong>Water</strong>-quality trading; trading-ratio system;1 <strong>We</strong> gratefully acknowledge financial support from a U.S. Environmental Protection Agency 2005 Targeted <strong>Water</strong>shedGrant and a Japan Society for <strong>the</strong> Promotion <strong>of</strong> Science Grant-in-Aid for Young Scientists.


1 IntroductionThe idea <strong>of</strong> using water-quality trading (WQT) to aid in protecting water quality is appealing. TheU.S. experience with its SO 2 allowance market proved that markets for pollution can work for air.Should <strong>the</strong>y not work for water pollution too? The U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA)seems to think <strong>the</strong>y can. It actively encourages states to establish rules for water-quality trading(WQT). 2 Currently, <strong>the</strong>re are a total <strong>of</strong> 54 water-quality trading programs in <strong>the</strong> United States,with eleven states having a state-wide trading policy in place or in development and three moreadopting watershed-specific state trading programs (EPA, 2011). The results from <strong>the</strong>se programshave, for <strong>the</strong> most part, been disappointing. Several barriers to trading have emerged (see, forexample, EPA, 2008; King and Kuch, 2003; Morgan and Wolverton, 2005; Woodward and Kaiser,2003).One such barrier is <strong>the</strong> difficulty <strong>of</strong> getting <strong>the</strong> prices <strong>of</strong> pollution right for WQT (Farrow etal., 2005; Hung and Shaw, 2005). By this we mean, following Muller and Mendelsohn (2009) thateach source faces a set <strong>of</strong> permit prices that reflect correctly <strong>the</strong> marginal damages caused over <strong>the</strong>landscape by its own emissions and those <strong>of</strong> its trading partners. The spatial relationship between<strong>the</strong> location <strong>of</strong> air emissions and <strong>the</strong> location <strong>of</strong> resulting damages is well known (Mauzerall et al.,2005). Spatial dependence is likely even more prominent for water pollution, where <strong>the</strong> attenuationand transport characteristics <strong>of</strong> numerous water pollutants are <strong>of</strong>ten critically dependent upon localhydrogeographic conditions at and downstream from each source (Todd and Mays, 2005; Schnoor,1996).Thirty years ago or so a lively literature arose in which various permit-trading schemes wereproposed. Montgomery’s (1972) ground-breaking ambient pollution system (APS) establishes aseparate permit market for every receptor point. This system is impractical, as firms would haveto know <strong>the</strong> impacts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir emissions on all relevant receptors and participate in a number <strong>of</strong>downstream markets. Ano<strong>the</strong>r early contribution is by Atkinson and Tietenberg (1982), who considereda system <strong>of</strong> pollution <strong>of</strong>fsets (POS) in which each new or expanding source is required tobuy <strong>of</strong>fsets from existing sources if <strong>the</strong>ir emissions violate an ambient environmental standard atany receptor point. The emissions must be traded at <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> two sources’ transfer coefficients.A version <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> POS has been used in water-quality trading, but has <strong>of</strong>ten resulted insizable transaction costs, because each bilateral trade must undergo intensive scientific evaluationand ad hoc negotiations with potential trading partners. 3The papers by Montgomery and by Atkingson and Tietenberg belong to a large literature inwhich a host <strong>of</strong> competing arrangements for trading systems were proposed. Most were concerned,ei<strong>the</strong>r explicitly or implicitly, with trading for air quality.A more recent literature, aimed specifically at water trading, focuses on designing tradablepermitsystems that address characteristics specific to water. Our focus is upon two <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> recent2 The Agency’s “<strong>Water</strong>-<strong>Quality</strong> <strong>Trading</strong> Policy” (EPA 2003) and “<strong>Water</strong>-<strong>Quality</strong> <strong>Trading</strong> Assessment Handbook”(EPA 2004) are meant to help guide state and local environmental policy. Improving water quality in a cost-effectivemanner has become a top EPA priority, in part due to a series <strong>of</strong> litigations concerning Section 303(d) <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Clean<strong>Water</strong> Act (CWA) since <strong>the</strong> 1980’s. The CWA requires all states, territories, and authorized tribes to develop lists<strong>of</strong> “impaired waters” every two years and to develop <strong>the</strong> total maximum daily load (TMDL) for every impairedwaterbody/pollutant. By <strong>the</strong> early 2000’s, EPA was placed under court order, agreeing in a consent decree to enforcea TMDL in 27 litigated cases. A waterbody is designated as “impaired” for a pollutant when it violates ambientwater-quality standards for that pollutant. As <strong>of</strong> September 2010, 39,988 waters were listed as “impaired.” A TMDLis <strong>the</strong> maximum amount <strong>of</strong> a pollutant that a waterbody can receive and still meet water-quality standards. It alsoallocates that load among <strong>the</strong> various sources <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> controlled pollutant.3 In this connection, <strong>the</strong> following comment on Oregon’s <strong>the</strong>rmal-trading initiative makes <strong>the</strong> point: “[T]he tradetook considerable resources on <strong>the</strong> part <strong>of</strong> both CWS and DEQ to develop. The effort would have been nei<strong>the</strong>rpractical nor worthwhile for a source much smaller than CWS to undertake” (Oregon DEQ, 2007).1


contributions, both <strong>of</strong> which restrict attention to point-source problems. Hung and Shaw’s (2005)trading-ratio system (TRS) takes into account an important feature <strong>of</strong> rivers: water flows unidirectionallyfrom upstream to downstream. The TRS transforms ambient environmental standardsinto ambient zonal discharge constraints according to physical transfer coefficients. Firms <strong>the</strong>n participatein a single watershed-wide market in which <strong>the</strong>y can trade with each o<strong>the</strong>r (with certainrestrictions) at <strong>the</strong> predetermined trading ratios subject to <strong>the</strong> zonal discharge constraints. Anessential feature <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> TRS is that <strong>the</strong> trading ratios are based on physical transfer coefficientsra<strong>the</strong>r than marginal damages, which can be more difficult to estimate. Though it <strong>of</strong>fers severaladvantages over APS or POS, <strong>the</strong> TRS has an important drawback. The unidirectional nature <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> transfer characteristics means that <strong>the</strong> TRS might not work as advertised for branching riversystems.Farrow et al. (2005) proposed an alternative trading system, which was later applied successfullyin <strong>the</strong> study <strong>of</strong> air pollution markets by Muller and Mendelsohn (2009). Like <strong>the</strong> TRS, Farrowet al.’s system allows firms to trade freely in a single watershed-wide market at predeterminedexchange rates, but <strong>the</strong> rates are based on <strong>the</strong> ratios <strong>of</strong> marginal damages (hence, we refer to it asa damage-denominated trading ratio system or DTRS). Because <strong>the</strong> DTRS does not rely on <strong>the</strong>unidirectional nature <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> transfer characteristics, it is robust to branching. Its disadvantage,however, is that it may not be robust to damages that are nonlinear in pollution levels. Nonlineardamages may result from ei<strong>the</strong>r nonlinear pollution-transport processes (Todd and Mays, 2005) ora nonlinear biological response <strong>of</strong> aquatic species to water pollution (Anderson et al., 2002; VanKirk and Hill, 2007) or both, even if economic agents’ marginal (dis)utility from water pollution isapproximately constant. 4This paper extends <strong>the</strong> work <strong>of</strong> Hung and Shaw (2005) and Farrow et al. (2005) by incorporatinginto a single model <strong>the</strong> two important features noted above: (i) branching rivers and (ii) nonlineardamages. <strong>We</strong> investigate <strong>the</strong> efficiency and cost-effectiveness properties <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> two systems in aframework similar in nature to that <strong>of</strong> Muller and Mendelsohn (2009). In Section 2, we start bydefining a social planner’s efficient decision program in water-quality management for a genericwatershed. Our planner minimizes <strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> abatement costs and pollution damages by choosinga vector <strong>of</strong> emissions from stationary point sources distributed across space in a watershed drainedby a branching river. The model generalizes Farrow et al. (2005) and Muller and Mendelsohn (2009)in a non-trivial manner by accounting for nonlinear damages. <strong>We</strong> show that under some regularityconditions, <strong>the</strong>re exists a cost-effectiveness program that implements <strong>the</strong> efficient outcome. Theresult thus allows us to discuss <strong>the</strong> TRS and DTRS on <strong>the</strong> same efficiency grounds.Sections 3 and 4 consider in turn <strong>the</strong> problems with <strong>the</strong> TRS and <strong>the</strong> DTRS. First, in Section 3,we show that <strong>the</strong> TRS fails to achieve a cost-effective optimum and, hence, <strong>the</strong> social optimum,when a critical zone (that is, a hot spot at which <strong>the</strong> pollution arriving from upstream excedes<strong>the</strong> zone’s concentration constraint) exists at a confluence <strong>of</strong> a branching river. In this case <strong>the</strong>discharge constraint in <strong>the</strong> critical zone must be set to zero and <strong>the</strong> constraint upstream <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>critical zone must be tightened. At a confluence, though, <strong>the</strong> required adjustment to <strong>the</strong> upstreamdischarge constraints becomes indeterminate. Thus, Hung and Shaw’s main result, that <strong>the</strong> TRSequilibrium achieves <strong>the</strong> cost-effective outcome, is not robust to branching.Second, in Section 4, we show that Farrow et al.’s DTRS is robust to branching, but failsto achieve <strong>the</strong> cost-effective optimum (hence, <strong>the</strong> social optimum) in <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> nonlineardamages. Under <strong>the</strong> DTRS, <strong>the</strong> trading ratios across space must be fixed prior to trading, whichcan give false incentives for trading participants at <strong>the</strong> margin. Ma<strong>the</strong>matically, this result is due4 It appears that <strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> nonlinear damages have not yet been given <strong>the</strong> attention <strong>the</strong>y deserve in <strong>the</strong> context<strong>of</strong> water trading, though <strong>the</strong>ir existence and importance have long been well recognized in <strong>the</strong> economics literature(Helfand and House, 1995; Larson et al., 1996; Segerson, 1988).2


to <strong>the</strong> multiplicity <strong>of</strong> emissions vectors that can satisfy <strong>the</strong> necessary conditions for <strong>the</strong> socialoptimum, which occurs precisely because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> nonlinearity <strong>of</strong> pollution damages.The zest <strong>of</strong> our paper lies in Section 5. <strong>We</strong> show that <strong>the</strong> TRS fails precisely where <strong>the</strong> DTRSsucceeds, and vice versa. This suggests that <strong>the</strong> relative performance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> two systems maydepend on <strong>the</strong> distribution <strong>of</strong> sources in a watershed featuring both branching rivers and nonlineardamages. <strong>We</strong> investigate this question by constructing a small numerical model and perturbing <strong>the</strong>geographic distribution <strong>of</strong> pollution sources in a watershed. Our simulation model is an illustrativeadaptation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> National <strong>Water</strong> <strong>Pollution</strong> Control Assessment (NWPCA) model developed forEPA. That model was used in Farrow et al. (2005) as well as in o<strong>the</strong>r regulatory applications. Themodel is well grounded in hydrology and so is suitable for estimation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> water-quality impacts<strong>of</strong> pollution in a complex watershed.Using our parameterized model, we consider a second-best scenario in which <strong>the</strong> total number<strong>of</strong> permits available at <strong>the</strong> initial allocation is optimal, but <strong>the</strong>ir distribution among sources is not.This assumption helps us disentangle <strong>the</strong> sources <strong>of</strong> inefficiency if ei<strong>the</strong>r TRS or DTRS fails toachieve <strong>the</strong> social optimum. Because <strong>the</strong> total amount <strong>of</strong> permits is optimal, any inefficiency mustbe attributed to problems with <strong>the</strong> trading ratios. That is, sources are faced with incorrect pricesignals. Our simulation results demonstrate that nei<strong>the</strong>r system dominates; each stumbles in itsown way. On one hand, <strong>the</strong> TRS can result in welfare loss because <strong>the</strong> trading ratios based ontransfer characteristics may preclude some efficient trades across branches. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand,<strong>the</strong> DTRS can result in welfare loss because <strong>the</strong> fixed trading ratios based on marginal damagesat some emissions vectors may, due to incorrect marginal incentives, encourage inefficient trades.Under <strong>the</strong> DTRS, sources may ei<strong>the</strong>r over-abate or under-abate relative to <strong>the</strong> optimum. In thissense, our results suggest <strong>the</strong> impossibility <strong>of</strong> getting <strong>the</strong> spatially explicit prices right for WQT.Alas, we do not <strong>of</strong>fer a magic bullet to solve <strong>the</strong>se problems.More encouraging, though, is <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> deadweight losses associated with ei<strong>the</strong>r systemare relatively modest so long as <strong>the</strong> total number <strong>of</strong> permits is optimal. Put ano<strong>the</strong>r way, <strong>the</strong>efficiency loss from failing to issue <strong>the</strong> correct number <strong>of</strong> permits is much greater than <strong>the</strong> efficiencyloss from failing to set <strong>the</strong> correct trading ratios. This last is what is meant by getting prices right.Moreover, somewhat paradoxically, even with perfectly competitive markets we show that issuing<strong>the</strong> correct number <strong>of</strong> permits can be also essential for getting <strong>the</strong> prices <strong>of</strong> pollution right. <strong>We</strong> deferto <strong>the</strong> concluding section a brief discussion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> implications <strong>of</strong> our results for nonpoint-sourcepollution.2 A <strong>the</strong>oretical model <strong>of</strong> water-quality managementIn this section we develop a static model <strong>of</strong> water-quality management in a generic river basin.<strong>We</strong> show how <strong>the</strong> TRS and <strong>the</strong> DTRS can both be derived directly from this more generic model.Thus, <strong>the</strong> two alternatives can be compared on <strong>the</strong> same efficiency grounds within our framework.Let e = (e 1 , . . . , e i , . . . , e N ) be a vector <strong>of</strong> emissions, where e i represents emissions from source i,and let ē be a vector <strong>of</strong> baseline or uncontrolled emissions. Index i serves <strong>the</strong> dual purpose<strong>of</strong> denoting a source and also its geographic location. Clearly, e i ≤ ē i for every i. Let x =(x 1 , ..., x m , . . . , x M ) be a vector <strong>of</strong> ambient pollution levels, where x m denotes concentration atreceptor m. Assume that <strong>the</strong>re exists a linear mapping T : R N → R M describing <strong>the</strong> scientificrelationship between e and x. This linearity assumption has a long heritage in <strong>the</strong> economicsliterature (see Montgomery, 1972; Krupnick et al., 1983; McGartland and Oates, 1985; and Hungand Shaw, 2005). Let T be given by x = T e ′ , where T is a M × N matrix <strong>of</strong> nonnegative transfer3


coefficients. 5 Let S : R M → R, given by S(x), be a differentiable function that describes totaleconomic damages as a function <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> vector <strong>of</strong> ambient pollution levels. Assume that ∂S/∂x m > 0for all m. It follows that total economic damages as a function <strong>of</strong> emissions are differentiable andare given by D(e) = S(T e ′ ). Define a vector <strong>of</strong> abatement levels a = ē − e, where by definitiona i ∈ [0, ē i ]. Each source i is assumed, here and throughout <strong>the</strong> paper, to have a twice-differentiableabatement cost function C i (a i ), with C i ′ > 0 and C′′ i > 0.Under <strong>the</strong>se standard assumptions, an efficient program minimizes <strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> abatement costsand damages:mina∑ Ni=1 C i(a i ) + D(ē − a). (1)Given that <strong>the</strong> C i ’s and D are differentiable (and so continuous) and that a i ∈ [0, ē i ] for all i, <strong>the</strong>Wiestaurass <strong>the</strong>orem ensures that a solution to (1) exists. Denote this optimum a eff .In <strong>the</strong> earlier literature (Montgomery, 1972; Krupnick et al., 1983; McGartland and Oates,1985; Hung and Shaw, 2005), it was <strong>of</strong>ten assumed that a social planner solves, instead <strong>of</strong> (1), anauxiliary cost-effectiveness program <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> form:mina∑ Ni=1 C i(a i ) s.t. x m ≤ ¯X m ∀m and x = T e ′ , (2)where ¯X = ( ¯X 1 , . . . , ¯X M ) is a vector <strong>of</strong> environmental constraints on ambient pollution levels, onefor each receptor. Denote <strong>the</strong> solution to (2), by a HS . As we will see in Section 3, <strong>the</strong> TRS attemptsto solve <strong>the</strong> cost-effective program (2) ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> efficient program (1).And we will see in Section 4 that Farrow et al. (2005) considered a different program still.Their DTRS is aimed at minimizing <strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> abatement costs subject to a constraint on totaldamages, TD. Assuming that D is an additively separable, linear damage function <strong>of</strong> emissions,D(e) = ∑ i d ie i , Farrow et al. solvemina∑ Ni=1 C i(a i ) s.t. D(ē − a) ≤ TD. (3)Muller and Mendelsohn (2009) observe that in order for <strong>the</strong> solution to (3) to coincide with <strong>the</strong>solution to (1), <strong>the</strong> planner must set <strong>the</strong> constraint on total damages, TD, at <strong>the</strong> efficient level.Let a FSCH denote <strong>the</strong> solution to (3).Let us now establish a preliminary result, which links Hung and Shaw’s TRS and Farrow etal.’s DTRS.Proposition 1. Provided that <strong>the</strong> C i ’s and D are continuous, <strong>the</strong> following are true:(i) Given <strong>the</strong> efficient solution a eff , <strong>the</strong>re exists a constraint vector ¯X eff in terms <strong>of</strong> pollutionconcentrations such that <strong>the</strong> solution a HS to <strong>the</strong> auxiliary program (2) subject to ¯X eff is <strong>the</strong>optimal solution a eff ;(ii) Given <strong>the</strong> efficient solution a eff , <strong>the</strong>re exists a constraint value TD eff <strong>of</strong> total damages suchthat <strong>the</strong> solution a FSCH to <strong>the</strong> auxiliary program (3) subject to T D eff is <strong>the</strong> optimal solutiona eff ; and5 The literature on groundwater hydrology suggests that <strong>the</strong> mapping T may not be linear (see Todd and Mays,2005). Thus, damage functions can be nonlinear for two different reasons. First, environmental harm may be anonlinear function <strong>of</strong> concentrations (our S). Second, concentrations at receptors may <strong>the</strong>mselves be a nonlinearfunction <strong>of</strong> emissions (our T ). Our results apply to linearity <strong>of</strong> ei<strong>the</strong>r type, but we maintain <strong>the</strong> assumption <strong>of</strong>linearity in T throughout <strong>the</strong> paper.4


(iii) The social planner requires no more information to implement program (2) than to implementprogram (3) in order to achieve <strong>the</strong> efficient solution a eff .Pro<strong>of</strong>. To see (i), given <strong>the</strong> efficient solution a eff , let <strong>the</strong> efficient constraint vector ¯X eff be definedas¯X eff = T (ē − a eff ) ′ .Suppose, by way <strong>of</strong> contradiction, that a HS solves (2) subject to ¯X = ¯X eff , but a HS ≠ a eff . BecauseD is originally an increasing function <strong>of</strong> concentrations x, and because x eff = T (ē − a eff ) ′ = ¯X eff ,we have:∑C i(a effii ) + D(x eff ) < ∑ C i(a HSii ) + D(x HS ) ≤ ∑ C i(a HSii ) + D(x eff ).The first inequality follows from a HS ≠ a eff and <strong>the</strong> second inequality follows because x HS ≤ x effimplies D(x HS ) ≤ D(x eff ). But this last inequality implies that <strong>the</strong>re exists a eff ≠ a HS such that∑i C i(a eff i ) < ∑ i C i(a HS i ) with x eff = ¯X eff . This contradicts <strong>the</strong> assumption that a eff minimizes<strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> abatement costs subject to <strong>the</strong> environmental constraint ¯X eff .The pro<strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> (ii) is analogous, with <strong>the</strong> constraint value TD eff defined as TD eff = D(ē − a eff ).To establish (iii), note that in order for <strong>the</strong> solution to (3) to achieve a eff , <strong>the</strong> planner must setTD at <strong>the</strong> efficient level, which requires that <strong>the</strong> planner knows <strong>the</strong> two mappings T : R N → R Mand D : R M → R. But this information is all that is required for <strong>the</strong> regulator to find <strong>the</strong> optimalconstraint vector ¯X eff . This completes <strong>the</strong> pro<strong>of</strong>.Proposition 1 establishes <strong>the</strong> practical equivalence <strong>of</strong> (2) and (3), <strong>the</strong> two alternative costeffectivenessprograms. In practice, so long as <strong>the</strong> social planner has perfect knowledge <strong>of</strong> T andD, it does not matter whe<strong>the</strong>r environmental policy is set based upon ¯X m or upon T D. Thisdoes not mean, however, that <strong>the</strong> two trading mechanisms are equivalent. As we shall see, <strong>the</strong>TRS and <strong>the</strong> DTRS present different informational requirements: <strong>the</strong> TRS requires that transfercoefficients be estimated while <strong>the</strong> DTRS requires that ratios <strong>of</strong> marginal damages be estimated.More importantly, we will describe a set <strong>of</strong> conditions under which <strong>the</strong> TRS equilibrium maynot achieve <strong>the</strong> solution to (2). <strong>We</strong> will also describe a (different) set <strong>of</strong> conditions under which<strong>the</strong> DTRS equilibrium may not achieve <strong>the</strong> solution to (3). <strong>We</strong> show, <strong>the</strong>refore, that one cannotguarantee that <strong>the</strong> equilibrium under <strong>the</strong> TRS is equivalent to that under <strong>the</strong> DTRS. In <strong>the</strong> followingsections, we investigate <strong>the</strong>se questions by incorporating (i) branching <strong>of</strong> a river in <strong>the</strong> mapping Tand (ii) nonlinear damages in <strong>the</strong> mapping S.A word <strong>of</strong> caution is in order when interpreting our Proposition 1. This is that <strong>the</strong> equivalencebetween <strong>the</strong> two cost-effectiveness programs assumes that <strong>the</strong> planner knows a eff . This in turnrequires that she has complete information regarding <strong>the</strong> abatement cost functions. A primaryappeal <strong>of</strong> permit trading is that in many cases <strong>the</strong> policy can be put in place, and an optimaloutcome <strong>the</strong>nce achieved, by a planner who has no information regarding individual abatementcost functions. That may not be true here. The point is important because <strong>the</strong> apparent advantage<strong>of</strong> DTRS over TRS is that DTRS can achieve <strong>the</strong> efficient optimum provided that T D is setoptimally. This advantage <strong>of</strong> DTRS disappears, though, in view <strong>of</strong> our proposition, if <strong>the</strong> TRSequilibrium can itself achieve <strong>the</strong> optimum <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> alternative program (2). For <strong>the</strong>n, <strong>the</strong> sameoptimum can be achieved ei<strong>the</strong>r by TRS or by DTRS. In determining under which conditions oneis to be preferred over <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong>n, it is important for us to re-evaluate <strong>the</strong> equivalence between<strong>the</strong> TRS equilibrium and <strong>the</strong> optimum <strong>of</strong> (2) under general conditions.5


3 The <strong>Trading</strong>-Ratio System (TRS)The Hung-Shaw TRS allocates tradable discharge permits beginning at <strong>the</strong> zone (and thus <strong>the</strong>source) that is fur<strong>the</strong>st upstream. Allocation proceeds from <strong>the</strong>re on down <strong>the</strong> stream, ensuringalong <strong>the</strong> way that <strong>the</strong> concentration standard is met at each zone. This means that for somesources low on <strong>the</strong> river few permits, or even none, will be recieved in <strong>the</strong> initial allocation. 6 TheHung-Shaw system indexes zones so that m = 1 indicates <strong>the</strong> most upstream source and M <strong>the</strong>most downstream source. 7 For simplicity, Hung and Shaw assume that <strong>the</strong>re is one discharger ineach zone. This means that, in our notation, <strong>the</strong> set <strong>of</strong> zones {m} coincides with <strong>the</strong> set <strong>of</strong> pollutingsources {i}. As <strong>the</strong>y observe, this does not jeopardize <strong>the</strong> generality <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir results. Thus, in thissection we shall use i to denote both sources and zones (or receptors). Given <strong>the</strong> unidirectionalflow <strong>of</strong> a river, <strong>the</strong> transfer matrix T has a special characteristic: for any m and n with m > n,τ mn = 0, where τ mn is <strong>the</strong> element <strong>of</strong> T that measures <strong>the</strong> water-quality impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> pollutionfrom zone m upon concentration at zone n. As do Hung and Shaw, we assume that each sourceinfluences its own zone in a unitary fashion: τ ii = 1 for all i.Given <strong>the</strong> ambient zonal pollution standards ¯X from program (2), <strong>the</strong> TRS regulator uses<strong>the</strong> transfer coefficients in T to allocate zonal tradable discharge permits (TDPs) ¯Z so that <strong>the</strong>standards are met if no trade occurs. Starting from <strong>the</strong> most upstream zone, define ¯Z 1 = ¯X 1 and,for j > 1, define ¯Z j = ¯X j − ∑ j−1i=1 τ ij ¯Z i . It is possible that, for a given j, we might find thatτ (j−1)j ¯Xj−1 > ¯X j . That is, <strong>the</strong> level <strong>of</strong> pollutant arriving from upstream when <strong>the</strong> standard isexactly met <strong>the</strong>re exceeds zone j’s standard even when no pollution is emitted in zone j. In thiscase, zone j is called a critical zone. The Hung-Shaw allocation scheme sets ¯Z j = 0 and, in turn,reduces <strong>the</strong> allocation <strong>of</strong> permits to <strong>the</strong> upstream zone (or, possibly more than one upstream zone)to <strong>the</strong> point at which zone j is no longer critical: ¯Zj−1 = ( ¯X j /τ (j−1)j ) − ∑ j−2k=1 τ kj ¯Z k . (See Hungand Shaw, p. 88).The TRS allocation scheme ensures that <strong>the</strong> water-quality impacts <strong>of</strong> all upstream zonal standardson a given zone are accounted for via <strong>the</strong> upstream transfer coefficients. Note that in using<strong>the</strong> TRS procedure, <strong>the</strong> regulator takes as given <strong>the</strong> set <strong>of</strong> zones {i}, <strong>the</strong> zonal environmentalstandards ¯X, and <strong>the</strong> transfer coefficients T . Each discharger is <strong>the</strong>n allowed to trade freely in awatershed-wide permit market according to <strong>the</strong> transfer coefficients T , so long as its emissions donot exceed <strong>the</strong> permits it holds.Formally, each source i solves:minr ki ,r si ,r sjC i (a i ) − p i r si + ∑ j p jr ji (4)s.t.¯Zi ≥ (ē i − r ki ) − ∑ i−1jir jij=1(5)a i = r ki + r si (6)r si = ∑ nijj=i+1(7)0 ≤ r ki , r si , r sj , (8)where p i and p j are <strong>the</strong> market prices <strong>of</strong> permits from sources i and j, r ji is <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> pollution6 The TRS allocation scheme, by design, privileges upstream sources over downstream sources. This might createa certain amount <strong>of</strong> political resistence in practice, but it makes good economic sense. An efficient outcome should“fill <strong>the</strong> river” with pollution up to <strong>the</strong> standard at each receptor. Failing to do this will lead to higher aggregateabatement costs.7 Indexes along two branches above <strong>the</strong>ir confluence, though important for bookkeeping purposes, have no ordinalrelationship to each o<strong>the</strong>r.6


control purchased from source j to <strong>of</strong>fset pollution at source i, r ki is <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> pollution controlfrom source i that is kept by source i to meet <strong>the</strong> zonal standard ¯Z i , and r si is <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong>pollution control sold by source i. As Hung and Shaw observe, <strong>the</strong> TRS possesses two advantagesover o<strong>the</strong>r trading schemes. The first is that each discharger must participate in only a singlewatershed-wide permit market, so that transaction costs are low. The second is that <strong>the</strong> regulatorallocates initial zonal discharge permits ¯Z in such a way that <strong>the</strong> ambient environmental constraints¯X are satisfied exactly at <strong>the</strong> initial allocation.One can rewrite constraint (5) to obtain Hung and Shaw’s trading constraint (<strong>the</strong>ir equation(5)):e i ≤ ¯Z i + ∑ i−1τ jir ji − ∑ nr ij, (9)j=1 j=i+1where r ij is <strong>the</strong> net amount <strong>of</strong> zonal discharge permits sold by source i to source j. This constraintmeans that any discharger can buy permits only from upstream zones and sell permits only todownstream zones. Because sources can trade permits at exchange rates τ, in any TRS equilibrium(including <strong>the</strong> boundary case), for any j > i, <strong>the</strong> spatially explicit prices <strong>of</strong> permits must satisfyτ ij p j = p i . (10)The economic implications <strong>of</strong> this equality are substantial. Even if a high-cost source is locatedupstream <strong>of</strong>, or on a different branch from, a low-cost source, this constraint strictly prohibits anycost-minimizing trade between <strong>the</strong>m: τ ij = 0 for i > j. This might seem justifiable at first on <strong>the</strong>grounds that water flows downstream, so that any downstream pollution reduction or a reductionon a different branch has no effect on <strong>the</strong> concentration at <strong>the</strong> upstream location. However, <strong>the</strong>marginal damages <strong>of</strong> pollution from dischargers located in <strong>the</strong> different branch can be higher thanthose located in <strong>the</strong> upstream, particularly when damages are nonlinear. If so, <strong>the</strong>n more abatementby low-cost firms in <strong>the</strong> different branch in exchange for less abatement at high-cost firms in <strong>the</strong>upstream would be Pareto improving. The TRS, <strong>the</strong>n, disallows some trades that would increasewelfare. <strong>We</strong> shall return to this point in Section 5 when presenting <strong>the</strong> results <strong>of</strong> our numericalwork.According to Proposition 1, <strong>the</strong> solution to program (2) also solves program (1), regardless <strong>of</strong>branching or nonlinear damages. The question is whe<strong>the</strong>r Hung and Shaw’s TRS equilibrium isguaranteed to achieve <strong>the</strong> solution to program (2). Our next result, Proposition 2, shows that <strong>the</strong>answer is no. 8 There are situtions, not unusual in actual practice, in which <strong>the</strong> outcome <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>TRS is ei<strong>the</strong>r indeterminant (<strong>the</strong> permit-allocation scheme breaks down) or inefficient (it fails tosolve program (2)).<strong>We</strong> first turn our attention to an important property <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> transfer coefficients. This propertyis satisfied in Hung and Shaw’s numerical example, but is not o<strong>the</strong>rwise noted in <strong>the</strong>ir paper. Thecoefficients must be associative. Intuitively, this means that <strong>the</strong> amelioration or degradation <strong>of</strong> aunit <strong>of</strong> pollutant between zone i and zone i + 1 is <strong>the</strong> same whe<strong>the</strong>r that unit was emitted at zone ior arrived from upstream. Formally, associativity is defined as follows.Definition. Given a matrix T = {τ ij } <strong>of</strong> transfer coefficients, say that T is associative if for alli, m, and k, τ im τ ki = τ km . Say that T is non-associative if <strong>the</strong>re exist i, m, and k for whichτ im τ ki ≠ τ km .8 <strong>We</strong> have also shown that when <strong>the</strong>re are multiple adjacent critical zones, <strong>the</strong> original TRS allocation schemebreaks down. For this situation we have derived a modified version <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> TRS in which permits are allocated startingat <strong>the</strong> downstream-most source and proceeding upstream. Our modified version achieves <strong>the</strong> optimal outcome in <strong>the</strong>face <strong>of</strong> adjacent critical zones. The pro<strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> this claim is available upon request. It appears that <strong>the</strong> TRS cannot besalvaged in <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> a critical zone at <strong>the</strong> confluence <strong>of</strong> branches.7


Proposition 2. The equilibrium under <strong>the</strong> Hung-Shaw TRS does not achieve <strong>the</strong> cost-effectivesolution to program (2) if (i) transfer coefficients are non-associative or (ii) <strong>the</strong>re exists a criticalzone at <strong>the</strong> confluence <strong>of</strong> upstream branches.Pro<strong>of</strong>. To prove (i), suppose that T is non-associative and let i, m, and k be such that τ im τ ki > τ km .(The argument is similar if this inequality is reversed.) Using <strong>the</strong> transfer coefficients and <strong>the</strong>definition <strong>of</strong> x i , <strong>the</strong> constraint in program (2) can be rewritten as∑i τ ime i ≤ ¯X m for all m.Let Ω eff be <strong>the</strong> set <strong>of</strong> emissions vectors that satisfy this constraint. Let Ω trs be <strong>the</strong> set <strong>of</strong> emissionsvectors that satisfy <strong>the</strong> TRS trading constraint (9). Because each polluter must obey this constraint,<strong>the</strong> TRS equilibrium solves program (2) only if <strong>the</strong> constraint sets Ω eff and Ω trs are equivalent.<strong>We</strong> shall show that <strong>the</strong>re exists an emissions vector e ∈ Ω trs that is not in Ω eff .For any e ∈ Ω TRS , (9) is satisfied. Thus, let A m = ¯Z m − e m + ∑ m−1i=1 τ imr im − ∑ ni=m+1 r mi ≥ 0.Using <strong>the</strong> definition ¯Z m = ¯X m − ∑ m−1i=1 τ im ¯Z i , we havem−1∑e m − τ im r im +i=1n∑i=m+1m−1∑r mi + A m + τ im ¯Zi = ¯X m .Using <strong>the</strong> trading constraint (9) for ¯Z i and rearranging terms, we obtaini=1∑ m τ ime m + ∑ nr mi + A m − ∑ m−1i=1 i=m+1+ ∑ m−1τ im(− ∑ i−1τ kir ki + ∑ ni=1 k=1i=1 τ imr imk=i+1 r ik)≤ ¯X m .The last two terms <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> left-hand side can be fur<strong>the</strong>r rearranged to yield:− ∑ m−1τ imr im + ∑ m−1τ im(− ∑ i−1τ kir ki + ∑ m−1r ik + r im + ∑ ni=1 i=1 k=1 k=i+1= ∑ m−1i=1∑ i−1k=1 (−τ imτ ki + τ km )r ki + ∑ m−1i=1 τ imk=m+1 r im∑ nk=m+1 r ik,where we have used <strong>the</strong> fact that indexes i and k are anonymous and are <strong>the</strong>refore interchangeable.Thus we obtain:∑ m τ ime m + ∑ nr mi + A m + ∑ m−1τ ∑ nim r iki=1 i=m+1 i=1 k=m+1+ ∑ m−1i=1∑ i−1k=1 (−τ imτ ki + τ km )r ki ≤ ¯X m . (11)Note that because A m ≥ 0 and r ik , r mi ≥ 0, if <strong>the</strong> last term on <strong>the</strong> left side <strong>of</strong> (11) is non-negative<strong>the</strong>n it must be <strong>the</strong> case that ∑ i τ ime i ≤ ¯X m (that is, e ∈ Ω eff ). But if transfer coefficients arenon-associative with τ im τ ki > τ km , as we have assumed, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> last four terms in (11)can be negative. It follows <strong>the</strong>n that <strong>the</strong>re exists e ∈ Ω trs with e /∈ Ω eff .To see (ii), suppose that e hs is <strong>the</strong> solution vector for program (2). By assumption, we musthave a critical zone at <strong>the</strong> confluence receptor m: ∑ m−1 iτ (m−1i )m ¯X m−1i > ¯X m where {m − 1 i } i is<strong>the</strong> collection <strong>of</strong> indices immediately upstream <strong>of</strong> zone m, along two or more branches. <strong>We</strong> knowthat at <strong>the</strong> optimum,¯X m ≥ ∑ m−1 iτ (m−1i )me hsm−1 i,)8


with equality if abatement costs are strictly increasing. Suppose, without loss <strong>of</strong> generality, that<strong>the</strong>re are two zones upstream <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> critical confluence, say, m − 1 i = a, b. By assumption,¯X m = τ am e hsa+ τ bm e hsb ,On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, <strong>the</strong> TRS must allocate zonal discharge load standards ¯Z’s such that ¯Z m = 0and¯X m = τ am ¯Za + τ bm ¯Zb ,without knowledge <strong>of</strong> e hs . Because <strong>the</strong>re is only one constraint equation for two zonal standards,<strong>the</strong> allocation is indeterminate. It is trivial to see that if <strong>the</strong> TRS allocates, for example, e hsa > ¯Z aand ¯Z b = ( ¯X m − τ am ¯Za )/τ bm > e hsb, <strong>the</strong> trading equilibrium can never achieve e hs . Similararguments apply when <strong>the</strong>re are more than two upstream zones. This completes <strong>the</strong> pro<strong>of</strong>.Proposition 2 implies that if ei<strong>the</strong>r condition (i) or condition (ii) holds, <strong>the</strong> TRS cannot berelied upon to deliver <strong>the</strong> efficient outcome even if <strong>the</strong> ambient environmental constraints ¯X areset optimally. One might ask whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> conditions are likely to be met in practice. Nonassociativityis unlikely to be a serious concern. In many cases, perhaps most cases, a linear T is agood approximation and so associativity is guaranteed. <strong>We</strong> return to this point in Section 5. 9<strong>We</strong> believe that <strong>the</strong> second condition, in which a critical zone lies at a confluence <strong>of</strong> branches,is not at all unusual. In a branching river, confluence zone m is critical if ∑ m−1 iτ (m−1i )m ¯X m−1i >¯X m , where {m − 1 i } i is <strong>the</strong> collection <strong>of</strong> indices directly upstream <strong>of</strong> zone m, along all contributingbranches. Economic activity and population both tend to concentrate around <strong>the</strong> confluence <strong>of</strong>rivers. The water quality <strong>the</strong>re is <strong>of</strong>ten important for both aquatic species and people livingnearby. Thus a zone <strong>of</strong> confluence might be more likely than o<strong>the</strong>rs to be critical.Moreover, <strong>the</strong> TRS mechanism also has a practical disadvantage. Consider a branchless riversystem. Here <strong>the</strong> TRS equilibrium achieves <strong>the</strong> efficient outcome, if it achieves it at all, with notrade. To see this, note that as in <strong>the</strong> pro<strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Proposition 1, <strong>the</strong> efficient environmental constraintsare found by setting ¯X eff = T (ē − a eff ) ′ . Then as Hung and Shaw show, in a branchless watershed<strong>the</strong> constraint set arising from ¯Z is equivalent to that arising from ¯X eff and <strong>the</strong> TRS equilibriumachieves <strong>the</strong> cost-effective outcome. But because <strong>the</strong> cost-effective outcome must coincide with <strong>the</strong>efficient outcome, which also coincides with <strong>the</strong> initial allocation, and because it is assumed that<strong>the</strong>re is only one discharger in each zone, this implies that discharging pollution so as to satisfy¯Z exactly, without engaging in any trade, is also cost-minimizing. Put ano<strong>the</strong>r way, <strong>the</strong> regulatorcannot implement <strong>the</strong> efficient optimum in a decentralized manner. This claim is stated in <strong>the</strong>following result, which we state without pro<strong>of</strong>.Proposition 3. Suppose that in program (2), zonal environmental constraints ¯X are set at <strong>the</strong>efficient levels and that <strong>the</strong>re is only one discharger in each zone. Then if <strong>the</strong> TRS trading achieves<strong>the</strong> cost-effective optimum <strong>of</strong> program (2), it is achieved with no trade.9 Associativity is violated in <strong>the</strong> following hydrological model <strong>of</strong> pollutant flow in a groundwater aquifer. Toddand Mays (2005) model <strong>the</strong> concentration <strong>of</strong> a pollutant at distance δ and time t from a point source as:andτ(δ) = 1 2{1 − erf( d − vt2 √ tDX(d) = X 0τ(δ),) ( ) [ dv+ exp 1 − erfD( d + vt2 √ tD)]},where erf(·) is <strong>the</strong> Gauss error function, D <strong>the</strong> dispersion coefficient, v <strong>the</strong> average linear velocity, and X 0 <strong>the</strong> pollutionconcentration at <strong>the</strong> point source. The transfer coefficients τ(δ) derived from this model are not associative. See alsoSado et al. (2010), who apply <strong>the</strong> TRS to a set <strong>of</strong> point sources on <strong>the</strong> Passaic River in New Jersey. Their transfercoefficients do not quite satisfy <strong>the</strong> associativity property.9


4 The Damage-denominated <strong>Trading</strong>-Ratio System (DTRS)The DTRS <strong>of</strong> Farrow et al. is similar to <strong>the</strong> TRS <strong>of</strong> Hung and Shaw in that both are innovativeschemes for controlling water quality through trade in permits to emit pollution. 10 Both requirethat trades between sources satisfy a set <strong>of</strong> trading ratios. There <strong>the</strong> similarity ends.The fundamental regulatory constraint in <strong>the</strong> DTRS is a single limit on aggregate monetarydamages, here denoted TD, ra<strong>the</strong>r than a set <strong>of</strong> physical environmental standards. The tradingratios are <strong>the</strong>mselves based upon marginal damages, ra<strong>the</strong>r than upon physical transfer coefficients.Each source i’s marginal damage d i is calculated by integrating its contribution to monetary damagesover that source’s “zone <strong>of</strong> influence.” Having calculated marginal damages for each source, <strong>the</strong>regulator distributes permits ¯L i (in terms <strong>of</strong> emissions at <strong>the</strong> point <strong>of</strong> discharge) in such a way thataggregate damages meet <strong>the</strong> overall monetary constraint at <strong>the</strong> initial allocation: ∑ i d i ¯L i = TD.Trade is allowed between any two sources, but only according to <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir marginal damages.The aggregate limit on damages will continue to be satisfied in <strong>the</strong> face <strong>of</strong> any permissibletrade at <strong>the</strong>se ratios.Given <strong>the</strong> vector d <strong>of</strong> marginal damages and a vector e <strong>of</strong> emissions, Farrow et al. (and alsoMuller and Mendelsohn 2009) assume that aggregate damages are linear: D(e) = ∑ ni=1 d ie i . It isthis quantity that must not exceed TD. The assumed linearity <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> damage function means that<strong>the</strong> d i ’s do not depend upon emissions from o<strong>the</strong>r sources.Each source i solves <strong>the</strong> following cost-minimization program:min C i (a i ) − p i r si + ∑ p jr sj (12)r ki ,r si ,r sj js.t. (ē i − r ki ) − ∑ d jr sj ≤j d ¯L i (13)ia i = r ki + r si (14)r ki , r si , r sj ≥ 0, (15)where p i and p j are <strong>the</strong> market prices for a permit from source i and j, r sj is <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> pollutioncontrol purchased from source j to <strong>of</strong>fset pollution at source i, r ki is <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> pollution controlfrom source i that is kept by source i to meet <strong>the</strong> emissions standard ¯L i , and r si is <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong>pollution control sold by source i.Note that substituting e i = ē i − a i and r ki = a i − r si into (13), one obtains an analogue <strong>of</strong> (9),<strong>the</strong> Hung-Shaw trading constraint:e i ≤ ¯L i + ∑ jd jd ir sj − r si . (16)This constraint means that each polluting source can trade with any source, according to <strong>the</strong>marginal damage ratios, so long as <strong>the</strong> level <strong>of</strong> its discharge does not exceed <strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>original discharge limits ¯L i and <strong>the</strong> net purchase <strong>of</strong> damage-denominated permits ∑ j (d j/d i )r sj −r si .Because sources can trade permits at <strong>the</strong> exchange rates d j /d i , <strong>the</strong> spatially explicit prices <strong>of</strong> permitsin <strong>the</strong> equilibrium (including <strong>the</strong> boundary case) satisfy <strong>the</strong> analogue <strong>of</strong> (10):d jd ip j = p i . (17)10 In fact, <strong>the</strong> DTRS can be said to be <strong>the</strong> more powerful <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> two because it does not rely upon <strong>the</strong> strictlydownstream flow <strong>of</strong> a river. Muller and Mendelsohn (2009) build directly upon <strong>the</strong> DTRS in <strong>the</strong>ir model <strong>of</strong> air-qualitytrading.10


Note that unlike in <strong>the</strong> TRS, one can be sure that d i ≠ 0 in practice for all i: a source for whichthis is not true would not be part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> trading system. Therefore, each source can trade with anyo<strong>the</strong>r source, including those located upstream or downstream or on o<strong>the</strong>r branches <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> river.Farrow et al. (2005) derive <strong>the</strong> first-order necessary (and sufficient) conditions for each source’soptimization problem, from which <strong>the</strong> following interior equilibrium condition is derived:∂C i /∂a i∂C j /∂a j= d id j= p ip j. (18)This condition is, however, an incomplete characterization <strong>of</strong> a market equilibrium. First, <strong>the</strong>rewill be n − 1 equations for (n × 2) + n 2 unknowns {a i , r ki , r sj } i,j . Second, as Farrow et al. observe,this condition holds only when source i is a net buyer and source j is a net seller (and vice versa).Proposition 4 confirms that equation (17) must hold for any equilibrium, interior or boundary. Italow establishes conditions that must be satisfied at an interior equilibrium.Proposition 4. Suppose that marginal abatement cost C ′ i (a i) is strictly increasing for every source i.Then for given baseline emissions {ē i }, initial permits {¯L i }, and trading ratios {d i }, an interiormarket equilibrium <strong>of</strong> Farrow et al.’s DTRS mechanism is a vector {p ∗ i , a∗ i , r∗ ki , r∗ si , r∗ sj } i,j that solves<strong>the</strong> following system <strong>of</strong> equations:a ∗ i = R i (p ∗ i ), (19)∑di[ēi − R i (p ∗ i ) − ¯L i]= 0, (20)p ∗ id i= p∗ jd jfor alli, j, (21)where R i (p i ) is an abatement decision function given <strong>the</strong> price p i . The vector {rki ∗ , r∗ si , ∑ jis uniquely determined by <strong>the</strong> following response functions:d jd ir ∗ sj } i,jr ∗ ki = { ¯Li if ē i − R i (p ∗ i ) ≤ ¯L i0 if ē i − R i (p ∗ i ) > ¯L i(22){ ¯Lirsi ∗ − ē=i + R i (p ∗ i ) if ē i − R i (p ∗ i ) ≤ ¯L i0 if ē i − R i (p ∗ i ) > ¯L i(23)∑{d jr ∗ 0 if ēi − Rjsj =i (p ∗ i ) ≤ ¯L id i ē i − R i (p ∗ i ) − ¯L i if ē i − R i (p ∗ i ) > ¯L i(24)Pro<strong>of</strong>. First, we show a stronger version <strong>of</strong> condition (18): under <strong>the</strong> DTRS, prices must satisfy(21) in any equilibrium regardless <strong>of</strong> whe<strong>the</strong>r each source is a net buyer or a net seller. To see this,note that if (21) does not hold, say ifp i> p j,d i d j<strong>the</strong>n unlimited arbitrage pr<strong>of</strong>its are available to any source k ≠ i, j who buys permits from j andsells <strong>the</strong>m to i. Market demand for permits from j is infinite while <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> permits availablefrom j is finite at ¯L j . Note that whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y can actually buy and sell permits or not is irrelevant:<strong>the</strong>y simply demand permits while taking prices as given. Thus equilibrium prices must adjust insuch a way that (21) is satisfied. Therefore, each source i faces <strong>the</strong> same effective price in all zonalmarkets j: p i = p j (d i /d j ). It is irrelevant, <strong>the</strong>n, from which sources i buys permits or to whichsources it sells. It <strong>the</strong>n follows that i abates to <strong>the</strong> point at which ∂C i /∂a i = p i . Because ∂C i /∂a i11


is strictly increasing, <strong>the</strong> optimal abatement level a ∗ i = MC−1 d(p i ) is unique. Thus r = p i = p i j d jfor all j.Now, let us construct an excess demand function. Given an arbitrary price r <strong>of</strong> permits, sourcei would choose abatement R i such that MC i = r. Thus, R i is a well-defined function. The excessdemand for permits from source i is z i (p i ; ē i , ¯L i ) = ē i − R i (p i ) − ¯L i . If z i > 0, <strong>the</strong>n i must buypermits from elsewhere. If z i < 0, it sells its excess permits in <strong>the</strong> market. All permits sold toand purchased from i must be exchanged at <strong>the</strong> ratio d i /d j with permits from any source j. Thismeans that <strong>the</strong> common units <strong>of</strong> exchange are d i z i . Thus, <strong>the</strong> market clears in equilibrium only ifequations (19)–(24) holds. For a given vector {ē i , ¯L i , d i } i and n sources, this gives us n equationsfor n unknown prices {p ∗ i } i. Thus <strong>the</strong> equilibrium is exactly identified. The pro<strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> expressionsfor {r ki , r si , ∑ d jj d ir sj } i,j is obvious and thus omitted. The completes <strong>the</strong> pro<strong>of</strong>.This characterization <strong>of</strong> market equilibrium turns out to be useful for <strong>the</strong> simulations in Section5. There may be non-trivial boundary equilibria in which a ∗ i = 0 or a∗ i = ē i. These boundarycases can be dealt with by defining R i (p ∗ i ) = 0 if ∂C i/∂a i > p ∗ i for all a i ∈ [0, ē i ] and R i (p ∗ i ) = ē iif ∂C i /∂a i < p ∗ i for all a i ∈ [0, ē i ]. The rest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> equilibrium conditions are intact. <strong>We</strong> now askwhe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> equilibrium <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> DTRS achieves <strong>the</strong> cost-effective solution <strong>of</strong> program (3).Our next result is directly analogous to Proposition 2. According to Proposition 1, <strong>the</strong> solutionto program (3) also solves program (1), regardless <strong>of</strong> branching or nonlinear damages. The questionis whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> DTRS equilibrium is guaranteed to achieve <strong>the</strong> solution to program (3). Proposition 5shows that <strong>the</strong> answer is no. If <strong>the</strong> aggregate damage function is nonlinear in concentrations, <strong>the</strong>n<strong>the</strong> DTRS equilibrium does not minimize costs.Proposition 5. Suppose that aggregate environmental damages are a nonlinear function <strong>of</strong> pollutionconcentration, such that for all e we have:D(e) ≠ ∑ i (∂D(e)/∂e i)e i .Then <strong>the</strong> DTRS equilibrium does not achieve <strong>the</strong> cost-effective solution <strong>of</strong> program (3).Pro<strong>of</strong>. <strong>We</strong> <strong>of</strong>fer a pro<strong>of</strong> for <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> an interior optimum <strong>of</strong> (3). Note that at <strong>the</strong> interioroptimum, <strong>the</strong> emission vector e eff must satisfy <strong>the</strong> necessary (but not sufficient) condition∂D(e eff )/∂e i∂D(e eff = ∂C i(a eff i )/∂a i)/∂e j ∂C j (a eff)/∂ajjfor all i, j,where e eff i= ē i − a eff i . On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, under Proposition 4, at an interior equilibrium we haved i= ∂C i(a eff i )/∂a id j ∂C j (a eff)/∂ajjfor all i, j.Thus, in order for <strong>the</strong> equilibrium to achieve <strong>the</strong> cost-effective solution, <strong>the</strong> regulator must evaluate<strong>the</strong> exchange rates (<strong>the</strong> d’s) at <strong>the</strong> optimum: d eff i = ∂D(e eff )/∂e i . Under <strong>the</strong> DTRS, <strong>the</strong> regulatorallocates ¯L in such a way that ∑d effii¯L i = T D = D(e eff ). (25)<strong>We</strong> now ask whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>re exists some initial allocation ¯L, satisfying (25), such that <strong>the</strong> resultingequilibrium would achieve <strong>the</strong> cost-effective solution. Suppose, by contradiction, that <strong>the</strong>re existssuch an allocation ¯L and that <strong>the</strong> resulting equilibrium is also efficient: e dtrs = e eff . Because <strong>the</strong>12


equilibrium must satisfy <strong>the</strong> market-clearing condition (21), we have∑d effii¯L i = ∑ i d effiDT RSei . (26)However, because <strong>the</strong> aggregate damage function is nonlinear, we have∑d effii e effi ≠ D(e eff ). (27)Combining (25), (26), and (27), we see that∑d effii¯L i = ∑ d effii e dtrsiwhich contradicts that e dtrs = e eff . This completes <strong>the</strong> pro<strong>of</strong>.= D(e eff ) ≠ ∑ d effii e effi .As is evident from <strong>the</strong> pro<strong>of</strong>, <strong>the</strong> DTRS breaks down because <strong>the</strong> initial allocation <strong>of</strong> permits ¯Lfollows Farrow et al.’s original allocation rule (25). A natural question arises: what would happenif one were to use a different allocation rule? For example, <strong>the</strong> regulator could allocate permitsso that S(¯L 1 , . . . , ¯L n ) = TD. Here one encounters an insuperable difficulty: <strong>the</strong>re is no allocationrule <strong>the</strong> regulator could rely upon in this case. Indeed, <strong>the</strong> problem arises under <strong>the</strong> TRS too.To see this, suppose that <strong>the</strong> regulator agreed upon <strong>the</strong> desired level <strong>of</strong> aggregate damage TD.Because <strong>the</strong> damage function is nonlinear, <strong>the</strong>re will inevitably exist many vectors ¯L such thatS(¯L 1 , . . . , ¯L n ) = TD. The regulator’s problem is indeterminate. (Recall that D is <strong>the</strong> compositionfunction D(e) = S(T e).)In <strong>the</strong> following section, we investigate how <strong>the</strong> TRS and DTRS perform, relative to <strong>the</strong> efficientsolution as well as to each o<strong>the</strong>r, if <strong>the</strong> initial allocation <strong>of</strong> permits follows such an arbitrary rule.5 A numerical modelThe results <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> previous two sections imply that in numerous watersheds <strong>of</strong> practical interest,water-quality trading based on ei<strong>the</strong>r TRS or DTRS may not achieve <strong>the</strong> efficient outcomes. Thenumerical exercise reported here is designed to quantify <strong>the</strong> welfare losses associated with <strong>the</strong>shortcomings <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> two systems, relative to each o<strong>the</strong>r and also relative to <strong>the</strong> social optimum.<strong>We</strong> do this by constructing a numerical model. Though <strong>the</strong> model is fairly sophisticated in itsconstituent parts, incorporating <strong>the</strong> relevant scientific aspects <strong>of</strong> a realistic watershed, in order toilluminate our key question we have kept it relatively small. The specific parameter values arehypo<strong>the</strong>tical but realistic.Consider a second-best scenario in which <strong>the</strong> regulator has imperfect information regarding polluters’abatement costs, but has perfect information regarding environmental damages. Toge<strong>the</strong>r,<strong>the</strong>se conditions mean that <strong>the</strong> fundamental constraints ¯X (for <strong>the</strong> TRS) or TD (for <strong>the</strong> DTRS)cannot be set at <strong>the</strong> efficient levels. There can be infinitely many ways to allocate initial permitsunder such a scenario, all meeting <strong>the</strong> constraint in <strong>the</strong> absence <strong>of</strong> trade. <strong>We</strong> assume that <strong>the</strong> totalnumber <strong>of</strong> permits in <strong>the</strong> initial allocation is equal to <strong>the</strong> socially optimal level. This assumptionenables us to disentangle <strong>the</strong> sources <strong>of</strong> inefficiency, as it implies that TRS and DTRS could potentiallyachieve <strong>the</strong> social optimum. Put ano<strong>the</strong>r way, if ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> TRS or <strong>the</strong> DTRS fails to achieve<strong>the</strong> social optimum, it is not because <strong>the</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> permits is incorrect relative to <strong>the</strong> optimum.Indeed, <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>oretical premise <strong>of</strong> ideal permit trading is that, in <strong>the</strong> absence <strong>of</strong> market failures oro<strong>the</strong>r distortions, <strong>the</strong> trading outcome does not depend on <strong>the</strong> initial distribution <strong>of</strong> permits. Herewe have no market imperfections, but <strong>the</strong> premise is violated anyway.13


5.1 The water-quality modelThe Environmental Protection Agency has developed a <strong>the</strong>oretically acceptable and practicalmethod <strong>of</strong> modelling water-quality impacts, <strong>the</strong> NWPCAM. Farrow et al. (2005) consider a waterqualityimpact model based on <strong>the</strong> hydrologic assumptions used in NWPCAM. <strong>We</strong> follow <strong>the</strong> samestrategy.<strong>Water</strong> pollutants, such as phosphorus, nitrogen, and heat, decay as water carrying <strong>the</strong>m flowsdownstream through a river system. For instance, a pound <strong>of</strong> phosphorus discharged at one point in<strong>the</strong> river contributes to phosphorus concentrations at all points downstream <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> discharge pointuntil it is entirely assimilated. Let x mi be source i’s contribution to <strong>the</strong> pollution concentration atlocation m downstream. Then x mi is a function <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> emissions e i at source i, stream flow Q, andan exponential decay term:{0 if m is not downstream <strong>of</strong> ix mi =( )e iQ exp −ˆkδ mi if m is downstream <strong>of</strong> i, (28)where ˆk is <strong>the</strong> decay parameter and δ mi is a distance in river miles between source i and location m. 11Note that (28) implies that in <strong>the</strong> absence <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r pollution sources, <strong>the</strong> pollution concentrationat location i is simply x i = x ii = e i /Q. The pollution concentration at location m is <strong>the</strong> sum<strong>of</strong> contributions to <strong>the</strong> pollution concentrations across sources: x m = ∑ i x mi. This hydrologicalmodel incorporates both <strong>the</strong> unidirectional flow and <strong>the</strong> natural decay as important characteristics<strong>of</strong> a river system. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> model can also incorporate branching in <strong>the</strong> river. 12It is clear that <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> changes in pollution concentrations at source i’s location onpollution concentrations at any downstream location j is linear:τ ijdef= dx jdx i= exp(−ˆkδ ij ), (29)where <strong>the</strong> τ ij are <strong>the</strong> transfer coefficients. Note that we can easily establish <strong>the</strong> associative property<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> transfer coefficients: τ ik = τ ij τ jk for any sources i, j, k where source j is located downstream<strong>of</strong> source i but upstream <strong>of</strong> source k. 13Given <strong>the</strong> hydrological relationship between emissions and ambient pollution concentrations,11 In Farrow et al., <strong>the</strong> function takes <strong>the</strong> form{ ( )}e iQ exp −kθ t−20 δmi,Uwhere k is <strong>the</strong> nominal decay rate, θ is a coefficient reflecting sensitivity <strong>of</strong> k to <strong>the</strong> mean temperature t, and U is<strong>the</strong> stream velocity. Because units do not have any significant meaning in this simulation, we have simplified thisrelationship by replacing kθ (t−20) /U with ˆk, which is assumed to be constant and is evaluated at average hydrologicalparameters.12 To see this, suppose two sources, i and j, are located along two different branches upstream <strong>of</strong> a confluence. Theimpacts <strong>of</strong> emissions from i and j on pollution concentrations at location k below <strong>the</strong> confluence are expressed as x kiand x kj .13 Using (29), we can write:))τ ijτ jk = exp(−ˆkδ ij exp(−ˆkδ jk ,()= exp −ˆk[δ ij + δ jk ] ,)= exp(−ˆkδ ik = τ ij,where <strong>the</strong> last equality follows because δ ik = δ ij + δ jk by assumption.14


an important question remains as to how we should model <strong>the</strong> relationship between pollutionconcentrations and (monetary) damages. In this regard, Farrow et al. assumed that marginaldamages D are constant at each location m: ∂D/∂x m = W T P × H m where W T P is <strong>the</strong> constantper-capita marginal damages from changes in water quality and H m is <strong>the</strong> population size atlocation m. According to this specification, damages from each source’s emissions are given byD i (e i ) = d i e i , where d i is constant and independent <strong>of</strong> emissions levels e i :d i =M∑W T P × H m × τ mi × 1 Q .m=1To justify <strong>the</strong> constant marginal willingness to pay (WTP), Farrow et al. argue that water qualityis inversely related to pollution concentrations (that is, ∂W m /∂x m = −1) and that “<strong>the</strong> householdmarginal willingness to pay for a small improvement in water quality, WTP, is constant . . . over <strong>the</strong>range <strong>of</strong> water-quality conditions considered in this study.” (2005, p. 197).In <strong>the</strong> non-market valuation literature, however, it is <strong>of</strong>ten found that individuals obtain utilityfrom recreational and aes<strong>the</strong>tic values <strong>of</strong> water quality ra<strong>the</strong>r than directly from pollution concentrationlevels. That is, individuals care if <strong>the</strong> river water is swimmable, drinkable, and fishable,and if <strong>the</strong> river water provides habitat for important aquatic species. The quality <strong>of</strong> water andaquatic habitat at any location in <strong>the</strong> river is typically a nonlinear function <strong>of</strong> concentrations <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong>se pollutants in <strong>the</strong> area. Numerous examples exist: brown trout may cease growth at watertemperatures above 18.7-19.5 celsius degrees (Elliott and Hurley, 2001) and may not survive sevendays above 24.7±0.5 celsius degrees (Elliott, 2000). The population size <strong>of</strong> cutthroat trout is ahighly nonlinear function <strong>of</strong> selenium exposure and was estimated to experience 90% declines atmean selenium concentrations exceeding 17 µg/g <strong>of</strong> dry weight (Van Kirk and Hill, 2007). Andalgae growth is <strong>of</strong>ten modeled as a logistic function <strong>of</strong> nutrient concentrations (Anderson et al.,2002). Biological and chemical responses to pollution levels may not be linear.Willingness to pay may not be linear ei<strong>the</strong>r. In many watersheds in <strong>the</strong> U.S., water qualityis already impaired, so that a fur<strong>the</strong>r increase in pollution concentrations might cause seriouswater-quality degradation. Even if WTP for a small change in quality is constant over a range<strong>of</strong> concentration levels, it might be much bigger for <strong>the</strong> same small change above a particularconcentration threshold. Indeed, our communications with water practitioners reveal that <strong>the</strong>irprimary concern is closely related to this nonlinear biological response around hotspots. <strong>We</strong> stresshere that this concern is one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> important political factors that has plagued water-qualitytrading in many watersheds.To model <strong>the</strong> nonlinear biological responses that allow for <strong>the</strong> type <strong>of</strong> threshold effects highlightedabove, we consider a logistic damage response to pollution concentrations at each locationm:bS m (x m ) =for all m = 1, . . . , M, (30)1 + exp(−a(x m − c))where a is a damage-sensitivity parameter, b a scale parameter, and c a concentration threshold.The total economic damages are <strong>the</strong>n given by D(e) = ∑ m S m(x m ). Logistic models are commonlyused in biology and ecology for modelling <strong>the</strong> response <strong>of</strong> species’ mortality or population size topollution. Though in biology, <strong>the</strong> parameters a and c <strong>of</strong>ten depend on a variety <strong>of</strong> environmentalfactors, we treat <strong>the</strong>m as constants that do no vary by time or location for simplicity <strong>of</strong> analysis.The parameter b is a scaling parameter that transforms biological damages into monetary economicdamages, which we also assume are constant. With <strong>the</strong>se assumptions, marginal aggregate damageswith respect to emissions from any source i depend not only upon emissions from that source but15


Parameter Units Valuek Decay rate mile −1 0.005Q Stream flow ft 3 /s 10a Damage parameter none 5b Damage scale parameter none 6.7c Concentration threshold mg/L 5Table 1: Parameters for water-quality modelalso∑upon emissions from o<strong>the</strong>r sources, both downstream and upstream <strong>of</strong> i (that is, ∂D/∂e i =m (∂S m/∂x m ) (∂x m /∂e i )). When <strong>the</strong>re is a branch in a river system, marginal damages alsodepend on <strong>the</strong> emissions from sources located along <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r branches.The parameter values <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> model can vary widely by pollutant and watershed. Becauseour goal is to obtain generic efficiency properties <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> two trading systems, we decided to chooserepresentative parameter values for <strong>the</strong> water-quality model (28) and <strong>the</strong>n choose a set <strong>of</strong> parametersa, b, and c that generate interior optima for at least two out <strong>of</strong> three sources given <strong>the</strong> assumedcost parameters (see below). The value <strong>of</strong> ˆk = 0.005 is chosen based on three parameters: <strong>the</strong>mean <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> decay rates for seven representative water pollutants (U.S. EPA, 2002), <strong>the</strong> averagewater temperature <strong>of</strong> 20 Celsius degrees, and <strong>the</strong> stream velocity <strong>of</strong> 1.5 miles per hour. The scaleparameter b and <strong>the</strong> threshold parameter c are important in generating interior solutions. <strong>We</strong> thusstarted with arbitrary values a = 5 and c = 5 and <strong>the</strong>n searched for <strong>the</strong> associated value <strong>of</strong> b. Theparameters used for <strong>the</strong> simulation are summarized in Table 1.5.2 Simulation Scenarios<strong>We</strong> assume that <strong>the</strong> river has a main stem M and a single branch B. The river has a maximumlength <strong>of</strong> 200 river miles along <strong>the</strong> main stem and 150 river miles along <strong>the</strong> branch: m M ∈ [0, 200]and m B ∈ [0, 150]. The confluence occurs at m M = 100 (or equivalently, m B = 50). There arethree polluting sources. Source 1 is located in <strong>the</strong> most upstream point <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> main stem (m M = 0),source 2 at <strong>the</strong> confluence (m M = 100 or m B = 50), and source 3 at <strong>the</strong> most upstream point <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> branch (see Figure 1). The firms (or sources) have quadratic abatement cost functions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>form C i (a i ) = (1/α i ) × a 2 i , with a i ∈ [0, ē i ] and α i > 0.For a given initial allocation <strong>of</strong> permits, we first compute <strong>the</strong> social optimum, and <strong>the</strong>n allocatepermits in an equal amount to each polluting source: ¯L1 = ¯L 2 = ¯L 3 = ∑ e eff /3. Under <strong>the</strong> TRS,this means that zonal environmental standards, <strong>the</strong> ¯X’s, are allocated so that ¯X 1 = ¯L 1 , ¯X3 = ¯L 3 ,¯X 2 = ¯L 2 + τ 12 ¯X1 + τ 32 ¯X3 . Once again, we do not assume that <strong>the</strong> regulator knows e eff i or ∑ e eff i .<strong>We</strong> chose this allocation rule because we are interested in <strong>the</strong> relative performance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> twotrading systems under conditions that can be compared to <strong>the</strong> social optimum. Under <strong>the</strong> TRS,<strong>the</strong> correct transfer coefficients are known to <strong>the</strong> regulator and are announced to <strong>the</strong> polluters.Under <strong>the</strong> DTRS, <strong>the</strong> regulator does not know <strong>the</strong> social optimum, and so she evaluates <strong>the</strong> d i ’sat <strong>the</strong> initial allocation. 14 In each <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se setups, we simulate <strong>the</strong> trading outcomes for two sets<strong>of</strong> cost parameters: (A) α 1 = 7.5, α 2 = 15, α 3 = 7.5 and (B) α 1 = 15.0, α 2 = 7.5, α 3 = 15.0.14 <strong>We</strong> also experimented with various choices <strong>of</strong> d i’s. The results were not sensitive to <strong>the</strong>se values.i16


Figure 1: Hypo<strong>the</strong>tical riverCase A Outcome e 1 e 2 e 3 Damage Cost TotalTRS 23.7 23.7 23.7 511 1,942 2,454DTRS 48.9 0.0 34.4 530 1,589 2,119Optimum 42.0 0.0 29.0 60 1,787 1,848Case B Outcome e 1 e 2 e 3 Damage Cost TotalTRS 18.5 32.0 0.0 10 1,710 1,720DTRS 20.5 31.4 0.0 9 1,716 1,725Optimum 21.0 34.5 0.0 42 1,655 1,6975.3 Simulation Results5.3.1 Case A: α 1 = 7.5, α 2 = 15, α 3 = 7.5Table 2: Simulation resultsIn this case, a low-cost firm is located downstream <strong>of</strong> two high-cost firms. At <strong>the</strong> socially optimaloutcome, source 2 abates all <strong>of</strong> its emissions while source 1 emits more than source 3 despite <strong>the</strong>fact that <strong>the</strong>y have <strong>the</strong> same marginal costs and <strong>the</strong> same baseline emissions (Table 2). This occursbecause marginal damages at <strong>the</strong> optimum increase more in source 3’s emissions than in source 1’semissions. The TRS mechanism, as noted above, precludes upstream firms from buying permitsfrom downstream firms. It also precludes firms located on different branches above a commonconfluence from engaging in any trades. Because <strong>the</strong> potential seller (<strong>the</strong> low-cost firm) is locateddownstream, no trade can occur between <strong>the</strong> downstream firm and <strong>the</strong> upstream firms. Moreover,at a social optimum efficient trades should occur between <strong>the</strong> two upstream firms. Yet again notrade between <strong>the</strong>m is allowed under <strong>the</strong> TRS. As a result, firms incur higher abatement costsunder <strong>the</strong> TRS than at <strong>the</strong> optimal outcome. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, <strong>the</strong> DTRS does allow tradesamong any <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> three sources.The problem with <strong>the</strong> DTRS, however, is that in this case <strong>the</strong> damage-denominated tradingcoefficients turn out to be poor approximations to <strong>the</strong> true marginal damages at <strong>the</strong> optimum. This17


Figure 2: Marginal damages, marginal costs, and trading coefficientspoint is demonstrated in Figure 2. The figure plots marginal damages as a function <strong>of</strong> each source’semissions, holding o<strong>the</strong>r sources’ emissions at <strong>the</strong> optimum. Figure 2 also shows each source’smarginal cost and trading coefficient. The social optimum occurs where marginal damages fromeach source are equated with its marginal cost and <strong>the</strong> overall constraint is satisfied. Interestingly,<strong>the</strong> equilibrium does not occur where each source’s marginal cost equals its trading coefficient d i .This is because each source makes its abatement/trading decision so that its marginal cost equals<strong>the</strong> spatially explicit price it faces, p i = (d j /d i )p j . Thus, when <strong>the</strong> d i ’s are poor approximationsto actual marginal damages, <strong>the</strong> trading outcome under DTRS does not equate marginal damageswith marginal costs.Ano<strong>the</strong>r problem with <strong>the</strong> DTRS∑is that, in equilibrium, <strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> emissions can exceed <strong>the</strong>sum <strong>of</strong> initial emissions permits: e dtrsi > ∑ e eff i . This occurs because nei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> individualpolluters nor <strong>the</strong> equilibrium market-clearing condition are constrained by ∑ e dtrsi ≤ ∑ e eff i . Themarket clears instead with ∑ d i e dtrsi ≤ ∑ d i ¯Li where ∑ d i ¯Li∑can be greater than or less thandi e eff i . Because sources can emit more than <strong>the</strong> socially efficient amount, environmental damagesare higher, but abatement costs are lower, at <strong>the</strong> DTRS equilibrium than at <strong>the</strong> social optimum.Lastly, note that Figure 2 shows that <strong>the</strong> first-order conditions are not sufficient in two ways.First, for source 3, its marginal cost curve intersects with <strong>the</strong> marginal damage curve at two points.Second, though not plotted, each source has infinitely many marginal damage curves correspondingto different emissions levels by o<strong>the</strong>r sources.18


5.3.2 Case B: α 1 = 15.0, α 2 = 7.5, α 3 = 15.0In this case, a high-cost firm is located downstream <strong>of</strong> two low-cost firms. At <strong>the</strong> social optimum,source 3 abates all <strong>of</strong> its emissions while source 2 emits <strong>the</strong> most (Table 2). Efficient trades shouldoccur under <strong>the</strong> TRS, because this system allows <strong>the</strong> high-cost downstream source to buy permitsfrom <strong>the</strong> two low-cost upstream sources. Indeed, this is exactly what happened in <strong>the</strong> simulation.Each firm is allocated 18.5 units <strong>of</strong> discharge permits-+ initially in both <strong>the</strong> TRS and <strong>the</strong> DTRS.In <strong>the</strong> TRS equilibrium, firm 2 bought 14.4 units from source 3 to increase its emissions to 32.9while firm 3 sold 18.5 units at <strong>the</strong> trading ratio τ 32 ≈ 0.78 (i.e. 18.5×τ 32 = 14.4 units for source 2).Note that under <strong>the</strong> TRS, <strong>the</strong> downstream firm has a choice <strong>of</strong> buying permits from ei<strong>the</strong>r source1 or source 3. Therefore, if <strong>the</strong> effective price <strong>of</strong> permits from source 1 is higher than that fromsource 3, <strong>the</strong>n source 2 would buy permits from source 3 and vice versa.It follows <strong>the</strong>n that <strong>the</strong> effective equilibrium prices are equalized across space: p 1 = τ 12 p 2 =τ 32 p 2 = p 3 . At this equilibrium price, source 1 has no incentive to sell its permits to source 2and thus ends up emitting exactly at <strong>the</strong> initial allocation. The trading outcome in <strong>the</strong> DTRS issimilar. Source 3 abates its emissions down to zero and sells its permits mostly to source 2. Adifference occurs, because source 3 also sold its permits to source 1. As we have noted, under <strong>the</strong>DTRS firms located in different branches are allowed to trade, and <strong>the</strong> equilibrium prices satisfyp 1 = (d 1 /d 2 )p 2 = (d 1 /d 3 )p 3 . It turns out that at <strong>the</strong>se equilibrium prices, it is cheaper for source 1to buy permits from source 2. As a result, source 1’s equilibrium emissions are slightly higher under<strong>the</strong> DTRS than under <strong>the</strong> TRS while source 3’s equilibrium emissions are lower under <strong>the</strong> DTRSthan under <strong>the</strong> TRS. The extra trade between source 1 and source 3, however, decreased efficiencyslightly, compared to <strong>the</strong> TRS equilibrium. This is because <strong>the</strong> damage-denominated tradingcoefficients, <strong>the</strong> d i ’s, are poor approximations <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> true marginal damages at <strong>the</strong> optimum, asshown in Figure 2. In this case, <strong>the</strong>refore, <strong>the</strong> DTRS encouraged inefficient trades. Note, however,that both TRS and DTRS closely approximate <strong>the</strong> social optimum in this case.5.4 <strong>Price</strong>s vs. quantitiesOn one hand, our numerical analysis suggests <strong>the</strong> impossibility <strong>of</strong> getting prices right in watershedshaving certain characteristics. Nei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> TRS nor <strong>the</strong> DTRS succeeds in providing <strong>the</strong> correctprice signals for water-quality trading. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, our analysis also indicates that in somecases, <strong>the</strong> equilibria approximate <strong>the</strong> social optimum quite closely. <strong>We</strong> obtained <strong>the</strong>se results bysetting <strong>the</strong> total supply <strong>of</strong> permits equal to <strong>the</strong> socially optimal level. A natural question <strong>the</strong>nis, which type <strong>of</strong> inefficiency is larger: not getting <strong>the</strong> prices <strong>of</strong> pollution right or not getting <strong>the</strong>quantity <strong>of</strong> permits right? <strong>We</strong> investigate this question by simulating <strong>the</strong> trading outcomes forvarying levels <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> permits (in percentage reduction from <strong>the</strong> baseline discharge level)and allocating permits in equal number to each discharger. The result is shown in Figure 3.First, <strong>the</strong> relative performance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> two systems varies, in an unsystematic way, with <strong>the</strong>supply <strong>of</strong> permits. In Case A (α 1 = 7.5, α 2 = 15, and α 3 = 7.5) where a low-cost source is locateddownstream <strong>of</strong> two high-cost sources, <strong>the</strong> DTRS performed substantially better than TRS when <strong>the</strong>total supply <strong>of</strong> permits was kept to <strong>the</strong> socially optimal level. This is because <strong>the</strong> TRS prohibitedany trade from taking place. However, when <strong>the</strong> total supply <strong>of</strong> permits is reduced to 60-70% <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>baseline discharge level, <strong>the</strong> TRS performs better than <strong>the</strong> DTRS despite <strong>the</strong> fact that no tradingstill takes place under <strong>the</strong> TRS. This occurs because <strong>the</strong> efficiency loss due to <strong>the</strong> TRS precludingtrading was outweighed by <strong>the</strong> efficiency loss due to <strong>the</strong> DTRS encouraging inefficient trades,which increased environmental damages substantially relative to no trade. In contrast, in Case B(α 1 = 15.0, α 2 = 7.5, and α 3 = 15.0), in which a high-cost source is located downstream <strong>of</strong> two19


low-cost sources, <strong>the</strong> DTRS performed slightly better than <strong>the</strong> TRS for all levels <strong>of</strong> initial permitsupplies. In this case, TRS and DTRS provide similar price signals so that <strong>the</strong> magnitude <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>efficiency loss due to environmental damages is similar between <strong>the</strong> two systems (see <strong>the</strong> left panel<strong>of</strong> Case B in Figure 3). However, because <strong>the</strong> DTRS <strong>of</strong>fers more flexibility in trading, it reducesabatement costs a bit more than does <strong>the</strong> TRS. This effect dominates <strong>the</strong> relative performance <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> two systems.Second, total economic costs C + D do not exhibit a simple convex relationship with respectto <strong>the</strong> total supply <strong>of</strong> permits under <strong>the</strong> two systems. This is because nei<strong>the</strong>r environmentaldamages nor abatement cost has a simple relationship to <strong>the</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> permits. Despite <strong>the</strong>fact that environmental damages are defined as a decreasing function <strong>of</strong> emissions or pollutionconcentrations, environmental damages in <strong>the</strong> trading equilibrium are not necessarily a decreasingfunction <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> reduction in <strong>the</strong> total supply <strong>of</strong> permits, and analogously, despite <strong>the</strong> fact thatabatement costs are a convex function <strong>of</strong> abatement levels, total abatement costs are not necessarilya convex function <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> reduction in <strong>the</strong> total supply <strong>of</strong> permits. These effects are especiallystrong in <strong>the</strong> DTRS, because <strong>the</strong> damage-denominated trading coefficients are based on marginaldamages at <strong>the</strong> initial allocation, and thus depend endogenously on <strong>the</strong> initial supply <strong>of</strong> permits.Somewhat counter-intuitively, <strong>the</strong>se trading coefficients can ei<strong>the</strong>r decrease or increase efficiencyrelative to <strong>the</strong> TRS. On one hand, <strong>the</strong> trading coefficient can decrease efficiency by providing wrongtrading margins, which adversely affects environmental damages. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, however, <strong>the</strong>trading coefficients can improve efficiency by providing flexibility for trading partners, which reducesabatement costs.Lastly, at least in <strong>the</strong> current model, getting <strong>the</strong> quantity <strong>of</strong> permits right appears to be moreimportant than getting <strong>the</strong> prices <strong>of</strong> permits right. In Case A, <strong>the</strong> estimated efficiency losses areonly 18.2% and 0.1% <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> total economic damages, respectively, for TRS and DTRS when <strong>the</strong>socially optimal number <strong>of</strong> permits are distributed. (In Case B <strong>the</strong> corresponding results are 3.6%for TRS and 0.03% for DTRS.) In contrast, <strong>the</strong> maximum efficiency losses due to mis-specifying <strong>the</strong>total supply <strong>of</strong> permits are 80.9% and 97.8% <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> total economic damages, respectively, for TRSand DTRS. (In Case B <strong>the</strong> corresponding results are 80.3% for TRS and 78.1% for DTRS.) It isimportant to emphasize that this result is not a direct consequence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> logistic damage responsewe assumed in (30). Ra<strong>the</strong>r it stems from <strong>the</strong> multiple effects <strong>of</strong> mis-specifying <strong>the</strong> quantity <strong>of</strong>pollution, including <strong>the</strong> incorrect price signals that arise from it.6 DiscussionThis paper examined <strong>the</strong> efficiency properties <strong>of</strong> two recently developed water-quality tradingmodels, <strong>the</strong> trading ratio system (TRS) proposed in Hung and Shaw (2005) and <strong>the</strong> damagedenominatedtrading ratio system (DTRS) proposed in Farrow et al. (2005). These two modelsemerged as potential water-quality trading models that address both spatially explicit damagesand transaction costs. <strong>We</strong> showed that both trading systems fail to achieve <strong>the</strong> efficient optimum(and <strong>the</strong> cost-effectiveness optimum) under general conditions that are likely to hold in numerouswatersheds. More specifically, <strong>the</strong> TRS fails when <strong>the</strong> river has critical zones in a branching riverwhereas <strong>the</strong> DTRS fails when <strong>the</strong> pollution damages are nonlinear in ei<strong>the</strong>r emissions levels orpollution concentrations. <strong>We</strong> derived <strong>the</strong>se results under <strong>the</strong> first-best scenario in which <strong>the</strong> regulatorknows <strong>the</strong> efficient vector <strong>of</strong> environmental constraints (for TRS) and <strong>the</strong> efficient damageconstraint (for DTRS).Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, in a second-best scenario where <strong>the</strong> regulator cannot set <strong>the</strong>se constraints at<strong>the</strong> efficient levels, nei<strong>the</strong>r system dominates in terms <strong>of</strong> efficiency, because <strong>the</strong> TRS excludes20


Figure 3: Total supply <strong>of</strong> permits and relative performance <strong>of</strong> TRS and DTRSefficient trades while <strong>the</strong> DTRS promotes inefficient trades. These results indicate, in this sense, <strong>the</strong>impossibility <strong>of</strong> getting <strong>the</strong> spatially explicit prices <strong>of</strong> pollution right under ei<strong>the</strong>r system. However,our computational results do indicate <strong>the</strong> possibility that <strong>the</strong> two systems may still approximate<strong>the</strong> socially efficient optimum sufficiently closely if <strong>the</strong> total allowable permits are set initially atlevels sufficiently close to <strong>the</strong> optimum. The (maximum) efficiency loss due to mis-specifying <strong>the</strong>total supply <strong>of</strong> permits was much larger than that from mis-specifying <strong>the</strong> spatial prices <strong>of</strong> permits.Interestingly, <strong>the</strong> magnitude <strong>of</strong> inefficiency due to incorrect signals may also depend on <strong>the</strong> totalsupply <strong>of</strong> permits. Thus our paper suggests <strong>the</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> getting <strong>the</strong> quantity <strong>of</strong> pollutionright even while striving to get <strong>the</strong> spatial prices <strong>of</strong> pollution right.Though we kept <strong>the</strong> assumptions <strong>of</strong> our model as general as possible with respect to waterpollution and watershed characteristics, like Hung and Shaw and also Farrow et al. we ignored <strong>the</strong>problem <strong>of</strong> nonpoint-source pollution (NSP). Nonpoint sources can <strong>of</strong> course play an importantrole in a watershed. It is usually difficult and costly to identify and monitor <strong>the</strong> level <strong>of</strong> NPSpollution-causing activity (or discharge levels), because land-use practices (for example, fertilizerapplication) or land use itself (for example, buildings and parking lots) are <strong>the</strong> major sources<strong>of</strong> such pollution. If <strong>the</strong> discharge from each source is difficult to identify, nei<strong>the</strong>r trading nordirect control would achieve <strong>the</strong> efficient outcome. However, in recent years substantial efforts havebeen devoted to transforming nonpoint sources into point sources. Scientists <strong>of</strong> various disciplinescontinue to improve <strong>the</strong>ir ability to identify and monitor pollution levels from nonpoint sources.As our understanding <strong>of</strong> NPS improves, <strong>the</strong> present study could have important implications for<strong>the</strong> optimal management <strong>of</strong> nonpoint-source pollution.In <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> nonpoint pollution, <strong>the</strong> business <strong>of</strong> getting <strong>the</strong> spatial prices <strong>of</strong> pollution rightbecomes even more difficult for two reasons. First, because water pollution can travel through mul-21


tiple nonpoint sources before it reaches <strong>the</strong> river, and because <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> nonpoint sources is<strong>of</strong>ten quite large, <strong>the</strong> spatial dependence <strong>of</strong> marginal damages from each source’s pollution is likelyto be exacerbated. Second, each nonpoint source’s discharge is likely to affect pollution concentrationlevels at multiple receptors. In such a case, allowing sources to trade at <strong>the</strong> exchange ratesbased on <strong>the</strong> transfer coefficients between <strong>the</strong> receptor points along <strong>the</strong> river, as in <strong>the</strong> TRS, wouldlikely result in substantial deadweight loss for two reasons. First, because each source’s emissionscan affect pollution concentrations at multiple receptors for some <strong>of</strong> which transfer coefficients canbe zero (across branches, for example), trading based only on <strong>the</strong> non-zero transfer coefficients mayresult in inefficient trades. Second, just as with point-source pollution, <strong>the</strong> TRS can also precludeefficient trades from taking place by restricting <strong>the</strong> exchange among sources whose emissions affectpollution concentrations at receptors located on separate branches. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, <strong>the</strong> DTRSwould be relatively robust to nonpoint-source pollution. As long as <strong>the</strong> discharge level from eachnonpoint source can be identified, pollution damages still being <strong>the</strong> function <strong>of</strong> pollution concentrationlevels at receptor points, <strong>the</strong> marginal damage from each nonpoint source can be calculated.Because trading ratios based on <strong>the</strong> marginal damages are <strong>the</strong> correct exchange rates for <strong>the</strong> nonpointsources, <strong>the</strong> DTRS could potentially <strong>of</strong>fer <strong>the</strong> correct trading incentives. The problem arises,however, when damages are highly nonlinear. As we have demonstrated, evaluating <strong>the</strong> marginaldamages at any allocation (including <strong>the</strong> optimum) and fixing <strong>the</strong> trading ratios at that evaluationpoint would encourage inefficient trades to take place by giving incorrect trading incentives. Thenumber <strong>of</strong> trading sources is likely to be large in <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> NSP, and so <strong>the</strong> error from pre-fixing<strong>the</strong> trading ratios might result in substantial deadweight loss.22


References[1] Anderson, D.M, P.M. Glibert, J.M. Burkholder. (2002). Harmful Algal Blooms and Eutrophication:Nutrient Sources, Composition, and Consequences. Estuaries, 25(4), 704–726[2] Atkinson, S.E., T.H. Tietenberg. (1982). The Empirical Properties <strong>of</strong> Two Classes <strong>of</strong> Designsfor Transferable Discharge Permit Markets. Journal <strong>of</strong> Environmental Economics and Management,9(2), 101-121.[3] Breetz, H.L., Karen Fisher-Vanden, Laura Garzon, Hanna Jacobs, Kailin Kroetz, and RebeccaTerry. (2004). <strong>Water</strong> quality trading and <strong>of</strong>fset initiatives in <strong>the</strong> U.S.: A comprehensive survey.Dartmouth College, New Hampshire.[4] Elliott, J.M. (2000). Pools as refugia for brown trout during two summer droughts: troutresponses to <strong>the</strong>rmal and oxygen stress. Journal <strong>of</strong> Fish Biology, 56, 938-948.[5] Elliott, J.M. and M.A. Hurley. (2001). Modelling growth <strong>of</strong> brown trout, Salmo trutta, in terms<strong>of</strong> weight and energy units. Freshwater Biology, 46, 679-692.[6] Environomics. (1999). A summary <strong>of</strong> U.S. effluent trading and <strong>of</strong>fset projects. Prepared forU.S. EPA Office <strong>of</strong> <strong>Water</strong>.[7] Fang, Feng, K. William Easter, and Patrick L. Brezonik. (2005). Point-nonpoint source waterquality trading: a case study in <strong>the</strong> Minnesota River Basin. Journal <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> American <strong>Water</strong>Resources Association, 41(3), 645-658.[8] Farrow, R.S, Shultz, M.T., Celikkol, P. Van Houtven, G.L. (2005). <strong>Pollution</strong> <strong>Trading</strong> in <strong>Water</strong><strong>Quality</strong> Limited Areas: Use <strong>of</strong> Benefits Assessment and Cost-Effective <strong>Trading</strong> Ratios. LandEconomics, 81(2), 191-205.[9] Helfand, G.E. and B.W. House. (1995). Regulating Nonpoint Source <strong>Pollution</strong> under HeterogeneousConditions. American Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics, 77(4), 1024-1032.[10] Hung, Ming-Feng and Daigee Shaw. (2005). A trading-ratio system for trading water pollutiondischarge permits. J. <strong>of</strong> Env. Economics & Mgmt., 49, 83-102.[11] King, Denis M. (2005). Crunch time for water quality trading. Choices, 20(1), 71-75.[12] King, Denis M. and Peter J. Kuch. (2003). Will nutrient credit trading ever work? An assessment<strong>of</strong> supply and demand problems and institutional obstacles. The Environmental LawReporter. Washington, DC: Environmental Law Institute.[13] Mauzeralla, D.L., B. Sultanc, N. Kima, and D.F. Bradford. (2005) NOx emissions from largepoint sources: variability in ozone production, resulting health damages and economic costs.Atmospheric Environment 39, 2851–2866.[14] McGartland, A. and W.E. Oates. (1985). Marketable Permits for <strong>the</strong> Prevention <strong>of</strong> EnvironmentalDeterioration. J. <strong>of</strong> Env. Economics and Mgmt., 12, 207–228.[15] Montgomery, W. David. (1972). Markets in licenses and efficient pollution control programs.Jour. <strong>of</strong> Economic Theory, 5, 395-418.23


[16] Morgan, Cynthia and Ann Wolverton. (2005). <strong>Water</strong> quality trading in <strong>the</strong> United States.Working paper #05-07, U.S. EPA National Center for Environmental Economics, WathingtonDC: EPA.[17] Muller, N.Z., Mendelsohn, R. (2009). Efficient <strong>Pollution</strong> Regulation: <strong>Get</strong>ting <strong>the</strong> <strong>Price</strong>s <strong>Right</strong>.American Economic Review, 99(5), 1714-1739.[18] Oregon Department <strong>of</strong> Environmental <strong>Quality</strong>. <strong>Water</strong> quality credit trading in Oregon: A casestudy report. Available online.[19] Sado, Y., R.N. Boisvert, and G.L. Poe. (2010). Potential cost savings from discharge allowancetrading: A case study and implications for water quality trading. <strong>Water</strong> Resour. Res., 46,W02501.[20] Schnoor, J.L. (1996). Environmental modeling: Fate and transport <strong>of</strong> pollutants in water, air,and soil. Wiley: New York.[21] Segerson, K. (1988). Uncertainty and Incentives for Nonpoint <strong>Pollution</strong> Control. J. <strong>of</strong> Env.Economics & Mgmt., 15, 87-98.[22] Shortle, J.S. and J.W. Dunn. (1989). The Relative Efficiency <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Source <strong>Water</strong><strong>Pollution</strong> Control Policies. American Journal <strong>of</strong> Agricultural Economics, 68(3), 668-677.[23] Taff, Steve J. and Norman Senjem. (1996). Increasing regulators’ confidence in point-nonpointpollutant trading schemes. <strong>Water</strong> Resources Bulletin, 32(6), 1187-1193.[24] Tietenberg, Tom H. (1st ed.1985; 2nd ed. 2006). Emissions trading: principles and practice.Washington DC: Resources for <strong>the</strong> Future. 2nd edition.[25] Todd and Mays, 2005.[26] U.S. EPA. (2002). Estimation <strong>of</strong> national economic benefits using <strong>the</strong> National <strong>Water</strong> <strong>Pollution</strong>Control Assessment Model to evaluate regulatory options for concentrated animal feedingoperations. U.S. EPA Office <strong>of</strong> <strong>Water</strong>, Washington DC: EPA. EPA-821-R-03-009.[27] U.S. EPA. (2003). <strong>Water</strong> quality trading policy. U.S. EPA Office <strong>of</strong> <strong>Water</strong>, Washington DC:EPA.[28] U.S. EPA. (2004). <strong>Water</strong> quality trading assessment handbook: <strong>Can</strong> water quality tradingadvance your watershed’s goal? U.S. EPA Office <strong>of</strong> <strong>Water</strong>, Washington DC: EPA.[29] Woodward, R.T., R.A. Kaiser, and A.M. Wicks. (2002). The structure and practice <strong>of</strong> waterquality trading markets. Journal <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> American <strong>Water</strong> Resources Association.[30] Van Kirk, R.W., Hill, S.L., (2007). Demographic model predicts trout population response toselenium based on individual-level toxicity. Ecological Modeling 206, 407-420.24

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!