02.02.2021 Views

The 1451 Review (Volume 1) 2021

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

The impacts of 2°C warming is estimated to be drastic (IPCC 2018; CAT 2019).

As we are on track to exceed 2.9°C, I would argue that current mitigation policies are

insufficient, which makes adaptation even more important (CAT 2019). As de Bruin et

al. (2009: 11) argue, ‘the near-term impacts of climate change are already “locked in”,

irrespective of the stringency of mitigation efforts thus making adaptation inevitable’.

Yet, policy makers and scholars devote considerably more attention on mitigation than

adaptation (Fankhauser; 2017). Hence this dissertation will focus on adaptation while

recognising mitigation as a crucial complement.

Adaptation Measures

Adaptation has been shown to be highly beneficial and adapting early may bear several

advantages compared to action later on. Benefits exceed costs by a wide margin for

various adaptation measures from enhanced meteorological services to sustainable

agricultural land management, with as high as a 5:1 cost-benefit ratio for flood-risk

management measures (Watkiss 2016).

Fankhauser (2017) explains why some adaptation action should be undertaken

earlier rather than later. Firstly, it may be cheaper to factor in climate change into

long-term decisions at the outset rather than adapting them later; this is especially

relevant to long-lived infrastructure since it may be more expensive to risk-proof or

retrofit already existing structures than to design resilient infrastructure to begin with.

Secondly, some solutions might bear early benefits as they are ‘win-win’ for both

adaptation and wider economic or environmental goals; especially true for ecosystembased

adaptation measures such as mangrove protection. Finally, some adaptation

measures such as capacity building may only provide benefits in the long run, and

therefore early investment is needed. Above all, ‘pursuing place-specific adaptation

pathways towards a 1.5°C warmer world has the potential for significant positive

outcomes for well-being in countries at all levels of development’ (IPCC 2018: 44).

Some adaptation can occur autonomously with funding from private sources.

In other words, households and firms change their behaviour, adapting to new

information about their environment (Fankhauser 2017). Private adaptation is

thought to be more efficient than public adaptation as both the benefits and costs

accrue to the same decision-maker; hence action is only taken when the benefits

exceed the costs (Mendelsohn 2012). However, this is only true under the assumptions

that there are no externalities, there is access to markets, private property rights exist

and perfect information is available (Mendelsohn 2012). If any one of these

assumptions is violated, market failure occurs, leading to sub-optimal adaptation

undertaken by the private sector.

Firstly, market failure exists because adaptation creates (local) public goods.

For example, the investment in a seawall creates positive spillovers for everyone living

in the area, although they have not paid for it (Stern 2007). The presence of positive

externalities leads to sub-optimal investment in adaptation by the private sector.

Secondly, climate change is characterised by deep uncertainties; current climate

information is subject to constant change. Furthermore, the level of uncertainty is

much higher for adaptation than mitigation, because of the uncertainty of climate

change impacts on the local level. There is also a lack of regional climate information,

which is most relevant for adaptation (Fankhauser 2017; Heal and Millner 2014).

Under imperfect information, it becomes impossible for actors to assess the costs and

benefits of adaptation accurately (Stern 2007). Thirdly, developing countries may lack

protection of private property rights, resulting in limited incentives to climate-proof

the property when the risk of losing the property is high (Mendelsohn 2012).

Finally, people in the Global South may lack access to capital. Adaptation often

requires a high upfront investment while developing countries tend to have general

scarcity of resources. With lacking access to capital markets and/or a high cost of

capital, investment in adaptation is unlikely to reach socially desirable levels (Stern

2007). Buhr et al. (2018: 4) show that vulnerability to climate change actually

increases the cost of capital in developing countries. In particular, they found that ‘for

every USD 10 paid in interest by developing countries, an additional dollar will be

spent due to climate vulnerability’. This would further exacerbate the capital

constraints on adaptation investment and adds to the current economic challenges in

developing countries.

Given the market failure, the state has an important role in providing

adaptation. Fankhauser and Soare (2013) suggest three roles for the government. The

government should a) create an environment that is conducive to private adaptation,

for example by enhancing the security of property rights, b) provide climate-resilient

public goods such as flood prevention measures, climate information services and

resilient public infrastructure, and c) assist vulnerable groups who cannot adapt

adequately themselves in order to minimise the implications of climate change on

inequality. However, due to the resource constraints Global South governments face,

10 11

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!