05.04.2013 Views

WEALTH, DISPOSABLE INCOME AND CONSUMPTION - Economics

WEALTH, DISPOSABLE INCOME AND CONSUMPTION - Economics

WEALTH, DISPOSABLE INCOME AND CONSUMPTION - Economics

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

1 INTRODUCTION<br />

Empirical research on consumption behaviour over the past 15 or so years<br />

has been strongly influenced by two papers, both published in 1978. Hall<br />

(1978) examined the stochastic implications of the permanent income<br />

hypothesis, and Davidson et al. (1978) developed dynamic econometric<br />

models for aggregate consumption based on an error-correction (EC)<br />

specification.<br />

Hall’s innovation was to exploit the restrictions implied by the firstorder<br />

conditions of a representative consumer’s intertemporal optimization<br />

problem. The attractive feature of this approach is that the resulting<br />

Euler equations do not require the specification of all future variables relevant<br />

to the household’s consumption decisions, so the difficulties associated<br />

with measuring wealth and obtaining closed-form relationships<br />

between consumption and wealth can be largely avoided.<br />

These advantages are, however, achieved at some cost. While the<br />

estimation of Euler equations allows the empirical researcher to examine<br />

whether consumers adjust optimally between adjacent periods, it provides<br />

little direct evidence on the determinants of consumption or on how various<br />

random disturbances or policy changes are transmitted to consumption.<br />

Consequently, the Euler equation approach to modelling<br />

consumption is not particularly well-suited to policy analysis and forecasting.<br />

In addition, the stochastic permanent income model also suffers the<br />

practical problem that it is frequently rejected by the data (see, for example,<br />

Flavin 1981, Hayashi 1982, Nelson 1987, and Wirjanto 1991). These rejections<br />

are often interpreted as evidence that some consumers face binding<br />

liquidity constraints (see Hall and Mishkin 1982, Flavin 1985, Zeldes 1989,<br />

and Campbell and Mankiw 1990).<br />

Partly as a result of these limitations, policy makers and practitioners<br />

in general have largely turned to the more eclectic EC consumption<br />

model proposed by Davidson et al. (1978). The EC model is not usually<br />

derived from the micro foundations of optimizing behaviour, but is proposed<br />

as a robust empirical relationship between macro aggregates that is<br />

1

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!