29.06.2013 Views

Evaluating Patient-Based Outcome Measures - NIHR Health ...

Evaluating Patient-Based Outcome Measures - NIHR Health ...

Evaluating Patient-Based Outcome Measures - NIHR Health ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

1995). This form of measure may therefore be<br />

described as using preference-based methods in<br />

contrast to non-preference approaches, which<br />

would describe many of the other types of instrument<br />

we have already reviewed (Gold et al., 1996).<br />

The former is concerned as far as possible to obtain<br />

the respondent’s own overall value of the different<br />

dimensions of his or her health status whereas the<br />

latter, as has already been described, mostly derives<br />

scores for dimensions of health status based on<br />

summing responses to questionnaire items, with<br />

the possibility of dimension scores being in<br />

turn summed.<br />

Utility measures therefore elicit the personal<br />

preferences of individuals regarding health states.<br />

This kind of measure has also been regarded as a<br />

means of obtaining important evidence of the<br />

overall value to society of health states. Data from<br />

utility measures are applied to assess in turn the<br />

social value of health care interventions by means<br />

of cost–utility analysis (Patrick, 1976). Data regarding<br />

costs and utilities for different health care<br />

interventions have been used to inform decisions<br />

about resource allocation between competing<br />

interventions (Gold et al., 1996). Whilst most attention<br />

has been given to utility measures because of<br />

their role in cost–utility analyses to inform decisions<br />

about resource allocation, there is some<br />

research on their use as decision-aids in individual<br />

patient care where patients face difficult choices<br />

between treatment options (McNeil et al., 1982).<br />

In the context of a clinical trial, there are two<br />

basically different methods of assessing the preferences<br />

or utilities of the patients involved. The most<br />

direct way of assessing patients’ utilities associated<br />

with health states is for them to be elicited directly<br />

from patients who are in the health states of interest<br />

by means of an interview in which respondents<br />

take part in experimental tasks such as standard<br />

gamble or time trade-off to elicit their values and<br />

preferences (Read et al., 1984; Torrance, 1986,<br />

1987; Drummond, 1987). In simplistic terms, the<br />

experimental method employed with standard<br />

gamble elicits respondents’ values regarding health<br />

states by finding out how ready an individual would<br />

be hypothetically to undergo varying levels of risk<br />

associated with treatment to avoid a given health<br />

state. The greater the level of risk acceptable to the<br />

individual, the more severe the health state. The<br />

analogous experimental task with time trade-off is<br />

for subjects to judge the equivalence of periods of<br />

time in a particular health state with varying shorter<br />

periods in perfect health. The shorter the period<br />

of perfect health considered equivalent, the more<br />

severe the health state.<br />

<strong>Health</strong> Technology Assessment 1998; Vol. 2: No. 14<br />

The use of experimental tasks such as standard<br />

gamble or time trade-off may be considered forms<br />

of direct utility measurement in that patients in<br />

a trial directly report their own values through<br />

responses to experimental tasks in an interview.<br />

Alternatively, utilities may be assessed by obtaining<br />

information from the patients in a trial by means<br />

of self-completed questionnaires that assess health<br />

status more or less in the same way as other patientbased<br />

outcome measures already reviewed. That is,<br />

patients select items that most describe their health<br />

state. However, in this second approach, questionnaire<br />

items have weighted utility scores attached<br />

that have been derived from prior survey data in<br />

which utilities have been measured from, as far<br />

as possible, appropriate samples of respondents<br />

(Feeny et al., 1995; Brooks et al., 1996). This<br />

second approach may be considered indirect<br />

utility measurement in that whilst patients directly<br />

report their health states, utility values attached to<br />

these states are derived from prior research on the<br />

preferences of other samples. A variant of indirect<br />

utility measurement is to elicit values of a specific<br />

patient group, say patients with arthritis, that can<br />

then be used in other clinical trials of patients with<br />

arthritis from whom it may not always be feasible<br />

to perform full interviews.<br />

It should be emphasised that the utilities approach<br />

to patient-based outcome measures (whether considered<br />

as a type of measure or as one form of<br />

weighting the scores of measures) is distinctive in<br />

the extent to which it draws on specific theoretical<br />

assumptions. In particular the concept of utility<br />

itself is central to utility measures. It is fundamental<br />

to economic theory but, partly because of its<br />

axiomatic status, it is hard to define (van Praag,<br />

1993). Richardson (1994) refers to four different<br />

concepts or uses employed by the literature when<br />

referring to ‘utilities’. In one sense, it has been<br />

used to refer to a psychological concept of wellbeing;<br />

measurable levels of satisfaction and desirability<br />

of individuals in relation to matters such<br />

as health. A second usage refers to utility as the<br />

ordinal ranking individuals have about options<br />

such as health states. Thirdly, utility may be used<br />

to refer to the intensity of preferences regarding<br />

options. The fourth sense of the term refers to preferences<br />

between options under conditions of risk.<br />

These important differences of emphasis remain in<br />

the current literature and cannot be resolved from<br />

research evidence. A somewhat simplistic approximation<br />

to the concept in the field of health states<br />

that ‘the more ‘utility’ an individual expects to<br />

obtain from a particular good or service the more<br />

he will be willing to pay for it’ (Hurst and Mooney,<br />

1983). However, willingness to pay is only a<br />

13

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!