20.07.2013 Views

Question 1 What did Marx mean with his formu - University of Utah

Question 1 What did Marx mean with his formu - University of Utah

Question 1 What did Marx mean with his formu - University of Utah

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

U <strong>of</strong> <strong>Utah</strong> Econ 5080 2007fa 23<br />

other, they are also not shocked if the price <strong>of</strong> milk in one store is different than the price<br />

<strong>of</strong> milk in a different store – although t<strong>his</strong> diversity contradicts the idea that t<strong>his</strong> is the price<br />

“<strong>of</strong>” milk. To us, t<strong>his</strong> diversity is a familiar every-day occurrence, but when East Germany<br />

switched from a socialist system to a capitalist system, people used to call the radio station<br />

saying: “I just was in two different stores and they sold milk at two different prices; isn’t<br />

one <strong>of</strong> these stores doing something illegal?” Under socialist price controls, they were used<br />

to getting milk everywhere at the same price. T<strong>his</strong> seemed to be natural to them, because<br />

after all it was the same milk, and they were shocked to see that now the same milk was sold<br />

at different prices.<br />

<strong>Marx</strong>’s theory <strong>of</strong>fers here the following explanation: we are not shocked about t<strong>his</strong> contradiction<br />

because we understand that both contradictory aspects have some truth in them.<br />

The exchange-value <strong>of</strong> milk is commonly associated <strong>with</strong> milk and not seen as something<br />

purely relative, i.e., newly generated in the interaction between each buyer and seller, because<br />

it is the exterior manifestation <strong>of</strong> the value <strong>of</strong> milk. T<strong>his</strong> value is indeed closely<br />

associated <strong>with</strong> milk, because it is the socially necessary labor-time to produce t<strong>his</strong> milk.<br />

On the other hand, the variability <strong>of</strong> prices <strong>of</strong> the same good is also accepted because the<br />

sellers compete on the markets. I.e., the value is not set by a direct organization <strong>of</strong> producers,<br />

but the producers produce independently and then let their goods fight <strong>with</strong> each other on<br />

the market. Prices are the results <strong>of</strong> these competitive battles. T<strong>his</strong> does not <strong>mean</strong> that they<br />

are entirely “accidental,” the value still shines through as the regulatory principle since every<br />

producer has similar production costs. In <strong>Marx</strong>’s terminology, prices are the exterior surface<br />

manifestations <strong>of</strong> the intrinsic value, and t<strong>his</strong> manifestation is indeed relative, because it is<br />

the exchange relation between the two commodities.<br />

Chased makes a distinction between the intrinsic quality and its exterior surface manifestation<br />

when he writes: “alas, it is not a question <strong>of</strong> what the worth is, but <strong>of</strong> the exchangevalue.”<br />

But in <strong>his</strong> answer, if I understand it right, the intrinsic thing is the use-value, while<br />

the exchange-value comes from the market power <strong>of</strong> the suppliers who “control” the market.<br />

<strong>Marx</strong> does not believe that use-value has an influence on the price; in the long run, use-value<br />

only has an influence on the quantities supplied. Instead, the intrinsic basis for pricing is the<br />

ultimate cost <strong>of</strong> the commodity to society, which is its labor input. T<strong>his</strong> theoretical disagreement<br />

has important implications: in <strong>Marx</strong>’s theory, value is produced in production by the<br />

workers, while in the neoclassical theory, value is produced on the market by the consumers.<br />

Message [155] referenced by [2010fa:24]. Next Message by Hans is [157].<br />

<strong>Question</strong> 63 is 64 in 2008SP, 64 in 2008fa, 66 in 2009fa, 67 in 2010fa, 61 in 2012fa, and<br />

67 in Answer:<br />

<strong>Question</strong> 63 The French economist Le Trosne wrote that the value <strong>of</strong> a thing consists in<br />

its exchange-proportions <strong>with</strong> other things. Does <strong>Marx</strong> agree <strong>with</strong> t<strong>his</strong>, or how would he<br />

re-<strong>formu</strong>late t<strong>his</strong> proposition to make it correct?<br />

[131] Daru: Le Trosne doesn’t know the difference. Le Trosne’s statment can be broken<br />

in two parts. He first mentions the “value <strong>of</strong> a thing” (and by ‘thing’ we here assume that<br />

he <strong>mean</strong>s a ‘commodity’) and then defines it relative to the exchange proportions <strong>with</strong> other<br />

commodities. <strong>Marx</strong> would not agree <strong>with</strong> t<strong>his</strong> for the simple reason that he defines the two<br />

24 2007fa Econ 5080 U <strong>of</strong> <strong>Utah</strong><br />

concepts differently. Every time <strong>Marx</strong> uses the word ‘value’ he is referring to the congealed<br />

abstract labour expended on the commodity (Hans [105]). Le Trosne on the other hand<br />

suggests that the value <strong>of</strong> a commodity exists only because it can be exchanged <strong>with</strong> some<br />

other commodity/ies. Here to <strong>Marx</strong>, Le Trosne is only talking about the exchange value <strong>of</strong><br />

the commodity and not its value.<br />

The exchange value <strong>of</strong> a commodity for <strong>Marx</strong> is an outcome <strong>of</strong> some social relations<br />

that take pace in the marketplace. The exchange-value only provides producers <strong>with</strong> signals<br />

about the quantity <strong>of</strong> a commodity to be produced. For <strong>Marx</strong>, the value <strong>of</strong> a commodity<br />

makes it exchangeable (Hans [105]). From the last sentence it seems that <strong>Marx</strong> is agreeing<br />

<strong>with</strong> Le Trosne and alludes to the same type <strong>of</strong> connection that Le Trosne has developed<br />

between value and exchange value. It must be noted that <strong>Marx</strong> considers exchange value<br />

to be only a superficial manifestation <strong>of</strong> value. <strong>Marx</strong> believes that although value in its<br />

own right is a social relation stemming from production, he describes exchange-value as<br />

form <strong>of</strong> value (Annotations page 76). Also, I think for him value exists independent <strong>of</strong><br />

exchange value <strong>of</strong> a commodity. The exchange value comes about only in the market place<br />

i.e. only through some social relations that govern trading <strong>of</strong> commodities. If a commodity<br />

is produced and consumed <strong>with</strong>out being traded then it still contains value i.e. the congealed<br />

abstract labor inside it. <strong>What</strong> it would not have is an exchange value since it has not been<br />

put up for trading. Le Trosne’s statment on the other hand implies that if commodities are<br />

not traded then they will not contain any value—an argument that <strong>Marx</strong> would not find<br />

palatable. In summary, exchange value comes about due to social relations taking place<br />

on the surface, whereas the value <strong>of</strong> a commoditiy exists due to the social relations that<br />

exist behind the surface phenomena. T<strong>his</strong> is a crucial distinction to <strong>Marx</strong> that Le Trosne’s<br />

statment completely seems to miss or ignore.<br />

Hence, if <strong>Marx</strong> were to rephrase Le Trosne’s statment he probably would have said ‘the<br />

value <strong>of</strong> a commodity exists because <strong>of</strong> the congealed abstract labour present inside it.’ or<br />

‘the value <strong>of</strong> a commodity makes it exchangeable.’<br />

Hans: Very good, just one quibble: if the product is never traded but consumed by the producer then it is not<br />

a commodity and has no value. The difference between <strong>Marx</strong> and Le Trosne is whether value is produced in<br />

production (<strong>Marx</strong>) or in the market (Le Trosne).<br />

Message [131] referenced by [208] and [263]. Next Message by Daru is [256].<br />

[147] Caroline: <strong>What</strong> exactly is being traded for t<strong>his</strong> Thing. A thing, or a commodity,<br />

in Le Trosne’s view is only valuable in relation to other commodities. <strong>Marx</strong> would probably<br />

dissect Le Trosne’s proposition, and disagree <strong>with</strong> part <strong>of</strong> it, because there are more values<br />

in a commodity than just its “exchange-proportions <strong>with</strong> other things” (Hans’ annotations,<br />

pg. 22).<br />

Le Trosne does not specify what is actually being traded. <strong>What</strong> does one consumer<br />

see in a commodity that drives them to exchange or purchase it? “The value <strong>of</strong> a thing<br />

consists in its exchange-proportions,” but t<strong>his</strong> begs for more interpretation. <strong>Marx</strong> would<br />

probably argue that the exchange proportions <strong>of</strong> a thing, or commodity, consists <strong>of</strong> usevalues,<br />

as well as its exchange values. They are interrelated, as <strong>Marx</strong> says in question 75 <strong>of</strong><br />

the annotations: “exchange-relations are characterized by an abstraction from use-values...if<br />

use-value is in high demand,...then it commands a higher exchange-value.” Also, on page 18<br />

<strong>of</strong> the annotations, there are explanations as to how they are related, but also independent in

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!