22.08.2013 Views

Chapter 14 Appendix: Free Trade, Financial Globalization, and Growth

Chapter 14 Appendix: Free Trade, Financial Globalization, and Growth

Chapter 14 Appendix: Free Trade, Financial Globalization, and Growth

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Chapter</strong> <strong>14</strong><br />

<strong>Appendix</strong><br />

<strong>Free</strong> <strong>Trade</strong>, <strong>Financial</strong> <strong>Globalization</strong>,<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>Growth</strong><br />

Although we have seen in the chapter that financial development spurs economic<br />

growth, implementing financial development is by no means easy. In this appendix, we<br />

show how free trade <strong>and</strong> financial globalization help promote financial development<br />

<strong>and</strong> hence economic growth.<br />

<strong>Free</strong> <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Financial</strong> Development<br />

In your principles of economics course, you probably discussed the concept of comparative<br />

advantage, which provided a strong argument for why free trade, the opening up<br />

of domestic markets to goods <strong>and</strong> services from abroad, raises the st<strong>and</strong>ard of living in<br />

an economy. <strong>Free</strong> trade, however, can also lead to institutional reforms that raise the<br />

rate of economic growth. To see why, we need to ask an important question: why do<br />

countries not adopt institutional frameworks that promote financial development <strong>and</strong><br />

economic growth? After all, it is in the best interest of a country to promote high economic<br />

growth.<br />

Special Interests <strong>and</strong> <strong>Financial</strong> Repression<br />

The benefits of financial development are enjoyed by numerous sectors of the population,<br />

while the costs are borne by narrower special-interest groups. The benefits of an<br />

efficient financial system are spread widely: to the young couple who can now buy a<br />

house with the help of a mortgage, to the new car owner who is able to finance its purchase<br />

with an auto loan, to the entrepreneur who can get capital to start her new business,<br />

<strong>and</strong> to the corporation that can finance its investment in a new manufacturing<br />

1


2 CHAPTER <strong>14</strong> APPENDIX<br />

plant. On the other side, there are relatively few, powerful, concentrated special-interest<br />

groups who lose from financial development <strong>and</strong> so try to slow its progress with<br />

financial repression. 1<br />

GOVERNMENT. Government is often the primary source of financial repression.<br />

Although strong property rights are a crucial element in financial development, they<br />

severely constrain a government’s ability to expropriate property <strong>and</strong> ideas whenever it<br />

wants to profit from them. Governments also have strong incentives to establish <strong>and</strong><br />

support state-owned banks through which politicians <strong>and</strong> government officials can<br />

channel funds to themselves, their families, their cronies, <strong>and</strong> businesses that support<br />

their political campaigns.<br />

REPRESSIVE INCUMBENTS. Incumbents, entrenched, rich elites who own businesses<br />

that are threatened by competitive, free markets, also often support financial<br />

repression. 2 Large, established business firms often finance new investment projects<br />

out of their previous earnings <strong>and</strong> so do not need funds from external sources in the<br />

financial markets. Incumbent financial institutions also have incentives to repress the<br />

financial system because they have little to gain from financial development, <strong>and</strong> frequently<br />

have much to lose. A better-developed financial system will allow new businesses<br />

to access funds that will increase competition <strong>and</strong> thus lower the incumbents’<br />

profits. They are therefore likely to oppose institutional reform that promotes financial<br />

development.<br />

How <strong>Free</strong> <strong>Trade</strong> Fosters <strong>Financial</strong> Development <strong>and</strong><br />

Economic <strong>Growth</strong><br />

Allowing entry of foreign goods <strong>and</strong> services into an economy produces a more competitive<br />

environment that will drive down the revenue of incumbent firms <strong>and</strong> reduce<br />

their profits, requiring them to seek out external sources of finance. These sources of<br />

finance will be available only if the financial system has the wherewithal to solve asymmetric<br />

information problems. As a result, incumbent firms <strong>and</strong> their rich, elite owners<br />

will now have incentives to support the necessary institutional reforms to make the<br />

financial system work better. In turn, the resulting reforms will increase the size of the<br />

financial sector <strong>and</strong> will foster economic growth. <strong>Free</strong> trade can therefore be an important<br />

force that stimulates economic growth.<br />

The Evidence: <strong>Free</strong> <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>and</strong> Economic <strong>Growth</strong><br />

A well-known study by Andrew Warner of the Millennium Challenge Corporation <strong>and</strong><br />

Jeffrey Sachs of Columbia University found that developed economies that were open to<br />

trade grew at a 1.6% higher rate than ones that were closed to trade. 3 For developing countries,<br />

the difference was even larger, 3.8%. However, there is a possibility that causation<br />

1For further discussion of why financial repression occurs, see Frederic S. Mishkin, The Next Great<br />

<strong>Globalization</strong>: How Disadvantaged Nations Can Harness Their <strong>Financial</strong> Systems to Get Rich (Princeton, NJ:<br />

Princeton University, 2006).<br />

2Raghuram Rajan <strong>and</strong> Luigi Zingales, Saving Capitalism from the Capitalists: Unleashing the Power of <strong>Financial</strong><br />

Markets to Create Wealth <strong>and</strong> Spread Opportunity (New York: Crown Business, 2003).<br />

3Jeffrey D. Sachs <strong>and</strong> Andrew Warner, “Economic Reform <strong>and</strong> the Process of Global Integration,” Brookings<br />

Papers on Economic Activity (1995): 1–95.


FREE TRADE, FINANCIAL GLOBALIZATION, AND GROWTH 3<br />

might run from faster growth to trade openness, rather than the other way around.<br />

Alternatively, opening up to trade might occur at the same time as other institutional<br />

reforms, <strong>and</strong> these other reforms are what might have stimulated economic growth.<br />

In a later study, Jeffrey Frankel <strong>and</strong> David Romer of the University of California at<br />

Berkeley used geography to help evaluate whether causality actually runs from trade to<br />

higher growth, <strong>and</strong> they found that it does. 4 The location of a country affects the<br />

amount of trade because countries that are isolated geographically (like New Zeal<strong>and</strong>)<br />

or are l<strong>and</strong>locked <strong>and</strong> have very few natural seaports (like Bolivia) have less trade<br />

because transportation costs for goods are higher. These countries have less trade <strong>and</strong><br />

also grow slower than other countries. Because the location of a country is surely<br />

exogenous—where a country is located is not a choice—this evidence suggests that<br />

causality indeed runs from trade to growth. Their study concludes that a rise of one percentage<br />

point in the ratio of trade to GDP raises income per person by one-half of a percentage<br />

point.<br />

In addition, research has linked greater openness to trade to a larger financial sector<br />

<strong>and</strong> the increased competition from foreigners that stimulates domestic firms to become<br />

more productive in order to survive. 5 The evidence is strongly supportive of free trade<br />

being good for economic growth.<br />

<strong>Financial</strong> <strong>Globalization</strong> <strong>and</strong> Economic <strong>Growth</strong><br />

The benefits of globalization of trade in goods <strong>and</strong> services are not a controversial subject<br />

among economists (although they are among the general public). One of the few things<br />

economists agree on is that the globalization of international trade, in which markets are<br />

opened to flows of foreign goods <strong>and</strong> services, is desirable. <strong>Financial</strong> globalization,<br />

the opening of markets to flows of foreign capital (also referred to as capital account<br />

liberalization) is, however, highly controversial even among economists.<br />

<strong>Financial</strong> globalization can encourage financial development <strong>and</strong> economic growth<br />

by directly improving the way financial markets work. Indirectly, as occurs with free<br />

trade, financial globalization changes the distribution of economic power <strong>and</strong> increases<br />

incentives for financial development.<br />

Direct Benefits<br />

When foreign financial institutions enter a country, domestic financial institutions have<br />

to become more efficient in order to survive, which typically happens. 6 Foreign financial<br />

institutions bring “best practices” to domestic financial markets based on expertise<br />

4Jeffrey A. Frankel <strong>and</strong> David Romer, “Does <strong>Trade</strong> Cause <strong>Growth</strong>?” American Economic Review 89 (June 1999):<br />

379–399.<br />

5Raghuram Rajan <strong>and</strong> Luigi Zingales, “The Great Reversals: The Politics of <strong>Financial</strong> Development in the<br />

20th Century,” Journal of <strong>Financial</strong> Economics 69 (2003): 5–50; <strong>and</strong> H. Svalaeryd <strong>and</strong> J. Vlachos, “Market for Risk<br />

<strong>and</strong> Openness to <strong>Trade</strong>: How Are They Related?” Journal of Public Economics 57 (2002): 364–95.<br />

6For example, see Ross Levine, “Foreign Banks, <strong>Financial</strong> Development <strong>and</strong> Economic <strong>Growth</strong>,” in International<br />

<strong>Financial</strong> Markets: Harmonization versus Competition, ed. Claude E. Barfield (Washington, D.C.: AEI Press, 1996); Stijn<br />

Claessens et al., “The Role of Foreign Banks in Domestic Banking Systems,” in The Internationalization of <strong>Financial</strong><br />

Services: Issues <strong>and</strong> Lessons for Developing Countries, eds. Stijn Claessens <strong>and</strong> Marion Jansen (Boston: Kluwer<br />

Academic, 2000); <strong>and</strong> Stijn Claessens, Asli Demirguc-Kunt <strong>and</strong> Harry Huizinga., “How Does Foreign Bank Entry<br />

Affect Domestic Banking Markets,” Journal of Banking <strong>and</strong> Finance 25 (2001): 891–911.


4 CHAPTER <strong>14</strong> APPENDIX<br />

they have gained from their past experience, <strong>and</strong> they are also likely to promote technology<br />

transfer to domestic financial institutions. Entry of foreign financial institutions helps<br />

improve domestic prudential regulation <strong>and</strong> supervision. Government supervisors are<br />

now able to see the risk management practices that have been successfully used in foreign<br />

institutions <strong>and</strong> to insist that they be adopted by domestic institutions.<br />

<strong>Financial</strong> globalization has additional direct benefits for domestic financial markets.<br />

Allowing foreign capital to freely enter domestic financial markets increases the availability<br />

of funds, which in turn increases liquidity <strong>and</strong> lowers the cost of borrowing, stimulating<br />

investment <strong>and</strong> economic growth. This cycle has happened as countries have opened up<br />

their stock markets to foreign capital, as documented in a study by Peter Blair Henry, now<br />

of New York University. On average, dividend yields (the amount of dividends relative to<br />

the price of shares of stock) fall by 2.4 percentage points, the growth rate of investment<br />

increases by 1.1 percentage points, <strong>and</strong> the growth rate of output per worker increases by<br />

2.3 percentage points. These results prompted Henry to state that “the increasingly popular<br />

view that capital account liberalization brings no real benefits seems untenable.” 7<br />

Indirect Benefits<br />

Opening up to foreign capital <strong>and</strong> foreign financial institutions is a strong force for institutional<br />

reforms that promotes financial development. When domestic businesses can<br />

borrow from abroad or from foreign financial institutions that establish affiliates in the<br />

less-developed country, domestic financial institutions will start to lose many of their old<br />

customers. To stay in business, they will have to seek out new customers <strong>and</strong> lend to them<br />

profitably. They will need the information to screen out the good credit risks from the bad<br />

<strong>and</strong> to monitor borrowers to make sure they do not take on excessive risk. Domestic<br />

financial institutions will thus have incentives to encourage politicians to adopt institutional<br />

reforms, such as better accounting st<strong>and</strong>ards <strong>and</strong> disclosure requirements, that will<br />

make it easier for them to acquire the information that they need to make profitable loans.<br />

The institutions will also see the need to improve the legal system so they can enforce<br />

restrictive covenants or be able to take title to collateral if a borrower defaults. With globalization,<br />

domestic financial institutions will support legal reform that will help them<br />

make profits <strong>and</strong> also strengthen the property rights that directly encourage investment.<br />

Will <strong>Financial</strong> <strong>Globalization</strong> Always Work?<br />

Given the benefits of financial globalization, it seems as though opening up domestic<br />

financial markets to international capital should have an unambiguously positive<br />

impact on economic growth <strong>and</strong> the reduction of poverty. However, evidence from<br />

aggregate data on the benefits of financial globalization is mixed: there is no clear-cut<br />

relationship between international financial openness <strong>and</strong> economic growth. 8<br />

7Peter Blair Henry, “Capital Account Liberalization, the Cost of Capital <strong>and</strong> Economic <strong>Growth</strong>,” American<br />

Economic Review 93 (2003): 91–96.<br />

8For example, see the surveys in Ross Levine, “<strong>Financial</strong> Development <strong>and</strong> Economic <strong>Growth</strong>: Views <strong>and</strong><br />

Agenda,” Journal of Economic Literature 35 (1997): 688–672; Barry Eichengreen, “Capital Account<br />

Liberalization: What Do Cross-Country Studies Tell Us?” World Bank Economic Review 15 (2001): 341–365;<br />

Stanley Fischer, “<strong>Globalization</strong> <strong>and</strong> Its Challenges,” American Economic Review 93 (2003): 1–30; Hali J. Edison,<br />

Michael W. Klein, Luca Antonio Ricci, <strong>and</strong> Torsten Slok, “Capital Account Liberalization <strong>and</strong> Economic<br />

Performance: Survey <strong>and</strong> Synthesis,” IMF Staff Papers 51, no. 2 (2004): 26–62; <strong>and</strong> Eswar Prasad, Kenneth<br />

Rogoff, Shang-Jin Wei, <strong>and</strong> M. Ayhan Kose, “Effects of <strong>Financial</strong> <strong>Globalization</strong> on Developing Countries:<br />

Some Empirical Evidence.” International Monetary Fund mimeo. (March 2003).


SUMMARY<br />

FREE TRADE, FINANCIAL GLOBALIZATION, AND GROWTH 5<br />

Why doesn’t opening up financial markets always work? Opening up an economy<br />

to international capital flows, particularly if the transition is not managed to prevent<br />

excessive risk taking, can damage the financial system <strong>and</strong> in turn the economy.<br />

Although financial globalization can be a strong force for good, it can also go very<br />

wrong if a country doesn’t manage the process properly. This riskiness makes financial<br />

globalization very controversial.<br />

1. <strong>Free</strong> trade helps promote financial development <strong>and</strong><br />

economic growth by increasing competition <strong>and</strong><br />

driving down the profits of incumbent firms, requiring<br />

them to seek out external sources of finance.<br />

Incumbent firms will now have incentives to support<br />

the necessary institutional reforms to make the<br />

financial system work better, thereby fostering economic<br />

growth.<br />

KEY TERMS<br />

capital account liberalization,<br />

p. 3<br />

financial globalization, p. 3<br />

financial repression, p. 2<br />

REVIEW QUESTIONS AND PROBLEMS<br />

1. What is financial repression? Why does it occur?<br />

2. Who supports financial repression <strong>and</strong> why?<br />

2. <strong>Financial</strong> globalization can encourage financial development<br />

<strong>and</strong> economic growth by directly improving<br />

the way financial markets work <strong>and</strong> also by changing<br />

the distribution of economic power, thereby increasing<br />

incentives for financial development. <strong>Financial</strong><br />

globalization may not be beneficial if it is not managed<br />

to prevent excessive risk taking, which can damage<br />

the financial system <strong>and</strong> in turn the economy.<br />

free trade, p. 1<br />

3. How does free trade promote financial<br />

development?<br />

4. What are the benefits of financial globalization?

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!