01.01.2014 Views

Supreme Court Agenda Setting in a System of Shared Powers Ryan ...

Supreme Court Agenda Setting in a System of Shared Powers Ryan ...

Supreme Court Agenda Setting in a System of Shared Powers Ryan ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

10 The Journal <strong>of</strong> Law, Economics, & Organization. V0 N0<br />

Because the <strong>Court</strong> has taken a status quo policy and made it worse for the political<br />

branches, they will respond with override legislation that sets new policy<br />

somewhere on LR. Because the policy result<strong>in</strong>g from this override would represent<br />

a policy loss for the <strong>Court</strong>—as well as damage to its legitimacy—the<br />

<strong>Court</strong> will deny review to the case. 11<br />

Regime 3 shows a semi-constra<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>Court</strong>. In this regime, the <strong>Court</strong>’s ability<br />

to set policy is dependent on the pivots’ preferred-to sets. Look first at SQ 1 .<br />

Assume that the <strong>Court</strong> is represented by J 1 . In this example, the <strong>Court</strong> could<br />

set policy at its ideal po<strong>in</strong>t because it falls with<strong>in</strong> both pivots’ preferred-to sets<br />

relative to SQ 1 . That is, the <strong>Court</strong>’s new policy would be an improvement for<br />

both the Left and the Right Pivots. Now, however, assume that after personnel<br />

change, the <strong>Court</strong> median is represented by J 2 . If the <strong>Court</strong> tried to set policy<br />

at J 2 , its decision would be vulnerable to a legislative override. To be sure,<br />

sett<strong>in</strong>g policy at J 2 would make the Right Pivot better <strong>of</strong>f. Nevertheless, the<br />

policy shift would be worse for the Left Pivot. In response, the Left Pivot<br />

would propose legislation somewhere on LR that makes it and the Right Pivot<br />

better <strong>of</strong>f than J 2 . Anticipat<strong>in</strong>g this response, the <strong>Court</strong> would simply render<br />

its decision at SQ L 1 ∗ . This is the location <strong>in</strong> policy space that makes R and<br />

J 2 better <strong>of</strong>f, and L no worse <strong>of</strong>f than SQ. Even though the <strong>Court</strong> cannot set<br />

policy at J 2 , its policy decision at SQ L 1 ∗ still reflects a net policy ga<strong>in</strong> for the<br />

<strong>Court</strong>. As such, it would vote to grant review.<br />

Now, assume that the status quo is SQ 2 rather than SQ 1 and that the <strong>Court</strong>’s<br />

median is aga<strong>in</strong> J 1 . The <strong>Court</strong> <strong>in</strong> this scenario would be forced to render a decision<br />

at R. If the <strong>Court</strong> rendered a decision at J 1 , it would, <strong>of</strong> course, improve<br />

policy for the Right Pivot but make a worse policy for the Left Pivot. In response,<br />

the Left Pivot would propose override legislation somewhere on LR.<br />

S<strong>in</strong>ce the legislation L strategically proposes will always be better for R, R<br />

would agree to the override. To avoid this response, the <strong>Court</strong> would be forced<br />

to render a decision on the merits at R. As this is the Right Pivot’s ideal po<strong>in</strong>t,<br />

noth<strong>in</strong>g L proposes would lead R to move policy away from the <strong>Court</strong>’s decision.<br />

The <strong>Court</strong>’s policy, then, survives any override attempt. In the end, while<br />

the <strong>Court</strong> cannot set policy at its ideal po<strong>in</strong>t (either J 1 or J 2 ), the equilibrium<br />

policy it adopts nevertheless will be an improvement for the <strong>Court</strong>. Consequently,<br />

it will grant review to cases <strong>in</strong> this regime.<br />

Regime 4 also shows a semi-constra<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>Court</strong>. Look first at a <strong>Court</strong> whose<br />

median is J 1 . If the <strong>Court</strong> rendered a decision at J 1 , it would make both legislative<br />

pivots worse <strong>of</strong>f than the status quo and they, <strong>in</strong> turn, would pass override<br />

legislation (which could, quite conceivably be worse than the exist<strong>in</strong>g status<br />

quo for the <strong>Court</strong>). 12 The <strong>Court</strong> at J 1 , then, would be constra<strong>in</strong>ed to render a<br />

11. Of course, the <strong>Court</strong> could grant review and set policy just to the right <strong>of</strong> SQ (a po<strong>in</strong>t<br />

with<strong>in</strong> both pivots’ preferred-to sets). While a majority <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Court</strong> is not likely to grant review<br />

<strong>in</strong> this type <strong>of</strong> case because it would make worse policy for them, a m<strong>in</strong>ority <strong>of</strong> justices us<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the Rule <strong>of</strong> Four could force the case on the <strong>Court</strong>’s docket to <strong>in</strong>duce such a shift. Nevertheless,<br />

these four justices would be little assuaged by the grant s<strong>in</strong>ce the <strong>Court</strong> would only shift policy<br />

marg<strong>in</strong>ally. They are not likely to waste their resources on such a trivial policy shift.<br />

12. Even if the policy that results from the override is better for the <strong>Court</strong> than the status quo,

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!