01.01.2014 Views

Supreme Court Agenda Setting in a System of Shared Powers Ryan ...

Supreme Court Agenda Setting in a System of Shared Powers Ryan ...

Supreme Court Agenda Setting in a System of Shared Powers Ryan ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

4 The Journal <strong>of</strong> Law, Economics, & Organization. V0 N0<br />

oppos<strong>in</strong>g review <strong>in</strong>creases (Caldeira and Wright, 1988; Caldeira, Wright and<br />

Zorn, 1999), when the lower courts are <strong>in</strong> conflict over the correct application<br />

or <strong>in</strong>terpretation <strong>of</strong> federal law, and when other important legal considerations<br />

exist.<br />

All <strong>of</strong> these studies have served to further our understand<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> the conditions<br />

under which the <strong>Court</strong> sets its agenda. Nevertheless, they tell us noth<strong>in</strong>g<br />

about whether congressional and executive preferences <strong>in</strong>fluence the manner<br />

<strong>in</strong> which the <strong>Supreme</strong> <strong>Court</strong> sets its agenda. Do congressional and executive<br />

preferences cause the <strong>Supreme</strong> <strong>Court</strong> to decl<strong>in</strong>e to review cases? In what follows,<br />

I address these questions.<br />

3. Expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Strategic SOP <strong>Agenda</strong> <strong>Sett<strong>in</strong>g</strong><br />

Exist<strong>in</strong>g studies which analyze whether the separation <strong>of</strong> powers <strong>in</strong>fluences<br />

the <strong>Court</strong> arrive at mixed conclusions with most, however, f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g no evidence<br />

<strong>of</strong> an SOP effect (Segal, 1997; Segal and Westerland, 2005; Sala and Spriggs,<br />

2004; Spriggs and Hansford, 2001). The few studies that observe an SOP <strong>in</strong>fluence<br />

are limited <strong>in</strong> important ways which make their conclusions somewhat<br />

suspect. For example, Hansford and Damore (2000) f<strong>in</strong>d that some justices<br />

moderate their votes based on legislative preferences. Analyz<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>Court</strong>’s<br />

statutory decisions from 1963 to 1995, the authors f<strong>in</strong>d that justices more conservative<br />

than the president and both judiciary committees cast more liberal<br />

votes than they would <strong>in</strong> a non-SOP context. On the other hand, liberal outlier<br />

justices were no more likely to rule conservatively to avoid legislative rebuke.<br />

These results do not square with the SOP model exam<strong>in</strong>ed however, as the<br />

model asserted that both types <strong>of</strong> outlier justices would behave strategically.<br />

Moreover, the study uses preference estimates for the different branches that<br />

do not scale, limit<strong>in</strong>g the f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs. 3<br />

Spiller and Gely (1992) f<strong>in</strong>d that the <strong>Court</strong> renders more pro-labor decisions<br />

as Congress becomes <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly liberal; yet, the study does not <strong>in</strong>clude the<br />

president as a pivotal actor and relies on ADA scores as proxies <strong>of</strong> legislative<br />

ideology. These scores have been attacked as poor surrogates <strong>of</strong> congressional<br />

preferences (B<strong>in</strong>der, Lawrence and Maltzman, 1999; Snyder, 1992).<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, Harvey and Friedman (2006) f<strong>in</strong>d that the 1994 Republican Revolution,<br />

which provided the <strong>Court</strong> with a friendly Congress, played a key role<br />

<strong>in</strong> the <strong>Court</strong>’s <strong>in</strong>creased proclivity to strike federal laws after 1994. Still, the<br />

substantive impact <strong>of</strong> their SOP variable is weak: The predicted probability<br />

that the <strong>Court</strong> would strike a federal statute <strong>in</strong>creased from 0.00036 <strong>in</strong> 1987 to<br />

0.00137 <strong>in</strong> 2000 as the result <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Court</strong>’s new position between key pivots<br />

<strong>in</strong> Congress. What is more, s<strong>in</strong>ce the study does not <strong>in</strong>clude the president as<br />

a pivotal actor (other than <strong>in</strong> the Filibuster-Veto model), it is unclear whether<br />

these results are the product <strong>of</strong> an artificially small legislative equilibrium. 4<br />

3. Justice ideology is measured as the percent <strong>of</strong> liberal votes a justice cast, while legislative<br />

and executive preferences are coded us<strong>in</strong>g DW-NOMINATE scores (see also Bergara, Richman<br />

and Spiller, 2003).<br />

4. The study is, however, an <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g piece with a unique approach to the separation <strong>of</strong>

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!