01.01.2014 Views

Why are Mexican mayors getting killed by traffickers? The dynamics ...

Why are Mexican mayors getting killed by traffickers? The dynamics ...

Why are Mexican mayors getting killed by traffickers? The dynamics ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Why</strong> <strong>are</strong> <strong>Mexican</strong> <strong>mayors</strong> <strong>getting</strong> <strong>killed</strong> <strong>by</strong> <strong>traffickers</strong>?<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>dynamics</strong> of corruption in illegal-drug markets<br />

Viridiana Rios<br />

Harvard University Department of Government ∗<br />

November 4, 2010<br />

Abstract<br />

This is a paper about how organized crime and politicians interact, and the way in<br />

which political institutions, and market <strong>dynamics</strong> impact this relationship. Recent years<br />

have seen the transformation of <strong>Mexican</strong> drug traffic organizations (DTOs) into highly<br />

violent political actors. Just in the first 9 months of 2010, 12 <strong>mayors</strong> have been <strong>killed</strong><br />

<strong>by</strong> organized crime, a sharp contrast with a history of complete absence of political violence.<br />

I present a formal model of corruption <strong>dynamics</strong> to understand these outcomes and<br />

show that, if <strong>mayors</strong> <strong>are</strong> <strong>getting</strong> kill more is not because <strong>traffickers</strong> <strong>are</strong> more powerful -as<br />

traditional accounts of corruption would argue– but because of (a) political decentralization,<br />

and (b) changes in the structure of the illegal-drug industry (i.e. higher competition,<br />

and a recently open domestic drug market). My conclusions <strong>are</strong> drawn from an extensive<br />

fieldwork in Mexico’s drug war zone.<br />

∗ 1737 Cambridge St; Cambridge, MA 02138; vrios@fas.harvard.edu; Telephone: (617) 997 2471<br />

1


‘Well, first I pray to God every day and at every moment. <strong>The</strong>n, I do not denounce,<br />

I do not see, I do no listen besides, I do not even have the [constitutional] mandate<br />

to prosecute drug <strong>traffickers</strong>! Finally, at my home, I talk to God again 1 ”<br />

Recent years have seen the mutation of <strong>Mexican</strong> organized crime into a politically violent<br />

actor. In 2010 elections, <strong>Mexican</strong> drug <strong>traffickers</strong> made clear that organized crime was not going<br />

to be a simple political spectator anymore. <strong>The</strong>y attempted to change political preferences<br />

<strong>by</strong> prohibiting the press to cover stories or <strong>by</strong> openly funding their favorite candidates; they<br />

tried to reduce electoral turn out via blatant intimidation; they succeeding selecting candidates<br />

either <strong>by</strong> assassinating the opposition, or <strong>by</strong> terrifying politicians until they withdraw from the<br />

competition. If the previous actions were not effective, they just <strong>killed</strong> politicians. Political<br />

violence became the norm. In 2010, 26 <strong>mayors</strong> were assassinated, at least 126 more were death<br />

threatened, 8 journalists were <strong>killed</strong> or disappe<strong>are</strong>d, and 411 policemen were murdered. Some<br />

political parties were unable to compete in local elections because of “a lack of braveness (El<br />

Universal 2010)” of the potential candidates. Complete towns remained without de facto authorities,<br />

as <strong>mayors</strong> and policemen frequently ran out of office, terrified.<br />

Yet, just recently <strong>Mexican</strong> drug traffic organizations (DTOs) were commonly referred as the<br />

counter-case of political Colombian DTOs. Mexico’s organized crime was notoriously disinterested<br />

in politics (Resa Nesateres, 2006). Under this traditional narrative, <strong>Mexican</strong> kingpins<br />

were portrayed as unsophisticated but clever dealers who knew what was good for business<br />

(Bunker and Sullivan 2001). <strong>The</strong>y did not wanted people fighting in the streets, neither did<br />

they wanted to take visible positions in politics; they were there for the money. <strong>Mexican</strong>s were<br />

not politically involved criminals, they were businessman.<br />

In this paper, I provide an explanation for the abrupt change in the relationship between<br />

criminals and politicians. This is a paper about how organized crime and politicians interact.<br />

I challenge the traditional “silver-or-lead” approach to understand the political/criminal nexus<br />

–according to which as <strong>traffickers</strong> become more powerful, they also become more politically<br />

visible, and they increasingly force politicians to decide between accepting bribes (silver), and<br />

being assassinated (lead). I show that criminals’ political violence does not necessarily come<br />

from an increase in the power of <strong>traffickers</strong> versus politicians. My story is able to explain why<br />

Mexico’s corruption outcomes have changed even if, as I show, <strong>traffickers</strong> have actually become<br />

weaker.<br />

<strong>The</strong> standard Silver-or-bribe narrative fails to comprehend corruption outcomes because it<br />

does not disentangle the factors that determine corruption supply versus those that determine<br />

corruption demand. Corruption mechanics, I argue, <strong>are</strong> a bargaining game between a corruption<br />

supplier (i.e. politicians willing/able to be corrupt) and a corruption demander (i.e. organized<br />

1 Mayor of Pueblo Nuevo, Durango, when asked what he do to keep himself alive (Abrego 2010)<br />

2


crime willing/able to corrupt) in which supply is largely determined <strong>by</strong> institutional factors,<br />

and demand is determined <strong>by</strong> the industrial organization of illegal-drug markets. My main<br />

argument is that the mechanics of corruption can only be understood if we analyze government<br />

institutions (i.e. degree of centralization), and illegal-drug markets (i.e. degree of competition<br />

and type of targeted market). Institutions and Illegal-drug markets determine corruption supply<br />

and demand, and explain why corruption outcomes have changed.<br />

<strong>The</strong> paper is divided in six main sections. I begin <strong>by</strong> briefly explaining why we would ever<br />

expect to have corruption markets; this is to say, why <strong>traffickers</strong> would ever c<strong>are</strong> about bargaining<br />

with politicians instead of just disintegrating the state, or becoming the state themselves. A<br />

second section presents a simple bargaining model of corruption <strong>dynamics</strong>, and argues in favor of<br />

analyze corruption demand and corruption supply separately. A third section presents a model<br />

which departs from previous literature (i.e. Silvel-or-lead approaches). I analyze the strategies<br />

of corruption demanders with particular attention to the complexities of killing (i.e. violence is<br />

costly, uncertain, and has a signaling value). I follow <strong>by</strong> analyzing the strategies available for<br />

corruption suppliers noting that a weak state is not always the preferred outcome for bribers.<br />

A fourth presents some comparative statics to show that sometimes bribing more is less, not<br />

more expensive for <strong>traffickers</strong>; that sometimes politicians want small bribes; that even weak<br />

<strong>traffickers</strong> can extort powerful states, and that politicians not always take a decision between<br />

being bribed or <strong>killed</strong>. Killing can complement bribing, and bribes/killing may be completely<br />

absent. A final interesting result refers to the quality of politicians. In a corrupt environment,<br />

all available politicians will be corrupt unless the state has the ability to extort criminals. To<br />

be completely virtuous, a politician needs to be capable of being completely corrupt. A fifth<br />

section uses the previous model to explain why corruption outcomes in Mexico have changed.<br />

I show that the recent emergence of political violence in Mexico can only be understood <strong>by</strong><br />

analyzing changes in the determinants of (a) corruption supply (i.e. political institutions), and<br />

(b) corruption demand (i.e. illegal-markets structure). Finally, a sixth section concludes.<br />

1 <strong>The</strong> utility of the political-criminal nexus<br />

<strong>The</strong> first question to make when trying to understand why <strong>Mexican</strong> <strong>traffickers</strong> have become<br />

more politically violent over time is why, in the first place, would <strong>traffickers</strong> ever prefer to make<br />

deals with politicians, instead of just being violent, taking over the state and running it themselves.<br />

Relating to politicians is costly and uncertain. Bribing requires the establishment of a<br />

millionaire secret pact between two parts –two criminal parts of obviously dubious principles–<br />

without any legal institution to appeal in case of default. Furthermore, the terms of the contract<br />

<strong>are</strong> generally agreed verbally which allows for misinterpretations and cheating. It is not trivial<br />

thus, to analyze when and why would an DTO ever prefer to bargain with politicians. <strong>Why</strong><br />

would <strong>traffickers</strong> ever demand corruption?<br />

3


Current academic literature understands the relationship between criminals and government<br />

as an evolutionary phenomenon. Criminals have as one of their main interests to control the<br />

state in order to facilitate the conduction of their illegal business. Yet, in its first stages, when<br />

crime is less pervasive, profitable and organized, controlling the state is impossible for DTOs.<br />

It is only when DTOs “evolve” and become more powerful, that they <strong>are</strong> able to impose their<br />

will into a relatively weaker state (Baylor and Godson 2001, pg 14-15). At the peak of their<br />

evolution, criminal organizations become parallel states (Bunker and Sullivan 2010) and supply<br />

services –such as protection– that the state is not able to provide. In short, literature argues<br />

that <strong>traffickers</strong> demand corruption only when they <strong>are</strong> not powerful enough as to become the<br />

government themselves.<br />

This understanding of the political/criminal nexus however has failed to take in consideration<br />

many other reasons why, I argue, even a highly powerful DTO may prefer to have a state<br />

(rather than being the state themselves). A state benefits <strong>traffickers</strong> as it ensures larger and<br />

cheaper trade.<br />

A legitimate state is useful for <strong>traffickers</strong> as it (a) provides a platform of legal trade that<br />

is used <strong>by</strong> <strong>traffickers</strong> to smuggle their products, and (b) a series of public goods and positive<br />

externalities, such as a structure of law enforcement and infrastructure that <strong>traffickers</strong> can use<br />

for their own advantage. A state is required for the survival of any type of business, illegal ones<br />

included. Ironically, even criminals need politicians.<br />

First, having a legitimate state secures an stable amount of commercial transactions and<br />

trade. Legal trade facilitates illegal trade because a large sh<strong>are</strong> of illegal products cross borders<br />

camouflaged as legal cargo. Actually, increments in US-Mexico trade during the late nineties<br />

as a result of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) proved to be a blessing<br />

for <strong>Mexican</strong> DTOs. If Mexico became the main illegal-drug exporter into the US is precisely<br />

because the country became an increasingly important commercial partner for the US 2 . Drug<br />

lords love trade, and traders love governments. <strong>The</strong> circle is closed.<br />

Furthermore, as trade increases, the burden of inspection increases exponentially. About 40<br />

percent of all trade between Mexico and the US crosses via Nuevo L<strong>are</strong>do, a small city at the<br />

border of Texas (INEGI 2005), that is thousands of trucks per day. <strong>Mexican</strong> migration officers<br />

2 During the nineties, <strong>Mexican</strong> DTOs were well aw<strong>are</strong> of the value that Mexico would acquire if NAFTA was<br />

signed. <strong>The</strong>y saw the trade bonanza approaching. As soon as the trade agreement was signed in 1994, some of<br />

them hired migration experts to advice them on which were the best type of cargo for introducing their products<br />

into the US (Blancornelas 2001). Advisors were necessary because for health and other considerations, some<br />

cargos were going to be (and currently <strong>are</strong>) inspected less c<strong>are</strong>fully than others (e.g. perishable goods cross the<br />

border faster than say, electronics). Knowing the probability of inspection in advance was a de facto reduction<br />

in transportation costs for DTOs.<br />

4


have neither the capability, nor the resources, to inspect all cargos. Inspecting all of them will<br />

slow down trade and result in millionaire losses. As Mr. (XX- confidential), director of customs<br />

at L<strong>are</strong>do told me: “sometimes US inspectors seize drugs in cargos that we had just let in. We<br />

<strong>are</strong> not doing this on purpose, as they think, it is just that we can only inspect some of the<br />

cargos. We cannot do more than that. 3 ”<br />

Axiom 1a: Illegal profits (M) increase in legal trade<br />

Note that the expected profitability of illegal business is a necessary but not sufficient condition<br />

for corruption markets to emerge. Very profitable territories, with a healthy and prosperous<br />

legal trade, may not sh<strong>are</strong> the institutional and structural factors required for a corruption demand/supply<br />

to exist. Most South American countries could be fertile territory for <strong>traffickers</strong><br />

and yet, DTOs have largely been confined to a bunch of countries (Colombia, Mexico, Peru and<br />

Bolivia). It is only in these countries where institutions allow politicians to supply corruption,<br />

and <strong>traffickers</strong> find politicians useful enough as to demand their participation.<br />

Axiom 1b: M > 0 is a necessary but not sufficient condition for trafficking to exist.<br />

A second reason why <strong>traffickers</strong> prefer to have a state is that a state provides public goods<br />

–such as highways, airports, ports– that traders (both legal and illegal) need to perform their<br />

operations. On the absence of a government, <strong>traffickers</strong> would have to take all of these costly<br />

operations in their hands. Peru is an example. When in the early nineties <strong>traffickers</strong> started<br />

using Peru as a drug production paradise, DTOs had to invest large amounts of money into<br />

developing transportation systems and urban infrastructure (Lupsha 1995). That was certainly<br />

not a good deal but nothing could be done given the de facto absence of Peruvian state.<br />

That even very strong drug trafficking organizations need a state is not a secret; for a proof,<br />

Haiti. When increments in law enforcement reduced the ability of Colombian DTOs to do<br />

business, the most immediate and logical action to take was to reallocate operations in the<br />

Caribbean. Back then, the most important drug corridor took drugs from Colombia, transporting<br />

them via maritime, to introduce them into the US using Miami. Haiti, with a premier<br />

location in the Caribbean, was the natural choice. Traffickers though, soon realized that Haiti<br />

was not going to work. Haiti’s state was too weak, chaotic and uncertain, even for illegal business.<br />

Government instability made bribe agreements to be short-lived, and required periodic<br />

and burdensome renegotiations between DTOs and authorities. Traffickers quickly moved their<br />

operations to Mexico and Peru. Traffickers as businessmen, value binding contracts and strong<br />

3 Mexico has the capacity to inspect only 10% of all cargos that cross into the US. <strong>The</strong> numbers for <strong>traffickers</strong><br />

could not be better. Given the probability of inspection, seizure is just internalized as a cost of production. <strong>The</strong><br />

price of cocaine at least doubles at the moment that it leaves Mexico and touches American territory (RAND<br />

2010). Even if <strong>Mexican</strong> DTOs smuggled drugs without any strategic consideration -say, <strong>by</strong> placing drugs in<br />

every single cargo crossing into the US–, <strong>traffickers</strong> would still make significant profits.<br />

5


states which can central-enforce and provide public services.<br />

In short, because legal trade increases illegal profits, even very powerful DTOs may find it<br />

harmful to dismantel the state and/or to substitute it <strong>by</strong> a parallel criminal state. Actually,<br />

the best scenario for DTOs is one in which they do not have to take the cumbersome and<br />

overly public task of ruling a country themselves. Traffickers prefer to outsource politics to a<br />

sufficiently strong and centralized government that will ensure the survival of illegal businesses.<br />

<strong>The</strong> paradox of the political/criminal nexus is a simple but powerful one: having a state reduces<br />

operational costs for drug <strong>traffickers</strong> (e.g. provides infrastructure, and increase legal trade) but<br />

also weakens <strong>traffickers</strong> because dealing with the state may entail non-trivial monetary costs<br />

(i.e. bribes).<br />

Lemma 1: Organized crime (i.e. a group of drug <strong>traffickers</strong> (N)) prefers to have a legitimate<br />

state (i.e. a group of politicians (A)) than to become the state, independently its relative<br />

strength (P n ) versus that of the state (P a ).<br />

Given Lemma 1, a question remains as to which would be the mechanism used <strong>by</strong> criminals<br />

and politicians to interact. In the following section, I introduce the traditional way in which the<br />

relationship between politicians and <strong>traffickers</strong> has been understood <strong>by</strong> the literature (“Silveror-lead”<br />

argument).<br />

2 Corruption mechanics: a bargain game between criminals<br />

and politics<br />

<strong>The</strong> political/criminal nexus between organized crime and politicians has so far being understood<br />

as a very straightforward exercise described <strong>by</strong> the “silver-or-lead” dichotomy. Those<br />

politicians ruling in <strong>are</strong>as of interests for <strong>traffickers</strong> have to decide between accepting bribes<br />

(silver) and <strong>getting</strong> <strong>killed</strong> (lead). According to this narrative, bribes <strong>are</strong> determined <strong>by</strong> how<br />

costly corruption is for politicians, as well as <strong>by</strong> the relative power of <strong>traffickers</strong> versus the state<br />

(Bo etal 2006). <strong>The</strong> price of a bribe thus is the outcome of a rational calculation.<br />

<strong>The</strong> price of bribes is determined <strong>by</strong> the relative power of the state versus <strong>traffickers</strong>. As<br />

a government becomes more powerful (i.e. able to enforce law), its ability to extract <strong>traffickers</strong>’<br />

profits via bribes increases. On one side of the spectrum, a powerful government extorts<br />

<strong>traffickers</strong> keeping most of the illegal profits for itself. Such would be the case of Montesinos at<br />

Peru, and the Communist Party at China. On the other side, <strong>traffickers</strong> retain almost all profits<br />

for themselves with small –or non-existent– bribes for authorities. Such would be the world of<br />

trafficker organizations that have managed to work in a virtual autonomy from the state, such<br />

6


as FARC.<br />

Definition 1: Corruption is a bargaining game in which N and A agree on the price of a<br />

bribe (b).<br />

Fixing the price of a bribe is not a trivial exercise. As an analysis of corruption <strong>dynamics</strong> in<br />

Mexico shows, several mechanisms may be used to determine the price of bribes. Back in the<br />

late eighties, the leadership of the notoriously corrupt Federal Direction of Security (Direccion<br />

Federal de Seguridad, DFS) –the main institution for prosecuting DTO’s members– used to<br />

sell positions inside the institution using auctions. <strong>The</strong> positions located in the most valuable<br />

points for DTOs were priced the highest because such positions gave <strong>traffickers</strong> less bargaining<br />

power to set the price of the bribe. As expected, the price of bribes was determined (as it still<br />

is) <strong>by</strong> how much politicians could hurt, or help DTOs.<br />

Bribes thus have a large variance. In perhaps one of the most scandalous cases of corruption<br />

in Mexico, it was discovered that Ju<strong>are</strong>z DTO operated in Cancun under the protection of the<br />

governor, Mario Villanueva. <strong>The</strong> governor was arrested in 2001, and extradited to the US in<br />

2007 after he acknowledged accepting millions of dollars in kickbacks and bribes (Morris 2010).<br />

In 2007, another corruption scandal detonated in Cancun. This time the director of Cancun<br />

airport was accused of accepting a BMW (plus 45 thousand dollars) per each flight loaded with<br />

cocaine that was allowed to land (Gomez 2010). <strong>The</strong> price of bribes followed a clear trend:<br />

Governors got million of dollars, airport directors only BMWs.<br />

Axiom 2: b decreases in P n and increases in P a .<br />

In this section, I defined the mechanics of drug trafficking corruption as a bargaining game<br />

in which politicians and criminals agree on the price of a bribe. Until now, my definition follows<br />

the traditional Silver-and-Lead narrative. <strong>The</strong> final price of the bribe is determined <strong>by</strong> the<br />

relative power of the politicians and <strong>traffickers</strong> and is a non-trivial bargaining exercise. <strong>The</strong> two<br />

following sections depart from the Silver-or-lead narrative <strong>by</strong> making an explicit differentiation<br />

between corruption demand and supply. I draw upon some basic, logic axioms to present an<br />

enriched understanding of the political/criminal nexus.<br />

3 Corruption demand and supply<br />

<strong>The</strong> mechanics of corruption can be better grasped <strong>by</strong> analyzing first, the strategies available<br />

for corruption demanders (bribers, <strong>traffickers</strong>), and then those available for corruption suppliers<br />

(bribees, politicians).<br />

7


3.1 Demand side: Bribing, threatening or killing<br />

Definition 2: N decides between paying b, and exerting political violence (k) (i.e. killing A)<br />

<strong>The</strong> traditional Silver-and-Lead narrative understands killing as a substitute for bribing, and<br />

predicts violence would be more common as <strong>traffickers</strong> become relatively more powerful than the<br />

state. When <strong>traffickers</strong> <strong>are</strong> powerful enough as to posses a system capable of killing politicians,<br />

and state is weak enough as to be unable to enforce law against assassins, costly bribes will be<br />

substituted <strong>by</strong> killings. Political violence thus is a function of criminals’ power. As the relative<br />

power of the state versus DTOs diminishes, organized crime is supposed to become more violent<br />

(Godson 2003; Baylor and Pimentel (2001)) not only because (a) DTOs have the technology<br />

to kill politicians but because (b) a weak state cannot stop crime organizations from fighting<br />

among themselves. Under this logic, it is the state the one who can keep violence controlled;<br />

an “unleashed” crime is always bloody.<br />

In Mexico, the standard story argues, the arrival of opposition to power undermined the<br />

ability of the government to keep corruption agreements between the hegemonic ruling party<br />

(Institutional Revolutionary Party, PRI Partido Revolucionario Institucional) and criminal organizations.<br />

When the government of Vicente Fox, an opposition leader from the National<br />

Action Party (PAN Partido Accion Nacional) took office in 2000, it lacked of the expertise,<br />

power and/or networks to force criminals to conduct their business in peace. By then, the PRI<br />

had held power for more than seventy years, period at which it kept a pax mafiosa <strong>by</strong> extorting<br />

criminal organizations (Astorga 2006, Mercurio 2006). When <strong>Mexican</strong> DTOs saw themselves<br />

free from PRI supervision, violence exploited (Ravelo 2001, Gomez 1999).<br />

Preferences for violence though, I argue, <strong>are</strong> much more subtle than the traditional narrative<br />

argues. Violence is no free lunch. Three things have to be considered: (a) Killing is not always<br />

cheaper than bribing, even for powerful <strong>traffickers</strong>; (b) criminals do not always find it attractive<br />

to fight violently between each other; and (c) criminals cannot commit to kill with complete<br />

certain, they can only commit to try (very hard) to kill.<br />

Indeed, the balance of power between the state and <strong>traffickers</strong> matters for violence. Killing<br />

is more common when such action is expected to cause less negative consequences. As Alfredo<br />

Corchado, chief of the <strong>Mexican</strong> Buro from the Dallas Morning, and one of the most important<br />

reporters of drug trafficking activities in Mexico, told me when I asked him what measures he<br />

took to reduce his chances to be assassinated: “I make sure my batch from the Dallas is very<br />

visible, they would not d<strong>are</strong> to kill a gringo, it would be too dangerous.” Being a first generation<br />

<strong>Mexican</strong> American though, he joked: “the good news is that I am a gringo reporter, the bad<br />

one is that nobody could tell (Corchado 2009).” Alfredo is right. Traffickers have not d<strong>are</strong><br />

to kill a foreign reporter, but have <strong>killed</strong> 11 <strong>Mexican</strong> reporters, and disappe<strong>are</strong>d 7 more since<br />

2007. <strong>The</strong>y also target more local media than higher-profile national media. Only 4 out of the<br />

8


18 cases of murder/disappearance were journalist working for the national media. “Freedom of<br />

press can only be secured at the federal level; we local reporters do not have the international<br />

exposure as to affect [<strong>traffickers</strong>]. We just listen to them [<strong>traffickers</strong>] and comply. Who c<strong>are</strong><br />

about us? We <strong>are</strong> too little” accurately said Mr. (XX -confidential) director of a local in one of<br />

the most important cities located at the US-Mexico border.<br />

However, even powerful criminal organizations may find political assassinations unattractive.<br />

First, killing politicians is costly negotiations <strong>are</strong> costly themselves. After an assassination, all<br />

of the previous agreements, understandings and networks done with the defunct politician have<br />

to be redone with the new authority. In an illegal business –full of secrecy and where money<br />

laundering is inherently difficult– <strong>getting</strong> the cash and daring to expose in public to deal directly<br />

with politicians (i.e. sending messages, visit them at their offices, or at their houses) is<br />

not trivial. Making an agreement may also require several meetings over time, each one delaying<br />

a bit more the continuation of business as usual.<br />

Second, general violence between criminal organizations is also costly because the process of<br />

employee substitution is problematic. At the base of the organization, defunct petty <strong>traffickers</strong><br />

<strong>are</strong> substituted for new ones rapidly, but these ones normally lack of the expertise to keep running<br />

the business as usual. At the top of the organization, substituting defunct elite <strong>traffickers</strong><br />

is even more Challenging. Succession is never clear-cut established and normally causes intense<br />

internal fights. This is well exemplified at current Mexico’s drug war. <strong>The</strong> assassination of<br />

important drug lords, such as Beltran Leyva in 2009, and the capture of others, such as La<br />

Barbie in 2010 (I consider capture a de facto equivalent to death), have generated important<br />

spikes in violence because their successors have fought between each other.<br />

Axiom 3: Negotiating b is costly.<br />

One final reason why killing is costly for <strong>traffickers</strong> is that it is more uncertain than bribing.<br />

A trafficker can commit to bribe. If he offers a bribe in exchange for a service, the bribe will<br />

be paid unless the trafficker himself decides not to. <strong>The</strong> trafficker controls bribes. A trafficker<br />

though cannot commit to kill. Even if the trafficker decides that killing is the best strategy to<br />

follow, killing is difficult. It requires planning and it is always subject to in-the-field mistakes.<br />

Traffickers cannot entirely control who dies and lives. <strong>The</strong>y can only try (very hard) to kill but<br />

assassinations can always get it wrong.<br />

Actually, evidence demonstrates that mistakes in assassinations ordered <strong>by</strong> <strong>Mexican</strong> <strong>traffickers</strong><br />

<strong>are</strong> quite common. Perhaps, the most important one happened in 1993 when the Archbishop<br />

Juan J. Posadas was assassinated <strong>by</strong> the Tijuana DTO. He was mistakenly identified as a drug<br />

lord from the competing Sinaloa DTO. His assassination brought an important increase in<br />

federal enforcement. <strong>The</strong> <strong>Mexican</strong> government set a series of military raids in which several<br />

high-profile <strong>traffickers</strong> were assassinated and imprisonment.<br />

9


Axiom 4: k is affected <strong>by</strong> random factors (r).<br />

In short, we can find scenarios in which bribing may be preferred to killing, even <strong>by</strong> powerful<br />

organizations. Bribing is less disruptive and more certain. Actually, evidence shows that in<br />

states completely controlled <strong>by</strong> drug <strong>traffickers</strong>, such as Colombia during the seventies (Ledebur<br />

2005) or some regions of Brazil, political assassinations <strong>are</strong> limited. In Rondonia, a Brazilian<br />

region completely controlled <strong>by</strong> drug lords during the late eighties, political assasinatios were<br />

not even considered because to begin with, “no public figure [could ever] hope to get elected []<br />

without the explicit or implicit consent of <strong>traffickers</strong> (Geffray 2002)”.<br />

Most of the episodes of violence between <strong>Mexican</strong> drug traffic organizations have been ended<br />

<strong>by</strong> <strong>traffickers</strong> themselves. Keeping violence low has been a constant worry of <strong>Mexican</strong> DTOs.<br />

We can count at least 5 summits in which elite cartel members got together to discuss mechanisms<br />

and rules to avoid violent competition.<br />

Lemma 2: k does not necessarily increase in P n<br />

This is not to say though, that violence will be avoided always. Selective and controlled<br />

violence is beneficial for crime as it opens the possibility of using threats instead of bribes.<br />

Threatening is the cheapest strategy available for criminals (it is the equivalent of a zero-cost<br />

bribe) but to be used requires reputation.<br />

Reputation matters because of the interaction between politician and bribers <strong>are</strong> subject to<br />

information/commitment problems. Politicians normally ignore the actual ability of <strong>traffickers</strong><br />

to exert violence, and criminals cannot commit to kill even if such is their preferred strategy.<br />

Selective killing is beneficial in the long term as it provides the required reputation for threatening<br />

in the future. Only criminal organizations which have established a reputation of compliers<br />

will deliver credible threats.<br />

Politicians built beliefs about <strong>traffickers</strong>’ power based on information collected <strong>by</strong> intelligence<br />

agencies and observable actions of criminals. A trafficker is non-violent either because he<br />

is unable to assassin, or because he does not want to. Politicians never know. Criminals can affect<br />

politicians believes <strong>by</strong> killing. Violence sends an unequivocal sign that they <strong>are</strong> not kidding,<br />

that <strong>traffickers</strong> <strong>are</strong> actually capable of killing. Violence thus is useful because it increases the<br />

leverage of criminals in the bargaining process, deters potential competitors, and discourages<br />

current corrupted officials to cheat on the agreements. Paradoxically, present violence is needed<br />

to reduce the need to exert future violence.<br />

Lemma 3:Because k builds reputation (π), k reduces b<br />

10


Note that because killing is a sign, direct violence against high-level politicians can be substituted<br />

with slightly less politically visible killings of similar difficulty level. Actually, threats<br />

followed <strong>by</strong> intimidating actions <strong>are</strong> common in Mexico’s political/criminal relationships. When<br />

in February 2009, “La Linea” -a DTO operating in Ju<strong>are</strong>z- decided that it was in its best interest<br />

to take Roberto Orduna, chief of the Ministry of Public Security (Secretaria de Seguridad<br />

Publica SSP), out of their way, the DTO did not had to kill him to accomplish its goal. A<br />

credible threat with effective side killings was sufficiently efficient. La Linea started <strong>by</strong> killing<br />

a middle-level SSP agent, as well as three of Mr. Orduna’s bodyguards. A day later, the<br />

<strong>traffickers</strong> posted a billboard, directed to Mr. Orduna which read “if [you] do not resign, we<br />

will kill one agent every 48 hours.” Two days later, after a policemen and a guard had been<br />

executed, Mr. Odonez decided to leave office “not because [Mexico] is losing the war [on drugs]<br />

but precisely because they wanted to win it (Davila unknown year)”.<br />

When the mayor of Ju<strong>are</strong>z accepted Mr. Ordonez resign, he was immediately congratulated<br />

<strong>by</strong> La Linea for his “good” decision to “allow tainted Orduna to leave office.” La linea also left<br />

him very clear that “if you keep assisting more queers [sic], and helping those who you know,<br />

we won’t ask you to resign, we will cut your head and the heads of all your family, even if they<br />

live in El Paso, Texas (Davila unknown year)”<br />

La linea does not need to kill high-profile politicians to make them compliers because this<br />

DTO has heavily invested in its reputation. Perhaps, one of the most exemplary displays of<br />

their power happened again in Ciudad Ju<strong>are</strong>z. When at the beginning of 2008 the predecessor<br />

of Mr. Odonez, Mr. Prieto was in office, La Linea posted a billboard (this time at the policemen<br />

memorial, along with funeral flowers) in which the DTO listed 17 authorities who would be executed<br />

to instruct “those who still do not believe [in La Linea’s threats] (Topete 2008)”. One to<br />

one the authorities in the list were assassinated. By April, eight had been already <strong>killed</strong>, about<br />

one per week. When in may 2008, the second on board at SSP -and the closest collaborator of<br />

Mr. Prieto- was assassinated, the resign of Mr. Prieto arrived the office of the mayor (Gomez<br />

2008). La Linea won. Traffickers had “<strong>killed</strong>” Mr. Prieto <strong>by</strong> killing lower-key political figures.<br />

To summarize, this section discussed the strategies available for corruption demander. <strong>The</strong><br />

demander can choose between two strategies: bribing or killing. Killing is not always picked,<br />

even if the demander is powerful, because it is costly and uncertain. Selective killing though<br />

may be beneficial as it can be used to build a reputation. Reputation opens the possibility of<br />

a third strategy: threatening. Threatening is the preferred strategy of demanders because is<br />

equivalent to a zero-cost bribe. <strong>The</strong> following section analyzes the second side of corruption<br />

mechanics: corruption supply.<br />

11


3.2 Corruption supply: Prosecuting, ignoring or protecting<br />

Definition 3: A decides between rejecting b and prosecute N (e ≥ 0), and accepting b and<br />

protect N (e ≤ 0).<br />

Politicians decide how much they will enforce law given their capacity constraints. Law can<br />

be enforced against <strong>traffickers</strong> (i.e. prosecute) or in favor of them (i.e. protect). Politicians<br />

can also decide not to enforce (i.e. ignore). No enforcement means <strong>traffickers</strong> won’t be actively<br />

hunted; a de facto equivalent to decriminalization. Not enforcing is less compromising than any<br />

other option but gives fewer profits for politicians.<br />

<strong>The</strong> capacity to enforce of the state is a double-edge knife for <strong>traffickers</strong>. A strong government<br />

is an exceptional criminal protector but also, a threatening institution. A certain level of<br />

government strength is beneficial for <strong>traffickers</strong> because it allows corruption to be efficient <strong>by</strong><br />

securing that bribes will indeed buy what they <strong>are</strong> meant to buy: impunity.<br />

A very weak state may be entirely willing to contribute to <strong>traffickers</strong>’ wellness, but may be<br />

de facto unable to deliver what <strong>traffickers</strong> require. Securing say, an oligopolistic market for a<br />

DTO <strong>by</strong> prohibiting other organizations to sell or cross drugs in an <strong>are</strong>a, requires at the very<br />

least a government able to crush potential competitors and identify which members belong to<br />

each DTO. Tijuana local police, for example, famous during the 90s for protecting the Arellano<br />

Felix DTO, regularly beat up local gang members who were trying to become small drug traders<br />

in Mr. Arellano territory. Policemen were effectively protecting the oligopolistic benefits that<br />

Mr. Arellano’s bribes had paid for (Proceso 1995). If Tijuana government would have been<br />

unable to track and hunt gang members, Mr. Arellano would have found it completely useless<br />

to bribe them and would have to take c<strong>are</strong> of the cumbersome task of protecting his territory<br />

himself.<br />

<strong>The</strong> ability of the state to enforce along all its territory and levels is also beneficial for organized<br />

crime; such state keeps the price of bribing under control and ensures that agreements will<br />

bind. Bribing such state may indeed be expensive but it will never be as expensive as bribing a<br />

fractionalized state. When bribing one fraction of the state does not ensure that the agreement<br />

will bind in all the territory (as would be the case during a civil war), more bribes <strong>are</strong> needed 4 .<br />

In short, a strong state with ability to enforce and vertical control over its bureaucracy will<br />

ensure that <strong>traffickers</strong> bribe only one actor, keeping the price of bribes under certain affordable<br />

limits. If instead, several agents have legitimacy over one single territory, drug trafficking organization<br />

may need to spend more money to get the impunity and monopoly that they need<br />

4 Note that keeping bargaining power fixed, more bribes do not necessarily mean fewer profits for <strong>traffickers</strong><br />

(e.g. a same bribe may be divided among two bribees) but it does mean that trafficker’s profits will not be more<br />

than with a single actor.<br />

12


for their business. <strong>The</strong> simplicity of closing a deal with a single actor is always preferred to the<br />

chaotic dynamic of multi-agent bribing processes.<br />

Lemma 4: N has concave preferences over P a<br />

To summarize, this section showed the strategies available for corruption suppliers. <strong>The</strong>y<br />

can prosecute, protect or ignore criminals. Both prosecution and protection require a strong<br />

state which means that, <strong>traffickers</strong> may not always want to have a weak state. <strong>The</strong> following<br />

section presents some comparative statics and shows interesting results of the previously defined<br />

model of corruption.<br />

4 Equilibrium results: How much silver, how little lead?<br />

Definition 4: A corruption interaction finishes when A accepts a bribe, and a level of political<br />

violence is exerted.<br />

Corruption is a dynamic, non-zero cost negotiation between a briber (trafficker) and a bribee<br />

(politician) which has as observable outcomes either (a) impunity towards <strong>traffickers</strong> with or<br />

without political violence (corruption agreement), (b) active prosecution of <strong>traffickers</strong> with political<br />

violence (if no agreement), or (c) no trafficking.<br />

<strong>The</strong> size of the bribe, as a sh<strong>are</strong> of total illegal profits, will be determined <strong>by</strong> politicians’<br />

costs of corruption (given <strong>by</strong> relative power of the state versus <strong>traffickers</strong>, the value politician<br />

attributes to virtuous behavior, and the probability of being prosecuted), and <strong>traffickers</strong>’ benefits<br />

of corruption (given <strong>by</strong> the profitability of the business, their relative power of the state<br />

versus <strong>traffickers</strong>, and the costs of killing). Politician’s power refers to their ability to prosecute<br />

criminals; trafficker’s power refers to their ability to exert violence against politicians.<br />

<strong>The</strong> relationship between the price of bribes and the capacity of enforcement of the state<br />

is pictured in Graph 1. <strong>The</strong> normal line pictures all equilibriums in which bribes <strong>are</strong> priced to<br />

pay exactly the benefits of no-enforcement; I call this the “fair trade bribe”. <strong>The</strong> actual bribe<br />

paid can be above or below fair trade, depending on the value that politician give to virtue, the<br />

probability of politicians to be prosecuted, and the cost of killing. <strong>The</strong> cost of killing depends<br />

on expected state reaction (i.e. how much retaliation will increase after the killing, and the<br />

value that current corruption agreements with the politician (if such <strong>are</strong> in place).<br />

Several cases could be portrayed. <strong>The</strong> dashed line represents the bribe paid to politicians<br />

who <strong>are</strong> very well connected into the political <strong>are</strong>na or in very politically relevant positions.<br />

Killing well connected, relevant politicians is costly. How crucial buying those politicians is for<br />

13


profits’ levels determines the baseline price of the bribe, that is to say, the origin of the fairtrade-bribe<br />

line. <strong>The</strong> bold-dashed line represents a well-connected, politically relevant politician<br />

in a non-crucial position. <strong>The</strong> attenuated-dashed line represents a non-connected, politically<br />

irrelevant politician in a crucial position.<br />

[Graph 1 about here]<br />

<strong>The</strong> cost of corruption for politicians is larger as bribes increase in size because hiding a<br />

large amount of illegal profits is increasingly difficult. This explains why some politicians get<br />

moderate bribes even if they could get much more. Mr. (XX -closed source), high-level authority<br />

at Tijuana’s office of the Attorney General (Procuraduria General de Justicia del Estado<br />

de Baja California, PGJE) protected Arellano Felix DTO and yet, had a very modest car and<br />

lived in a very small apartment. He was using his moderately priced bribes only to take their<br />

daughters to private universities (XX -closed source). For politicians thus, the marginal costs<br />

of corruption <strong>are</strong> increasing which means their fair trade bribe is a convex function.<br />

Contrary, the cost of corruption for <strong>traffickers</strong> is smaller as bribes increase. Bribing one<br />

politician reduces the cost of bribing others because it shows the last ones that the probability<br />

of prosecution is low. If others do it, it should not be that dangerous. Corruption is contagious.<br />

Furthermore, corrupt authorities may pressure new authorities to be corrupt. As (XX<br />

-closed source), ex-member of Tijuana police acknowledge, “it is impossible not to [be corrupt],<br />

if you do not get [bribes] your boss will be pissed off because he won’t get his sh<strong>are</strong> of it.” In<br />

very a very well structured corruption market, as is Tijuana local police department, bribes<br />

<strong>are</strong> commonly distributed along the hierarchy <strong>by</strong> chunks. Each member gets a sh<strong>are</strong> of what<br />

their subordinate got, and gives a sh<strong>are</strong> of his profits to his supervisor. Supervisors ask for a<br />

“required quota” to each subordinate. As long as the quote is fulfilled, subordinates can keep<br />

the rest for themselves. Failures to get the quota <strong>are</strong> punished. Non-corrupt officials thus may<br />

become liabilities in corrupted institutions. Because for bribers the marginal costs of corruption<br />

is decreasing, the fair trade bribe for <strong>traffickers</strong> is a concave function.<br />

Result 1: <strong>The</strong> concavity of fair trade bribes (b ′ ) is undetermined; “Sometimes bribing more<br />

is less, not more expensive, and sometimes politicians want small bribes”<br />

Uncertainty plays an important role when determining whether actual bribes will be above<br />

or below fair trade bribes. If the briber is paying a higher bribe than the benefits he gets from<br />

no enforcement, is because the bribee is more powerful than the briber (i.e. the state extorts<br />

<strong>traffickers</strong> and takes part of their profits). <strong>The</strong> opposite is not true. We can imagine a situation<br />

in which the briber is paying less than the benefits he gets from no enforcement (i.e. <strong>traffickers</strong><br />

<strong>are</strong> extorting the state) without the briber being necessarily more powerful than the bribee.<br />

Because of information issues (Axiom 5), and the randomness of violence (Axiom 4), politicians<br />

<strong>are</strong> never certain about the real power of <strong>traffickers</strong>, and <strong>traffickers</strong> may get lucky in a political<br />

14


assassination. Given this, it may be that politicians miscalculate their power (versus that of<br />

<strong>traffickers</strong>) and “under-price” their value.<br />

Result 2: If b < b ′ , P n has not to be larger than P a ; “Even weak <strong>traffickers</strong> can extort<br />

powerful states”<br />

Other interesting results come from analyzing the relationship between killing and bribes<br />

(see Graph 2). Violence relates to bribes in two ways: it substitutes them when these <strong>are</strong> too<br />

high, and it reduces them <strong>by</strong> signaling <strong>traffickers</strong>’ power. Killing is a substitute for bribing,<br />

when bribing politicians is too expensive (because for example, they put al lot of value into<br />

being honest). Yet, when bribes <strong>are</strong> very high, <strong>traffickers</strong> also find it more difficult to kill. As<br />

bribe increases thus, violence is more wanted but more difficult to attain for <strong>traffickers</strong><br />

[Graph 2 about here]<br />

Note that it is the relationship between capability to kill and willingness to kill what determines<br />

whether violence would be positively or negatively correlated to bribe size. <strong>The</strong> traditional<br />

silver-or-lead approach fails to understand corruption because it always assumes a relationship<br />

in the form of the dashed line. <strong>The</strong> relationship, I argue, can have the form pictured with the<br />

bold line because violence has a random factor, and because quietness has an intrinsic value.<br />

<strong>The</strong> bold line describes the behavior of a not very powerful organized crime. <strong>The</strong>y will kill<br />

less (not more) when bribes <strong>are</strong> high because they <strong>are</strong> incapable to kill highly-bribed, powerful<br />

politicians. <strong>The</strong>y may want to kill politicians more when bribing is too expensive, but they do<br />

not do it because it is costly. If any killing at all, they will kill the underdogs. <strong>The</strong> key here is<br />

that the reason why they kill underdogs is because such killings signal the top guys, and reduce<br />

their demands. This proves result 3:<br />

Result 3: Correlation between b and k must not be assumed to be negative; “Silver or<br />

lead, Silver and lead”<br />

Graph 2 also shows that politicians will always receive a sh<strong>are</strong> of illegal profits unless they<br />

<strong>are</strong> sc<strong>are</strong>d enough as to not ask for money. Scaring politicians requires credible threatening.<br />

Note that there is always a point at which killing more is not valuable. When politicians <strong>are</strong><br />

intimidated enough as to accept reducing enforcement without bribes, killing only remains there<br />

as a residual; as a reminder for politicians of the power of <strong>traffickers</strong>. Thus, if traffic is done<br />

and bribes <strong>are</strong> zero, it is because selective killing is working as a mechanism to keep politicians<br />

intimidated.<br />

Result 4: When M > 0, k > 0 is required for b = 0;“No-silver and lead”<br />

To understand why result 4 holds, consider an alternative scenario in which a politician does<br />

15


not receive illegal profits (b=0), and there <strong>are</strong> no killings (k=0). This would only be the case if<br />

he places a lot of value into virtue and has the force to control <strong>traffickers</strong>’ violence. Under this<br />

circumstance, there will be not illegal profits because trafficking would be controlled. It won’t<br />

be worth for <strong>traffickers</strong> to go into illegal business because the state is too powerful and virtuous.<br />

Result 5: When M > 0, k = 0 if and only if b = M is a viable equilibrium;“Silver and<br />

no-lead”<br />

If organized crime is in business, political violence will only be absent (k = 0) if the corrupt<br />

state is powerful enough as to take all of the illegal profits for itself. Recall that <strong>traffickers</strong> always<br />

have an incentive to kill either to (a) reduce the price of bribes, or (b) keep their reputation.<br />

Killing thus will only be zero in the very extreme case that <strong>traffickers</strong> <strong>are</strong> unable to kill. This<br />

is not easy given than even weak <strong>traffickers</strong> may get lucky at times. Only a very powerful state<br />

will be able to have a peaceful drug market yet, this requires the state to be strong enough as<br />

to extort criminals. Such strong state can decide between eradicating crime at all, or take all<br />

illegal profits for itself. This is the case of a potentially extortionist state (i.e. b=M is a viable<br />

equilibrium)<br />

Results 4 and 5 have important implications for the quality of politicians. When running for<br />

office, politicians know that if trafficking is in place is because either there has been a corruption<br />

agreement (b > 0), or because politicians <strong>are</strong> too sc<strong>are</strong>d to (fully) enforce against crime (result<br />

4).<br />

Result 6: When M > 0, only corrupt A’s will take office, unless b = M is a viable equilibrium;<br />

“To be completely virtuous, one need to be able to be completely corrupt”<br />

Those politicians who take office at corrupted places know they will be bribed because otherwise<br />

they will be <strong>killed</strong>. Because of result 6, we know that the only chance for political violence<br />

to be absent, given that traffic is present, is to have a very powerful state. Rational politicians<br />

deny running for office if they have a positive probability to be <strong>killed</strong> 5 . Weak politicians who<br />

decide to enforce have a positive probability to be <strong>killed</strong>. Thus, we will only have non-corrupt<br />

candidates if the incumbent is powerful enough as to be completely corrupt. Quiet drug markets,<br />

like the US, require politicians to be potential extortionists 6 .<br />

5 <strong>The</strong> rationality of politicians may be debatable as it may be affected <strong>by</strong> the value that they put into virtue.<br />

A very virtuous politician could be argued, will take office even if it is to be a martyr. I do not discard this<br />

possibility but find it improbable given that, if the ultimate motivation of a virtuous politician is to reduce<br />

crime, his assassinated will not put him any closer to achieve his goal. Nobody can change the world from the<br />

grave. Martyrs though may still give their live for a uncertain, further ulterior purpose. A politician may think<br />

that even if <strong>killed</strong>, his assassination will generate international attention and a increase in retaliation against<br />

crime.<br />

6 Enforcement <strong>by</strong> a weak politician is only possible if such enforcement does not really hurt <strong>traffickers</strong>, at<br />

16


To summarize, the current section has analyzed corruption mechanics and the outcomes<br />

that the political-criminal nexus is expected to generate. I defined a simple model of corruption<br />

bargaining, and used a small set of logically derived axioms to show that corruption is far more<br />

than a decision between accepting a reasonable bribe (silver) and <strong>getting</strong> <strong>killed</strong> (lead). Silver<br />

may actually come hand with hand with lead, there may be no offer of silver at all, there may<br />

be no chances of lead, politicians may want to have fewer silver than available, and <strong>traffickers</strong><br />

may want politicians to take their silver. Furthermore, I presented and logically proved the<br />

validity of some app<strong>are</strong>ntly counter-intuitive statements. I showed that to be non-corrupt one<br />

has to be able to be corrupt, that <strong>traffickers</strong> want politicians to be around, and that power is<br />

not a necessary condition for criminals to be able to extort politicians. In the following section<br />

I present a study case to asses the validity of the results presented so far. In particular, I draw<br />

attention towards the mechanics of sub-national corruption in Mexico, and explain its particularly<br />

puzzling outcomes.<br />

5 Silver and lead in real life: <strong>Why</strong> <strong>Mexican</strong> majors <strong>are</strong><br />

<strong>getting</strong> <strong>killed</strong> like never before?<br />

<strong>The</strong> puzzle<br />

Political-criminal interactions and outcomes have abruptly changed in recent Mexico. Drug<br />

<strong>traffickers</strong>, previously known for their relative distance to politics, have become increasingly<br />

politically violent. Traffickers have become active electoral participants <strong>by</strong> killing candidates,<br />

intimidating voters, and assassinating the press.<br />

Political assassinations -which were pretty r<strong>are</strong> in <strong>Mexican</strong> history- have recently become<br />

alarmingly common. Local governments, in particular <strong>mayors</strong>, have taken most of the burden.<br />

Just in the first ten months of 2010, 12 majors were <strong>killed</strong>; a considerable figure if we note that<br />

from 1999 to 2003 not even a single one was executed (See figure 1). Both the rapid increase in<br />

assassinations over the last five years, and the total absence of political violence during the previous<br />

five years <strong>are</strong> puzzling corruption outcomes. Killing should not be absent. As explained<br />

<strong>by</strong> the model above, we know that killing not only substitute bribes but, because of its value as<br />

a signal, it complements them. In a corrupt system, we should expect thus to have some sp<strong>are</strong><br />

violence. Complete quietness is not then norm. <strong>The</strong> steep increase in assassinations during the<br />

last five years also cries for an explanation. <strong>Why</strong>, if drug trafficking has long been present in<br />

least not as much as to make them angry in a meaningful way. Traffickers <strong>are</strong> not hurt <strong>by</strong> enforcement only if it<br />

is done in non-valuable territories or targets non-valuable assets. I do not consider this possibility because (a)<br />

I assume that corruption demand will only exists in valuable territories, and (b) I believe selective-enforcement<br />

is a form of corruption.<br />

17


Mexico, it is only now that has become violent?<br />

[Figure 1 about here]<br />

In this section, I present a detailed analysis of the causes behind each of the 26 political<br />

assassinations that have happened in Mexico since 1999. My case <strong>by</strong> case study shows how<br />

the theoretical implications of my model of corruption <strong>are</strong> able to make sense of the observed<br />

trends in violence. Political violence is not a simple decision between silver and lead –in which<br />

increments in the power of <strong>traffickers</strong> increase levels of violence– as the traditional narrative<br />

has argued. Silver and lead complement each other, and depend on more factors that just the<br />

power of <strong>traffickers</strong>.<br />

<strong>The</strong> methodology<br />

Getting to know the reasons why <strong>traffickers</strong> have <strong>killed</strong> politicians has not been an easy task.<br />

<strong>The</strong> following <strong>are</strong> the results of an extensive fieldwork during which I conducted over a hundred<br />

interviews in <strong>Mexican</strong> cities known <strong>by</strong> their strong presence of illegal trafficking -Ciudad Ju<strong>are</strong>z,<br />

Nuevo L<strong>are</strong>do, Tijuana, to name a few. Accompanied <strong>by</strong> the most renowned journalists covering<br />

Mexico’s drug traffic -most of them already threatened <strong>by</strong> <strong>traffickers</strong>-, I repeatedly visited<br />

each city, slowly gaining the confidence of local journalist, citizens and politicians to speak up<br />

their first-hand experience on the mafia/politics relation. My fieldwork was complemented <strong>by</strong><br />

the brave reporting of <strong>Mexican</strong> local newspaper journalists. Local journalists <strong>are</strong> well informed<br />

sources which have a fair amount of corruption stories that remain unknown due to their lack of<br />

national relevance. I went over the local and national press myself, reviewing and corroborating<br />

data that anonymous oral sources told me. This was a deep jump into <strong>Mexican</strong> corruption<br />

mechanics.<br />

Sometimes though, even the most tenacious research efforts were unsuccessful. “You cannot<br />

know that much,” an important human rights advocate with first hand information on DTOs<br />

once told me (XX -confidencial). I humbly agree. I cannot claim that I know the exact reasons<br />

why <strong>mayors</strong> <strong>are</strong> <strong>killed</strong>, but I can claim that, to the best of mine and my sources knowledge, what<br />

I present here is a fair portray of Mexico’s corruption <strong>dynamics</strong>. However, this is a research<br />

topic that will always have some degree of speculation. <strong>The</strong> key, I believe, is to accept what we<br />

do not know, and work creatively with what we know.<br />

Not quite silver OR lead<br />

<strong>The</strong> reason why, if <strong>Mexican</strong> organized crime has long been in business, it is just now that it<br />

has become politically violent, cannot be found <strong>by</strong> using the traditional Silver-or-lead narrative.<br />

18


Such theory, which assumes that bribes (silver) and political violence (lead) <strong>are</strong> substitutes,<br />

can only make sense of recent political violence trends <strong>by</strong> arguing that <strong>traffickers</strong> have become<br />

relatively more powerful overtime, which has lead to substitute bribes for killings. This thesis<br />

is highly contestable. <strong>Mexican</strong> DTOs <strong>are</strong> currently more powerful than a couple of decades ago<br />

but, if anything, during the last five years –period at which assassinations have increased– they<br />

have weakened.<br />

<strong>Mexican</strong>s indeed get a larger sh<strong>are</strong> of illegal revenues than during the eighties –when illegal<br />

drug production and distribution was controlled <strong>by</strong> Colombians. Colombians weakened<br />

when the US set up “Plan Colombia,” an important policy to provide that Latin American<br />

country with about 1.5 billion dollars a year to fight drug production and transportation. Intensive<br />

drug eradication, a clever policy to promote voluntary surrender (i.e. no extradition,<br />

shorter sentences for confessed <strong>traffickers</strong>), and higher surveillance over the Caribbean diminished<br />

the power of Colombian DTOs, and consequently empowered <strong>Mexican</strong>s (UNODC 2010,<br />

XX).Empirically testing the Colombia-Mexico shift is not easy but evidence on the relationship<br />

between the press and organized crime can give us an insight of it. <strong>Mexican</strong> DTOs, for example,<br />

have become increasingly violent against the press at the same time at which Colombian’s have<br />

become more pacific (Figure 2) 7 .<br />

[Figure 2 about here]<br />

Matching this trend, drugs have become increasingly available in Mexico as <strong>Mexican</strong> <strong>traffickers</strong><br />

have taken over Colombians. Using data of deaths caused <strong>by</strong> illegal drug consumption<br />

to proxy for the presence of DTOs in Mexico, figure 3 shows how in the late nineties, <strong>Mexican</strong>s<br />

stopped being a mainly opium producer country and entered the cocaine business. <strong>The</strong> industry<br />

of illegal drugs changed, Mexico became a Cocaine producer, and relative importance of<br />

Mexico as an opium producer diminished versus Afghanistan and China. <strong>The</strong> entrance into the<br />

Cocaine business –and the small but stable business of marihuana that <strong>Mexican</strong> DTO’s already<br />

had– supported <strong>Mexican</strong>s as their relative importance as opium producer diminished. In 2004,<br />

<strong>Mexican</strong> DTOs were at the peak of their power selling a fair amount of opium and marihuana,<br />

transporting cocaine into the US, and booming in the methamphetamine business.<br />

[Figure 3 about here]<br />

Figure 3 though, also shows how Mexico’s organized crime faced a large decrease in its power<br />

starting in 2005 8 . It is 2005, the year at which a large territorial battle between Sinaloa and<br />

7 Other variables, such as (a) the number of asylum petitions to the US, as well as (a) the number of criminals<br />

caught at American territory, follow the same negative correlation.<br />

8 Power is defined here, as wall as in the rest of the paper, as violence capacity. <strong>The</strong> assumption is that higher<br />

sales increases <strong>traffickers</strong>’ ability to be violent because higher revenues can be invested in improving killing<br />

technology.<br />

19


Golf DTOs emerged. <strong>The</strong> battle has as a goal to get control of Nuevo L<strong>are</strong>do, the main port<br />

of entry of legal merchandise into the US. This year, marks the beginning of a drug war that<br />

still remains alive and that has taken the live of at least 26,739 individuals in the last three<br />

years (Figure 4). <strong>The</strong> territorial war between Golf an Sinaloa DTOs was triggered, among other<br />

things because of a temporal instability in Golf’s leadership caused <strong>by</strong> the imprisonment of the<br />

head of Golf organization, Mr. Osiel Cardenas (Ravelo 2009). <strong>The</strong> war was further increased<br />

when Mexico’s Federal government launched, in 2007, the most important offensive against drug<br />

trafficking that the country has seen. Mr. Felipe Calderon, elected president of Mexico in 2006,<br />

called during his first month in office for a “war on drugs,” and sent troops to control the most<br />

important trafficking points. This increase in enforcement reduced the ability of <strong>traffickers</strong> to<br />

keep doing business as usual, and further destabilized the internal <strong>dynamics</strong> of DTOs when<br />

drug lords were captured and extradited.<br />

[Figure 4 about here]<br />

Changes in the power of organized crime <strong>are</strong> comp<strong>are</strong>d with changes in the capability of the<br />

<strong>Mexican</strong> government to prosecute in Figure 5. State capacity is here measured as the number<br />

of law enforcement officials working at the Federal Agency of Investigations (Agencia Federal<br />

de Investigaciones, AFI), and the number of active elements at the army and the military<br />

(Secretaria de Defensa Nacional (Sedena) and Secretaria de Marina (Semar)). This measure<br />

is imperfect as it only measures capacity, not capability/willingness to enforce. Other aspects,<br />

such as leadership, coordination, training, and physical resources may be more important to<br />

determine the real power of the government 9 . Yet, even if these figures were not completely<br />

accurate, there is no doubt that, at least since Felipe Calderon took office in 2007, enforce<br />

against drug <strong>traffickers</strong> has increased in Mexico.<br />

[Figure 5 about here]<br />

To summarize, this is not the story of an increasingly powerful <strong>Mexican</strong> organized crime<br />

that became more violent. This is the story of an organized crime that boomed quietly, and<br />

weakened loudly. If anything, during the years where political violence has increased (2004 and<br />

on), <strong>Mexican</strong> DTOs have diminish their power as a result of intra/inter DTO’s territorial battles<br />

and increases in law enforcement. Empirical shows a <strong>Mexican</strong> government that has systematically<br />

increased its human resources to fight drug traffic, and (since 2007) its willingness to do it.<br />

Political violence thus, has increased as <strong>traffickers</strong> have become less powerful, a result at odds<br />

with traditional understandings of corruption. <strong>Mexican</strong> politicians seem to be increasing their<br />

capability to get silver, at the same time that they <strong>are</strong> <strong>getting</strong> more lead 10 .<br />

9 Using statistics on detention and drug seizures though, is not recommendable as those figures <strong>are</strong> endogenous<br />

to the size of DTOs.<br />

10 An alternative explanation is that of general disorder. Current drug war may have diminished the cost of<br />

killing because homicides have increased overall. Authorities <strong>are</strong> not able to punish homicides, and impunity has<br />

20


Insight 1: Traffickers <strong>are</strong> not stronger, government is not (necessarily) weaker, and yet<br />

politicians <strong>are</strong> <strong>getting</strong> <strong>killed</strong> more.<br />

Understanding corruption outcomes in Mexico: demand and supply<br />

<strong>dynamics</strong><br />

My model of the <strong>dynamics</strong> of corruption can yield some insights into the reasons for this puzzling<br />

result. Corruption supply and demand <strong>are</strong> the key. Mayors were not <strong>killed</strong> before (1999 - 2003)<br />

because during the strongly centralized PRI-regime there was not a market for sub-national corruption.<br />

Mayors <strong>are</strong> <strong>killed</strong> because the illegal-drug industry has changes. Markets have become<br />

more competitive, and DTOs have turned into multiproduct, domestic sellers. Such changes<br />

have increased the demand for sub-national corruption, made killings more valuable as signals,<br />

and increased the price of bribes. In short, corruption outcomes changes in Mexico because of<br />

(a) the decentralization of political institutions, and (b) changes in the illegal-drug industry.<br />

First, the decentralization of <strong>Mexican</strong> government has increased political violence because<br />

it opened a new source of corruption supply (the sub-national supply). <strong>The</strong> rupture of the<br />

hegemony of PRI as the dominant party shifted the balance of power from the national to the<br />

sub-national level. <strong>The</strong> PRI, which ruled Mexico for more than 70 years, had a very centralized<br />

form of government. All policy decisions were taken at the center and were not questioned <strong>by</strong><br />

state politicians, mainly because a well instituted system of political clientelism was in place.<br />

All the political c<strong>are</strong>ers of state-level politicians were determined <strong>by</strong> direct appointments coming<br />

from the national level. Beginning in the late eighties this started to change. State politicians<br />

became increasingly independent when the first victories of the opposition broke the ability of<br />

the federation to keep political clientelism working 11 . <strong>The</strong> recent independence of sub-national<br />

figures made sub-national corruption a possibility.<br />

If majors <strong>are</strong> being <strong>killed</strong> more now, is not (necessarily) because <strong>traffickers</strong> <strong>are</strong> more powerful<br />

than before (which may not be) but because, <strong>mayors</strong> now have the political power to influence<br />

the trafficking business <strong>by</strong> endorsing or rejecting federal policies. It is not a coincidence that<br />

the number of <strong>mayors</strong> assassinated has increased with decentralization.<br />

increased. Indeed, political assassinations have increased following national homicide rates (see Appendix 5). I<br />

doubt of the explanatory power of general disorder theories because (a) <strong>mayors</strong> have not been assassinated in the<br />

most violent municipalities, (b) neither during the peak of violence of their states (Appendix 4) or municipalities<br />

(Appendix 5)<br />

11 Note that this is not an argument about democratization but about centralization. Even under an authoritarian<br />

regime, sub-national politics could have been decentralized, and <strong>mayors</strong> could have supplied corruption.<br />

Democratization and centralization <strong>are</strong> not interchangeable terms.<br />

21


<strong>The</strong> case of Mr. Alfonso Pena, the mayor of Tepehuanes, a municipality of Durango where<br />

poppy has long being growth, is an example of the power that <strong>mayors</strong> have recently got. In<br />

2008, just a couple of months after Mr. Pena took office, his entire police department resigned.<br />

His police though was integrated <strong>by</strong> only five members. <strong>The</strong>y were sc<strong>are</strong>d because <strong>traffickers</strong><br />

had <strong>killed</strong> one policeman, kidnapped another, and wounded one more. After the massive resignation<br />

nobody in the municipality wanted to be a policeman anymore. Mr. Pena decided to<br />

become the police himself. With his armored hummer and his brother company, he patrolled<br />

Tepehuanes for a month until help, brought from the federal government, arrived town. Traffickers<br />

did not liked this. “Allow us to work bastard, and take out the military or do you want<br />

to lose your head?” were the type of calls that Mr. Pena started <strong>getting</strong> (Almazan 2010). Mr.<br />

Pena disappe<strong>are</strong>d on July 26th, 2010 (Hernandez 2010) and has not being founded yet.<br />

Even if Mr. Pena lacked of a real enforcement capacity himself (at most five policemen), he<br />

had the possibility to call the federation for support. This possibility would not have been an<br />

option during the PRI hegemony because all enforcement decisions were taken at the center;<br />

<strong>mayors</strong> lacked of a voice. It is the recent capacity of Mr. Pena to supply corruption (<strong>by</strong> deciding<br />

whether to work or not with the federation), what made him (and other <strong>mayors</strong> 12 ) a target of<br />

<strong>traffickers</strong>.<br />

Insight 2: Decentralization made sub-national politicians potential corruption suppliers<br />

Second, <strong>mayors</strong> <strong>are</strong> being <strong>killed</strong> more because changes in DTOs target consumers and products<br />

have increased the demand for sub-national corruptions. DTOs now need <strong>mayors</strong> more.<br />

As Figure 6 shows, <strong>Mexican</strong> DTO’s have shifted from being drug exporters only, to be drug<br />

dealers inside Mexico. <strong>The</strong> exporting business only requires control of highways and ports of<br />

entry into the US –which <strong>are</strong> all federally regulated. Domestic sells though, require a tighter<br />

control of local authorities; drugs have to be sold in street corners and local policemen have to<br />

agree on it. Corrupting <strong>mayors</strong> in more profitable because <strong>by</strong> gaining control over a territory,<br />

DTOs can both use the highways to introduce drugs into the US (old consumers) and sell to<br />

<strong>Mexican</strong> consumers (new consumers).<br />

[Figure 6 about here]<br />

Furthermore, <strong>Mexican</strong> DTOs have also become multiproduct firms. <strong>Mexican</strong>s became<br />

methamphetamine producers at the beginning of the 00s. <strong>The</strong> production of synthetic drugs<br />

requires building laboratories which significantly increase the value of corruption agreements<br />

with local authorities. <strong>The</strong> laboratories have to remain clandestine. Out of all laboratories that<br />

12 Mr. Luis Carlos Ramirez, mayor of Ocampo, Durango, was assassinated on July 1st, 2009 for denouncing<br />

<strong>traffickers</strong> to federal authorities. As the mayor of Pueblo Nuevo, another municipality of Durango, candidly<br />

acknowledged: “[he] was <strong>killed</strong> because he denounced an armed group [], the mayor of El Mezquital, I do not<br />

know what [he did to] bother them [<strong>traffickers</strong>], but they <strong>killed</strong> him” (La Loncheria, 2010).<br />

22


have been discovered <strong>by</strong> the federation, 56% of them were located in politically violent states,<br />

even though these only represent 34% of all the states.<br />

Insight 3a: Changes in Mexico’s illegal-drug industry (i.e. DTOs becoming multiproduct<br />

and domestic sellers) created a demand for sub-national corruption.<br />

Mayors <strong>are</strong> also being <strong>killed</strong> more because Mexico’s illegal industry became more competitive,<br />

and with competition the price of bribes have increased, and killing has become more<br />

valuable as a signal. In short, the utility of political assassinations increased. Because corrupting<br />

the government is a necessary input for drug production, competition for territory makes<br />

bribes very expensive for the newcomer DTO. If a mayor works for Sinaloa DTO, he must<br />

refuse to accept bribes from another DTO, as this will create a large incentive for Sinaloa DTO<br />

to kill him. Traffickers have made it very clear that making deals with two DTOs is a death<br />

sentence. “[<strong>The</strong> mayor] has been <strong>killed</strong> [] because he betrayed his people. He [] became the<br />

principal operator of a group of assassins and kidnappers called Los Zetas (Proceso 2010)” was<br />

the message that Golf DTO left when Mr. Leal, mayor of Hidalgo, Tamaulipas was <strong>killed</strong> in<br />

August 28th, 2010.<br />

Bribing a mayor that is already being bribed is very expensive (or impossible). Newcomer<br />

DTOs face the logical equivalent of an infinite bribe price. Kill the mayor thus, becomes the<br />

only possibility to compete into the market. Killing is a high entry cost to pay but, never as<br />

costly as remaining out of business.<br />

Figure 7 shows the detailed causes of mayor assassinations. Competition, which takes form<br />

as violent territorial fights, is perhaps one of the stronger determinants of political violence.<br />

From the 26 cases of assasinated <strong>mayors</strong> from 1999 to September 2010, 24 <strong>are</strong> directly related<br />

to drug trafficking. I could find the causes for 20 cases. Out of these, 14 <strong>are</strong> directly related to<br />

territorial wars. Historically, we can see how the number of <strong>mayors</strong> assassinated has increased<br />

as the number of competing organization has increased. <strong>The</strong> first rupture of oligopolies in the<br />

00s came in December of 2004, the exact year in which the first two <strong>mayors</strong> were assassinated.<br />

Since then, inter-DTOs conflicts have increased in number. While in 2007 there were only four<br />

competitive markets (Sinaloa vs. Tijuana; Sinaloa vs. Ju<strong>are</strong>z, Sinaloa vs. Golfo-Zetas, and<br />

La Familia vs. Zetas), in 2010 the number increased to eight (Sinaloa vs. Tijuana, Golfo vs.<br />

Ju<strong>are</strong>z, Sinaloa vs. Golfo, La Familia vs. Zetas, Sinaloa vs. Beltran Leyva, Sinaloa vs Linea,<br />

Golfo vs. Zetas, and Pacifico Sur vs. La Barbie) (Guerrero etal 2010 complemented <strong>by</strong> author).<br />

[Figure 7 about here]<br />

Mayors <strong>are</strong> well aw<strong>are</strong> of the negative consequences that competition may bring them and<br />

thus have changed their strategy from taking bribes and not enforce, to not taking bribes and<br />

not enforce. When the mayor of (XX- confidential) took office in 2007, he received as a gift a<br />

23


iefcase full of money. He rejected it because he knew that under the strong competition that<br />

the municipality faced, any deal done with a DTO will immediately put him in danger to be<br />

<strong>killed</strong> <strong>by</strong> the other. <strong>The</strong> only viable solution for <strong>mayors</strong> ruling in competitive municipalities is<br />

to reject bribes at all and not enforce. Enforcing is twice as dangerous when two enemies <strong>are</strong><br />

being fought.<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>mayors</strong> of Durango, a state where seven <strong>mayors</strong> have been <strong>killed</strong> since 2004 –three on<br />

row at the municipality of Otaez–, have been very explicit about their approach to corruption.<br />

First, “pretend to be stupid” claimed one of them (XX-confidential). Second, never enforce<br />

“Nooo!” said the mayor of Santiago when asked whether he prosecuted <strong>traffickers</strong>, “I never<br />

bother anybody. My police do not prosecute drug <strong>traffickers</strong>, they only arrests boozers and<br />

petty thieves.” Third, better avoid becoming a mayor. “This job of being a mayor is not recommendable<br />

anymore” concluded the mayor of Guacevi. <strong>The</strong> advice, given <strong>by</strong> the Mayor of<br />

Poanas, to those that already have the job was “to trust in God.”<br />

Note that assassinations will only happen when <strong>mayors</strong> get trapped into a bad equilibrium.<br />

When they took office competition was not in place, which allowed them to made explicit arrangements<br />

with one DTO. Later though, competition started and they were unable to either<br />

break the agreement that they had, or made a new one with the new DTO. <strong>The</strong> only chance to<br />

remain alive in such case is to run away, but even that is difficult given that <strong>traffickers</strong> can still<br />

take revenge with whoever remains in town (i.e. family, friends). In the words of the mayor of<br />

Pueblo Nuevo: “if I leave now, they [drug <strong>traffickers</strong>] will think that I’m guilty.”<br />

With competition the value of killing as a sign of power increases. Killing is a way to generate<br />

a reputation. Reputation double pays in competitive environments because it not only<br />

reduces the price of bribes but, deters potential competitors. At least 2 of the 20 cases studied<br />

here <strong>are</strong> explained as signaling cases. <strong>The</strong> mayor of Mezquital was <strong>killed</strong>, an intelligence report<br />

(XX-confidential) claim, as a threat to the governor of Durango; the mayor and the governor<br />

were very close friends.<br />

Insight 3b: Changes in Mexico’s illegal-drug industry (i.e. DTOs becoming more competitive)<br />

increased the price of bribes, and made killing more valuable as a signal.<br />

To summarize, this section has presented the results of a case <strong>by</strong> case study of assassinated<br />

<strong>mayors</strong>. I showed that, unlike silver-or-lead narrative would predict, political violence does<br />

not necessarily increase as <strong>traffickers</strong> become more powerful. Mayors <strong>are</strong> <strong>getting</strong> <strong>killed</strong> now<br />

because (a) decentralization open a new sub-national corruption market, and (b) recent market<br />

competition between DTOs made bribes get higher, and increased the value of killing as a signal.<br />

24


6 Conclusion<br />

<strong>The</strong> simplicity through which drug-trafficking and mafia-related corruption has been understood<br />

<strong>by</strong> current literature oversimplifies the decisions, interactions and strategies available for<br />

the actors. We have not being able to get a complete understanding of corruption outcomes<br />

because we have failed to consider how institutions and market changes affect the <strong>dynamics</strong> of<br />

corruption. In this paper I showed that the state is useful for <strong>traffickers</strong>, and that violence does<br />

not always increase as the power of <strong>traffickers</strong> increase. Killing is costly and uncertain, and<br />

dismantling the state may entail higher costs (because of reductions in legal trade) than any<br />

benefit brought <strong>by</strong> the elimination of bribes.<br />

A simple bargaining model to explain political/criminal interactions was presented. In my<br />

model, bribes can be substituted <strong>by</strong> killings (as traditional understandings of corruption would<br />

argue) but can also be complemented with killings. Killings may complement bribes because<br />

politicians <strong>are</strong> never sure about the actual power that <strong>traffickers</strong> have to kill. Killing functions<br />

as a signal to keep bribes affordable.<br />

<strong>The</strong> comparative statics of the model showed that sometimes bribing more is less, not more<br />

expensive for <strong>traffickers</strong>; that sometimes politicians want small bribes; that even weak <strong>traffickers</strong><br />

can extort powerful states, and that politicians not always take a decision between being bribed<br />

or <strong>killed</strong>. A final interesting result refers to the quality of politicians: In a corrupt environment,<br />

all available politicians will be corrupt unless the state has the ability to extort criminals. To<br />

be completely virtuous, a politician needs to be capable of being completely corrupt.<br />

My model of corruption <strong>dynamics</strong> was originally motivated <strong>by</strong> the need to explain recent<br />

puzzling changes in the relationship between Mexico’s politicians and criminals that I believe<br />

the traditional silver-or-lead approach cannot fully account for. Mexico shifted from being a<br />

completely peaceful country (no politicians were <strong>killed</strong> from 1999 to 2004), to be a mayhem (12<br />

<strong>mayors</strong> were <strong>killed</strong> in the first 9 months of 2010).<br />

Drawing on my own fieldwork experience in Mexico’s drug war zone, I use the results of my<br />

model to explain political violence. <strong>The</strong> reasons for such radical change, I have argued <strong>are</strong> not<br />

to be found in increases in the power of <strong>traffickers</strong> –as traditional narrative would argue– but<br />

in analyzing political institutions and features of the illegal-drug industry. Mayors <strong>are</strong> being<br />

<strong>killed</strong> because of (a) as the country has decentralized a market for sub-national corruption has<br />

emerged, because (b) <strong>Mexican</strong> DTOs have become multiproduct firms which sell drugs inside<br />

Mexico (not only transport them to the US), and because (c) the illegal drug-industry have<br />

become more competitive. <strong>The</strong>se changes have made <strong>mayors</strong>’ killings more prevalent because<br />

<strong>mayors</strong> have increased their relevance as political actors, bribes have become more expensive,<br />

and signaling has become more valuable.<br />

25


Corruption is a complex game where signals, beliefs and expectations play a large role in<br />

determining outcomes. Bribe and <strong>getting</strong> bribed <strong>are</strong> actions subject to many subtleties. One<br />

side has to avoid to get <strong>killed</strong>; the other has to keep a fragile equilibrium between killing, and<br />

not-killing; both sides cannot get too powerful neither too weak. Power sometimes hurts, and<br />

weakness sometimes benefits. <strong>The</strong> game of corruption is without any doubt a difficult one to<br />

play. In the words of Mr. (XX -closed source), local politician: “I do not know [what one has<br />

to do to remain alive], one just has to be very, very clever.”<br />

26


Graphs, Figures and Appendixes<br />

Graph 1: Determining the price of bribes<br />

(1a) Different bribes for different politicians/territories.<br />

Bribe<br />

Fair-trade b'<br />

State protection (negative enforcement)<br />

b' for a relevant/connected politician<br />

b' for relevant/connected politician at non-crucial territory<br />

b' for unrelevant/disconnected politician at crucial territory<br />

Traffickers pay politicians a bribe in exchange for state protection. <strong>The</strong> “fair-trade” price of a bribe (b’) is<br />

determined <strong>by</strong> (a) how much protection the trafficker gets, (b) how relevant/connected the politician is,<br />

and (c) how crucial the territory in question is for illegal businesses. <strong>The</strong> slope of b’ increases as the<br />

politician is more relevant/connected; the point at which b’ crosses the y access increases as the territory<br />

becomes more crucial. In very relevant territories even no-enforcement policies require the trafficker to<br />

pay a positive bribe to the politician.<br />

All bribes above the b’ line represents the politicians extorting <strong>traffickers</strong> and viceversa. Note that<br />

trafficker extortion may happen with more frequency because unlike <strong>traffickers</strong>, the state never<br />

completely known the power of his enemies.<br />

1


(1b) What should the price of the bribe be according to trafficker’s/politician’s logic?<br />

Bribe<br />

State protection (negative enforcement)<br />

according to trafficker's logic<br />

according to politicians's logic<br />

Politicians want bribes to be relatively higher as they protect <strong>traffickers</strong> more because hiding a lot of<br />

protection is more difficult. Traffickers believe bribes should be relatively lower as state protection<br />

increases because a corrupt state prosecutes <strong>traffickers</strong> less. <strong>The</strong> actual form of the line is undetermined.<br />

2


Graph 2: <strong>The</strong> relationship between bribes and killings<br />

Politicians' power<br />

Trafficker's power<br />

Bribes<br />

If killing substitute bribes<br />

If killing complements bribes<br />

Bribes decrease as the power of trafficker’s increases (normal line) up to a point in which they <strong>are</strong> zero. At<br />

this point politicians do not enforce (and sometimes even protect <strong>traffickers</strong>) without <strong>getting</strong> bribes<br />

because they <strong>are</strong> too sc<strong>are</strong>d. Once this “threatening level” is crossed, the number of killings gets stabilized<br />

(zero slope). Killing does not become zero because some selective killing has to be done to keep<br />

politicians sc<strong>are</strong>d over time (i.e. trafficker’s power is unknown for politicians; there is an information<br />

problem).<br />

<strong>The</strong> traditional understanding of corruption <strong>dynamics</strong> (Silver-or-lead) argues that killings increase with<br />

trafficker’s power because bribes get substituted <strong>by</strong> political violence. Powerful <strong>traffickers</strong> do not c<strong>are</strong><br />

about making deals with politicians; they just kill them (dashed line). I argue that killings we can also think<br />

on killings as complement of bribes (bold line). When bribes <strong>are</strong> high, <strong>traffickers</strong> want to kill more because<br />

killing diminishes the price of bribes <strong>by</strong> changing politicians’ beliefs about <strong>traffickers</strong>’ power. Lower bribes<br />

give <strong>traffickers</strong> fewer incentives to be violent.<br />

3


Figure 1: <strong>Mexican</strong> <strong>mayors</strong> assassinated <strong>by</strong> DTOs<br />

14<br />

12<br />

10<br />

8<br />

6<br />

4<br />

2<br />

0<br />

0 0 0 0 0<br />

12<br />

6<br />

3<br />

2 2<br />

1<br />

0<br />

2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010<br />

Mexico’s total lack of political violence until 2004 is as puzzling as the following spike.<br />

Source: Author based on press and official reports<br />

Figure 2: Drug trafficking moves from Mexico to Colombia (proxies)<br />

(2.1) Journalist murdered <strong>by</strong> confirmed/unconfirmed motives<br />

10<br />

8<br />

6<br />

4<br />

2<br />

0<br />

-2<br />

1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010<br />

Mexico<br />

Colombia<br />

<strong>Mexican</strong> press has been increasingly assassinated <strong>by</strong> organized crime, as trafficking has moved from<br />

Colombia to Mexico (See Appendix 2 for a complete list of assassinated <strong>Mexican</strong> journalists assassinated<br />

during the last four years <strong>by</strong> name, media and place)<br />

Note: Not counted <strong>are</strong> other seven journalists which have disappe<strong>are</strong>d in Mexico since 2007. <strong>The</strong> direct<br />

implication of DTOs has not been officially proved in all instances given that most of the judicial cases <strong>are</strong><br />

still open.<br />

Source: Lauria and Mike O'Connor (2010) complemented <strong>by</strong> author.<br />

4


Figure 3: <strong>Mexican</strong> DTOs presence, <strong>by</strong> drug type (1990 – 2008)<br />

Overdosis deaths<br />

50<br />

45<br />

40<br />

35<br />

30<br />

25<br />

20<br />

15<br />

10<br />

5<br />

0<br />

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008<br />

Opium Marihuana Cocaine Total<br />

<strong>Mexican</strong> DTOs’ presence increases from 1990 to 2004, and sharply decline from 2005 to 2007. Profits<br />

from opium have diminished over time, marihuana was profitable only during the late nineties, and<br />

cocaine experienced a boom from 1998 until 2005. Profits from hallucinogens (not pictured) and other<br />

synthetic drugs, boomed in the early 2000-2003.<br />

Note: I use number of overdoses deaths in Mexico as a proxy of DTOs presence (Rios 2010a). I rely in two<br />

assumptions: (a) overdoses happen with a fixed probability among consumers, and (b) the correlation<br />

between domestic and international profits is positive and fixed over time.<br />

Source: Author compilation based on <strong>Mexican</strong> census information (Rios 2010a).<br />

Figure 4: Drug-related deaths (2007 – August 2010)<br />

1400<br />

1200<br />

1000<br />

Drug-related homicides<br />

800<br />

600<br />

400<br />

200<br />

0<br />

J F M A M J J A S O N D<br />

2007 2008 2009 2010<br />

Drug related deaths increased in 2008, and 2010, and remained stable in 2007 and 2009. From 2007 until<br />

August 16 th , 2010 official intelligence reports (XX –closed source) had accounted for 26,739 drug related<br />

assassinations, most of them in Chihuahua. Independent media accounts, less accurate, counted 21,806<br />

assassinations for the same period. Source: Duran and Rios (2010) and (XX –closed source)<br />

5


Figure 5: Strength of <strong>Mexican</strong> <strong>traffickers</strong> versus the state (1995 – 2009)<br />

2<br />

1<br />

0<br />

-1<br />

-2<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009<br />

Strenght of Drug <strong>traffickers</strong> (market presence)<br />

State capacity to prosecute (Military personel)<br />

State capacity to investigate (AFI agents)<br />

Traffickers were more powerful than the state in the late nineties, and the period immediately before the<br />

drug battles exploited. Mayors have been assassinated the most in the periods where drug <strong>traffickers</strong><br />

have been the least powerful.<br />

Note: <strong>The</strong> strength of drug <strong>traffickers</strong> was calculated using drug consumption measures (see Table 4).<br />

State capacity to investigate was measured as the number of law enforcement officials working at the<br />

Federal Agency of Investigations (Agencia Federal de Investigaciones, AFI). State capacity to prosecute<br />

was measured as the number of active elements at the army and the military (Secretaria de Defensa<br />

Nacional (Sedena) and Secretaria de Marina (Semar)). All measures were normalized for comparison.<br />

Figures for 2009 <strong>are</strong> linearly projected, based on monthly averages.<br />

Source: Guerrero etal (2010) and author compilation based on <strong>Mexican</strong> census information (Rios 2010a).<br />

Figure 6: Size of <strong>Mexican</strong> domestic illegal-drug market (1990 – 2008)<br />

600<br />

500<br />

400<br />

300<br />

200<br />

100<br />

0<br />

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008<br />

Municipalities with openned domestic drug markets<br />

Overdoses fatalities<br />

A domestic market is considered to be opened when at least one overdoses fatality happened in the<br />

municipality. This measure underestimates consumption for municipalities with fewer population.<br />

Source: Author compilation based on <strong>Mexican</strong> census information (Rios 2010a).<br />

6


Figure 7: Causes of political assassinations, case <strong>by</strong> case (1999 – 2010)<br />

Name Municipality State Date Territorial fight Reason?<br />

Jose Manuel Soto Ortiz Otaez** Durango July 8, 2004 Sinaloa vs Linea Had nexus with Sinaloa<br />

Esteban Estrada Corral Otaez Durango October 5, 2004 Sinaloa vs Linea Retailiation for his debts or nexus with a DTO, both motives were investigated<br />

Fernando Chavez Lopez Buenavista Michoacan July 8, 2005 Refused to pay quota to Golf<br />

Raul Delgado Benavides Cuauhtitlan de GB Jalisco July 16, 2006 Not-drug related<br />

Walter Herrera Ramirez Huimanguillo Tabasco November 16, 2006 Milenio vs Valencia<br />

Marcelo Ibarra Villa Villa Madero Michoacan June 1, 2008<br />

Homero Lorenzo Rios Ayutla de los Libres Guerrero September 25, 2008 Yes (not specified)<br />

Salvador Vergara Ixtapan de la Sal Mexico October 4, 2008 Refused to be extorted <strong>by</strong> La Familia<br />

PRD says that groups linked to PRI <strong>are</strong> guilty; others argue he was linked to<br />

trafficking but no evidence.<br />

Claudio Reyes Nunez Otaez Durango February 6, 2009 Sinaloa vs Linea Retailiation for asassination of mayor Manuel Soto<br />

Raul Mendivil Sotelo Guadalupe y Calvo Chihuahua February 17, 2009 Sinaloa vs. Linea Signaling to federal government<br />

Octavio Carrillo Vista Hermosa Michoacan February 24, 2009 Retailiation for firing policemen<br />

Luis Carlos Ramirez Ocampo Durango June 1, 2009 Sinaloa vs. Linea Denounced to federation<br />

Manuel de Jesus Angulo Topia* Durango June 3, 2009 Sinaloa vs. Linea Linea vs Sinaloa<br />

Hector Ariel Meixueiro Namiquipa Chihuahua July 14, 2009 Sinaloa vs Linea Linea vs Sinaloa<br />

Bernardo Mecinas Lopez Animas Trujano Oaxaca February 19, 2010<br />

Manuel Estrada Mezquital Durango February 22, 2010 Sinaloa vs Linea Signaling to governor<br />

Jose Santiago Agustino Zapotitlan Tablas Guerrero April 28, 2010<br />

Manuel Lara Rodriguez Guadalupe Chihuahua June 19, 2010 Sinaloa vs. Linea Had nexus with Linea; her daughter was dating a trafficker<br />

Oscar Venancio Martinez San Jose del Progreso Oaxaca June 19, 2010 Not-drug related<br />

Nicolas Garcia Ambrosio Sto Dom de Morelos Oaxaca June 30, 2010 Not-drug related<br />

Alfonso Pena Pena Tepehuanes* Durango July 26, 2010 Sinaloa vs. Linea Denounced to federation<br />

Edelmiro Cavazos Leal Santiago NL August 18, 2010 Zetas because he was interfering with business<br />

Marco Antonio Leal Hidalgo Tamaulipas August 28, 2010 Golfo vs Zetas<br />

Alexander Lopez Garcia El Naranjo SLP September 8, 2010 Called federal forces<br />

Prisciliano Rodriguez Dr Gonzalez NlL September 24, 2010 Golfo vs Zetas<br />

Jesus Montejano Tancitaro Michoacan September 28, 2010<br />

Mayors began to be <strong>killed</strong>/disappe<strong>are</strong>d in 2004; 26 have been <strong>killed</strong> until September 2010, 24 in relation with drug trafficking; I found the cause of the murder<br />

for 20 of the 24 drug-related cases. Note: * disappe<strong>are</strong>d, ** elected but had not taken office yet; the DTO to which the killing was attributed is underlined.<br />

7


Appendix 1: Notation<br />

N – Drug trafficker<br />

M – Illegal profits<br />

A – Politician<br />

Pn – Trafficker’s strength (power of violence)<br />

Pa – Politician’s strength (power of violence)<br />

b – Bribe (aka silver); given as a sh<strong>are</strong> of total drug trafficking profits<br />

k – Kill (aka lead); either 0 or 1<br />

e – Enforce; positive if enforcing law, negative if protecting criminals<br />

pi – Politician’s believes; probability of trafficker’s power of violence to be higher than<br />

politician’s.<br />

DTO – Drug traffic organization<br />

Appendix 2: Definitions, Axioms, Lemmas, Results and Empirical Insights<br />

Definition 1: Corruption is a bargaining game in which N and A agree on the price of a<br />

bribe (b).<br />

Definition 2: N decides between paying b, and exerting political violence (k) (i.e. killing<br />

A)<br />

Definition 3: A decides between rejecting b and prosecute/ignore crime crimes (e>=0),<br />

and accepting b and protect/ignore crimes (e0 is a necessary but not sufficient condition for trafficking to exist.<br />

Axiom 2: b decreases in Pn and increases in Pa.<br />

Axiom 3: Negotiating the value of b is costly.<br />

Axiom 4: k is affected <strong>by</strong> r<br />

Lemma 1: N prefers to have an A than to become the state themselves, independently<br />

of Pn and Pa.<br />

Lemma 2: k does not necessarily increase in Pn<br />

Lemma 3: Because k builds pi, k reduces b<br />

Lemma 4: N does not always prefer to face a small Pa<br />

Result 1: <strong>The</strong> concavity of b’ is undetermined. “Sometimes bribing more is less, not more<br />

expensive, and sometimes politicians want small bribes”<br />

Result 2: If b0, k>0 is required for b=0 “No-silver and lead”<br />

Result 5: When M>0, k=0 if and only if b=M is a viable equilibrium “Silver and no-lead”<br />

8


Result 6: When M>0, only corrupt A will take office, unless b=M is a viable equilibrium<br />

“To be completely virtuous, one need to be able to be completely corrupt”<br />

Insight 1: Traffickers <strong>are</strong> not stronger, government is not (necessarily) weaker, and yet<br />

politicians <strong>are</strong> <strong>getting</strong> <strong>killed</strong> more.<br />

Insight 2: Decentralization made sub-national politicians potential corruption suppliers<br />

Insight 3a: Changes in Mexico’s illegal-drug industry (i.e. DTOs becoming multiproduct<br />

and domestic sellers) created a demand for sub-national corruption.<br />

Insight 3b: Changes in Mexico’s illegal-drug industry (i.e. DTOs becoming more<br />

competitive) increased the price of bribes, and made killing more valuable as a signal.<br />

Appendix 3: <strong>Mexican</strong> journalists murdered<br />

(a) Motive confirmed<br />

Journalists slain in direct relation to their work:<br />

1 Rodolfo Rincon Taracena, Tabasco Hoy, January 20, 2007, Villahermosa<br />

2 Amado Ramirez Dillanes, Televisa and Radiorama, April 6, 2007, Acapulco<br />

3 Alejandro Zenon Fonseca Estrada, EXA FM , September 24, 2008, Villahermosa<br />

4 Armando Rodriguez Carreon, El Diario de Ciudad Ju<strong>are</strong>z, November 13, 2008, Ciudad<br />

Ju<strong>are</strong>z<br />

5 Eliseo Barron Hernandez, La Opinion, May 25, 2009, Gomez Palacio<br />

6 Norberto Miranda Madrid, Radio Vision, September 23, 2009, Nuevo Casas Grandes<br />

7 Bladimir Antuna Garcia, El Tiempo de Durango, November 2, 2009, Durango<br />

8 Valentin Valdes Espinosa, Zocalo de Saltillo, January 8, 2010, Saltillo<br />

Media support workers slain in the course of their duties:<br />

9 Flor Vasquez Lopez, El Imparcial del Istmo, October 8, 2007, between Salina Cruz and<br />

Tehuantepec<br />

10 Mateo Cortes Martinez, El Imparcial del Istmo, October 8, 2007, between Salina Cruz<br />

and Tehuantepec<br />

11 Agustin Lopez Nolasco, El Imparcial del Istmo, October 8, 2007, between Salina Cruz<br />

and Tehuantepec<br />

Journalists missing<br />

12 Gamaliel Lopez Candanosa, TV Azteca Noreste, May 10, 2007, Monterrey<br />

13 Gerardo P<strong>are</strong>des Perez, TV Azteca Noreste, May 10, 2007, Monterrey<br />

14 Maria Esther Aguilar Cansimbe,, El Diario de Zamora and Cambio de Michoacan,<br />

November 11, 2009, Zamora<br />

15 David Silva, El Manana and La Tarde, March 2010, Reynosa<br />

16 Pedro Argüello, El Manana and La Tarde, March 2010, Reynosa<br />

17 Miguel Angel Dominguez Zamora, El Manana, March 2010, Reynosa<br />

18 Ramon Angeles Zalpa, Cambio de Michoacan, April 6, 2010, Paracho,<br />

(b) Motive unconfirmed<br />

Journalist possibly slain for their work:<br />

19 Saul Noe Martinez Ortega, Interdiario, April 2007, Nuevo Casas Grandes,<br />

9


20 Gerardo Israel Garcia Pimentel, La Opinion de Michoacan, December 8, 2007,<br />

Uruapan,<br />

21 Mauricio Estrada Zamora, La Opinion de Apatzingan, February 12, 2008,<br />

Apatzingan,<br />

22 Teresa Bautista Merino, La Voz que Rompe el Silencio, April 7, 2008, Putla de<br />

Guerrero,<br />

23 Felicitas Martinez Sanchez, La Voz que Rompe el Silencio, April 7, 2008, Putla de<br />

Guerrero,<br />

24 Miguel Angel Villagomez Valle, La Noticia de Michoacan, October 10, 2008,<br />

between Lazaro Cardenas and Zihuatanejo,<br />

25 Jean Paul Ibarra Ramirez, El Correo, February 13, 2009, Iguala,<br />

26 Carlos Ortega Samper, El Tiempo de Durango , May 3, 2009, Santa Maria del Oro,<br />

27 Juan Daniel Martinez Gil, Radiorama and W Radio , July 28, 2009, Acapulco,<br />

28 Jose Emilio Galindo Robles, Radio Universidad de Guadalajara, November 24, 2009,<br />

Ciudad Guzman,<br />

29 Jose Alberto Velazquez Lopez, Expresiones de Tulum, December 22, 2009, Tulum,<br />

30 Jose Luis Romero, Linea Directa, January 2010, Los Mochis,<br />

31 Jorge Ochoa Martinez, El Sol de la Costa, January 29, 2010, Ayutla de los Libres,<br />

32 Evaristo Pacheco Solis, Vision Informativa, March 12, 2010, Chilpancingo<br />

Appendix 4: Drug-related murders in municipalities with/without political violence<br />

(2007 – September 2010)<br />

40<br />

35<br />

30<br />

25<br />

20<br />

15<br />

10<br />

5<br />

0<br />

1<br />

1<br />

1<br />

3<br />

2<br />

1<br />

2<br />

1<br />

1<br />

1<br />

2<br />

3<br />

Jan, 2007<br />

Feb, 2007<br />

Mar, 2007<br />

Apr, 2007<br />

May, 2007<br />

Jun, 2007<br />

Jul, 2007<br />

Aug, 2007<br />

Sep, 2007<br />

Oct, 2007<br />

Nov, 2007<br />

Dec, 2007<br />

Jan, 2008<br />

Feb, 2008<br />

Mar, 2008<br />

Apr, 2008<br />

May, 2008<br />

Jun, 2008<br />

Jul, 2008<br />

Aug, 2008<br />

Sep, 2008<br />

Oct, 2008<br />

Nov, 2008<br />

Dec, 2008<br />

Jan, 2009<br />

Feb, 2009<br />

Mar, 2009<br />

Apr, 2009<br />

May, 2009<br />

Jun, 2009<br />

Jul, 2009<br />

Aug, 2009<br />

Sep, 2009<br />

Oct, 2009<br />

Nov, 2009<br />

Dec, 2009<br />

Jan, 2010<br />

Feb, 2010<br />

Mar, 2010<br />

Apr, 2010<br />

May, 2010<br />

Jun, 2010<br />

Jul, 2010<br />

Aug, 2010<br />

Sep, 2010<br />

Total<br />

Mayor (drug related)<br />

Drug-related murders at non-politically<br />

violent municiaplities<br />

1400<br />

1200<br />

1000<br />

800<br />

600<br />

400<br />

200<br />

0<br />

Jan, 2007<br />

Feb, 2007<br />

Mar, 2007<br />

Apr, 2007<br />

May, 2007<br />

Jun, 2007<br />

Jul, 2007<br />

Aug, 2007<br />

Sep, 2007<br />

Oct, 2007<br />

Nov, 2007<br />

Dec, 2007<br />

Jan, 2008<br />

Feb, 2008<br />

Mar, 2008<br />

Apr, 2008<br />

May, 2008<br />

Jun, 2008<br />

Jul, 2008<br />

Aug, 2008<br />

Sep, 2008<br />

Oct, 2008<br />

Nov, 2008<br />

Dec, 2008<br />

Jan, 2009<br />

Feb, 2009<br />

Mar, 2009<br />

Apr, 2009<br />

May, 2009<br />

Jun, 2009<br />

Jul, 2009<br />

Aug, 2009<br />

Sep, 2009<br />

Oct, 2009<br />

Nov, 2009<br />

Dec, 2009<br />

Jan, 2010<br />

Feb, 2010<br />

Mar, 2010<br />

Apr, 2010<br />

May, 2010<br />

Jun, 2010<br />

Jul, 2010<br />

Aug, 2010<br />

Sep, 2010<br />

Political violence increases as general violence increase but does not necessarily happen in the most<br />

violent periods. Drug-related deaths in non-politically violent municipalities follows an increasing trend<br />

not matched <strong>by</strong> politically violent municipalities.<br />

Source: Rios 2010a and (XX –closed source)<br />

General<br />

10


11<br />

Appendix 5: Drug-related deaths at states where <strong>mayors</strong> were assassinated<br />

Chihuahua<br />

0<br />

10<br />

20<br />

30<br />

40<br />

50<br />

60<br />

70<br />

80<br />

90<br />

42/07<br />

46/07<br />

52/07<br />

3/08<br />

7/08<br />

11/08<br />

15/08<br />

19/08<br />

23/08<br />

27/08<br />

31/08<br />

35/08<br />

39/08<br />

43/08<br />

47/08<br />

51/08<br />

3/09<br />

7/09<br />

11/09<br />

15/09<br />

19/09<br />

23/09<br />

27/09<br />

31/09<br />

35/09<br />

39/09<br />

43/09<br />

47/09<br />

51/09<br />

3/10<br />

7/10<br />

11/10<br />

15/10<br />

19/10<br />

23/10<br />

27/10<br />

31/10<br />

35/10<br />

Durango<br />

0<br />

10<br />

20<br />

30<br />

42/07<br />

46/07<br />

52/07<br />

3/08<br />

7/08<br />

11/08<br />

15/08<br />

19/08<br />

23/08<br />

27/08<br />

31/08<br />

35/08<br />

39/08<br />

43/08<br />

47/08<br />

51/08<br />

3/09<br />

7/09<br />

11/09<br />

15/09<br />

19/09<br />

23/09<br />

27/09<br />

31/09<br />

35/09<br />

39/09<br />

43/09<br />

47/09<br />

51/09<br />

3/10<br />

7/10<br />

11/10<br />

15/10<br />

19/10<br />

23/10<br />

27/10<br />

31/10<br />

35/10<br />

Guerrero<br />

0<br />

10<br />

20<br />

30<br />

42/07<br />

46/07<br />

52/07<br />

3/08<br />

7/08<br />

11/08<br />

15/08<br />

19/08<br />

23/08<br />

27/08<br />

31/08<br />

35/08<br />

39/08<br />

43/08<br />

47/08<br />

51/08<br />

3/09<br />

7/09<br />

11/09<br />

15/09<br />

19/09<br />

23/09<br />

27/09<br />

31/09<br />

35/09<br />

39/09<br />

43/09<br />

47/09<br />

51/09<br />

3/10<br />

7/10<br />

11/10<br />

15/10<br />

19/10<br />

23/10<br />

27/10<br />

31/10<br />

35/10<br />

Estado de Mexico<br />

0<br />

10<br />

20<br />

30<br />

42/07<br />

46/07<br />

52/07<br />

3/08<br />

7/08<br />

11/08<br />

15/08<br />

19/08<br />

23/08<br />

27/08<br />

31/08<br />

35/08<br />

39/08<br />

43/08<br />

47/08<br />

51/08<br />

3/09<br />

7/09<br />

11/09<br />

15/09<br />

19/09<br />

23/09<br />

27/09<br />

31/09<br />

35/09<br />

39/09<br />

43/09<br />

47/09<br />

51/09<br />

3/10<br />

7/10<br />

11/10<br />

15/10<br />

19/10<br />

23/10<br />

27/10<br />

31/10<br />

35/10<br />

Michoacan<br />

0<br />

10<br />

20<br />

30<br />

42/07<br />

46/07<br />

52/07<br />

3/08<br />

7/08<br />

11/08<br />

15/08<br />

19/08<br />

23/08<br />

27/08<br />

31/08<br />

35/08<br />

39/08<br />

43/08<br />

47/08<br />

51/08<br />

3/09<br />

7/09<br />

11/09<br />

15/09<br />

19/09<br />

23/09<br />

27/09<br />

31/09<br />

35/09<br />

39/09<br />

43/09<br />

47/09<br />

51/09<br />

3/10<br />

7/10<br />

11/10<br />

15/10<br />

19/10<br />

23/10<br />

27/10<br />

31/10<br />

35/10


12<br />

Nuevo Leon<br />

0<br />

10<br />

20<br />

30<br />

40<br />

50<br />

42/07<br />

46/07<br />

52/07<br />

3/08<br />

7/08<br />

11/08<br />

15/08<br />

19/08<br />

23/08<br />

27/08<br />

31/08<br />

35/08<br />

39/08<br />

43/08<br />

47/08<br />

51/08<br />

3/09<br />

7/09<br />

11/09<br />

15/09<br />

19/09<br />

23/09<br />

27/09<br />

31/09<br />

35/09<br />

39/09<br />

43/09<br />

47/09<br />

51/09<br />

3/10<br />

7/10<br />

11/10<br />

15/10<br />

19/10<br />

23/10<br />

27/10<br />

31/10<br />

35/10<br />

Tamaulipas<br />

0<br />

10<br />

20<br />

30<br />

40<br />

50<br />

60<br />

70<br />

80<br />

90<br />

42/07<br />

46/07<br />

52/07<br />

3/08<br />

7/08<br />

11/08<br />

15/08<br />

19/08<br />

23/08<br />

27/08<br />

31/08<br />

35/08<br />

39/08<br />

43/08<br />

47/08<br />

51/08<br />

3/09<br />

7/09<br />

11/09<br />

15/09<br />

19/09<br />

23/09<br />

27/09<br />

31/09<br />

35/09<br />

39/09<br />

43/09<br />

47/09<br />

51/09<br />

3/10<br />

7/10<br />

11/10<br />

15/10<br />

19/10<br />

23/10<br />

27/10<br />

31/10<br />

35/10

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!