01.01.2014 Views

Supreme Court Agenda Setting in a System of Shared Powers Ryan ...

Supreme Court Agenda Setting in a System of Shared Powers Ryan ...

Supreme Court Agenda Setting in a System of Shared Powers Ryan ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

6 The Journal <strong>of</strong> Law, Economics, & Organization. V0 N0<br />

colleagues (see, e.g. Maltzman, Spriggs and Wahlbeck, 2000) and, perhaps,<br />

the political branches (Epste<strong>in</strong> and Knight, 1998; Rosenberg, 1991).<br />

Of course, this begs the question, why would the <strong>Court</strong> follow congressional<br />

and presidential preferences? One answer to this question turns on the appo<strong>in</strong>tment<br />

process. Dahl (1957) argues that judicial decision mak<strong>in</strong>g is majoritarian<br />

because presidents and senators, on average, nom<strong>in</strong>ate and confirm a new justice<br />

every two years. S<strong>in</strong>ce politicians can only be expected to appo<strong>in</strong>t justices<br />

whose ideologies track their own, the <strong>Court</strong> should be composed <strong>of</strong> justices<br />

sympathetic to the policy aims <strong>of</strong> the rul<strong>in</strong>g majority (Rehnquist, 1987). As a<br />

result, the <strong>Court</strong> rarely—if ever—will render decisions <strong>in</strong> a manner counter to<br />

the majority’s policy goals. Indeed, this assumption largely undergirds recent<br />

attacks on lifetime tenure (Calabresi and L<strong>in</strong>dgren, 2006a).<br />

A second answer—the one made by strategic SOP theorists—argues that the<br />

<strong>Court</strong> will buckle under congressional and executive preferences because the<br />

political branches have the constitutional authority to punish the <strong>Court</strong> and pass<br />

legislation that alters its policies (Epste<strong>in</strong>, Knight and Mart<strong>in</strong>, 2001). Congress<br />

can <strong>in</strong>itiate and support constitutional amendments to overturn judicial decisions.<br />

It can reduce the <strong>Court</strong>’s budget, alter its composition, strip it <strong>of</strong> jurisdiction,<br />

regulate <strong>Court</strong> procedure, hold judicial salaries constant, and impeach justices<br />

(George and Epste<strong>in</strong>, 1992). Perhaps most importantly, Congress can pass<br />

legislation that overrides <strong>Supreme</strong> <strong>Court</strong> decisions. S<strong>in</strong>ce 1975, each Congress<br />

has overridden an average <strong>of</strong> roughly twelve statutory <strong>in</strong>terpretation decisions<br />

and, dur<strong>in</strong>g the same time period, nearly half <strong>of</strong> the <strong>Court</strong>’s decisions received<br />

some type <strong>of</strong> congressional hear<strong>in</strong>g (Eskridge, 1991; Ignagni and Meernik,<br />

1994). These data suggest that Congress has the ability to respond to <strong>Supreme</strong><br />

<strong>Court</strong> decisions it dislikes and, if it so chooses, to act swiftly.<br />

Presidents also, the story goes, may <strong>in</strong>fluence the <strong>Court</strong>. “Even the members<br />

<strong>of</strong> the <strong>Court</strong> not appo<strong>in</strong>ted by the sitt<strong>in</strong>g president understand that the president’s<br />

status as a nationally elected <strong>of</strong>ficial and his position at the re<strong>in</strong>s <strong>of</strong> every<br />

executive branch agency make him a formidable foe under any circumstance”<br />

(Yal<strong>of</strong>, 2005, 501). Presidents can refuse to enforce the <strong>Court</strong>’s decisions and<br />

order Cab<strong>in</strong>et Secretaries and other high-rank<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong>ficials to ignore them. They<br />

can unilaterally create their own executive policies and shift the policy status<br />

quo (Moe and Howell, 1999; Black et al., 2007), mobilize <strong>in</strong>terest groups to<br />

attack and underm<strong>in</strong>e the <strong>Court</strong>’s decisions (Peterson, 1992), and use their<br />

agenda-sett<strong>in</strong>g power to focus public scrut<strong>in</strong>y on judicial decisions. And, <strong>of</strong><br />

course, they can sign or veto override legislation.<br />

In sum, strategic SOP theorists argue that the comb<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> these powers—<br />

even the threat <strong>of</strong> their use—will force the <strong>Court</strong> to anticipate how Congress<br />

and the president will respond to its decisions and make policy <strong>in</strong> compliance<br />

with majoritarian preferences. (Spiller and Gely, 1992; Bergara, Richman and<br />

Spiller, 2003; Harvey and Friedman, 2006; Epste<strong>in</strong> and Knight, 1998). Accord<strong>in</strong>g<br />

to these scholars, if the <strong>Court</strong> (i.e., the <strong>Court</strong> median) perceives that<br />

by vot<strong>in</strong>g for its most preferred alternative it will create policy out <strong>of</strong> step with<br />

key policymakers, it will moderate its decision so as to make policy that is<br />

more favorable to them. Influence from the elected branches, then, forces the

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!