25.07.2014 Views

Delay and Haircuts in Sovereign Debt - University of St Andrews

Delay and Haircuts in Sovereign Debt - University of St Andrews

Delay and Haircuts in Sovereign Debt - University of St Andrews

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

(<br />

s)<br />

2<br />

is the creditor’s cont<strong>in</strong>uation value. By computation, it follows that<br />

~x 2 = 2 <br />

2 +<br />

s<br />

2 . Let x0 2 be any positive number such that x0 ( s)<br />

2 <<br />

2<br />

,<br />

<br />

+<br />

s<br />

2 .<br />

where ~x 2 < x 0 2 < . It follows that x0 2 > 2 <br />

2<br />

In a mixed strategy 21 , the Optimistic debtor may r<strong>and</strong>omize between a<br />

high o¤er ~x 2 <strong>and</strong> a low o¤er x 0 2 . Suppose the Optimistic debtor o¤ers<br />

(~x 2 ; ~x 2 ) with a probability (1 ) <strong>and</strong> o¤ers (x 0 2 ; x0 2 ) with a probability<br />

, while the Cautious debtor o¤ers (x 0 2 ; x0 2 ) with a probability 1.<br />

Recall that the creditor’s posterior belief at t = 3, is given by q 1 = s<br />

.<br />

Updat<strong>in</strong>g the belief accord<strong>in</strong>g to the Bayesian updat<strong>in</strong>g rule implies that, <strong>in</strong><br />

the equilibrium, the Optimistic debtor o¤ers (x 0 2 ; <br />

such that q 1 =<br />

that<br />

q 0<br />

q 0 +(1<br />

Solv<strong>in</strong>g equation (A4) for yields:<br />

x0 2 ) with a probability<br />

q 0 ) , where q 0 is the creditor’s prior belief. It follows<br />

q 0<br />

q 0 + (1 q 0 ) = s<br />

: (A4)<br />

s 1<br />

=<br />

s<br />

To ensure that < 1, it requires that<br />

s 1<br />

s<br />

q 0<br />

q0<br />

<br />

q 0<br />

q0<br />

<br />

.<br />

< 1 , (1 q 0 ) < s , q 0 > s<br />

: (A5)<br />

Condition (A5) implies that, for a delay <strong>in</strong> the second period to exist,<br />

the susta<strong>in</strong>ability concern needs to be su¢ ciently important or the creditor’s<br />

prior that the debtor is Optimistic is su¢ ciently high s<strong>in</strong>ce, <strong>in</strong> these two<br />

cases, the value <strong>of</strong> signall<strong>in</strong>g is greater. As long as q 0 > s , there exists<br />

<br />

2 (0; 1) which solves equation (A4). For the creditor, by observ<strong>in</strong>g x 0 2 , it<br />

follows that q 1 = s<br />

. Given q 1 = s<br />

<br />

, the creditor is <strong>in</strong>di¤erent between<br />

accept<strong>in</strong>g (~x 2 ; ~x 2 ) <strong>and</strong> reject<strong>in</strong>g it (<strong>and</strong> obta<strong>in</strong>s his cont<strong>in</strong>uation value).<br />

From condition (A5), we have q 0 > s<br />

<br />

. Let us denote the lower bound<br />

for q 0 by q = s<br />

. It is obvious that q0 1 < q. The creditor accepts (~x 2; ~x 2 )<br />

with a probability <strong>and</strong> rejects it with a probability (1 ). After observ<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the o¤er (x 0 2 ; x0 2 ), the creditor rejects the debtor’s o¤er with a probability<br />

1. The debtor’s expected payo¤ from an o¤er (~x 2 ; ~x 2 ) is given by ~x 2 +<br />

(1 ) <br />

2 , where<br />

<br />

2<br />

is the cont<strong>in</strong>uation value for the Optimistic debtor,<br />

21 See Spence (1974) <strong>and</strong> Fudenberg <strong>and</strong> Tirole (1991).<br />

30

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!