23.01.2015 Views

Estimation of Educational Borrowing Constraints Using Returns to ...

Estimation of Educational Borrowing Constraints Using Returns to ...

Estimation of Educational Borrowing Constraints Using Returns to ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

educational borrowing constraints 151<br />

Second, schooling is a choice among more than two options, so the<br />

Imbens and Angrist (1994) results do not apply directly. Instead, instrumental<br />

variable estimates will be a weighted average <strong>of</strong> returns for<br />

marginal decision makers at each level <strong>of</strong> schooling. The weights in the<br />

average will likely depend on the instrument used. We strongly expect<br />

that if borrowing constraints are important, the coefficient on schooling<br />

will be higher when direct costs are the instrument, but we have not<br />

formally proved this result. A major advantage <strong>of</strong> the structural econometric<br />

model developed below is that identification <strong>of</strong> borrowing constraints<br />

is formally justified.<br />

B. First-Stage Results<br />

This subsection presents first-stage estimates <strong>to</strong> demonstrate that the<br />

instruments have predictive power in the first stage and that their signs<br />

are consistent with the model presented above. Because individuals appear<br />

in our data only after leaving school, the variable measuring schooling<br />

attainment is constant. This makes for difficult interpretation <strong>of</strong> a<br />

first-stage panel regression <strong>of</strong> schooling on time-varying local labor market<br />

variables and other characteristics. However, <strong>to</strong> convey the content<br />

<strong>of</strong> the first-stage regressions, we construct the variable mean local earnings<br />

over working life, which takes the mean value <strong>of</strong> l it over the years<br />

in which the individual is included in the wage regressions. We regress<br />

schooling on this variable, local earnings at age 17, an indica<strong>to</strong>r for the<br />

presence <strong>of</strong> a college in the county (local college), and a number <strong>of</strong><br />

other control variables.<br />

The first row in column 1 <strong>of</strong> table 2 shows that local college has a<br />

large and statistically significant effect, implying that individuals with a<br />

college in their county complete almost one-half year more <strong>of</strong> school,<br />

on average. The other covariates have estimates with signs and magnitudes<br />

consistent with those reported in other work (see, e.g., Cameron<br />

and Heckman 2001).<br />

Column 2 reports estimates when local earnings at age 17 is included<br />

in the regression instead <strong>of</strong> local college (row 2). The estimated coefficient<br />

has the expected negative sign but is not statistically significant<br />

at conventional levels. This variable apparently reflects both time-series<br />

variation in county earnings due <strong>to</strong> business cycle effects and crosssectional<br />

differences in average earnings and wealth across counties.<br />

Adding mean local earnings over working life <strong>to</strong> control for levels <strong>of</strong><br />

wealth across counties allows us <strong>to</strong> sort out these two avenues <strong>of</strong> influence.<br />

The third row <strong>of</strong> column 3 shows that the coefficient on the new<br />

variable is significant and positive, indicating that students from wealthier<br />

counties are more likely <strong>to</strong> attend college—perhaps as a result <strong>of</strong><br />

superior schools or peer effects. In addition, the coefficient on local

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!