27.01.2015 Views

Through a Glass Darkly: Measuring Loss Under ... - Land Use Law

Through a Glass Darkly: Measuring Loss Under ... - Land Use Law

Through a Glass Darkly: Measuring Loss Under ... - Land Use Law

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

594 THE URBAN LAWYER VOL. 39, NO. 3 SUMMER 2007<br />

<strong>Use</strong> of the fair market value at the time of purchase (historical FMV),<br />

rather than the actual price of purchase, reduces the public payment<br />

payable by $85,000. 114 This sum represents a windfall to the landowner;<br />

rather than merely compensating for the reduction in value of his property<br />

caused by the land use regulation, the utilization of the actual purchase<br />

price additionally “compensates” landowners for their irrational<br />

(in economic terms) overpayment at the time of purchase.<br />

A potentially more serious challenge to the Plantinga/Jaeger method<br />

arises from the assumption, made in order to arrive at the hypothetical<br />

value, that the income stream from the property would have remained<br />

constant between the time of the original purchase and the date of the<br />

Measure 37 claim had the land use regulation not been enacted. While<br />

land markets are comparatively stable, this assumption undoubtedly<br />

detracts from the accuracy of their method.<br />

To see why this is the case, it is important to revisit the lessons learned<br />

from the failings of the exemption method. It will be remembered that<br />

the exemption method was based on a fallacious rationale, and that, in<br />

light of the criticisms of its rationale, it was concluded that any accurate<br />

valuation method must at least purport to capture “the difference<br />

between the current value of the property and the [hypothetical] value<br />

of the property that would have existed if the regulation had not been<br />

imposed in the first place.” 115<br />

In order to capture this differential it is clearly vital to delineate those<br />

variations in land value which are attributable in some way to the land<br />

use regulation and those which are wholly extraneous. Unfortunately,<br />

there is an implicit assumption made by Plantinga and Jaeger that any<br />

variance in the actual income stream between the time of purchase and<br />

date of the claim is entirely due to the implementation of the land use<br />

regulation in question. While the value of the land may be reduced by<br />

any number of causes related or unrelated to the land use regulation, the<br />

value of the hypothetical land in the Plantinga/Jaeger method is impervious<br />

to any such variables. The method operates so as to insulate the<br />

hypothetical value from the vagaries of the property market, freezing<br />

the income stream at the date of purchase. In doing so, because the<br />

actual value of the property (and its income stream) is affected by the<br />

vagaries of the land market, so the “compensation”—the differential<br />

between the value of the hypothetical and value of the actual land—is<br />

affected by all causes since the property was purchased. Thus, the<br />

114. $440,000 − $355,000 $85,000.<br />

115. Hascic & Wu, supra note 77, at 3.<br />

ABA-TUL-07-0701-Sullivan.indd 594<br />

9/18/07 10:43:42 AM

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!