02.12.2012 Views

Chapter 6 Why Authoritarian Parties? The Regime Party as an ...

Chapter 6 Why Authoritarian Parties? The Regime Party as an ...

Chapter 6 Why Authoritarian Parties? The Regime Party as an ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Chapter</strong> 6<br />

<strong>Why</strong> <strong>Authoritari<strong>an</strong></strong> <strong>Parties</strong>? <strong>The</strong><br />

<strong>Regime</strong> <strong>Party</strong> <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> Instrument of<br />

Cooptation <strong>an</strong>d Control<br />

While a party card is of course no guar<strong>an</strong>tee of success, lack of it is<br />

a guar<strong>an</strong>tee that you will not have a career of <strong>an</strong>y kind.<br />

Voslensky, Nomenklatura (1984, p. 98)<br />

What actually holds the present regime together is not a set of<br />

uncoordinated policies that ple<strong>as</strong>es all sectors <strong>an</strong>d paralyzes the<br />

government, but rather a system of mobility that attracts the<br />

personal allegi<strong>an</strong>ce of spokesmen for all the PRI sectors from the<br />

bottom to the top of the party hierarchy.<br />

H<strong>an</strong>sen, <strong>The</strong> Politics of Mexic<strong>an</strong> Development (1971, p. 220)<br />

A growing body of research finds that dictatorships with a single or a domin<strong>an</strong>t political<br />

party represent <strong>an</strong> especially resilient form of authoritari<strong>an</strong> rule. In a seminal paper, Geddes<br />

1


CHAPTER 6<br />

(1999a) cl<strong>as</strong>sified dictatorships into personalist, military, single-party, <strong>an</strong>d their hybrids, <strong>an</strong>d<br />

showed that single-party dictatorships are less likely to break down <strong>an</strong>d democratize th<strong>an</strong><br />

the remaining categories of dictatorship. Research on <strong>an</strong> institutionally related category of<br />

dictatorship – domin<strong>an</strong>t or hegemonic party regimes – similarly concludes that these regimes<br />

are particularly robust, even in the face of economic crises <strong>an</strong>d popular opposition (Brownlee<br />

2007; Magaloni 2006; Smith 2005; Slater 2003). In a complementary line of research, G<strong>an</strong>dhi<br />

<strong>an</strong>d Przeworski (2007) report that leaders in single-party regimes survive longer in office,<br />

<strong>an</strong>d I showed in <strong>Chapter</strong> 4 that leadership in dictatorships with parties is less likely to<br />

be deposed by non-institutional me<strong>an</strong>s, such <strong>as</strong> coups <strong>an</strong>d popular uprisings. Even when<br />

single<strong>an</strong>ddomin<strong>an</strong>tpartydictatorshipsdemocratize, formerpartyelitesfrequentlyshapethe<br />

tr<strong>an</strong>sition process <strong>an</strong>d, in m<strong>an</strong>y c<strong>as</strong>es, continue to maintain economic <strong>an</strong>d political influence<br />

(Grzyma̷la-Busse 2002, 2007).<br />

How does the institution of the party facilitate the survival of dictatorships? In spite<br />

of this growing body of research <strong>an</strong>d the emerging consensus that parties contribute to au-<br />

thoritari<strong>an</strong> resilience, we still lack a precise statement of the political mech<strong>an</strong>ism by which<br />

particular org<strong>an</strong>izational features of authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties account for the resilience of dicta-<br />

torships with single or domin<strong>an</strong>t parties.<br />

Consider two prominent views of how authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties affect the survival of dictator-<br />

ships. According to one view, parties are the vehicles through which the regime rewards its<br />

supporters (Geddes 1999b; G<strong>an</strong>dhi 2008). This political exch<strong>an</strong>ge is typically called coopta-<br />

tion <strong>an</strong>d frequently takes the form of patronage (Blaydes 2010; Magaloni 2006). Yet dicta-<br />

torships without parties also commonly appe<strong>as</strong>e popular discontent via policy concessions or<br />

material h<strong>an</strong>douts, <strong>an</strong>d patronage networks pervade m<strong>an</strong>y societies, operating both within<br />

2


CHAPTER 6<br />

<strong>an</strong>d outside of authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties (see e.g. Bratton <strong>an</strong>d V<strong>an</strong> de Walle 1997; Kitschelt <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Wilkinson 2007; V<strong>an</strong> de Walle 2001). What makes authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties such particularly<br />

apt vehicles for the cooptation of the m<strong>as</strong>ses?<br />

According to <strong>an</strong>other prominent view, authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties facilitate cooperation <strong>an</strong>d<br />

prevent factionalism among the regime’s elites (Brownlee 2007; Geddes 1999b; Magaloni<br />

2006). According to Geddes (1999b; 2003), for inst<strong>an</strong>ce, in single-party regimes “everyone is<br />

better off if all factions remain united <strong>an</strong>d in office” (Geddes 2003, 59). Arguably, however,<br />

incentives to “stick together or h<strong>an</strong>g separately” – to paraphr<strong>as</strong>e Benjamin Fr<strong>an</strong>klin – gener-<br />

ically exist in most dictatorships. What is the mech<strong>an</strong>ism by which authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties so<br />

uniquely maintain elite cohesion?<br />

In this chapter, I attempt to adv<strong>an</strong>ce existing research onthe roleof parties inauthoritar-<br />

i<strong>an</strong>govern<strong>an</strong>cebydeveloping argumentsthatexplaini)how<strong>an</strong>dwhichspecificorg<strong>an</strong>izational<br />

features of authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties contribute to authoritari<strong>an</strong> resilience, ii) why these benefi-<br />

cial functions could not be carried out without the institution of the party, <strong>an</strong>d iii) why some<br />

dictatorships establish <strong>an</strong>d maintain a regime-s<strong>an</strong>ctioned party while others do not.<br />

I identify three org<strong>an</strong>izational features of successful authoritari<strong>an</strong>parties that account for<br />

the effectiveness of parties <strong>as</strong> instruments of authoritari<strong>an</strong> cooptation, both at the m<strong>as</strong>s <strong>an</strong>d<br />

elite level. <strong>The</strong>se features are hierarchical <strong>as</strong>signment of service <strong>an</strong>d benefits, political control<br />

over appointments, <strong>an</strong>d selective recruitment <strong>an</strong>d repression. Crucially, these features of in-<br />

ternal party org<strong>an</strong>ization accomplish much more th<strong>an</strong> simply distribute rewards in exch<strong>an</strong>ge<br />

for party members’ support of the regime, <strong>as</strong> the existing literature often concludes. Rather<br />

th<strong>an</strong> fora for political exch<strong>an</strong>ge, authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties are better thought of <strong>as</strong> institutional-<br />

ized incentive structures that encourage sunk political investment by their members, which<br />

3


CHAPTER 6<br />

will be lost should the regime fall. <strong>The</strong> three org<strong>an</strong>izational features effectively exploit their<br />

members’ opportunism <strong>an</strong>d career <strong>as</strong>pirations in order to create a stake in the perpetua-<br />

tion of the regime among the most productive <strong>an</strong>d ideologically agreeable segments of the<br />

population. In turn, authoritari<strong>an</strong> regimes that coopt via a party with these org<strong>an</strong>izational<br />

features survive under less favorable circumst<strong>an</strong>ces th<strong>an</strong> dictatorships without a party, even<br />

if the latter spend the same resources on cooptation.<br />

In order to examine the political logic that links internal party org<strong>an</strong>ization, career <strong>as</strong>pi-<br />

rations among the population, <strong>an</strong>d the survival of dictatorships, I build on existing research<br />

on parties <strong>an</strong>d develop a series of simple formal models of authoritari<strong>an</strong> cooptation. <strong>The</strong><br />

<strong>an</strong>alysis in section 6.1 highlights that, jointly, thethree institutional features ofauthoritari<strong>an</strong><br />

parties that I identify contribute to the survival of dictatorships via two distinct political<br />

mech<strong>an</strong>isms.<br />

<strong>The</strong> first of these may be called party-b<strong>as</strong>ed cooptation. Cooptation via authoritari<strong>an</strong><br />

parties differs from cooptation via tr<strong>an</strong>sfers – which frequently takes the form of c<strong>as</strong>h, price<br />

controls, subsidies, or redistribution – in a key political <strong>as</strong>pect: Cooptation via authoritari<strong>an</strong><br />

parties breeds <strong>an</strong> enduring rather th<strong>an</strong> momentary stake in the regime’s survival. When the<br />

regime <strong>as</strong>signs costly party service to lower levels of the party hierarchy – <strong>an</strong>d hence early in<br />

party members’ career – <strong>an</strong>d the benefits of party membership to higher levels of the party<br />

hierarchy – <strong>an</strong>d hence later in the party members’ career – party members’ costly service<br />

becomes sunk investment by the time they reap the benefits of party seniority. Hence what<br />

makes cooptation via a party so effective is not the distribution of benefits by itself – those<br />

could be e<strong>as</strong>ily distributed without a party. Rather it is the conditioning of those benefits<br />

on prior costly service, which becomes sunk investment that c<strong>an</strong>not be tr<strong>an</strong>sferred across<br />

4


CHAPTER 6<br />

political coalitions <strong>an</strong>d will most likely be lost should the regime or leadership ch<strong>an</strong>ge. In<br />

turn, party members become political hostages of their own career success, with a vested<br />

interest in the perpetuation of the existing regime.<br />

<strong>The</strong> three institutional features of successful authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties identified here con-<br />

tribute to authoritari<strong>an</strong> resilience via <strong>an</strong>other, conceptually separate mech<strong>an</strong>ism, which we<br />

may call direct political control. This mech<strong>an</strong>ism refers to those <strong>as</strong>pects of party activity<br />

that are aimed primarily at the general population, such <strong>as</strong> political communication, mobi-<br />

lization, intelligence gathering, <strong>an</strong>d the mainten<strong>an</strong>ce of political discipline (see e.g. Friedrich<br />

<strong>an</strong>d Brzezinski 1965; Huntington 1968). Smith (2005), for inst<strong>an</strong>ce, identifies the ability au-<br />

thoritari<strong>an</strong> parties to mobilize their constituencies in times of crisis <strong>as</strong> a key <strong>as</strong>pect of party<br />

“strength”, Geddes (2008) argues that m<strong>as</strong>s parties help dictators to counter threats form<br />

the military, <strong>an</strong>d Magaloni (2008, 723) <strong>an</strong>d Wintrobe (1998, 65) emph<strong>as</strong>ize that long-l<strong>as</strong>ting<br />

parties are essential for effective cooptation. <strong>The</strong> <strong>an</strong>alysis here highlights how particular<br />

features of internal party org<strong>an</strong>ization – the party’s recruitment, promotion, <strong>an</strong>d retirement<br />

policies – ensure that sufficient incentives exist for key segments of the population to join the<br />

party <strong>an</strong>d, in turn, provide the political service that results in the party’s “l<strong>as</strong>ting strength”.<br />

By examining how optimal recruitment, promotion, <strong>an</strong>d retirement policies depend on the<br />

regimes’ resources, ideology, <strong>an</strong>d non-partis<strong>an</strong> opportunities for career adv<strong>an</strong>cement, we gain<br />

a better underst<strong>an</strong>ding of the connection between org<strong>an</strong>izational features of authoritari<strong>an</strong><br />

parties <strong>an</strong>d the potential <strong>an</strong>d limits to their “l<strong>as</strong>ting strength”.<br />

<strong>The</strong> results of this formal <strong>an</strong>alysis both corroborate <strong>an</strong>d qualify existing expl<strong>an</strong>ations<br />

of how authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties contribute to the survival of dictatorships. Brownlee (2007),<br />

Geddes (1999b; 2003), Gehlbach <strong>an</strong>d Keefer (2008), <strong>an</strong>d Magaloni (2006, 2008) argue that<br />

5


CHAPTER 6<br />

parties help maintain elite cohesion. <strong>The</strong> <strong>an</strong>alysis below outlines the logic by which partic-<br />

ular features of authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties’ internal org<strong>an</strong>ization generate a stake in a regime’s<br />

survival that grows with <strong>an</strong> individual’s r<strong>an</strong>k within the party hierarchy <strong>an</strong>d goes beyond the<br />

immediate benefits that the individual receives. Yet in contr<strong>as</strong>t to arguments that emph<strong>as</strong>ize<br />

the contribution of parties to elite-level power-sharing, the <strong>an</strong>alysis here underscores that<br />

party-b<strong>as</strong>ed cooptation is most effective when the possibility of career adv<strong>an</strong>cement within<br />

<strong>an</strong> authoritari<strong>an</strong> party is available to select segments among the general population, not only<br />

to the elites.<br />

In this regard, the present chapter shares the focus on the cooptation of the m<strong>as</strong>ses<br />

with Blaydes (2010), G<strong>an</strong>dhi <strong>an</strong>d Przeworski (2006, 2007), G<strong>an</strong>dhi (2008) <strong>an</strong>d Malesky <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Schuler (2010). Yet in its emph<strong>as</strong>is on the softer, institutional <strong>as</strong>pects of authoritari<strong>an</strong> poli-<br />

tics, the existing literature rarely considers cooptation alongside a quintessential instrument<br />

ofauthoritari<strong>an</strong>govern<strong>an</strong>ce–repression. 1 Infact, mostdictatorshipswithsingleordomin<strong>an</strong>t<br />

parties maintain a large repressive apparatus. 2<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>an</strong>alysis in this chapter helps us underst<strong>an</strong>d the complementarity of repression <strong>an</strong>d<br />

cooptation via a regime-s<strong>an</strong>ctioned political party. In order to ensure that sufficient incen-<br />

tives exist for the population to join the party <strong>an</strong>d provide the <strong>as</strong>sociated political service,<br />

party membership must be a consideration for a signific<strong>an</strong>t number of career appointments.<br />

Inturn, the government needs to establish <strong>an</strong>dmaintain political control over not only politi-<br />

cal<strong>an</strong>dadministrative postsbut alsokey economic<strong>an</strong>dsocialones. Thus effective cooptation<br />

via a regime-s<strong>an</strong>ctioned partyrequires that thegovernment comm<strong>an</strong>d the repressive capacity<br />

1 See Wintrobe (1998) <strong>an</strong>d Gershenson <strong>an</strong>d Gorossm<strong>an</strong> (2001) for <strong>an</strong> exception; Wintrobe (1998) <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Gershenson <strong>an</strong>d Gorossm<strong>an</strong> (2001) however do not examine whom a dictator will coopt <strong>an</strong>d whom repress.<br />

2 See e.g. Waterbury (1983) on Egypt, see Batatu (1981) on Syria, Gregory (2009) on the Soviet Union,<br />

Crouch (1978) on Indonesia, Stevens (1974) on Mexico, <strong>an</strong>d Baum (1997) on China.<br />

6


to counter opposition to the exercise of widespread political control.<br />

CHAPTER 6<br />

When I juxtapose cooptation via a regime-s<strong>an</strong>ctioned political party <strong>an</strong>d repression, I<br />

find that dictatorships coopt most effectively when they aim at ideologically most proximate<br />

segments of the population rather th<strong>an</strong> actual opposition. Because the cost of cooptation<br />

is more sensitive th<strong>an</strong> the cost of repression to the ideological dist<strong>an</strong>ce between a member<br />

of the population <strong>an</strong>d the regime, the regime spends scarce resources most effectively when<br />

it recruits those who are ideologically closer to it. This finding is consistent with historical<br />

<strong>an</strong>d qualitative research on the selective nature of party recruitment <strong>an</strong>d promotion policies<br />

<strong>an</strong>d suggests a qualification to the frequent claim that parties serve to coopt opposition. 3<br />

<strong>The</strong> present <strong>an</strong>alysis implies that the logic of party-b<strong>as</strong>ed, selective cooptation is to enlist<br />

those segments of the population that will best help marginalize actual opposition rather<br />

th<strong>an</strong> coopt it. 4<br />

This chapter’s findings about the contribution of regime-s<strong>an</strong>ctioned parties to authori-<br />

tari<strong>an</strong> resilience also suggest <strong>an</strong> amendment to Bueno de Mesquita et al.’s (2003) influential<br />

selectorate theory. At the heart of selectorate theory is the claim that potential defectors<br />

from<strong>an</strong>incumbent regime must weighthe certainbenefits that theycurrently receive against<br />

the uncertain benefits that a challenger offers them. Bueno de Mesquita et al. (2003) <strong>as</strong>sume<br />

that such uncertainty results in <strong>an</strong> incumbency adv<strong>an</strong>tage that decre<strong>as</strong>es with the size of<br />

the incumbent’s coalition. <strong>The</strong> present arguments imply that dictatorships that coopt via a<br />

regime party with the org<strong>an</strong>izational features that I examine below survive under less favor-<br />

able circumst<strong>an</strong>ces <strong>an</strong>d in the face of stronger challengers th<strong>an</strong> those without such parties,<br />

3On party recruitment <strong>an</strong>d promotion policies, see e.g. Domínguez (1978, <strong>Chapter</strong> 8), Grzyma̷la-Busse<br />

(2002), Shambaugh (2009), <strong>an</strong>d Staar (1988).<br />

4C.f. Geddes (1999b, 135) <strong>an</strong>d G<strong>an</strong>dhi <strong>an</strong>d Przeworski (2007).<br />

7


CHAPTER 6<br />

even if a the latter spend the same material resources on cooptation. Hence the institutional<br />

architecture of a regime’s ruling coalition critically conditions the loyalty of its members.<br />

Although the questions that drive the research in this chapter are primarily theoretical,<br />

I also examine the empirical <strong>as</strong>sociation between authoritari<strong>an</strong> political parties <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

survival of dictatorships. In section 6.2, I conduct a stronger test of this relationship th<strong>an</strong><br />

h<strong>as</strong>been attempted inexisting research. Specifically, Iavoidconfounding theeffect ofparties<br />

with the strength of individual leaders by me<strong>as</strong>uring the survival of authoritari<strong>an</strong> ruling<br />

coalitions rather th<strong>an</strong> individual leaders <strong>an</strong>d I employ direct, institutional indicators of the<br />

partis<strong>an</strong>org<strong>an</strong>izationofdictatorships. Ifindthat, onceweaccountforthelegislativestrength<br />

of regime-s<strong>an</strong>ctioned political parties in dictatorships with multiple parties, dictatorships<br />

with parties that control a supermajority of seats in the legislature survive on average about<br />

<strong>as</strong> long <strong>as</strong> ruling coalitions with single parties. Thus in accord<strong>an</strong>ce with my theoretical<br />

arguments, what facilitates the survival of dictatorships is the presence of a strong party,<br />

not necessarily a single one.<br />

<strong>The</strong>seresultsareb<strong>as</strong>edoncomprehensive, originaldataonauthoritari<strong>an</strong>rulingcoalitions,<br />

restrictions on political parties in dictatorships, <strong>an</strong>d legislative strength of regime-s<strong>an</strong>ctioned<br />

authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties that cover the period 1946-2008. I find that regime-s<strong>an</strong>ctioned author-<br />

itari<strong>an</strong> parties effectively take one of three distinct forms. <strong>The</strong> first are regime parties in<br />

single-party regimes, which account for about of 35% of all country-year observations. <strong>The</strong><br />

remaining two groups exist in dictatorships that allow for multiple parties: the first group<br />

consists of hegemonic or domin<strong>an</strong>t parties 5 , which on average control roughly 76% of all leg-<br />

islative seats <strong>an</strong>d account for 32% percent of all country-year observations; the second group<br />

5 Magaloni (2006), Greene (2007), Magaloni <strong>an</strong>d Kricheli (2010), Blaydes (2010), <strong>an</strong>d Reuter <strong>an</strong>d G<strong>an</strong>dhi<br />

(2010) examine this category of authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties.<br />

8


CHAPTER 6<br />

consists of parties under a conceptual category of dictatorship frequently characterized <strong>as</strong><br />

electoral or competitive authoritari<strong>an</strong>ism (Levitsky <strong>an</strong>d Way 2002; Schedler 2006). Author-<br />

itari<strong>an</strong> parties in this l<strong>as</strong>t group typically control a bare majority or minority of legislative<br />

seats <strong>an</strong>d account for about 11% of all country-year observations. 6 <strong>The</strong> existing literature<br />

h<strong>as</strong> so far examined the categories of hegemonic or domin<strong>an</strong>t parties <strong>an</strong>d parties under com-<br />

petitive authoritari<strong>an</strong>ismby using either qualitative data or by relying for their identification<br />

on a pre-defined criterion on their legislative strength or durability. <strong>The</strong> empirical <strong>an</strong>alysis<br />

in this chapter contributes to this literature by directly identifying these disparate empirical<br />

categories from the empirical distribution of comprehensive, large-N data on the legislative<br />

strength of authoritari<strong>an</strong> regime parties.<br />

<strong>The</strong>coreofthischapteraddressesthefirstofthethreequestionsthatI<strong>as</strong>kedattheoutset,<br />

how <strong>an</strong>d which org<strong>an</strong>izational features of authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties contribute to authoritari<strong>an</strong><br />

resilience? I conclude this chapter by <strong>an</strong>swering the two remaining questions, why dictators<br />

need the actual institution of the party, <strong>an</strong>d why only some dictatorships establish a party.<br />

My <strong>an</strong>alysis implies that two of the org<strong>an</strong>izational features of authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties that I<br />

identify–politicalcontroloverappointments<strong>an</strong>dselectiverecruitment<strong>an</strong>drepression–act<strong>as</strong><br />

catalysts for the third – hierarchical <strong>as</strong>signment of service <strong>an</strong>d benefits. Hence dictatorships<br />

benefit from coordinating the three org<strong>an</strong>izational features within a single institution – a<br />

regime-s<strong>an</strong>ctioned political party.<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>an</strong>alysis in this chapter contributes to our underst<strong>an</strong>ding of not only the potential<br />

but also the limits to party-b<strong>as</strong>ed cooptation <strong>an</strong>d thus provides clues about why not all<br />

6 A fourth, smallest group of authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties are those that control only a fraction of legislative<br />

seats <strong>an</strong>d typically exist in tr<strong>an</strong>sitioning regimes; 18% of all dictatorships b<strong>an</strong> political parties. See Section<br />

6.2 for details.<br />

9


CHAPTER 6<br />

dictatorships establish a regime-s<strong>an</strong>ction party. Because effective party-b<strong>as</strong>ed cooptation<br />

requires that the regime control a large number of appointments <strong>an</strong>d ch<strong>an</strong>nel signific<strong>an</strong>t<br />

resources through the party, dictatorships whose support b<strong>as</strong>e is limited to traditional elites<br />

– l<strong>an</strong>ded aristocracy or the owners of capital – will find cooptation <strong>an</strong>d control via parties<br />

less adv<strong>an</strong>tageous th<strong>an</strong> the alternatives of repression <strong>an</strong>d cooptation via direct tr<strong>an</strong>sfers.<br />

6.1 <strong>The</strong> Logic of <strong>Party</strong>-b<strong>as</strong>ed <strong>Authoritari<strong>an</strong></strong> Coopta-<br />

tion<br />

Which org<strong>an</strong>izational features of authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties facilitate the survival of dictatorships<br />

<strong>an</strong>d how do they do it? Historical <strong>an</strong>d c<strong>as</strong>e-b<strong>as</strong>ed research on single <strong>an</strong>d domin<strong>an</strong>t parties re-<br />

veals a striking degree of similarity in the internal makeup of long-l<strong>as</strong>ting regime-s<strong>an</strong>ctioned<br />

partiesacrossawider<strong>an</strong>geofdictatorships. Inthissection, Ibuildonthisresearch<strong>an</strong>dexam-<br />

ine the political logic by which three common org<strong>an</strong>izational features of single <strong>an</strong>d domin<strong>an</strong>t<br />

parties – hierarchical <strong>as</strong>signment of service <strong>an</strong>d benefits, political control over appointments,<br />

<strong>an</strong>d selective recruitment <strong>an</strong>d repression – contribute to the survival of dictatorships.<br />

6.1.1 Hierarchical Assignment of Service <strong>an</strong>d Benefits<br />

Most authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties entail a hierarchical apparatus that sp<strong>an</strong>s several levels of mem-<br />

bership. As a representative example, consider the Syri<strong>an</strong> Baath <strong>Party</strong>. In the 1980s,<br />

according to Hinnebusch (2002, <strong>Chapter</strong> 4), the internal structure of the party consisted of<br />

11,163 cells that were grouped into 1,395 b<strong>as</strong>ic units at the level of villages, factories, neigh-<br />

10


CHAPTER 6<br />

borhoods, <strong>an</strong>d public institutions; these in turn formed 154 sub-br<strong>an</strong>ches at the district or<br />

town level; <strong>an</strong>d these then constituted 18 br<strong>an</strong>ches in the provinces, cities, <strong>an</strong>d major insti-<br />

tutions. <strong>The</strong> leadership of the party consisted of regional <strong>an</strong>d national comm<strong>an</strong>ds, with the<br />

general secretary at the very top (Hinnebusch 2002, 75-79).<br />

Realistically, the administration of <strong>an</strong>y large org<strong>an</strong>ization requires a vertical comm<strong>an</strong>d<br />

structure, which may account for the hierarchical <strong>as</strong>pects of the party apparatus. Yet a<br />

notable feature of such party hierarchies is the differentiated allocation of the benefits <strong>an</strong>d<br />

service <strong>as</strong>sociated with party membership across the levels of the party hierarchy. Put<br />

simply, lower r<strong>an</strong>ks within the party provide most of the service, while higher r<strong>an</strong>ks of party<br />

membership reap most of the benefits. In fact, most political party service – frequently in<br />

the form of ideological work, intelligence gathering, <strong>an</strong>d popular mobilization – occurs at<br />

the lowest level of the party hierarchy. Accordingly, m<strong>an</strong>y single <strong>an</strong>d domin<strong>an</strong>t parties have<br />

entry-level membership r<strong>an</strong>ks, such <strong>as</strong> that of c<strong>an</strong>didate member, apprentice, or “friend of<br />

the party”. <strong>Party</strong> statutes commonly condition the adv<strong>an</strong>cement to full membership on<br />

gr<strong>as</strong>sroots party service <strong>an</strong>d sometimes even stipulate a minimum time that a prospective<br />

member must spend in such probationary status before acquiring full membership. 7 To take<br />

one example, probationary membership in the Iraqi Baath <strong>Party</strong> took a minimum of seven<br />

years <strong>an</strong>d entailed a progression through the r<strong>an</strong>ks of sympathizer, supporter, c<strong>an</strong>didate,<br />

<strong>an</strong>d trainee (Sissons 2008).<br />

Some <strong>as</strong>pects of party service underst<strong>an</strong>dably differ between dictatorships with single<br />

<strong>an</strong>d domin<strong>an</strong>t parties because the latter have multiparty elections, even if highly m<strong>an</strong>ipu-<br />

lated. While party service in single-party regimes may involve activities whose purpose is to<br />

7 On communist parties, see e.g. Simons <strong>an</strong>d White (1984) <strong>an</strong>d Staar (1988); on Baath parties, see<br />

Perthes (1995, <strong>Chapter</strong> 4) <strong>an</strong>d Batatu (1978, <strong>Chapter</strong> 58).<br />

11


CHAPTER 6<br />

maintain political discipline, social stability, <strong>an</strong>d turnout at regime-s<strong>an</strong>ctioned events, party<br />

service in dictatorships with domin<strong>an</strong>t parties additionally involves voter mobilization <strong>an</strong>d<br />

campaigning in multiparty elections. 8 According to Ch<strong>an</strong> (1976), for inst<strong>an</strong>ce, c<strong>an</strong>didates<br />

for the People’s Action <strong>Party</strong> in Singapore were chosen b<strong>as</strong>ed on their potential to play one<br />

or more of four b<strong>as</strong>ic roles: technocrat, mobilizer, Malay vote-getter, <strong>an</strong>d Chinese-educated<br />

intellectual. Evidence from other dictatorships with domin<strong>an</strong>t parties indicates that voter<br />

mobilization <strong>an</strong>d the delivery of set vote quot<strong>as</strong>, possibly by engaging in electoral fraud <strong>an</strong>d<br />

voter intimidation, are a key part of r<strong>an</strong>k <strong>an</strong>d file-level party service. 9<br />

Ontheother h<strong>an</strong>d, thebenefitsofpartymembership r<strong>an</strong>gefromemployment forfull-time<br />

party functionaries to better promotion prospects within the government bureaucracy <strong>an</strong>d<br />

government-controlled enterprizes, privileged access to educational opportunities <strong>an</strong>d social<br />

services, such <strong>as</strong> child care or public housing (see e.g. Voslensky 1984; Walder 1995). Such<br />

benefits typically incre<strong>as</strong>e with one’s r<strong>an</strong>k within the party <strong>an</strong>d m<strong>an</strong>y positions of economic<br />

or social signific<strong>an</strong>ce may only be accessible to those with established partis<strong>an</strong> credentials.<br />

Nonetheless, the complete scope of benefits to party membership is rarely officially recog-<br />

nized. Consider, for inst<strong>an</strong>ce, the nomenklatura system adopted by the communist regimes<br />

of E<strong>as</strong>tern Europe <strong>an</strong>d China <strong>an</strong>d emulated by the Baathist regimes in Syria <strong>an</strong>d Iraq. <strong>The</strong><br />

system w<strong>as</strong> – <strong>an</strong>d in the c<strong>as</strong>e of China still is – b<strong>as</strong>ed on a list (or several lists) of lucrative<br />

positions for which a history of service within the party <strong>an</strong>d a demonstrated loyalty to the<br />

regime in <strong>an</strong> essential precondition. In the Soviet Union <strong>an</strong>d China, the nomenklatura lists<br />

8See Edin (2003) on social stability <strong>as</strong> a criterion for local cadre promotion in China, see Staar (1988)<br />

on communist parties in E<strong>as</strong>tern Europe.<br />

9See Magaloni (2006), Greene (2007), <strong>an</strong>d L<strong>an</strong>gston <strong>an</strong>d Morgenstern (2009) on the PRI in Mexico;<br />

Brownlee (2007) <strong>an</strong>d Blaydes (2010) on the National Democratic <strong>Party</strong> in Egypt, Elson (2001) <strong>an</strong>d Smith<br />

(2005) on Golkar in Indonesia, <strong>an</strong>d Abrami et al. (2008) <strong>an</strong>d Malesky <strong>an</strong>d Schuler (2010) on Vietnam .<br />

12


CHAPTER 6<br />

have been administered by the Org<strong>an</strong>ization Department of the party’s Central Commit-<br />

tee <strong>an</strong>d contain positions within the party, the government, the military, state controlled<br />

enterprizes, <strong>an</strong>d other politically sensitive entities (e.g. universities, professional <strong>an</strong>d civic<br />

<strong>as</strong>sociations). Although the nomenklatura system probably represents the most systematic<br />

form of administrative formalization of benefits to party membership <strong>an</strong>d service, the precise<br />

content of nomenklatura lists <strong>an</strong>d criteria for promotion to a position on the lists have been<br />

rarely publicly stated. 10<br />

Whatarethepoliticalconsequences ofsuchhierarchical<strong>as</strong>signmentofservice<strong>an</strong>dbenefits<br />

within authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties? Before examining in detail the role of recruitment, promotion,<br />

<strong>an</strong>d retirement policies that shape this feature of authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties, consider a simple<br />

illustration of how hierarchical <strong>as</strong>signment of service <strong>an</strong>d benefits contributes to the survival<br />

of dictatorships. To keep this illustration <strong>as</strong> simple <strong>as</strong> possible, suppose that a dictator needs<br />

the active support of two citizens in order to stay in power. Consider first cooptation within<br />

the institutional structure of a regime party. To stay with the most rudimentary concept of<br />

a hierarchical party structure, suppose that the party apparatus consists of only two r<strong>an</strong>ks<br />

of membership, junior <strong>an</strong>d senior members. Juniors provide costly service for the regime<br />

at the individual cost c > 0, where<strong>as</strong> seniors enjoy the individual benefit b, b > c. For now,<br />

<strong>as</strong>sume that citizens live for two periods only; a junior automatically becomes a senior after<br />

one period of service <strong>an</strong>d all seniors retire after one period. <strong>The</strong>n, in <strong>an</strong>y period <strong>an</strong>d after<br />

accounting for the costly service that juniors provide, the dictator’s total net expenditures<br />

on the party are b−c.<br />

I will refer to cooptation without <strong>an</strong> authoritari<strong>an</strong> party <strong>as</strong> cooptation via tr<strong>an</strong>sfers.<br />

10 On the Soviet Union <strong>an</strong>d E<strong>as</strong>tern Europe, see Grzyma̷la-Busse (2002), Rigby (1988), <strong>an</strong>d Voslensky<br />

(1984); on China, see L<strong>an</strong>dry (2008) <strong>an</strong>d Shambaugh (2009); on Cuba see Domínguez (1978).<br />

13


CHAPTER 6<br />

<strong>The</strong>se tr<strong>an</strong>sfers frequently take the form of c<strong>as</strong>h, subsidies, price regulation, l<strong>an</strong>d reform, or<br />

programmatic redistribution. 11 All such policies are in effect tr<strong>an</strong>sfers of income from the<br />

government to a targeted segment of the population. For inst<strong>an</strong>ce, in attempts to appe<strong>as</strong>e<br />

the m<strong>as</strong>ses during to the wave of protests that swept through the Middle E<strong>as</strong>t <strong>an</strong>d North<br />

Africa at the beginning of 2011, Bahrain’s King Hamad ibn Isa al-Khalifa gave to each<br />

Bahraini family the equivalent of $2,650, the Syri<strong>an</strong> government of B<strong>as</strong>har al-Asad froze<br />

electricity prices <strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong>nounced a 72% rise in heating-oil benefits for public workers, <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the Saudi government <strong>an</strong>nounced <strong>an</strong> incre<strong>as</strong>e in subsidies for new marriages, home owners,<br />

<strong>an</strong>d businesses. 12<br />

In order to explicitly contr<strong>as</strong>t cooptation with <strong>an</strong>d without a regime party, suppose that<br />

the dictator distributes via tr<strong>an</strong>sfers <strong>an</strong> amount equivalent to his total net expenditures on<br />

partis<strong>an</strong> cooptation, b−c. That is, in <strong>an</strong>y period, the dictator compensates each citizen’s<br />

support for the regime by a tr<strong>an</strong>sfer in the amount of (b−c)/2.<br />

How much does a challenger have to offer to each citizen in order to attract both citizens’<br />

support? Suppose that the challenger does not have a party <strong>an</strong>d simply offers a period-by-<br />

period tr<strong>an</strong>sfer to each of the two citizens. In the c<strong>as</strong>e of cooptation via tr<strong>an</strong>sfers, the two<br />

citizens will be willing to join him if he offers each <strong>an</strong> equivalent tr<strong>an</strong>sfer, that is at le<strong>as</strong>t<br />

(b − c)/2. Hence a challenger must have a budget of at le<strong>as</strong>t b − c in order to replace <strong>an</strong><br />

incumbent who coopts via tr<strong>an</strong>sfers.<br />

On the other h<strong>an</strong>d, a challenger who would like to attract defectors from a dictator who<br />

coopts via a party h<strong>as</strong> to consider not only their current costs <strong>an</strong>d benefits but also the effect<br />

11 Magaloni (2008) refers to these <strong>as</strong> “tr<strong>an</strong>sfers on the spot”.<br />

12 “Bahrain’s king gives out c<strong>as</strong>h ahead of protests,” Reuters, 12 February 2011; “Hard choices for the<br />

government,” <strong>The</strong> Economist, 20 J<strong>an</strong>uary, 2011; “Bahrain King in Saudi Arabia to discuss unrest,” <strong>The</strong> New<br />

York Times, 23 February 2011.<br />

14


CHAPTER 6<br />

Table 6.1: A comparison of cooptation via tr<strong>an</strong>sfers <strong>an</strong>d cooptation via a regime party<br />

Tr<strong>an</strong>sfers <strong>Regime</strong> party<br />

per-period Current Expected Average<br />

<strong>Party</strong> r<strong>an</strong>k payoff r<strong>an</strong>k payoff lifetime payoff per-period payoff<br />

Senior<br />

Junior<br />

b−c<br />

2 b b b<br />

b−c<br />

b−c<br />

−c b−c 2 2<br />

of the party hierarchy on their incentives to defect. As in the setting without a party, the<br />

junior expects to receive b −c over the two stages of her career in the party <strong>an</strong>d therefore<br />

h<strong>as</strong> to be offered <strong>an</strong> average payoff of at le<strong>as</strong>t (b−c)/2 in each period in order to defect to<br />

the challenger. However, the senior now h<strong>as</strong> to be offered at le<strong>as</strong>t b – the benefit she will<br />

obtain from the incumbent in the current period – in order to defect to the challenger. Thus<br />

with a hierarchical <strong>as</strong>signment of service <strong>an</strong>d benefits within the party, the challenger must<br />

comm<strong>an</strong>d greater resources in order to replace the incumbent dictator th<strong>an</strong> if he were facing<br />

<strong>an</strong> incumbent without a party, b+(b−c)/2 > b−c. Or equivalently, the incumbent needs to<br />

comm<strong>an</strong>d fewer resources in order to deter the same challenger when he coopts via a regime<br />

party.<br />

Table 6.1 contr<strong>as</strong>ts the costs of coopting the two citizens with <strong>an</strong>d without a regime<br />

party. By <strong>as</strong>signing costly service to the early stages of party members’ career <strong>an</strong>d delaying<br />

the benefits of membership to the latter stages, the hierarchical structure of the party makes<br />

the incumbent dictator more resilient to potential challengers. Because they have already<br />

expended the costly service at the junior stage <strong>an</strong>d only expect to reap the benefits, senior<br />

party members have a stake in the incumbent dictator’s survival that is absent in a regime<br />

that coopts without the institution of the party, even if the latter spend the same resources<br />

15


on cooptation.<br />

CHAPTER 6<br />

<strong>The</strong> following two examples illustrate this logic. In their <strong>an</strong>alysis of patrimonial politics<br />

in Africa, Bratton <strong>an</strong>d V<strong>an</strong> de Walle (1997, 86) identify “plebiscitary” <strong>an</strong>d “competitive”<br />

one-party regimes <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> import<strong>an</strong>t subset of Afric<strong>an</strong> dictatorships. Insiders within these<br />

regimes have strong incentives to remain loyal because<br />

“[they] have typically risen through the r<strong>an</strong>ks of political service <strong>an</strong>d ...derive<br />

livelihood principally from state or party offices. Because they face the prospect<br />

of losing all visible me<strong>an</strong>s of support in a political tr<strong>an</strong>sition, they have little<br />

option but to cling to the regime, to sink or swim with it.”<br />

In a similar spirit, Hough (1980, 33) explains that prospects for regime ch<strong>an</strong>ge in the<br />

Soviet Union under Brezhnev were grim because<br />

“the Soviet government h<strong>as</strong> thus far been skillful in the way it h<strong>as</strong> tied the fate<br />

of m<strong>an</strong>y individuals in the country to the fate of the regime. By admitting<br />

such a broad r<strong>an</strong>ge of the educated public into the party, it h<strong>as</strong> provided full<br />

opportunities for upward social mobility for those who avoid dissidence, while<br />

giving everyone in the m<strong>an</strong>agerial cl<strong>as</strong>s re<strong>as</strong>on to wonder what the impact of <strong>an</strong><br />

<strong>an</strong>ti-Communist revolution would be on him or her personally.”<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Party</strong> Hierarchy <strong>an</strong>d Incentives for <strong>Party</strong> Membership<br />

As the above examples illustrates, the key political adv<strong>an</strong>tage of allocating party service<br />

<strong>an</strong>d benefits hierarchically is the stake in the regime’s survival that arises endogenously<br />

among the senior r<strong>an</strong>ks of the party. A key challenge for authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties that structure<br />

16


CHAPTER 6<br />

party service <strong>an</strong>d benefits hierarchically is therefore to provide incentives for juniors at<br />

a m<strong>an</strong>ageable cost to the regime. When the dem<strong>an</strong>ds on service <strong>an</strong>d the entitlement to<br />

benefits vary across the r<strong>an</strong>ks of the party, the provision of too large benefits may strain<br />

the regime’s resources where<strong>as</strong> the dem<strong>an</strong>d of too much service may discourage prospective<br />

members.<br />

In order to better underst<strong>an</strong>d the implications of hierarchical <strong>as</strong>signment of service <strong>an</strong>d<br />

benefits for incentive5s to join the party, we may extend the above rudimentary model <strong>as</strong><br />

follows. Suppose that each citizen now lives indefinitely over time periods t = 1,2,... In<br />

<strong>an</strong>y period, a citizen who is not a party member earns a wage w. As above, if a citizen<br />

joins the regime party, she starts at the junior r<strong>an</strong>k <strong>an</strong>d provides party service that entails<br />

a per-period cost c; once promoted to the senior r<strong>an</strong>k, she obtains the per-period benefit<br />

b > w > 0.<br />

A citizen’s payoff from a career within the party depends on the regime’s promotion <strong>an</strong>d<br />

retirement policies. In <strong>an</strong>y period, a junior member is promoted to a senior r<strong>an</strong>k with the<br />

probability p ∈ [0,1]. Me<strong>an</strong>while, a senior member is retired with the probability r ∈ [0,1]<br />

<strong>an</strong>d receives the wage w after retiring. 13 Thus senior party member i’s expected discounted<br />

career payoff is<br />

where u N i<br />

u S i = b+δ[ruN i +(1−r)uS i<br />

], (6.1)<br />

= w/(1 − δ) is the discounted career payoff of non-members <strong>an</strong>d δ ∈ (0,1) is a<br />

13 Lazarev (2005; 2007) develops a related model of a single party with two levels of membership <strong>an</strong>d<br />

examines the optimal structure of promotion <strong>an</strong>d retirement rules. Among other things, the present model<br />

differs from Lazarev’s by explicitly comparing the resilience of dictatorships with <strong>an</strong>d without a regime party<br />

to potential challengers.<br />

17


discount factor. 14 Solving equation (6.1) for u S i<br />

, we obtain<br />

CHAPTER 6<br />

u S i = b+δruN i<br />

. (6.2)<br />

1−δ(1−r)<br />

<strong>The</strong>n citizen i’s expected payoff from party membership, which begins at the junior level, is<br />

Solving equation (6.3) for u J i<br />

u J i = −c+δ[puS i +(1−p)uJ i<br />

, we get<br />

u J i = −c+δpuS i<br />

1−δ(1−p) .<br />

Thus citizen i will have <strong>an</strong> incentive to join the party <strong>as</strong> long <strong>as</strong><br />

]. (6.3)<br />

u J i ≥ uN i or equivalently p ≥ 1−δ(1−r) c+w<br />

. (6.4)<br />

δ b−w<br />

We may call inequality (6.4) the party service constraint. <strong>The</strong> party service constraint<br />

implies that, in order to maintain party membership, the regime must maintain a minimal<br />

rate of promotions <strong>an</strong>d bal<strong>an</strong>ce its promotion <strong>an</strong>d retirement policies. More precisely, the<br />

minimalrateofpromotionsimpliedbythepartyservice constraintispositive<strong>an</strong>d, intuitively,<br />

incre<strong>as</strong>inginthecostofpartyofservicec<strong>an</strong>dnon-partywagew; itisdecre<strong>as</strong>ing inthebenefit<br />

from seniority b.<br />

At the same time, the total resources available to the regime will re<strong>as</strong>onably limit the<br />

14 Since citizens are infinitely-lived, the discount factor δ may be interpreted <strong>as</strong> a natural mortality rate.<br />

That is, in each period, a citizen expects to die with the probability δ.<br />

18


CHAPTER 6<br />

generosity of the benefits to senior party members <strong>an</strong>d hence the party’s promotion <strong>an</strong>d re-<br />

tirement policies. Assuming that the regime intends to maintain const<strong>an</strong>t party membership<br />

over time, the rate of retirement implies <strong>an</strong> upper bound on the rate of promotions. That<br />

is, in <strong>an</strong>y period, junior members c<strong>an</strong> only be promoted into vac<strong>an</strong>cies created by retired<br />

seniors,<br />

rN S = pN J , (6.5)<br />

where N S <strong>an</strong>d N J are the number of seniors <strong>an</strong>d juniors in the party. Thus equation (6.5) is<br />

<strong>an</strong> <strong>as</strong>sumption about const<strong>an</strong>t party size. 15 When B are the total resources that the regime<br />

c<strong>an</strong> spend on the party, the party’s retirement policy must respect the budget constraint<br />

B ≥ N S b. (6.6)<br />

Combining the <strong>as</strong>sumption about const<strong>an</strong>t party size <strong>an</strong>d the budget constraint, we see that<br />

the retirement rate must be at le<strong>as</strong>t<br />

r ≥ pbNJ<br />

B ,<br />

or equivalently, the promotion rate c<strong>an</strong> be at most<br />

p ≤ rB<br />

bN J.<br />

15This <strong>as</strong>sumption c<strong>an</strong> be e<strong>as</strong>ily relaxed: the evolution party membership at the senior r<strong>an</strong>k is described<br />

by the equation NS t = (1−r)N S t−1 +pNJ t−1 . <strong>The</strong> <strong>an</strong>alysis here <strong>as</strong>sumes that NS t = NS t−1 <strong>an</strong>d thus strategies<br />

p <strong>an</strong>d r are stationary. Also note that the bal<strong>an</strong>ce on the probabilities p <strong>an</strong>d q implied by const<strong>an</strong>t party<br />

size is a “long run” one. That is, across individual periods, the realizations of p <strong>an</strong>d q may actually reduce<br />

or exceed previous period’s party size, but party size will be const<strong>an</strong>t in the long run.<br />

19


CHAPTER 6<br />

Intuitively, when the regime h<strong>as</strong> fewer resources it must retire senior r<strong>an</strong>ks at a higher rate<br />

<strong>an</strong>d promote junior r<strong>an</strong>ks at a lower rate.<br />

Suppose that the regime’s benefit s(c) from a junior party member’s service is incre<strong>as</strong>ing<br />

<strong>an</strong>d concave in c, s ′ (c) > 0 <strong>an</strong>d s ′′ (c) < 0, <strong>an</strong>d that s(0) = 0. If the regime did not need<br />

to consider incentives for party membership, it would never promote (p = 0) <strong>an</strong>d retire<br />

immediately (r = 1). However, a resource constrained regime will adopt promotion <strong>an</strong>d<br />

retirement policies that respect the budget constraint <strong>an</strong>d hold the party service constraint<br />

at equality. Jointly, the resource <strong>an</strong>d party service constraints imply a set of limits on the<br />

fe<strong>as</strong>ible structure of career incentives within the party hierarchy: in order for the promise of<br />

seniority to attract new members, the rate of promotions p must be positive; in order to be<br />

fiscally sustainable, the retirement rate r must be above a certain minimum level; <strong>an</strong>d within<br />

these boundaries, a resource constrained regime will bal<strong>an</strong>ce the two policies – a higher rate<br />

of promotions p will be compensated by a higher retirement rate r <strong>an</strong>d vice versa. More<br />

precisely, the regime chooses promotion <strong>an</strong>d retirement policies that maximize its discounted<br />

net payoff subject to binding party service <strong>an</strong>d budget constraints,<br />

�<br />

max<br />

p,r<br />

s(c)<br />

1−δ(1−p) −<br />

�<br />

b<br />

1−δ(1−r)<br />

subject to p = 1−δ(1−r) c+w<br />

δ b−w <strong>an</strong>d r ≥ b−(1−δ)¯ B<br />

δ ¯ .<br />

B<br />

Intuitively, the optimal promotion rate p ∗ is decre<strong>as</strong>ing in the benefit from party service s<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the compensation to seniors b; p ∗ is incre<strong>as</strong>ing in the wage earned by non-party members<br />

w <strong>an</strong>d the costs of party service c. <strong>The</strong> party service constraint implies that <strong>an</strong>y incre<strong>as</strong>e<br />

or decre<strong>as</strong>e in p ∗ will be compensated by a corresponding ch<strong>an</strong>ge r ∗ . <strong>The</strong> optimal trade-<br />

off between the promotion <strong>an</strong>d retirement policies therefore reflects the relative political<br />

20


elev<strong>an</strong>ce of the parameters b, w, <strong>an</strong>d c.<br />

CHAPTER 6<br />

This <strong>an</strong>alysis illuminates several org<strong>an</strong>izational dilemm<strong>as</strong> that we frequently observe in<br />

m<strong>an</strong>y single <strong>an</strong>d domin<strong>an</strong>t party regimes. <strong>The</strong> party service constraint implies that – in<br />

order to attract new members who provide politically valuable service – the regime must<br />

maintain a minimal rate of promotions <strong>an</strong>d, in turn, a positive rate of retirement. <strong>The</strong><br />

Chinese Communist <strong>Party</strong>, for inst<strong>an</strong>ce, h<strong>as</strong> strived to maintain <strong>an</strong> appropriate bal<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

between these two policies at various levels of the party hierarchy. In the 1980s, Deng<br />

Xiaoping initiated efforts at rejuvenating the party’s leadership by promoting age limits for<br />

Politburo members (M<strong>an</strong>ion 1992, 1993), <strong>an</strong>d in 2002, Ji<strong>an</strong>g Zemin instituted term limits<br />

<strong>an</strong>d rotation for leading local cadres in the party <strong>an</strong>d government (Bo 2007; Nath<strong>an</strong> 2003).<br />

Underst<strong>an</strong>dably, wemayexpectseniorr<strong>an</strong>kswithinthepartytoresistpoliticalretirement<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the implementation of <strong>an</strong> appropriate bal<strong>an</strong>ce in promotion <strong>an</strong>d retirement policies may<br />

present a political challenge for the party leadership. Consider Nikita Khrushchev’s proposal<br />

at the 22nd <strong>Party</strong> Congress in 1961 to revise CPSU’s statutes <strong>an</strong>d implement a “systematic<br />

renewal of cadres” that would consist of term limits for individuals in elected party posts <strong>an</strong>d<br />

rules forturnover inother party bodies(Burlatsky 1991, 129-30). Khrushchev’s putative mo-<br />

tives <strong>as</strong> well <strong>as</strong> the party membership’s negative reaction to this policy ch<strong>an</strong>ge accords with<br />

the implications of the present model. According to Thompson, for inst<strong>an</strong>ce, Khrushchev<br />

worried that “a gradual freezing of personnel policy would block up the system, <strong>an</strong>d stag-<br />

nation would occur” (Tompson 1995, 242-244). In terms of the present model, Khrushchev<br />

w<strong>as</strong> concerned about the incre<strong>as</strong>ing costs of the existing retirement policy (a too low r <strong>an</strong>d<br />

a too high b in the present model) <strong>an</strong>d the diminishing incentives to provide party service<br />

among the junior r<strong>an</strong>ks within the party. On the other h<strong>an</strong>d, the membership of the <strong>Party</strong><br />

21


CHAPTER 6<br />

opposed the proposed ch<strong>an</strong>ges because “older officials were faced with the const<strong>an</strong>t threat of<br />

replacement by younger men, while younger officials believed that the rules would prevent<br />

them from enjoying long careers at the top” (Tompson 1995, 244). In fact, some attribute<br />

Khrushchev’s fall to the party elite’s hostility to these policies (Tompson 2003, 22).<br />

<strong>The</strong> present model clarifies the political risk that reforms that reduce benefits to senior<br />

r<strong>an</strong>ks within the party entail. By curtailing the benefits to party seniority, Khrushchev<br />

w<strong>as</strong> threatening those r<strong>an</strong>ks within the party who would otherwise have the largest stake<br />

in his survival – <strong>as</strong> long <strong>as</strong> their benefits are preserved. As in the simpler model earlier, a<br />

challenger who would like to attract defectors from the leader’s ruling coalition must offer a<br />

per-period benefit of at le<strong>as</strong>t (1−δ)u J i <strong>an</strong>d (1−δ)uS i<br />

to <strong>an</strong>y junior <strong>an</strong>d senior party member,<br />

respectively. Because the seniors’ cost of party service is sunk, they have to be offered more<br />

th<strong>an</strong> juniors to be willing to defect, u S i > uJ i .<br />

But note that party-b<strong>as</strong>ed cooptation only protects the incumbent dictator against those<br />

challengers who might dism<strong>an</strong>tle the party hierarchy after they come to office, <strong>as</strong> is typically<br />

thec<strong>as</strong>eafteraregimech<strong>an</strong>georthearrivalof<strong>as</strong>ubst<strong>an</strong>tiallydifferentrulingcoalition. <strong>Party</strong>-<br />

b<strong>as</strong>ed cooptation does not safeguard against challengers from within the party who propose<br />

to maintain or even incre<strong>as</strong>e the benefits to the senior r<strong>an</strong>ks. After he removed Khrushchev<br />

from power in 1964, Brezhnev reversed Khrushchev’s cadre policies <strong>an</strong>d instead emph<strong>as</strong>ized<br />

the “stability of cadres”. This earned him the loyalty of the party’s senior membership but<br />

at the long-term cost of <strong>an</strong> ossified party structure, the emergence of local fiefdoms, <strong>an</strong>d<br />

lack of incentives for a younger generation of party members to provide political service<br />

(Mawdsley <strong>an</strong>d White 2000; Tompson 2003). 16 Geddes (1999b, 122) prominently observed<br />

16 A major internal policy theme in Gorbachev’stenure <strong>as</strong> General Secretary w<strong>as</strong> a correctionto this trend<br />

22


CHAPTER 6<br />

that single-party regimes “tend to be brought down by exogenous events rather th<strong>an</strong> internal<br />

splits.” <strong>The</strong> present <strong>an</strong>alysis helps us underst<strong>an</strong>d why single-party regimes remain resilient<br />

to elite defections in spite of frequent internal factionalism.<br />

<strong>The</strong> mainten<strong>an</strong>ce of <strong>an</strong> appropriate bal<strong>an</strong>ce in promotion <strong>an</strong>d retirement policies poses<br />

a distinct challenge in domin<strong>an</strong>t party systems. Because these regimes have multiparty<br />

elections, disgruntled juniors who were p<strong>as</strong>sed up for a promotion <strong>an</strong>d seniors who are being<br />

pressured into retirement may challenge the party <strong>as</strong> independents or opposition c<strong>an</strong>didates.<br />

When, in attempts at party “renewal”, Lee Ku<strong>an</strong> Yew pressured senior party members into<br />

political retirement, he reluct<strong>an</strong>tly kept the former government minister Toh Chin Chye <strong>as</strong> a<br />

member of parliament for the People’s Action <strong>Party</strong> because Toh could e<strong>as</strong>ily win his district<br />

<strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> independent. Only when the boundaries of his district had been redrawn could Toh be<br />

retired <strong>an</strong>d even then he became one Lee’s most powerful critics (Mauzy <strong>an</strong>d Milne 2002).<br />

Arelated concern shaped theprocess by which presidential c<strong>an</strong>didates for Mexico’s ruling<br />

Institutional Revolutionary <strong>Party</strong> used to be unveiled: <strong>The</strong> incumbent president tactically<br />

delayed the <strong>an</strong>nouncement of the next PRI nominee <strong>as</strong> long <strong>as</strong> possible, so that all in-<br />

fluential cabinet members believed that they stood a ch<strong>an</strong>ce. Otherwise they might have<br />

attempted to defect from the party with enough time to promote <strong>an</strong> independent c<strong>an</strong>didacy,<br />

<strong>as</strong> Cuauhtémoc Cárden<strong>as</strong> did in 1988 after he unsuccessfully tried to win the presiden-<br />

tial nomination within the PRI (C<strong>as</strong>tañeda 2000). Although the official nomination to the<br />

presidential c<strong>an</strong>didacy guar<strong>an</strong>teed the chosen c<strong>an</strong>didate the presidency – <strong>an</strong>d w<strong>as</strong> therefore<br />

technically apromotion–itimpliedpoliticalretirement formostoftheunsuccessful hopefuls.<br />

In fact, Mexico under the PRI provides <strong>an</strong> example of uniquely intertwined promotion<br />

(Bunce 1999; Mawdsley <strong>an</strong>d White 2000; Rush 1991).<br />

23


CHAPTER 6<br />

<strong>an</strong>d retirement policies within a domin<strong>an</strong>t party regime. Due to a constitutionally m<strong>an</strong>dated<br />

one-term limit for all elected posts, a ch<strong>an</strong>ge in the administration every six <strong>an</strong>d, at the<br />

municipal level, three years implied the re-<strong>as</strong>signment or retirement for not only elected<br />

politici<strong>an</strong>s but also for thous<strong>an</strong>ds of government employees who held a position due their<br />

political or clientelistic <strong>as</strong>sociation with a politici<strong>an</strong> in <strong>an</strong> elected post. Thus in the 1960s,<br />

accordingtoBr<strong>an</strong>denburg(1964,157), everysix-year administrationwitnessed “aturnoverof<br />

approximately 18,000elective offices<strong>an</strong>d25,000appointive posts.” <strong>The</strong>coupling ofthefixed,<br />

term-b<strong>as</strong>edtimehorizonwiththePRI’s politicaldomin<strong>an</strong>ce inMexico resulted in<strong>as</strong>ystem of<br />

upward <strong>an</strong>d downward political mobility that w<strong>as</strong> distinctively interlocked. <strong>The</strong> expectation<br />

of such mobility is consistent with the present model’s emph<strong>as</strong>is on <strong>an</strong> appropriate bal<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

in the provision of incentives for political party service between the promise of promotion<br />

<strong>an</strong>d a positive rate of political retirement. In the c<strong>as</strong>e of Mexico, the nature of this incentive-<br />

preserving bal<strong>an</strong>ce is eloquently summarized by Grindle (1977, 42):<br />

“<strong>The</strong> six-year procession often resembles a national game of musical chairs in<br />

which the same actors may reappear in different positions; new players are freely<br />

admitted, however, <strong>an</strong>d the number of chairs may be enlarged to accommodate<br />

some of them. Those who fail to find a chair <strong>an</strong>d must leave the game do so<br />

knowingly they have the possibility of reentering it at a later date.”<br />

Note, however, thatthe<strong>an</strong>alysis above doesnotrequire that theregime’s leadership retire<br />

on a regular b<strong>as</strong>is or even with a positive probability, <strong>as</strong> w<strong>as</strong> the c<strong>as</strong>e in Mexico under the<br />

PRI. This w<strong>as</strong> a unique feature of the Mexic<strong>an</strong> dictatorship, which I addressed in <strong>Chapter</strong> 4,<br />

<strong>an</strong>d which the present model does not account for. 17 Nonetheless, the regular re-<strong>as</strong>signment<br />

17 In <strong>Chapter</strong> 4, I suggested that Mexic<strong>an</strong> presidential term limits were a rather unique form of intertem-<br />

24


CHAPTER 6<br />

or dismissal of thous<strong>an</strong>ds of senior elected <strong>an</strong>d administrative posts raises <strong>an</strong> import<strong>an</strong>t<br />

question about the credibility of retirement rules: <strong>Why</strong> don’t the senior party r<strong>an</strong>ks simply<br />

attempt to stay?<br />

A quick but inadequate <strong>an</strong>swer is that the senior r<strong>an</strong>ks retire because the regime’s lead-<br />

ership tells them to go. Gorbachev initiated a large-scale retirement of senior party cadres<br />

in the Communist <strong>Party</strong>’s Central Committee <strong>an</strong>d throughout the Soviet administration<br />

after years of “stagnation” under Brezhnev (Mawdsley <strong>an</strong>d White 2000, <strong>Chapter</strong> 6), <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Lee Ku<strong>an</strong> Yew steadily pressured for “leadership renewal” throughout the People’s Action<br />

<strong>Party</strong>’s existence (Hong <strong>an</strong>d Hu<strong>an</strong>g 2008, 101-107). Stalin’s Great Purge <strong>an</strong>d Mao’s Cultural<br />

Revolution may in part be interpreted <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> exceedingly ruthless way of replacing old by new<br />

party cadres (Rigby 1968; MacFarquhar <strong>an</strong>d Schoenhals 2006). But <strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>swer that stops<br />

with the regime’s leadership is incomplete because it only begs the question of why a leader<br />

would feel compelled to retire senior party cadres.<br />

<strong>The</strong> present model shows that incentives for party service among the junior r<strong>an</strong>ks are<br />

inextricably tied to the promise of a promotion, which in turn depends on <strong>an</strong> appropriate<br />

rate of retirement among the senior r<strong>an</strong>ks. At the same time, however, the benefits that<br />

senior party members enjoy depend on the continuing survival of the regime, <strong>an</strong>d in turn,<br />

on the junior r<strong>an</strong>ks’ party service. Hence the credibility of the leadership’s promise to retire<br />

the senior r<strong>an</strong>ks rests on the indispensability of party service for the survival of the regime.<br />

If the senior r<strong>an</strong>ks retire at a lower rate or refuse to retire, the motivation to provide costly<br />

party service among <strong>as</strong>piring <strong>an</strong>d junior party members will diminish or disappear. That is,<br />

poral power-sharing among the Mexic<strong>an</strong> elites. In fact, with the exception of Mexico <strong>an</strong>d potentially China<br />

since Ji<strong>an</strong>g Zemin, there are no single or domin<strong>an</strong>t party dictatorships with fixed <strong>an</strong>d effective term-limits<br />

for the leadership.<br />

25


CHAPTER 6<br />

they may join a challenger who promises better prospects within the regime or opposition<br />

that aims to overthrow the regime <strong>an</strong>d establish democracy. <strong>The</strong>refore the regime’s promise<br />

to maintain <strong>an</strong> appropriate bal<strong>an</strong>ce in its promotion <strong>an</strong>d retirement policies is credible only<br />

<strong>as</strong> far <strong>as</strong> the regime’s survival depends on the juniors’ party service. 18<br />

<strong>The</strong> present <strong>an</strong>alysis also highlights that, in order to launch the cooptation mech<strong>an</strong>ism,<br />

the regime needs to signal its strength, <strong>an</strong>d hence durability, at the time of the party’s<br />

founding. This initial, exogenous impetus is needed so that prospective party members<br />

<strong>an</strong>ticipate that the party will l<strong>as</strong>t long enough for their costly investment to come to fruition<br />

in the form of party seniority. Hence the establishment of a single or domin<strong>an</strong>t party regime<br />

should witness more repression, <strong>an</strong>d in the c<strong>as</strong>e of domin<strong>an</strong>t party regimes, more restrictions<br />

on competition th<strong>an</strong> later periods. According with Huntington’s (1970) <strong>an</strong>d Smith’s (2005)<br />

observations that the strength of single <strong>an</strong>d domin<strong>an</strong>t parties depends on the intensity of<br />

the struggle that brought them to power, this logic suggests that dictatorships that came<br />

to power by revolutionary me<strong>an</strong>s may be in a better position to initiate a party-b<strong>as</strong>ed<br />

cooptationmech<strong>an</strong>ism. Yet departing fromHuntington (1970)<strong>an</strong>dSmith (2005), thepresent<br />

<strong>an</strong>alysis suggests that these initial dem<strong>an</strong>ds on credibility abate once the overlapping, inter-<br />

generational cooptation mech<strong>an</strong>ism self-perpetuates <strong>an</strong>d independently contributes to the<br />

expectation of the regime’s continuing survival.<br />

Finally, we havebeenworking withahighlysimplified modelofhierarchical <strong>as</strong>signment of<br />

18 This intuition could e<strong>as</strong>ily be formalized: <strong>The</strong> interaction between junior <strong>an</strong>d senior party members c<strong>an</strong><br />

be seen <strong>as</strong> a two-periodsnapshotof <strong>an</strong> infinitely repeated overlappinggenerationsgame. Cooperationin such<br />

a game c<strong>an</strong> then be enforced by a grim trigger threat according to which junior party members withdraw<br />

their service if the senior r<strong>an</strong>ks do not retire at a promised rate. In the c<strong>as</strong>e of Mexico, for inst<strong>an</strong>ce, the<br />

prohibition on the re-election for all elected offices may be have been interpreted by the party’s r<strong>an</strong>k-<strong>an</strong>dfile<br />

membership <strong>as</strong> a focal indicator of the elite’s commitment to upward mobility. On Folk <strong>The</strong>orems for<br />

repeated games with overlapping generations, see Smith (1992).<br />

26


CHAPTER 6<br />

service <strong>an</strong>d benefits within authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties. <strong>The</strong> <strong>as</strong>sumption of only two party r<strong>an</strong>ks is<br />

probably the starkest departure from real-world partis<strong>an</strong> hierarchies. This is a simplification<br />

whose sole purpose is to facilitate our examination of the incentives that emerge within<br />

party hierarchies by keeping our <strong>an</strong>alysis tractable. This <strong>as</strong>sumption c<strong>an</strong> be e<strong>as</strong>ily relaxed:<br />

we c<strong>an</strong> view the present setting <strong>as</strong> a partial model of career incentives across <strong>an</strong>y two levels<br />

of a multi-level party hierarchy. For inst<strong>an</strong>ce, our partial <strong>an</strong>alysis implies that, in order to<br />

provide sufficient incentives for party membership <strong>an</strong>d costly service by the junior r<strong>an</strong>ks,<br />

the ch<strong>an</strong>ces of promotion only have to be positive, not necessarily certain. When applied to<br />

<strong>an</strong>y two levels of the party hierarchy, this result explains the pyramid-shaped structure of<br />

party apparatusesthat we typically observe inauthoritari<strong>an</strong>parties. 19 Similarly, we saw that<br />

after a junior party member provides costly service, she acquires <strong>an</strong> interest in the regime’s<br />

perpetuation. When applied across <strong>an</strong>y two levels of the party hierarchy, this insight implies<br />

that a stake in the regime’s survival compounds with a member’s r<strong>an</strong>k in the party hierarchy.<br />

6.1.2 Political Control over Appointments<br />

M<strong>an</strong>y single-party dictatorships appear to have <strong>as</strong>pired after total political <strong>an</strong>d social control<br />

of their societies. As articulated by Benito Mussolini’s (1935, 30) “everything in the State,<br />

nothing outside the State, nothing against the State” (Mussolini 1935, 30), the presumed<br />

political ambition of these regimes w<strong>as</strong> a complete fusion of the state, the party, <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

society. Cl<strong>as</strong>sic works on totalitari<strong>an</strong>ism have attributed this tendency to the social atomiza-<br />

tion of modern m<strong>as</strong>s societies (Arendt 1951, 308-17) <strong>an</strong>d the emergence of all-encomp<strong>as</strong>sing<br />

ideologies whose ultimate goal w<strong>as</strong> to tr<strong>an</strong>sform the hum<strong>an</strong> nature (Friedrich <strong>an</strong>d Brzezin-<br />

19 See e.g. Brownlee (2007, <strong>Chapter</strong> 2), Hinnebusch (2002, <strong>Chapter</strong> 4), L<strong>an</strong>dry (2008), <strong>an</strong>d Staar (1988).<br />

27


CHAPTER 6<br />

ski 1965, 130-132). Thus according to Arendt (1951), the aim of totalitari<strong>an</strong>ism is “the<br />

perm<strong>an</strong>ent domination of each single individual in each <strong>an</strong>d every sphere of life” (Arendt<br />

1951, 326). Yet even by the admission of its theorists, this totalitari<strong>an</strong> ideal w<strong>as</strong> rarely<br />

approximated outside a few emblematic c<strong>as</strong>es, especially those of Adolf Hitler’s Germ<strong>an</strong>y<br />

<strong>an</strong>d Joseph Stalin’s Soviet Union.<br />

<strong>The</strong> present framework suggests a very different interpretation of the dense nexus of<br />

the party, government, <strong>an</strong>d key economic <strong>an</strong>d social positions that we observe across single<br />

<strong>an</strong>d domin<strong>an</strong>t party dictatorships. Rather th<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong> end in itself – <strong>as</strong> cl<strong>as</strong>sic theorists of<br />

totalitari<strong>an</strong>ism may view it – single <strong>an</strong>d domin<strong>an</strong>t party regimes aim at political control of<br />

their economies <strong>an</strong>d societies because such control is key to effective party-b<strong>as</strong>ed cooptation.<br />

Individual incentives to provide the costly party service that the regime values are inversely<br />

related to the e<strong>as</strong>e with which signific<strong>an</strong>t career adv<strong>an</strong>ces c<strong>an</strong> occur outside the framework of<br />

the party. Only if sufficiently m<strong>an</strong>y desirable careers depend on partis<strong>an</strong> credentials will the<br />

party be able to coopt a politically consequential fraction of the society while accomplishing<br />

the direct objective of political control.<br />

In order to examine this intuition, we may extend our model of party-b<strong>as</strong>ed cooptation<br />

by <strong>as</strong>suming that, in <strong>an</strong>y period, a citizen who is not a party member is promoted to a<br />

position that pays a wage that equals the benefit to party seniority b with probability q.<br />

Thus the expected discounted payoff to a career outside the party is now<br />

u NJ<br />

i<br />

= w +δ[quNS<br />

i +(1−q)uNJ<br />

i ], (6.7)<br />

where u NJ<br />

i istheexpected discounted payoff to apartynon-member ibeforeapromotion<strong>an</strong>d<br />

28


u NS<br />

i<br />

CHAPTER 6<br />

= b/(1−δ) is her payoff after a promotion. <strong>The</strong> modified party service constraint (6.7)<br />

<strong>as</strong>ks that u J i ≥ u NJ<br />

i . Intuitively, incentives for party membership <strong>an</strong>d the provision of the<br />

<strong>as</strong>sociated costly service are stronger when the likelihood q of obtaining benefits equivalent<br />

to party seniority outside the party is minimal.<br />

<strong>The</strong> present expl<strong>an</strong>ation also suggests that – even thought dictatorships with single par-<br />

ties may maintain deeper <strong>an</strong>d more extensive political control over their societies th<strong>an</strong> dicta-<br />

torships with domin<strong>an</strong>t parties – the underlying political logic is identical. Thus one extreme<br />

may be exemplified by the Soviet nomenklatura system whose essence, according to Rigby<br />

(1988, 523), w<strong>as</strong> to “consciously m<strong>an</strong>age every area of socially relev<strong>an</strong>t activity, outside a<br />

closely circumscribed private sphere, through <strong>an</strong> array of hierarchically structured formal<br />

org<strong>an</strong>izations, all coordinated <strong>an</strong>d directed at the center <strong>an</strong>d at successively lower levels by<br />

the apparatus of the Communist <strong>Party</strong>.” When Deng Xiaoping’s economic reforms com-<br />

promised the Chinese Communist <strong>Party</strong>’s ability to maintain such control in the emerging<br />

private sector, Ji<strong>an</strong>g Zemin recommended that private entrepreneurs be allowed to join the<br />

CCP <strong>an</strong>d encouraged the formation of gr<strong>as</strong>sroots party org<strong>an</strong>izations within private corpo-<br />

rations (Dickson 2003).<br />

On the other h<strong>an</strong>d, party control over key economic <strong>an</strong>d social appointments in dictator-<br />

ships with domin<strong>an</strong>t <strong>an</strong>d hegemonic parties is typically less formalized <strong>an</strong>d perv<strong>as</strong>ive th<strong>an</strong><br />

in dictatorships with single parties. <strong>The</strong>se regimes primarily rely on a bloated public sec-<br />

tor for the distribution of politically administered patronage (Blaydes 2010; Magaloni 2006;<br />

V<strong>an</strong> de Walle 2001) <strong>as</strong> well <strong>as</strong> the regulation <strong>an</strong>d co-ownership of the private sector. In<br />

Singapore, to take one example, the sole legal trade union since 1968 is the pro-government<br />

National Trade Union Congress <strong>an</strong>dthe government maintains political influence throughout<br />

29


CHAPTER 6<br />

the city-state’s economy through “government-linked comp<strong>an</strong>ies”, <strong>as</strong> they are known, whose<br />

corporate boards fuse government, party, <strong>an</strong>d business elites (Mauzy <strong>an</strong>d Milne 2002, 28-35).<br />

Nonetheless, inmost dictatorships withdomin<strong>an</strong>t <strong>an</strong>dhegemonic parties, thegovernment<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the party may frequently be “perceived <strong>as</strong> a single structure in terms of the pursuit off<br />

regime goals” <strong>as</strong> Grindle (1977, 47) observed about Mexico under the PRI. After Suharto’s<br />

government in Indonesia decided to hold its first post-coup election in 1971, it put in force a<br />

policy of “monoloyalty” according to which a “civil serv<strong>an</strong>t w<strong>as</strong> obliged to serve unstintingly<br />

the government that employed him, <strong>an</strong>d to renounce other competing ties”(Ward 1974, 33).<br />

In practice, all civil serv<strong>an</strong>ts were required to sever their ties with <strong>an</strong>y other party <strong>an</strong>d<br />

encouraged to join the government-s<strong>an</strong>ctioned Golkar (Elson 2001, 186-191).<br />

Because dictatorships with domin<strong>an</strong>t <strong>an</strong>d hegemonic parties have multi-party elections,<br />

political control over the public sector serves the dual role of providing incentives for party<br />

service <strong>as</strong> well <strong>as</strong> ensuring electoral hegemony. Magaloni (2006, 8) shows how in the c<strong>as</strong>e<br />

of Mexico “a public image of invincibility” discouraged both defections from within the<br />

ruling party <strong>an</strong>d helped maintain domin<strong>an</strong>ce at the polls. <strong>The</strong> present model highlights<br />

the import<strong>an</strong>ce of a large <strong>an</strong>d politically administered public sector, which in combination<br />

with the expectation of a continued control of the government strengthens the incentives for<br />

service within the governing party. As <strong>an</strong> Egypti<strong>an</strong> member of parliament for the ruling<br />

National Democratic <strong>Party</strong> explains,<br />

”<strong>The</strong> NDP is good. But I am not talking about ideology or <strong>an</strong>ything like that.<br />

This is not import<strong>an</strong>t. I do not think <strong>an</strong>y of us [NDP deputies] care about that.<br />

What I me<strong>an</strong> is that it provides access to the services needed by the people. This<br />

is because it is the President’s <strong>Party</strong>. I or <strong>an</strong>ybody else in the NDP would join<br />

30


CHAPTER 6<br />

<strong>an</strong>y party that is in the NDP’s position. This is because it would be able to<br />

provide the necessary services to the constituents.” (K<strong>as</strong>sem 1999, 81)<br />

<strong>The</strong> party’s control over a large public sector also facilitates continued electoral domi-<br />

n<strong>an</strong>ce by allowing it to condition the distribution of public funds on the m<strong>an</strong>ifestation of<br />

political loyalty at the polls. 20 When the ruling People’s Action <strong>Party</strong> in Singapore faced<br />

the risk of receiving less th<strong>an</strong> 60% of the popular vote in 1997, prime minister Goh Chok<br />

Tong exploited the government’s widespread control over public housing – <strong>as</strong> of the year<br />

2000, 86% of Singapore<strong>an</strong>s lived in public housing (Mauzy <strong>an</strong>d Milne 2002, 90) – by threat-<br />

ening to turn into “a slum” <strong>an</strong>y district that would not vote for the ruling party. <strong>The</strong> prime<br />

minister considered this strategy “the single most import<strong>an</strong>t” factor in preserving the PAP’s<br />

domin<strong>an</strong>ce at the polls. 21<br />

<strong>The</strong> modified party service constraint (6.7) also suggests that the regime c<strong>an</strong> strengthen<br />

incentives for party service in two different but related ways. First, it c<strong>an</strong> provide more<br />

attractive terms of party membership. More specifically, the former alternative implies that<br />

better outside opportunities w must be matched by a larger promotion rate p. Consistently<br />

with this prediction, one observer of Cuba notes that admission st<strong>an</strong>dards for Cuba’s Com-<br />

munist <strong>Party</strong> membership rose <strong>an</strong>d fell depending on the state of the economy: st<strong>an</strong>dards<br />

rose in the 1970s <strong>an</strong>d 1990s, when the economy is doing poorly; st<strong>an</strong>dards declined in the<br />

1980s, when the economy improved (Corbett 2002, 178). Similarly, Schnytzer <strong>an</strong>d Sustersic<br />

(1998) report that membership in the League of Communists of Yugoslavia w<strong>as</strong> positively<br />

20See e.g. Blaydes (2010) on Egypt under the National Democratic <strong>Party</strong> <strong>an</strong>d Magaloni (2006) on Mexico<br />

under the PRI.<br />

21Eventually, the PAP won 65% the popular vote <strong>an</strong>d 81 out of 83 legislative seats. See “Upgrading link<br />

swung vote in GE”, <strong>The</strong> Straits Times, 12 J<strong>an</strong>uary 1998, <strong>an</strong>d “Singapore’s Voters Get a Choice: Slums or<br />

the Ruling <strong>Party</strong>,“ <strong>The</strong> Wall Street Journal, 31 December, 1996.<br />

31


CHAPTER 6<br />

correlated with unemployment <strong>an</strong>d negatively with real wages across the federal republics.<br />

Since non-partis<strong>an</strong> opportunities for upward mobility may vary across the population, re-<br />

cruitment <strong>an</strong>d promotion policies must be targeted accordingly. Guo (2005) documents the<br />

downward trend in interest in party membership among the college-educated in China dur-<br />

ing the economic rise of the 1980s <strong>an</strong>d the ensuing targeting of the college-educated by the<br />

party in the 1990s via a screening process that favors those with a higher education.<br />

<strong>The</strong> second way in which the regime c<strong>an</strong> strengthen incentives for party service is to<br />

extend the number of career appointments for which party membership is a consideration.<br />

Moreprecisely, themodifiedpartyservice constraint (6.7)implies thattheregimec<strong>an</strong>accom-<br />

plish this by both requiring partis<strong>an</strong> credentials for a larger number of positions (a decre<strong>as</strong>e<br />

in q) <strong>an</strong>d by focusing on lucrative careers (a decre<strong>as</strong>e in w). <strong>The</strong> intuition behind the lat-<br />

ter is illustrated by Grzyma̷la-Busse’s (2002, 31) observation about the differing incentives<br />

for membership in the Communist <strong>Party</strong> of Czechoslovakia between white <strong>an</strong>d blue-collar<br />

employees:<br />

“White-collarworkers hadconsiderable incentives tojointheparty–employment<br />

in the stare sector w<strong>as</strong> made exclusively the proven<strong>an</strong>ce or the party, <strong>as</strong> w<strong>as</strong><br />

adv<strong>an</strong>cement within its r<strong>an</strong>ks. <strong>The</strong> [party] had w<strong>an</strong>ted to recruit blue-collar<br />

workers but had fewer incentives for blue-collar workers to join, <strong>an</strong>d far fewer<br />

s<strong>an</strong>ctions to keep them from leaving. For example, while white-collar workers<br />

were demoted to menial jobs if they were expelled from the party, blue-collar<br />

workers faced no such punishments.”<br />

To summarize, widespread partis<strong>an</strong> control over political, administrative, <strong>an</strong>d economic<br />

32


CHAPTER 6<br />

appointments enh<strong>an</strong>ces incentives for costly <strong>an</strong>d valuable party service. Hence this org<strong>an</strong>iza-<br />

tionalfeatureofauthoritari<strong>an</strong>partiescomplements theoneweexaminedearlier–hierarchical<br />

<strong>as</strong>signment of service <strong>an</strong>d benefits – <strong>an</strong>d thus facilitates party-b<strong>as</strong>ed cooptation. While such<br />

incentives would be strongest when partis<strong>an</strong> credentials are required for essentially <strong>an</strong>y ca-<br />

reer, the exercise of such widespread political control would encounter signific<strong>an</strong>t opposition<br />

<strong>an</strong>d hence require a matching level of repression. As the example of the Communist <strong>Party</strong><br />

of Czechoslovakia illustrates, rather th<strong>an</strong> maintaining a monopoly over all kind of careers,<br />

party-b<strong>as</strong>ed cooptation may be most effective if political control over appointments is selec-<br />

tive.<br />

6.1.3 Selective Recruitment, Promotion, <strong>an</strong>d Repression<br />

I now turn to a closer examination of the complementarity between party-b<strong>as</strong>ed cooptation<br />

<strong>an</strong>d repression suggested by the above discussion. Cooptation needs to be accomp<strong>an</strong>ied by<br />

repression because policies that establish state control over a wide r<strong>an</strong>ge of careers – r<strong>an</strong>ging<br />

from outright expropriation of key industries to heavy regulation – encounter opposition<br />

from the society. While the above discussion highlighted the benefits to partis<strong>an</strong> control<br />

over lucrative careers, a dictatorship may also benefit from being selective about the type of<br />

individuals it chooses to coopt.<br />

Whom should the regime coopt <strong>an</strong>d whom repress? In the <strong>an</strong>alysis that follows, I will<br />

focusonselective cooptationalong<strong>as</strong>ingledimension –theideological affinityfortheregime.<br />

In order to examine the relationship between ideological affinity <strong>an</strong>d cooptation, suppose<br />

that, in addition to the material benefits from cooptation via the party, each citizen also<br />

considers the incumbent dictator’s <strong>an</strong>d the challenger’s ideology when deciding whether to<br />

33


CHAPTER 6<br />

defect to the challenger. I am using the term ideology in a very broad sense, incorporating<br />

<strong>an</strong>y nonmaterial factors that may affect a citizen’s preference for the incumbent dictator<br />

vis-à-vis the challenger, including religious, ethnic, or charismatic attributes of the dictator<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the challenger.<br />

Suppose that the population’s ideology g is distributed on the real line according to<br />

the probability distribution function F(g) = Pr(gi < g) <strong>an</strong>d gi ∈ R is citizen i’s ideology.<br />

To keep the exposition simple, I will <strong>as</strong>sume that ideological concerns enter each citizen’s<br />

preferences additively, intheformofaquadraticlossfunction−(gi−gj) 2 , wheregj ∈ {gI,gC}<br />

is the incumbent’s <strong>an</strong>d challenger’s ideological position, respectively. Thus when deciding<br />

between supporting the incumbent dictator <strong>an</strong>d defecting to the challenger, each citizen is<br />

comparing her material <strong>an</strong>d ideological payoffs under the two regimes, uI = ˆ bI −(gi −gI) 2<br />

<strong>an</strong>d uC = ˆ bC − (gi − gC) 2 , where ˆ bI <strong>an</strong>d ˆ bC denote the expected per-period payoff under<br />

he incumbent dictator <strong>an</strong>d the challenger, respectively. When the incumbent coopts via a<br />

regime-s<strong>an</strong>ctioned party, ˆ bI will correspond to the average per-period payoffs (1 − δ)u J i or<br />

(1−δ)u S i<br />

, depending on citizen i’s party r<strong>an</strong>k.<br />

In addition to coopting, the incumbent c<strong>an</strong> also repress. In <strong>an</strong>y period, the cost of<br />

repressing a single citizen is r. I adopt a very rudimentary notion of repression: repressing a<br />

citizen prevents her from defecting to the challenger <strong>an</strong>d the cost of repression are const<strong>an</strong>t<br />

in a citizen’s ideology. 22<br />

Whom should the incumbent dictator coopt <strong>an</strong>d whom repress? Without a loss of gener-<br />

22 <strong>The</strong> latter reflects the idea that, once <strong>an</strong> individual decides to defect to the challenger, the cost of<br />

imprisoning her does not vary with that individual’s ideology. A more realistic model of <strong>an</strong> opposition<br />

resist<strong>an</strong>ce might <strong>as</strong>sume that the cost of repression is incre<strong>as</strong>ing in a citizen’s ideological dist<strong>an</strong>ce from the<br />

incumbent. <strong>The</strong> argument below follows <strong>as</strong> long the marginal cost of repression is incre<strong>as</strong>ing in a citizen’s<br />

ideological dist<strong>an</strong>ce from the incumbent at a lower rate that the marginal cost of cooptation.<br />

34


CHAPTER 6<br />

ality, suppose thattheincumbent dictator’sideologyistotheleft ofthechallenger’s ideology,<br />

gI < gC. Tokeep the<strong>an</strong>alysis interesting, also<strong>as</strong>sume that thebenefit fromcooptationunder<br />

the incumbent ˆ bI is large enough so that the citizen whose ideological positions is identical<br />

to that of the incumbent would prefer to support the incumbent rather th<strong>an</strong> defect to the<br />

challenger, ˆ bI ≥ ˆ bC − (gi − gC) 2 . In turn, <strong>an</strong>y citizen whose ideology is to the left of the<br />

incumbent will prefer the incumbent dictator to the challenger. Thus, the dictator’s decision<br />

of whom to coopt <strong>an</strong>d whom to repress amounts to finding a citizen with the threshold<br />

ideological position g ∗ i > gI such that the marginal cost ˆ bI of coopting this citizen equals<br />

the cost r of repressing her. In other words, the threshold ideological position g ∗ i<br />

quadratic equation,<br />

r −(gi −gI) 2 = ˆ bC −(gi −gC) 2 .<br />

solves the<br />

Because the marginal cost of cooptation are incre<strong>as</strong>ing in the ideological dist<strong>an</strong>ce from the<br />

incumbent dictator, the dictator optimally coopts all citizens to the left of g ∗ i<br />

of citizens to the right of g ∗ i .<br />

<strong>an</strong>d represses<br />

Akeyinsightthatfollowsfromthissimple<strong>an</strong>alysisisthattheincumbentregimewillcoopt<br />

those who are ideologically close to it <strong>an</strong>d repress those who are more dist<strong>an</strong>t. 23 This result<br />

is consistent with evidence on the targets of repression <strong>as</strong> well <strong>as</strong> recruitment policies <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the social structure of membership across dictatorships with single <strong>an</strong>d domin<strong>an</strong>t parties. 24<br />

But note that those who are coopted are not being “useful idiots”; party-b<strong>as</strong>ed cooptation<br />

23 M<strong>an</strong>ysingle<strong>an</strong>d domin<strong>an</strong>tpartiesalsoaim atthe most productive<strong>an</strong>d educated amongtheir population<br />

(e.g. China, Singapore, or Mexico.) As I have argued earlier, this may be because there are political benefits<br />

to the control of economically desirable appointments. But such cooptation strategy may also have <strong>an</strong><br />

additional, deterrent effect: <strong>an</strong>y challenger will have to convince his followers that he c<strong>an</strong> deliver better<br />

results th<strong>an</strong> a regime that already coopts the most productive <strong>an</strong>d educated.<br />

24 On repression, see Gregory(2009); on recruitment policies see Domínguez (1978, <strong>Chapter</strong> 8), Grzyma̷la-<br />

Busse (2002), Perthes (1995, <strong>Chapter</strong> 4), Shambaugh (2009), <strong>an</strong>d Staar (1988).<br />

35


CHAPTER 6<br />

exploits natural career <strong>as</strong>pirations within the general population in order to marginalize<br />

actual, ideological opposition<br />

To summarize my theoretical arguments so far, I have examined how three org<strong>an</strong>izational<br />

features of authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties – hierarchical <strong>as</strong>signment of service <strong>an</strong>d benefits, political<br />

control over appointments, <strong>an</strong>d selective recruitment <strong>an</strong>d repression – contribute to the sur-<br />

vival of dictatorships. <strong>The</strong>se features have been well known at the descriptive level, but the<br />

precise mech<strong>an</strong>isms by which they may account for authoritari<strong>an</strong> resilience is frequently left<br />

underspecified. A key empirical implication of this theoretical <strong>an</strong>alysis is that authoritari<strong>an</strong><br />

regimes that coopt via a party with these org<strong>an</strong>izational features – not necessarily a single<br />

one – survive under less favorable circumst<strong>an</strong>ces <strong>an</strong>d in the face of stronger challengers th<strong>an</strong><br />

dictatorships without a party. I now empirically <strong>as</strong>sess this prediction.<br />

6.2 <strong>Regime</strong> <strong>Parties</strong> <strong>an</strong>d <strong>Authoritari<strong>an</strong></strong> Resilience<br />

Does the establishment <strong>an</strong>d mainten<strong>an</strong>ce of a regime-s<strong>an</strong>ctioned political party contribute to<br />

the survival of a dictatorship, <strong>as</strong> the above theoretical <strong>an</strong>alysis suggests? Existing empirical<br />

research takes two approaches to this question. <strong>The</strong> first w<strong>as</strong> initiated by Geddes (1999a),<br />

who cl<strong>as</strong>sified dictatorships into personalist, military, single-party, <strong>an</strong>d their hybrids <strong>an</strong>d<br />

studied the differences in the survival of these regime categories. 25 <strong>The</strong> second is exemplified<br />

by G<strong>an</strong>dhi <strong>an</strong>d Przeworski (2007), who study the <strong>as</strong>sociation between the number of parties<br />

under dictatorship <strong>an</strong>d the survival of dictators. 26<br />

25See also Brownlee (2007, <strong>Chapter</strong> 2), Geddes (2003, <strong>Chapter</strong> 2), Hadenius <strong>an</strong>d Teorell (2007), Magaloni<br />

(2008), <strong>an</strong>d Smith (2005).<br />

26See also G<strong>an</strong>dhi <strong>an</strong>d Przeworski (2006) <strong>an</strong>d G<strong>an</strong>dhi (2008).<br />

36


CHAPTER 6<br />

While both approaches find that authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties are <strong>as</strong>sociated with the survival of<br />

regimes or leaders, they face two limitations: Because Geddes’s cl<strong>as</strong>sification of dictatorships<br />

is not b<strong>as</strong>ed on formal <strong>an</strong>d exclusively party-b<strong>as</strong>ed institutional criteria, inferences b<strong>as</strong>ed on<br />

this data raise questions about whether the longer survival of single-party regimes c<strong>an</strong> be<br />

attributed to the institution of the authoritari<strong>an</strong> party. On the other h<strong>an</strong>d, studies that<br />

examine the <strong>as</strong>sociation between the number of parties <strong>an</strong>d the survival of dictators may be<br />

confounding the effect of parties with the strength of individual leaders.<br />

Consider, first, the approaches b<strong>as</strong>ed on Geddes’s cl<strong>as</strong>sification of dictatorships into per-<br />

sonalist, military, <strong>an</strong>d single-party regimes, <strong>an</strong>d the hybrids of these ideal types. Geddes’s<br />

discussion of the rationale behind her cl<strong>as</strong>sification indicates that she devised it in order to<br />

describe the distinct patterns of leadership origin, political interests, <strong>an</strong>d exercise of power<br />

across dictatorships; it is not a cl<strong>as</strong>sification b<strong>as</strong>ed on formal institutional characteristics. 27<br />

As I have argued in <strong>Chapter</strong> 2, this cl<strong>as</strong>sification design limits our inferences about the<br />

effect of authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties on the survival of dictatorships in two ways. First, because<br />

Geddes’s cl<strong>as</strong>sification is not b<strong>as</strong>ed on formal institutional characteristics, some personalist<br />

<strong>an</strong>d military dictatorships in fact have either multiple political parties (e.g. Brazil during<br />

the military dictatorship from 1965 to 1979) or maintain a single party (e.g. the Cameroon<br />

People’s Democratic Movement under Paul Biya between 1985 <strong>an</strong>d 1990). On the other<br />

h<strong>an</strong>d, some single-party regimes allow for a nontrivial participation of more th<strong>an</strong> one party<br />

(e.g. PAN, <strong>an</strong>d later PRD, in Mexico). In turn, because Geddes’s cl<strong>as</strong>sification is b<strong>as</strong>ed on<br />

a set of criteria that attempt to reflect the functioning of a dictatorship broadly rather th<strong>an</strong><br />

specific institutional characteristics, the distinction between the categories of personalist,<br />

27 See Geddes (1999b, 123-125), Geddes (1999a, 17-22), <strong>an</strong>d Geddes (2003, 69-78).<br />

37


CHAPTER 6<br />

military, <strong>an</strong>d single-party provides only a limited me<strong>as</strong>ure of the restrictions on <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

presence of political parties across these categories.<br />

Second, <strong>an</strong>d more import<strong>an</strong>tly, if we are interested in whether political parties contribute<br />

to the survival of dictatorships, the contr<strong>as</strong>t between personalist, military, <strong>an</strong>d single-party<br />

dictatorships is not the conceptually appropriate one. Rather, the relev<strong>an</strong>t conceptual dis-<br />

tinction should reflect differences in the partis<strong>an</strong> org<strong>an</strong>ization across dictatorships. Some<br />

regimes b<strong>an</strong> political parties entirely, some s<strong>an</strong>ction the existence of a single party, <strong>an</strong>d<br />

others allow multiple parties to operate. Hence the proper conceptual b<strong>as</strong>eline to which<br />

single-party regimes should be compared are not military or personalist dictatorships but<br />

instead those that b<strong>an</strong> parties entirely <strong>an</strong>d those that allow for multiple political parties.<br />

Crucially, single-party regimes may compare to either of these categories differently th<strong>an</strong><br />

they compare to the categories of military <strong>an</strong>d personalist dictatorships. <strong>The</strong>refore the lat-<br />

ter may not be the appropriate comparison groups when we are interested in the effect of<br />

political parties on the survival of dictatorships.<br />

Me<strong>an</strong>while, approaches that use the length of leader tenures in order to <strong>as</strong>sess whether<br />

authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties contribute to authoritari<strong>an</strong> survival potentially confound the effect of<br />

parties with the strength of individual leaders. Consider for inst<strong>an</strong>ce the Popular Movement<br />

of the Revolution, which w<strong>as</strong> founded <strong>an</strong>d maintained <strong>as</strong> the sole party in the Congo by<br />

Mobutu, between 1967 <strong>an</strong>d 1997. In spite of Mobutu’s long tenure in office, the Popular<br />

Movement of the Revolution did not survive his fall from power <strong>an</strong>d appears to have merely<br />

been Mobutu’s propag<strong>an</strong>da tool, lacking <strong>an</strong>y subst<strong>an</strong>tive institutional structure (Callaghy<br />

1984, 10, 320). By contr<strong>as</strong>t, Mexic<strong>an</strong> presidents left office every six years, yet the same<br />

party ruled Mexico for more th<strong>an</strong> 70 years <strong>an</strong>d, according to most accounts, w<strong>as</strong> a key factor<br />

38


ehind the regime’s stability (Magaloni 2006).<br />

CHAPTER 6<br />

Hence the duration of leader tenures is <strong>an</strong> imperfect metric of the potential contribution<br />

of authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties to regime survival: First, this approach risks confounding the effect<br />

of the party with the strength of the leader, <strong>as</strong> illustrated by those c<strong>as</strong>es when the latter<br />

uses his power to establish a weak single-party that collapses when the leader is removed<br />

from power or dies. Second, this approach potentially underestimates the contribution of<br />

the party to authoritari<strong>an</strong> survival when the same political coalitions remains in power in<br />

spite of frequent leadership ch<strong>an</strong>ges within the governing party, <strong>as</strong> w<strong>as</strong> the c<strong>as</strong>e in Mexico.<br />

6.2.1 <strong>Regime</strong> <strong>Parties</strong> <strong>an</strong>d the Survival of <strong>Authoritari<strong>an</strong></strong> Ruling<br />

Coalitions<br />

Iaddress these limitationsoftheexisting approachesintwo ways: Idevelop <strong>an</strong>ewme<strong>as</strong>ureof<br />

authoritari<strong>an</strong>stability<strong>an</strong>demploydirect, institutionalindicatorsofthepartis<strong>an</strong>org<strong>an</strong>ization<br />

of dictatorships.<br />

In order to me<strong>as</strong>ure authoritari<strong>an</strong> stability, I study the survival of authoritari<strong>an</strong> ruling<br />

coalitions. A ruling coalition consists of the uninterrupted succession in office of politically<br />

affiliated authoritari<strong>an</strong> leaders. More precisely, I say that a leader w<strong>as</strong> affiliated with the<br />

previous regime, <strong>an</strong>d hence from the same ruling coalition, if he w<strong>as</strong> a member of the govern-<br />

ment, a government party, the royal or ruling family, or a military junta under the previous<br />

authoritari<strong>an</strong> leader.<br />

Table 6.2summarizes the politicalaffiliationof allauthoritari<strong>an</strong>leaders during theperiod<br />

1946-2008. Weseethatabout60%ofalldictatorscomefromthesamerulingcoalition<strong>as</strong>their<br />

39


Table 6.2: Political affiliation of authoritari<strong>an</strong> leaders, 1946-2008<br />

Political Affiliation Frequency Percentage<br />

<strong>Regime</strong> 408 60.44<br />

Unaffiliated 135 20.00<br />

Opposition 79 11.70<br />

Independence 53 7.85<br />

Note: <strong>The</strong> unit of observation is <strong>an</strong> authoritari<strong>an</strong> leader. See the codebook<br />

for details about coding rules for each category.<br />

CHAPTER 6<br />

predecessor. Prominent examples of ruling coalitions that sp<strong>an</strong> multiple leaders include the<br />

leadership incommunist <strong>an</strong>dbaathist regimes, Mexic<strong>an</strong> presidents under the PRI, hereditary<br />

successions in m<strong>an</strong>y Middle E<strong>as</strong>tern monarchies, <strong>an</strong>d the leadership of the Argentine <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Brazili<strong>an</strong> military governments.<br />

But note that leadership ch<strong>an</strong>ges within the same ruling coalition do not always occur<br />

peacefully or constitutionally. To name one example, before becoming the president of Syria<br />

in 1970, Hafez al-Asad served <strong>as</strong> a Minister of Defence in the Baath government that came<br />

to power in 1966. Al-Asad came to power by staging a coup against the de facto head<br />

of government Salah Jadid, after growing disagreements over the direction of the country<br />

between Jadid’s ideological <strong>an</strong>d al-Asad’s pragmatic faction within the Baath party <strong>an</strong>d<br />

military (Seale 1990, <strong>Chapter</strong> 11).<br />

When recording the political affiliation of those authoritari<strong>an</strong> leaders who were not af-<br />

filiated with the previous regime, I distinguish between leaders who were in opposition,<br />

unaffiliated leaders, <strong>an</strong>d leaders of newly independent countries. A leader w<strong>as</strong> in opposition,<br />

if heopenly opposedthe previous leader prior to<strong>as</strong>suming office, typically <strong>as</strong>aguerilla leader<br />

or <strong>an</strong> opposition c<strong>an</strong>didate in <strong>an</strong> executive or legislative election. I say that a leader w<strong>as</strong><br />

40


Frequency<br />

0 50 100 150 200<br />

0 20 40 60<br />

Duration in years<br />

Figure 6.1: T he duration of authoritari<strong>an</strong> ruling coalitions, 1946-2008.<br />

CHAPTER 6<br />

unaffiliated with the previous authoritari<strong>an</strong> leader, if he did not openly or unambiguously<br />

state support or opposition to the preceding government. As Table 6.2 indicates, these two<br />

categories account for approximately 12% <strong>an</strong>d 20% of all authoritari<strong>an</strong> leaders, respectively.<br />

Finally, I separately record leaders who came into office at a time when their country gained<br />

independence. This category is coded separately because the nature of political conflicts <strong>an</strong>d<br />

alli<strong>an</strong>ces during independence struggles is very different from those within sovereign polities.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se leaders make up about 8% of all leaders <strong>an</strong>d are a mix of independence fighters who<br />

opposed the previous (typically) colonial government <strong>an</strong>d those who served in the previous<br />

colonial administration or legislature.<br />

<strong>The</strong> information in Table 6.2 allows us to me<strong>as</strong>ure the duration of distinct authoritari<strong>an</strong><br />

41


CHAPTER 6<br />

ruling coalitions by adding up the lengths of tenures of individual leaders from within the<br />

same regime. <strong>The</strong> resulting data contains 374 ruling coalitions whose length varies between<br />

1 <strong>an</strong>d 63 years <strong>an</strong>d 54 of which were in existence <strong>as</strong> of 2008. <strong>The</strong> me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d medi<strong>an</strong> duration<br />

of a ruling coalition is 16 <strong>an</strong>d 8 years, respectively. <strong>The</strong> distribution of ruling coalition<br />

durations is summarized by a histogram in Figure 6.1.<br />

In order to study the effect of authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties on the survival of authoritari<strong>an</strong> rul-<br />

ing coalitions, I directly me<strong>as</strong>ure two features of the partis<strong>an</strong> org<strong>an</strong>ization of dictatorships:<br />

restrictions on political parties <strong>an</strong>d the mainten<strong>an</strong>ce of a regime party. I outlined my mea-<br />

surement of restrictions on political parties in detail in <strong>Chapter</strong> 2, where I distinguished<br />

between authoritari<strong>an</strong> regimes that b<strong>an</strong> political parties, s<strong>an</strong>ction the existence of only a<br />

single party or two parties, <strong>an</strong>d those that allow multiple parties to operate. Here, I sub-<br />

sume dictatorships with two-parties under the latter category. 28 Figure 2.4 in <strong>Chapter</strong> 2<br />

summarized the pattern of restrictions on political parties in dictatorships throughout the<br />

period 1946-2008.<br />

In addition to restrictions on political parties, I also record whether a dictatorship main-<br />

tained a regime party. We may say that a dictatorship h<strong>as</strong> a regime party when the head of<br />

theexecutive isamember ofapartyorendorsesaparticularpoliticalparty(orapartyfront).<br />

This w<strong>as</strong> trivially the c<strong>as</strong>e in single party regimes. However, dictatorships that allowed for<br />

multiple parties did not have a regime party in about one-fourth of the country-years in the<br />

data. M<strong>an</strong>y of these c<strong>as</strong>es are military dictatorships <strong>an</strong>d monarchies that do not b<strong>an</strong> all<br />

parties but at the same time do not openly endorse a particular party, <strong>as</strong> h<strong>as</strong> been the c<strong>as</strong>e<br />

in Morocco since its independence.<br />

28 G<strong>an</strong>dhi (2008) <strong>an</strong>d Cheibub et al. (2010) employ a similar me<strong>as</strong>ure of restrictions on political parties.<br />

42


CHAPTER 6<br />

Table 6.3: Restrictions on political parties <strong>an</strong>d the survival of authoritari<strong>an</strong> ruling coalitions,<br />

1946-2008<br />

Restrictions on At the beginning At the end<br />

<strong>Party</strong> Org<strong>an</strong>ization of a Ruling Coalition of a Ruling Coalition<br />

Medi<strong>an</strong> Me<strong>an</strong> N Medi<strong>an</strong> Me<strong>an</strong> N<br />

<strong>Parties</strong> b<strong>an</strong>ned 9 16.56 81 3 13.85 57<br />

(3,15) (12.33,20.78) (2,8) (8.63,19.08)<br />

Single party 27 29.87 51 22 25.08 49<br />

(20,35) (24.51,34.24) (15,30) (20.00,30.17)<br />

Multiple parties 8 15.91 195 10 17.90 223<br />

(7,10) (13.10,18.53) (8,13) (15.26,20.54)<br />

Note: <strong>The</strong> unit of observation is <strong>an</strong> authoritari<strong>an</strong> ruling coalition. 95% confidence intervals in<br />

parentheses. Largest ruling coalition durations are right-censored; me<strong>an</strong>s are therefore<br />

underestimated.<br />

Dopartiescontribute tothesurvival ofauthoritari<strong>an</strong>rulingcoalitions? Table6.3presents<br />

the estimated me<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d medi<strong>an</strong> survival times of ruling coalitions by the type of restriction<br />

on political parties. I list the 95% confidence interval below each estimated qu<strong>an</strong>tity in Table<br />

6.3. 29 Because restrictions on political parties may vary throughout the duration of a ruling<br />

coalition, I present estimates b<strong>as</strong>ed on the type of restrictions on political parties in place<br />

both at the beginning <strong>an</strong>d at the end of a ruling coalition’s existence. 30<br />

Table 6.3 indicates that ruling coalitions with single parties indeed survive between two<br />

<strong>an</strong>d three times longer th<strong>an</strong> either those without parties or those ruling coalitions that allow<br />

for the existence of multiple parties. We see that this difference is statistically signific<strong>an</strong>t <strong>as</strong><br />

there is almost no overlap between the 95% confidence intervals for the me<strong>an</strong> or the medi<strong>an</strong><br />

29 <strong>The</strong>se confidence intervals are calculated using the Kapl<strong>an</strong>-Meier estimator, accounting for the presence<br />

of right-censored data in the sample; see Klein <strong>an</strong>d Moeschberger (2003, chapter 4).<br />

30 We may directly account for the variation in restrictions on political parties by including this information<br />

<strong>as</strong> a covariate in a survival model. Estimates b<strong>as</strong>ed on both the Cox proportional hazard model <strong>an</strong>d<br />

parametric accelerated failure-time models lead to conclusions that identical to those discussed here.<br />

43


CHAPTER 6<br />

Table 6.4: Do the survival functions of authoritari<strong>an</strong> ruling coalitions differ depending on<br />

their restrictions on political parties?<br />

Restrictions on At the beginning At the end<br />

<strong>Party</strong> Org<strong>an</strong>ization of a Ruling Coalition of a Ruling Coalition<br />

Log-r<strong>an</strong>k Wilcoxon Log-r<strong>an</strong>k Wilcoxon<br />

Single party v. <strong>Parties</strong> b<strong>an</strong>ned 11.77 ∗∗∗ 19.56 ∗∗∗ 7.78 ∗∗∗ 20.28 ∗∗∗<br />

Single party v. Multiple parties 16.83 ∗∗∗ 25.64 ∗∗∗ 4.94 ∗∗ 11.53 ∗∗∗<br />

Multiple parties v. <strong>Parties</strong> b<strong>an</strong>ned 0.01 0.47 4.36 ∗∗ 14.43 ∗∗∗<br />

Note: <strong>The</strong> unit of observation is <strong>an</strong> authoritari<strong>an</strong> ruling coalition. Signific<strong>an</strong>ce levels<br />

∗ 10%, ∗∗ 5%, ∗∗∗ 1% are for the χ 2 1 statistic.<br />

of ruling coalitions with single parties <strong>an</strong>d those of the other two categories. However,<br />

there is a subst<strong>an</strong>tial overlap between the confidence intervals for either the me<strong>an</strong> or the<br />

medi<strong>an</strong> of ruling coalitions without parties <strong>an</strong>d those with multiple parties. Hence only<br />

single-parties appear to contribute to the survival of authoritari<strong>an</strong> ruling coalitions; ruling<br />

coalitions that allow for the existence of multiple parties have a much shorter lifesp<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d<br />

do not signific<strong>an</strong>tly differ from ruling coalitions that b<strong>an</strong> parties.<br />

This conclusion is partially corroborated by tests for the overall equality of survivor<br />

functions. In Table 6.4, I report the χ 2 statistics b<strong>as</strong>ed on the log-r<strong>an</strong>k <strong>an</strong>d Wilcoxon<br />

tests, which compare overall survivor functions – rather th<strong>an</strong> particular summary statistics<br />

– across the three forms of restrictions on political parties in dictatorships. Both tests<br />

indicate that the survival dynamics of ruling coalitions in dictatorships with single parties is<br />

signific<strong>an</strong>tly different from the remaining two categories. However, the tests do not lead to<br />

<strong>an</strong>unambiguous conclusion aboutthedifferences inthesurvival dynamics ofruling coalitions<br />

without parties <strong>an</strong>d those with multiple parties; the two categories differ signific<strong>an</strong>tly when<br />

we compare restrictions on political parties at the end of a ruling coalition’s tenure but not<br />

44


Density<br />

0 .005 .01 .015 .02 .025<br />

CHAPTER 6<br />

0 20 40 60 80 100<br />

Share of legislative seats controlled by the regime party<br />

Density<br />

8%: Normal(19.57,7.55)<br />

23%: Normal(51.39,7.03)<br />

69%: Normal(75.78,11.93)<br />

Figure 6.2: <strong>The</strong> share of legislative seats controlled by authoritari<strong>an</strong> regime parties in dictatorships<br />

with multiple parties, 1946-2008.<br />

at the beginning.<br />

Do regime parties in dictatorships that allow for multiple parties contribute to their<br />

survival at all? If – <strong>as</strong> the above <strong>an</strong>alysis indicates – single parties signific<strong>an</strong>tly contribute to<br />

the survival of authoritari<strong>an</strong> ruling coalitions, then we may wonder whether, even in those<br />

dictatorships that allowformultiple parties, strong parties still contribute toregime survival,<br />

eveniftheydonotcontrolalllegislativeseats. Inordertoinvestigatethishypothesis, weneed<br />

to differentiate between authoritari<strong>an</strong> regime parties b<strong>as</strong>ed on their legislative strength. <strong>The</strong><br />

histograminFigure6.2summarizesthedistributionoftheshareoflegislativeseatscontrolled<br />

45


CHAPTER 6<br />

Table 6.5: Three subgroups of authoritari<strong>an</strong> regime parties by legislative seat share<br />

Subgroup Fraction Legislative Seat Share<br />

Me<strong>an</strong> Vari<strong>an</strong>ce 95% Conf. Int.<br />

Domin<strong>an</strong>t/hegemonic parties 69.35% 75.78 11.93 (73.41,78.15)<br />

<strong>Parties</strong> under competitive auth. 22.88% 51.39 7.04 (48.90,53.88)<br />

Tr<strong>an</strong>sitional c<strong>as</strong>es 7.78% 19.57 7.55 (17.21,21.94)<br />

Note: <strong>The</strong> unit of observation is a country-year. Maximum-likelihood estimates of a 3-component mixture<br />

of Normal densities.<br />

by authoritari<strong>an</strong> regime parties across all dictatorships with multiple parties.<br />

A notable feature of the distribution in Figure 6.2 is that it appears to contain three<br />

qualitatively distinct groups of observations. Going from left to right, there first appears to<br />

be small subset of regime parties that only have a minority of legislative seats, next there<br />

is a larger group of parties that on average control a bare majority of legislative seats, <strong>an</strong>d<br />

finally, there is a large group of regime parties that comm<strong>an</strong>d a supermajority of legislative<br />

seats.<br />

In order to better underst<strong>an</strong>d <strong>an</strong>d qu<strong>an</strong>tify the differences between these three groups,<br />

I fit to this data a mixture of three Normal densities. 31 As Table 6.5 summarizes <strong>an</strong>d the<br />

density plots in Figure 6.2 illustrate, the three groups are re<strong>as</strong>onably well represented by<br />

Normal densities with me<strong>an</strong> seat shares of 19.57, 51.39, <strong>an</strong>d 75.78. <strong>The</strong> estimates in Table<br />

6.5 also indicate that the three groups are distinct: the 95% confidence intervals for the three<br />

me<strong>an</strong>s do not overlap.<br />

<strong>The</strong> largest of these subgroups contains roughly 69% of all observations <strong>an</strong>d describes<br />

31 Since the share of legislative seats is bounded between 0 <strong>an</strong>d 1, the Normal distribution is not the<br />

most appropriate probability model for this setting; I adopt it primarily because its parameters are e<strong>as</strong>ily<br />

interpreted. On the estimation of finite mixture models, see McLachl<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d Peel (2000).<br />

46


CHAPTER 6<br />

parties that on average control about three-fourths of all legislative seats. Two examples of<br />

well-known observations in this subgroup are the PRI in Mexico during the period between<br />

1946 <strong>an</strong>d 1987 <strong>an</strong>d Golkar in Indonesia under Suharto (1971-1998). <strong>The</strong> observations in this<br />

subgroup thus correspond to a conceptual category that h<strong>as</strong> been alternately referred to <strong>as</strong><br />

domin<strong>an</strong>t parties (Greene 2007; Magaloni <strong>an</strong>d Kricheli 2010; Reuter <strong>an</strong>d G<strong>an</strong>dhi 2010) or<br />

hegemonic parties (Magaloni 2006; Blaydes 2010).<br />

<strong>The</strong> second largest of these three groups h<strong>as</strong> the me<strong>an</strong> legislative seat share of 51.39%<br />

<strong>an</strong>d accounts for roughly one-fifth of all observations. In this group, the regime party h<strong>as</strong><br />

close to a bare majority or minority in the legislature. One prominent observations in this<br />

subgroup is the Kenya Afric<strong>an</strong> National Union (KANU) after D<strong>an</strong>iel Arap Moi restored<br />

multiparty elections in 1992; KANU controlled 53% <strong>an</strong>d 51% of legislative seats in the<br />

two terms between 1992 <strong>an</strong>d 2002. Another example is the PRI which only controlled<br />

52% <strong>an</strong>d 48% of legislative seats in the Mexic<strong>an</strong> Chamber of Deputies for parts of Carlos<br />

Salin<strong>as</strong>’s <strong>an</strong>d Ernesto Zedillo’s presidencies. 32 As these c<strong>as</strong>es illustrate, signific<strong>an</strong>t legislative<br />

opposition exists in this subgroup of regimes, even if it is divided. Hence the political setting<br />

under which regime parties in this subgroup operate may be conceptually characterized <strong>as</strong><br />

“electoral authoritari<strong>an</strong>ism” (Schedler 2006) or “competitive authoritari<strong>an</strong>ism” (Levitsky<br />

<strong>an</strong>d Way 2002).<br />

<strong>The</strong> l<strong>as</strong>t of these three groups may seem somewhat perplexing: with the me<strong>an</strong> legisla-<br />

tive seat share of only 19.57%, the authoritari<strong>an</strong> leader’s party is hardly in charge of the<br />

legislature. However, once we examine the observations corresponding to this group, we see<br />

that they primarily reflect temporary tr<strong>an</strong>sitional scenarios, in which either a democracy just<br />

32 This are the legislative terms of 1988-1990 <strong>an</strong>d 1998-2000, respectively.<br />

47


CHAPTER 6<br />

tr<strong>an</strong>sitioned to dictatorship or a dictatorship is about to democratize. Alberto Fujimori is <strong>an</strong><br />

example of the former: Before he subverted democracy in Peru, he established Cambio 90, a<br />

party whose primary purpose w<strong>as</strong> to promote his presidential c<strong>an</strong>didacy in 1990. Although<br />

it strengthened its st<strong>an</strong>ding in the legislature in 1992 <strong>an</strong>d 1995, Cambio 90 initially won only<br />

17% of the seats (see e.g. Klaren 1999). Empirically, these temporary tr<strong>an</strong>sitional scenarios<br />

are rare <strong>an</strong>d account for only 8% of all observations.<br />

Doesthelegislative strength ofregime parties indictatorships that allow formultiple par-<br />

tiesparallelthecontributionofsinglepartiestothesurvivalofauthoritari<strong>an</strong>rulingcoalitions?<br />

In Table 6.6, I present <strong>an</strong> estimate of the <strong>as</strong>sociation between a regime party’s legislative<br />

seat share <strong>an</strong>d the survival of authoritari<strong>an</strong> ruling coalitions b<strong>as</strong>ed the Cox survival model.<br />

<strong>The</strong> estimated coefficients are presented in the form of a hazard ratio: a coefficient smaller<br />

th<strong>an</strong> 1 implies that the <strong>as</strong>sociated covariate reduces the relative risk that <strong>an</strong> authoritari<strong>an</strong><br />

ruling coalition loses power.<br />

Model1preserves thelargestnumber ofobservations, models2<strong>an</strong>d3controlforeconomic<br />

<strong>an</strong>dinstitutional covariatestypically employed intheresearch onauthoritari<strong>an</strong>survival. <strong>The</strong><br />

covariate data on GDP per capita <strong>an</strong>d GDP growth are from Maddison (2008), the data on<br />

fuel <strong>an</strong>d ore exports are from World B<strong>an</strong>k (2008), <strong>an</strong>d the data on democratic neighbors w<strong>as</strong><br />

constructed by combining the contiguity data from the Correlates of War Project (2006) <strong>an</strong>d<br />

the regime data described in <strong>Chapter</strong> 2.<br />

We see that there is a strong <strong>as</strong>sociation between legislative seat share <strong>an</strong>d the survival<br />

of authoritari<strong>an</strong> ruling coalitions: Each percentage point incre<strong>as</strong>e in the regime party’s<br />

seat share lowers the risk of a ruling coalition’s demise by about 2%. For inst<strong>an</strong>ce, <strong>an</strong><br />

incre<strong>as</strong>e a regime party’s legislative seat share from 55% to 75% corresponds to a 30%<br />

48


CHAPTER 6<br />

Table 6.6: <strong>The</strong> effect of a regime party’s legislative seat share on the survival of authoritari<strong>an</strong><br />

ruling coalitions<br />

(1) (2) (3)<br />

Legislative Seat Share 0.982 ∗∗∗ 0.983 ∗∗∗ 0.976 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.005) (0.005) (0.009)<br />

Log of GDP per capita 0.975 1.367<br />

(0.153) (0.453)<br />

GDP growth 0.983 0.953<br />

(0.015) (0.031)<br />

Fuel exports (% of total exports) 0.977 ∗∗<br />

(0.011)<br />

Ore exports (% of total exports) 1.010<br />

(0.010)<br />

Civili<strong>an</strong> (v. military) 0.823<br />

(0.319)<br />

Cold War 1.382<br />

(0.591)<br />

Democratic neighbors 1.301<br />

(0.861)<br />

Log-likelihood -377.402 -299.732 -101.849<br />

Ruling coalitions 126 108 65<br />

Country-years 1,224 1,035 534<br />

Note: A ch<strong>an</strong>ge-point Cox survival model, coefficients are expressed <strong>as</strong> hazard ratios. Breslow<br />

method for ties. Signific<strong>an</strong>ce levels ∗ 10%, ∗∗ 5%, ∗∗∗ 1%. Robust st<strong>an</strong>dard errors in parentheses.<br />

reduction in the <strong>an</strong>nual risk of a ruling coalition’s demise. This <strong>as</strong>sociation survives even<br />

after controlling for economic <strong>an</strong>d institutional covariates typically employed in the research<br />

on authoritari<strong>an</strong> survival. <strong>The</strong> only other covariate that is signific<strong>an</strong>tly <strong>as</strong>sociated with the<br />

survival of authoritari<strong>an</strong> ruling coalitions is the percentage of fuel exports. In fact, each<br />

point incre<strong>as</strong>e in fuel exports <strong>as</strong> a percentage of a dictatorship’s total exports h<strong>as</strong> roughly<br />

the same effect on regime survival <strong>as</strong> does a corresponding incre<strong>as</strong>e in the regime party’s<br />

legislative seat shares.<br />

49


Me<strong>an</strong> Ruling Coalition Age<br />

in Years<br />

5 10 15 20 25 30<br />

CHAPTER 6<br />

0−9 10−19 20−29 30−39 40−49 50−59 60−69 70−79 80−89 90−99<br />

Me<strong>an</strong> Legislative Seat Share<br />

Me<strong>an</strong> Ruling Coalition Age Linear Fit<br />

Figure 6.3: <strong>The</strong> <strong>as</strong>sociation between legislative seat share <strong>an</strong>d the age of authoritari<strong>an</strong> ruling<br />

coalitions, 1946-2008.<br />

Inordertoillustratethis<strong>as</strong>sociation, Iplottheme<strong>an</strong>ageofauthoritari<strong>an</strong>rulingcoalitions<br />

against the me<strong>an</strong> share of legislative seats that the coalition’s regime party controlled in<br />

Figure 6.3. To simplify the presentation, the latter qu<strong>an</strong>tity is grouped into ten equally<br />

spaced intervals. We see that dictatorships with regime parties that control a supermajority<br />

of legislative seats survive on average almost <strong>as</strong> long <strong>as</strong> those with single parties.<br />

To summarize, the findings of this empirical <strong>an</strong>alysis are consistent with the implications<br />

of my theoretical <strong>an</strong>alysis in Section 6.1. We see that the empirical <strong>as</strong>sociation between<br />

dictatorships withsingleparties<strong>an</strong>dthesurvival oftheregimesthatmaintainthemisrobust.<br />

50


CHAPTER 6<br />

I attempted a stronger test of this <strong>as</strong>sociation th<strong>an</strong> h<strong>as</strong> been carried out in existing research.<br />

Specifically, I avoid confounding the effect of parties with the strength of individual leaders<br />

by me<strong>as</strong>uring the survival of authoritari<strong>an</strong> ruling coalitions rather th<strong>an</strong> individual leaders<br />

<strong>an</strong>d I employ direct, institutional indicators of the partis<strong>an</strong> org<strong>an</strong>ization of dictatorships.<br />

We also arrive at several new insights into the relationship between authoritari<strong>an</strong> regime<br />

parties <strong>an</strong>d the survival of dictatorships. What appears to be key to the survival of authori-<br />

tari<strong>an</strong>ruling coalitionsis thepresence of<strong>as</strong>trong party, notnecessarily a singleone. Oncewe<br />

control for the regime party’s legislative strength in dictatorships with multiple parties, we<br />

see that ruling coalitions with parties that control a supermajority of seats in the legislature<br />

survive on average about <strong>as</strong> long <strong>as</strong> ruling coalitions with single parties. Consistent with the<br />

theoretical <strong>an</strong>alysis in this chapter, this finding suggests that – in order to better underst<strong>an</strong>d<br />

the institutional origins of this resilience – we should focus on those institutional features<br />

of regime parties that are common to both single <strong>an</strong>d hegemonic or domin<strong>an</strong>t parties, <strong>as</strong> I<br />

have attempted in the theoretical part of this chapter.<br />

Finally, my <strong>an</strong>alysis of original data on the legislative seat share of authoritari<strong>an</strong> regime<br />

partiesshows that thesepartiescome inthree distinct forms: hegemonic ordomin<strong>an</strong>t parties,<br />

parties under competitive authoritari<strong>an</strong>ism, <strong>an</strong>d parties in tr<strong>an</strong>sitioning regimes. Since the<br />

first two groups account for more th<strong>an</strong> 90% of all observations, the present <strong>an</strong>alysis suggests<br />

that regime parties in multiple-party dictatorships effectively take one of these two forms.<br />

Import<strong>an</strong>tly, thesamepartymaytakeeachoftheseforms,dependingontheregime’sevolving<br />

strength, <strong>as</strong>theexampleofthePRIillustrates. Import<strong>an</strong>tly, whenIempiricallyidentifythese<br />

categories of authoritari<strong>an</strong> regime parties, I do not rely on a pre-defined criterion on their<br />

legislative strength or durability, <strong>as</strong> is common in the ext<strong>an</strong>t literature. Especially the latter<br />

51


CHAPTER 6<br />

criterion precludes the valid use of such data in the study of authoritari<strong>an</strong> durability since<br />

survival in power p<strong>as</strong>t a fixed time threshold is <strong>as</strong>sumed by the definition of a domin<strong>an</strong>t or<br />

hegemonic party. 33 By contr<strong>as</strong>t, I infer the presence of these categories directly from the<br />

empirical distribution of their legislative seat share.<br />

6.3 <strong>Why</strong> <strong>Authoritari<strong>an</strong></strong> <strong>Regime</strong> <strong>Parties</strong>?<br />

In this chapter, I have examined the internal make-up of regime-s<strong>an</strong>ctioned authoritari<strong>an</strong><br />

parties<strong>an</strong>didentified theorg<strong>an</strong>izationalfeatures bywhich partiescontributetoauthoritari<strong>an</strong><br />

resilience. While ext<strong>an</strong>t literature frequently concludes that single <strong>an</strong>d domin<strong>an</strong>t party<br />

dictatorships coopt opposition <strong>an</strong>d maintain elite cohesion, the precise mech<strong>an</strong>isms by which<br />

the institution of the party accounts for these functions frequently remains elusive. Geddes<br />

(1999b, 135), for inst<strong>an</strong>ce, influentially observed that single-party regimes survive longer<br />

th<strong>an</strong> personalist <strong>an</strong>d military dictatorships “because their institutional structures make it<br />

relativelye<strong>as</strong>yforthemtoallowgreaterparticipation<strong>an</strong>dpopularinfluenceonpolicywithout<br />

giving up their domin<strong>an</strong>t role in the political system.” In this chapter, I attempt to adv<strong>an</strong>ce<br />

this research by identifying the specific institutional structures <strong>an</strong>d the underlying political<br />

mech<strong>an</strong>isms by which the institution of the single or domin<strong>an</strong>t party accounts for Geddes’s<br />

observation.<br />

Three org<strong>an</strong>izational features of authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties – hierarchical <strong>as</strong>signment of service<br />

<strong>an</strong>d benefits, political control over appointments, <strong>an</strong>d selective recruitment <strong>an</strong>d repression<br />

33 For inst<strong>an</strong>ce, Magaloni (2006, 36-37) <strong>an</strong>d Greene (2007, 12) <strong>as</strong>k that a domin<strong>an</strong>t party controls the<br />

executive <strong>an</strong>d the legislature for at le<strong>as</strong>t 20 years, <strong>an</strong>d Geddes (1999b, 125) calls <strong>an</strong> authoritari<strong>an</strong> regime<br />

single-party if the “domin<strong>an</strong>t party h<strong>as</strong> never lost control of the executive since coming to power <strong>an</strong>d usually<br />

wins more th<strong>an</strong> two thirds of the seats in the legislature.”<br />

52


CHAPTER 6<br />

– take adv<strong>an</strong>tage of natural career <strong>as</strong>pirations in order to create <strong>an</strong> enduring stake in the<br />

regime’s survival among the most productive <strong>an</strong>d ideologically agreeable segments of the<br />

population. This <strong>an</strong>alysis highlights the need to <strong>an</strong>alytically distinguish between cooptation<br />

via policies or tr<strong>an</strong>sfers, <strong>an</strong>d cooptation via the institution of the party. <strong>The</strong> adv<strong>an</strong>tages <strong>an</strong>d<br />

operation of the latter are intimately linked to specific org<strong>an</strong>izational features of authori-<br />

tari<strong>an</strong> parties. <strong>The</strong> simple formal models of party-b<strong>as</strong>ed cooptation in Section 6.1 help us<br />

examine the political mech<strong>an</strong>ism by which those org<strong>an</strong>izational features facilitate cooptation<br />

<strong>an</strong>d suggest that, rather th<strong>an</strong> “political exch<strong>an</strong>ge”, cooptation via authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties is<br />

better thought of <strong>as</strong> “sunk investment” on part of their members.<br />

Crucially, these models help us underst<strong>an</strong>d not only the potential of party-b<strong>as</strong>ed coop-<br />

tation but also its limits. We saw that cooptation via the institution of the party must be<br />

initiated by a signal of the regime’s strength, it requires the mainten<strong>an</strong>ce of a politically<br />

sensitive bal<strong>an</strong>ce between recruitment, promotion, <strong>an</strong>d retirement policies within the party,<br />

<strong>an</strong>d contributes to the regime’s resilience to challengers from the outside but not from the<br />

inside. <strong>The</strong> theoretical <strong>an</strong>alysis in this chapter h<strong>as</strong> so far focused on the first of the three<br />

questions that I <strong>as</strong>ked at the outset: How <strong>an</strong>d which org<strong>an</strong>izational features of authoritari<strong>an</strong><br />

parties contribute to authoritari<strong>an</strong> resilience? An explicit focus on both the potential of but<br />

also the limits to party-b<strong>as</strong>ed cooptation allows us to address the two remaining, affiliated<br />

questions.<br />

<strong>Why</strong> c<strong>an</strong>not dictators obtain the political benefits of party-b<strong>as</strong>ed cooptation <strong>an</strong>d control<br />

without the actual institution of the party? According to the arguments outlined above,<br />

the institution of the party provides the org<strong>an</strong>izational skeleton through which the regime<br />

jointly m<strong>an</strong>ages hierarchical <strong>as</strong>signment of service <strong>an</strong>d benefits, selective recruitment <strong>an</strong>d<br />

53


CHAPTER 6<br />

repression, <strong>an</strong>d maintains political control over appointments. <strong>The</strong> primary role of the latter<br />

two org<strong>an</strong>izationalfeaturesistoenh<strong>an</strong>ce theeffectiveness withwhich hierarchical <strong>as</strong>signment<br />

of service <strong>an</strong>d benefits generates incentives for party members to remain loyal <strong>an</strong>d provide<br />

costly political service. Although the three org<strong>an</strong>izational features could be in principle<br />

administered inisolation, withinseparateinstitutions, theircomplementarity createsbenefits<br />

to their coordination <strong>an</strong>d m<strong>an</strong>agement within a single institution – the regime party.<br />

<strong>Why</strong> do not all dictatorships establish <strong>an</strong>d maintain a regime-s<strong>an</strong>ctioned party? By<br />

examining the political logic that underlies the functioning of authoritari<strong>an</strong> parties, we also<br />

gain insight into the limits of party-b<strong>as</strong>ed cooptation <strong>an</strong>d control. <strong>The</strong> <strong>an</strong>alysis in this<br />

chapter implies that the effective operation of the three org<strong>an</strong>izational features that I have<br />

discussed requires that the regime provide partis<strong>an</strong> access to a large number of political,<br />

economic, <strong>an</strong>d social appointments <strong>an</strong>d thus ch<strong>an</strong>nel signific<strong>an</strong>t resources through the party.<br />

Wemaytherefore expect thatdictatorships whose support b<strong>as</strong>eislimited totraditional elites<br />

– l<strong>an</strong>ded aristocracy or the owners of capital – will not be willing to give up the resources<br />

necessary for the party to effectively perform its cooptation <strong>an</strong>d control functions. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

regimes will find cooptation <strong>an</strong>d control via parties less adv<strong>an</strong>tageous th<strong>an</strong> the alternatives<br />

of repression <strong>an</strong>d cooptation via direct tr<strong>an</strong>sfers. <strong>The</strong> <strong>an</strong>alysis in this chapter thus helps<br />

us underst<strong>an</strong>d why dictatorships in particular structural conditions do not establish regime-<br />

s<strong>an</strong>ctioned parties or maintain parties without the org<strong>an</strong>izational features examined here,<br />

which in turn remain politically inconsequential.<br />

54


Bibliography<br />

Abrami, Regina, Edmund Malesky, <strong>an</strong>d Yu Zheng. 2008. “Accountability <strong>an</strong>d Inequality<br />

in Single-<strong>Party</strong> <strong>Regime</strong>s: A Comparative Analysis of Vietnam <strong>an</strong>d China.” Unpublished<br />

Working Paper .<br />

Arendt, H<strong>an</strong>nah. 1951. <strong>The</strong> Origins of Totalitari<strong>an</strong>ism. New York: Harvest Books.<br />

Batatu, H<strong>an</strong>na. 1978. <strong>The</strong> Old Social Cl<strong>as</strong>ses <strong>an</strong>d the Revolutionary Movements In Iraq.<br />

Princeton: Princeton University Press.<br />

Batatu, H<strong>an</strong>na. 1981. “Some Observations on the Social Roots of Syria’s Ruling, Military<br />

Group <strong>an</strong>d the Causes for Its Domin<strong>an</strong>ce.” Middle E<strong>as</strong>t Journal 35(3):331–344.<br />

Baum, Richard. 1997. “<strong>The</strong> road to Ti<strong>an</strong><strong>an</strong>men: Chinese politics in the 1980s.” In MacFar-<br />

quhar, Roderick (Ed.), “<strong>The</strong> Politics of China. <strong>The</strong> Er<strong>as</strong> of Mao <strong>an</strong>d Deng,” New York:<br />

Cambridge University Press, pp. 340–371.<br />

Blaydes, Lisa. 2010. Elections <strong>an</strong>d Distributive Politics in Mubaraks Egypt. New York:<br />

Cambridge University Press.<br />

Bo, Zhiyue. 2007. China’s elite politics: Political tr<strong>an</strong>sition <strong>an</strong>d power bal<strong>an</strong>cing. NewJersey:<br />

World Scientific.<br />

Br<strong>an</strong>denburg, Fr<strong>an</strong>k. 1964. <strong>The</strong> Making of Modern Mexico. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-<br />

55


Hall.<br />

BIBLIOGRAPHY<br />

Bratton, Michael <strong>an</strong>dNicol<strong>as</strong>V<strong>an</strong>deWalle. 1997. Democratic experiments in Africa: <strong>Regime</strong><br />

tr<strong>an</strong>sitions in comparative perspective. New York: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Brownlee, J<strong>as</strong>on. 2007. <strong>Authoritari<strong>an</strong></strong>ism in <strong>an</strong> Age of Democratization. New York: Cam-<br />

bridge University Press.<br />

Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, Al<strong>as</strong>tair Smith, R<strong>an</strong>dolph M. Siverson, <strong>an</strong>d James D. Morrow.<br />

2003. <strong>The</strong> Logic of Political Survival. Cambridge: MIT Press.<br />

Bunce, Valerie. 1999. Subversive institutions : the design <strong>an</strong>d the destruction of socialism<br />

<strong>an</strong>d the state. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Burlatsky, Fedor. 1991. Khrushchev <strong>an</strong>d the First Russi<strong>an</strong> Spring. London: Weidenfeld &<br />

Nicolson.<br />

Callaghy, Thom<strong>as</strong> M. 1984. <strong>The</strong> state-society struggle: Zaire in comparative perspective.<br />

New York: Columbia University Press.<br />

C<strong>as</strong>tañeda, Jorge G. 2000. Perpetuating power: How Mexic<strong>an</strong> presidents were chosen. New<br />

York: New Press.<br />

Ch<strong>an</strong>, Heng Chee. 1976. “<strong>The</strong> Role of Parliamentary Politici<strong>an</strong>s in Singapore.” Legislative<br />

Studies Quarterly 1(3):423–441.<br />

Cheibub, José A., Jennifer G<strong>an</strong>dhi, <strong>an</strong>d James R. Vreel<strong>an</strong>d. 2010. “Democracy <strong>an</strong>d dicta-<br />

torship revisited.” Public Choice 143(1):67–101.<br />

Corbett, Ben. 2002. This is Cuba: An outlaw culture survives. Cambridge, MA: Westview<br />

Press.<br />

Correlates of War Project. 2006. Direct Contiguity Data, 1816-2006. Version 3.1.<br />

Crouch, Harold. 1978. <strong>The</strong> army <strong>an</strong>d politics in Indonesia. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University<br />

56


Press.<br />

BIBLIOGRAPHY<br />

Dickson, Bruce J. 2003. Red Capitalists in China: <strong>The</strong> <strong>Party</strong>, Private Entrepreneurs, <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Prospects for Political Ch<strong>an</strong>ge. New York: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Domínguez, Jorge I. 1978. Cuba: order <strong>an</strong>d revolution. Cambridge, M<strong>as</strong>s.: Belknap Press.<br />

Edin, Maria. 2003. “State Capacity <strong>an</strong>d Local Agent Control in China: CCP Cadre M<strong>an</strong>-<br />

agement from a Township Perspective.” <strong>The</strong> China Quarterly 173:35–52.<br />

Elson, R. E. 2001. Suharto: A Political Biography. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Friedrich, Karl <strong>an</strong>d Zbigniew Brzezinski. 1965. Totalitari<strong>an</strong> Dictatorship <strong>an</strong>d Autocracy.<br />

Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.<br />

G<strong>an</strong>dhi, Jennifer. 2008. Political Institutions under Dictatorship. New York: Cambridge<br />

University Press.<br />

G<strong>an</strong>dhi, Jennifer <strong>an</strong>d Adam Przeworski. 2006. “Cooperation, Cooptation, <strong>an</strong>d Rebellion<br />

Under Dictatorships.” Economics & Politics 18(1):1–26.<br />

G<strong>an</strong>dhi, Jennifer <strong>an</strong>d Adam Przeworski. 2007. “<strong>Authoritari<strong>an</strong></strong> Institutions <strong>an</strong>d the Survival<br />

of Autocrats.” Comparative Political Studies 40(11):1279–1301.<br />

Geddes, Barbara. 1999a. “<strong>Authoritari<strong>an</strong></strong> Breakdown: Empirical Test of a Game <strong>The</strong>oretic<br />

Argument.” Working Paper .<br />

Geddes, Barbara. 1999b. “What do we know about democratization after twenty years?”<br />

Annual Review of Political Science 2:115–144.<br />

Geddes, Barbara. 2003. Paradigms <strong>an</strong>d s<strong>an</strong>d c<strong>as</strong>tles: <strong>The</strong>ory building <strong>an</strong>d research design in<br />

comparative politics. Ann Arbor: University of Michig<strong>an</strong> Press.<br />

Geddes, Barbara. 2008. “<strong>Party</strong> Creation <strong>as</strong> <strong>an</strong> Autocratic Survival Strategy.” Unpublished<br />

M<strong>an</strong>uscript, UCLA.<br />

57


BIBLIOGRAPHY<br />

Gehlbach, Scott G. <strong>an</strong>d Philip Keefer. 2008. “Investment without Democracy: Ruling-<strong>Party</strong><br />

Institutionalization <strong>an</strong>d Credible Commitment in Autocracies.” Unpublished M<strong>an</strong>uscript,<br />

University of Wisconsin, Madison.<br />

Gershenson, Dmitriy <strong>an</strong>d Hershel I. Gorossm<strong>an</strong>. 2001. “Cooption <strong>an</strong>d repression the Soviet<br />

Union.” Economics <strong>an</strong>d Politics 13(1):31–47.<br />

Greene, Kenneth F. 2007. <strong>Why</strong> Domin<strong>an</strong>t <strong>Parties</strong> Lose: Mexico’s Democratization in Com-<br />

parative Perspective. New York: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Gregory, Paul R. 2009. Terror by Quota: State security from Lenin to Stalin. New Haven:<br />

Yale University Press.<br />

Grindle, Merilee Serrill. 1977. Bureaucrats, politici<strong>an</strong>s, <strong>an</strong>d pe<strong>as</strong><strong>an</strong>ts in Mexico: A c<strong>as</strong>e study<br />

in public policy. Berkeley: University of California Press.<br />

Grzyma̷la-Busse, Anna.2002. Redeemingthe communistp<strong>as</strong>t: the regenerationof communist<br />

parties in E<strong>as</strong>t Central Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Grzyma̷la-Busse, Anna.2007. Rebuilding Leviath<strong>an</strong>: <strong>Party</strong> competition <strong>an</strong>d state exploitation<br />

in post-communist democracies. New York: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Guo, G<strong>an</strong>g. 2005. “<strong>Party</strong> Recruitment of College Students in China.” Journal of Contem-<br />

porary China 14(43):371393.<br />

Hadenius, Axel <strong>an</strong>d J<strong>an</strong> Teorell. 2007. “Pathways From <strong>Authoritari<strong>an</strong></strong>ism.” Journal of<br />

Democracy 18(1):143–157.<br />

Hinnebusch, Raymond. 2002. Syria: Revolution From Above. London: Routledge.<br />

Hong, Lysa <strong>an</strong>d Ji<strong>an</strong>li Hu<strong>an</strong>g. 2008. <strong>The</strong> scripting of a national history: Singapore <strong>an</strong>d its<br />

p<strong>as</strong>t. Hong Kong: Hong Kong University Press.<br />

Hough, Jerry F. 1980. Soviet leadership in tr<strong>an</strong>sition. W<strong>as</strong>hington, D.C .: Brookings Insti-<br />

58


tution.<br />

BIBLIOGRAPHY<br />

Huntington, Samuel P. 1968. Political order in ch<strong>an</strong>ging societies. New Haven: Yale Uni-<br />

versity Press.<br />

Huntington, Samuel P. 1970. “Social <strong>an</strong>d Institutional Dynamics of One-<strong>Party</strong> Systems.” In<br />

Huntington, Samuel P. <strong>an</strong>d Clement H. Moore (Eds.), “<strong>Authoritari<strong>an</strong></strong> Politics in Modern<br />

Society: <strong>The</strong> Dynamics of Established One-<strong>Party</strong> Systems,” New York: B<strong>as</strong>ic Books, pp.<br />

3–45.<br />

K<strong>as</strong>sem, May. 1999. In the guise of democracy: Govern<strong>an</strong>ce in contemporary Egypt. Reading:<br />

Ithaca Press.<br />

Kitschelt, Herbert <strong>an</strong>d Steven Wilkinson. 2007. Patrons, clients, <strong>an</strong>d policies: patterns<br />

of democratic accountability <strong>an</strong>d political competition. New York: Cambridge University<br />

Press.<br />

Klaren, Peter F. 1999. Peru: Society <strong>an</strong>d Nationhood in the Andes. New York: Oxford<br />

University Press.<br />

Klein, JohnP. <strong>an</strong>dMelvin L.Moeschberger. 2003. Survival Analysis Techniques for Censored<br />

<strong>an</strong>d Truncated Data. New York: Springer.<br />

L<strong>an</strong>dry, Pierre F. 2008. Decentralized <strong>Authoritari<strong>an</strong></strong>ism in China: <strong>The</strong> Communist <strong>Party</strong>’s<br />

Control of Local Elites in the Post-Mao Era. New York: Cambridge University Press.<br />

L<strong>an</strong>gston, Joy <strong>an</strong>d Scott Morgenstern. 2009. “Campaigning in <strong>an</strong> Electoral <strong>Authoritari<strong>an</strong></strong><br />

<strong>Regime</strong>: <strong>The</strong> C<strong>as</strong>e of Mexico.” Comparative Politics 41(2):165–181.<br />

Lazarev, Valery. 2005. “Economics of One-<strong>Party</strong> State: Promotion Incentives <strong>an</strong>d Support<br />

for the Soviet <strong>Regime</strong>.” Comparative Economic Studies 47:346–363.<br />

Lazarev, Valery. 2007. “Political labor market, government policy, <strong>an</strong>d stability of a non-<br />

59


democratic regime.” Journal of Comparative Economics 35:546563.<br />

BIBLIOGRAPHY<br />

Levitsky, Steven <strong>an</strong>d Luc<strong>an</strong> A. Way. 2002. “<strong>The</strong> rise of competitive authoritari<strong>an</strong>ism.”<br />

Journal of Democracy 13(2):51–65.<br />

MacFarquhar, Roderick <strong>an</strong>d Michael Schoenhals. 2006. Maos l<strong>as</strong>t revolution. Cambridge,<br />

M<strong>as</strong>s.: Harvard University Press.<br />

Maddison, Angus. 2008. “Statistics on World Population, GDP <strong>an</strong>d Per Capita GDP, 1-2006<br />

AD.”<br />

Magaloni, Beatriz. 2006. Voting for autocracy: Hegemonic party survival <strong>an</strong>d its demise in<br />

Mexico. New York: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Magaloni, Beatriz.2008. “CrediblePower-Sharing <strong>an</strong>dtheLongevityof<strong>Authoritari<strong>an</strong></strong>Rule.”<br />

Comparative Political Studies 41(4/5):715–741.<br />

Magaloni, Beatriz <strong>an</strong>d Ruth Kricheli. 2010. “Political Order <strong>an</strong>d One-<strong>Party</strong> Rule.” Annual<br />

Review of Political Science 13:123–143.<br />

Malesky, Edmund <strong>an</strong>d Paul Schuler. 2010. “Nodding or Needling: Analyzing Delegate<br />

Responsiveness in <strong>an</strong> <strong>Authoritari<strong>an</strong></strong> Parliament.” Americ<strong>an</strong> Political Science Review<br />

104(3):482–502.<br />

M<strong>an</strong>ion, Mel<strong>an</strong>ie. 1992. “Politics <strong>an</strong>d Policy in Post-Mao Cadre Retirement.” <strong>The</strong> China<br />

Quarterly 129:1–25.<br />

M<strong>an</strong>ion, Mel<strong>an</strong>ie. 1993. Retirement of revolutionaries in China: public policies, social norms,<br />

private interests. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.<br />

Mauzy, Di<strong>an</strong>e K. <strong>an</strong>d R.S. Milne. 2002. Singapore Politics Under the People’s Action <strong>Party</strong>.<br />

London: Routledge.<br />

Mawdsley, Ev<strong>an</strong> <strong>an</strong>d Stephen White. 2000. <strong>The</strong> Soviet Elite from Lenin to Gorbachev: <strong>The</strong><br />

60


BIBLIOGRAPHY<br />

Central Committee <strong>an</strong>d Its Members, 1917-1991. New York: Oxford University Press.<br />

McLachl<strong>an</strong>, Geoffrey <strong>an</strong>d David Peel. 2000. Finite Mixture Models. New York: Wiley.<br />

Mussolini, Benito. 1935. F<strong>as</strong>cism: doctrine <strong>an</strong>d institutions. Rome: Ardita.<br />

Nath<strong>an</strong>, Andrew J. 2003. “<strong>Authoritari<strong>an</strong></strong> Resilience.” Journal of Democracy 14(1):6–17.<br />

Perthes, Volker. 1995. <strong>The</strong> Political Economy of Syria Under Asad. London: I. B. Tauris.<br />

Reuter, Ora John <strong>an</strong>d Jennifer G<strong>an</strong>dhi. 2010. “Economic Perform<strong>an</strong>ce <strong>an</strong>d Elite Defection<br />

from Hegemonic <strong>Parties</strong>.” Brit 41:83–110.<br />

Rigby, T. H. 1968. Communist <strong>Party</strong> membership in the U.S.S.R., 1917-1967. Princeton,<br />

N.J.: Princeton University Press.<br />

Rigby, T. H. 1988. “Staffing USSR Incorporated: <strong>The</strong> Origins of the Nomenklatura System.”<br />

Soviet Studies 40(4):523–537.<br />

Rush, Myron. 1991. <strong>The</strong> Fate of the <strong>Party</strong> Apparatus Under Gorbachev. RANDCorporation.<br />

Schedler, Andre<strong>as</strong>. 2006. Electoral <strong>Authoritari<strong>an</strong></strong>ism: <strong>The</strong> Dynamics of Unfree Competition.<br />

Boulder: Lynne Rienner.<br />

Schnytzer, Adi <strong>an</strong>d J<strong>an</strong>ez Sustersic. 1998. “<strong>Why</strong> join the party in a one-party system?<br />

Popularity versus political exch<strong>an</strong>ge.” Public Choice 94:117134.<br />

Seale, Patrick. 1990. Asad: <strong>The</strong> Struggle for the Middle E<strong>as</strong>t. Berkeley: University of<br />

California Press.<br />

Shambaugh, David. 2009. China’s Communist <strong>Party</strong>: Atrophy <strong>an</strong>d Adaptation. Berkeley:<br />

University of California Press.<br />

Simons, William B. <strong>an</strong>d Stephen White. 1984. <strong>The</strong> <strong>Party</strong> statutes of the Communist world.<br />

Boston: Kluwer.<br />

Sissons, Mir<strong>an</strong>da. 2008. “Iraq’s New Accountability <strong>an</strong>d Justice Law.” International Center<br />

61


for Tr<strong>an</strong>sitional Justice Briefing Paper .<br />

BIBLIOGRAPHY<br />

Slater, D<strong>an</strong>. 2003. “Iron Cage in <strong>an</strong> Iron Fist: <strong>Authoritari<strong>an</strong></strong> Institutions <strong>an</strong>d the Personal-<br />

ization of Power in Malaysia.” Comparative Politics 36(1):81–101.<br />

Smith, Benjamin. 2005. “Life of the <strong>Party</strong>: <strong>The</strong> Origins of <strong>Regime</strong> Breakdown <strong>an</strong>d Persis-<br />

tence Under Single-<strong>Party</strong> Rule.” World Politics 57(3):421–51.<br />

Smith, Lones.1992. “Folktheoremsinoverlappinggenerationsgames.” Games <strong>an</strong>dEconomic<br />

Behavior 4(3):426–449.<br />

Staar, Richard F. 1988. Communist regimes in E<strong>as</strong>tern Europe. St<strong>an</strong>ford, Calif.: Hoover<br />

Institution Press.<br />

Stevens, Evelyn P. 1974. Protest <strong>an</strong>d Response in Mexico. Cambridge, M<strong>as</strong>s.: MIT Press.<br />

Tompson, William. 2003. <strong>The</strong> Soviet Union under Brezhnev. Pearson.<br />

Tompson, William J. 1995. Khrushchev: A Political Life. New York: Macmill<strong>an</strong>.<br />

V<strong>an</strong> de Walle, Nicol<strong>as</strong>. 2001. Afric<strong>an</strong> economies <strong>an</strong>d the politics of perm<strong>an</strong>ent crisis, 1979-<br />

1999. New York: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Voslensky, Michael. 1984. Nomenklatura: the Soviet ruling cl<strong>as</strong>s. Doubleday.<br />

Walder, Andrew G. 1995. “Career Mobility <strong>an</strong>d the Communist Political Order.” Americ<strong>an</strong><br />

Sociological Review 60(3):309–328.<br />

Ward, Ken. 1974. <strong>The</strong> 1971 Elections in Indonesia: An E<strong>as</strong>t Java C<strong>as</strong>e Study. Mon<strong>as</strong>h<br />

University: Center of Southe<strong>as</strong>t Asi<strong>an</strong> Studies.<br />

Waterbury, John. 1983. <strong>The</strong> Egypt of N<strong>as</strong>ser <strong>an</strong>d Sadat: <strong>The</strong> political economy of two<br />

regimes. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.<br />

Wintrobe, Ronald. 1998. <strong>The</strong> political economy of dictatorship. Cambridge: Cambridge<br />

University Press.<br />

62


World B<strong>an</strong>k. 2008. World Development Indicators. WorldB<strong>an</strong>k.<br />

63<br />

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!