05.02.2013 Views

From Principle-Based Risk Management to Solvency ... - Scor

From Principle-Based Risk Management to Solvency ... - Scor

From Principle-Based Risk Management to Solvency ... - Scor

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

is not exercised, and that fi(ORPi) denotes the pay out from the ORP in<br />

year i.<br />

For balance sheets which are not economic in the sense above, it might<br />

not be possible <strong>to</strong> express the additional restriction in terms of values and<br />

ORPs. At any rate, the restriction introduces additional frictional costs.<br />

There is an obvious instrument <strong>to</strong> provide the one-year max covers: the<br />

shareholders equity. The equity corresponds <strong>to</strong> capital put up by outside<br />

inves<strong>to</strong>rs, which in an economic balance sheet corresponds <strong>to</strong> the difference<br />

between the market-consistent value of the assets less the market-consistent<br />

value of the liabilities.<br />

In this situation, the composition of the asset side is per se arbitrary,<br />

and so the assets do not necessarily replicate the liabilities in the sense of<br />

the ORP. This results in an additional cash flow mismatch between assets<br />

and liabilities. However, for simplicity we assume in the following that the<br />

assets correspond <strong>to</strong> the required super-replicating portfolio.<br />

Valuation of the basis risk, which we reformulated as valuation of the<br />

required coupon for the one-year max covers, is then further translated in<strong>to</strong><br />

the cost of capital margin CoCM approach. In this approach, one needs <strong>to</strong><br />

determine<br />

� The required shareholder capital ˜ Ki for all years i<br />

� The cost of capital, i.e. the required return on the capital ηi<br />

The required return on capital ηi is a proportionality fac<strong>to</strong>r applied <strong>to</strong> the<br />

required capital ˜ Ki. Per se, the returns can be different for different years.<br />

However, in practice, one usually assumes that the required return is prescribed<br />

externally and is constant over the years equal <strong>to</strong> some η. The<br />

required return on capital has <strong>to</strong> be unders<strong>to</strong>od as an expected value: The<br />

expected value of the actual return has <strong>to</strong> be equal <strong>to</strong> the required return.<br />

The required capital corresponds <strong>to</strong> the amounts Ki for the one-year max<br />

covers. Usually, <strong>to</strong> calculate the amounts Ki, the supremum over a set Ω ⋆ t<br />

of states of the world is expressed by choosing an appropriate, usually lawinvariant<br />

risk measure. For instance, selecting the same law-invariant risk<br />

measure ρ for any year i, the formula (2.7) for the amounts Ki determined<br />

at time t becomes<br />

Ki = ρ(Mi) (2.9)<br />

where the distribution of the mismatch Mi given by (2.8) is conditional on<br />

the information available at time t ≤ i.<br />

Since the set Ω ⋆ t reflects the states of the world where the default option<br />

is not exercised, the selection of the risk measure is directly connected <strong>to</strong><br />

the (value of the) default option. For instance, selecting as risk measure the<br />

expected shortfall at a less conservative level α = 10% instead of at α =1%<br />

21

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!