25.02.2013 Views

Merger Controls First Edition - J Sagar Associates

Merger Controls First Edition - J Sagar Associates

Merger Controls First Edition - J Sagar Associates

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Ashurst LLP United Kingdom<br />

important UK national newspaper titles with Sky News, BSkyB’s wholesale and retail news provider. Concerns were<br />

identified that this would result in a loss of plurality as the second and fourth largest news providers came together. Rather<br />

than refer the merger to the CC (as Ofcom had recommended) the Secretary of State concluded, following discussions<br />

with NewsCorp, that undertakings in lieu of reference could be used, requiring BSkyB to separate out Sky News from the<br />

merger so that NewsCorp would continue to have only a minority stake of 39 per cent in it, with other provisions to ensure<br />

the editorial independence and integrity of Sky News. Ultimately, this merger was abandoned.<br />

Many media sector mergers are assessed simply on competition grounds, but transactions involving the larger players<br />

and/or consolidation of the more important news sources in the UK may well merit additional scrutiny and government<br />

involvement in the clearance process, to ensure that the public interest is protected.<br />

Key economic appraisal techniques applied<br />

The UK Guidelines provide a good overview of the range of economic techniques applied by the OFT and the CC, and<br />

these are considered further in Chapter 1 of The ICLG to: <strong>Merger</strong> Control 2011 on “The Economics of Horizontal <strong>Merger</strong>s<br />

– recent lessons in avoiding surprises”. The Commentary on retail mergers provides further guidance in the specific<br />

context of retailing mergers.<br />

De-emphasising market definition<br />

One of the key points to note as regards the UK Guidelines is that there has been a shift away from concentrating the<br />

competition analysis on market definition and market shares towards more directly considering the degree of rivalry<br />

between firms, including identifying which businesses are the closest competitors. This is particularly an issue in<br />

“differentiated” markets. Differentiated markets arise where there are tangible differences in products or services, or<br />

according to the locations in which they are available (unlike, for example, internationally traded commodities).<br />

Differentiation is a key feature of many markets due to differences in firms’:<br />

• products/services (characteristics, quality, branding and so on); and/or<br />

• geographical proximity (which impacts on firms’ competitiveness due to transport costs or if customers prefer to<br />

buy from local suppliers).<br />

In differentiated markets, the significance of a merger will not necessarily be reflected by market shares as some firms<br />

may be much closer rivals than others, whilst at the same time it would be wrong to disregard rivalry from those firms<br />

whose products are less close substitutes.<br />

Instead, there is an increasing tendency for market definition questions to be re-focused on whether a merger between<br />

rivals creates upward pricing pressure or reduces rivalry in other dimensions.<br />

Theoretical measures of upward pricing pressure<br />

One particular theoretical measure, Upward Pricing Pressure (“UPP”), has been advanced by Farrell and Shapiro (2010).<br />

(Joseph Farrell is Director of the Bureau of Economics at the Federal Trade Commission, and Carl Shapiro is the Deputy<br />

Assistant Attorney General for Economics at the Antitrust division of the US Department of Justice.)<br />

The intuition underpinning measures assessing upward pricing pressure is that following a merger between competitors:<br />

• each merging firm may have an incentive to raise its price post-merger, because it would recapture through its<br />

merging partner some of the sales it would have lost pre-merger as a consequence of price increases. The “diversion<br />

ratio” refers to the percentage of sales lost by one firm which are won by another – the higher this ratio is between<br />

two firms, the “closer” these firms are as competitors; and<br />

• the value of these recaptured sales is evaluated by multiplying the diversion ratio between the merging firms’<br />

products by the gross profit margin on the merging partner’s product (i.e. the increase in contribution to fixed costs<br />

and profits from winning the additional sales). The higher the diversion ratios between the parties and their gross<br />

profit margins, the greater the value of recaptured sales.<br />

Farrell and Shapiro propose a simple test of upward pricing pressure, which has been referred to as the gross upward<br />

pricing pressure index (“GUPPI”), which is simply based on the value of recaptured sales. They argue that the greater the<br />

value of recaptured sales, the greater the incentive of the merging parties to raise prices post-merger will tend to be, all<br />

other things being equal and in the absence of other competitive constraints.<br />

The first UK case which applied this methodology was the CC’s 2010 report on the Zipcar/Streetcar merger. In that case,<br />

the CC estimated that diversion ratios between the parties’ services were 22-24% based on a survey of consumers which<br />

asked if one party’s car service was no longer in operation, what alternatives would the individual being surveyed consider.<br />

Using these estimates and for a range of estimated gross margins, the CC concluded that “..absent entry or the threat of<br />

entry .. the main parties would have at least a moderate incentive to increase prices post-merger”. Nevertheless, the CC<br />

concluded that new market entry would be likely, expected to be timely and on a scale sufficient to prevent a substantial<br />

lessening of competition. The market was expected to continue to grow rapidly and there were two other credible entrants<br />

with well-developed plans to enter the car club market in the UK.<br />

Unfortunately, the CC was silent as to what it meant by “a moderate incentive to increase prices”. This is important<br />

Global Legal Insights ­ <strong>Merger</strong> Control <strong>First</strong> <strong>Edition</strong><br />

—200—<br />

© Published and reproduced with kind permission by Global Legal Group Ltd, London<br />

www.globallegalinsights.com

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!