14.04.2013 Views

The Birth of Insurance Contracts - The Ataturk Institute for Modern ...

The Birth of Insurance Contracts - The Ataturk Institute for Modern ...

The Birth of Insurance Contracts - The Ataturk Institute for Modern ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Proposition 1 <strong>The</strong> more risky and costly the venture is (the higher py and the lower y, the higher<br />

k relative to k2, and the lower E[x] = px x + p¯x ¯x given x ≥ t pc ), the more likely it is that the risk<br />

averse merchant raises funds from the risk averse financier through a sea loan, optimally.<br />

If the venture is highly risky and costly, the financier might suffer a substantial loss. On the<br />

likely event <strong>of</strong> a navigation incident (py high), he cannot recoup any amount beyond what is saved<br />

from mis<strong>for</strong>tune, which is dreadfully insufficient (y very low) to reward his capital investment:<br />

τ(y) ≤ y ≪ k. This implies a very significant loss to him, <strong>for</strong> he has invested a major part <strong>of</strong><br />

his scarce initial endowment in the costly venture (k high relative to k2). To compensate <strong>for</strong> the<br />

possibility <strong>of</strong> loss, the financier requires soaring payments when the merchandise arrived at port<br />

safe and sound. As a consequence, his consumption varies widely, whereas that <strong>of</strong> the merchant<br />

is invariably small. At any feasible and individually-rational allocation,<br />

c2(y) ≤ k2 − k + y, c2(x) ≥ k2 − k + ˜t, and c1(y) ≥ 0, E[c1(x)] ≤ E[x] − ˜t,<br />

where ˜t ∈ [t pc , x] denotes the transfer required by the investor to compensate him <strong>for</strong> assuming as<br />

less marine risk as possible, i.e. the very high transfer a sea loan establishes on the event <strong>of</strong> safe<br />

arrival <strong>of</strong> the ship and its cargo to destination. <strong>The</strong> second and fourth inequalities derive from<br />

the downward slope <strong>of</strong> the financier’s indifference curves (see figure 1 and 4). Thus, on the choice<br />

set the merchant’s consumption is smoother than the financier’s consumption<br />

max{E[c1(x)] − c1(y)} = E[x] − ˜t ≪ ˜t − y = min{c2(x) − c2(y)}. (11)<br />

Because both agents are assumed to have the same preferences, the merchant values insurance<br />

relatively less than the financier so that it is optimal that he receives as less marine insurance as<br />

possible. Since the higher the amount paid out in the case <strong>of</strong> loss, the lower the repayment required<br />

otherwise and the less volatile the investor’s event-consumption relative to the merchant’s, it is<br />

optimal that the investor recoup as much <strong>of</strong> his capital as possible from the venture’s return. A<br />

sea loan, establishing τ = −k, τ(y) = y, and τ(x) = τ(¯x) = ˜t, can sustain all the allocations in<br />

the core, with ˜t ∈ [t pc , x] taking different values <strong>for</strong> each individually-rational level <strong>of</strong> bargaining<br />

12

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!