06.05.2013 Views

Financing Unquoted High-Growth Companies: From Extending

Financing Unquoted High-Growth Companies: From Extending

Financing Unquoted High-Growth Companies: From Extending

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Faculty of Economics and Business Administration<br />

DEPARTMENT OF ACCOUNTING AND<br />

CORPORATE FINANCE<br />

<strong>Financing</strong> <strong>Unquoted</strong> <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong>:<br />

<strong>From</strong> <strong>Extending</strong> Existing Finance Theory Towards an<br />

Evolutionary Theory of the Finance Process<br />

Submitted to the Faculty of Economics and Business Administration (Ghent University,<br />

Belgium) in Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Doctor in Applied Economics<br />

Tom Vanacker<br />

Supervisor: Prof. dr. ir. Sophie Manigart<br />

Funded by the Intercollegiate Center for Management Science (I.C.M.), Brussels, Belgium<br />

& Impulsfonds<br />

Ghent, May 2009


PhD Series - Ghent University, May 2009<br />

Faculty of Economics and Business Administration<br />

http://www.feb.ugent.be<br />

© 2009, Tom Vanacker<br />

All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any<br />

means electronic or mechanical, including photocopying, recording, or by any other information<br />

storage and retrieval system, without permission in writing from the author.


<strong>Financing</strong> <strong>Unquoted</strong> <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong>:<br />

<strong>From</strong> <strong>Extending</strong> Existing Finance Theory Towards an<br />

Evolutionary Theory of the Finance Process


Doctoral Jury<br />

Prof. dr. Marc De Clercq (Ghent University, President)<br />

Prof. dr. Patrick Van Kenhove (Ghent University, Secretary)<br />

Prof. dr. ir. Sophie Manigart (Ghent University & Vlerick Leuven Gent Management School,<br />

Supervisor)<br />

Prof. dr. Ignace De Beelde (Ghent University)<br />

Prof. dr. Frédéric Delmar (EM Lyon, France and Research Institute of Industrial Economics,<br />

Sweden)<br />

Prof. dr. Mirjam Knockaert (Ghent University)<br />

Prof. dr. Hans Landström (Lund University, Sweden)<br />

Prof. dr. Peter Roosenboom (Rotterdam School of Management, Erasmus University, The<br />

Netherlands)<br />

Prof. dr. Harry Sapienza (Carlson School of Management, University of Minnesota, US)<br />

i


Acknowledgements<br />

This dissertation is the creation of almost four years of intense doctoral studies. It is not produced in a<br />

social vacuum, but a variety of people guided and supported me throughout this process. Without their<br />

support, guidance and encouragement this dissertation would never be what it is today and I would<br />

have missed many challenging but also rewarding experiences. I am grateful to all contributors and<br />

although it is impossible to sum them all up, I would like to highlight my appreciation to some specific<br />

individuals.<br />

I have been privileged with Sophie Manigart as my supervisor. Sophie, I was afraid to start working<br />

for you as a research and teaching assistant. After all, you were the professor who laughed at me when<br />

I was unable to answer one of the follow-up questions during my oral exam as a Master student. I got<br />

even more afraid when I received back your extensive comments on a draft of my very first academic<br />

paper. However, for the same reasons I enjoyed working with you. I very much appreciate your<br />

constant support and motivation to develop high-quality work. Thank you for all the time and energy<br />

you put in (re)reading my papers and offering feedback. Moreover, you integrated me into a vibrant<br />

community of researchers by providing me the ability to present on many international conferences<br />

and bringing me into contact with Shaker Zahra and Harry Sapienza thereby allowing me to study in<br />

the United States. I have truly enjoyed working together and hope this will continue in the future.<br />

Moreover, the members of my outstanding doctoral guidance committee, Harry Sapienza and Hans<br />

Landström, played a critical role in shaping my dissertation. Harry, thank you for giving me the<br />

opportunity to visit the University of Minnesota. You have always been an inspiring force, extremely<br />

considerate, and your positive comments made me feel proud of my own work. Hans, thank you for<br />

reading my papers meticulously and providing me with detailed feedback. Your challenging questions<br />

throughout our meetings shaped me into a more reflective researcher. I could not have imagined more<br />

dedicated members in my doctoral committee.<br />

Other members in my exam committee, namely Frédéric Delmar, Peter Roosenboom, Mirjam<br />

Knockaert and Ignace de Beelde played an important role as well. Frédéric, I was extremely pleased<br />

iii


you were willing to become part of my exam committee. I consider you to be one of the most<br />

influential organizational growth scholars and knowing that you appreciate my research gives me even<br />

more energy to rewrite my papers and target for high-quality publications. Peter, I first met you as a<br />

discussant for one of my papers on the corporate finance day in Rotterdam where you provided me<br />

extremely valuable feedback. I would like to thank you for your time and energy in evaluating and<br />

improving this dissertation. Mirjam, I have been lucky to previously work with you on the Global<br />

Entrepreneurship Monitor (Belgium) struggling through T.E.A. calculations. Thank you for your<br />

constructive feedback not only during the final stages of writing my dissertation but on many<br />

occasions. Ignace, I would like to thank you for your interest in my research. Moreover, as department<br />

chair you provided me a great workplace over the past years.<br />

My stay at the Carlson School of Management (University of Minnesota) provided me with<br />

knowledge, professional contacts, but also deep friendship. I am especially appreciative to Shaker<br />

Zahra and Patricia Zahra. Shaker and Patricia, thank you for making me feel more than welcome in<br />

Minneapolis. <strong>From</strong> day one you have both amazed me with your hospitality and friendship. Thank you<br />

for showing me around the many beautiful places in Minneapolis and surroundings, inviting me at<br />

your home for lunch and dinner on many many occasions, being there to discuss my research and<br />

having long talks about things besides research. You have made my visiting scholarship in the United<br />

States an unforgettable experience. I am also grateful to Daniel Forbes, who contributed immeasurably<br />

and beyond the call to the process of improving my case study paper. Dan, thank you for your interest<br />

in my research and the fun times outside academia.<br />

Veroniek, you deserve a special word of thanks. Some 10 years ago we had one thing in common: we<br />

did not want to know each other. We could not have imaged this would quickly change when we<br />

started our doctoral studies together. You have been an inspirational colleague: extremely intelligent<br />

and dedicated. You have shaped my dissertation in more ways than you probably imagine. More<br />

importantly, we developed a deep friendship and I am extremely proud you are my best friend. Even<br />

after two years when we have hardly seen each other and were busy with studying and meeting new<br />

people we did not loose contact. On the contrary, we had weekly and some weeks even daily telephone<br />

iv


calls. We know everything about each other although we often mention the juicy details with (some)<br />

delay. I am looking forward to having fun, laughing and traveling with you in the future.<br />

I would also like to thank my current and former accounting and corporate finance colleagues, many<br />

who became good friends. A special word of thanks goes to (in a random order): Elisabeth, Katleen,<br />

Sofie, Wouter, Christof, Miguel, Sofie, Christophe, Dries, Lotte, Nick, David, Hannes, Andy,<br />

Pieterjan, Arnout, Bivas and last but not least Sonia. Many of the doctoral students at Carlson also<br />

deserve a special note. This not only for their valuable feedback during our entrepreneurship sessions,<br />

but for some also for the Friday night social events: Jaume, John, Mazhar, Nachiket, Hans, Carla,<br />

Zeke, Isil and Youngeun. I have been lucky Sofia joined me as a visiting doctoral student for a couple<br />

of months. We combined hard work at our shared office with great experiences outside work. I would<br />

also like to thank my friends from outside academia (sorry for not listing all your names, this does not<br />

mean I do not appreciate you all).<br />

This research and my stay at the Carlson School of Management would not have been possible without<br />

the financial support of the Intercollegiate Center for Management Science (I.C.M.). A special thanks<br />

goes to Françoise Degembe and Dirk Symoens. <strong>Financing</strong> from our Faculty of Economics and<br />

Business Administration (including Impulsfonds) played a critical role in allowing me to optimize this<br />

dissertation and attending international conferences as well.<br />

Tenslotte wens ik mijn familie en in het bijzonder mijn ouders te bedanken. Ik wens jullie uit de grond<br />

van mijn hart te bedanken voor jullie constant geloof in mijn kunnen en onvoorwaardelijke toewijding.<br />

Ik apprecieer ontzettend dat jullie mij altijd de vrijheid hebben gegeven mijn eigen weg te gaan.<br />

Ondanks de vele stemmen die twijfel hadden of ik zou slagen eerst in het secundair onderwijs, later op<br />

universitair niveau, zijn jullie mij steeds blijven steunen zonder mij in een andere richting te willen<br />

duwen. Zonder jullie was ik nooit geworden wie ik nu ben.<br />

Tom Vanacker, May 2009<br />

v


Table of Contents<br />

Acknowledgements........................................................................iii<br />

Table of Contents........................................................................... vi<br />

List of Tables ................................................................................. xi<br />

List of Figures..............................................................................xiii<br />

Nederlandstalige samenvatting (Summary in Dutch) ................. xiv<br />

Executive Summary....................................................................xvii<br />

Chapter 1: General Introduction..................................................... 1<br />

1.1. Finance and Company <strong>Growth</strong>.....................................................................................2<br />

1.1.1. Study 1: Incremental Finance Decisions in <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong>: Pecking Order and<br />

Debt Capacity Considerations ........................................................................................................ 3<br />

1.1.2. Study 2: Seeking Experienced or Legitimate Partners? A Longitudinal Study on the Impact<br />

of Venture Capital Firm Heterogeneity on Portfolio Company <strong>Growth</strong> ........................................ 4<br />

1.1.3. Study 3: Early Differences and Persistence in the Entrepreneurial Finance Process:<br />

Evidence from <strong>High</strong>- and Low-<strong>Growth</strong> Biotechnology Startups ................................................... 5<br />

1.2. Key Dimensions of Financial Decision-Making and Foundational Finance Theories....6<br />

1.2.1. Amount of Finance ............................................................................................................... 8<br />

1.2.2. Type of Finance .................................................................................................................. 10<br />

1.2.3. Source of Finance ............................................................................................................... 13<br />

1.2.4. Dynamics ............................................................................................................................ 16<br />

1.2.5. How the Studies in this Dissertation Cover the Different Dimensions of Financial<br />

Decision-Making .......................................................................................................................... 17<br />

1.3. The Link between Process Theories and Foundational Finance Theories....................18<br />

vi


1.4. Company <strong>Growth</strong> as a Complex Organizational Process: What is <strong>High</strong> <strong>Growth</strong>? What<br />

are <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong>?...........................................................................................23<br />

1.4.1. <strong>Growth</strong> Indicators, <strong>Growth</strong> Formula and Timeframe......................................................... 24<br />

1.4.2. How the Studies in this Dissertation Address the Multidimensional Nature of <strong>Growth</strong> .... 27<br />

1.5. Research Context .......................................................................................................28<br />

1.5.1. The Belgian Financial System ............................................................................................ 29<br />

1.5.2. The Belgian Entrepreneurial Landscape............................................................................. 31<br />

1.5.3. Implications of the Research Setting for the Studies in this Dissertation........................... 34<br />

1.6. Data...........................................................................................................................35<br />

1.6.1. BEL-FIRST Financial Accounts Database......................................................................... 36<br />

1.6.2. Belgian Venture Capital & Private Equity Association (BVA) Database.......................... 38<br />

1.6.3. Zephyr Database ................................................................................................................. 39<br />

1.6.4. Interview data ..................................................................................................................... 41<br />

1.7. Main Findings............................................................................................................42<br />

1.7.1. Study 1: Incremental Finance Decisions in <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong>: Pecking Order and<br />

Debt Capacity Considerations ...................................................................................................... 42<br />

1.7.2. Study 2: Seeking Experienced or Legitimate Partners? A Longitudinal Study on the Impact<br />

of Venture Capital Firm Heterogeneity on Portfolio Company <strong>Growth</strong> ...................................... 43<br />

1.7.3. Study 3: Early Differences and Persistence in the Entrepreneurial Finance Process:<br />

Evidence from <strong>High</strong>- and Low-<strong>Growth</strong> Biotechnology Startups ................................................. 45<br />

1.8. Overall Academic Contributions ................................................................................46<br />

1.8.1. Finance Literature............................................................................................................... 46<br />

1.8.2. <strong>Growth</strong> Literature ............................................................................................................... 51<br />

1.9. Structure of the Dissertation.......................................................................................54<br />

References........................................................................................................................54<br />

Chapter 2: Incremental Finance Decisions in <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong><br />

<strong>Companies</strong>: Pecking Order and Debt Capacity Considerations .. 63<br />

2.1. Abstract .....................................................................................................................64<br />

2.2. Introduction ...............................................................................................................64<br />

vii


2.3. Theory and Hypotheses..............................................................................................67<br />

2.4. Method and Descriptive Statistics ..............................................................................74<br />

2.4.1. Identifying <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong> ................................................................................. 75<br />

2.4.2. Dependent Variables: Finance Events ................................................................................ 78<br />

2.4.3. Independent Variables ........................................................................................................ 80<br />

2.5. Empirical Results.......................................................................................................82<br />

2.5.1. Independent Variables by Issue Type................................................................................. 82<br />

2.5.2. Multivariate Analyses......................................................................................................... 83<br />

2.5.3. Robustness Checks ............................................................................................................. 89<br />

2.6. Discussion and Conclusions.......................................................................................90<br />

References........................................................................................................................93<br />

Chapter 3: Seeking Experienced or Legitimate Partners? A<br />

Longitudinal Study on the Impact of Venture Capital Firm<br />

Heterogeneity on Portfolio Company <strong>Growth</strong> ........................... 100<br />

3.1. Abstract ...................................................................................................................101<br />

3.2. Introduction .............................................................................................................101<br />

3.3. Theory and Hypotheses............................................................................................104<br />

3.3.1. Venture Capital Firm Experience and Portfolio Company <strong>Growth</strong>.................................. 105<br />

3.3.2. Venture Capital Firm Legitimacy and Portfolio Company <strong>Growth</strong> ................................. 107<br />

3.4. Data and Method......................................................................................................108<br />

3.4.1. Sample .............................................................................................................................. 108<br />

3.4.2. Measures........................................................................................................................... 109<br />

3.4.3. Analysis ............................................................................................................................ 113<br />

3.5. Results.....................................................................................................................116<br />

3.5.1. Modeling Unconditional Change in Venture Capital Backed <strong>Companies</strong> ....................... 117<br />

3.5.2. Modeling Conditional Change in Venture Capital Backed <strong>Companies</strong> ........................... 119<br />

viii


3.5.3. Alternative Explanations for the Hypothesized Relationships: Investor Selection versus<br />

Value Adding.............................................................................................................................. 124<br />

3.6. Discussion and Conclusion ......................................................................................128<br />

3.6.1. Academic Contributions ................................................................................................... 128<br />

3.6.2. Implications for Practice................................................................................................... 131<br />

References......................................................................................................................131<br />

Appendix 1: Robustness Check.......................................................................................138<br />

Chapter 4: Early Differences and Persistence in the<br />

Entrepreneurial Finance Process: Evidence from <strong>High</strong>- and Low-<br />

<strong>Growth</strong> Biotechnology Startups ................................................. 140<br />

4.1. Abstract ...................................................................................................................141<br />

4.2. Introduction .............................................................................................................141<br />

4.3. Methods...................................................................................................................144<br />

4.3.1. Research Design ............................................................................................................... 144<br />

4.3.2. Data Sources ..................................................................................................................... 149<br />

4.3.3. Data Analysis.................................................................................................................... 153<br />

4.4. How does the Finance Process of <strong>High</strong>-and Low-<strong>Growth</strong> Ventures Differ?..............154<br />

4.4.1. Amount of Finance ........................................................................................................... 154<br />

4.4.2. Type of Investor................................................................................................................ 157<br />

4.5. How do Early Differences in the Finance Process Originate? ...................................159<br />

4.5.1. Initial Differences in Quality and <strong>Growth</strong> Potential......................................................... 159<br />

4.5.2. Initial Differences in <strong>Growth</strong> Ambition............................................................................ 162<br />

4.5.3. Local Search ..................................................................................................................... 162<br />

4.6. How do Early Differences in the Finance Process Persist across Time?....................167<br />

4.6.1. Venture Professionalization.............................................................................................. 168<br />

4.6.2. Stunted Learning............................................................................................................... 170<br />

4.6.3. Investor Syndication Preferences...................................................................................... 172<br />

ix


4.7. Discussion ...............................................................................................................175<br />

4.7.1. Reframing the Entrepreneurial Finance Process as an Evolutionary Model .................... 177<br />

4.7.2. Resource Mobilization and Initial Network Formation.................................................... 179<br />

4.8. Conclusion...............................................................................................................181<br />

References......................................................................................................................182<br />

Chapter 5: Limitations, Avenues for Future Research and<br />

Implications for Practice............................................................. 190<br />

5.1. Limitations and Avenues for Future Research ..........................................................191<br />

5.2. Practical Implications...............................................................................................195<br />

5.2.1. Entrepreneurs.................................................................................................................... 196<br />

5.2.2. Investors............................................................................................................................ 197<br />

5.2.3. Policy makers.................................................................................................................... 198<br />

References......................................................................................................................199<br />

x


List of Tables<br />

Chapter 1<br />

Table 1.1 The Three Studies and their Focus on the Different Dimensions of the Finance Process<br />

Table 1.2 Overlap (%) between Different Groups of <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong> using Different<br />

<strong>Growth</strong> Indicators and <strong>Growth</strong> Formula<br />

Table 1.3 The Three Studies and Multidimensional Nature of <strong>Growth</strong><br />

Table 1.4 Description of the Samples and Databases Used<br />

Chapter 2<br />

Table 2.1 Distribution of Sample Firms by Industry<br />

Table 2.2 Sample Split according to Finance Type<br />

Table 2.3 Correlation Matrix<br />

Table 2.4 Variables by Issue Type<br />

Table 2.5 Logistic Regression of the Determinants of Outside Finance Use<br />

Table 2.6 Logistic Regression of the Determinants of External Equity Use<br />

Chapter 3<br />

Table 3.1 Correlation Matrix<br />

Table 3.2 Descriptive Statistics for Employment and Total Assets<br />

Table 3.3 Unconditional Analysis for Employment and Total Assets<br />

Table 3.4 Conditional Analysis for Employment and Total Assets<br />

Table 3.5 Portfolio Company Characteristics by Type of Venture Capital Firm<br />

xi


Table 3.6 Conditional Analysis for Employment and Total Assets<br />

Chapter 4<br />

Table 4.1 Theoretical Sampling Procedure<br />

Table 4.2 Description of Biotechnology Cases Studied<br />

Table 4.3 Sources of Data Biotechnology Cases<br />

Table 4.4 Finance Process by Type of Investor and Venture <strong>Growth</strong><br />

Table 4.5 Early Signals of <strong>Growth</strong> Potential and Quality: Alliance Capital, Technology and<br />

Target Market at Startup<br />

Table 4.6 Local Search and the Impact of the Social Context on Initial <strong>Financing</strong><br />

Table 4.7 Key Changes in the Management Team Relating to the CEO and CFO<br />

xii


List of Figures<br />

Chapter 1<br />

Figure 1.1 The Static Trade-off Theory of Capital Structure<br />

Figure 1.2 Firm Continuum and Sources of Finance: The Financial <strong>Growth</strong> Cycle Paradigm<br />

Figure 1.3 Process Models of Organizational Development and Key Finance Theories<br />

Figure 1.4 Early-Stage Entrepreneurial Activity Rates for 2002/03, 2004/05 and 2006/07 in <strong>High</strong>-<br />

Income Countries<br />

Figure 1.5 Relative Prevalence of <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong> Expectation in Early-Stage Entrepreneurship,<br />

Chapter 3<br />

2000–2006<br />

Figure 3.1 Unconditional Models: Observed and Predicted Means<br />

Figure 3.2 Conditional Models: Predicted Means for <strong>Companies</strong> Backed by Investors with <strong>High</strong><br />

Industry Deal Experience versus Low Industry Deal Experience<br />

Figure 3.3 Conditional Models: Predicted Means for <strong>Companies</strong> Backed by Old versus Young<br />

Chapter 4<br />

Venture capital firms<br />

Figure 4.1 Cumulative Amount of Pre-Exit Finance Raised across Time<br />

Figure 4.2 Summarizing Framework of the Finance Process of <strong>High</strong>-and Low-<strong>Growth</strong><br />

<strong>Companies</strong><br />

xiii


Nederlandstalige samenvatting (Summary in Dutch)<br />

Snelgroeiende bedrijven zorgen voor een disproportioneel deel van de innovaties,<br />

tewerkstellingscreatie en waardegeneratie binnen een economie. Ondernemingsgroei is dan ook een<br />

centraal thema binnen academisch onderzoek en een belangrijk aandachtspunt van beleidsmakers.<br />

Financiering is een belangrijke factor die potentieel kan leiden tot blijvende verschillen in groei tussen<br />

bedrijven. Financiële middelen zijn immers essentieel daar ze groeigerichte bedrijven toelaten om te<br />

investeren. Een suboptimale financiële structuur, als gevolg van een gebrekkige toegang tot<br />

financiering of onvoldoende kennis van financieringsalternatieven, kan leiden tot een beperkte<br />

mogelijkheid voor verder groei, financiële moeilijkheden en zelfs een faillissement. Ondanks het<br />

belang van de relatie tussen financiering en groei is onze kennis hieromtrent beperkt. Het doel van de<br />

drie studies in dit doctoraat is dan ook om een meer inzichten te verwerven in de relatie tussen<br />

financiering en groei.<br />

De eerste studie gaat na hoe snelgroeiende bedrijven zich financieren en hoe de kenmerken van<br />

snelgroeiende bedrijven hun financieringskeuzes beïnvloeden. Ondanks de focus op het belang van<br />

nieuw aandelenkapitaal in de oprichting en verdere groei van bedrijven in de huidige literatuur, toont<br />

de eerste studie aan dat het merendeel van de managers van snelgroeiende bedrijven nooit een beroep<br />

doen op nieuw aandelenkapitaal om groei te financieren. Snelgroeiende bedrijven verkiezen om -<br />

indien mogelijk- hun investeringen intern te financieren en schuldcapaciteit te vrijwaren. Indien<br />

interne middelen ontbreken gaan snelgroeiende bedrijven met een laag risicoprofiel eerder geneigd<br />

zijn om additionele schulden aan te trekken. Nieuw aandelenkapitaal wordt voornamelijk<br />

aangetrokken door snelgroeiende bedrijven met een hoog risicoprofiel: niet-winstgevende bedrijven<br />

met lage kasstromen, een hoge schuldgraad, een hoge kans op faling en significante investeringen in<br />

immateriële activa. Verder blijkt dat éénmaal bedrijven een bepaald type externe financiering<br />

aantrekken er een hogere kans is dat ze hetzelfde type financiering terug zullen aantrekken in de nabije<br />

toekomst.<br />

xiv


De tweede studie gaat na hoe verschillende types van investeerders het groeipatroon van bedrijven<br />

beïnvloeden. Bedrijven die initiële financiering aantrekken van venture capital investeerders met meer<br />

ervaring binnen de sector van hun portefeuille bedrijven, vertonen een snellere groei in vergelijking<br />

met bedrijven die financiering aantrekken van investeerders met minder ervaring. Daarnaast vertonen<br />

bedrijven die financiering aantrekken van oudere investeerders en investeerders die meer in de media<br />

verschijnen eveneens een snellere groei. Initiële beslissingen met betrekking tot het type investeerder<br />

van wie bedrijven financiering aantrekken, beïnvloeden de mogelijkheid van bedrijven om additioneel<br />

personeel en activa aan te trekken en dit tot vijf jaar na de initiële beslissing. Meer financiering is dus<br />

niet noodzakelijk beter voor de groei van een bedrijf; minstens even belangrijk is van welke<br />

investeerder men initiële financiering verkrijgt.<br />

De derde studie toont aan hoe meer ervaren investeerders niet noodzakelijk toegang hebben tot<br />

bedrijven met het hoogste groeipotentieel. Ondernemers beperken hun zoektocht naar<br />

opstartfinanciering namelijk vaak tot één of een beperkt aantal investeerders en vermijden losse<br />

contacten met vele investeerders. De zoektocht naar opstartfinanciering is lokaal en ondernemers<br />

benaderen typisch enkel investeerders die ze kennen via vroegere werkervaringen of investeerders die<br />

een indirecte band hebben met het bedrijf, zoals spin-offs die in eerste instantie een universitair fonds<br />

zullen aanspreken. Initiële verschillen in het financieringsproces hebben een blijvende impact op latere<br />

financieringsbeslissingen. Zo krijgen bedrijven die starten met ervaren investeerders typisch grote<br />

bedragen aan opvolgfinanciering van andere ervaren investeerders, terwijl de bedrijven die starten met<br />

onervaren investeerders veel minder opvolgfinanciering ophalen en dit meestal van andere onervaren<br />

investeerders. De processen die ervoor zorgen dat initiële verschillen in het financieringsproces zich<br />

blijven verder zetten doorheen de tijd worden geïdentificeerd en besproken.<br />

Samen tonen de drie studies aan hoe we onze kennis omtrent financiering binnen niet-beursgenoteerde<br />

ondernemingen sterk kunnen verbeteren door deze te kaderen binnen een evolutionaire theorie. Een<br />

evolutionaire theorie stelt dat bedrijven strijden om toegang te krijgen tot beperkte middelen. Er wordt<br />

typisch vanuit gegaan dat investeerders bedrijven selecteren die het best passen binnen hun<br />

xv


espectievelijke omgeving. De verschillende studies binnen dit doctoraat tonen echter aan hoe<br />

ondernemers eveneens hun bedrijven selecteren als kandidaten voor het ontvangen van financiering<br />

van bepaalde investeerders. Alhoewel deze resultaten in lijn liggen met recent onderzoek, gaat mijn<br />

onderzoek een stap verder door aan te tonen hoe de rol van ondernemers de beslissing om al dan niet<br />

externe financiering aan te trekken overstijgt. Verder tonen de verschillende studies aan hoe initiële<br />

verschillen in het financieringsproces tussen bedrijven zich verder zetten doorheen de tijd. Initiële<br />

financieringsbeslissingen beïnvloeden latere financieringsbeslissingen en zelfs de ontwikkeling het<br />

volledig bedrijf. De processen die verklaren hoe verschillen ontstaan en hoe deze een blijvende impact<br />

hebben omvatten het lokale karakter van de zoektocht naar financiering, gebrekkig leren, verschillen<br />

in de professionalisering van bedrijven onder impuls van heterogene investeerders en routines die<br />

gehanteerd worden door investeerders om co-investeerders te selecteren. Deze processen staan in<br />

schril contrast met de focus in traditioneel financieringsonderzoek op neoklassieke economische<br />

concepten waaronder rationaliteit, homogeniteit van investeerders en perfecte contracten.<br />

xvi


Executive Summary<br />

<strong>High</strong>-growth companies contribute disproportionately to innovation, employment creation and value-<br />

added generation in most modern economies. Hence, firm growth is a central area of academic<br />

research and a major policy concern. Financial resources may cause sustainable differences in venture<br />

development, as financial resources allow ventures to invest in strategic assets. A suboptimal financial<br />

structure caused by finance constraints or limited knowledge of finance alternatives may constrain the<br />

future growth potential of a business and may even cause failure. Despite its importance our<br />

knowledge on relationship between finance and growth remains limited. The goal of the three studies<br />

in this dissertation is to further extend our knowledge on this relationship.<br />

The first study examines the importance of internal finance, debt finance and new equity finance in<br />

high-growth companies. Moreover, the study demonstrates how company characteristics influence the<br />

finance strategies of high-growth companies. While prior research has mainly focused on the role of<br />

new equity finance in the creation and growth of new ventures, this study demonstrates how the<br />

majority of high-growth companies never raise new equity finance. <strong>High</strong>-growth companies prefer to<br />

finance investments internally -whenever possible- thereby retaining debt capacity. When high-growth<br />

companies with a low risk profile lack internal finance they become more likely to raise debt finance.<br />

New equity issues, however, are especially important for high-growth companies with a high risk<br />

profile: unprofitable companies with low cashflows, high leverage, high risk of failure and significant<br />

investments in intangible assets. The study also demonstrates how high-growth companies that raised<br />

a particular type of finance become more likely to raise the same type of finance again in the future.<br />

The second study examines how particular types of investors affect the growth pattern of<br />

entrepreneurial ventures. <strong>Companies</strong> that initially raise finance from venture capital firms with more<br />

industry deal experience exhibit higher growth across time. This is not the case, however, for<br />

entrepreneurial companies that raise initial finance from investors with more overall deal experience.<br />

Moreover, companies that initially raise finance from older venture capital firms and venture capital<br />

xvii


firms that appear more frequently in the media also exhibit higher growth across time. The initial<br />

decision from whom to raise finance influences the ability of entrepreneurial ventures to attract<br />

employees and mobilize assets and this for up to five years after the initial decision. Hence, more<br />

financial resources are not necessarily better; at least as important is the source from which ventures<br />

raise finance.<br />

The third study demonstrates how more experienced investors not necessarily have access to<br />

entrepreneurial companies with the highest growth potential. This is because entrepreneurs typically<br />

limit their search for finance to one or a few investors and refrain from having loose contacts with<br />

many potential investors. The search for early finance is local and entrepreneurs generally search<br />

finance from investors they know from prior work experiences or investors that have an indirect tie<br />

with the company, such as university spin-offs who restrict their search for finance to the university<br />

fund. Initial differences in the finance process have a long-term impact on subsequent finance<br />

decisions. <strong>Companies</strong> that raise early finance from experienced investors typically raise large amounts<br />

of follow-on finance from other experienced investors, while companies that raise early finance from<br />

relatively inexperienced investors attract limited amounts of follow-on finance from other<br />

inexperienced investors. We theorize on the processes that cause early differences in the finance<br />

process to persist across time.<br />

Overall, the three studies indicate how our knowledge on financial decision-making may benefit from<br />

using an evolutionary lens. In such a perspective resource scarcity creates selection environments<br />

within which investors decide to invest in the companies that best fit within the environment.<br />

Nevertheless, the different studies in this dissertation demonstrate how entrepreneurs themselves also<br />

select their ventures as candidates for receiving finance from particular investors. While these findings<br />

confirm recent research, they also extend them in an important way by demonstrating how the role of<br />

entrepreneurs is more important than merely deciding whether they want to raise outside finance or<br />

not. Moreover, the studies demonstrate how early differences between companies persist across time.<br />

Early finance decisions are likely to influence subsequent finance decisions and even affect company<br />

xviii


development as a whole. The processes that cause early differences to originate and persist across time<br />

include local search, imperfect learning, differential professionalization of entrepreneurial ventures by<br />

heterogeneous investors and investor routines used to select potential syndication partners. These<br />

processes stand in stark contrast to current research in finance based on neoclassical paradigms such as<br />

comprehensive search, rationality, investor homogeneity and optimal contracts.<br />

xix


Chapter 1: General Introduction<br />

Company growth is a central area of academic research and a major policy concern, as it provides<br />

insights into the dynamics of the competitive process, strategic behaviour, the evolution of market<br />

structure, and even the growth of the aggregate economy (Carpenter and Petersen, 2002a). A recent<br />

literature review by Henrekson and Johansson (2009) demonstrates how only a small group of high-<br />

growth companies contribute disproportionately to employment generation, innovation and wealth<br />

creation in most modern economies. Research in the U.K. for example demonstrates how only 4% of<br />

startups create more than half of the jobs created by all startups together (Storey, 1994). Even more<br />

striking findings emerge from the U.S., where research shows that some 2-3% of all companies create<br />

almost all net jobs in the economy (Acs, Parsons, and Tracey, 2008). Yet despite its importance the<br />

growth literature is fragmented and much remains unknown about the antecedents of company growth<br />

(O’Regan, Ghobadian, and Gallear, 2006; Delmar, Davidsson, and Gartner, 2003; Carpenter and<br />

Petersen, 2002a).<br />

Financial capital is one of the crucial resources companies require to realize high growth. Financial<br />

capital allows companies to carryout crucial investments in tangible assets, intangible assets and<br />

working capital (Gilbert, McDougall, and Audretsch, 2006). An unsuitable financial structure, caused<br />

by finance constraints or inadequate knowledge about finance alternatives amongst other issues, may<br />

cause a limited potential for future growth, financial distress and even company failure (Cassar, 2004;<br />

Carpenter and Petersen, 2002b; Van Auken, 2001; Himmelberg and Petersen, 1994). The financial<br />

structure may not only constrain subsequent growth, but might also act as a facilitator. Scholars have<br />

indicated that the finance process operates as a key external prompt, which initiates sustainable<br />

differences in venture growth (Maurer and Ebers, 2006). These scholars, however, have not addressed<br />

what it is exactly that is different in the financing of high- and low-growth companies. The overall<br />

goal of the different studies in this dissertation is to extend our knowledge on the interrelatedness<br />

between the entrepreneurial finance process and the growth of unquoted companies.<br />

1


The rest of this introduction is structured as follows. First, I introduce the different studies and<br />

highlight the main purposes of each study. Second, I define the key dimensions of financial decision-<br />

making and describe the most influential theories in modern business finance. The goal of this section<br />

is to offer a common frame of reference, present the most influential theories relevant to the different<br />

studies in this dissertation and highlight how the different studies address different dimensions of<br />

financial decision-making. Third, I introduce process theories into the finance literature and link<br />

existing finance theories to these process theories. While finance scholars have generally ignored<br />

dynamics in financial decision-making, this section presents multiple frameworks proposed by<br />

organizational scholars to study change or dynamics across time. Fourth, I define entrepreneurial<br />

growth as a multidimensional process, identify the key dimensions of growth and its implications for<br />

the studies in this dissertation. Fifth, I offer an overview of the research context, including the Belgian<br />

financial system, the Belgian entrepreneurial landscape and its implications for the studies in this<br />

dissertation. Sixth, I discuss the datasets used in this dissertation and reflect on their advantages and<br />

disadvantages. Seventh, I summarize the main findings of each individual study. Next, I highlight the<br />

overall contributions of this dissertation to both the finance and growth literature. Finally, I discuss the<br />

structure of the rest of this dissertation.<br />

1.1. Finance and Company <strong>Growth</strong><br />

In this section, I start by introducing the three studies included within this dissertation. We have no<br />

choice but to cut down on the complexity of a problem by putting some processes in the foreground<br />

and others in the background (Van de Ven, 2007). Prior research demonstrates the critical nature of<br />

financial resources as they may both constrain and facilitate venture growth. Hence, my decision to<br />

more fully focus on the finance process in all studies and research how finance relates to company<br />

growth. Below I stipulate the main questions addressed by each study individually.<br />

2


1.1.1. Study 1: Incremental Finance Decisions in <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong>:<br />

Pecking Order and Debt Capacity Considerations<br />

Managers of high-growth companies typically have multiple types of finance available to finance new<br />

investment projects, including internal finance, debt finance and new equity finance. However,<br />

scholars have typically assumed that internal finance, if available, will be largely insufficient to<br />

finance high growth (Michaelas, Chittenden, and Poutziouris, 1999; Gompers, 1995). Furthermore,<br />

scholars argue that high-growth companies consistently use less debt finance as they grow across time<br />

(Barclay, Smith, and Morellec, 2006). Debt finance is sometimes even considered inappropriate,<br />

especially for high-growth companies active in technology-based industries, given their small or<br />

negative operational cashflows and lack of tangible assets that could serve as collateral (Carpenter and<br />

Petersen, 2002b). Instead, it is proposed that high-growth companies actively use new equity, which is<br />

the most suitable source of finance for high-growth companies (Fama and French, 2005; Frank and<br />

Goyal, 2003; Carpenter and Petersen, 2002b).<br />

Few studies on financial policies in high-growth companies, however, consider a broad range of<br />

finance alternatives, including inside finance, debt finance and new equity finance (Eckhardt, Shane,<br />

and Delmar, 2006), but instead focus on the role of new equity in the creation and growth of new<br />

companies (Davila, Foster, and Gupta, 2003; Carpenter and Petersen, 2002b; Gompers, 1995).<br />

Nevertheless, one of the most influential theories in modern business finance, namely the pecking<br />

order theory, argues that high-growth companies will avoid using new equity when internal finance or<br />

debt finance is available (Myers, 1984). Overall, while prior research stresses the role of new equity in<br />

the financing of high-growth companies, finance theory indicates a more central role for internal funds<br />

and debt finance in companies that are characterized by high informational asymmetry. A more<br />

comprehensive study on the role of different types of finance in high-growth companies is therefore<br />

timely.<br />

3


More significantly, finance scholars have typically treated high-growth companies as a homogenous<br />

group within a larger sample of companies. Few studies have addressed how different high-growth<br />

companies are more or less likely to use these different types of finance. Nevertheless, such a<br />

perspective is critical as high-growth companies are heterogeneous in nature and hence do not all grow<br />

in the same way (Delmar, Davidsson, and Gartner, 2003). As a result, one might expect high-growth<br />

companies with different characteristics to resort to different types of finance.<br />

The goal of the first study in this dissertation “Incremental finance decisions in high-growth<br />

companies: pecking order and debt capacity considerations” is twofold. First, I offer a more<br />

comprehensive insight into how high-growth companies are financed across time and offer more<br />

detailed insights into the importance of internal finance, debt finance and new equity finance. Second,<br />

I demonstrate how particular high-growth companies are more or less likely to use different types of<br />

finance.<br />

1.1.2. Study 2: Seeking Experienced or Legitimate Partners? A Longitudinal<br />

Study on the Impact of Venture Capital Firm Heterogeneity on Portfolio<br />

Company <strong>Growth</strong><br />

Most finance research has focused on broad types of finance, such as debt finance and equity finance<br />

(Frank and Goyal, 2005). Thereby these studies largely ignore from which source finance is raised and<br />

treat all debt and equity providers as homogenous (Kochhar and Hitt, 1998). Nevertheless, the value of<br />

investors often lies in providing not only money, but also value added services, such as monitoring,<br />

offering contacts with other businesses and offering business advice (Sapienza, Manigart, and<br />

Vermeir, 1996; David, O’Brien, and Yoshikawa, 2008). As investors come in all shapes and sizes, one<br />

might expect that they will not all contribute equally to company development. This makes the choice<br />

of managers with respect to the source of finance they target an important strategic decision.<br />

4


Although more recent studies address the consequences of investor heterogeneity, nearly all of these<br />

studies have put the investor in the foreground and the company in the background (Sorensen, 2007;<br />

Hochberg, Ljungqvist, and Lu, 2007; Dimov and De Clercq, 2006; Dimov and Shepherd, 2005). In<br />

other words, most of these studies have focused on the impact of investor heterogeneity on investor<br />

performance, but have largely ignored the impact on portfolio company growth and performance<br />

(Hochberg, Ljungqvist, and Lu, 2007). In the second study in this dissertation, I focus on the<br />

perspective of the entrepreneurial venture that raises finance instead of the investor that infuses<br />

finance in entrepreneurial ventures. This is vital as studying organizational processes from different<br />

perspectives may offer different insights into the phenomenon studied (Van de Ven, 2007).<br />

Moreover, although scholars agree that particular investors are more beneficial than others, it remains<br />

unclear which types of investors will contribute most to company development. The second study in<br />

this dissertation titled “Seeking Experienced or Legitimate Partners? A Longitudinal Study on the<br />

Impact of Venture Capital Firm Heterogeneity on Portfolio Company <strong>Growth</strong>” hence focuses on how<br />

investor heterogeneity affects portfolio company growth.<br />

1.1.3. Study 3: Early Differences and Persistence in the Entrepreneurial Finance<br />

Process: Evidence from <strong>High</strong>- and Low-<strong>Growth</strong> Biotechnology Startups<br />

A common assumption by finance scholars is that all financial decision-makers are economically<br />

rational and make comprehensive finance decisions in such a way that company value is maximized<br />

(Subrahmanyam, 2007). Nevertheless, the second study in this dissertation demonstrates that growth-<br />

oriented companies end-up with different types of investors and that these investors have a different<br />

impact on subsequent company growth. If all entrepreneurs are rational then why do they not all raise<br />

finance from high quality investors and why are rents related to affiliating with these better investors<br />

not entirely reduced through competition in the factor market? An important question that arises is<br />

how entrepreneurs structure their search for finance and why they raise finance from particular<br />

investors?<br />

5


Furthermore, in light of current finance theories the finding in the second study that early finance<br />

decisions have a long-lasting impact on company growth and development is remarkable. Optimal<br />

capital structure theories indicate that all companies can relatively easily rebalance their financial<br />

structure and all move towards an optimal target financial structure (Leary and Roberts, 2005;<br />

Hovakimian, Opler, and Titman, 2001). This assumption precludes a long-term impact of the financial<br />

structure on company development. Hence, a more balanced vision is required which offers more<br />

insight why early finance decisions facilitate and/or constrain the subsequent finance process.<br />

The final study in this dissertation “Early Differences and Persistence in the Entrepreneurial Finance<br />

Process: Evidence from <strong>High</strong>- and Low-<strong>Growth</strong> Biotechnology Startups” focuses on dynamics in the<br />

finance process. The goal of this study is three-fold. First, it studies the finance process from startup<br />

through development of both high- and low performing entrepreneurial companies and identifies key<br />

differences in the finance process. Second, it demonstrates how early differences in the finance<br />

process originate between these high- and low-growth companies. Finally, I theorize on the processes<br />

that explain why early finance decisions may both facilitate and constrain subsequent finance<br />

decisions.<br />

1.2. Key Dimensions of Financial Decision-Making and Foundational<br />

Finance Theories<br />

Modern theory on business finance started with Modigliani and Miller (1958). They demonstrated that<br />

in a perfect market characterized by free and directly available information, no transaction costs,<br />

rational actors, homogenous expectations and no taxes amongst other assumptions, finance behavior is<br />

irrelevant and does not influence firm value. It does not matter whether companies will raise debt or<br />

equity finance and short-term or long-term finance to give just two examples. Why? When investors<br />

have equal access to financial markets, investors can create any financial structure that is optimal for<br />

them, even if the company itself does not offer it. Investors will not pay for something they can create<br />

6


themselves and hence the financial structure will not be valued. While the Modigliani and Miller<br />

theorem does not provide a realistic description of actual finance behavior, it did provide a theoretical<br />

framework for finding reasons why finance matters (Frank and Goyal, 2005). Financial markets are<br />

not perfect and imperfections, such as taxes, bankruptcy costs, agency conflicts and imperfect<br />

information have all been advanced to explain why finance does matter in the value creation process.<br />

Financial decision-making is complex and multidimensional in nature. Most studies focus on at least<br />

one of the following dimensions: (a) the amount of finance raised, (b) type of finance raised, (c) the<br />

source from which finance is raised and (d) dynamics in the finance process. The finance process<br />

relates to the amount, type and source of finance raised across time and how these finance decisions<br />

interrelate 1 . Financial decision-making and the finance process can be studied from different<br />

perspectives. The majority of studies have focused on the finance obtained (i.e. the intersection<br />

between the demand and supply side of the market) and how financial intermediaries make decisions<br />

on whether or not to provide finance (i.e. supply side). Less is known about how entrepreneurs<br />

structure their search for finance (i.e. demand side). Hence, researchers have typically put investors–as<br />

the more established resource-rich firms–in the foreground and put entrepreneurial companies–as the<br />

more passive resource-poor firms–in the background when studying the financing of entrepreneurial<br />

companies (Cassar, 2004; Katila, Rosenberger, and Eisenhardt, 2008).<br />

I will discuss the different dimensions of financial decision-making in more detail below. The goal of<br />

this section is to offer a common frame of reference to the reader. It is beyond the scope of this<br />

section, however, to offer a complete overview of the vast literature on company finance (Harris and<br />

Raviv (1991) and more recently Frank and Goyal (2005) offer a more comprehensive overview of this<br />

literature). Rather, I will focus on the most influential theories in corporate finance that have direct<br />

relevance to the subsequent studies included in this dissertation.<br />

1 I do not focus on financial bootstrap strategies, which include more or less creative techniques that reduce the need for<br />

external finance (Winborg and Landström, 2001). Nevertheless, such techniques may have a significant impact on company<br />

growth. I address the impact of financial bootstrap strategies on startup growth in a paper that is not included in this<br />

dissertation (Manigart, Vanacker, Meuleman and Sels, 2009). It is available upon simple request.<br />

7


1.2.1. Amount of Finance<br />

A first dimension of financial decision-making is the amount of finance. The amount of finance<br />

required by companies depends on a number of factors. I briefly discuss the main factors influencing<br />

the finance needs, namely the characteristics of the operations, working capital policies, profitability<br />

and growth (Smith and Smith, 2000). First, the characteristics of the operations, such as whether<br />

companies are active in capital-intensive versus labor-intensive industries, minimum efficient scale<br />

and time to first customer, all have an important impact on the finance needs of companies (Porter,<br />

1980). For example, manufacturing companies generally require significant amounts of finance to<br />

carryout upfront investments in production facilities and equipment, while service companies require<br />

relatively little upfront investments in equipment and can expand more gradually. Thus, the average<br />

capital requirement at startup between capital- and labor-intensive industries differs markedly<br />

(Chandler and Hanks, 1998).<br />

Second, working capital policies are related to the finance needs of companies. Young and small<br />

ventures generally operate in industries that are characterized by particular norms, which are difficult<br />

to change by these companies (Smith and Smith, 2000). <strong>Companies</strong> need to offer credit to customers<br />

or otherwise potential customers will not be willing to do business with the company. <strong>High</strong>ly uncertain<br />

companies may be forced to pay their resource providers before they will offer goods or services. All<br />

these requirements will increase the amount of finance needed by companies. Nevertheless, when<br />

companies are confronted with external finance constraints, some companies may more actively<br />

implement more or less creative policies to increase the speed with which inventories and accounts<br />

receivable are transformed into cash inflows and accounts payables are transformed into cash outflows<br />

(Winborg and Landström, 2001). Hence, companies may change their working capital policies to<br />

increase the amount of internal funds available and reduce its need for external finance.<br />

Finally, profitability and firm growth significantly influence the financial needs of companies. All else<br />

equal, the more profitable a company, the lower its need for external finance (Titman and Wessels,<br />

8


1988). Retained earnings represent inside equity created by profitable companies (Frank and Goyal,<br />

2005). However, if a company’s growth rate is high relative to its profitability, internal funds may not<br />

be sufficient and external finance will be necessary to support company growth (Smith and Smith,<br />

2000). Hence, scholars generally assume that internal finance will be insufficient to finance a high<br />

growth strategy and that high-growth companies are particularly likely to raise outside debt or equity<br />

finance in order to realize high-growth (Michaelas, Chittenden, and Poutziouris, 1999).<br />

Nevertheless, not all companies will have automatic access to sufficient outside financial resources in<br />

order to carryout crucial investments in tangible and intangible assets needed to achieve high growth.<br />

Given the existence of market imperfections, such as asymmetric information and transaction costs,<br />

external finance is costly, if available at all (Berger and Udell, 1998). Asymmetric information entails<br />

that outside investors have less information about company prospects than company managers. This<br />

implies that external investors do not know whether the investment projects for which companies<br />

search finance are as valuable as managers claim. These information problems are especially<br />

important for uncertain companies, such as young and small companies, which lack a track record of<br />

past performance and where publicly available information is sparse. Investors may require a risk<br />

premium, thereby offering only an “average” price for the securities offered by the company, to<br />

compensate for the risk of selecting companies with poor projects. Moreover, the perceived risk of<br />

adverse selection (i.e., the risk of selection companies with bad projects) may become so high that<br />

investors decide to ration credit to these informationally opaque companies (Stiglitz and Weiss, 1981).<br />

Additionally, public equity and debt finance are subject to significant costs, including market due<br />

diligence, distribution and security registration, which are essentially fixed and create economies of<br />

scale in issue size (Berger and Udell, 1998). These economies of scale in issue create a barrier which<br />

small and young companies may not be able to overcome. Hence, transaction costs make particular<br />

types of external finance extremely costly. Overall, the process of obtaining sufficient outside finance<br />

is a process fraught with difficulties and this especially for new and small ventures.<br />

9


Empirical research confirms that companies are generally confronted with external finance constraints.<br />

Himmelberg and Petersen (1994) demonstrate for a panel of US companies active in high-technology<br />

industries that investments in Research and Development (R&D) are positively related to the<br />

availability of internal finance. Manigart, Baeyens and Verschueren (2002) offer similar findings for<br />

unquoted Belgian companies and demonstrate how investments in tangible fixed assets are positively<br />

related to the availability of internal finance. Using the growth of the whole company instead of an<br />

individual component, such as R&D-investments or investments in fixed tangible assets, Carpenter<br />

and Petersen (2002a) confirm that the growth of small manufacturing companies is constrained by the<br />

availability of internal finance.<br />

1.2.2. Type of Finance<br />

A second dimension of financial decision-making relates to the type of finance. Two of the most<br />

influential theoretical frameworks on finance behavior relate to the type of finance, i.e. the static trade-<br />

off theory and pecking order theory (Fama and French, 2005; Frank and Goyal, 2005; Cassar, 2004).<br />

Both grew out of the debate sparked by Modigliani and Miller. The static trade-off theory indicates<br />

that companies will trade-off the benefits of debt against the costs of debt finance. Debt finance has an<br />

important advantage compared to equity finance under the corporate tax system in most developed<br />

countries: while the interests that businesses pay are tax-deductible expenses, dividends and retained<br />

earnings typically are not or less so. Hence, debt yields a benefit in that it shields earnings from<br />

corporate taxes (Modigliani and Miller, 1963). Moreover, an agency perspective indicates an<br />

additional benefit related to debt finance as it is proposed to reduce the free cashflow problem in<br />

companies with large amounts of cashflows (Jensen, 1986). The fixed debt-related payments force<br />

managers to distribute excessive cashflow to debtholders instead of using it to invest in pet projects or<br />

other value destroying investments.<br />

One would expect companies to entirely finance their operations with debt if there would be no<br />

offsetting costs (Figure 1.1.). However, excessive use of debt finance creates bankruptcy costs. Debt<br />

10


finance entails fixed debt-related payments; when a company is unable to fulfill these payments both<br />

indirect and direct bankruptcy costs will decrease company value (Figure 1.1.). Additionally, highly<br />

levered companies with significant growth opportunities may face an underinvestment problem and<br />

company shareholders may forego value-creating investments (Myers, 1977). In these highly levered<br />

companies additional investments may disproportionately benefit debtholders, while shareholders have<br />

to carry the entire cost of new investments. <strong>Companies</strong> may avoid that agency conflicts emerge<br />

between debtholders and shareholders by reducing debt levels. In the static trade-off theory companies<br />

have an optimal capital structure where the marginal cost of an additional euro of debt finance equals<br />

the marginal benefit of an additional euro of debt finance (Figure 1.1). Moreover, it is proposed that<br />

companies make incremental finance decisions in such a way that they gradually move towards their<br />

target (optimal) debt ratio.<br />

Market value of<br />

firm<br />

Source: Shyam-Sunder and Myers (1999), pp. 220.<br />

FIGURE 1.1<br />

The Static Trade-off Theory of Capital Structure<br />

PV interest tax shields<br />

Firm value under all-equity financing<br />

Optimum<br />

PV costs of financial distress<br />

A different perspective is the pecking order theory (Myers, 1984; Myers and Majluf, 1984). In a<br />

pecking order framework, the cost related to the existence of informational asymmetries between<br />

company managers and investors is of first-order importance, while the costs and benefits proposed in<br />

Debt<br />

11


the static trade-off theory are only of second-order importance. Informational asymmetry entails that<br />

while business managers have private information on the value of assets in place and future growth<br />

options, outside investors can merely estimate these values. When outside investors underestimate the<br />

value of debt or equity issued by a company, this company may decide not to accept the finance and<br />

scale down or completely abandon valuable investment projects. The undervaluation of the securities<br />

offered by a company may be so severe that when the company accepts prohibitively expensive<br />

external finance to execute new investment projects this may damage company value. <strong>Companies</strong> may<br />

avoid these problems by financing projects internally (Myers, 1984). Moreover, debt finance will be<br />

preferred to new equity finance because the information problems are lower when companies issue<br />

new debt (Myers, 1984). When companies have no cashflow problems debtholders are guaranteed<br />

companies will be able to fulfill the fixed debt-related payments. Nevertheless, new shareholders are<br />

not sure that companies will distribute sufficiently high dividends over time as these are neither fixed<br />

nor required.<br />

In summary, companies prefer to finance new investments with internal funds, which are not subject<br />

to asymmetric information problems. When internal funds are insufficient to meet the finance needs,<br />

managers will turn to more costly outside funds. In this situation, companies are expected to issue the<br />

safest securities first as these will suffer less from information asymmetries (Myers, 1984). This<br />

implies managers will first raise debt finance and only consider new equity as a final option. Finally, it<br />

is important to note that in a pecking order framework companies have no target debt ratio. Debt ratios<br />

merely reflect companies’ cumulative past requirements for external finance (Myers, 1984).<br />

These two different perspectives, often presented as competing frameworks, sparked a vast stream of<br />

large-sample empirical studies testing which framework performs best in explaining real-world<br />

financing behavior (López-Garcia and Sogorb-Mira, 2008; Fama and French, 2005; Frank and Goyal,<br />

2003; Shyam-Sunder and Myers, 1999). The standard versions of both theories, however, appear to be<br />

inadequate. A particularly important problem for the static trade-off theory is that some of the most<br />

successful companies –e.g. Microsoft– succeed by using no or limited debt finance thereby foregoing<br />

12


valuable interest tax shields (Brealey and Myers, 2000). More significantly, debt ratios did not change<br />

considerably in the last decades despite significant changes in corporate tax levels over the same<br />

period (Frank and Goyal, 2005; Brealey and Myers, 2000). A particularly important problem for the<br />

standard pecking order theory is that debt ratios are typically low in high-technology, high-growth<br />

industries, despite significant external finance needs (Fama and French, 2005; Frank and Goyal, 2005;<br />

Brealey and Myers, 2000). Both static trade-off and pecking order proponents are fine-tuning<br />

abovementioned standard versions of their theories to account for known facts. Trade-off theorists are<br />

currently developing dynamic tradeoff models, while pecking order theorists are focusing their efforts<br />

on the development of an extended pecking order theory -incorporating the notion of debt capacity-<br />

and the development of more complex adverse selection models (Frank and Goyal, 2005).<br />

The first study “Incremental Finance Decisions in <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong>: Pecking Order and Debt<br />

Capacity Considerations” builds further on this tension in modern business finance. It contributes to<br />

the literature on the extended pecking order theory by more fully developing the notion of debt<br />

capacity. While prior research generally defines debt capacity as sufficiently high debt ratios that<br />

restrain a company from raising additional debt finance, this paper demonstrates the key role of<br />

cashflows necessary to fulfill the fixed debt-related payments. The goal of this study is not to test<br />

whether the pecking order or static trade-off theory performs best in a sample of high-growth<br />

companies. Rather it demonstrates the value of combining both perspectives in order to increase our<br />

understanding of financial decision-making.<br />

1.2.3. Source of Finance<br />

A third important dimension of financial decision-making relates to the finance source. Particularly<br />

influential is the financial growth cycle as proposed by Berger and Udell (1998). Based on pecking<br />

order considerations and optimal security design this life-cycle model indicates that different sources<br />

of finance become more or less important when companies become larger, older and more<br />

informationally transparent. Figure 1.2 indicates that startups, which are highly uncertain and lack a<br />

13


track record, will heavily rely on inside finance and trade credit. For companies with high-growth<br />

ambitions and limited debt capacity (due to, for example, a lack of collateral) outside equity finance<br />

from business angels and venture capital investors will be a particularly important source of finance.<br />

When a company has valuable assets, which can serve as collateral, bank debt will become available.<br />

Only when companies develop a track record of past performance and thereby become more<br />

informationally transparent public equity and debt markets will become important sources of finance<br />

to finance future growth.<br />

Firm Size<br />

Firm Age<br />

FIGURE 1.2<br />

Firm Continuum and Sources of Finance: The Financial <strong>Growth</strong> Cycle Paradigm<br />

Information Availability<br />

Very small firms,<br />

possibly with no<br />

collateral and no<br />

track record.<br />

Initial Insider Finance<br />

Small firms, possibly<br />

with high growth<br />

potential but often with<br />

limited track record.<br />

Source: Berger and Udell (1998), pp. 623.<br />

Medium-sized firms.<br />

Some track record.<br />

Collateral available, if<br />

necessary.<br />

Angel Finance Venture Capital Public Equity<br />

Short-Term Financial Institutions Loans<br />

Trade Credit<br />

Intermediate-Term Financial Institutions<br />

Mezzanine<br />

Private Placements<br />

Large firms of known<br />

risk and track record<br />

Commercial paper<br />

Medium Term<br />

Notes<br />

Public Debt<br />

14


Although the financial growth cycle paradigm is generally accepted in the finance literature, it has not<br />

been subject to much empirical scrutiny (Gregory, Rutherford, Oswald, and Gardiner, 2005).<br />

Moreover, the financial growth cycle does not address more fine-grained questions with respect to the<br />

source of finance. For example, which particular source of finance are companies more likely to<br />

target? Are companies more likely to target venture capital investor A or venture capital investor B?<br />

This is a problem characterizing most finance theories given the central role of rationality and investor<br />

homogeneity in mainstream finance theories (Subrahmanyam, 2007).<br />

Eckhardt, Shane and Delmar (2006), for example, consider both the demand and the supply side of the<br />

market and propose that the finance process is a two-stage process. First, companies decide whether to<br />

raise external finance or not based on the quality perception of their venture. Second, investors select<br />

from the pool of companies that are willing to raise external finance based on their own quality<br />

assessment. Implicit in these models is that all companies with external finance needs target all<br />

possible external investors and/or investors screen all entrepreneurial companies with external finance<br />

needs. Furthermore, entrepreneurs are proposed to rank order all finance offers received from investors<br />

according to a particular criterion. <strong>Companies</strong> are expected to rank order finance offers based on the<br />

price offered as indicated by traditional finance theory or the reputation of the investor as<br />

demonstrated more recently by Hsu (2004). This results a very deterministic view on financial<br />

decision-making.<br />

In the second study “Seeking Experienced or Legitimate Partners? A Longitudinal Study on the Impact<br />

of Venture Capital Firm Heterogeneity on Portfolio Company <strong>Growth</strong>” I offer new evidence on the<br />

importance for the type of investor within a particular subset of investors, namely venture capital<br />

investors, on the growth of portfolio companies. Moreover, the third study “Early Differences and<br />

Persistence in the Entrepreneurial Finance Process: Evidence from <strong>High</strong>- and Low-<strong>Growth</strong><br />

Biotechnology Startups” offers additional insights into how entrepreneurs structure their search for<br />

early finance thereby contributing to a general gap in our understanding.<br />

15


1.2.4. Dynamics<br />

<strong>Companies</strong> have to make decisions with respect to the amount, type and source of finance at different<br />

points in time throughout their development. However, dynamics in the finance process or how<br />

financial decisions interrelate have received comparatively little research attention (Eckhardt, Shane<br />

and Delmar, 2006; Gregory, Rutherford, Oswald, and Gardiner, 2005; Berger and Udell, 1998). This<br />

relates to the lack of longitudinal data especially on small and unquoted entrepreneurial companies.<br />

While the financial growth cycle theory, for example, indicates that companies will prefer different<br />

sources of finance as they develop and grow, this is traditionally tested using a cross sectional research<br />

design. A good example is the study by Gregory, Rutherford, Oswald, and Gardiner (2005) who claim<br />

to provide one of the first empirical tests of the financial growth cycle theory use a cross sectional<br />

dataset. This study analyzes the effect of company age, size and information availability on the use of<br />

one of three finance types (insider funding, venture capitalist/mid-term loan or public equity/long-term<br />

loan). Although such cross-sectional studies are informative about differences between companies,<br />

they simply cannot study how companies make finance decisions over time since the response<br />

variables are measured at a single occasion (Fitzmaurice, Laird, and Ware, 2004).<br />

More significantly, traditional capital structure theories generally ignore the role of company history<br />

on future finance behavior (Hovakimian, Opler and Titman, 2001). Traditional finance scholars, who<br />

build upon the idea proposed by the static trade-off theory that companies have an optimal financial<br />

structure and will make finance decisions in such a way that they reach this optimum, are more<br />

interested on how quickly companies move towards their target financial structure. Leary and Roberts<br />

(2005) indicate that companies move relatively quickly towards their optimum financial structure.<br />

Moreover, it is proposed that companies not only manage their financial structure actively, but also<br />

rebalance towards a target that is more or less time-invariant (Lemmon, Roberts, and Zender, 2008).<br />

In the third study “Early Differences and Persistence in the Entrepreneurial Finance Process:<br />

Evidence from <strong>High</strong>- and Low-<strong>Growth</strong> Biotechnology Startups” I focus explicitly on dynamics in the<br />

16


finance process. The study demonstrates how differences originate in the finance process and<br />

elucidates the processes that cause initial finance decisions to constrain or facilitate subsequent<br />

financial decision-making.<br />

1.2.5. How the Studies in this Dissertation Cover the Different Dimensions of<br />

Financial Decision-Making<br />

Table 1.1 offers an overview of the different studies and the dimensions of financial decision-making<br />

on which they focus. By design, the first study does not focus on the amount of finance raised, but<br />

rather focuses on the type of finance raised and more specifically on the choice between internal<br />

finance, debt finance and outside equity finance. Contrary to traditional capital structure research,<br />

however, which often treats all equity finance as homogenous, this study makes a distinction between<br />

inside finance (retained earnings) and outside equity finance. Although this study focuses on the<br />

source of finance, or the distinction between inside and outside sources of finance, this distinction<br />

remains rather crude. The study controls for the impact of prior finance decisions on future finance<br />

decisions.<br />

The second study focuses on the initial source of finance and its impact on company growth. It studies<br />

the impact of venture capital firm heterogeneity on company growth. It controls for both the effects of<br />

the amount of finance by including a control variable measuring the amount of startup finance raised.<br />

Furthermore, the second study controls for the impact of the type of finance by focusing on a<br />

homogenous group of venture capital backed companies, which all raise initial venture capital. The<br />

study largely ignores the impact of initial finance decisions on the subsequent finance process.<br />

The third study focuses explicitly on dynamics in the finance process and studies how the finance<br />

process differs with respect to the amount of finance and source of finance raised between high- and<br />

low-growth entrepreneurial ventures. It demonstrates how early finance decisions may both facilitate<br />

and constrain future finance decisions. The third study controls for the impact of the type of finance by<br />

17


focusing on the acquisition of venture capital finance across time within new biotechnology ventures.<br />

Other more traditional sources of finance, such as internally generated funds and bank debt, are known<br />

to be unavailable for this type of ventures.<br />

TABLE 1.1<br />

The Three Studies and their Focus on the Different Dimensions of the Finance Process a<br />

Study 1: Incremental finance decisions in high-growth<br />

companies: pecking order and debt capacity considerations<br />

Study 2: Seeking Experienced or Legitimate Partners? A<br />

Longitudinal Study on the Impact of Venture Capital Firm<br />

Heterogeneity on Portfolio Company <strong>Growth</strong><br />

Study 3: Early Differences and Persistence in the<br />

Entrepreneurial Finance Process: Evidence from <strong>High</strong>- and<br />

Low-<strong>Growth</strong> Biotechnology Startups<br />

Amount Type Source Dynamics<br />

0 • • C<br />

C C • 0<br />

• C • •<br />

a Where • indicates this aspect of the finance process is the focus of the study, c implies the study controls for this aspect of<br />

the finance process and 0 indicates the study does not focus on this aspect of finance process.<br />

1.3. The Link between Process Theories and Foundational Finance<br />

Theories<br />

In the prior section, I argued how current finance research has generally failed to addresses dynamics<br />

in financial decision-making. In this subsection, I start by depicting the finance process as an<br />

organizational process and present multiple models advanced by organizational scholars to grasp the<br />

reality of complex organizational processes. I link these basic organizational process models to<br />

foundational finance theories discussed above. Four basic process models have been proposed, which<br />

each depict the process of development as unfolding in a fundamentally different progression of<br />

change events, governed by different generative mechanisms or motors of change (Van de Ven and<br />

Poole, 1995). Figure 1.3 summarizes these four basic models and relates them to existing finance<br />

theory. I elaborate on the four process models below:<br />

18


First, a teleological (or planned change) model depicts development as movement towards attaining a<br />

goal or desired end-state. These models posit a set of goals desired by entrepreneurs, which they have<br />

to attain in order to realize their aspirations. Development is viewed as a cycle of goal formulation,<br />

implementation, evaluation and modification of goals and stresses the purposeful enactment of<br />

entrepreneurs as the motor for development. Teleological models incorporate the systems theory<br />

assumption of equifinality, which implies there are several equally effective ways to achieve a goal.<br />

Hence, there is no assumption about historical necessity and teleological models do not specify what<br />

future trajectories will follow. At best, these models list a set of possible trajectories by relying on<br />

norms of decision and action rationality (Van de Ven, 2007).<br />

Static trade-off and pecking order theories are the most influential theories in modern corporate<br />

finance (Myers, 1984). Although these theories have been depicted as competing frameworks in<br />

numerous empirical finance studies (e.g., López-Garcia and Sogorb-Mira, 2008; Shyam-Sunder and<br />

Myers, 1999), both the static trade-off theory and pecking order theory fit within the definition of a<br />

teleological model. The static trade-off theory and pecking order theory both assume that<br />

entrepreneurs have one overriding goal, namely value maximization (Subrahmanyam, 2007). Hence,<br />

entrepreneurs structure their search for finance in such a way that they minimize the cost of finance.<br />

More specifically, the static trade-off theory indicates managers will trade-off the benefits of debt<br />

against the cost of debt and choose a financial structure where the cost of finance is minimized. A<br />

pecking order theory proposes entrepreneurs will minimize the costs of informational asymmetry by<br />

avoiding external finance, and especially new equity, whenever possible. It is only when entrepreneurs<br />

are confronted with finance needs that they will act. When internal finance is available, they will use<br />

these funds to finance investments. When internal funds are not available, entrepreneurs will start the<br />

search for debt finance, and only when debt finance is unavailable or prohibitively costly will they<br />

consider external equity (Myers, 1984).<br />

19


Moreover, historical finance decisions have no impact on future finance decisions in the static trade-<br />

off and pecking order theory (Hovakimian, Opler, and Titman, 2001). More specifically, the static<br />

trade-off theory proposes that managers move towards an optimal financial structure with more or less<br />

difficulty (Leary and Roberts, 2005). Movement towards the target financial structure is hence<br />

independent from prior financial decisions. In a pecking order framework, when managers are<br />

confronted with finance needs they observe at that time whether sufficient internal funds are available.<br />

If that is the case, they will use internal funds to finance the investments, irrespective of how the<br />

company was financed before. If internal funds are not sufficient, companies will consider raising<br />

outside finance (preferably debt) and this irrespective of prior finance decisions.<br />

Second, next to teleology, life-cycle models are perhaps the most common explanation of<br />

development in the broader management and finance literature. A life-cycle (or regulated change)<br />

model depicts the process of change in an entity as progression through a necessary sequence of<br />

stages. An institutional, natural or logical program prescribes the specific contents of these stages. It is<br />

this institutional, natural or logical program that moves the company from a given point towards an<br />

end-state. The final end-state is prefigured and requires a specific historical sequence of events (Van<br />

de Ven, 2007). The most influential life-cycle theory in corporate finance is probably the financial<br />

growth cycle (Berger and Udell, 1998). This theory indicates that the availability and suitability of<br />

different finance sources changes as companies age, become larger and more transparent. Hence, the<br />

motor for change in the financial growth cycle is the uncertainty of companies and the availability of<br />

information.<br />

Third, dialectical models are founded on the assumption that companies exist in a pluralistic world of<br />

colliding events, forces or contradictory values that compete with each other for dominance and<br />

control. Change occurs when opposing values, forces or events gain sufficient power to confront the<br />

status quo. The conflicts that emerge between entities espousing opposing thesis and antithesis collide<br />

to produce a synthesis (i.e. a change in the finance process for the better or worse), which in time<br />

20


ecomes the thesis for the next cycle. Confrontation and conflict between opposing entities are central<br />

within these models and generate a dialectical cycle of change (Van de Ven, 2007).<br />

A key finance theory focusing on the design of alternative governance structures to mitigate agency<br />

conflicts arising from the possible divergence of interest between shareholders, managers and<br />

debtholders, is agency theory (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). Agency theory, for example, presents debt<br />

finance as a governance device useful in reducing conflicts between shareholders and managers<br />

(Jensen, 1986). Agency theory indicates that companies with plenty of internal funds will attract debt<br />

finance as a mechanism to reduce the risk of managers investing in pet projects. This is because the<br />

managers within companies that raise additional debt finance will have to use excessive funds to fulfill<br />

the fixed debt-related payments.<br />

Finally, an evolutionary model of business development and change incorporates both the ideas of<br />

“organizational selection” or the role of the external market environment in determining the survival<br />

and growth of companies (Van de Ven, 2007) and “organizational genetics” or the transmission of<br />

organizational traits through time (Helfat, 1994). The variation-selection-retention framework is a key<br />

element within an evolutionary perspective (Aldrich, 1999). Variation involves the creation of novel<br />

organizations. Selection occurs primarily through competition among companies for scare resources,<br />

such as financial resources. The environment selects those companies that best fit the resource base of<br />

that specific environment. Retention involves the forces including inertia and persistence, which<br />

perpetuate and maintain certain organizational forms. Overall, an evolutionary theory proposes that<br />

early differences, which emerge between companies operating within the same industry, are likely to<br />

persist across time (Nelson and Winter, 1982).<br />

21


I. TELEOLOGY<br />

FIGURE 1.3<br />

Process Models of Organizational Development and Key Finance Theories a<br />

Dissatisfaction<br />

Implement Search/<br />

Goals Interact<br />

Set/Envision<br />

Goals<br />

Motors of change: Purposeful enactment and equifinality.<br />

Finance theory: Pecking order theory and static tradeoff theory<br />

(Myers, 1984)<br />

III. DIALECTIC<br />

Thesis<br />

Antithesis<br />

Conflict Synthesis<br />

Motors of change: Diversity, confrontation and conflict.<br />

Finance theory: Agency theory (Jensen and Meckling, 1976)<br />

II. LIFE CYCLE<br />

Stage 4 (Terminate)<br />

Stage 3 Stage 1<br />

(Harvest) (Startup)<br />

Stage 2<br />

(Grow)<br />

Motors of change: Immanent program, regulation and compliant<br />

adaptation.<br />

Finance theory: Financial growth cycle (Berger and Udell, 1998)<br />

IV. EVOLUTION<br />

Variation Selection Retention<br />

Motors of change: External market and organizational “genetics”.<br />

Finance theory: ---<br />

a Largely adapted from Van de Ven, A.H. and Poole M.S. (1995) “Explaining development and change in organizations.” Academy of Management Review, 20: 520.<br />

22


While current finance theories fit within a teleological, life cycle or dialectical model, few theory building<br />

and empirical research has focused on the finance process as an evolutionary process. Nevertheless, recent<br />

research demonstrates that such a perspective may be particularly valuable in order to further develop our<br />

understanding of financial decision-making. Eckhardt, Shane and Delmar (2006) demonstrate that the<br />

finance process is characterized by double selection, where not only investors as resource providers, but<br />

also entrepreneurs play a key role. Entrepreneurs will first select whether or not they want to raise outside<br />

funds, based on their perceptions of company quality, and it is only from the pool of ventures that is<br />

willing to raise outside finance that investors will subsequent be able to select the ventures to which they<br />

will offer finance (Eckhardt, Shane and Delmar, 2006). As will be demonstrated later on, the overall<br />

contribution of this dissertation lies in further developing the entrepreneurial finance process as an<br />

evolutionary process.<br />

1.4. Company <strong>Growth</strong> as a Complex Organizational Process: What is <strong>High</strong><br />

<strong>Growth</strong>? What are <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong>?<br />

Although organizational growth is a central area of academic research, this research has failed to develop<br />

a cumulative body of knowledge and remains rather fragmented (O’Regan, Ghobadian, and Gallear, 2006;<br />

Delmar, Davidsson, and Gartner, 2003). A reason, which is typically advanced for this fragmentation, is<br />

that organizational growth is a multidimensional concept (Weinzimmer, Nystrom, and Freeman 1998). It<br />

is the failure to recognize the multidimensional nature of organizational growth that has led to confusion<br />

and even conflict in both theory building and empirical research (Delmar, Davidsson, and Gartner, 2003).<br />

Below I first discuss the multidimensional nature of growth, before highlighting its consequences for the<br />

different studies 2 .<br />

2 This section mainly focuses on the methodological issues in growth studies. It is beyond the scope of this section to offer an<br />

overview of foundational growth theories as well. Wiklund, Patzelt and Shepherd (2009) provide an excellent review of growth<br />

theory. I do relate my findings back to growth theory when discussing the overall contributions of this dissertation (section 1.8.2.).<br />

23


1.4.1. <strong>Growth</strong> Indicators, <strong>Growth</strong> Formula and Timeframe<br />

When studying high-growth companies, three dimensions merit particular attention: (a) the growth<br />

concept, (b) the growth formula and (c) dynamics in growth (Davidsson and Wiklund, 2006; Weinzimmer,<br />

Nystrom, and Freeman 1998). I discuss these elements in more detail below. First, different growth<br />

indicators have been used in prior research (Delmar, Davidsson, and Gartner, 2003) and the most popular<br />

include growth in sales, growth in employment and growth in assets (Weinzimmer, Nystrom, and Freeman<br />

1998). Other relevant growth indicators include growth in value added and growth in cash flow amongst<br />

other.<br />

It is crucial to acknowledge that each growth indicator has shortcomings. <strong>Growth</strong> in total assets will be<br />

more relevant for capital-intensive industries and as a result using total assets as a growth concept is likely<br />

to ascribe higher growth to capital-intensive companies compared to service companies. Employment<br />

growth will be more relevant in labor-intensive industries; using employment as a growth concept is likely<br />

to ascribe higher growth to more labor-intensive companies. Sales is not a perfect growth concept either,<br />

as it is sensitive to inflation and currency exchange rates (Delmar, Davidsson, and Gartner, 2003).<br />

Moreover, many R&D-intensive companies, such as biotechnology ventures, have no sales for long<br />

periods, while they might develop themselves and grow in other dimensions. As a result, organizational<br />

scholars advise to use multiple growth indicators, which should give richer, more robust and more<br />

comparable findings, compared to studies resorting to only a single growth indicator (Delmar, Davidsson,<br />

and Gartner, 2003; Weinzimmer, Nystrom, and Freeman, 1998).<br />

Second, organizational growth scholars mostly discuss two growth formulas, namely absolute growth and<br />

relative growth. This distinction is vital, as absolute growth measures tend to attribute higher growth rates<br />

to larger companies, while relative growth measures tend to attribute higher growth to smaller companies.<br />

As an example, it is easier for a small company with only 10 employees to grow with 100% (i.e. relative<br />

24


terms) to a company with 20 employees, than for a company with 500 employees to growth with 100% to<br />

a company of 1,000 employees. For a company with 500 employees, however, it will be easier to add 20<br />

people (i.e. absolute terms) to its workforce, compared to a small company employing only 10 people.<br />

Using the dataset from the first study in this dissertation, Table 1.2 demonstrates the critical nature of the<br />

decision with respect to the growth concept and the growth formula researchers use. The overlap between<br />

companies selected by using different growth indicators is low. For example, only 29% of the companies<br />

selected as high-growth companies based on absolute growth in sales are also selected as high-growth<br />

companies based on absolute growth in assets. This indicates that growth in sales is quite different from<br />

growth in assets. These findings correspond with Delmar, Davidsson, and Gartner, (2003) for Swedish<br />

companies.<br />

Table 1.2 further demonstrates that the overlap between companies selected by using absolute or relative<br />

growth measures is low. For example, only 19% of the companies selected as high growth based on<br />

absolute growth in employment are also selected as high growth based on relative growth in employment.<br />

Hence, the distinction between absolute and relative growth measures is critical. Interesting is the<br />

observation that the overlap between the different groups of absolute growth companies is higher than the<br />

overlap between the different groups of relative growth companies. It indicates that the typical absolute<br />

growth company grows over more dimensions than the typical relative growth company.<br />

25


TABLE 1.2<br />

Overlap (%) between Different Groups of <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong> using Different <strong>Growth</strong> Indicators and<br />

<strong>Growth</strong> Formula a<br />

Absolute growth<br />

in total assets<br />

Absolute growth in total assets 100 *** *** *** *** ***<br />

Absolute growth in sales 29 100 *** *** *** ***<br />

Absolute growth in employment 19 37 100 *** *** ***<br />

Relative growth in total assets 11 5 4 100 *** ***<br />

Relative growth in sales 8 16 13 13 100 ***<br />

Relative growth in employment 3 5 19 8 26 100<br />

a <strong>Growth</strong> is measured as a three year moving average over a ten-year timeframe. Five growth indicators (assets, sales,<br />

employment, value added and cash flow) and two growth formula (absolute and relative) are used. This gives 10 listings offering<br />

a growth figure for all Flemish and Brussels companies that employ at least 10 people. <strong>High</strong>-growth companies are defined as<br />

those companies that are among the first percentile in one of those listings for at least two years. This results in a dataset of 2,106<br />

companies. Reported here are the three most commonly used growth indicators (i.e. total assets, sales and employment).<br />

Source: Van Eeckhout, Clarysse, Vanacker and Manigart (2006) “Op Safari in Vlaanderen: De identificatie en kenmerken van<br />

gazellen” In: Durven groeien in Vlaanderen: Een boek voor gevorderden (Eds. B. Clarysse) Roularta Books, Roeselare.<br />

Third, organizational growth is an inherently dynamic measure of change across time (Davidsson and<br />

Wiklund, 2006; Weinzimmer, Nystrom, and Freeman, 1998). A five-year period has been the time frame<br />

most widely used in prior organizational growth studies (Weinzimmer, Nystrom, and Freeman 1998).<br />

Surprisingly, scholars generally neglect the central role of the time frame of a study on its findings<br />

(Zaheer, Albert and Zaheer, 1999). More surprisingly, despite the inherently dynamic nature of growth,<br />

growth studies typically use only first and last year sizes. Consequently, these studies do not fully capture<br />

the growth of companies, because they ignore development in between these two time points (Delmar,<br />

Davidsson, and Gartner, 2003; Weinzimmer, Nystrom, and Freeman 1998). As a result, most growth<br />

Absolute growth<br />

in sales<br />

Absolute growth<br />

in employment<br />

Relative growth<br />

in total assets<br />

Relative growth<br />

in sales<br />

Relative growth<br />

in employment<br />

26


studies make –often-implicit– assumptions about the temporal pattern of growth in between two points in<br />

time. Some researchers assume that growth occurs as one large quantum size leap over the period studied<br />

while others assume that growth is a linear process (Davidsson and Wiklund, 2006).<br />

1.4.2. How the Studies in this Dissertation Address the Multidimensional Nature of<br />

<strong>Growth</strong><br />

Organizational growth scholars argue that researchers should be more explicit about how they measure<br />

growth (Davidsson and Wiklund, 2006). Table 1.3 offers an overview of the different studies and how<br />

they incorporate the multidimensional nature of growth. The first study defines high-growth companies by<br />

using five growth indicators, which include employment, revenues, total assets, added value and cashflow.<br />

Moreover, growth is measured in both absolute and relative terms. Given that the goal of the first paper<br />

was to obtain a broad sample of high-growth companies in order to study their finance policies, we<br />

combined multiple measures and growth formula. Although, this study is longitudinal in the sense that I<br />

follow the financial decisions of high-growth companies for up to eight years, dynamics in company<br />

growth were not the focus of the study.<br />

In the second study, I used two growth indicators, namely growth in employment and growth in total<br />

assets (excluding cash and cash equivalents). These two growth indicators are particularly suitable to<br />

study the development of venture capital backed companies on which I focus in this study. Venture capital<br />

backed companies typically develop new products or services without any immediate sale prospects even<br />

in low-tech sectors (Puri and Zarutskie 2008). Given that many venture capital backed companies in the<br />

sample are startups, I decided to focus on absolute growth, as it is impossible to calculate relative growth<br />

when initial values are zero. The second study explicitly models the dynamic and non-linear nature of<br />

growth by using an appropriate longitudinal technique called Linear Mixed Model (LMM).<br />

27


Study 1: Incremental Finance Decisions in <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong><br />

TABLE 1.3<br />

The Three Studies and Multidimensional Nature of <strong>Growth</strong><br />

<strong>Companies</strong>: Pecking Order and Debt Capacity Considerations<br />

Study 2: Seeking Experienced or Legitimate Partners? A<br />

Longitudinal Study on the Impact of Venture Capital Firm<br />

Heterogeneity on Portfolio Company <strong>Growth</strong><br />

Study 3: Early Differences and Persistence in the Entrepreneurial<br />

Finance Process: Evidence from <strong>High</strong>- and Low-<strong>Growth</strong><br />

Biotechnology Startups<br />

Indicator Formula Dynamics<br />

Multiple indicators Absolute and relative<br />

Multiple indicators<br />

growth<br />

Absolute growth only<br />

Ignored<br />

Explicitly modeled<br />

through LMMs<br />

Multiple indicators Absolute growth only Explicitly studied<br />

through longitudinal<br />

case studies<br />

The third study makes a distinction between high- and low-growth biotechnology startups. Three<br />

performance measures are used including employment growth, growth in total assets and patenting rate.<br />

The focus is again on absolute growth since all ventures are startups where initial values equal zero.<br />

Within the high- and low-growth ventures, we study the accumulation of financial resources across time.<br />

We explicitly theorize on the dynamics in the finance process, which foster and/or constrain ventures in<br />

their ability to raise follow-on finance.<br />

1.5. Research Context<br />

All studies in this dissertation focus on unquoted Belgian companies. In this section, I first describe the<br />

Belgian financial system and demonstrate it is a typical example of a bank-based financial system.<br />

Second, I describe the entrepreneurial landscape in Belgium and compare it with the entrepreneurial<br />

landscape in other high-income countries. Finally, I discuss the implications of the research setting for the<br />

studies in this dissertation.<br />

28


1.5.1. The Belgian Financial System<br />

Belgium has a bank-based financial system and banks play a central role in mobilizing savings, allocating<br />

capital, exerting corporate control and providing risk management vehicles (Demirguc-Kunt and Levine,<br />

1999). Other examples of so-called bank-oriented countries include Germany, France, Italy, Spain and<br />

Japan (Demirguc-Kunt and Levine, 1999). In market-oriented countries like the U.K., U.S. and Canada,<br />

securities markets (together with banks) play a central role in mobilizing and allocating capital, corporate<br />

control and risk management (Demirguc-Kunt and Levine, 1999). Rajan and Zingales (1995) argue that<br />

the difference between the two types of financial systems is not so much present in the level of debt<br />

companies use, but is more likely reflected in the choice between public finance (e.g. stocks and bonds)<br />

and private finance (e.g. bank loans and venture capital finance).<br />

The following figures illustrate the central role played by banks in the Belgian financial system. While<br />

Belgian GDP equaled 314.1 billion euro in 2006, the amount of assets controlled by the Belgian Bank<br />

sector equaled 1,422 billion euro by the end of December 2006 (NBB, 2008). Loans by banks account for<br />

over 60% of their assets, a figure that has remained quite stable over the last years (NBB, 2008). The two<br />

most common parties to whom banks grant loans are other financial intermediaries and companies. They<br />

each represent about one third of the loan portfolio. Moreover, private individuals represent another fourth<br />

of the loan portfolio (NBB, 2008). The Belgian banking sector is highly developed as measured by its<br />

size, activity and efficiency (see Demirguc-Kunt and Levine (1999) for cross-country comparisons). This<br />

is definitely the case when compared by the development of its public equity markets.<br />

The amount of finance raised through public equity markets equaled 1.3 billion euro in 2006, of which -<br />

some 700 million euro- was raised by one financial holding. Only 14 companies conducted an Initial<br />

Public Offering (IPO) in 2006. In 2005, 1.8 billion euro was raised through public equity markets and<br />

eight companies conducted an IPO (NBB, 2008). These figures demonstrate that public equity is only<br />

29


accessible for a limited number of companies. Moreover, IPOs are rare events in the Belgian financial<br />

market. The value of public bond issues increased from 5 billion in 2005 to 5.5 billion euro in 2006. It is<br />

important to note, however, that over 90% of the corporate bond issues relate to foreign companies,<br />

including a number of subsidiaries of Belgian financial intermediaries (NBB, 2008). Hence, public bond<br />

issues are extremely rare for Belgian non-financial companies.<br />

The Belgian venture capital and private equity market, although less developed than the U.S. and U.K.<br />

markets, is quite similar compared to other Continental European venture capital and private equity<br />

markets (Baeyens, 2006). In 2006, 721.7 million euro of venture capital and private equity was raised, a<br />

sharp increase from the 352.7 million raised in 2005 (EVCA, 2007). Banks contribute a significant<br />

amount of funds to the venture capital and private equity industry, with 78.8% and 28.3% of the funds<br />

raised in respectively 2006 and 2005. This is further evidence pointing towards the key role played by<br />

banks in the Belgian financial system.<br />

In 2006, 940 million euro was invested through 349 investments in 244 companies (EVCA, 2007).<br />

Although public sector investors used to dominate the Belgian venture capital and private equity market<br />

(Baeyens, 2006), more recently independent funds are the most common type of investor, representing<br />

45% of the amount invested and 57% of the number of investments in 2006 (EVCA, 2007). Only 4% of<br />

the amount invested and 12% of the number of investments are in the seed and startup stage. This is a<br />

significant drop from 2005, where some 32% of the amount invested and 39% of the investments were in<br />

the seed and startup stage. In 2006, high-technology investments represented 12% of the amount invested<br />

and 47% of the number of investments. In 2005, the amount invested in high-technology companies still<br />

represented 44% of the amount invested. This sharp drop in the amount invested in high-technology<br />

industries is mainly due to a significant reduction in the amount invested in the biotechnology industry.<br />

Divestments by trade sale, public offering, write-off and sale to financial institutions (the most important<br />

options) represented respectively 14.7%, 14.7%, 11.8% and 20.6% of divestments in 2006.<br />

30


Overall, the Belgian financial system is a typical example of a bank-based financial system (Demirguc-<br />

Kunt and Levine, 1999). It allows us to provide more insight into the finance process in a different setting<br />

compared to the majority of prior empirical studies. Prior studies more often analyze the finance process<br />

of large Anglo-Saxon companies, which often raise funds by issuing corporate debt and equity on public<br />

capital markets (Zingales, 2000).<br />

1.5.2. The Belgian Entrepreneurial Landscape<br />

The Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM) offers an annual assessment and review of entrepreneurial<br />

activity in countries participating in the GEM project. In 2007, the ninth annual assessment, 42 countries<br />

participated. A central indicator is the early-stage entrepreneurial activity index. This index represents the<br />

percentage of the working population (i.e., people between 18 and 64 years old) of a country that is<br />

currently involved in setting up a company (nascent entrepreneurs) or recently started a new company<br />

(owner-managers of companies up to 42 months old).<br />

In 2007, the early-stage entrepreneurial activity index equaled 3.2% in Belgium. This implies that on<br />

average 3.2% of the working population indicated they were involved in setting up a business or recently<br />

founded a new business. The rate of entrepreneurial activity in Belgium lies significantly below the<br />

European average (5.3%) and global average (8.9%). Figure 1.4 reports the early-stage entrepreneurial<br />

activity rates for 2002/03, 2004/05 and 2006/07 and demonstrates how Belgium can be consistently found<br />

in the lower rankings on the entrepreneurial activity scale in high-income countries for each of the three<br />

periods studied. These figures are worrying as research indicates a positive relationship between the<br />

prevalence of entrepreneurial activity in high-income countries and economic growth (van Stel, Carree,<br />

and Thurik, 2005).<br />

31


FIGURE 1.4<br />

Early-Stage Entrepreneurial Activity Rates for 2002/03, 2004/05 and 2006/07 in <strong>High</strong>-Income Countries<br />

Source: Global Entrepreneurship Monitor Adult Population Survey (Global Report, 2007, pp. 17).<br />

While the early-stage entrepreneurial activity index reflects the prevalence of entrepreneurship in general,<br />

the focus of the different studies in this dissertation is on high-growth companies. It is generally<br />

acknowledged that only a small fraction of new firms contribute disproportionately to economic growth<br />

(Storey, 1994). Achieving high-growth is non-trivial and does not happen by accident. On the contrary, it<br />

requires significant investments both in tangible and intangible assets. These investments are unlikely to<br />

be carried out if the entrepreneur has no or only limited growth ambition (Wiklund and Shepherd, 2003).<br />

Autio (2005) defines high-growth expectation entrepreneurship as the percentage of entrepreneurs that<br />

expect to employ at least 20 people within a timeframe of five years after founding.<br />

Autio (2005) demonstrates how the overall early-stage entrepreneurial activity negatively relates with<br />

high-growth expectation entrepreneurship. So, while the general entrepreneurial activity in a country may<br />

be quite low, a large fraction of this activity may be high-growth expectation entrepreneurship.<br />

Unfortunately, figure 1.5 demonstrates how Belgium also hinges behind in terms of the relative<br />

prevalence of high-growth expectation entrepreneurship.<br />

32


FIGURE 1.5<br />

Relative Prevalence of <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong> Expectation in Early-Stage Entrepreneurship, 2000–2006<br />

Source: Global Entrepreneurship Monitor Adult Population Survey (Global Report, 2007, pp. 27).<br />

In 2007, on average 6.9% of Belgian entrepreneurs are involved in establishing a new business and expect<br />

to employ more than 20 people in five years time. Alternatively, only 0.2% of the 18-64 Belgian<br />

population is involved in high-growth expectation entrepreneurship. In Europe, on average 9.6% of<br />

entrepreneurs are involved in establishing a new business with high-growth expectations. This represents<br />

0.48% of the 18-64 European population.<br />

Both the absolute level of high-growth expectation entrepreneurship and especially the relative level of<br />

high-growth expectation entrepreneurship are positively related with the business angel activity and the<br />

availability of finance within countries (Autio, 2005). While prior research stresses the role of founder<br />

experience in securing resources from professional investors (Hallen, 2008; Hsu, 2007), the majority of<br />

people indicate they lack the necessary skills to start a new business. The 2007 GEM survey indicates that<br />

only 35% of the Belgians perceive themselves as capable and believe they have the necessary skills to<br />

start a business. This figures lies in line with other European countries, including Finland (31%), France<br />

(32%), Denmark (33%), the Netherlands (33%), Sweden (39%) and Spain (41%).<br />

33


Overall, a low level of entrepreneurial activity and low prevalence of high-growth expectation<br />

entrepreneurship characterize the Belgian context. Mobilizing sufficient and adequate financial resources<br />

is a key element of the venture creation process. However, many people express they lack the necessary<br />

skills and knowledge to start a new company. Hence, studying the relationship between the finance<br />

process and company growth is particularly acute in such a setting. It is my hope that entrepreneurs,<br />

investors and policymakers can gain a more thorough insight into the financial policies that relate to high<br />

growth.<br />

1.5.3. Implications of the Research Setting for the Studies in this Dissertation<br />

In this section, I discuss how the Belgian financial system and entrepreneurial context bear implications<br />

for the different studies in this dissertation. In the first study, I focus on the role of different types of<br />

finance within high-growth companies. While prior studies have touted that new equity finance may be<br />

particularly suitable for high-growth companies, debt finance may play a more crucial role in Continental<br />

European countries, as banks play a central role in the mobilization and allocation of capital. Both private-<br />

and public equity markets are less developed in Continental European countries. This makes it more<br />

difficult for entrepreneurs to tap finance from these sources. It calls for a broader study on the role of<br />

different types of finance (including debt and equity finance) for high-growth companies within a<br />

Continental European context and demonstrates the limits to generalize results from studies in an Anglo-<br />

Saxon setting to a Continental European setting and vice versa.<br />

In the second paper, I study the growth of venture capital backed companies and the impact of investor<br />

heterogeneity on the relationship between venture capital and growth relationship. Nearly all studies have<br />

focused on the impact of investor heterogeneity on the relative amounts of exits. In these studies, which<br />

are often in an Anglo-Saxon context, it is assumed that IPOs are the most favorable exit, while M&As are<br />

only a second-best option. In the Belgian and more broadly continental European context these<br />

34


assumptions are problematic. First, in order to conduct an IPO an active stock market is required. As<br />

previously indicated the Belgian stock market is relatively underdeveloped and only few companies go<br />

public. Second, M&As are often the preferred exit route both for very promising and less promising<br />

ventures. This is why I focus on the perspective of the entrepreneurial company in the second paper and<br />

study how different initial investors in these ventures help to accumulate more human resources and assets<br />

across time.<br />

In the third study, we make a distinction between young biotechnology ventures which exhibit high or low<br />

growth based on changes in employment, changes total assets and patenting rate. I previously argued that<br />

many Belgian entrepreneurs setup ventures with low growth-ambitions from startup. Hence, it will be<br />

necessary to consider the growth ambitions of the entrepreneurs that setup these new ventures. The study<br />

argues that entrepreneurial ventures that raise finance from experienced investors at startup raise more<br />

follow-on finance compared to ventures that raise early finance from relatively inexperienced investors. A<br />

particular challenge in this study will hence be to assure that both venture backed by more experienced<br />

and less experienced investors have high-growth ambitions in order to rule this out as an alternative<br />

explanation for the findings.<br />

1.6. Data<br />

All three studies in this dissertation use a different longitudinal dataset. The goal of this section is to offer<br />

more detail on the basic building blocks of the different datasets used within this dissertation. No data<br />

source is perfect and in this section I reflect on the advantages and disadvantages of the data sources on<br />

which my studies build. Table 1.4 summarizes the samples used in each study and the databases on which<br />

they build. Note that the first study is fundamentally different in design from the second and third study.<br />

In the first study, I only select companies that realized high growth during one particular period over the<br />

35


timeframe of the study 3 . However, the goal of this study was not to explain how finance decisions cause<br />

high growth or vice versa. Rather it was to study how a broad sample of high-growth companies financed<br />

themselves across time. The second study and third study, however, comprise both companies that<br />

realized high growth and companies that failed to realize high growth despite having growth potential.<br />

TABLE 1.4<br />

Description of the Samples and Databases Used a<br />

Sample Description<br />

Study 1 Incremental finance decisions of 2,077<br />

high-growth companies for up to eight<br />

years (1997-2004)<br />

Study 2 94 companies receiving initial venture<br />

Study 3<br />

capital between 1999 and 2003. These<br />

companies are tracked for 5 years after the<br />

initial investment resulting in 487 firm-year<br />

observations<br />

Longitudinal case study of 9 young Flemish<br />

biotechnology ventures active in research<br />

and development<br />

BEL-FIRST<br />

BVA<br />

Zephyr<br />

Interviews<br />

• 0 0 0 None<br />

• • • 0<br />

• 0 0 •<br />

a Where • indicates the database is used in a particular study and 0 indicates it is not used.<br />

1.6.1. BEL-FIRST Financial Accounts Database<br />

Other Data Sources<br />

European Patent Database, trade<br />

directories<br />

European Patent Database,<br />

statutory required publications,<br />

business plans, websites, press<br />

releases<br />

The BEL-FIRST database maintained by Bureau van Dijk offers electronic access to detailed yearly<br />

financial accounts of Belgian companies. An advantage of the Belgian setting is that all limited liability<br />

companies –irrespective of their size– are required to file detailed financial accounts with the Belgian<br />

3 This does not imply that I only study successful companies, as my sample also includes high-growth companies that eventually<br />

go bankrupt.<br />

36


Central Bank. Hence, rich longitudinal data is available for all companies, which provides a unique setting<br />

to study the finance process of unquoted high-growth companies.<br />

Not all companies are required to file complete financial statements, however. SMEs are allowed to report<br />

abbreviated financial statements, which are still rather extensive compared to the information that is<br />

typically available to researchers studying small unquoted ventures. One major difference between<br />

abbreviated and complete financial statements is that sales levels only have to be disclosed in complete<br />

financial statements. Fortunately, both complete and abbreviated formats report net added value, which<br />

may be used as an alternative output measure to sales.<br />

Investors heavily use and value general accounting information from financial statements. The decision to<br />

lend and the terms of the loan contract are often based on the strength of the balance sheet and income<br />

statements (Berger and Udell, 2002). Financial statements also play an important role in the screening and<br />

selection of companies by venture capital investors. Falconer, Reid, and Terry (1995) report that venture<br />

capital investors are heavy users of financial statement information and more specifically, that this<br />

information is a key component to evaluate ventures ex-post. Manigart, De Waele, Wright, et al. (2000)<br />

show that when venture capital investors have a financial or banking background they emphasize<br />

accounting and financial statement information even more and this both in screening and monitoring.<br />

Overall, financial statement data is expected to play a key role in the relationship between investors and<br />

entrepreneurs.<br />

Most financial account data from small and unquoted companies is unaudited, which may raise concerns<br />

about the reliability of the data. In many small ventures the boundaries between entrepreneurs and their<br />

ventures is blurry and entrepreneurs often use firm assets for private purposes. Moreover, reliable<br />

financial accounts require sophisticated accounting infrastructures which many small businesses lack<br />

(Berger and Udell, 2002). Nevertheless, the most important data with respect to the finance process that<br />

37


are collect through the financial accounts (for example, external debt and external equity) are relatively<br />

difficult to manipulate. Moreover, there is no reason to expect entrepreneurs to provide more accurate<br />

financial information through a survey, which is one of the main alternatives to obtain financial data from<br />

entrepreneurs. Surveys would also have an additional disadvantage in that it would be particularly difficult<br />

for entrepreneurs to recall key financial indicators for different periods in time.<br />

In the different studies the research context further limits some of the concerns on the reliability of the<br />

financial account data raised above. The first paper excludes those companies that employ less than 10<br />

people. <strong>From</strong> this size category onwards, ventures typically have developed internal specialization, there<br />

is an identifiable management function, and there is usually at least some separation of ownership and<br />

employees, in the sense that not all employees are also owners of the company (Autio, 2005). In the<br />

second and third paper, I focus on venture capital backed companies. Prior research demonstrates how the<br />

quality of financial account data reported by venture capital backed companies is higher compared to non-<br />

venture capital backed companies as venture capital firm monitoring is influencing the financial reporting<br />

discipline of their portfolio companies (Beuselinck, Deloof and Manigart, 2009).<br />

1.6.2. Belgian Venture Capital & Private Equity Association (BVA) Database<br />

The BVA was founded in 1986 and is the professional association that represents the Belgian private<br />

equity and venture capital community. The BVA currently has 36 venture capital firms as full members.<br />

Members are well balanced with respect to the type of investors (private and public institutions),<br />

background (financial and industrial), focus (venture and development capital as well as buy-outs), timing<br />

of exit (open ended and closed) and nationality of investors (Belgian and foreign ultimate investors).<br />

The raw database constructed by the BVA forms the building block of the second study in this<br />

dissertation. It comprises a sample of companies that received an initial venture capital investment<br />

38


etween 1999 and 2003. The dataset is quite straightforward and includes the year of the initial venture<br />

capital investment, portfolio company name, portfolio company VAT number (which allows linking the<br />

BVA database to the BEL-FIRST database) and name of the lead investor (which allows linking the BVA<br />

database to the Zephyr database). The 94 companies selected represent roughly 1/3 of all initial<br />

investments by the BVA members over the period studied. It is a representative sample including<br />

companies that eventually fail.<br />

The structure of the database forces me to focus on the impact of the lead investor on venture<br />

development. Although it is common for venture capital investors to invest in a syndicate, the focus on the<br />

lead investor is in line with prior studies (e.g., Gompers, 1996; Dimov and Shepherd, 2005). Moreover,<br />

the focus on the lead investor is motivated by the fact that it is this investor, who is typically responsible<br />

for the main contacts with the portfolio company. The content of the database also implies that I am<br />

focusing on investors that are members of the BVA. Venture capital investors may affiliate with<br />

professional organizations in order to gain legitimacy. Hence, I am likely to focus on a sample of more<br />

legitimate investors. Given that I study the impact of investor legitimacy on portfolio company growth this<br />

selection is important. However, the selection of investors that may on average be more legitimate is only<br />

likely to decrease the probability of finding a relationship between legitimacy and venture growth.<br />

1.6.3. Zephyr Database<br />

Venture capital firm characteristics play a central role in the second study within this dissertation. In order<br />

to obtain longitudinal data on investor characteristics, such as overall deal experience and industry deal<br />

experience, I used the Zephyr database. Zephyr is a database of private equity deals (similar to<br />

Thomson.One) with a special focus on pan-European transactions. The Zephyr database starts to cover<br />

venture capital backed deals from 1997.<br />

39


Two drawbacks of the Zephyr database are important to acknowledge. First, given that the coverage of the<br />

Zephyr database only starts from 1997, I miss the experience of particular venture capital firms<br />

accumulated before that period. Hence, in the second study I focus on the more recently accumulated<br />

experience. However, it is especially this experience that is thought to be important, given that the<br />

knowledge accumulated through experience has been shown to depreciate over time (Darr, Argote, and<br />

Epple, 1995). Second, there is a tendency of the Zephyr database to focus on larger more visible deals.<br />

Again, we limit this drawback in the second study by relying not only on the Zephyr database, but adding<br />

information from the BVA to our dataset.<br />

While databases such as Zephyr and Thomson.One form the building block of many datasets in current<br />

venture capital research, one should be particularly careful as research solely relying on these databases<br />

might lead to the wrong conclusions due to abovementioned shortcomings. For example, one<br />

biotechnology venture was both in the dataset of the second paper and included as a longitudinal case<br />

study in the third paper. The Zephyr database indicated this company raised 5,000,000 from startup from<br />

both local and international investors. At that time, a highly experienced manager was already in the<br />

venture. This observation might guide researchers to conclude that experienced managers are able to raise<br />

significant amounts of finance from highly experienced investors. Detailed interviews on the finance<br />

process, however, indicated that the company was founded by purely scientific entrepreneurs who first<br />

raised a limited amount of seed finance from a local experienced investor. This local investor helped with<br />

hiring a professional biotechnology manager. Once a highly experienced manager joined the company the<br />

local investor committed more funds and helped in the search for other finance from international<br />

investors. Hence, a different story emerges: inexperienced entrepreneurs are able to raise finance from<br />

experienced investors, who help the venture to professionalize and subsequently raise more finance from<br />

other (international) experienced investors.<br />

40


1.6.4. Interview data<br />

In the third study, I address how the finance process differs between high- and low-growth companies and<br />

why early differences have a tendency to persist across time. Case studies are particularly apt to address<br />

these how and why questions on which traditional finance frameworks offer little guidance. Central within<br />

the longitudinal case studies are my interviews with venture capital investors and entrepreneurs.<br />

All investors and entrepreneurs are active in the biotechnology industry and all cases are young Flemish<br />

biotechnology companies active in research and development. Homogenous case selection allows<br />

reducing the non-measured variance as much as possible. Moreover, biotechnology ventures typically<br />

require large amounts of finance, hence, the cases should allow me to study multiple finance events within<br />

one venture. A drawback is that the external validity of the findings for other types of ventures (i.e. ICT<br />

ventures, low technology-based ventures) might be questioned. Nevertheless, Yin forcefully argues that<br />

“you should try to aim toward analytical generalization in doing case studies…” (Yin, 2003: 33).<br />

Consequently, case studies are used to make generalizations to theory and leave it up to theory-testing<br />

research to conclude whether findings can be generalized to other settings (i.e. other industries, older<br />

companies).<br />

Particular attention was given to minimize retrospective biases, amongst other the capacity of informants<br />

to accurately remember past finance events. First, finance decisions are important decisions made by<br />

entrepreneurs. Biotechnology entrepreneurs are expected to devote considerable time and energy to raising<br />

finance, which should assure that they remember their finance decisions more fully compared to routine<br />

decisions. Second, the selected biotechnology ventures are maximum 5 years old at the time of the first<br />

interviews. It should be easier for entrepreneurs to remember less distant decisions. Third, interviews<br />

focused on facts rather than feelings or believes. Moreover, information on the finance obtained could be<br />

at least partially double-checked with detailed financial accounts data. If entrepreneurs had difficulties in<br />

41


accurately remembering finance events we would have noted important differences between these two<br />

sources of data. This was not the case, however.<br />

1.7. Main Findings<br />

In this section, I present the main findings and contributions of each study individually. The studies have<br />

been organized in such a way that they gradually move from extending existing finance theory, pointing<br />

towards gaps in existing finance theory and developing an alternative framework to study the<br />

entrepreneurial finance process.<br />

1.7.1. Study 1: Incremental Finance Decisions in <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong>:<br />

Pecking Order and Debt Capacity Considerations<br />

The first study focuses on the role of retained earnings, debt finance and new equity finance in high-<br />

growth companies. At least three fundamental insights emerged from this study. First, the majority of<br />

high-growth companies realize high-growth without raising new equity finance. This is remarkable given<br />

the focus in prior research on the role of new equity finance as the most suitable type of finance for high-<br />

growth companies. Almost 45% of the finance events observed relate to high-growth companies that raise<br />

additional debt finance. Moreover, nearly 39% of finance events relate to high-growth companies that<br />

decide to retain their earnings within the business. Retained earnings provide profitable companies with<br />

internal finance which allows them to conduct additional investments without the need to raise outside<br />

finance.<br />

However, high-growth companies are heterogeneous in nature and different types of high-growth<br />

companies are more or less likely to resort to different types of finance. A second fundamental insight is<br />

that profitable high-growth companies prefer to finance investments with retained earnings. Surprisingly,<br />

42


these companies are less likely to raise additional debt and thereby prefer to retain their debt capacity.<br />

While this finding is in line with the pecking order theory, it is contrary to the prediction of the static<br />

trade-off theory, which indicates that especially profitable high-growth companies will raise additional<br />

debt finance to fully take advantage of the interest tax-shield related to debt finance. This latter behavior is<br />

not observed in our sample of high-growth companies.<br />

Third, while new equity issues are less widespread in high-growth companies as initially expected they are<br />

important for a particular subset of companies. Unprofitable high-growth companies with high debt levels,<br />

limited cash flows, high risk of failure and significant investments in intangible assets are more likely to<br />

raise new equity. These findings indicate that high-growth companies are pushed towards new equity<br />

when there are few alternatives, such as internal finance and debt finance. Hence, new equity issues allow<br />

companies to grow beyond their debt capacity. This behavior is in line with the extended pecking order<br />

theory. More significantly, the findings demonstrate that debt capacity is not only determined by leverage,<br />

as implicit in prior studies, but is also determined by the ability to fulfill the fixed debt-related payments<br />

through internally generated cashflows.<br />

1.7.2. Study 2: Seeking Experienced or Legitimate Partners? A Longitudinal Study<br />

on the Impact of Venture Capital Firm Heterogeneity on Portfolio Company<br />

<strong>Growth</strong><br />

A basic assumption in foundational finance theories, such as the pecking order theory, is that investors are<br />

homogenous. In the second study, I demonstrate the impact of investor heterogeneity on subsequent<br />

company growth. Overall, results demonstrate how the initial source of finance has a significant impact on<br />

subsequent company growth and has the potential to create sustainable differences in development<br />

between companies. First, venture capital firms with more prior experience within the industry of their<br />

portfolio companies contribute disproportionately to the growth of these companies. However, the overall<br />

43


experience of venture capital firms does not influence the subsequent growth of portfolio companies.<br />

Results further demonstrate how older venture capital firms and venture capital firms that appear more<br />

often in the business press (i.e. more legitimate investors) also contribute significantly to the growth of<br />

portfolio companies.<br />

Second, investors with more industry deal experience do not select companies with higher intangible<br />

assets on total assets ratios or more patents granted before the venture capital investment compared to<br />

their less experienced peers. More legitimate investors, however, select companies with lower average<br />

intangible assets on total assets ratios and fewer patents granted before the venture capital investment<br />

compared to their less legitimate peers. This indicates that companies backed by more experienced or<br />

more legitimate venture capital investors have lower or similar growth potential before the venture capital<br />

investment, compared to companies that raise initial finance from less experienced or less legitimate<br />

investors. Despite similar or lower growth potential at startup, portfolio companies of more experienced<br />

and more legitimate investors grow at a higher rate. These results hint that more experienced and more<br />

legitimate investors add value after their investment and help companies to realize higher growth rates.<br />

The study also addresses two related shortcomings in organizational growth studies. First, growth studies<br />

typically only look at first and last year sizes and ignore development in between these two time points.<br />

This is problematic as growth is an inherently dynamic measure of change across time. This study<br />

explicitly models the dynamic nature of growth and resorts to modern longitudinal data analysis<br />

techniques for that purpose. Second, researchers typically make rather simplistic assumptions about the<br />

growth pattern across time. It is common to assume that growth occurs as a quantum size leap at one point<br />

in time or that growth is linear. Results indicate that the growth pattern of companies is typically more<br />

complex and that models assuming linear growth trajectories are generally misspecified.<br />

44


1.7.3. Study 3: Early Differences and Persistence in the Entrepreneurial Finance<br />

Process: Evidence from <strong>High</strong>- and Low-<strong>Growth</strong> Biotechnology Startups<br />

In this paper, we study the finance process of both high- and low-growth biotechnology ventures from<br />

startup through development. Three major findings emerged. First, high- and low-growth biotechnology<br />

ventures did not differ systematically in the amount of finance raised at startup. Some high-growth<br />

companies raise even less initial finance compared to similar low-growth companies. More crucial than<br />

the amount of finance raised was the source from which finance was raised. <strong>High</strong>-growth companies<br />

typically raise finance from highly experienced venture capital investors in their first or second finance<br />

round, while low-growth companies typically raise early finance from relatively inexperienced investors.<br />

Second, these initial differences in the finance process between high-and low growth companies are<br />

unlikely caused by differences in growth potential or growth ambition at startup. <strong>High</strong>- and low- growth<br />

biotechnology ventures did not differ systematically in their human capital, alliance capital, technology<br />

development and market orientation at startup. Moreover, even the low-growth companies had high-<br />

growth ambitions and were striving to develop into professional biotechnology ventures. Early differences<br />

in the finance process are more likely the result of the entrepreneurs themselves who engage in a local<br />

search, which pushes them towards one or a few investors, they happen to know.<br />

Third, these early differences in the finance process persist across time. The high-growth companies raise<br />

more follow-on finance from other experienced investors, while the low-growth companies raise less<br />

follow-on finance from other relatively inexperienced investors. This is explained by venture<br />

professionalization, stunted learning and preferences in investor syndication which all facilitate and<br />

constrain the future finance process and thereby may act as isolating mechanisms making it difficult for<br />

entrepreneurs to replicate successful finance strategies from their peers. We demonstrate, for example,<br />

how more experienced investors are more likely to initiate changes in the management team from<br />

45


founding. The increased professionalization within these portfolio companies puts them in a competitive<br />

advantage when raising follow-on finance.<br />

1.8. Overall Academic Contributions<br />

This dissertation lies at the crossroad of both the finance literature and the organizational growth<br />

literature. All studies tackle the interrelatedness between the finance process of unquoted companies and<br />

company growth. In this section, I start with discussing the overall contribution to the finance literature,<br />

before discussing the overall contributions to the organizational growth literature.<br />

1.8.1. Finance Literature<br />

A deep understanding of the entrepreneurial finance process requires multiple theoretical frameworks. I<br />

previously linked key finance theories, such as the pecking order theory, static trade-off theory, the<br />

financial life cycle theory and agency theory to basic process theories, such as teleological, life cycle and<br />

dialectical models. All studies in this dissertation, however, indicate that foundational assumptions in<br />

current finance theories are violated in entrepreneurial ventures or at least that there are key elements<br />

missing in these theories.<br />

While both the static trade-off theory and pecking order theory have provided valuable insights into<br />

financial decision-making, which was further demonstrated in the first study in this dissertation, these<br />

teleological models also have problems in explaining some of the key observations within this<br />

dissertation. First, the third study demonstrated how entrepreneurs are not comprehensive in their search<br />

for finance, despite the critical nature of finance decisions. Rather, it was observed how entrepreneurs<br />

approach only one or a few investors when searching for startup finance and decided to accept finance<br />

from the investor(s) without considering the long-term implications of early finance decisions. Hence, the<br />

46


underlying assumption in teleological models that entrepreneurs are rational and structure their financial<br />

decision-making in such a way that company value is maximized seems inappropriate.<br />

Second, as demonstrated in the first and third study finance decisions are interrelated. The first study<br />

showed how companies that raise a particular type of finance at one point in the past are more likely to<br />

raise the same type of finance in the future. Moreover, the third study demonstrated how entrepreneurs<br />

that raise early finance from experienced investors are more likely to raise experienced finance in the<br />

future, something that is extremely difficult for the entrepreneurs that raised early finance from relatively<br />

inexperienced investors. Overall, contrary to the assumption in teleological models the studies in my<br />

dissertation indicate that it is possible to predict future finance trajectories based on past financing<br />

behavior.<br />

Several findings in this dissertation also fail to fit within life-cycle models, such as the financial growth<br />

cycle theory. Life-cycle models indicate that companies, which have an ambition to IPO, will generally<br />

search for venture capital in order to reach the IPO stage. However, the third study in this dissertation<br />

indicated that despite the ambition of companies to conduct an IPO some companies that raise early<br />

venture capital were unable to go public, while others were successful. Life-cycle models offer no insight<br />

into what is driving these differences in the finance process between companies. Furthermore, some of the<br />

companies that went public in the third study could hardly be defined as old, large or informational<br />

transparent. On the contrary, the third study demonstrated that it is no exception to see biotechnology<br />

ventures that are only five to seven years old, without products on the market and employing less than 50<br />

people to go public. Finally, the life-cycle models offer little to no guidance in understanding why<br />

particular investors are more or less valuable<br />

Several observations are also problematic for the dialectical models, such as agency theories in finance.<br />

The first study indicated that high-growth companies with plenty of internal funds prefer to finance<br />

47


investments internally and not to attract additional debt finance. This is contrary to the prediction of<br />

agency theory, which indicates that exactly these high-growth companies should attract debt finance to<br />

mitigate potential conflicts between managers and shareholders. Moreover, while entrepreneurs and<br />

investors are often portrayed as organizational actors with different (incompatible) goals, in many young<br />

ventures they act as a syndicate and jointly work towards the attainment of organizational goals (see<br />

Graebner and Eisenhardt, 2004). In the second and third study, for example, it is indicated how<br />

experienced investors help their portfolio companies with mobilizing key resources, such as human<br />

capital, financial resources and other (in)tangible assets.<br />

All studies in this dissertation point towards the relevance of an evolutionary theory on the finance<br />

process. Nevertheless, an evolutionary perspective is probably the least developed perspective in current<br />

finance theory. The evolutionary perspective explains change as a recurrent, cumulative and probabilistic<br />

progression of variation, selection and retention among ventures generated by the competition for scarce<br />

resources (Aldrich, 1999; Van de Ven, 2007). The population of new ventures exhibits significant<br />

variation as different types of entrepreneurs are known to start-up and develop ventures with different<br />

strategies, structures and forms (Eckhardt, Shane and Delmar, 2006).<br />

Selection principally occurs through the competition among ventures for scarce resources. It is generally<br />

proposed that the environment selects those ventures that are best suited to the resource base of an<br />

environmental niche (Van de Ven, 2007). Recent studies however demonstrate how the finance process is<br />

essentially a staged selection process with two sequential selection events. First, entrepreneurs select their<br />

ventures as candidates for receiving external finance based on their own assessment of the venture.<br />

Second, investors use objective characteristics of the ventures to select which ventures to finance from the<br />

pool of ventures that entrepreneurs have put forth as candidates for external finance (Eckhardt, Shane, and<br />

Delmar, 2006). The first and third study in this dissertation confirm the critical role played by the<br />

entrepreneur in this double selection process and extend the findings by Eckhardt and colleagues.<br />

48


The first study demonstrates how selection by entrepreneurs is more important than initially indicated by<br />

Eckhardt and colleagues. The latter assume that once entrepreneurs are willing to raise external finance,<br />

they will consider the entire range of external investors and external investors will be able to select from<br />

the entire pool of ventures that are willing to raise external finance. The first study, however, demonstrates<br />

how ventures with sufficient debt capacity are unlikely to consider the use of new equity finance. Hence,<br />

equity investors may only have access to a more limited pool of high potential ventures with limited debt<br />

capacity.<br />

The third study offers even more striking results on the role of entrepreneurs in the entrepreneurial finance<br />

process. Even within the pool of ventures that are willing to raise venture capital finance, not all venture<br />

capital investors will have access to the entire pool of ventures. Entrepreneurs typically approach only one<br />

or a few venture capital investors during the startup phase. Hence, the search for finance is local. They<br />

avoid loose contacts with many potential investors and rather prefer to negotiate with investors known<br />

from prior experiences or investors that are related in one way or another. Overall, this dissertation points<br />

towards the central role of selection by entrepreneurs in the entrepreneurial finance process.<br />

Finally, retention within the evolutionary perspective involves the forces, including inertia and<br />

persistence, which perpetuate and maintain differences between ventures. All studies in this dissertation<br />

demonstrate how early finance decisions have a sustainable impact on subsequent finance decisions and<br />

even company development as a whole. The first study demonstrates how high-growth companies that<br />

previously raised debt finance are more likely to raise debt finance again. Moreover, companies that<br />

previously raised new equity are more likely to raise new equity in the future. However, high-growth<br />

companies that previously raised additional debt finance are not necessarily more likely to raise new<br />

equity in the future. These results at least suggest the existence of path dependent learning: once<br />

entrepreneurs learn how to negotiate and price a particular type of finance this does not necessarily<br />

49


contribute to the acquisition of other types of finance and as a result entrepreneurs are likely to stick to the<br />

finance types previously raised.<br />

The second study demonstrates how initial finance decisions may even have a long-lasting impact on<br />

company development as a whole. Experienced and legitimate investors individually contribute<br />

disproportionately to the growth path of their portfolio companies. The initial investor affects the ability of<br />

entrepreneurial ventures to attract employees and assets for up to five-years after the initial investment.<br />

Hence, relatively small differences in the early finance process or the source from which ventures raise<br />

initial finance, may cause not only persistent, but also increasing differences in the development of<br />

entrepreneurial ventures.<br />

The third study demonstrates how the finance process differs between high- and low-growth companies<br />

from startup through development. Results confirm with the second study as it is shown how ventures that<br />

raise early finance from experienced investors raise more follow-on finance from other experienced<br />

investors. Ventures that raise early finance from inexperienced investors, however, raise limited follow-on<br />

finance typically from other inexperienced investors. Moreover, the third study delves deeper into the<br />

processes that cause this persistence in the finance process. Differences in venture professionalization,<br />

imperfect learning and investor syndication preferences maintain differences in the finance process.<br />

Overall, a core contribution of the dissertation is that it develops an alternative framework to study the<br />

finance process. This evolutionary framework indicates that one way to increase our understanding of how<br />

financial decisions are made may well lie in systematically studying the finance process right from the<br />

start. Moreover, it offers a more behaviorally accurate view of the finance process by demonstrating the<br />

existence of evolutionary trajectories and the central role of local search, investor heterogeneity and prior<br />

finance decisions in the origination and persistence of these trajectories. These ideas stand in stark contrast<br />

50


to traditional corporate finance theories in which neoclassical concepts, such as comprehensive search,<br />

value-maximization, investor homogeneity and optimal contracts hold sway.<br />

1.8.2. <strong>Growth</strong> Literature<br />

The resource-based view (RBV) is one of the key theoretical perspectives on company growth. The RBV<br />

states that building distinctive resources and capabilities will benefit company growth and performance<br />

(Barney, 1991; Wernerfelt, 1984). <strong>Companies</strong> that possess valuable, scarce, unique and imperfectly<br />

mobile resources and capabilities will be able to realize a sustainable competitive advantage and<br />

subsequently generate above-normal returns compared to their competitors (Barney, 1991). Resources and<br />

capabilities that received particular attention in the strategy field include human capital, including<br />

knowledge, skills and experience (Chandler and Hanks, 1998), networks resources (Baum, Calabrese, and<br />

Silverman, 2000) and intellectual capital (Baum and Silverman, 2004).<br />

In the traditional RBV literature financial resources are generally not considered to provide a competitive<br />

advantage (Lee, Lee, and Pennings, 2001). RBV scholars build upon early finance theory, which indicates<br />

that there is enough finance for value-creating projects in perfect financial markets (Modigliani and<br />

Miller, 1958). Moreover, in perfect financial markets investor homogeneity is assumed: the role of<br />

financial intermediaries is restricted to offering finance without active involvement in portfolio<br />

companies. This makes financial resources non-distinctive, not scarce, not unique and perfectly mobile.<br />

Hence, financial resources are not expected to provide ventures with a sustainable competitive advantage.<br />

Financial markets, however, are not perfect and imperfections, such as information asymmetries and<br />

transaction costs, make that the finance process of small ventures is fraught with difficulties (Berger and<br />

Udell, 1998; Cassar, 2004). Finance is scarce and entrepreneurial ventures may find it difficult to attract<br />

sufficient and adequate finance under acceptable conditions (Guiso, 1998), ultimately leading to finance<br />

51


constraints (Himmelberg and Petersen, 1994). Hence, entrepreneurship scholars building upon the RBV<br />

theory indicate that the amount of finance raised at startup is expected to offer startups a competitive<br />

advantage as startups that raise more initial finance are likely to accumulate a larger stock of strategic<br />

resources compared to their finance constrained peers (Lee, Lee, and Pennings, 2001).<br />

A basic premise of the RBV is that more resources and capabilities will increase the efficiency and<br />

effectiveness of firms (Barney, 1991). Having more resources is typically considered to be better than<br />

having fewer resources (see for example Cooper, Gimeno-Gascon and Woo, 1994). Recent research<br />

started to challenge this basic assumption. Katila and Shane (2005) demonstrate how in particular<br />

environments resource constraints promote innovation. Mishina, Pollock, and Porac (2004) demonstrate<br />

how human resource slack enhances short-term market expansion, but slows down short-term product<br />

expansion. The studies in this dissertation have joined the few voices that have expressed reservations<br />

about the view that more resources are necessarily better for venture growth.<br />

The second study in this dissertation, for example, demonstrates how controlling for the amount invested<br />

by venture capital investors the characteristics of these investors heavily influence the subsequent growth<br />

of venture capital backed companies. Hence, two companies raising the same amount of finance may<br />

exhibit a completely different growth pattern depending on the type of investor that offered early finance.<br />

The third study indicates that raising relatively large amounts of startup finance from inexperienced<br />

investors may even constrain the subsequent finance process. Ventures that raise smaller amount of<br />

finance from highly experienced investors, however, may find it easier to raise follow-on finance and<br />

exhibit significantly higher growth rates.<br />

Overall, while entrepreneurship scholars have introduced financial resources as an important resource<br />

within the RBV literature they have almost exclusively focused on the role of the amount of finance. The<br />

implicit assumption in most research is that more financial resources, especially at startup, are better than<br />

52


fewer financial resources. This dissertation encourages researchers to more fully explore the role of<br />

finance beyond the amount of finance on venture growth.<br />

Moreover, I make an important methodological contribution to growth research. While growth is a<br />

fundamentally dynamic measure of change over time, almost no growth research has focused on the<br />

temporal pattern of change within companies (Delmar, Davidsson, and Gartner, 2003; Weinzimmer,<br />

Nystrom, and Freeman, 1998). All studies in this dissertation indicate the inadequacy of prior studies,<br />

which typically assume that growth occurs as a quantum size leap over time or that growth is a linear<br />

process (see Davidsson and Wiklund (2006) for a more comprehensive discussion). First, growth curves<br />

are non-linear and much more complex than often assumed. Second, different companies exhibit very<br />

different growth curves. Hence, while one growth model may be particularly appropriate for one<br />

company, it may be inadequate for another company.<br />

Although the argument that the growth process is a non-linear and complex process may not be entirely<br />

new, few scholars have offered a suitable alternative of how to proceed and solve this drawback. The<br />

second study in this dissertation demonstrates how modern longitudinal techniques, such as Linear Mixed<br />

Models, may be particularly helpful to capture the dynamic nature of change in organizations more fully.<br />

To my knowledge, and supported by the literature overview provided by Davidsson and Wiklund (2006),<br />

this is the first study to use these advanced longitudinal methods to study company growth. Moreover, the<br />

third study demonstrates how qualitative longitudinal case studies may be used to complement<br />

quantitative longitudinal techniques to obtain a better understanding of critical junctures in company<br />

growth. It is my hope this dissertation has set a standard for future empirical research on high-growth<br />

companies.<br />

53


1.9. Structure of the Dissertation<br />

The remainder of this dissertation is organized as follows. Chapter 2 contains the first study: “Incremental<br />

Finance Decisions in <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong>: Pecking Order and Debt Capacity Considerations”. This<br />

study investigates the discrete finance choices of 2,077 high-growth companies for up to eight years. It<br />

extends the traditional pecking order theory and more fully develops the notion of debt capacity. Chapter 3<br />

comprises the second study: “Seeking Experienced or Legitimate Partners? A Longitudinal Study on the<br />

Impact of Venture Capital Firm Heterogeneity on Portfolio Company <strong>Growth</strong>”. Using a longitudinal<br />

dataset of 94 venture capital backed companies, I examine which investors contribute most to company<br />

growth. Thereby this study addresses the foundational assumption of investor homogeneity in traditional<br />

finance theories. Chapter 4 includes the third study: “Early Differences and Persistence in the<br />

Entrepreneurial Finance Process: Evidence from <strong>High</strong>- and Low-<strong>Growth</strong> Biotechnology Startups”. This<br />

longitudinal case study examines the finance process of high- and low-growth biotechnology ventures<br />

from startup through development. In this study, an alternative lens is developed to study the finance<br />

process. Finally, chapter 5 formulates the limitations of this dissertation, avenues for further research and<br />

implications for entrepreneurs, investors and government officials.<br />

References<br />

Acs Z.J., Parsons W. and Tracey S. (2008) “<strong>High</strong> impact firms: gazelles revisited.” An Office of<br />

Advocacy Working Paper, U.S. Small Business Administration.<br />

Aldrich H. (1999) “Organizations Evolving.” Sage Publications.<br />

Autio E. (2005) “Report on high-expectation entrepreneurship.” Global Entrepreneurship Monitor,<br />

www.gemconsortium.org (Last consulted: Jan 2008)<br />

Baeyens K. (2006) “Essays on the determinants and long-term effects of entrepreneurial financing<br />

choices.” Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Ghent University.<br />

54


Barclay M.J., Smith Jr., C.W. and Morellec E. (2006) “On the debt capacity of growth options.” Journal of<br />

Business 79: 37-59.<br />

Barney J. (1991) “Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage.” Journal of Management 17:<br />

99-120.<br />

Baum J.A.C. and Silverman B.S. (2004) “Picking winners or building them? Alliance, intellectual, and<br />

human capital as selection criteria in venture financing and performance of biotechnology startups.”<br />

Journal of Business Venturing 19: 411-436.<br />

Baum J.A.C., Calabrese T. and Silverman B.S. (2000) “Don't go it alone: Alliance network composition<br />

and startups' performance in Canadian biotechnology.” Strategic Management Journal 21: 267-294.<br />

Berger A.N. and Udell G.F. (2002) “Small business credit availability and relationship lending: The<br />

importance of bank organisational structure.” Economic Journal 112: F32-F53.<br />

Berger A.N. and Udell G.F. (1998) “The economics of small business finance: The roles of private equity<br />

and debt markets in the financial growth cycle.” Journal of Banking and Finance 22: 613-673.<br />

Beuselinck C., Deloof M. and Manigart S. (2009) “Private Equity Involvement and Earnings Quality.”<br />

Journal of Business, Finance and Accounting, In Press.<br />

Brealey R.A. and Myers S.C. (2000) “Principles of Corporate Finance.” McGraw-Hill.<br />

Carpenter R.E. and Petersen B.C. (2002a) “Is the growth of small firms constrained by internal finance?”<br />

The Review of Economics and Statistics 84, 298-309.<br />

Carpenter R.E. and Petersen B.C. (2002b) “Capital market imperfections, high-tech investment and new<br />

equity financing.” The Economic Journal 112, 54-72.<br />

Cassar G. (2004) “The financing of business start-ups.” Journal of Business Venturing 19: 261-283.<br />

55


Chandler G.N. and Hanks S.H. (1998) “An examination of the substitutability of founders human and<br />

financial capital in emerging business ventures” Journal of Business Venturing 13: 353-369.<br />

Cooper A.C., Gimeno-Gascon F.J. and Woo C.Y. (1994) “Initial human and financial capital as predictors<br />

of new venture performance.” Journal of Business Venturing 9: 371-395.<br />

Darr E.D., Argote L. and Epple D. (1995) “The Acquisition, Transfer, and Depreciation of Knowledge in<br />

Service Organizations: Productivity in Franchises.” Management Science 41: 1750-1762.<br />

David P., O’Brien J.P. and Yoshikawa T. (2008) “The implications of debt heterogeneity for R&D<br />

investment and firm performance.” Academy of Management Journal, 51: 165-181.<br />

Davidsson P. and Wiklund J. (2006) “Conceptual and empirical challenges in the study of firm growth”<br />

In: P Davidsson, F Delmar, J Wiklund (ed.), Entrepreneurship and the <strong>Growth</strong> of Firms, 39-61, Edward<br />

Elgar Publishing.<br />

Davila A., Foster G. and Gupta M. (2003) “Venture capital financing and the growth of startup firms.”<br />

Journal of Business Venturing 18: 689-708.<br />

Delmar F., Davidsson P. and Gartner W.B. (2003) “Arriving at the high-growth firm.” Journal of Business<br />

Venturing 18: 189-216.<br />

Demirguc-Kunt A. and Levine R. (1999) “Bank-based and market-based financial systems: Cross-country<br />

comparisons.” World Bank Policy Working Paper No. 2143.<br />

Dimov D.P. and De Clercq D. (2006) “Venture capital investment strategy and portfolio failure rate: A<br />

longitudinal study.” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 30: 207-223.<br />

Dimov D.P. and Shepherd D.A. (2005) “Human capital theory and venture capital firms: exploring "home<br />

runs" and "strike outs".” Journal of Business Venturing 20: 1-21.<br />

Eckhardt J.T., Shane S. and Delmar F. (2006) “Multistage selection and the financing of new ventures.”<br />

Management Science 52: 220-232.<br />

56


EVCA (2007) “Annual survey of pan-European private equity and venture capital activity.” Zaventem:<br />

EVCA.<br />

Falconer M., Reid G.C. and Terry N.G. (1995) “Post investment demand for accounting information by<br />

venture capitalists.” Accounting and Business Research 25: 186-196.<br />

Fama E.F. and French K.R. (2005) “<strong>Financing</strong> decisions: Who issues stock?” Journal of Financial<br />

Economics 76: 549-582.<br />

Fitzmaurice G.M., Laird N.M. and Ware J.H. (2004) “Applied Longitudinal Analysis.” John Wiley and<br />

Sons, NJ.<br />

Frank M.Z. and Goyal V.K. (2003) “Testing the pecking order theory of capital structure.” Journal of<br />

Financial Economics 67: 217-248.<br />

Frank M.Z. and Goyal V.K. (2005) “Trade-off and pecking order theories of debt.” In: Handbook of<br />

corporate finance: Empirical corporate finance, ed. Espen Eckbo B., Chapter 7, Elsevier/North-Holland.<br />

GEM (2007) “Global entrepreneurship monitor: 2007 global report.” by N. Bosma, K. Jones, E. Autio and<br />

J. Levie, Babson College, London Business School and Global Entrepreneurship Research Consortium<br />

(GERA).<br />

Gilbert, B.A., McDougall, P.P., and Audretsch, D.B. (2006). New venture growth: A review and<br />

extension. Journal of Management 32: 926-950.<br />

Gompers P.A. (1996) “Grandstanding in the venture capital industry.” Journal of Financial Economics 42:<br />

133-156.<br />

Gompers P.A. (1995) “Optimal investment, monitoring, and the staging of venture capital.” Journal of<br />

Finance 50: 1461-1489.<br />

Graebner M.E. and Eisenhardt K.M. (2004) “The seller’s side of the story: Acquisition as courtship and<br />

governance as syndicate in entrepreneurial firms.” Administrative Science Quarterly 49: 366-403.<br />

57


Gregory B.T., Rutherford M.W., Oswald S. and Gardiner L. (2005) “An Empirical Investigation of the<br />

<strong>Growth</strong> Cycle Theory of Small Firm <strong>Financing</strong>.” Journal of Small Business Management 43: 382-392.<br />

Guiso L. (1998) “<strong>High</strong>-tech firms and credit rationing.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization<br />

35: 39-59.<br />

Hallen B. (2008) “The causes and consequences of the initial network positions of new organizations:<br />

<strong>From</strong> whom do entrepreneurs receive investments?” Administrative Science Quarterly 53: 685-718.<br />

Harris M. and Raviv A. (1991) “The theory of capital structure.” Journal of Finance 46: 297-356.<br />

Helfat C.E. (1994) “Evolutionary trajectories in petroleum firm research-and-development.” Management<br />

Science 40: 1720-1747.<br />

Henrekson M. and Johansson D. (2009) “Gazelles as job contributors – A survey and interpretation of the<br />

evidence.” Small Business Economics, In Press.<br />

Himmelberg C.P. and Petersen B.C. (1994) “Research-and-development and internal finance - A panel<br />

study of small firms in high-tech industries.” Review of Economics and Statistics 76: 38-51.<br />

Hochberg Y.V., Ljungqvist A. and Lu Y. (2007) “Whom you know matters: Venture capital networks and<br />

investment performance.” Journal of Finance 62: 251-301.<br />

Hovakimian A., Opler T. and Titman S. (2001) “The debt-equity choice.” The Journal of Financial and<br />

Quantitative Analysis 36: 1-24.<br />

Hsu D.H. (2007) “Experienced entrepreneurial founders, organizational capital, and venture capital<br />

funding.” Research Policy 36: 722-741.<br />

Hsu D.H. (2004) “What do entrepreneurs pay for venture capital affiliation?” Journal of Finance 59: 1805-<br />

1844.<br />

Jensen M.C. (1986) “Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance and takeovers.” American<br />

Economic Review 76: 323-339.<br />

58


Jensen M.C. and Meckling W. (1976) “Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs, and capital<br />

structure.” Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305-360.<br />

Katila R., Rosenberger J.D. and Eisenhardt K.M. (2008) “Swimming with sharks: Technology ventures,<br />

defense mechanisms and corporate relationships.” Administrative Science Quarterly 53: 295-332.<br />

Katila R. and Shane S. (2005) “When does lack of resources make new firms innovative?” Academy of<br />

Management Journal 48: 814-829.<br />

Kochhar R. and Hitt M.A. (1998) “Research notes and communications linking corporate strategy to<br />

capital structure: diversification strategy, type and source of financing.” Strategic Management Journal 19:<br />

601-610.<br />

Leary M.T. and Roberts M.R. (2005) “Do firms rebalance their capital structure?” Journal of Finance 60:<br />

2575-2619.<br />

Lee C., Lee K. and Pennings J.M. (2001) “Internal capabilities, external networks, and performance: A<br />

study on technology-based ventures.” Strategic Management Journal 22: 615-640.<br />

Lemmon M.L., Roberts M.R. and Zender J.F. (2008) “Back to the Beginning: Persistence and the Cross-<br />

Section of Corporate Capital Structure.” Journal of Finance 63: 1575-1608.<br />

López-Garcia J. and Sogorb-Mira F. (2008) “Testing trade-off and pecking order theories financing<br />

SMEs.” Small Business Economics 31: 117-136.<br />

Manigart S., Vanacker T., Meuleman M. and Sels L. (2009) “Bootstrapping strategies and entrepreneurial<br />

growth: A longitudinal study”. Working Paper.<br />

Manigart S., Baeyens K. and Verschueren I. (2002) “<strong>Financing</strong> and investment interdependencies in<br />

unquoted Belgian companies: the role of venture capital.” National Bank of Belgium: Working Paper 29.<br />

59


Manigart S., De Waele K., Wright M., Robbie K., Desbrières P., Sapienza H. J. and Beekman A. (2000)<br />

“Venture capitalists, investment appraisal and accounting information: A comparative study of the USA,<br />

UK, France, Belgium and Holland.” European Financial Management 6: 389-403.<br />

Maurer I. and Ebers M. (2006) “Dynamics of social capital and their performance implications: Lessons<br />

from biotechnology startups.” Administrative Science Quarterly 51: 262-292.<br />

Michaelas N., Chittenden F. and Poutziouris P. (1999) “Financial policy and capital structure choice in<br />

U.K. SMEs: Empirical evidence from company panel data.” Small Business Economics 12: 113-130.<br />

Mishina Y, Pollock T.G. and Porac J.F. (2004) “Are more resources always better for growth? Resource<br />

stickiness in market and product expansion.” Strategic Management Journal 25: 1179-1197.<br />

Modigliani F. and Miller M.H. (1963) “Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: A correction.”<br />

American Economic Review 53: 433-443.<br />

Modigliani F. and Miller M.H. (1958) “The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of<br />

investment.” American Economic Review 48: 261-297.<br />

Myers S.C. (1984) “The capital structure puzzle.” Journal of Finance 39: 575-592.<br />

Myers S.C. and Majluf N.S. (1984) “Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have<br />

information that investors do not have.” Journal of Financial Economics 13: 187-221.<br />

Myers S.C. (1977) “Determinants of corporate borrowing.” Journal of Financial Economics 5: 147-175.<br />

NBB (2008) “Statistisch overzicht van het Belgisch financieel systeem” (E: Statistical overview Belgian<br />

financial system) http://www.bnb.be/doc/ts/Publications/FSR/StatOver08NL.pdf (Last consulted: Jan<br />

2008).<br />

Nelson R.R. and Winter S.G. (1982) “An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change.” Belknap Press,<br />

Cambridge, MA.<br />

60


O’Regan N., Ghobadian A., Gallear D. (2006) “In search of the drivers of high growth in manufacturing<br />

SMEs.” Technovation 26: 30-41.<br />

Porter M.E. (1980) “Competitive Strategy.” Emerald.<br />

Puri M. and Zarutskie R. (2008) “On the lifecycle dynamics of venture-capital- and non-venture-capital-<br />

financed firms.” US Census Bureau Center for Economic Studies Paper No. CES-WP-08-13.<br />

Rajan R.G. and Zingales L. (1995) “What do we know about capital structure: Some evidence from<br />

international data.” The Journal of Finance 50: 1421-1460.<br />

Sapienza H.J., Manigart S. and Vermeir W. (1996) “Venture capitalists governance and value added in<br />

four countries.” Journal of Business Venturing 11: 439-469.<br />

Shyam-Sunder L. and Myers S.C. (1999) “Testing static tradeoff against pecking order models of capital<br />

structure.” Journal of Financial Economics 21: 219-244.<br />

Smith J.K. and Smith R.L “Entrepreneurial Finance.” John Wiley & Sons, Inc.<br />

Sorensen M. (2007) “How smart is smart money? A two-sided matching model of venture capital.”<br />

Journal of Finance 62: 2725-2762.<br />

Stiglitz J.E. and Weiss A. (1981) “Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information.” American<br />

Economic Review 71: 393-410.<br />

Storey D. (1994) “Understanding the Small Business Sector.” Routledge, London.<br />

Subrahmanyam A. (2007) “Behavioural finance: A review and synthesis.” European Financial<br />

Management 14: 12-29.<br />

Titman S. and Wessels R. (1988) “The determinants of capital structure choice.” Journal of Finance 43, 1-<br />

19.<br />

61


Van Auken H. (2001) “<strong>Financing</strong> small technology-based companies: the relationship between familiarity<br />

with capital and ability to price and negotiate investments.” Journal of Small Business Management 39:<br />

240-258.<br />

Van de Ven A.H. and Poole M.S. (1995) “Explaining development and change in organizations.”<br />

Academy of Management Review 20: 510-540.<br />

Van de Ven A.H. (2007) “Engaged scholarship: A guide for organizational and social research.” Oxford:<br />

Oxford University Press.<br />

van Stel A.J., Carree M.A. and Thurik A.R. (2005) “The Effect of Entrepreneurial Activity on National<br />

Economic <strong>Growth</strong>” Small Business Economics 24: 311-321.<br />

Weinzimmer L.G., Nystrom P.C. and Freeman S.J. (1998) “Measuring organizational growth: Issues,<br />

Consequences and Guidelines.” Journal of Management 24: 235-262.<br />

Wernerfelt B. (1984) “A resource-based view of the firm.” Strategic Management Journal 5: 171-180.<br />

Winborg J. and Landström H. (2001) “Financial bootstrapping in small businesses: Examining small<br />

business managers' resource acquisition behaviors.” Journal of Business Venturing 16: 235-254.<br />

Wiklund J., Patzelt H. and Shepherd D.A. (2009) “Building an integrative model of small business<br />

growth.” Small Business Economics 32: 351-374.<br />

Wiklund J. and Shepherd D. (2003) “Aspiring for, and achieving growth: The moderating role of<br />

resources and opportunities.” Journal of Management Studies 40: 1919-1941.<br />

Yin R.K. (2003) “Case study research: Design and Methods.” Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.<br />

Zaheer S., Albert S. and Zaheer A. (1999) “Time scales and organizational theory.” Academy of<br />

Management Review 24: 725-741.<br />

Zingales L. (2000) “In Search of New Foundations.” Journal of Finance 55: 1623-1653.<br />

62


Chapter 2: Incremental Finance Decisions in <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong><br />

<strong>Companies</strong>: Pecking Order and Debt Capacity Considerations<br />

Tom Vanacker<br />

Ghent University, Department of Accounting and Corporate Finance, Kuiperskaai 55E, 9000 Gent, Belgium;<br />

TomR.Vanacker@UGent.be<br />

Sophie Manigart<br />

Ghent University, Department of Accounting and Corporate Finance, Kuiperskaai 55E, 9000 Gent, Belgium &<br />

Vlerick Leuven Gent Management School, Reep 1, 9000 Gent, Belgium; Sophie.Manigart@UGent.be<br />

A version of this paper is forthcoming in Small Business Economics under the title “Pecking order and debt<br />

capacity considerations for high-growth companies seeking financing”. A preliminary version of this paper is also<br />

published in the 2006 edition of Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research (ISBN 0-910897-27-1). The authors<br />

appreciate helpful comments and suggestions from Rajesh Aggarwal, Gavin Cassar, Wouter De Maeseneire, Miguel<br />

Meuleman, Hans Landström, Harry Sapienza and anonymous referees. We also thank participants from the 2008<br />

Academy of Management Meeting, the 2006 Babson College Entrepreneurship Research Conference and the<br />

Finance Seminars at Ghent University and the Katholieke Universiteit Leuven for their valuable feedback. We are<br />

indebted to Bart Clarysse and Caroline Van Eeckhout for help in constructing the high-growth company database.<br />

The financial support of the Intercollegiate Center for Management Science (I.C.M.) and “Steunpunt<br />

Ondernemingen, Ondernemerschap en Innovatie” is gratefully acknowledged.<br />

63


2.1. Abstract<br />

This study examines incremental finance decisions within high-growth companies. A large longitudinal<br />

dataset, free of survivorship bias, to cover finance events of high-growth companies for up to 8 years is<br />

analyzed. The empirical evidence shows that profitable high-growth companies prefer to finance<br />

investments with retained earnings, even if they have unused debt capacity. External equity is particularly<br />

important for unprofitable high-growth companies with high debt levels, limited cash flows, high risk of<br />

failure and significant investments in intangible assets. These findings are consistent with the extended<br />

pecking order theory controlling for constraints imposed by debt capacity. It suggests that new equity<br />

issues are particularly important to allow high-growth companies to grow beyond their debt capacity.<br />

2.2. Introduction<br />

Although few in number, high-growth companies contribute disproportionately to employment and wealth<br />

creation in an economy (Henrekson and Johansson, 2009; Storey, 1994). This makes organizational<br />

growth a central area of research in entrepreneurship and a major policy concern. Proper financial<br />

management, including raising suitable finance, is one of the key factors shaping high-growth companies<br />

(Maurer and Ebers, 2006). The purpose of this paper is to offer an insight into the discrete finance<br />

decisions taken within high-growth companies. Information asymmetries are thought to be particularly<br />

severe in this setting (Frank and Goyal, 2003), causing a substantial wedge between the costs of internal<br />

and external (debt and equity) finance (Carpenter and Petersen, 2002a). We therefore focus on the pecking<br />

order theory to explain the finance choices of high-growth companies. The pecking order theory predicts<br />

the existence of a finance hierarchy, where business managers avoid the cost of external finance if<br />

possible. As a result, they will first prefer to use internal funds, then debt and finally outside equity as a<br />

last resort to finance investments (Myers, 1984; Myers and Majluf, 1984).<br />

64


The impact of company characteristics on financial decision-making may vary according to the research<br />

setting (Harris and Raviv, 1991). It is therefore important to test financial theories in settings where our<br />

knowledge is limited to determine the generalizability of the theories across different settings (Cassar,<br />

2004). Although high-growth companies are subject to the same market forces as any other company,<br />

studying the finance decisions of high-growth companies is germane for a number of reasons.<br />

First, a recent stream in the finance and growth literature discusses the importance of external equity from<br />

private equity investors, like venture capitalists and business angels in the financing of high-growth<br />

companies (e.g., Baum and Silverman, 2004; Davila, Foster, and Gupta, 2003). Conversely, it is assumed<br />

that bank debt is an unsuitable source of finance, especially for innovative entrepreneurial companies<br />

(e.g., Audretsch and Lehmann, 2002; Carpenter and Petersen, 2002b; Gompers and Lerner, 2001). Most<br />

studies in entrepreneurial finance have therefore focused on private equity finance, ignoring other<br />

potentially important sources of finance such as retained earnings and debt finance (Eckhardt, Shane, and<br />

Delmar, 2006). In contrast to most contributions on the financing of high-growth companies, we do not<br />

limit ourselves to external equity finance, but empirically consider a diverse range of finance choices,<br />

covering internally generated funds, bank finance and new equity finance.<br />

Second, some entrepreneurs may never consider the use of outside debt or equity finance (Howorth,<br />

2001). The fear of loosing control and independence may inhibit entrepreneurs from raising outside<br />

finance and especially outside equity finance (Manigart and Struyf, 1997). Most high-growth companies,<br />

however, have considerable outside finance needs. Internal finance is often insufficient to finance high<br />

growth (Michaelas, Chittenden, and Poutziouris, 1999; Gompers, 1995). Hence, we may expect financial<br />

decision-makers in companies that realized high growth to at least consider a broader range of finance<br />

alternatives compared to those in “Mom and Pop” companies.<br />

65


<strong>Companies</strong> do not continuously raise finance, which implies that finance behavior is characterized by<br />

discrete “jumps” (Jansson, 2002). We therefore study the discrete decision (i.e., whether a particular type<br />

of finance is raised or not) rather than the continuous decision (i.e., how much of a particular type of<br />

finance is raised). Discrete models may be criticized because they use less information compared to<br />

continuous models. However, models of continuous decisions ignore the inherently qualitative aspects of<br />

finance behavior, which may introduce serious misspecification problems (Jansson, 2002). Moreover, by<br />

studying incremental finance decisions, our research addresses a number of drawbacks of previous<br />

research focusing on capital structure.<br />

First, traditional capital structure research does not distinguish between internal finance and external<br />

equity finance. Nevertheless, this distinction may be particularly important in our setting characterized by<br />

high informational asymmetry (de Haan and Hinloopen, 2003). For example, an informationally opaque<br />

company with sufficient internal funds should be more likely to finance investments internally and hence<br />

should be less likely to attract additional external equity finance. Hence, company characteristics may<br />

have a different impact on the probability of using internal finance or external equity finance.<br />

Second, the capital structure of a company is the aggregate of its past finance decisions 4 . Therefore,<br />

capital structure research generally masks information on the timing of the finance acquired. The<br />

characteristics of a business change as it grows, which affects the availability and suitability of different<br />

finance options (Berger and Udell, 1998; Gompers, 1995). For example, as a company grows it may invest<br />

more in tangible assets, which can serve as collateral and make more and cheaper bank finance available.<br />

It is therefore important to take into account the dynamic nature of company characteristics and finance<br />

choices.<br />

4 Rather than focusing on incremental finance decisions, one might also focus on the number of times companies raise a particular<br />

type of finance across time. However, such a count measure is also an aggregate measure and hence is subject to the same<br />

problems as described below for traditional capital structure research.<br />

66


Further, while most studies research finance choices of quoted companies (Fama and French, 2005; Frank<br />

and Goyal, 2003; de Haan and Hinloopen, 2003; Shyam-Sunder and Myers, 1999; Helwege and Liang,<br />

1996), we focus on finance choices of predominantly unquoted companies. Quoted companies have,<br />

however, more finance options due to lower information asymmetries (Berger and Udell, 1998; Harris and<br />

Raviv, 1991). This may lead to different finance strategies for quoted and unquoted companies.<br />

<strong>From</strong> a methodological perspective, the lack of longitudinal studies in entrepreneurship research has been<br />

described as a major weakness (Davidsson and Wiklund, 1999). Our study analyses the incremental<br />

finance decisions of companies over a period of up to 8 years, during which all companies in our sample<br />

have grown extensively. We include start-ups, failed and merged companies, if they have grown<br />

considerably after start-up or before disappearing as independent entities. This implies that our study<br />

limits survivorship bias.<br />

The study starts with a discussion of the theoretical background and development of the hypotheses. Next,<br />

we discuss the data set, where we describe in detail how high-growth companies are identified, how<br />

finance decisions are defined and how independent constructs are measured. Thereafter, we present our<br />

research findings, followed by conclusions and avenues for further research.<br />

2.3. Theory and Hypotheses<br />

In perfect financial markets, companies will always find sufficient and suitable finance for value-creating<br />

investments (Modigliani and Miller, 1958). Hence, finance decisions are irrelevant, and internal finance<br />

and external debt and equity finance are perfect substitutes. Real-world financial markets, however, are<br />

not perfect, and market imperfections cause finance decisions to matter for business development and<br />

company value. Unsuitable finance decisions may have major consequences, such as limited potential for<br />

67


future expansion, financial distress and even company failure (Carpenter and Petersen, 2002b; Michaelas,<br />

Chittenden, and Poutziouris, 1999).<br />

It is well established in the finance literature that market imperfections cause a considerable wedge<br />

between the costs of internal finance and outside finance (see Colombo and Grilli, 2007; Carpenter and<br />

Petersen, 2002a; Berger and Udell, 1998). Asymmetric information is probably one of the most important<br />

reasons why outside funds are thought to be substantially more costly compared to internal funds (Berger<br />

and Udell, 1998). Informational asymmetry entails that while managers have private information about the<br />

value of assets in place and future growth options, outside investors can merely estimate these values.<br />

Faced with the risk of adverse selection, outside investors will demand a ‘‘lemons’’ premium for the<br />

securities offered by companies (Akerlof, 1970). The more risky the securities, the higher the premium<br />

will be, as risk exacerbates the effects of information asymmetry (Myers, 1984). As a result, companies<br />

prefer to finance new investments with retained earnings, which are not subject to asymmetric information<br />

problems. When internal funds are insufficient to meet the finance needs, managers will turn to more<br />

costly outside funds. In this situation companies are expected to issue the safest securities first as these<br />

will suffer less from information asymmetries and hence be subject to lower premiums (Myers, 1984;<br />

Myers and Majluf, 1984). This implies managers will first raise debt finance and only consider new equity<br />

as a last resort. The resulting finance hierarchy is often referred to as a pecking order and is one of the<br />

most influential theories in the finance literature (Frank and Goyal, 2003) 5 .<br />

5 We acknowledge that information asymmetries do not necessarily lead to a finance hierarchy (Halov and Heider, 2004) and the<br />

existence of asymmetric information may not be the only reason why there exists a finance hierarchy. First, transaction costs may<br />

also contribute to the wedge between the costs of internal and outside finance (Myers, 1984). Second, there is a potential cost of<br />

loosing control over the business when resorting to outside finance. These factors may further inhibit business managers from<br />

issuing outside finance and even constrain company growth (Manigart and Struyf, 1997). Finally, the existence of a knowledge<br />

gap from the entrepreneur’s perspective may cause a finance hierarchy, as business owners are typically most familiar with<br />

traditional sources of funding, such as inside finance and debt, but less familiar with capital commonly used to fund growth, such<br />

as venture capital and business angel finance (Van Auken, 2001).<br />

68


In this paper the focus is on the pecking order theory as a framework to understand incremental finance<br />

decisions. Consequently, this research is in line with prior studies, such as Helwege and Liang (1996);<br />

Shyam-Sunder and Myers (1999) and Frank and Goyal (2003), which focus on the finance choices of<br />

quoted American companies. Their direct tests of the two main tenets of the pecking order model—i.e.,<br />

(1) companies prefer to finance new investments with retained earnings and (2) external equity is only<br />

issued as a last resort if outside funds are needed—have offered inconclusive and even contradictory<br />

results, however.<br />

Helwege and Liang (1996), studying a panel of US companies that conducted an IPO in 1983, find that the<br />

probability of obtaining outside funds is not related to a shortfall in internally generated funds, which is in<br />

contrast with predictions of the pecking order theory. However, consistent with pecking order predictions,<br />

they find that companies with a cash surplus avoid outside finance. Finally, companies accessing the<br />

capital market do not follow a pecking order when choosing the type of security to offer. Shyam-Sunder<br />

and Myers (1999), however, draw a different picture of the predictive power of the pecking order model.<br />

Based on a sample of 157 US companies that traded continuously between 1971 and 1989, they conclude<br />

that ‘‘the pecking order theory is an excellent first-order descriptor of corporate finance behavior, at least<br />

in our sample of mature corporations’’ (Shyam-Sunder and Myers, 1999, p. 242). Frank and Goyal (2003)<br />

show that for a more elaborate sample of publicly quoted US companies, the greatest support for the<br />

pecking order theory is found among large firms. Smaller firms, which are expected to be more likely to<br />

be subject to information asymmetries, do not seem to follow a pecking order. Additionally, the pecking<br />

order theory prediction that high-growth companies will end up with high debt ratios because of their<br />

large finance needs is questioned (Fama and French, 2005). Barclay et al. (2006) demonstrate that high-<br />

growth companies consistently use less debt finance as they grow. These findings have led some scholar<br />

to conclude that ‘‘the pecking order theory works well when it should not and not so well when it should’’<br />

(Heider 2003, p. 3).<br />

69


Despite contradictory empirical findings, the motivation behind our choice of the pecking order as the<br />

main theoretical framework is clear-cut. Particularly, small and high-growth companies are subject to<br />

significant information asymmetries (Frank and Goyal, 2003; Carpenter and Petersen, 2002a), causing a<br />

substantial wedge between the costs of internal and external finance (Carpenter and Petersen, 2002a).<br />

Consequently, based on theoretical grounds one would expect the pecking order theory to be particularly<br />

useful to explain financing behavior in our sample of mostly unquoted high-growth companies. As a<br />

result, we expect these firms to prefer internally generated funds to external funds if possible. This<br />

suggests that in profitable companies internally generated funds will gradually replace outside debt and<br />

equity finance. This leads to our first hypothesis:<br />

Hypothesis 1: <strong>High</strong>-growth companies that have more internal funds will be less likely to raise additional<br />

external debt or equity finance.<br />

Our first hypothesis is non-trivial in light of previous contradictory empirical evidence. Furthermore, the<br />

main competing framework to the pecking order theory, the static trade-off theory, predicts a different<br />

behavior. The static trade-off theory states companies will trade off the benefits of debt, especially tax and<br />

agency benefits, against the cost of debt, especially bankruptcy and agency costs of debt (Modigliani and<br />

Miller, 1963; Titman, 1984; Myers, 1977). The static trade-off theory predicts companies will make<br />

incremental finance decisions in such a way that an optimal capital structure is obtained. This optimal<br />

capital structure is obtained when the marginal benefit of an additional dollar amount of debt finance<br />

equals its marginal cost. Following the static trade-off theory, we would expect companies with a lot of<br />

internal funds to rebalance their capital structure and issue additional outside debt finance. First,<br />

companies with plenty of internal funds or financial slack are less likely to fail, reducing the bankruptcy<br />

costs associated with debt finance. Financial slack buffers companies from shocks in the environment and<br />

allows them to survive during turbulent times (Sharfman, Wolf, Chase, and Tansik, 1988). Further,<br />

additional outside debt finance may mitigate potential agency conflicts resulting from abundant internal<br />

70


funds (Jensen, 1986). Hence, the static trade-off theory indicates that internal finance and outside debt<br />

finance are complements rather than substitutes. Profitable companies that built up internal equity capital<br />

in the past are predicted to be particularly likely to attract additional debt finance in the future.<br />

When internal funds are insufficient to finance company growth, the question whether to raise additional<br />

debt or new equity becomes critical. Bank finance is an important source of finance for young and<br />

growing companies in Continental Europe and is expected to be widely available (Manigart and<br />

Meuleman, 2004). Bank debt is considered to be the cheapest source of outside finance, as banks only<br />

require an interest on their loan and do not expect to share in the value creation, as equity investors do.<br />

Banks only have a limited return on their investment (i.e., interest margin) and as a result are expected to<br />

focus primarily on low-risk projects in companies with sufficient cash flow to fulfill the fixed debt-related<br />

payments (Carey, Post, and Sharpe, 1998). Furthermore, banks typically require collateral and may<br />

include restrictive debt covenants in the debt contract to reduce adverse selection and moral hazard<br />

problems (Berger and Udell, 1998). However, as leverage increases, the probability of financial distress<br />

and moral hazard problems increase, and hence the marginal cost of debt finance may increase rapidly<br />

(Carpenter and Petersen, 2002b).<br />

At a certain point the cost of additional debt may be excessively high or debt finance may simply be<br />

unavailable, and company owners may turn to new equity as a last resort. Contrary to additional financial<br />

debt, new equity issues do not increase the probability of failure, do not accentuate moral hazard problems<br />

and do not require collateral (Carpenter and Petersen, 2002b). Hence, new equity issues may allow high-<br />

growth companies with limited debt capacity to conduct additional value-creating investments, which<br />

would not be possible, when the company solely relied on debt finance. However, the cost of issuing new<br />

equity is thought to be significant, especially for small and unquoted companies. Venture capital investors,<br />

for example, require an average yearly return of more than 20% for later stage investments and as much as<br />

55% for early stage investments (Sapienza, Manigart, and Vermeir, 1996). A higher expected return<br />

71


lowers company value and in turn increases the equity stake required by the outside investor. This<br />

explains why managers will avoid new equity issues whenever possible.<br />

A particularly important problem for the traditional pecking order theory, however, is exactly the wide use<br />

of outside equity finance despite its high cost (Fama and French, 2005; Frank and Goyal, 2005).<br />

Significant external equity issues by high-growth companies are considered to refute the pecking order<br />

theory (Frank and Goyal, 2003). The extensive use of new equity by especially small and high-growth<br />

companies may, however, be explained in a pecking order framework by taking into account debt<br />

capacity. Myers (1977) defines debt capacity as the point at which additional debt issues would reduce the<br />

total market value of a firm’s debt. Lemmon and Zender (2004) are among the first to empirically examine<br />

the impact of debt capacity considerations on finance decisions in a pecking order framework. Using a<br />

sample similar to Frank and Goyal (2003), they show that the pecking order theory is a good predictor of<br />

financing behavior for a broad cross-section of firms when controlling for debt capacity. This is referred to<br />

as the extended pecking order theory (Lemmon and Zender, 2004). Furthermore, they show that high-<br />

growth companies have more restrictive debt capacity constraints and hence have lower debt capacity.<br />

Consequently, exactly high-growth companies will reach their debt capacity quickly and will issue outside<br />

equity as a last resort. Significant outside equity issues by high-growth companies are hence not<br />

necessarily in contradiction with the pecking order theory when taking debt capacity considerations into<br />

account.<br />

Current studies have defined debt capacity as the point at which companies reach ‘‘sufficiently high debt<br />

ratios’’ that curtail further debt issues or make them prohibitively expensive (Fama and French, 2005;<br />

Shyam-Sunder and Myers, 1999). Fama and French (2005) interpret their finding that more than half of<br />

small, unprofitable high-growth companies issue outside equity as invalidating the extended pecking order<br />

theory. They argue that these firms start with low levels of leverage, hence they should be able to raise<br />

cheaper additional debt (Fama and French, 2005). This conclusion reflects a more limited view on debt<br />

72


capacity than the traditional notion of debt capacity as coined by Myers (1977), which also takes into<br />

account the possibility of the company repaying the debt from operational cash flows. Banks are ‘‘cash<br />

flow lenders,’’ implying that they emphasize firms’ cash flows as the ultimate source of interest and<br />

principal repayment, rather than ‘‘asset lenders’’ which emphasize collateral (Carey, Post, and Sharpe,<br />

1998).<br />

Undoubtedly ‘‘sufficiently high debt ratios’’ may make it more difficult to get additional debt finance.<br />

<strong>Companies</strong> with high leverage have a higher financial risk, implying less protection for debt holders,<br />

because of the smaller equity buffer on which debt holders can rely in case of liquidation (Ooghe and Van<br />

Wymeersch, 2003). However, contrary to the narrow definition of debt capacity, even companies with low<br />

leverage may have no or very limited debt capacity. Take, for example, privately held biotechnology<br />

companies. These companies typically require large amounts of outside finance (Corolleur, Carrere, and<br />

Mangematin, 2004). Despite this, European biotechnology companies exhibit very low leverage ratios<br />

(EuropaBio, 2006). However, typically no or insufficient cashflows are available (Corolleur, Carrere, and<br />

Mangematin, 2004). This implies that while debt levels are low, these companies have no capacity to<br />

attract financial debt because of their inability to carry out debt-related payments.<br />

Accumulating fixed commitments, which increase liquidity risk (i.e., a company’s inability to carry out<br />

the fixed payments causing financial distress), will at a certain point reduce the total value of debt. As a<br />

result, firms with low levels of cashflows may find that issuing additional debt is not advantageous<br />

compared to outside equity or is even impossible to raise (Helwege and Liang, 1996). Therefore, they will<br />

move further down the pecking order to outside equity. Hence, we argue that debt capacity is not only<br />

determined by a firm’s leverage, but also by its capacity to carry out the fixed debt-related payments.<br />

<strong>High</strong>-growth companies with limited debt capacity are expected to issue external equity as a last resort<br />

(Lemmon and Zender, 2004). This leads to our second hypothesis:<br />

73


Hypothesis 2: <strong>High</strong>-growth companies with high leverage and/or limited cash flows will be more likely to<br />

raise additional external equity finance instead of additional external debt finance.<br />

In the above, we argue that companies will only issue new equity as a last resort (i.e., when internal<br />

finance and debt finance are unavailable). This might give a negative connotation to new equity issues.<br />

However, it is important to note that the pecking order theory indicates that raising new equity may be in<br />

the best interest of existing owners if growth opportunities are high. By raising new equity companies may<br />

invest in value-creating investment projects for which it is difficult to raise debt finance, such as additional<br />

research and development projects, which would not materialize without raising new equity finance.<br />

Hence, having no access to new equity finance would constrain future company growth.<br />

2.4. Method and Descriptive Statistics<br />

The empirical evidence of this paper is based on detailed yearly financial statement data of all Belgian<br />

companies, as provided in the BEL-FIRST database (Bureau Van Dijk). All Belgian limited liability<br />

companies, irrespective of their size, have to file detailed financial statement information. For each year<br />

between 1997 and 2004, we select all firms that are (1) active in Flanders and Brussels (the two most<br />

developed regions in Belgium comprising the majority of economic activity) and (2) employ at least ten<br />

people (in order to exclude micro-companies and companies founded for non-economic purposes). Both<br />

independent companies and companies that belong to a company group structure are included.<br />

Additionally, both companies established within the time frame of this study and firms disappearing from<br />

the database, because they failed or were taken over, are included. Thereby, we limit survivorship bias in<br />

our study, which is an important advantage compared to the majority of other finance studies (see Cassar,<br />

2004). This results in a data set of 32,754 companies active over at least some period during the time<br />

frame of our study.<br />

74


Belgium has a bank-based financial system. The most important source of external finance within firms is<br />

bank debt. Issuing public debt is a rare event for Belgian companies. Furthermore, only a minority of<br />

Belgian companies are quoted on the stock exchange. The private equity market, however, is quite well<br />

developed compared to some other Continental European countries (Reynolds et al., 2000).<br />

In what follows, we first discuss how high-growth companies are identified. Second, we develop the<br />

measures of finance events. Finally, we discuss the independent variables.<br />

2.4.1. Identifying <strong>High</strong>-<strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong><br />

Prior organizational growth research is often criticized because it does not take into account the<br />

multidimensional nature of growth. The classification of a company as a high-growth company depends<br />

on the growth concept and growth formula used (Delmar, Davidsson, and Gartner, 2003). We explicitly<br />

take into account the multidimensional nature of growth. First, we use different growth indicators, such as<br />

sales, employees, total assets, cash flow and added value. The use of different concepts gives richer<br />

information and is therefore better than the use of a single indicator (Weinzimmer, Nystrom, and Freeman,<br />

1998). Second, we use both absolute and relative growth measures following Davidsson and Wiklund<br />

(1999). While absolute growth measures tend to favor larger companies, relative growth measures tend to<br />

favor smaller companies. Although compound measures have been developed to tackle this problem (e.g.,<br />

the Birch index), these measures lack a conceptual basis (Davidsson and Wiklund, 1999).<br />

We calculated the growth of all companies in our database using five growth indicators (sales, employees,<br />

total assets, cash flow and added value) and two growth formulas (absolute and relative). <strong>Growth</strong> in each<br />

year is measured as a moving average of the growth rate in the previous three years. <strong>From</strong> each of ten<br />

yearly rankings (two growth formulas x five growth indicators), we selected the growth champions, i.e.,<br />

the first percentile of growers. In order to be selected in our sample as a high-growth company, a company<br />

75


had to be for at least two years among the first percentile 6 . More specifically, this means that a company<br />

has to be minimum twice among the top 250 companies in Flanders and Brussels in one of ten growth<br />

dimensions. 2,077 companies were selected in this way. Only 57 of the selected companies are quoted on<br />

a stock exchange, the other high-growth companies are privately held companies.<br />

The yearly absolute growth in added value is at least €5,256,179 for added value growers, the cash flow at<br />

least €4,067,419 for cash flow growers, the total assets at least €52,269,000 for total asset growers, the<br />

revenues at least €21,619,000 for revenue growers and 46 employees for employment growers. The cut off<br />

yearly relative growth rate lies between 317% (for revenue growers) and 2406% (for added value<br />

growers). These descriptive statistics clearly indicate that only top growth companies are considered.<br />

Similar growth rates have been reported by Markman and Gartner (2002) when studying the link between<br />

extraordinary growth and profitability in Inc. 500 high-growth companies.<br />

Some descriptive statistics on the sample of high-growth companies are interesting in their own respect. In<br />

line with the results of Delmar, Davidsson and Garter (2003) the growth concept and growth formula have<br />

a profound impact on the companies selected as high-growth companies. The overlap between the<br />

different types of high-growth companies is low, especially for relative growth. The highest overlap<br />

between the different samples of high-growth companies is between absolute growth in added value and<br />

absolute growth in revenues, which is 54%. The average age of the high-growth companies in the sample<br />

is 22 years. However, there is a remarkable difference between absolute growers and relative growers with<br />

the average age being respectively 28 and 16 years. Although the majority (71%) of high-growth<br />

companies are in existence over the entire time frame of the study, 22% of the companies are founded in<br />

1997 or later and 7% of the companies disappear due to company failure or a takeover.<br />

6 We use a three-year moving average of the growth rate and require a company to be at least twice among the first percentile of<br />

companies in order to exclude erratic or one-shot growth companies. The stability of the group of high-growth companies is an<br />

interesting question in its own respect. Few companies are able to report high-growth rates over a long period of time, especially<br />

when using relative growth rates. More details on the stability of the sample of high-growth companies may be found in Van<br />

Eeckhout et al. (2006).<br />

76


Table 2.1 shows the sector distribution of the high-growth companies. It is noteworthy that high-growth<br />

companies are active in all sectors of the economy, with a high prevalence in the transportation and<br />

communication sector (31.49%), the building and civil engineering industry (23.83%) and in the<br />

distributive trades, hotels, catering and repairs sector (13.34%). Moreover, around 80% of the high-growth<br />

companies are active in industries that are generally considered low-tech. This finding confirms prior<br />

growth research, which indicates that high-growth companies are not overrepresented in high-tech<br />

industries, but rather exist in all industries and if anything appear overrepresented in services (Henrekson<br />

and Johansson, 2009).<br />

TABLE 2.1<br />

Distribution of Sample Firms by Industry<br />

0 Agriculture, hunting, forestry and fishing 14 0.67%<br />

1 Energy and water 103 4.96%<br />

2<br />

Extraction and processing of non-energy producing minerals and<br />

derived products; chemical industry<br />

225 10.83%<br />

3 Metal manufacture; mechanical and instrument engineering 87 4.19%<br />

4 Other manufacturing industries 134 6.45%<br />

5<br />

Building and civil engineering 495<br />

23.83%<br />

6 Distributive trades, hotels, catering, repairs 277 13.34%<br />

7 Transport and communication 654 31.49%<br />

8 Banking and finance, insurance, business services, renting 27 1.30%<br />

9 Other services 61 2.94%<br />

TOTAL 2077<br />

100.00%<br />

77


2.4.2. Dependent Variables: Finance Events<br />

The dependent incremental finance event variables are constructed following Marsh (1982). A first way to<br />

finance projects is with retained earnings. Retained earnings represent inside equity created by profitable<br />

companies (Frank and Goyal, 2005). When the retained earnings within a year exceed 5% of total assets,<br />

we define this as an internal finance event. Second, companies are coded as using financial debt if there is<br />

a yearly net increase of outstanding financial debt (both short-term and long-term), which exceeds 5% of<br />

total assets. Finally, companies are coded as using new equity finance, when there is a net increase in<br />

external equity of at least 5% of total assets 7 . The threshold value of 5% is well established in the<br />

incremental finance literature and is used first to assure that the focus of the analyses is on relatively<br />

substantial finance events and second to guarantee consistency with previous studies (Hovakimian, Opler<br />

and Titman, 2001; de Haan and Hinloopen, 2003).<br />

<strong>High</strong>-growth companies may use different types of finance together. As a result, finance events are not<br />

mutually exclusive. When companies raise multiple types of finance together, even if the relative share of<br />

debt and equity remains unchanged, these finance events are included in the analyses. Furthermore, all<br />

finance events are measured on a yearly basis. Consequently, multiple finance events in one year are<br />

coded as one large issue. This is appropriate as firms actively rebalance their capital structure on average<br />

about once a year (Leary and Roberts, 2004). Finally, this approach makes that we study finance decisions<br />

conditional upon companies’ finance needs, which is conventional in related studies (see for example, de<br />

Haan and Hinloopen, 2003, pp. 667).<br />

The descriptive statistics of the dependent discrete finance events are reported in Table 2.2. Each year,<br />

more than half of the high-growth companies resort to internal finance or raise external finance. Over the<br />

eight year frame of our study, 92% of the companies have at least one finance event and the median<br />

7 Unfortunately, the identity of the finance provider(s) is not available. Hence, we are unable to make a distinction between<br />

investors that previously offered finance to the company and new investors.<br />

78


number of finance events equals 4. This suggests that being able to attract sufficient financial resources<br />

and high growth are interrelated.<br />

Table 2.2 shows that financial debt is the most common financing route, accounting for almost 45% of the<br />

finance events. This is interesting in light of prior studies claiming that high-growth companies seem to<br />

consistently use less debt finance across time (Barclay et al., 2006). Internal finance is the second most<br />

frequently used way to finance growth: nearly 39% of the finance events relate to the decision to retain<br />

earnings. Despite the assumption of prior research that rapidly growing companies have insufficient<br />

internal funds to finance their growth internally (Michaelas, Chittenden, and Poutziouris, 1999; Gompers,<br />

1995), it remains the second most common financing route. In the later years of our study (2003-2004),<br />

internal funds are even the most prevalent financing route. Finally, only 16% of the finance events relate<br />

to raising external equity finance. However, nearly 44% of the companies in our sample raise at least once<br />

outside equity finance. Consistent with Ou and Haynes (2006), who study the acquisition of external<br />

equity capital by small companies, the descriptive statistics indicate that even for high-growth companies<br />

the current emphasis on external equity finance in the literature may be somewhat overstated. Although<br />

external equity is undeniably an important source of finance, almost 85% of the finance events relate to<br />

retained earnings and financial debt.<br />

Table 2.2 further shows the average size of the finance events (excluding the cases without a finance<br />

event). The median size of internal finance events equals 15% of total assets, while the median debt issue<br />

equals 14% of total assets. Consistent with previous research (Colombo and Grilli, 2007; Helwege and<br />

Liang, 1996), the largest median issue size is for external equity issues with 21% of total assets. This<br />

shows that although new equity is issued less often than debt, the average equity issue size is larger than<br />

that of debt issues or internal funds.<br />

79


Percentage of<br />

firms using:<br />

TABLE 2.2<br />

Sample Split according to Finance Type a<br />

Internal finance Financial debt External Equity<br />

% of firms in<br />

sample with new<br />

issue:<br />

Number of<br />

finance events<br />

Number of firms in<br />

sample:<br />

1997 25.17% 33.59% 11.66% 55.03% 1021 1450<br />

1998 25.61% 30.35% 11.59% 53.71% 1055 1562<br />

1999 26.09% 32.57% 12.60% 56.21% 1188 1667<br />

2000 25.33% 35.98% 12.36% 56.93% 1329 1804<br />

2001 24.44% 31.48% 12.86% 55.50% 1289 1874<br />

2002 24.27% 27.35% 10.04% 51.51% 1161 1883<br />

2003 26.43% 24.67% 9.20% 50.83% 1127 1869<br />

2004 30.01% 21.42% 6.61% 49.84% 913 1573<br />

Total number of<br />

finance events:<br />

% of finance<br />

events:<br />

3538 4056 1489 9083<br />

38.95% 44.66% 16.39% 100.00%<br />

Issue size/Total<br />

assets (%):<br />

Median 14.70% 14.42% 21.20%<br />

a Note that companies may issue several types of finance within one year.<br />

2.4.3. Independent Variables<br />

All independent variables are lagged one year in order to avoid problems of reverse causality. Where<br />

appropriate, independent variables are scaled by total assets in order to standardize the variables and make<br />

them comparable for companies with a different size. Furthermore, all the independent variables are<br />

calculated using book values 8 . Below we define the independent and control variables.<br />

As proxies for the amount of internal finance available within the venture, we use its profitability ratio,<br />

measured as earnings on total assets and the amount of cash and marketable securities on total assets.<br />

Finally, the pay-out ratio, measured as dividends on total assets, indicates lower internal finance. Debt<br />

capacity is proxied by leverage and cash flow. Leverage is operationalized as a company’s debt ratio<br />

(financial debt on total assets). Furthermore, we include a variable indicating if debt is greater than total<br />

assets (negative stockholders’ equity dummy variable). Cash flow is operationalized by using the cash<br />

8 We are mainly studying unquoted high-growth companies and hence market values are generally unavailable.<br />

80


flow ratio (i.e. internally generated cash flow on total assets), indicating a company’s ability to support<br />

additional debt related payments.<br />

We additionally include a number of control variables related to the static trade-off theory, which is the<br />

main competing theoretical framework to the pecking order theory (Frank and Goyal, 2005). It is<br />

interesting to include these variables in the model and see if the pecking order variables hold in a nested<br />

model including the variables proposed by the static trade-off theory (Frank and Goyal, 2003). Under the<br />

static trade-off theory tax shields, financial distress and agency costs are expected to determine finance<br />

decisions. We include two types of tax shields, debt tax shields (interests on total assets) and non-debt tax<br />

shields (depreciations on total assets). The expected cost of financial distress depends on the probability<br />

of trouble and the value lost if trouble comes (Myers, 1984). Our proxy for the probability of financial<br />

distress is the OJD-score, is similar to the Altman Z-statistic, but adapted to the Belgian context (Ooghe<br />

and Van Wymeersch, 2003). A lower score indicates a higher risk of failure. Furthermore, we use asset<br />

structure operationalized as the ratio of property, plant and equipment to total assets, as a proxy for the<br />

cost of financial distress. A lower ratio indicates a higher cost of financial distress. Agency costs are<br />

particularly prevalent in a setting characterized by considerable future growth options. Firms generally<br />

engage in research and development to generate growth options (Titman and Wessels, 1988).<br />

Consequently, we use the ratio of intangible assets on total assets to operationalize growth potential and<br />

the corresponding agency costs.<br />

Other general control variables, including organizational size (i.e., natural logarithm of total assets),<br />

previous debt finance (i.e., dummy variable equal to 1 if the venture acquired debt financing in the<br />

previous year, zero otherwise) and previous external equity finance (i.e., dummy variable equal to 1 if the<br />

venture acquired external equity in the previous year, zero otherwise) are included in the model.<br />

Furthermore, we included year and industry dummy variables in the analysis to control for time and<br />

industry effects. Table 2.3 reports the correlations for the continuous independent and control variables.<br />

81


Noteworthy is the high correlation between the probability of financial distress (OJD-score) and the debt<br />

ratio, which equals -0.61. All other correlations are sufficiently low and do not indicate potential<br />

multicollinearity problems.<br />

Internal finance:<br />

Profitability ratiot-1<br />

Cash and cash equivalentst-1<br />

Pay-out ratio t-1<br />

Debt capacity:<br />

Debt ratio t-1<br />

Cash flow ratio t-1<br />

Control variables:<br />

Tax shields<br />

Debt tax shields t-1<br />

Non-Debt tax shields t-1<br />

Financial distress<br />

Probability of distress (OJD) t-1<br />

Cost of distress (Asset structure) t-1<br />

Agency costs<br />

Intangible assets t-1<br />

(1) 1.000<br />

TABLE 2.3<br />

Correlation Matrix a<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11)<br />

(2) -0.055 1.000<br />

(3) 0.203 0.019 1.000<br />

(4) -0.364 -0.017 -0.065 1.000<br />

(5) 0.161 0.102 0.030 0.119 1.000<br />

(6) -0.055 -0.162 -0.039 0.331 -0.083 1.000<br />

(7) -0.138 0.028 -0.053 0.192 0.291 0.062 1.000<br />

(8) 0.300 0.012 0.046 -0.609 0.042 -0.308 -0.027 1.000<br />

(9) -0.082 -0.087 -0.080 0.164 0.066 0.071 0.497 -0.004 1.000<br />

(10) -0.126 0.005 -0.033 0.068 0.015 -0.013 0.262 -0.026 -0.006 1.000<br />

Size t-1 (11) 0.135 -0.369 0.117 -0.157 -0.285 0.298 -0.209 0.125 -0.140 -0.054 1.000<br />

a Bold: Correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed).<br />

2.5. Empirical Results<br />

2.5.1. Independent Variables by Issue Type<br />

Table 2.4 shows the independent and control variables by issue type. While the average earnings on total<br />

asset ratio is positive for companies resorting to internal finance, companies issuing external debt and<br />

equity finance have on average negative earnings. This suggests that positive earnings replace bank loans<br />

and new equity issues. The median amount of cash and cash equivalents on total assets is quite similar for<br />

the different types of issuers. <strong>Companies</strong> issuing external finance have on average lower payout ratios<br />

than companies resorting to internal finance.<br />

82


<strong>Companies</strong> issuing external finance have higher debt ratios compared to companies resorting to internal<br />

finance. Particularly noteworthy is that more than 20% of external equity issues are related to companies<br />

that had a negative book value of shareholders’ equity in the previous year 9 . This is a considerable group<br />

of companies which previous studies in capital structure research sometimes explicitly remove from their<br />

dataset (e.g. Heyman, Deloof, and Ooghe, 2008; Sogorb-Mira, 2005), leading to potentially biased results.<br />

Furthermore, external equity issuers have much lower internally generated cash flow ratios compared to<br />

debt issuers. These findings suggest that companies issuing new equity are closer to their debt capacity.<br />

Some interesting observations occur with respect to the control variables related to financial distress and<br />

intangible assets. <strong>Companies</strong> issuing external equity have a higher risk of failure compared to internal<br />

finance users and debt issuers. Furthermore, on average external equity issuers hold less tangible assets,<br />

which can serve as collateral, compared to debt issuers. Finally, companies issuing external equity finance<br />

have the highest average ratio of intangible assets on total assets.<br />

2.5.2. Multivariate Analyses<br />

We start by addressing the question when high-growth companies utilize outside debt or equity finance.<br />

For this purpose, we report logistic regression models for the choice between internal finance and external<br />

finance (Table 2.5). Next, we address the use of external equity and report logistic regression models<br />

analyzing the characteristics of companies utilizing external equity (Table 2.6). All reported models are<br />

significant. The McFadden’s pseudo R² in the full models equal respectively 0.18 (Table 2.5-M5) and 0.12<br />

(Table 2.6-M5).<br />

9 In the entire sample less than 9% of all finance events are related to companies that have negative shareholders’ equity in the<br />

previous year.<br />

83


Internal finance:<br />

TABLE 2.4<br />

Variables by Issue Type<br />

Internal Finance (IF) Financial debt (FD) External equity (EE) Significance a<br />

Median Mean S.D. Median Mean S.D. Median Mean S.D. IF-FD IF-EE FD-EE<br />

(EARNINGS/TOTAL ASSETS)t-1 0.0412 0.0640 0.1463 0.0080 -0.0170 0.2164 0.0000 -0.0891 0.3142 ** ** **<br />

(CASH AND EQUIVALENTS/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1 0.0156 0.0698 0.1349 0.0143 0.0556 0.1198 0.0141 0.0767 0.1613 ** **<br />

(DIVIDENDS/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1 0.0000 0.0212 0.0614 0.0000 0.0111 0.0402 0.0000 0.0089 0.0332 ** ** †<br />

Debt capacity:<br />

(FINANCIAL DEBT/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1 0.5982 0.5532 0.3130 0.8003 0.7863 0.5664 0.7207 0.7184 0.6466 ** ** **<br />

(Negative shareholders’ equity) t-1 0.0124 0.1152 0.2058 ** ** **<br />

(INTERNALLY GENERATED CASH<br />

FLOW/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1 0.2835 0.5275 0.7604 0.2202 0.4305 0.6722 0.0871 0.2723 0.5996 ** ** **<br />

Control variables:<br />

Tax Shields<br />

(INTERESTS/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1 0.0051 0.0109 0.0147 0.0091 0.0155 0.0205 0.0046 0.0135 0.0218 ** ** **<br />

(DEPRECIATIONS/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1 0.0184 0.0411 0.0569 0.0284 0.0512 0.0667 0.0160 0.0437 0.0661 ** **<br />

Financial Distress<br />

(OJD-SCORE) t-1 1.0200 1.2190 1.5480 0.3500 -0.1130 6.5410 0.2700 -0.7990 10.8810 ** ** *<br />

(PROPERTY, PLANT AND EQUIPMENT/TOTAL<br />

ASSETS) t-1 0.0494 0.1369 0.1999 0.1034 0.2223 0.2728 0.0450 0.1832 0.2669 ** ** **<br />

Agency costs<br />

(INTANGIBLE ASSETS/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1 0.0000 0.0147 0.0582 0.0000 0.0195 0.0710 0.0000 0.0277 0.0845 ** ** **<br />

Ln(TOTAL ASSETS) t-1 10.6050 10.2060 2.7680 9.9554 9.7008 2.8614 9.9554 9.5220 3.2184 ** ** †<br />

Previous debt financing 0.2340 0.4530 0.3509 ** ** **<br />

Previous external equity financing 0.0707 0.1384 0.2928 ** ** **<br />

a Where † indicates significant at 0.1, * significant at 0.05 and ** significant at 0.01 (t-tests). Non-parametric Mann-Whitney tests offer similar results, except that the<br />

differences in median between cash and cash equivalents on total assets and dividends on total assets are not significantly different between the different finance issuers.


We correct for the dependence among finance outcomes for the same company. Consequently, we take<br />

into account that the observations are not independent within companies. This affects the estimated<br />

standard errors and variance-covariance matrix of the estimates (VCE). The Huber-White-Sandwich<br />

estimator of variance is used in order to obtain robust variance estimates.<br />

Table 2.5 reports logistic regression models with internal finance as the base outcome. We report several<br />

model specifications, starting with control variables (M1), and gradually adding internal finance variables<br />

(M2), debt capacity variables (M3), static trade-off variables excluding the probability of financial distress<br />

(i.e. OJD-score) (M4) and the probability of financial distress (M5). The probability of financial distress is<br />

included separately, because doing so reduces the sample size significantly. This is explained by the<br />

presence of missing data needed to calculate this measure.<br />

Supporting hypothesis 1, all model specifications indicate that more profitable companies prefer to finance<br />

investments internally 10 . This evidence suggests the existence of a possible substitution between internal<br />

and outside finance. This finding is consistent with prior capital structure research on privately held<br />

companies reporting a negative relationship between profitability and the debt ratio (for such evidence see<br />

Heyman, Deloof, and Ooghe, 2008; Sogorb-Mira, 2005). <strong>Companies</strong> with more cash and marketable<br />

securities are less likely to issue outside finance according to specifications (M2) to (M4), but are more<br />

likely to issue outside financing according to specification (M5) 11 . The ratio of dividends on total assets<br />

never shows a significant coefficient.<br />

10 The interpretation of the estimated regression coefficients in the fitted logistic models is not the straightforward interpretation<br />

of the parameters in a linear regression model (see Neter, Kutner, Nachtsheim and Wasserman, 1996). In the following, we focus<br />

on the sign of the estimated coefficients. As an alternative, one might also report the estimated odds ratios, which are obtained by<br />

taking the exponent of the coefficients. In model 5-5, for earnings on total assets, the odds of a company issuing outside finance is<br />

0.2516 (exp(-1.38) = 0.2516) times higher or alternatively 3.9749 (1/0.2516) times lower for a one-percentage point increase in<br />

earnings on total assets.<br />

11 The mean ratio of cash and cash equivalents on total assets is lower for debt issuers compared to companies resorting to equity<br />

finance (Table 2.4). The difference in the mean ratio of cash and cash equivalents on total assets for debt issuers compared to<br />

equity issuers is more pronounced when excluding these cases where data on financial risk is not available (not reported). This<br />

indicates that the change in sign may be due to a relatively larger number of companies with higher cash and cash equivalents<br />

issuing debt finance that are dropped because of missing values when including the financial risk measure.<br />

85


Internal finance:<br />

(EARNINGS/TOTAL ASSETS)t-1<br />

TABLE 2.5<br />

Logistic Regression of the Determinants of Outside Finance Use<br />

M1 M2 M3 M4 M5<br />

(CASH AND EQUIVALENTS/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

(DIVIDENDS/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

Debt capacity:<br />

(FINANCIAL DEBT/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

(Negative shareholders’ equity) t-1<br />

(INTERNALLY GENERATED CASH FLOW/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

(FINANCIAL DEBT/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1 x (INTERNALLY GENERATED<br />

CASH FLOW/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

Control variables:<br />

Tax Shields<br />

(INTERESTS/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

(DEPRECIATIONS/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

Financial distress<br />

(OJD-SCORE) t-1<br />

(PROPERTY, PLANT AND EQUIPMENT/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

Agency costs<br />

(INTANGIBLE ASSETS/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

Ln(TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

Previous debt finance<br />

Previous external equity finance<br />

Year dummies<br />

Industry dummies<br />

Coef. Coef. Coef. Coef. Coef.<br />

-3.82 ** -2.71 ** -2.69 ** -1.38 **<br />

-1.10 ** -0.87 ** -0.67 ** 1.62 **<br />

-0.11 0.07 0.42 0.25<br />

1.71 ** 1.50 ** 0.64 **<br />

1.18 ** 1.12 ** 0.94 **<br />

-0.42 ** -0.42 ** -0.27 **<br />

0.91 ** 1.06 ** 0.40<br />

7.67 ** 7.84 **<br />

-0.79 -2.36 *<br />

-0.59 **<br />

0.87 ** 1.23 **<br />

0.65 1.89 *<br />

-0.09 ** -0.09 ** -0.89 ** -0.09 ** -0.01<br />

0.94 ** 0.78 ** 0.51 ** 0.50 ** 0.48 **<br />

1.10 ** 0.86 ** 1.09 ** 1.07 ** 0.70 **<br />

Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes<br />

Number of obs. 8067 7995 7951 7896 5962<br />

Prob. 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00<br />

Pseudo R² 0.07 0.10 0.15 0.15 0.18<br />

Results indicate that companies using internal finance have a higher debt capacity (M3 to M5). <strong>Companies</strong><br />

with lower debt ratios, positive stockholders’ equity or higher cash flow are more likely to resort to<br />

internal finance. These findings are contrary to the predications of the static trade-off theory. One would<br />

expect companies with a lot of debt capacity to attract financial debt. This would allow profitable<br />

companies to benefit from the tax advantage of additional interest payments. Consistent with Lemmon and<br />

Zender (2004), we find evidence that profitable high-growth companies with a lot of debt capacity prefer<br />

86


to retain their debt capacity. This evidence again points to a substitution between outside finance and<br />

internal finance.<br />

When examining the control variables it is noteworthy that high-risk companies, as reported in<br />

specification (M5), are more likely to attract outside finance. <strong>Companies</strong> that have more tangible assets,<br />

which may serve as collateral, are more likely to attract outside finance (M4 and M5). We find marginal<br />

evidence that high-growth companies with investments in intangible assets are more likely to issue outside<br />

finance (M5). <strong>Companies</strong> that previously issued debt or equity finance are more likely to issue outside<br />

finance again in the future. This is strongly supported in all model specifications.<br />

Table 2.6 reports logistic regression models exploring the determinants of external equity issuers. We<br />

report several model specifications, starting with control variables (M1), and gradually adding internal<br />

finance variables (M2), debt capacity variables (M3), static trade-off variables excluding the probability of<br />

financial distress (M4) and the probability of financial distress (M5).<br />

The results consistently show that less profitable companies are more likely to finance new investments<br />

with external equity. External equity issuers do not differ significantly in terms of cash and cash<br />

equivalents from non-external equity issuers in model specifications (M2) to (M4), but are more likely to<br />

issue additional equity in model specification (M5). The negative coefficient of the debt ratio variable<br />

indicates that companies with higher debt ratios are less likely to issue new equity (M2 to M5). However,<br />

high-growth companies with extremely high debt ratios as proxied by the negative stockholders’ equity<br />

dummy are more likely to issue external equity (M3 to M5). Furthermore, companies with more cash<br />

flows, which are required to fulfill the fixed debt-related payments, have a lower probability of issuing<br />

external equity. We also included an interaction term between debt and cash flow in the model. Graphical<br />

representation of the interaction term indicates that as cash flow increases (and hence the ability to repay<br />

fixed debt-related payments increases), companies are less likely to raise external equity, but this decrease<br />

87


in the probability of raising external equity is smaller for companies that have higher debt ratios (M3 to<br />

M5) 12 . Overall, these findings support for hypothesis 2.<br />

Looking at the control variables proposed by the static trade-off theory we find no significant impact of<br />

debt and non-debt tax shields on the decision to issue new equity (M4 and M5). In line with the static<br />

trade-off theory, companies with a high risk of failure are more likely to attract external equity finance<br />

(M5). This finding is consistent with the results from Baum and Silverman (2004) and indicates that<br />

private equity investors are investing in companies on the edge of short-term failure. Although companies<br />

with more tangible assets are more likely to issue outside funding (Table 2.5), the level of tangible assets<br />

does not discriminate between new equity issuers and non-issuers (Table 2.6, M4 and M5). The results<br />

strongly support the idea that companies with more intangible assets are more likely to fund their<br />

investment projects with external equity finance rather than with debt finance or internal equity (M4 and<br />

M5). This last finding offers further evidence that the debt capacity of growth options may not only be<br />

lower compared to the debt capacity of assets in place, but may actually be negative (Barclay et al., 2006).<br />

Finally, it is worth noting the coefficients of the previous debt and external equity finance dummies.<br />

Similar to Helwege and Liang (1996) and de Haan and Hinloopen (2003), the results show that companies<br />

previously issuing external equity finance are more likely to do so in the future (M1 to M5). However,<br />

previous debt finance has no significant impact on the probability of subsequently raising new equity.<br />

These results indicate the existence of persistence in the finance process, which may be due to a learning<br />

effect in the search for finance (e.g. de Haan and Hinloopen, 2003; Jansson, 2002).<br />

12 Graphical representation of the interaction term in logit models as advocated by Norton, Wang and Ai (2004) is available from<br />

the authors upon request.<br />

88


Internal finance:<br />

(EARNINGS/TOTAL ASSETS)t-1<br />

TABLE 2.6<br />

Logistic Regression of the Determinants of External Equity Use<br />

(CASH AND EQUIVALENTS/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

(DIVIDENDS/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

Debt capacity:<br />

(FINANCIAL DEBT/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

(Negative shareholders’ equity) t-1<br />

(INTERNALLY GENERATED CASH FLOW/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

(FINANCIAL DEBT/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1 x (INTERNALLY GENERATED<br />

CASH FLOW/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

Control variables:<br />

Tax Shields<br />

(INTERESTS/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

(DEPRECIATIONS/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

Financial distress<br />

(OJD-SCORE) t-1<br />

(PROPERTY, PLANT AND EQUIPMENT/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

Agency costs<br />

(INTANGIBLE ASSETS/TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

Ln(TOTAL ASSETS) t-1<br />

M1 M2 M3 M4 M5<br />

Coef.<br />

Coef.<br />

Coef. Coef. Coef.<br />

-1.63 ** -1.12 ** -1.25 ** -0.92 **<br />

0.22<br />

-1.34<br />

0.36 0.41<br />

-0.71 -0.52<br />

0.82 *<br />

-0.76<br />

-0.31 ** -0.24 † -0.43 *<br />

1.47 ** 1.40 ** 1.64 **<br />

-0.46 ** -0.45 ** -0.28 **<br />

0.50 ** 0.71 ** 0.59 *<br />

1.71<br />

-1.35<br />

0.15<br />

-0.96<br />

-1.41<br />

-0.09 *<br />

0.19<br />

1.47 ** 1.91 **<br />

-0.06 ** -0.03 † -0.03 * -0.03 * 0.02<br />

Previous debt finance 0.01 -0.09 -0.10 -0.12 † -0.03<br />

Previous external equity finance 1.28 ** 1.09 ** 1.04 ** 1.02 ** 1.05 **<br />

Year dummies Yes<br />

Industry dummies Yes<br />

2.5.3. Robustness Checks<br />

Yes<br />

Yes<br />

Yes<br />

Yes<br />

Yes<br />

Yes<br />

Yes Yes<br />

Number of obs. 8067 7995 7951 7896 5962<br />

Prob. 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00<br />

Pseudo R² 0.05 0.07 0.10 0.11 0.12<br />

We first replaced the separate logistic regression models with a multinomial logit model, which has three<br />

possible outcomes: internal finance, financial debt and new equity finance. This model offered similar<br />

results to those of the separate logistic regression models reported in this paper.<br />

89


Additional analyses on smaller sub-samples have been conducted to test for the robustness of the main<br />

results. We conducted separate analyses for the companies that were in the database over the total<br />

observation period (thereby excluding failed companies and companies that are no longer independent),<br />

and we contrasted small versus large high-growth companies (median split on total assets) and absolute<br />

versus relative high-growth companies. We also excluded the 57 public high-growth companies from the<br />

analyses. Finally, left censoring of a population’s history requires researchers to the cautious in drawing<br />

inferences especially about the effects of aging (Aldrich, 1999). Remedial measures include the collection<br />

of additional data from before the timeframe of this study or exclude the older companies for which we<br />

lack data. We chose for the last option and selected a sample of younger companies where left censoring<br />

should be less problematic. Results remained qualitatively similar. First, less profitable companies are<br />

more likely to issue outside financing and prefer to retain debt capacity. Second, companies with limited<br />

debt capacity are more likely to issue external equity.<br />

Removing the companies with negative shareholder’s equity (i.e., companies with excessive debt levels)<br />

from the analyses slightly changes the results in favor of the traditional pecking order theory. <strong>High</strong>-growth<br />

companies end up with high debt ratios. <strong>Companies</strong> with lower cash flow ratios, however, remain more<br />

likely to issue outside equity finance. These results confirm that debt capacity is not only determined by<br />

the level of debt, but also by the capacity to carry additional debt-related payments. This finding shows<br />

that removing companies with negative equity from the sample may bias results.<br />

2.6. Discussion and Conclusions<br />

Financial capital is one of the key resources companies require to support their growth. This paper<br />

researches financial decision making in high-growth companies. Although previous research indicates that<br />

financial management is of paramount importance in a high-growth setting, little is known about financial<br />

policy of high-growth companies. Previous studies focused mainly on professional venture capital and<br />

90


more broadly new equity issues as a key finance option for high-growth companies, ignoring other<br />

frequently used alternatives. Using the pecking order theory, we provide testable hypotheses of finance<br />

behavior in a high-growth setting. Our results are based on a large longitudinal dataset of finance<br />

decisions made by high-growth companies over an eight year period. Startups and companies disappearing<br />

from our database, because of company failure or mergers and acquisitions, are included.<br />

Our results are consistent with the extended pecking order theory, taking into account constraints due to<br />

limited debt capacity. More profitable companies prefer to finance investments internally. <strong>Companies</strong><br />

using internal finance stockpile debt capacity and are less likely to attract debt finance. <strong>Companies</strong> with<br />

excessive leverage and lower cash flow ratios are more likely to issue outside equity finance. It is striking<br />

that stockholders’ equity is negative in more than 20% of the companies in the year prior to getting<br />

external equity. <strong>Companies</strong> issuing external equity may therefore be unable to attract more debt finance<br />

given the excessive leverage and difficulty to support additional debt-related payments. <strong>Companies</strong> with a<br />

high risk of failure are more likely to issue new equity. Finally, companies that invest more heavily in<br />

intangible assets are more likely to attract additional external equity.<br />

Together these results indicate that retained earnings will gradually replace outside finance when possible.<br />

Bank debt is primarily used by low risk companies, while external equity is used by high-risk companies.<br />

These findings are consistent with prior research focusing on financial decisions in private equity versus<br />

non-private equity backed firms in Belgium (Baeyens and Manigart, 2005). External equity is particularly<br />

important for unprofitable companies, companies investing more heavily in intangible assets, companies<br />

with high debt levels and limited cash flows or companies subject to high risks of failure. Consequently,<br />

new equity is crucial as it allows some high-growth companies to undertake investments and grow beyond<br />

their debt capacity.<br />

91


Our results are important for academics. External equity finance is undeniably important for high-growth<br />

companies needing finance beyond their debt capacity. However, contrary to the current focus in the<br />

literature on external equity finance for high-growth companies, internal finance and financial debt are the<br />

most frequently used finance alternatives. Pecking order proponents are currently developing and<br />

integrating the notion of debt capacity in the standard pecking order theory. Contrary to assumptions in<br />

prior studies (e.g., Fama and French, 2005), we claim that debt capacity is not only determined by<br />

leverage, but also by the capacity to fulfill fixed debt-related payments. Hence, even companies with low<br />

leverage may be unable to attract more debt finance.<br />

Despite its contributions, this research is not without limitations. First, we study finance decisions within<br />

companies that realized high-growth over the timeframe of our study. As a result, we are unable to identity<br />

differences in financial policies between high- and low-growth companies. Hence, while this study<br />

indicates that growth and finance are interrelated, we do not provide insight into the questions whether<br />

access to finance causes growth or whether it is growth that requires finance. Second, similar to the<br />

majority of other studies on company finance, we focus on the finance obtained. Therefore, we are unable<br />

to answer questions such as: What does the search for financing look like? Do company managers prefer<br />

to target one or a few investors, or do they target multiple potential investors? How does the initial search<br />

for finance influence the subsequent search for finance? Our results do hint that there is persistence in the<br />

acquisition of financial resources. Third, we focus on the decision of managers to use retained earnings,<br />

financial debt or new equity. We do not focus on the amount of finance managers attract. This would be a<br />

valuable avenue for further research. Finally, there are other potentially important sources of finance, such<br />

as trade credit and subsidy finance, on which we decided not to focus. The need to focus on one (or in<br />

exceptional cases, two) sources of finance is directly attributable to theoretical tractability (i.e. one cannot<br />

model everything). We cover the key finance alternatives advanced by the pecking order theory, which is<br />

a broader coverage compared to what one typically finds in the literature and leave it up to further<br />

research to examine the role of other finance alternatives in high-growth companies.<br />

92


Our results are also important for management practice. By studying the finance behavior of high-growth<br />

companies, entrepreneurs can gain a more thorough insight in the financial policies related to high growth.<br />

Our results are important for policymakers as well. Our research indicates the importance of retained<br />

earnings in the financing of investment projects by high-growth companies. Debt finance, however, has an<br />

important advantage compared to equity finance under the corporate tax system in most developed<br />

countries: while the interests that companies pay are tax-deductible expenses, dividends and retained<br />

earnings are not. The Belgian government recently implemented a unique tax incentive that reduces the<br />

fiscal discrimination between debt and equity finance. This incentive, called ‘notional interest deduction’<br />

allows companies subject to Belgian corporate tax to deduct from their taxable income an amount equal to<br />

the interest they would have paid on their capital (corrected equity capital more specifically, including<br />

capital and carry-forward profits, among other) if that capital was long-term debt finance. Given our<br />

research findings, tax incentives, such as the notional interest deduction, which increase the incentive to<br />

retain earnings within companies, are well taken.<br />

References<br />

Akerlof G.A. (1970) “The market for ‘lemons:’ Quality and the market mechanism.” Quarterly Journal of<br />

Economics 84: 488-500.<br />

Amit R., Brander J. and Zott C. (1998) “Why do venture capital firms exist? Theory and Canadian<br />

Evidence.” Journal of Business Venturing 49: 371-402.<br />

Audretsch D.B. and Lehmann E. (2002) “Debt or equity? The role of venture capital in financing the new<br />

economy in Germany.” Discussion paper series, Centre for Economic Policy Research.<br />

Baeyens K. and Manigart S. (2005) “Who gets venture capital?” In S.A. Zahra, C.G. Brush, P. Davidsson,<br />

J.O. Fiet, P.G. Greene, R.T. Harrison, M. Lerner, C. Mason, D. Shepherd, J. Sohl, J. Wiklund and M.<br />

Wright. Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research: 504-516. Babson College, Babson Park (USA).<br />

93


Barclay M.J., Smith Jr., C.W. and Morellec E. (2006) “On the debt capacity of growth options.” Journal of<br />

Business 79: 37-59.<br />

Baum J.A.C. and Silverman B.S. (2004) “Picking winners or building them? Alliance, intellectual, and<br />

human capital as selection criteria in venture financing and performance of biotechnology startups.”<br />

Journal of Business Venturing 19: 411-436.<br />

Berger A.N. and Udell G.F. (1998) “The economics of small business finance: The roles of private equity<br />

and debt markets in the financial growth cycle.” Journal of Banking and Finance 22: 613-673.<br />

Carey M., Post M. and Sharpe S.A. (1998) “Does corporate lending by banks and finance companies<br />

differ? Evidence on specialization in private debt contracting.” The Journal of Finance 53: 845-878.<br />

Carpenter R.E. and Petersen B.C. (2002a) “Is the growth of small firms constrained by internal finance?”<br />

The Review of Economics and Statistics 84: 298-309.<br />

Carpenter R.E. and Petersen B.C. (2002b) “Capital market imperfections, high-tech investment and new<br />

equity financing.” The Economic Journal 112: 54-72.<br />

Cassar G. (2004) "The financing of business start-ups." Journal of Business Venturing 19: 261-283.<br />

Colombo and Grilli (2007) “Funding gaps? Access to bank loans by high-tech start-ups.” Small Business<br />

Economics 29: 25-46.<br />

Corolleur C.D.F., Carrere A. and Mangematin V. (2004) “Turning scientific and technological human<br />

capital into economic capital: the experience of biotech start-ups in France.” Research Policy 33: 631-<br />

642.<br />

Davidsson P. and Wiklund J. (1999) “Conceptual and empirical challenges in the study of firm growth.”<br />

In Handbook of Entrepreneurship, ed. Sexton D. and Landström H., 26-44. Blackwell Business.<br />

Davila A., Foster G. and Gupta M. (2003) “Venture capital financing and the growth of startup firms.”<br />

Journal of Business Venturing 18: 689-708.<br />

94


de Haan L. and Hinloopen J. (2003) “Preference hierarchies for internal finance, bank loans, bond and<br />

share issues: Evidence for Dutch firms.” Journal of Empirical Finance 10: 661-681.<br />

Delmar F., Davidsson P. and Gartner W.B. (2003) “Arriving at the high-growth firm.” Journal of Business<br />

Venturing 18: 189-216.<br />

Eckhardt J.T., Shane S. and Delmar F. (2006) “Multistage selection and the financing of new ventures.”<br />

Management Science 52: 220-232.<br />

EuropaBio (2006) “Comparative study on biotech in Europe.” http://www.europabio.org/ (09 JUL 2007).<br />

Fama E.F. and French K.R. (2005) “<strong>Financing</strong> decisions: Who issues stock?” Journal of Financial<br />

Economics 76: 549-582.<br />

Frank M.Z. and Goyal V.K. (2003) “Testing the pecking order theory of capital structure.” Journal of<br />

Financial Economics 67: 217-248.<br />

Frank M.Z. and Goyal V.K. (2005) “Trade-off and pecking order theories of debt.” In Handbook of<br />

corporate finance: Empirical corporate finance, ed. Espen Eckbo B., Chapter 7, Elsevier/North-Holland.<br />

Gompers P.A. (1995) “Optimal investment, monitoring, and the staging of venture capital.” Journal of<br />

Finance 50: 1461-1489.<br />

Gompers P. and Lerner J. (2001) “The venture capital revolution.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 15:<br />

145-168.<br />

Halov N. and Heider F. (2004) “Capital structure, asymmetric information and risk.” Working paper, NY<br />

University.<br />

Harris M. and Raviv A. (1991) “The theory of capital structure.” Journal of Finance 46: 297-356.<br />

Heider F. (2003) “Leverage and asymmetric information about risk and value.” Unpublished Working<br />

Paper, Stern School of Business, New York University.<br />

95


Helwege J. and Liang N. (1996) “Is there a pecking order? Evidence from a panel of IPO firms.” Journal<br />

of Financial Economics 40: 429-458.<br />

Henrekson M. and Johansson D. (2009), “Gazelles as Job Contributors - A Survey and Interpretation of<br />

the Evidence” Small Business Economics (In Press).<br />

Heyman D., Deloof M. and Ooghe H. (2008) “The financial structure of privately held Belgian firms.”<br />

Small Business Economics 30: 301-313.<br />

Hovakimian A., Opler T. and Titman S. (2001) “The debt-equity choice.” Journal of Financial and<br />

Quantitative Analysis 36: 1-24.<br />

Howorth C.A. (2001) “Small firms' demand for finance: A research note.” International Small Business<br />

Journal 19: 78-86.<br />

Jansson J. (2002) “Empirical studies in corporate finance, taxation and investment.” Uppsala University,<br />

Economic Studies 67.<br />

Jensen M.C. (1986) “Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance and takeovers.” American<br />

Economic Review 76: 323-339.<br />

Leary M.T. and Roberts M.R. (2004) “Do firms rebalance their capital structures?” Working paper, Duke<br />

University.<br />

Lemmon M.L. and Zender J.F. (2004) “Debt capacity and tests of capital structure theories.” Working<br />

Paper, University of Colorado and University of Washington.<br />

Manigart S. and Struyf C. (1997) “<strong>Financing</strong> high technology start ups in Belgium: An explorative study.”<br />

Small Business Economics 9: 125-135.<br />

Manigart S. and Meuleman M. (2004) “<strong>Financing</strong> entrepreneurial companies” De Boeck & Larcier.<br />

96


Markman G.D. and Gartner W.B. (2002) “Is extraordinary growth profitable? A study of Inc. 500 high-<br />

growth companies.” Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice 27: 65-75.<br />

Marsh P. (1982) “The choice between equity and debt: An empirical study.” The Journal of Finance 37:<br />

121-144.<br />

Maurer I. and Ebers M. (2006) “Dynamics of social capital and their performance implications: Lessons<br />

from biotechnology startups.” Administrative Science Quarterly 51: 262-292.<br />

Michaelas N., Chittenden F. and Poutziouris P. (1999) “Financial policy and capital structure choice in<br />

U.K. SMEs: Empirical evidence from company panel data.” Small Business Economics 12: 113-130.<br />

Modigliani F. and Miller M.H. (1958) “The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of<br />

investment.” American Economic Review 48: 261-297.<br />

Modigliani F. and Miller M.H. (1963) “Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: A correction.”<br />

American Economic Review 53: 433-443.<br />

Myers S.C. (1977) “Determinants of corporate borrowing.” Journal of Financial Economics 5: 147-175.<br />

Myers S.C. (1984) “The capital structure puzzle.” The Journal of Finance 39: 575-592.<br />

Myers S.C. and Majluf N.S. (1984) “Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have<br />

information that investors do not have.” Journal of Financial Economics 13: 187-221.<br />

Neter J., Kutner M.H., Nachtsheim C.J. and Wasserman W. (1996) “Applied linear statistical methods.”<br />

McGraw-Hill, third edition.<br />

Norton E.C., Wang H. and Ai C. (2004) “Computing interaction effects and standard errors in logit and<br />

probit models.” The Stata Journal 4: 154-167.<br />

Ooghe H. and Van Wymeersch C. (2003) “Handboek financiële analyse van de onderneming.” Intersentia.<br />

97


Ou C. and Haynes G.W. (2006) “Acquisition of additional equity capital by small firms – Findings from<br />

the National Survey of Small Business Finances.” Small Business Economics 27: 157-168.<br />

Rajan R.G. and Zingales L. (1995) “What do we know about capital structure: Some evidence from<br />

international data.” The Journal of Finance 50: 1421-1460.<br />

Reynolds P.D., Bygrave W.D., Autio E. and Camp N. (2000) “Global Entrepreneurship Executive<br />

Report.” Kansas City, MO: Kauffman Center for Entrepreneurial Leadership.<br />

Sapienza H., Manigart S. and Vermeir W. (1996) “Venture capitalist governance and value added in four<br />

countries.” Journal of Business Venturing 11: 439-469.<br />

Sharfman M., Wolf G., Chase R. and Tansik D. (1988) “Antecedents of organizational slack.” Academy<br />

of Management Review 13: 601-614.<br />

Shyam-Sunder L. and Myers S.C. (1999) “Testing static tradeoff against pecking order models of capital<br />

structure.” Journal of Financial Economics 21: 219-244.<br />

Sogorb-Mira F. (2005) “How SME uniqueness affects capital structure: Evidence from a 1994-1998<br />

Spanish data panel.” Small Business Economics 25: 447-457.<br />

Storey D. (1994) “Understanding the Small Business Sector.” Routledge, London.<br />

Titman S. (1984) “The effect of capital structure on the firm’s liquidation decision.” Journal of Financial<br />

Economics 13: 137-152.<br />

Titman S. and Wessels R. (1988) “The determinants of capital structure choice.” Journal of Finance 43: 1-<br />

19.<br />

Van Auken H. (2001) “<strong>Financing</strong> small technology-based companies: the relationship between familiarity<br />

with capital and ability to price and negotiate investments.” Journal of Small Business Management 39:<br />

240-258.<br />

98


Van Eeckhout C., Clarysse B., Vanacker T. and Manigart S. (2006) “Op Safari in Vlaanderen: De<br />

Identificatie en Kenmerken van Gazellen.” In Durven groeien in Vlaanderen: Een boek voor gevorderden,<br />

ed. Clarysse B., 69-82. Roularta Books.<br />

Weinzimmer L.G., Nystrom P.C. and Freeman S.J. (1998) “Measuring organizational growth: Issues,<br />

Consequences and Guidelines.” Journal of Management 24: 235-262.<br />

99


Chapter 3: Seeking Experienced or Legitimate Partners? A<br />

Longitudinal Study on the Impact of Venture Capital Firm<br />

Heterogeneity on Portfolio Company <strong>Growth</strong><br />

Tom Vanacker<br />

Ghent University, Department of Accounting and Corporate Finance, Kuiperskaai 55E, 9000 Gent,<br />

Belgium; TomR.Vanacker@UGent.be<br />

I thank Sophie Manigart, Hans Landström, Harry Sapienza and Mirjam Knockaert for helpful comments. This paper<br />

received one of the awards reserved for top papers presented by doctoral students at the 2009 meetings of the<br />

Midwest Finance Association (Chicago, March 4-7) and is selected for presentation at the 2009 Annual Meeting of<br />

the Academy of Management (Chicago, August 7-11). A prior version of this paper was presented at the 2008<br />

Babson College Entrepreneurship Research Conference (The University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, US) and is<br />

published in the 2008 edition of Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research. The financial support of the<br />

Intercollegiate Center for Management Science (I.C.M.) and Impulsfonds are gratefully acknowledged.<br />

100


3.1. Abstract<br />

Although scholars agree that not all partners are equal, it remains unclear whether companies will<br />

particularly benefit from forming relationships with more experienced or more legitimate firms. This<br />

study examines the impact of venture capital firm experience and legitimacy on portfolio company<br />

growth. For this purpose, I track 94 companies forming initial investment relationships with venture<br />

capital firms for up to five years after the initial investment. Linear Mixed Models (LMMs) are used to<br />

gain more insight into the non-linear growth trajectories of portfolio companies. Findings indicate that<br />

both companies backed by venture capital firms with more industry experience, but not overall<br />

experience, and companies backed by more legitimate venture capital firms exhibit higher growth curves.<br />

3.2. Introduction<br />

The lack of established working relationships, social approval, tested routines, and the resulting high risk<br />

of failure make resource mobilization a key challenge and a process fraught with difficulties within young<br />

and small entrepreneurial ventures (Stinchcombe, 1965). Nevertheless, the mobilization of sufficient<br />

external resources is critical and ventures which are able to mobilize more strategic resources at startup<br />

are likely to develop a competitive advantage over their resource-constrained peers (Lee, Lee and<br />

Pennings, 2001). Interorganizational relationships have become an attractive way to obtain resources<br />

(Baum, Calabrese and Silverman, 2000). Hence, these relationships are likely to be particularly beneficial<br />

to young, resource-constrained ventures (Stuart, Hoang and Hybels, 1999; Stuart, 2000). This study<br />

focuses on investment relationships between professional venture capital firms and their portfolio<br />

companies as a representative form of interorganizational relationships (Hallen, 2008) and studies the<br />

impact of venture capital firm heterogeneity on portfolio company growth.<br />

Although scholars have recognized that certain relationships are more valuable than others, it remains<br />

unclear which type of partners contribute most to the development of young entrepreneurial ventures<br />

101


(Rindova, Williamson, Petkova and Sever, 2005). I focus on learning and signaling theory, which stress<br />

different mechanisms through which partners might influence venture development. Organizational<br />

learning theory stresses the importance of accumulated experience of partners through past actions (Hoang<br />

and Rothaermel, 2005). Firms are likely to learn how to identify and nurture promising ventures through<br />

repeated interactions with these ventures (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990) and are likely to develop a<br />

repertoire of proven routines (Nelson and Winter, 1982). Hence, partners will become more effective and<br />

efficient in their tasks as they accumulate experience. Signaling theories stress the transfer of legitimacy<br />

from more established partners to ventures that lack legitimacy in the marketplace (Stuart, Hoang and<br />

Hybels, 1999). In signaling theories it is the information exchange and social influence, which results<br />

from affiliating with more legitimate partners, that changes the perception of stakeholders about venture<br />

quality and makes them more likely to transact with an informationally opaque venture (Rao, 1994;<br />

Pollock and Rindova, 2003). The goal of this study is to examine whether entrepreneurial companies<br />

particularly benefit from forming investment relationships with more experienced or more legitimate<br />

venture capital firms.<br />

Empirical work on venture capital firm heterogeneity has almost exclusively put venture capital firms in<br />

the foreground by focusing on venture capital fund performance and put portfolio companies in the<br />

background (Dimov and Shepherd, 2005; Dimov and De Clercq, 2006; Sorensen, 2007; Hochberg,<br />

Ljungqvist and Lu, 2007; Bottazzi, Da Rin and Hellmann, 2007). Nearly all our knowledge on the<br />

consequences of venture capital firm heterogeneity comes from the proportion of initial public offerings<br />

(IPOs), mergers and acquisitions (M&As) and failures in the portfolios of venture capital funds. It is<br />

assumed that IPOs are the most lucrative exit, while M&As are only a second-best option (Berger and<br />

Udell, 1998). This raises two concerns. First, for venture capital firms to be able to exit from promising<br />

companies through an IPO, an active stock market is required, which is generally not the case in bank-<br />

based financial systems, including most Continental European countries (Black and Gilson, 1998).<br />

Second, M&As do not distinguish between successful and unsuccessful companies, as it represents a<br />

102


common exit route both for very promising companies and less promising ones (Schwienbacher, 2002;<br />

Graebner and Eisenhardt, 2004).<br />

More importantly, studying organizational processes from different perspectives may offer different<br />

insights (Van de Ven, 2007). A successful exit from the perspective of the venture capital firm may not<br />

always be successful from the perspective of the portfolio company. Exits by venture capital firms bear<br />

risks for entrepreneurs, like losing control and major changes in board composition (Schwienbacher,<br />

2002). While some entrepreneurs may have an active interest in selling their companies others may show<br />

strong opposition to an acquisition (Graebner and Eisenhardt, 2004). Additionally, venture capital firms<br />

sometimes have perverse incentives and act in their self-interest. Gompers (1996) shows how young<br />

venture capital firms bring their portfolio companies to the market prematurely in order to establish<br />

legitimacy. Thereby these young venture capital firms do not maximize the value of the IPO from the<br />

perspective of their portfolio companies and additionally may put a serious burden on these less mature<br />

companies, as the costs of maintaining stock exchange listings are very high (Berger and Udell, 1998).<br />

This study departs from extant research on venture capital firm heterogeneity which is generally interested<br />

in fund performance and studies the impact of investor heterogeneity from the perspective of the portfolio<br />

company thereby focusing on portfolio company growth or its ability to accumulate key resources.<br />

I use a unique longitudinal database, free of survivorship bias, tracking 94 Belgian venture capital backed<br />

companies for up to five years after the initial venture capital investment. LMMs are used as an<br />

appropriate longitudinal technique to model the dynamic (non-linear) nature of growth. This is an<br />

important methodological contribution to organizational growth research that typically measures growth<br />

as the difference in size between two points in time, thereby ignoring development in-between these two<br />

points (Weinzimmer, Nystrom and Freeman, 1998; Delmar, Davidsson and Gartner, 2003). Results<br />

demonstrate how companies which connect with venture capital firms with more industry experience, but<br />

not overall experience, and companies which connect with more legitimate venture capital firms exhibit<br />

103


higher growth paths both in employment and total assets. It is unlikely that only selection is driving these<br />

results. I find evidence indicating that more experienced and legitimate venture capital firms also provide<br />

superior value-added services to their portfolio companies and provide stronger signals to outside<br />

stakeholders which benefits venture growth.<br />

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. I first present a theoretical framework on the impact of<br />

venture capital firm experience and legitimacy on portfolio company growth and develop specific<br />

hypotheses. Next, I outline the methods, including the sample, measures and method of analysis. Then, I<br />

present the main research findings. Finally, I conclude by discussing the results from both a theoretical<br />

and practical perspective.<br />

3.3. Theory and Hypotheses<br />

Relationships with venture capital firms are one of the earliest and most critical relationships formed,<br />

especially within growth-oriented entrepreneurial ventures requiring quick access to a variety of resources<br />

(Katila, Rosenberger and Eisenhardt, 2008). Venture capital firms not only contribute well-needed<br />

financial resources to their portfolio companies, but generally also contribute knowledge-based resources<br />

like advice, referrals for executive hires and industry connections (Sapienza, Manigart and Vermeir,<br />

1996). Most prior research has treated venture capital firm participation as a dummy variable (Hsu, 2004),<br />

thereby assuming that all venture capital firms have equal capacity to source high quality companies and<br />

equal ability to nurture companies through active involvement (Megginson and Weiss, 1991; Kortum and<br />

Lerner, 2000; Hellmann and Puri, 2002; Davila, Foster and Gupta, 2003; Baum and Silverman, 2004).<br />

Nevertheless, venture capital firms exhibit significant heterogeneity both in their selection behavior<br />

(Muzyka, Birley and Leleux, 1996) and post-investment assistance to their portfolio companies (Elango,<br />

Fried, Hisrich and Polonchek, 1995). Grounded in learning and signaling theory, I develop testable<br />

104


hypotheses on the role of venture capital firm experience and legitimacy for portfolio company<br />

development. Experience and legitimacy constitute two kinds of intangible resources playing a central role<br />

in the venture capital industry. Their impact on the growth path of portfolio companies is discussed in<br />

more detail below.<br />

3.3.1. Venture Capital Firm Experience and Portfolio Company <strong>Growth</strong><br />

Learning theory indicates that firms learn how to manage relationships through repeated engagements<br />

with other ventures. Firms are likely to absorb and accumulate knowledge through prior relationship<br />

formation (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990). Firms are also likely to develop routines based on past<br />

experiences (Nelson and Winter, 1982). The routines that become part of an organization’s repertoire are<br />

those that previously produced favorable outcomes (Levinthal and March, 1993). Moreover, the<br />

application of routines increases their efficiency and the likelihood of a desirable outcome (Levitt and<br />

March, 1988).<br />

As venture capital firms gain experience they may become more capable at selecting the best ventures.<br />

The decision accuracy of venture capitalists increases with experience, although too much experience is<br />

not necessarily beneficial as experienced decision-makers may get trapped in their current modes of<br />

thought (Shepherd, Zacharakis and Baron, 2003). Despite the potential downside of having too much<br />

experience for decision-making accuracy, Sorensen (2007) demonstrates the existence of a monotonically<br />

increasing relationship between overall venture capital firm experience and the probability of portfolio<br />

companies going public 13 . The main driver behind the results is investor selection; more experienced<br />

venture capital firms invest in better companies (Sorensen, 2007).<br />

13 It should be noted that the precise shape of the relationship between experience and company growth -that is, whether it is<br />

monotonically increasing or an inverted U-shape- is a separate empirical issue. A priori, I would expect the monotonically<br />

increasing relationship to materialize in our research setting, as the Belgian venture capital industry although developed is still<br />

significantly less mature than its U.S. and U.K. equivalents. Hence, it is unlikely that Belgian venture capital firms already moved<br />

down to the flatter part of the learning curve (see more on this issue later).<br />

105


The accumulated experience may not only influence venture capital firms’ ability to select more<br />

promising ventures, but may also contribute to the quality of the extra-financial, knowledge-based<br />

resources they offer to their portfolio companies (Baum and Silverman, 2004). Venture capital firms<br />

typically play an important role in monitoring the management and progress of their portfolio companies<br />

(Lerner, 1995; Fried, Bruton and Hisrich, 1998) and often help their portfolio companies with<br />

professionalizing, for example, by influencing the structure and experience of the management team<br />

(Hellmann and Puri, 2002). The effectiveness of post-investment management is likely to be dependent<br />

upon venture capital firm ability (Dimov and De Clercq, 2006). Overall, both the expected ability of more<br />

experienced venture capital firms to source high quality companies and their ability to nurture companies<br />

through active involvement lead to the following hypothesis:<br />

Hypothesis 1A: <strong>Companies</strong> backed by venture capital firms with high overall experience will exhibit<br />

steeper growth curves compared to companies backed by venture capital firms with low overall<br />

experience.<br />

Not all experience is the same, however, and learning performance is expected to be the greatest when the<br />

object of learning is related to what is already known (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990). Scholars have argued<br />

that it is difficult to learn from experience when performing heterogeneous tasks (Zollo and Winter, 2002).<br />

<strong>Extending</strong> this idea, it may be difficult for venture capital firms to learn from prior experience if they form<br />

investment relationships with very different types of companies. Alternatively, venture capital firms<br />

investing in a more homogenous group of companies may maximally benefit from learning curve effects<br />

through the accumulation of superior knowledge. An important specialization strategy for venture capital<br />

firms is to invest in only one or a few industries (Norton and Tenenbaum, 1993).<br />

106


There are several ways through which specialized industry expertise held by venture capital firms may<br />

positively influence portfolio company growth. First, specialized industry expertise may allow for a better<br />

understanding of the intricacies associated with investing in particular industries. This may facilitate the<br />

selection of more promising ventures, as it is not because venture capital firms are good in selecting<br />

companies with high potential in for example the wholesale industry, that they will be equally able to do<br />

so in the biotechnology industry. Second, increased industry expertise may also benefit specialized<br />

venture capital firms in performing their governance role and value adding activities (Sapienza, Manigart<br />

and Vermeir, 1996). Venture capital firms with high industry deal experience may be better connected, for<br />

example, drawing on a greater number of contacts with relevant suppliers, customers, investors and<br />

managers for their portfolio companies (Hochberg, Ljungqvist and Lu, 2007). This leads to the following<br />

hypothesis:<br />

Hypothesis 1B: <strong>Companies</strong> backed by venture capital firms with high industry experience will exhibit<br />

steeper growth curves compared to companies backed by venture capital firms with low industry<br />

experience.<br />

3.3.2. Venture Capital Firm Legitimacy and Portfolio Company <strong>Growth</strong><br />

Signaling theory indicates that company stakeholders, like customers, suppliers, employees and investors -<br />

especially those that are risk averse- will be more likely to transact with entrepreneurial ventures after they<br />

have been endorsed by established firms (Stuart, Hoang and Hybels, 1999). Davila, Foster, and Gupta<br />

(2003) illustrate that venture capital firms as a group signal company quality to the labor market and<br />

thereby influence the ease with which companies attract key employees. Janney and Folta (2003) show<br />

how in a sample of publicly quoted technology companies, private equity placements send positive signals<br />

to the market and increase company value. This effect more pronounced when these quoted companies<br />

raise finance from more established investors (Janney and Folta, 2006). It indicates that the decision to<br />

107


offer finance by venture capital investors informs stakeholders about company quality and this manifests<br />

itself in increased growth.<br />

Not all venture capital firms are likely to provide credible signals as many venture capital firms still need<br />

to establish legitimacy in the marketplace themselves (Gompers, 1996). When entrepreneurial companies<br />

connect with partners that lack legitimacy it is unlikely that this will change the perception of outsiders in<br />

any significant way. However, the legitimacy of more established venture capital firms is likely to transfer<br />

to their portfolio companies that lack legitimacy in the marketplace (Stuart, Hoang and Hybels, 1999;<br />

Stuart, 2000). This should allow these portfolio companies to mobilize more resources from key<br />

stakeholders across time which should contribute to company growth. Accordingly, I put forth the<br />

following hypothesis:<br />

Hypothesis 2: <strong>Companies</strong> backed by more legitimate venture capital firms will exhibit steeper growth<br />

curves compared to companies backed by less legitimate venture capital firms.<br />

3.4. Data and Method<br />

3.4.1. Sample<br />

This study partially builds on a database provided by the Belgian Venture Capital and Private Equity<br />

Association linking venture capital backed companies to their lead investors. I track 94 companies that<br />

received initial venture capital finance between 1999 and 2003. Deals are only selected until 2003 in order<br />

to have at least three-year financial figures for the companies selected at the end of this timeframe, as the<br />

last financial figures available at the time of data collection were those of 2006.<br />

108


For each portfolio company I collected detailed yearly financial statement data for up to five years after<br />

the initial venture capital investment. This was possible as all Belgian limited liability companies,<br />

irrespective of their size, are required to file financial statements with the National Bank. It offered 487<br />

firm year observations. The average age of the portfolio companies at baseline (i.e. the year of the initial<br />

venture capital firm investment) equals 3.46 years, with a minimum of zero and maximum of 15 years. At<br />

baseline, the average company employs 9.78 people and has 3,905,500 euro of assets. Some 60% of the<br />

companies in the sample are active in four sectors, namely computer and related activities (24%),<br />

biotechnology (12%), manufacturing (11%) and wholesale (11%).<br />

In order to collect data on the lead venture capital firm providing initial venture capital, I combined<br />

multiple sources including the Zephyr database (a database of private equity deals with a special focus on<br />

pan-European transactions), the Belgian Venture Capital and Private Equity Association database and<br />

trade directories. The lead venture capital firms providing initial finance range from small venture capital<br />

firms with only six million euro of assets under management to venture capital firms with more than one<br />

billion euro of assets under management. The majority of lead investors offering initial finance to Belgian<br />

companies are domestic investors. Only two companies raised initial finance from international venture<br />

capital funds.<br />

3.4.2. Measures<br />

Dependent variable. Organizational scholars argue that growth studies should be longitudinal because of<br />

the dynamic nature of growth (Weinzimmer, Nystrom and Freeman, 1998). I study the temporal growth<br />

pattern of venture capital backed companies from the year of investment relationship formation up to five<br />

years after the initial investment. This is important as the typical lifespan of venture capital investments is<br />

109


around three to five years (Zarutskie, 2007). Furthermore, a five-year period has been the time frame most<br />

widely used in prior organizational growth studies (Weinzimmer, Nystrom and Freeman, 1998).<br />

<strong>Growth</strong> is multidimensional in nature and hence the classification of a company as a high growth<br />

company depends on the growth concept and growth formula used (Delmar, Davidsson and Gartner,<br />

2003). I take into account the multidimensional nature of growth by using two different growth indicators.<br />

Venture capital investors typically invest in companies which require large investments in employment<br />

and total assets but without immediate sale prospects, even in low-tech industries (Puri and Zarutskie,<br />

2008). This explains my choice to study growth in employment (in full time equivalents) and growth in<br />

total assets. I decided to focus on absolute changes in employment and total assets. Relative measures are<br />

not as suitable in the current research setting, since many variables may have a value equal or close to zero<br />

during the initial stage of venture capital firm involvement (Baum, Calabrese and Silverman, 2000).<br />

Independent variables. The key independent variables are correlates of experience and legitimacy of the<br />

lead venture capital firm measured at baseline. Overall experience is operationalized as the total number<br />

of investments made by the venture capital firm prior to the focal investment (Gompers, Kovner, Lerner<br />

and Scharfstein, 2008; Sorensen, 2007). It includes both the number of investments prior to the focal<br />

investment within the timeframe of this study (i.e., 1999-2003) and the number of investments made by<br />

the venture capital firm before this timeframe. Overall deal experience ranges from 1 to 90 investments<br />

with a median value of 9 investments. Industry experience, is constructed similarly to overall experience,<br />

but only examines investments in the same industry (2-digit industry code) as the focal company<br />

(Gompers, Kovner, Lerner and Scharfstein, 2008; Sorenson and Stuart, 2001). Industry deal experience<br />

ranges from 1 to 26 investments with a median value of 2 investments. The natural logarithm of overall<br />

and industry experience was used in subsequent analysis because doing so captured the decreasing<br />

marginal returns that experiential learning is subject to (Pennings, Barkema and Douma, 1994; Hoang and<br />

Rothaermel, 2005). Similar results were obtained using the non-transformed measures.<br />

110


As a proxy for venture capital firm legitimacy I construct a dummy variable which equals one when a<br />

venture capital firm is older than seven years (median value) and zero otherwise 14 . Older venture capital<br />

firms are like to be more legitimate compared to younger venture capital firms for at least two reasons.<br />

First, when venture capital firms invest it takes several years before the first results of the initial<br />

investments can be observed by outsiders (Zarutskie, 2007). Contrary to older venture capital firms with<br />

rich historical backgrounds, younger venture capital firms typically lack a track record of past<br />

performance. Second, many venture capital firms periodically raise follow-on funds to remain active in<br />

venture capital financing and firms generally have two or three overlapping funds each starting three to six<br />

years after the previous fund (Gompers and Lerner, 1996). Hence, older venture capital firms are likely to<br />

have demonstrated they conform to the generally accepted industry norms and practices, which should<br />

increase their legitimacy in the marketplace (Oliver, 1997).<br />

In the above, experience and legitimacy are portrayed as two independent constructs. While the<br />

experience of a venture capital firm reflects its ability to conduct its tasks better (i.e., being good), the<br />

legitimacy of a venture capital firm reflects its collective recognition in the eyes of outsiders including the<br />

financial community (i.e., being known). Nevertheless experience and legitimacy are likely to be related.<br />

Venture capital firms that accumulate experience in the venture capital industry are likely to develop<br />

legitimacy within the industry, and vice versa, legitimate venture capital firms are likely to have<br />

accumulated experience over time. Hence, empirically the two constructs will be related and are not fully<br />

orthogonal.<br />

In order to alleviate the concern that venture capital firm age reflects accumulated experience rather than<br />

legitimacy, I ran models that control for venture capital firm experience in order to pick up any residual<br />

14 Following Gompers (1996), I prefer to use a dummy variable in order to address potential nonlinearities. Nevertheless, similar<br />

results were obtained when using a continuous venture capital firm age variable instead of a dummy variable.<br />

111


effects of this potential confound. Additionally, as an alternative proxy for venture capital firm legitimacy,<br />

I looked up the number of times venture capital firms were cited in Belgian financial newspapers over the<br />

period 1995 until the year of initial investment. The media presents stakeholders with information that<br />

affects impression formation and legitimization of companies (Pollock and Rindova, 2003).<br />

Control variables. Prior studies have advanced important company and venture capital firm<br />

characteristics associated with growth. It is well established that age effects may cause differences in<br />

growth patterns (Jovanovic, 1982). Company age at baseline is measured as the difference between the<br />

year of initial investment and company founding year. Similarly, high-tech companies may exhibit a<br />

different growth path compared to low-tech companies (Harhoff, Stahl and Woywode, 1998). A high-tech<br />

dummy variable is equal to one when the company is active in a high tech sector and zero otherwise. The<br />

classification of an industry as a high-tech industry is based on a classification scheme provided by the<br />

Belgian government and is based on two digit industry codes. It includes industries, such as<br />

biotechnology, computer and related activities.<br />

<strong>Companies</strong> investing in intangible assets typically do this to generate future growth (Titman and Wessels,<br />

1988). Rather than the absolute level of intangible assets, scholars mainly emphasize the importance of<br />

intangible assets relative to tangible assets as one of the main drivers of the sustainability of performance<br />

(Villalonga, 2004). The ratio of intangible assets on total assets is used as a proxy for growth potential. I<br />

also control for the amount of equity finance received by the portfolio company at baseline. It is calculated<br />

based on financial accounts as the net increase in outside equity in the year of venture capital firm<br />

participation.<br />

It is also necessary to control for size differences between venture capital firms, as there are multiple<br />

reasons why larger venture capital firms may have fast growing companies in their portfolio besides<br />

experience and legitimacy (Sorenson and Stuart, 2001). Larger venture capital firms, for example, have<br />

112


more possibilities to offer large amounts of follow-on finance compared to smaller venture capital firms.<br />

Venture capital firm size at baseline is measured as the natural logarithm of capital under management.<br />

Finally, I include year and industry dummy variables in the analysis to control for potential time (year of<br />

initial investment) and industry effects. Table 3.1 reports the correlation matrix for the continuous<br />

variables.<br />

1. Employment 1.000<br />

2. Total Assets 0.342 1.000<br />

3. Overall Deal Experience 0.092 0.057 1.000<br />

TABLE 3.1<br />

Correlation matrix a<br />

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9<br />

4. Industry Deal Experience 0.015 -0.088 0.648 1.000<br />

5. Venture Capital Firm Age 0.185 0.137 0.469 0.288 1.000<br />

6. Company Age 0.377 0.246 -0.088 -0.153 -0.048 1.000<br />

7. Intangible Assets Ratio -0.293 -0.290 0.031 0.152 -0.215 -0.165 1.000<br />

8. Initial Investment Size 0.196 0.616 -0.005 0.029 0.056 0.055 -0.021 1.000<br />

9. VCF Size 0.247 0.420 0.432 0.169 0.349 0.126 -0.264 0.274 1.000<br />

10. VCF Media Citations 0.271 0.300 0.690 0.323 0.270 0.112 -0.070 0.197 0.534<br />

a Bold: Correlations (time=1) are significant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed).<br />

3.4.3. Analysis<br />

Linear Mixed Models (LMMs) for repeated measures are used to study change in employment and total<br />

assets (Weiss, 2005; Fitzmaurice, Laird and Ware, 2004). It is the mix of fixed and random effects in the<br />

same model that is the basis of the name Linear Mixed Model. Scholars have often used General<br />

Multivariate Regressions Models. These require longitudinal data where all companies have the same<br />

number of repeated measures, taken at time points, which are also the same for all companies<br />

(Fitzmaurice, Laird and Ware, 2004). These strict assumptions are rarely fulfilled in longitudinal (growth)<br />

studies and are not required when modeling LMMs 15 .<br />

15 All reported results remain robust when using General Linear Models (GLMs) with repeated measures covariance structures.<br />

Contrary to LMMs the structure of the covariance matrix in GLMs is not dictated by random effects, but the structure is selected<br />

to best model the empirical covariance model.<br />

113


It is conceptually convenient to depict LMMs as multilevel models (Fitzmaurice, Laird and Ware, 2004).<br />

The multilevel perspective is most useful if one assumes that companies randomly vary in terms of their<br />

initial size and growth trajectory. This assumption seems reasonable for many applications in<br />

organizational studies. Individual profile plots (not presented) confirm significant heterogeneity in initial<br />

company size and how companies evolve over time. For this purpose, I discuss two levels of equations.<br />

The first-level in the hierarchy is the individual-level model, which specifies the nature of change for each<br />

individual company. The simplest model of individual company change is the straight-line (linear) growth<br />

model:<br />

Yij = β1i + β2i tij + eij (1)<br />

where Yij is the ith company’s employment or total assets at the jth time point. tij is the linear time coding<br />

(0, 1, 2 … 5) used to fit a linear trend to the ith company’s data across time. β1i and β2i are the company<br />

specific intercept and linear coefficient, respectively. The values of the βs can vary among the companies.<br />

The eij are the residuals. Equation (1) illustrates the flexibility of LMMs. <strong>Companies</strong> can have different<br />

number of time points, they may be measured at different times and each company can have a different<br />

growth trajectory (Fitzmaurice, Laird and Ware, 2004). LMMs can also accommodate non-linear change.<br />

The simplest non-linear model is a quadratic model, which is specified by adding β3i tij² to equation (1) 16 :<br />

Yij = β1i + β2i tij + β3i tij² + eij (2)<br />

The second-level in the hierarchy are the group-level models. Though individual regression equations are<br />

informative, researchers are usually interested in group effects. Conceptually, the random change<br />

parameters from the individual-level model (e.g. β1i, β2i and β3i or company specific intercept, linear<br />

coefficient and quadratic coefficient respectively) are treated as response variables in a second set of<br />

models. Considering the equation (2) quadratic individual change model, the group level equations are:<br />

16 A point of confusion is that LMMs can be used to model non-linear change across time. The term linear in Linear Mixed Model<br />

refers to the linearity of the parameters and does not refer to the type of change that is modeled.<br />

114


β1i = β1 + b1i (3)<br />

β2i = β2 + b2i (4)<br />

β3i = β3 + b3i (5)<br />

β1, β2 and β3 are the fixed intercepts in the level 2 equations and thus the averages of the individual-level<br />

parameters. β1, β2 and β3 indicate the nature of change for the group as a whole, where β1 is the group<br />

mean intercept or mean initial size, β2 is the group mean linear change and β3 is the group mean quadratic<br />

change. These βs are known as fixed effects, because they do not vary among companies. b1i, b2i and b3i<br />

are the level 2 residual terms reflecting individual company differences from the fixed effects.<br />

An extension of the unconditional model discussed above is to incorporate one or more static covariates.<br />

A static covariate of change is a predictor of change that does not vary over the course of the study. The<br />

key covariates in this paper are overall deal experience, industry deal experience, venture capital firm age<br />

and venture capital firm media citations measured at baseline. That is, I examine whether the individual<br />

change parameters (e.g. β1i, β2i and β3i) vary as a function of the experience and legitimacy of the lead<br />

investor backing the company. Overall deal experience, industry deal experience, age and media citations<br />

are measured at baseline and consequently do not vary across time. Hence, they are incorporated in the<br />

group-level equations. Consider the individual-level quadratic change model (2) above. The group level<br />

equations studying change conditional on overall deal experience, for example, then become:<br />

β1i = β1 + β4 odei + b1i (6)<br />

β2i = β2 + β5 odei + b2i (7)<br />

β3i = β3 + β6 odei + b3i (8)<br />

where odei is the value of overall deal experience of the lead investor measured at baseline for the ith<br />

company. β4 is the relationship between overall deal experience and intercept (initial size), β5 is the<br />

relationship between overall deal experience and linear change and β6 is the relationship between overall<br />

deal experience and quadratic change. β4 is also known as the deal experience by intercept interaction, as<br />

115


it indicates how the mean initial size (or intercept) of companies is dependent on overall investor<br />

experience. β5 is known as the overall experience by linear trend interaction, as it indicates how the mean<br />

linear trend is dependent on investor overall experience. Similarly, β6 is the overall deal experience by<br />

quadratic trend interaction.<br />

There is obviously natural heterogeneity among companies in many extraneous variables. Although these<br />

extraneous variables may not be of any substantive interest they can potentially have an impact on the<br />

growth curve of companies. The beauty of the longitudinal research design adopted in this paper is that<br />

any extraneous factors (regardless of whether they have been measured or not) that influence the growth<br />

profile of companies and whose influence persists, but remains relatively stable throughout the duration of<br />

the study, are eliminated or blocked out when the size of companies is compared at several occasions. By<br />

eliminating these major sources of variability from the estimation of within-company change, a precise<br />

estimate of change can be obtained (Fitzmaurice, Laird and Ware, 2004).<br />

3.5. Results<br />

Table 3.2 shows descriptive information on employment and total assets. It reports unconditional means<br />

across time. The bottom of Table 3.2 shows the sample sizes at each time point. The study does not suffer<br />

from survivorship bias, as failing companies are included in the analysis. This information is typically<br />

unavailable to other researchers (see Cassar (2004) for a discussion on survivorship bias when examining<br />

startup financing). The sample size decreases at the end of the time frame for two main reasons. First,<br />

some companies are too young to have four or five-year observations. Second, due to M&As some<br />

companies stop to exist as independent entities. The companies are included in the analysis for the years<br />

before the M&A, but excluded as the companies stop to exist as separate entities after the M&A.<br />

116


The LMM methodology assumes that the response variable is normally distributed. I check the conditional<br />

and unconditional distributions of the raw employment and total assets values using longitudinal box plots<br />

(Weiss, 2005). These show that employment and total assets are positively skewed (not presented).<br />

Therefore, the natural logarithm of employment and the natural logarithm of total assets are used as<br />

normalizing transformations for all subsequent analyses.<br />

TABLE 3.2<br />

Descriptive Statistics for Employment and Total Assets a<br />

Time<br />

Measure Baseline 1 2 3 4 5<br />

Sample means (s.d.)<br />

Employment<br />

Total Assets<br />

N (% Missing)<br />

Employment<br />

Total Assets<br />

9.78<br />

(14.81)<br />

3,905<br />

(6,678)<br />

83<br />

(5.68)<br />

88<br />

(0.00)<br />

12.76<br />

(18.59)<br />

4,561<br />

(7,287)<br />

91<br />

(3.19)<br />

94<br />

(0.00)<br />

14.82<br />

(24.22)<br />

4,780<br />

(7,165)<br />

92<br />

(0.01)<br />

93<br />

(0.00)<br />

16.88<br />

(29.40)<br />

6,096<br />

(10,574)<br />

86<br />

(0.01)<br />

87<br />

(0.00)<br />

19.79<br />

(36.04)<br />

7,742<br />

(16,074)<br />

72<br />

(0.00)<br />

72<br />

(0.00)<br />

a Employment is in full time equivalents and total assets (excluding cash and cash equivalents) in 1,000EUR.<br />

Note: s.d. = standard deviation<br />

3.5.1. Modeling Unconditional Change in Venture Capital Backed <strong>Companies</strong><br />

22.47<br />

(45.52)<br />

6,087<br />

(10,299)<br />

53<br />

(0.00)<br />

53<br />

(0.00)<br />

I first develop models for unconditional change in employment and total assets. Unconditional models do<br />

not have static covariates of change. Therefore, unconditional models focus on mean change in the entire<br />

group of venture capital backed companies. Thereby, more insight is gained in the temporal pattern of<br />

growth within venture capital backed companies, which is a critical step in order to be able to start<br />

answering questions about what the effects are of particular covariates, such as venture capital firm<br />

experience and legitimacy, on this growth pattern (Weiss, 2005).<br />

117


The results of the unconditional analysis appear in Table 3.3. I start by testing an elaborate model<br />

including a linear, quadratic and cubic term. Models higher than third order are rarely used in social<br />

sciences. Following Peixoto (1987), testing involves backward elimination, starting with the highest order<br />

polynomial, in order to avoid bias. If the highest order term is significant, all lower order terms are left in<br />

the model regardless of their significance, because only the highest order term is interpretable, in the sense<br />

that it does not change when the time metric is arbitrarily changed (Peixoto, 1987). The unconditional<br />

model for loge employment has a linear, quadratic and cubic term. The omnibus null hypothesis of no time<br />

effects is rejected, F(3,79) = 14.32, p


Natural log employment<br />

2.2<br />

2.1<br />

2<br />

1.9<br />

1.8<br />

1.7<br />

1.6<br />

FIGURE 3.1<br />

Unconditional Models: Observed and Predicted Means<br />

0 1 2 3 4 5<br />

Time<br />

Observed Means Predicted Means<br />

Natural log total assets<br />

7.3<br />

7.2<br />

7.1<br />

7<br />

6.9<br />

6.8<br />

6.7<br />

6.6<br />

6.5<br />

0 1 2 3 4 5<br />

Time<br />

Observed Means Predicted Means<br />

For loge total assets, the cubic term is not significant in the highest order polynomial tested (Table 3.3).<br />

However, the omnibus null hypothesis of no time effects is rejected, F(3,86) = 3.25, p


significant quadratic trend. In this section, conditional LMMs are estimated, which allow to study the<br />

impact of venture capital firm experience and legitimacy on the shape of the growth curve of venture<br />

capital backed companies, controlling for a-priori covariates, such as company age, initial investment size<br />

and venture capital firm size amongst other controls.<br />

The results of the conditional analyses are reported in Table 3.4. Separate models for growth in<br />

employment (E) and total assets (TA) are reported. The relatively high bivariate correlation between<br />

overall deal experience and industry deal experience (0.648) is not a cause for concern because these<br />

variables were not entered simultaneously into any of the estimated models. Hypotheses are tested by<br />

focusing on the highest order terms in the LMMs. In polynomial models only the highest order terms are<br />

interpretable (Peixoto, 1987). The lower order terms may be informative about the shape of the growth<br />

curve, but only when considered with the higher order terms. Moreover, as previously indicated, if the<br />

highest order terms are significant, all lower order terms are left in the model regardless of their<br />

significance, because only the highest order terms are interpretable, in the sense that it does not change<br />

when the time metric is arbitrarily changed (Peixoto, 1987). In the following I will discuss the role of<br />

respectively overall deal experience, industry deal experience, venture capital firm age and venture capital<br />

firm citations on the shape of the growth curve of venture capital backed companies.<br />

In models E1 and TA1 the effect of overall deal experience on the shape of the growth curve in terms of<br />

employment and total assets is tested. In model E1 the overall deal experience by linear trend interaction<br />

is positive, but not significant (0.0597; p>0.1). It provides evidence that companies backed by investors<br />

with high overall deal experience do not exhibit a significantly steeper growth curve in employment<br />

compared to companies backed by less experienced investors. These results are confirmed for growth in<br />

total assets. In model TA1 the overall deal experience by linear trend interaction is positive, but not<br />

significant (0.1176; p>0.1). Overall, I find no support for hypothesis 1A.<br />

120


TABLE 3.4<br />

Conditional Analysis for Employment and Total Assets<br />

Employment Total Assets<br />

E1 E2 TA1 TA2<br />

INTERCEPT -0.9047 -0.8600 1.2383 1.2656<br />

Overall Deal Experience -0.1514 -0.1424<br />

Industry Deal Experience -0.2135 -0.4045<br />

VCF Age (Dummy) 0.4405 † 0.3834 † 0.5330 † 0.5189 *<br />

Company Age 0.1109 *** 0.1088 *** 0.0587 † 0.0545 †<br />

<strong>High</strong> Tech (Dummy) 0.4067 * 0.4263 * -0.2120 -0.1396<br />

Intangible Assets Ratio -0.0071 † -0.0072 * -0.0120 ** -0.0114 **<br />

Initial Investment Size 0.1217 † 0.1243 † 0.5932 *** 0.5948 ***<br />

VCF Size 0.1390 0.1268 0.1972 † 0.2043 *<br />

LINEAR TREND 0.5341 *** 0.5445 *** 0.1317 0.0792<br />

Overall Deal Experience*Linear Trend (H1A) 0.0597 0.1176<br />

Industry Deal Experience*Linear Trend (H1B) 0.0940 † 0.2539 *<br />

VCF Age (Dummy)*Linear Trend -0.2211 * -0.1936 * -0.4581 * -0.4198 *<br />

Company Age*Linear Trend -0.0139 * -0.0127 * 0.0010 0.0041<br />

QUADRATIC TREND -0.1921 *** -0.1921 *** -0.0705 * -0.0702 *<br />

VCF Age (Dummy)*Quadratic Trend (H2) 0.0424 ** 0.0418 ** 0.0700 † 0.0695 †<br />

CUBIC TREND 0.0191 *** 0.0191 *** --- ---<br />

Null Model Likelihood Ratio Test<br />

Chi-Square 723.20 *** 723.40 *** 455.85 *** 452.63 ***<br />

N 477<br />

† p < .10, * p < .05, ** p < .01, *** p < .001 (Conservative two-tailed tests)<br />

Next, I focus on the role of industry deal experience on the growth curve of venture capital backed<br />

companies. The industry deal experience by linear trend interaction is positive and significant both in<br />

model E2 (0.0940; p


exhibit steeper growth curves both in employment and total assets 18 . I find support for hypothesis 1B both<br />

for growth in employment and growth in total assets.<br />

FIGURE 3.2<br />

Conditional Models: Predicted Means for <strong>Companies</strong> Backed by Investors with <strong>High</strong> Industry Deal<br />

Natural log employment<br />

2,6<br />

2,4<br />

2,2<br />

2<br />

1,8<br />

1,6<br />

1,4<br />

Experience versus Low Industry Deal Experience<br />

0 1 2 3 4 5<br />

Time<br />

Pred. Means (Unconditional)<br />

Pred. Means (<strong>Companies</strong> backed by VCFs with high<br />

industry deal experience)<br />

Pred. Means (<strong>Companies</strong> backed by VCFs with low<br />

industry deal experience)<br />

Natural log total assets<br />

7,4<br />

7,3<br />

7,2<br />

7,1<br />

7<br />

6,9<br />

6,8<br />

6,7<br />

6,6<br />

6,5<br />

0 1 2 3 4 5<br />

The effect of venture capital firm legitimacy is tested by using the venture capital firm age dummy. The<br />

venture capital firm age dummy variable has an effect on the quadratic growth trend in all reported<br />

models. These models control for overall and industry deal experience respectively, which should alleviate<br />

the concern that venture capital firm age proxies for experience. The venture capital firm age dummy by<br />

quadratic term interaction is positive and significant in the employment models E1 (0.0424; p


and significant. Figure 3.3 plots the predicted means from the unconditional model and the predicted<br />

means for companies backed by old versus young venture capital firms (based on a median split). It shows<br />

considerable differences in the growth path of companies backed by old versus young venture capital<br />

firms, where the growth path of companies backed by older more legitimate venture capital firms lies<br />

consistently above that of companies backed by younger less legitimate venture capital firms. All models<br />

offer support for hypothesis 2.<br />

Natural log employment<br />

FIGURE 3.3<br />

Conditional Models: Predicted Means for <strong>Companies</strong> Backed by Old versus Young Venture capital firms<br />

2.6<br />

2.4<br />

2.2<br />

2<br />

1.8<br />

1.6<br />

1.4<br />

0 1 2 3 4 5<br />

Time<br />

Pred. Means (Unconditional)<br />

Pred. Means (<strong>Companies</strong> backed by young VCFs)<br />

Pred. Means (<strong>Companies</strong> backed by old VCFs)<br />

7.4<br />

7.3<br />

7.2<br />

7.1<br />

7<br />

6.9<br />

6.8<br />

6.7<br />

6.6<br />

6.5<br />

0 1 2 3 4 5<br />

As a robustness check, I ran additional models testing the impact of the natural logarithm of the number of<br />

citations to the respective venture capital firms on portfolio company growth (see Table 3.6 in Appendix<br />

A). Portfolio companies backed by investors that appear more frequently in the financial press exhibit a<br />

growth curve with a higher linear trend in employment (0.0996; p0.1). Overall, findings demonstrate the<br />

Natural log total assets<br />

Time<br />

123


obustness of the positive relationship between venture capital firm legitimacy and company growth<br />

reported above and this especially for growth in employment. It offers further support for hypothesis 2.<br />

Finally, some of the results of the control variables also merit attention. Company age by intercept<br />

interactions indicate that older companies are larger at baseline. The high tech dummy by intercept<br />

interactions are only significant in the employment models. <strong>Companies</strong> active in high technology<br />

industries employ more people at baseline. However, companies with more intangible assets are smaller in<br />

term of number of employees at baseline and smaller in term of total assets. <strong>Companies</strong> receiving a larger<br />

equity investment at baseline are larger in terms of employment and total assets. Larger venture capital<br />

firms have a tendency to invest in companies that have more assets at baseline. Finally, in the employment<br />

models, the negative and significant company age by linear trend interactions indicate that older<br />

companies have a lower linear growth rate.<br />

3.5.3. Alternative Explanations for the Hypothesized Relationships: Investor<br />

Selection versus Value Adding<br />

Two distinct processes may explain why the companies backed by investors with more industry<br />

experience and more legitimate investors exhibit higher growth across time. One explanation is that more<br />

experienced and legitimate venture capital firms have access to companies with different characteristics<br />

and select companies with higher growth potential. An alternative explanation is that more experienced<br />

and legitimate venture capital firms add more value post investment. More experienced venture capital<br />

firms, for example, may be better business advisors and have a larger network, while more legitimate<br />

venture capitals firms may convey a stronger signal to outside stakeholders.<br />

Amit, Brander and Zott (1998) argue that although venture capital firms exist because of their capacity to<br />

reduce informational asymmetry, venture capital firms will still prefer to select those companies where<br />

124


selection costs are relatively low. In other words, venture capital firms will prefer to invest in those<br />

companies where the cost of informational asymmetry is less severe. Information problems are thought to<br />

be particularly severe in young, small and technology-based companies (Berger and Udell, 1998;<br />

Carpenter and Petersen, 2002). Moreover, it should be easier for venture capital firms to select companies<br />

that eventually realize high growth when these are characterized by lower informational asymmetry<br />

(Lerner, 1999). Following this line of reasoning, if more experienced and legitimate investors select those<br />

companies that are more informationally transparent and hence easier to identify as potential high growth<br />

companies one would expect these investors to prefer older, larger and low-tech companies.<br />

Moreover, selection entails that more experienced and legitimate venture capital firms identify and invest<br />

in those companies that have more growth opportunities already present in the company prior to the<br />

investment (Sorensen, 2007) or alternatively that companies with high growth potential prefer to raise<br />

finance from more experienced venture capital firms (Hsu, 2004). <strong>Companies</strong> invest in intangible assets to<br />

generate future growth and hence, if selection is primarily driving the results, one might expect that more<br />

experienced and legitimate venture capital firms will match with those companies that have higher<br />

intangible assets on total assets ratios. Furthermore, it has been demonstrated that entrepreneurial ventures<br />

use patents to signal their value and commercial potential to outside stakeholders, including venture<br />

capital investors (Hsu & Ziedonis, 2007). As a robustness check, I looked up whether companies in the<br />

sample were granted patents up until one year after the initial investment using the European Patent Office<br />

database. If the more experienced and legitimate venture capital firms select those companies with higher<br />

growth potential, one would expect them to prefer to invest in companies that were granted more patents<br />

before the investment.<br />

Table 3.5 reports Non-parametric Mann-Whitney Tests, which indicate few differences in initial<br />

characteristics between the companies backed by investors with high versus low (based on median split)<br />

industry deal experience (Panel A). Both groups of companies do not differ in terms of age, total assets,<br />

125


employment and intangible assets ratio 19 . However, venture capital firms with high industry deal<br />

experience are more likely to invest in biotechnology ventures. The biotechnology industry is one of the<br />

riskiest and most uncertain industries in our modern knowledge-based economy. This finding is<br />

remarkable as selection costs will be particularly high in the biotechnology industry and it should be as<br />

easy, if not easier, to select companies with high growth potential in other industries.<br />

TABLE 3.5<br />

Portfolio Company Characteristics by Type of Venture Capital Firm a<br />

Low Industry Deal <strong>High</strong> Industry Deal<br />

Mann-Whitney<br />

Test<br />

Panel A<br />

Experience<br />

Experience<br />

(Two-tailed)<br />

Mean Median Mean Median<br />

Information asymmetry<br />

Age 3.250 2.000 3.730 2.000<br />

Ln(Total Assets) 7.012 6.892 6.519 6.444<br />

Employment (FTE) 7.000 3.000 6.530 3.000<br />

Computer 0.210 0.270<br />

Biotechnology 0.020 0.220 **<br />

Manufacturing 0.150 0.050<br />

Wholesale 0.130 0.050<br />

<strong>Growth</strong> potential<br />

Intangible Assets Ratio 0.109 0.001 0.112 0.006<br />

Patents 0.040 0.000 0.070 0.000<br />

Young Venture Capital Old Venture Capital<br />

Mann-Whitney<br />

Test<br />

Panel B<br />

Firms<br />

Firms<br />

(Two-tailed)<br />

Mean Median Mean Median<br />

Information asymmetry<br />

Age 3.830 2.500 3.100 1.500<br />

Ln(Total Assets) 6.575 6.423 7.009 6.975<br />

Employment (FTE) 4.840 3.000 8.800 3.000<br />

Computer 0.280 0.190<br />

Biotechnology 0.110 0.100<br />

Manufacturing 0.090 0.120<br />

Wholesale 0.150 0.040 †<br />

<strong>Growth</strong> potential<br />

Intangible Assets Ratio 0.144 0.063 0.078 0.001 *<br />

Patents 0.110 0.000 0.000 0.000 *<br />

a I do not differentiate between companies backed by investors with high versus low overall deal experience, as these<br />

ventures do not differ in their subsequent growth. <strong>Companies</strong> backed by investors with high versus low media citations<br />

only differ in terms of industry focus, where investors with more citations in the media are more likely to invest in<br />

biotechnology ventures.<br />

† p < .10, * p < .05, ** p < .01 (Conservative two-tailed tests)<br />

19 Multivariate logit models confirm the reported results. Company characteristics, such as size and intangible assets ratio, which<br />

may be influenced by the financing received are measured in the year prior to the investment (when possible) in order to avoid<br />

problems of reverse causality.<br />

126


I also compared the companies backed by young versus old (based on median split) venture capital firms<br />

(Panel B). Both groups of companies do not differ in terms of age, total assets, employment and industry<br />

focus. Young, less legitimate venture capital firms select companies with higher intangible asset on total<br />

asset ratios. Moreover, I find that younger, less legitimate venture capital firms are also more likely to<br />

select companies that successfully applied for patents. It indicates that younger less legitimate venture<br />

capital firms are more likely to select ventures with higher growth potential as poxied by their intangible<br />

asset ratio and patenting activity. Conversely, older more legitimate venture capital firms select companies<br />

with lower growth potential as proxied by their intangible asset ratio and patenting activity. Despite lower<br />

or at least equal initial growth potential the companies backed by more legitimate venture capital investors<br />

exhibit higher subsequent growth 20 .<br />

Why would young venture capital firms be more likely to invest in companies with high growth potential<br />

compared to their older counterparts? Young venture capital firms have incentives to grandstand or take<br />

actions that signal their ability to their own potential investors (Gompers, 1996). This is important as<br />

previous research indicates that past performance influences fundraising ability (Lakonishok, Shleifer,<br />

Thaler, and Vishny, 1991). Hence, younger venture capital firms have an incentive to bring companies<br />

public earlier than older venture capital firms, this in order to establish legitimacy in the marketplace and<br />

successfully raise capital for new funds (Gompers, 1996). <strong>Extending</strong> this line of reasoning, young venture<br />

capital firms may have a large incentive to invest in companies with high growth potential that can be<br />

brought public quickly.<br />

20 The characteristics included in Table 3.5 are only coarse characteristics (i.e. intangible assets on total assets, company age,<br />

company size…). Venture capital firms may also select on unobserved characteristics. However, the results reported here are in<br />

line with the findings reported in Chapter 4. In this chapter, detailed case study evidence indicates that biotechnology ventures<br />

backed by more experienced versus less experienced venture capital investors did not differ systematically in terms of human<br />

capital, alliance capital, technology and market-orientation at the time of the first venture capital investment. Hence, more<br />

experienced investors do not necessarily select the best companies ex-ante. However, the more experienced investors were more<br />

active in professionalizing the management team of their portfolio companies and helped their portfolio companies extensively<br />

with raising follow-on finance from other experienced investors among other value adding activities.<br />

127


3.6. Discussion and Conclusion<br />

Most prior research treated venture capital firms as a homogenous group, thereby obscuring experience<br />

and legitimacy differences between venture capital firms (Hsu, 2004). It remains unclear whether it is<br />

particularly the experience or legitimacy of the venture capital firm which will benefit venture<br />

development. Moreover, recent studies explicitly incorporating venture capital firm heterogeneity almost<br />

exclusively focus on explaining fund performance. In this study, I take the perspective of the portfolio<br />

company and examine the impact of venture capital firm heterogeneity on the growth pattern of venture<br />

capital backed companies.<br />

Using learning and signaling theory, I provide testable hypotheses on the impact of venture capital firm<br />

experience and legitimacy on portfolio company growth. I use a unique longitudinal database tracking<br />

employment and total assets within 94 companies for up to five years after the initial investment. Results<br />

indicate that both investor experience and legitimacy significantly influence the (non-linear) growth path<br />

of venture capital backed companies. However, not all experience matters. <strong>Companies</strong> backed by<br />

investors with more overall deal experience do not exhibit different growth curves compared to companies<br />

backed by investors with limited overall deal experience. I find no support for hypothesis 1A.<br />

Nevertheless, companies backed by investors with high industry experience exhibit steeper growth curves<br />

both in employment and total assets, thereby offering support for hypothesis 1B. Furthermore, companies<br />

backed more legitimate venture capital firms exhibit higher growth curves compared to companies backed<br />

by venture capital firms that lack legitimacy in the marketplace thereby offering support for hypothesis 2.<br />

3.6.1. Academic Contributions<br />

<strong>From</strong> a theoretical standpoint this study contributes in at least three ways. First, prior research has<br />

demonstrated a tension between economists and institutional theorists on who the most valuable partners<br />

are for young resource-constrained ventures (Rindova, Williamson, Petkova and Sever, 2005). It remains<br />

128


unclear whether entrepreneurial ventures will particularly benefit from connecting with partners that are<br />

good or known in the marketplace? Economists stress the role of experienced firms which are likely to<br />

provide higher quality tangible and knowledge-based resources through learning based on past actions.<br />

Institutional theorists stress the role of partner legitimacy which is transferred to entrepreneurial ventures,<br />

thereby influencing stakeholder perceptions making the latter more likely to transact with the venture.<br />

This study demonstrates the artificial nature of this tension, as the development of entrepreneurial ventures<br />

benefits both from connecting with more experienced and legitimate partners. Hence, both experience and<br />

legitimacy plays a complementary role and entrepreneurial ventures are likely to benefit both from<br />

forming relationships with good and well-known partners.<br />

Second, prior research unambiguously demonstrated that more experienced and legitimate firms perform<br />

better (Pollock and Rindova, 2003; Hoang and Rothaermel, 2005; Sorensen, 2007). More experienced<br />

and legitimate firms are, for example, able to ask a higher premium from entrepreneurial ventures that are<br />

willing to connect with them (Hsu, 2004). Given the cost of affiliating with more experienced and<br />

legitimate partners, it is important to consider how relationships with these partners affect the<br />

development of entrepreneurial companies. This study demonstrates how entrepreneurial ventures<br />

connecting with more experienced and legitimate partners are able to accumulate more human resources<br />

and total assets. Hence, as growth in employment is a good proxy for the value of private entrepreneurial<br />

companies (Davila, Foster and Gupta, 2003), the premium required by more experienced and legitimate<br />

investors may be worthwhile.<br />

Third, this study also starts to disentangle the processes underlying the higher growth of entrepreneurial<br />

ventures backed by more experienced and legitimate partners. Experienced and legitimate partners may be<br />

able to both select more promising ventures and contribute better intangible knowledge-based resources. It<br />

is unlikely that selection drives our results. The companies getting finance from more experienced and<br />

legitimate investors do not differ systematically in age and size prior to the initial investment. Results do<br />

129


suggest that venture capital firms with high industry deal experience are more likely to invest in the<br />

biotechnology industry, which is one of the riskiest industries in our modern economy. Furthermore,<br />

results suggest that companies getting finance from more legitimate venture capital firms may have lower<br />

growth opportunities prior to the investment as proxied by the intangible assets ratio and patenting<br />

activity. In sum, this indicates that results are not entirely driven by more experienced and legitimate<br />

investors selecting more promising companies before the investment, but also by their contribution of<br />

superior knowledge-based resources and the stronger signals they convey to outside stakeholders after the<br />

investment.<br />

<strong>From</strong> an empirical standpoint this study addresses two related shortcomings in organizational growth<br />

studies. First, growth studies often look only at first and last year sizes and ignore development in between<br />

these two time points (Delmar, Davidsson and Gartner, 2003; Weinzimmer, Nystrom and Freeman 1998).<br />

Second, researchers typically make highly simplistic (and often implicit) assumptions about the temporal<br />

growth pattern across time. It is common for researchers to assume that growth occurs as a quantum size<br />

leap at one particular point in time or that growth is a linear process (See Davidsson and Wiklund, 2006<br />

for a literature overview and critical comment). While nearly all organizational scholars agree that growth<br />

is a dynamic non-linear process, few scholars explicitly incorporate this idea in theory building and<br />

empirical testing.<br />

This study explicitly models the dynamic nature of growth and demonstrates how LMMs can be used for<br />

that purpose. LMMs allow modeling non-linear change trajectories and account for individual differences<br />

between companies as well as similarities among groups of companies (Weiss, 2005; Fitzmaurice, Laird<br />

and Ware, 2004). Despite major advances in statistical methods for longitudinal analysis in recent years,<br />

the methods have not been widely used (Fitzmaurice, Laird and Ware, 2004).<br />

130


3.6.2. Implications for Practice<br />

Entrepreneurs typically have to balance the pressure of running out of cash and the time needed to search<br />

for desirable investors. This study indicates that the decision from which investor to raise finance may<br />

have a long-term impact, besides the provision of cash at the time of the investment. Hence, raising initial<br />

finance from desirable venture capital firms may be worth the higher cost (Hsu, 2004). Moreover, a<br />

complaint often heard from entrepreneurs is that experienced and legitimate venture capital firms are<br />

especially wary to offer finance to young and small entrepreneurial companies. I did not find evidence,<br />

however, that more experienced and legitimate venture capital firms select older or larger entrepreneurial<br />

companies. Overall, my findings are encouraging for entrepreneurs as they suggest that even young and<br />

small entrepreneurial ventures have the potential for receiving investments from desirable investors.<br />

Results may also be informative for government officials. All over the world programs are implemented to<br />

increase the supply of venture capital, especially to young, innovative and growth-oriented entrepreneurial<br />

companies, which are considered to be the motor of any modern economy. Policy makers should take into<br />

account that not only to supply of financial capital as a commodity good is important. Policy measures<br />

targeting experienced and legitimate investors may have disproportionally positive effects on employment<br />

generation and asset accumulation within an economy.<br />

References<br />

Amit R., Brander J. and Zott C. (1998) “Why do venture capital firms exist? Theory and Canadian<br />

evidence.” Journal of Business Venturing 49: 371-402.<br />

Baum J.A.C. and Silverman B.S. (2004) “Picking winners or building them? Alliance, intellectual, and<br />

human capital as selection criteria in venture financing and performance of biotechnology startups.”<br />

Journal of Business Venturing 19: 411-436.<br />

131


Baum J.A.C., Calabrese T. and Silverman B.S. (2000) “Don't go it alone: Alliance network composition<br />

and startups' performance in Canadian biotechnology.” Strategic Management Journal 21: 267-294.<br />

Berger A.N. and Udell G.F. (1998) “The economics of small business finance: The roles of private equity<br />

and debt markets in the financial growth cycle.” Journal of Banking and Finance 22: 613-673.<br />

Black B.S. and Gilson R.J. (1998) “Venture capital and the structure of capital markets: banks versus<br />

stock markets.” Journal of Financial Economics 47: 243-277.<br />

Bottazzi L., Da Rin M. and Hellmann T. (2007) “Who are the active investors?: Evidence from venture<br />

capital” Journal of Financial Economics 89: 488-512.<br />

Carpenter R.E. and Petersen B.C. (2002) “Is the growth of small firms constrained by internal finance?”<br />

The Review of Economics and Statistics 84: 298-309.<br />

Cassar G. (2004) “The financing of business start-ups.” Journal of Business Venturing 19: 261-283.<br />

Cohen W.M. and Levinthal D.A. (1990) “Absorptive-capacity - A new perspective on learning and<br />

innovation.” Administrative Science Quarterly 35: 128-152.<br />

Davidsson and Wiklund (2006) “Conceptual and empirical challenges in the study of firm growth” In: P<br />

Davidsson, F Delmar, J Wiklund (ed.), Entrepreneurship and the <strong>Growth</strong> of Firms, 39-61, Edward Elgar<br />

Publishing.<br />

Davila A., Foster G. and Gupta M. (2003) “Venture capital financing and the growth of startup firms.”<br />

Journal of Business Venturing 18: 689-708.<br />

Delmar F., Davidsson P. and Gartner W.B. (2003) “Arriving at the high-growth firm.” Journal of Business<br />

Venturing 18: 189-216.<br />

Dimov D.P. and De Clercq D. (2006) “Venture capital investment strategy and portfolio failure rate: A<br />

longitudinal study.” Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 30: 207-223.<br />

132


Dimov D.P. and Shepherd D.A. (2005) “Human capital theory and venture capital firms: Exploring "home<br />

runs" and "strike outs".” Journal of Business Venturing 20: 1-21.<br />

Elango B., Fried V.H., Hisrich R.D. and Polonchek A. (1995) “How venture capital firms differ.” Journal<br />

of Business Venturing 10: 157-179.<br />

Fitzmaurice G.M., Laird N.M. and Ware J.H. (2004) “Applied Longitudinal Analysis.” John Wiley and<br />

Sons, NJ.<br />

Fried V.H., Bruton G.D. and Hisrich R.D. (1998) “Strategy and the board of directors in venture capital-<br />

backed firms.” Journal of Business Venturing 13: 493-503.<br />

Gompers P., Kovner A., Lerner J. and Scharfstein D. (2008) “Venture capital investment cycles: The<br />

impact of public markets.” Journal of Financial Economics 87: 1-23.<br />

Gompers P.A. (1996) “Grandstanding in the venture capital industry.” Journal of Financial Economics 42:<br />

133-156.<br />

Gompers P.A. and Lerner J. (1996) “The use of covenants: An empirical analysis of venture partnership<br />

agreements.” Journal of Law and Economics 39: 463-498.<br />

Graebner M. and Eisenhardt K.M. (2004) “The seller’s side of the story: Acquisition as courtship and<br />

governance as syndicate in entrepreneurial firms.” Administrative Science Quarterly 49: 366-403.<br />

Hallen B. (2008) “The causes and consequences of the initial network positions of new organizations:<br />

<strong>From</strong> whom do entrepreneurs receive investments?” Administrative Science Quarterly 53: 685-718.<br />

Harhoff D., Stahl K. and Woywode M. (1998) “Legal form, growth and exit for West German firms –<br />

Results for manufacturing, construction, trade and service industries.” The Journal of Industrial<br />

Economics 46: 453-488.<br />

Hellmann T. and Puri M. (2002) “Venture capital and the professionalization of start-up firms: Empirical<br />

evidence” Journal of Finance 57: 169–197.<br />

133


Hoang H. and Rothaermel F.T. (2005) “The effect of general and partner-specific alliance experience on<br />

joint R&D project performance.” Academy of Management Journal 48: 332-345.<br />

Hochberg Y.V., Ljungqvist A. and Lu Y. (2007) “Whom you know matters: Venture capital networks and<br />

investment performance.” Journal of Finance 62: 251-301.<br />

Hovakimian A., Opler T. and Titman S. (2001) “The debt-equity choice.” The Journal of Financial and<br />

Quantitative Analysis 36: 1-24.<br />

Hsu D.H. and Ziedonis R.H. (2007) “Patents as quality signals for entrepreneurial ventures” Working<br />

Paper, Wharton School.<br />

Hsu D.H. (2004) “What do entrepreneurs pay for venture capital affiliation?” Journal of Finance 59: 1805-<br />

1844.<br />

Janney J.J. and Folta T.B. (2006) “Moderating effects of investor experience on the signaling value of<br />

private equity placements.” Journal of Business Venturing 21: 27-44.<br />

Janney J.J. and Folta T.B. (2003) “Signaling through private equity placements and its impact on the<br />

valuation of biotechnology firms.” Journal of Business Venturing 18: 361-380.<br />

Jovanovic B. (1982) “Selection and evolution of industry.” Econometrica 50, 642-670.<br />

Katila R., Rosenberger J.D. and Eisenhardt K.M. (2008) “Swimming with sharks: Technology<br />

ventures, defense mechanisms and corporate relationships.” Administrative Science Quarterly 53: 295-<br />

332.<br />

Kortum S. and Lerner J. (2000) “Assessing the contribution of venture capital to innovation” The RAND<br />

Journal of Economics 31: 674-692.<br />

Lakonishok J., Shleifer A., Thaler R., Vishny R. (1991) “Window dressing by pension fund managers.”<br />

American Economic Review 81: 227-231.<br />

134


Leary M.T. and Roberts M.R. (2005) “Do firms rebalance their capital structure.” Journal of Finance 60:<br />

2575-2619.<br />

Lee C., Lee K. and Pennings J.M. (2001) “Internal capabilities, external networks, and performance: A<br />

study on technology-based ventures.” Strategic Management Journal 22: 615-640.<br />

Lerner J. (1999) “The government as venture capitalist: The long-run impact of the SBIR program.”<br />

Journal of Business 72: 285-318.<br />

Lerner J. (1995) “Venture capitalists and the oversight of private firms.” Journal of Finance 50: 301-318.<br />

Levinthal D.A. and March J.G. (1993) “The myopia of learning.” Strategic Management Journal 14: 95-<br />

112.<br />

Levitt B. and March J.G. (1988) “Organizational learning.” Annual Review of Sociology 14: 319-340.<br />

Megginson W.L. and Weiss K.A. (1991) “Venture capitalist certification in initial public offerings.”<br />

Journal of Finance 46: 879-903.<br />

Muzyka D., Birley S. and Leleux B. (1996) “Trade-offs in the investment decisions of European venture<br />

capitalists.” Journal of Business Venturing, 11: 273-287.<br />

Myers S.C. (1984) “The capital structure puzzle.” Journal of Finance 39: 575-592.<br />

Nelson R.R. and Winter S.G. (1982) “An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change.” Belknap Press,<br />

Cambridge, MA.<br />

Norton E. and Tenenbaum B.H. (1993) “Specialization versus diversification as a venture capital<br />

investment strategy.” Journal of Business Venturing 8: 431-442.<br />

Oliver C. (1997) “Sustainable competitive advantage: Combining institutional and resource-based views.”<br />

Strategic Management Journal 18: 697-713.<br />

135


Peixoto J.L. (1987) “Hierarchical variable selection in polynomial regression models.” The American<br />

Statistician 41: 311-313.<br />

Pennings J.M., Barkema H.G. and Douma S.W. (1994) “Organizational learning and diversification.”<br />

Academy of Management Journal 37: 608-640.<br />

Pollock T.G. and Rindova V.P. (2003) “Media legitimation effects in the market for Initial Public<br />

Offerings.” Academy of Management Journal 46: 631-642.<br />

Puri M. and Zarutskie R. (2008) “On the lifecycle dynamics of venture-capital- and non-venture-capital-<br />

financed firms” Working Paper, US Census Bureau Center for Economic Studies.<br />

Rao H. (1994) “The social construction of reputation: Certification contests, legitimation, and the survival<br />

of organizations in the American automobile industry: 1895-1912.” Strategic Management Journal 15, 29-<br />

44.<br />

Rindova V.P., Williamson I.O., Petkova A.P. and Sever J.M. (2005) “Being good or being known: An<br />

empirical examination of the dimensions, antecedents, and consequences of organizational reputation.”<br />

Academy of Management Journal 48, 1033-1049.<br />

Sapienza H.J., Manigart S. and Vermeir W. (1996) “Venture capitalists governance and value added in<br />

four countries.” Journal of Business Venturing 11: 439-469.<br />

Schwienbacher A. (2002) “An empirical analysis of venture capital exists in Europe and the United<br />

States.” Univ. of California at Berkeley and Univ. of Namur.<br />

Shepherd D.A., Zacharakis A. and Baron R.A. (2003) “VC’s decision processes: Evidence suggesting<br />

more experience may not always be better.” Journal of Business Venturing 18: 381-401.<br />

Sorensen M. (2007) “How smart is smart money? A two-sided matching model of venture capital.”<br />

Journal of Finance 62: 2725-2762.<br />

Sorenson O. and Stuart T.E. (2001) “Syndication networks and the spatial distribution of venture capital<br />

investments.” American Journal of Sociology 106: 1546-1588.<br />

136


Stinchcombe A.L. (1965) “Social structure and organizations”. In J.G. March (ed.), Handbook of<br />

Organizations, 153-193, Chicago: Rand McNally.<br />

Stuart T.E., Hoang H. and Hybels R.C. (1999) “Interorganizational endorsements and the performance of<br />

entrepreneurial ventures.” Administrative Science Quarterly 44: 315-349.<br />

Stuart T.E. (2000) “Interorganizational alliances and the performance of firms: A study of growth and<br />

innovation rates in a high-technology industry.” Strategic Management Journal 21: 791-811.<br />

Titman S. and Wessels R. (1988) “The determinants of capital structure choice.” Journal of Finance 43: 1-<br />

19.<br />

Van de Ven A.H. (2007) “Engaged scholarship: A guide for organizational and social research.” Oxford<br />

University Press.<br />

Villalonga B. (2004) “Intangible resources, Tobin’s q and sustainability of performance differences.”<br />

Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 54: 205-230.<br />

Weinzimmer L.G., Nystrom P.C. and Freeman S.J. (1998) “Measuring organizational growth: Issues,<br />

Consequences and Guidelines.” Journal of Management 24: 235-262.<br />

Weiss R.E. (2005) “Modeling longitudinal data.” Springer, NY.<br />

Zarutskie R. (2007) “Do venture capitalists affect investment performance? Evidence from first-time<br />

funds.” Fuqua School of Business, Duke University.<br />

Zollo M. and Winter S.G. (2002) “Deliberate learning and the evolution of dynamic capabilities.”<br />

Organization Science 13: 339-351.<br />

137


Appendix 1: Robustness Check<br />

In the paper I used venture capital firm age (dummy) as a proxy for legitimacy. An alternative proxy for<br />

legitimacy is the number of times a venture capital firm has been named in Belgian financial newspapers<br />

over the period 1995 until the year of investment. The media presents stakeholders with information that<br />

affects impression formation and the legitimization of firms (Pollock and Rindova, 2003). The number of<br />

venture capital firm citations ranges from zero to 654. Given this high dispersion I use the natural<br />

logarithm of this measure in subsequent analyses. It is important to note that venture capital firm citations<br />

is highly correlated with overall deal experience (0.690). Hence, venture capital firms that appeared more<br />

in the media conducted more investments. The correlation between venture capital firm citation and<br />

industry deal experience (0.323) and venture capital firm citations and venture capital firm age (0.270) is<br />

much lower.<br />

Table 3.6 presents additional LMMs modeling change in employment and total assets conditional upon<br />

venture capital firm citations. The positive and significant venture capital firm citation by linear trend<br />

interaction in the employment model indicates that companies backed by investors that appear more<br />

frequently in the financial press exhibit a steeper growth curve in employment. These results are not<br />

confirmed for growth in total assets. Interestingly, venture capital firm citations remain significant in a<br />

nested model including venture capital firm age (not reported). It indicates that legitimacy provided by age<br />

and legitimate provided by the media may act as complements.<br />

138


TABLE 3.6<br />

Conditional Analysis for Employment and Total Assets<br />

Employment Total Assets<br />

E3 TA3<br />

INTERCEPT -0.1007 1.7155<br />

VCF Citations 0.2773 0.1807<br />

Company Age 0.1113 *** 0.0572 †<br />

<strong>High</strong> Tech (Dummy) 0.2616 -0.3328<br />

Intangible Assets Ratio -0.0089 *** -0.0138 **<br />

Initial Investment Size 0.1048 0.5686 ***<br />

VCF Size 0.4502 0.1542<br />

LINEAR TREND 0.4502 *** 0.07684<br />

VCF Citations*Time 0.0996 * 0.0971<br />

Company Age*Time -0.1363 * 0.0011<br />

QUADRATIC TREND -0.1652 *** -0.0389 †<br />

CUBIC TREND 0.0179 ** ---<br />

Null Model Likelihood Ratio Test<br />

Chi-Square 663.3 *** 441.96 ***<br />

n 477<br />

† p < .10, * p < .05, ** p < .01, *** p < .001 (Conservative two-tailed tests).<br />

487<br />

139


Chapter 4: Early Differences and Persistence in the<br />

Entrepreneurial Finance Process: Evidence from <strong>High</strong>- and<br />

Low-<strong>Growth</strong> Biotechnology Startups<br />

Tom Vanacker<br />

Ghent University, Department of Accounting and Corporate Finance, Kuiperskaai 55E, 9000 Gent, Belgium;<br />

TomR.Vanacker@UGent.be<br />

Sophie Manigart<br />

Ghent University, Department of Accounting and Corporate Finance, Kuiperskaai 55E, 9000 Gent, Belgium and<br />

Vlerick Leuven Gent Management School, Reep 1, 9000 Gent, Belgium; Sophie.Manigart@UGent.be<br />

Miguel Meuleman<br />

Vlerick Leuven Gent Management School, Reep 1, 9000 Gent, Belgium and Nottingham University, Jubilee<br />

Campus, Nottingham NG8 1BB, United Kingdom; Miguel.Meuleman@Vlerick.be<br />

The paper benefited from the comments of Gavin Cassar, Daniel Forbes, Hans Landström, Peter Roosenboom, Harry<br />

Sapienza and Shaker Zahra, as well as from seminar participants at University of Minnesota (Carlson School of<br />

Management), Erasmus University (Rotterdam School of Management) and Ghent University. A prior version of this<br />

paper was presented at the 2008 Academy of Management Meeting and selected for inclusion in the 2008 Process<br />

Research Workshop. We thank Katleen Baeyens for excellent research assistance and Bart Clarysse for generously<br />

granting access to data on Flemish research-based startups. The financial support of the Intercollegiate Center for<br />

Management Science (I.C.M.) is gratefully acknowledged.<br />

140


4.1. Abstract<br />

We study financial resource mobilization from startup through development in both high- and low-growth<br />

entrepreneurial ventures. For this purpose, we use nine longitudinal case studies of young biotechnology<br />

ventures. Contrary to the most influential theories in corporate finance, which portray the finance process<br />

as either a teleological or a life-cycle model, we reframe this process as an evolutionary model. More<br />

broadly, we demonstrate that with whom entrepreneurs connect early-on influences how easily their<br />

ventures mobilize future resources. While entrepreneurial ventures are often depicted as passive in<br />

relationship formation with more established resource-rich firms, we show how entrepreneurs play a key<br />

role in early resource mobilization from these firms. More specifically, entrepreneurs engage in a local<br />

search and only target one or a few related firms to mobilize early resources. Moreover, we identify<br />

multiple processes explaining why early relationships that were critical to mobilize resources during the<br />

startup phase may both facilitate and constrain entrepreneurs in their resource mobilization efforts during<br />

the development phase.<br />

4.2. Introduction<br />

Young ventures typically lack social approval, tested routines and sufficient resources, which increases<br />

their risk of failure compared to more established companies (Stinchcombe, 1965). Young ventures may<br />

reduce these liabilities of newness by forming relationships with more established resource-rich firms<br />

(Baum, Calabrese, and Silverman, 2000). These relationships not only allow direct access to vital<br />

resources (Stuart, 2000), but also upgrade the focal venture’s own reputation, which makes risk-averse<br />

stakeholders, like customers, financiers and employees, more likely to transact with the venture (Stuart,<br />

Hoang, and Hybels, 1999; Stuart, 2000; Davila, Foster, and Gupta, 2003). Ventures that are able to<br />

mobilize more strategic resources at startup are likely to develop a competitive advantage over their<br />

resource-constrained peers (Lee, Lee, and Pennings, 2001). The goal of this study is to investigate<br />

141


financial resource mobilization from startup through development in both high- and low-growth<br />

entrepreneurial ventures.<br />

To date, research has only provided partial guidance on how different resource positions originate (Noda<br />

and Collis, 2001; Ahuja and Katila, 2004; Hsu, 2007). While young ventures are often depicted as passive<br />

bystanders in relationship formation, it is generally assumed that established resource-rich firms dominate<br />

relationship formation (Katila, Rosenberger, and Eisenhardt, 2008). The latter are more likely to provide<br />

resources to entrepreneurs with proven reputations and prior direct or indirect working relationships (Uzzi,<br />

1999; Shane and Cable, 2002; Hsu, 2007; Hallen, 2008). If entrepreneurs lack prior experience and<br />

working relationships, an alternative path to mobilize resources from established resource-rich firms is to<br />

first demonstrate outstanding venture accomplishments (Hallen, 2008). Nevertheless, it is problematic that<br />

the majority of entrepreneurs lack prior business experience (Westhead, Ucbasaran, and Wright, 2003)<br />

and often require substantial amounts of outside resources from startup (Puri and Zarutskie, 2008). A key<br />

challenge for entrepreneurs is hence to convince established resource-rich firms to form a relationship and<br />

provide the needed resources (Hsu, 2004). Overall, our knowledge of the mechanisms initiating<br />

differences in early resource positions between ventures remains limited, especially in settings where<br />

entrepreneurs lack prior business experience and working relationships.<br />

Besides focusing on how different resource positions originate, research needs to further explore dynamics<br />

in resource mobilization. Early relationships with established resource-rich firms may invoke a cycle of<br />

accumulating advantages for young ventures thereby expediting the mobilization of resources across time<br />

(Stuart, Hoang, and Hybels, 1999). However, the same relationships that were critical to mobilize startup<br />

resources may also constrain ventures in their subsequent resource mobilization and development (Maurer<br />

and Ebers, 2006). Hence, more insight is needed in the processes affecting resource mobilization and the<br />

contingencies under which early relationships become an asset or a liability (Hoang and Antoncic, 2003).<br />

142


In this study, we focus on the mobilization of financial resources from startup through development. The<br />

finance process is critical for at least two reasons. First, organizational studies offer suggestive evidence<br />

that the finance process may act as a key prompt initiating sustainable differences in development between<br />

high- and low-growth ventures. The finance process is likely to initiate changes in how ventures arrange<br />

and reconfigure their social capital (Maurer and Ebers, 2006) and influences the structure and experience<br />

of the management team (Beckman and Burton, 2008). Second, ties to outside investors are typically the<br />

first and one of the most critical ties formed by early-stage, high-potential ventures (Katila, Rosenberger,<br />

and Eisenhardt, 2008).<br />

We ask three related questions: (a) how does the finance process differ between high- and low-growth<br />

ventures, (b) how do differences originate and (c) how do differences persist across time? We chose to<br />

conduct comparative longitudinal case studies of high- and low-growth entrepreneurial ventures, because<br />

of our interest in looking at rarely explored questions for which extant theory did not appear to be<br />

particularly revealing. In such situations, case studies are likely to generate novel and more accurate<br />

insights into the phenomenon under study compared to other research methods (Eisenhardt, 1989a).<br />

In contrast with current theories in corporate finance that portray the finance process as either a<br />

teleological or a life-cycle model, we reframe the finance process as an evolutionary model. It indicates<br />

that one path to increase our understanding of how financial decisions are made may well lie in<br />

systematically studying the finance process right from the start. More broadly, we contribute to the<br />

literature on resource mobilization and initial network formation within entrepreneurial ventures. We<br />

demonstrate the key role played by entrepreneurs in shaping early differences in resource positions. More<br />

specifically, entrepreneurs engage in a local search and prefer to connect to related firms when mobilizing<br />

startup resources. We demonstrate how early decisions from whom entrepreneurs mobilize resources may<br />

both facilitate and constrain ventures in their subsequent resource mobilization and identify several<br />

143


processes that make it difficult for ventures to replicate successful resource mobilization strategies from<br />

their peers.<br />

The paper first explains the research method. We then present the nine entrepreneurial ventures, and the<br />

three major findings that relate to how the finance process differs between high- and low-growth ventures,<br />

how differences originate and how differences persist across time. We conclude by discussing theoretical<br />

contributions to corporate finance and, more broadly, organizational research.<br />

4.3. Methods<br />

4.3.1. Research Design<br />

The research design is a longitudinal, multiple case study involving nine young biotechnology ventures.<br />

Multiple longitudinal cases are particularly suitable to study dynamic processes (Van de Ven, 2007) and<br />

enable a replication logic in which each case serves to confirm or disconfirm inferences drawn from the<br />

others (Yin, 1984). We employ an embedded design (i.e. multiple levels of analysis) that includes<br />

entrepreneurs, ventures, investors and the finance process. Although an embedded design is more complex<br />

than a holistic design, it permits the development of richer, more reliable models (Yin, 1984).<br />

We chose young biotechnology ventures as our research setting for at least two reasons. First, it allows us<br />

to focus on the mobilization of venture capital (e.g., professional venture capital investors, business angels<br />

and corporate investors), without ignoring other potentially important finance alternatives. More<br />

traditional sources of finance, such as internal finance and debt finance are typically unavailable and even<br />

unsuitable for most young biotechnology ventures (Pisano, 2006). Furthermore, in order to get at a stage<br />

where it is possible to raise finance from large pharmaceutical companies (if that is part of the strategy of<br />

the venture) and public equity finance, it is typically necessary to first raise several rounds of venture<br />

144


capital (Nilsson, 2001). Second, young biotechnology ventures are characterized by high risk and<br />

uncertainty, which makes finance constraints particularly acute in this setting (Himmelberg and Petersen,<br />

1994). Hence, mobilizing financial resources is of heightened importance and entrepreneurs are expected<br />

to devote considerable energy and time to raising finance (Greene, 1999).<br />

We selected cases based on a theoretical sampling procedure (Eisenhardt, 1989a). To generate insights on<br />

how the finance process of young biotechnology ventures relates to growth, we selected matched pairs of<br />

biotechnology ventures that operated under similar conditions and regulatory regimes but differed<br />

considerably with respect to their growth (Table 4.1). Young biotechnology ventures were labeled as high-<br />

or low-growth based on widely applied proxies, such as employment growth, total asset growth and<br />

patenting rate (Maurer and Ebers, 2006). These dimensions gauge biotechnology startups’ growth across a<br />

diverse range of dimensions critical to early success, such as success in recruiting human resources,<br />

investments in tangible and intangible assets, and development of intellectual property (Baum, Calabrese,<br />

and Silverman, 2000).<br />

All cases are dedicated Flemish biotechnology ventures active in research and development (R&D). We<br />

do not consider ventures from traditional sectors whose activities only partially involve biotechnology. In<br />

order to be included in our research, the ventures had to undertake R&D to develop new innovative<br />

products or services. This ensures that we study a more homogenous group of ventures with high growth<br />

ambitions and large financing needs (Nilsson, 2001). We make sure that the cases are active in R&D by<br />

asking a filter question through preliminary telephone interviews.<br />

We restrict our cases to Flemish ventures to control for institutional and spatial contingencies that may<br />

affect venture founding, development and growth (Maurer and Ebers, 2006). The Flemish biotechnology<br />

cluster is vibrant, but developing. The number of biotechnology ventures per inhabitant and the number of<br />

employees per biotechnology venture lies above the European average (Flanders Institute for<br />

145


Biotechnology, 2002). The biotechnology industry, however, is relatively young. Most of the medical<br />

biotechnology ventures have been founded in 1995 or later. This implies that Flemish biotechnology<br />

ventures are typically founded by pure scientists. There is still no well-developed market of “second-<br />

generation” biotechnology managers (Flanders Institute for Biotechnology, 2002). This is similar to other<br />

Continental European biotechnology industries, but stands in contrast to the UK and US biotechnology<br />

industries where scientific entrepreneurs accumulated founding and management experience through<br />

earlier foundings (Maurer and Ebers, 2006). Limiting our cases to Flemish biotechnology ventures thus<br />

has the advantage that founding teams are rather similar: all are characterized by limited prior business<br />

experience and limited formal education in business administration. Our findings should therefore be<br />

interpreted in the context of an emerging industry.<br />

We selected matched pairs of academic spin-offs, corporate spin-offs and spin-offs from specialized<br />

research institutes (Table 4.1). The origin of one venture, Myosic, is dual: a university and a corporate<br />

jointly developed its core technology. Given the R&D-intensive nature, it is unlikely that entrepreneurs<br />

will start an independent biotechnology venture. As a result, most biotechnology ventures originate from<br />

academia or the business community. Ventures from different origins need and acquire different types of<br />

resources due to their different background and hence their finance process might be different (Lindelof<br />

and Lofsten, 2005). Our theoretical sampling procedure allows us to control for possible differences in<br />

venture origin.<br />

Finally, it is well established that venture capital investments show a cyclical pattern (Gompers and<br />

Lerner, 1998). We control for the availability of venture capital by sampling matched pairs raising their<br />

first venture capital during “hot” and “cold” markets (Table 4.1). Pharmaleads and Theraptosis raised<br />

initial venture capital during 2000. This was a record year, both in terms of amount of finance raised by<br />

European venture capital investors and in terms of amount invested in their portfolio companies<br />

(European Venture Capital Association, 2005). Entomed, Myosic, AC Pharma, Irogene, Genom, I-Zyme<br />

146


and Aptanomics raised initial venture capital after 2000, a period during which venture capital investments<br />

decreased dramatically, especially in high-tech sectors (European Venture Capital Association, 2005).<br />

Most of our cases raised initial finance during “cold” markets. This is because our research interest was in<br />

studying dynamics in the finance process of young ventures that were maximum five years old at the time<br />

of first data collection. During “cold” markets, less finance is available compared to “hot” markets, which<br />

might lead entrepreneurs to devote more time to locate and negotiate with potential investors.<br />

DEDICATED FLEMISH<br />

BIOTECHNOLOGY VENTURES<br />

ACTIVE IN R&D<br />

MARKET<br />

SENTIMENT<br />

HOT MARKET<br />

(1999-2000)<br />

COLD<br />

MARKET<br />

(2002-2003)<br />

TABLE 4.1<br />

Theoretical Sampling Procedure a<br />

FIRM ORIGIN<br />

a The names of the ventures are disguised to guarantee anonymity.<br />

LOW GROWTH<br />

COMPANIES<br />

HIGH GROWTH<br />

COMPANIES<br />

ACADEMIC Pharmaleads Theraptosis<br />

ACADEMIC Entomed, (Myosic) AC Pharma<br />

CORPORATE Irogene, (Myosic) Genom<br />

RESEARCH INSTITUTE I-Zyme Aptanomics<br />

The characteristics of the cases are summarized in table 4.2. The oldest venture is Genom, founded in<br />

1999, while the youngest venture is Myosic, founded in 2003 21 . Ventures are active in areas such as<br />

diagnostics, therapeutics, environment and technology platforms. We ensured that matched pairs of cases<br />

are active in similar areas, as a venture’s activity within the biotechnology sector might influence both the<br />

availability of finance and venture growth (Maurer and Ebers, 2006). Nevertheless, a perfect match was<br />

not always possible.<br />

21 Before the legal founding of ventures, scientists typically worked on the technology for many years within the university or the<br />

parent company. Hence, the legal founding year may be arbitrary and ventures that are legally founded in the same year may be in<br />

a different stage of development at that time. This explains why we prefer to select matched cases that raised initial venture<br />

capital in the same year, which indicates all ventures were deemed “investor-ready” at that point in time. Nevertheless, in most<br />

cases the year of initial venture capital investment and founding year are the same.<br />

147


Table 4.2 differentiates between high- and low-growth ventures. The initial financial accounts indicate<br />

ventures were rather similar in terms of employment in their first year of operation. Furthermore, from the<br />

initial accounts we do not observe a systematic difference in the amount of total assets accumulated in the<br />

first year of operation 22 . At startup, ventures had no patents on their name yet, but all had an exclusive<br />

license on a patent or patent portfolio from the university or parent company. All cases appeared in a<br />

confidential listing of ventures that applied for R&D subsidies from the most important subsidy-granting<br />

agency in their region of operation, which further confirms their active involvement in R&D. Based on the<br />

2006 financial accounts, high-growth ventures that survived as independent entities employ between 33<br />

and 67 people, while low-growth ventures only employ between three and four people. The amount of<br />

assets ranges from €9,848,000 to €119,559,000 for high-growth cases, while the maximum amount of<br />

assets equals only €657,000 for the surviving low-growth cases. <strong>High</strong>-growth ventures were granted a<br />

minimum of 10 and a maximum of 22 new patents up to 2006. Low-growth ventures have not been<br />

granted patents since founding, except Entomed with two patents granted.<br />

The median number of finance rounds equals two, with a minimum of one and a maximum of four. In<br />

none of the cases had an investor exited at the time of our main data collection effort (interviews).<br />

However, in some cases investors realized a partial or full exit while we followed the cases in real time<br />

and this under different forms such as an IPO, trade sale or failure. This implies that our findings do not<br />

suffer from a success or survivorship bias.<br />

22 One should be careful when comparing initial figures across cases, as there may be important differences in the length of the<br />

initial reporting period, which ranges from a minimum of seven months to a maximum of 23 months.<br />

148


Case<br />

Founding year<br />

Activity profile<br />

TABLE 4.2<br />

Description of Biotechnology Cases Studied a<br />

Length first reporting period<br />

(months)<br />

Employment<br />

(first reporting period, FTE)<br />

Employment<br />

(2006, FTE)<br />

Total Assets (first reporting<br />

period, in 000 EUR)<br />

<strong>High</strong> <strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong><br />

Theraptosis 2000 Therapeutics 23 3 33 691 9,848 17 3 600 28,800 IPO<br />

(2007)<br />

AC Pharma 2002 Platform technologies<br />

and therapeutics<br />

Genom 1999 Platform technologies<br />

and therapeutics<br />

Aptanomics 2002 Platform technologies,<br />

diagnostics and<br />

therapeutics<br />

Pharmaleads 2000 Therapeutics and<br />

platform technologies<br />

Total Assets (2006, in 000<br />

EUR)<br />

Cumulative number of<br />

patents granted (until 2006)<br />

Number of finance rounds<br />

First round finance<br />

(in 000 EUR)<br />

Pre-exit finance<br />

(in 000 EUR)<br />

12 2 10 b 4,081 2,248 b 19 2 4,500 6,750 Trade<br />

Sale<br />

(2006)<br />

18 16 67 4,550 119,559 10 2 4,450 29,400 IPO<br />

(2005)<br />

18 6 59 6,207 29,285 22 4 62 70,000 IPO<br />

(2007)<br />

Low <strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong><br />

14 5 3 604 81 0 2 1,100 2,600 No<br />

Entomed 2002 Platform technologies 13 1 4 536 657 2 3 470 1,189 No<br />

Myosic 2003 Diagnostics 7 1 3 b 1,140 894 b 0 1 1,500 1,500 Bankrupt<br />

(2006)<br />

Irogene 2002 Therapeutics 14 4 N.A. 371 31 0 1 350 350 No<br />

I-Zyme 2002 Platform technologies,<br />

industrial and<br />

environmental biotech<br />

7 2 N.A. 101 18 0 1 62 62 No<br />

a N.A. indicates recent employment data was not available for Irogene and I-Zyme. However, when looking at the wages and remunerations paid<br />

by these ventures, it is highly unlikely that employment increased.<br />

b Data from 2005, as more recent data was not available given that the company failed or stopped to exist as a separate entity.<br />

Source: financial accounts, interviews, European Patent Office and company websites<br />

4.3.2. Data Sources<br />

We used several data sources (Table 4.3) including (1) quantitative and qualitative data from semi-<br />

structured interviews with key financial decision makers from both biotechnology ventures and their<br />

investors, (2) excerpts from initial business plans used to raise startup finance, (3) e-mails and phone calls<br />

Exit<br />

149


to follow-up interviews, (4) financial statement data and statutory required publications on capital<br />

increases and shareholder structure and (5) archival data, including Web sites, business publications and<br />

materials provided by informants. The use of multiple data sources increases the validity and reliability of<br />

the evidence (Yin, 1984).<br />

Case<br />

Entrepreneurs<br />

Theraptosis CEO, 2<br />

interviews<br />

AC Pharma CEO, 2<br />

interviews<br />

TABLE 4.3<br />

Sources of Data Biotechnology Cases<br />

Interviews:<br />

Follow-up<br />

Entrepreneurs Investors<br />

2 Investor<br />

B, D and G<br />

- Investor<br />

B and D<br />

Genom CEO 1 Investor<br />

F<br />

Aptanomics CEO and<br />

Business<br />

Developer<br />

- Investor<br />

F and H<br />

Pharmaleads CEO and CSO - Investor<br />

D and G<br />

Entomed CEO, 2<br />

interviews<br />

- Investor<br />

C and I<br />

Myosic CEO 1 Investor<br />

A and E<br />

Irogene CEO, 2<br />

interviews<br />

<strong>High</strong> <strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong><br />

Archival Documents:<br />

Detailed yearly financial accounts, statutory required publications,<br />

press releases, prospectus, (slides) management road show<br />

Detailed yearly financial accounts, statutory required publications,<br />

press releases, confidential reports venture capital investor<br />

Detailed yearly financial accounts, statutory required publications,<br />

press releases, (slides) presentation CEO at Belgian Biotechnology<br />

Association, (slides) presentation CFO at university seminar<br />

Detailed yearly financial accounts, statutory required publications,<br />

press releases, (slides) presentation CEO at Belgian Biotechnology<br />

Association<br />

Low <strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong><br />

Detailed yearly financial accounts, statutory required publications,<br />

press releases, excerpts initial business plan (university report)<br />

Detailed yearly financial accounts, statutory required publications,<br />

press releases, internal university reports, excerpts initial business<br />

plan<br />

Detailed yearly financial accounts, statutory required publications,<br />

press releases, initial business plan, confidential reports venture<br />

capital investor<br />

- Parent Detailed yearly financial accounts, statutory required publications,<br />

press releases<br />

I-Zyme CEO 1 - Detailed yearly financial accounts, statutory required publications,<br />

press releases<br />

Total Number:<br />

(excl. pilot<br />

interviews)<br />

15<br />

5<br />

10<br />

Part of this study is historical, in the sense that we rely on interviews and archival data to obtain a<br />

retrospective account of the finance process. However, we also tracked changes in the finance process in<br />

real time after the interviews. In total, we conducted more than 40 interviews. All interviews were<br />

150


conducted by at least two researchers, where one researcher exclusively dealt with making field notes.<br />

Additionally all interviews were taped and then transcribed in the hours following the interview. The first<br />

phase included pilot interviews with biotechnology entrepreneurs, biotechnology investors, policy makers<br />

and members of the biotechnology association. During the pilot interviews, we fine-tuned the interview<br />

guides targeting entrepreneurs and investors. The pilot interviews indicated that the Chief Executive<br />

Officer (CEO) eventually helped by a Chief Financial Officer (CFO) typically make finance decisions.<br />

Other individuals, such as senior scientists, generally have less detailed knowledge of the finance events<br />

taking place.<br />

We conducted 15 semi-structured interviews with key informants in biotechnology ventures (Table 4.3).<br />

The interviewees who were our informants were the founding entrepreneurs and senior management. We<br />

typically conducted multiple interviews in each venture; there was a first round of interviews in 2003 and<br />

a follow-up round in 2004. The interviews generally took between 90 and 120 minutes and followed an<br />

interview guide that had variations for the different cases. The interviews began with background<br />

information, such as management composition and prior experiences, core technology, products in the<br />

pipeline, market characteristics and alliances. We then asked informants to chronologically discuss the<br />

history of the venture with respect to its financing. Access to detailed yearly financial accounts and<br />

statutory required publications on capital increases allowed interviewers to prepare a finance timeline in<br />

advance of each interview. This finance timeline captured the history of the finance obtained and was used<br />

during the interview to crosscheck information provided by our informants. During the interviews, we<br />

additionally discussed the finance unsuccessfully applied for and the finance sources which entrepreneurs<br />

were not willing to consider.<br />

Throughout our interviews with entrepreneurs, we took steps to minimize informant biases. Given that we<br />

study young biotechnology ventures that were maximum five years old at the time of the first interview<br />

and that capital acquisition decisions are major decisions, we limit recall bias (Neisser, 1982). If<br />

151


informants had difficulties in accurately remembering finance events, we would expect differences in the<br />

information they provided with data from other sources. This was not the case, however. We also focused<br />

on facts during the interview process. An emphasis on facts is likely to be less subjective to both cognitive<br />

biases and impression management as opposed to beliefs or feelings (Miller, Cardinal, and Glick, 1997).<br />

The information given was quite objective, e.g. whether entrepreneurs applied for different sources of<br />

finance, whether they had prior ties to the investors from which they raised finance and how investors<br />

helped or constrained the venture when raising follow-on finance. To further motivate our informants to<br />

give accurate data we promised confidentiality.<br />

We also conducted 10 semi-structured interviews with selected investors that offered finance to the cases<br />

studied (Table 4.3). Given the sensitive nature of the finance process, we did not require investors to<br />

discuss individual portfolio companies. We focused on the general investment process and discussed the<br />

different phases in the investment process from deal origination through exit. This strategy allowed us to<br />

link detailed investor characteristics and insights from investors to the cases. However, during the<br />

interviews we motivated investors to offer examples involving the cases studied. Other investors were<br />

even willing to provide confidential reports on their portfolio companies at the end of the interview. We<br />

interviewed independent and private, independent and quoted, university-related, bank-related and<br />

corporate venture capital investors that invested as little as €500,000 to as much as €194,000,000 in<br />

biotechnology ventures. Furthermore, we interviewed one parent company that offered startup finance.<br />

After the interviews and up to December 2007, we tracked changes in the finance process in real time.<br />

Given the information requirements in our research setting (i.e. even private ventures are required by law<br />

to file detailed yearly financial statements to the National Bank), we are confident that we observed all<br />

important finance rounds that occurred after our interviews. If important changes took place in the finance<br />

process, we collected press releases, asked additional questions through e-mail or telephone and attended<br />

management road shows amongst other.<br />

152


4.3.3. Data Analysis<br />

Transcriptions alone totaled 700 double spaced pages. In order to manage the large amount of data<br />

collected, we started by building individual case studies synthesizing the interview transcripts and archival<br />

sources. Case histories were used for two analyses: within-case and cross-case. The within-case analysis<br />

focused on the finance timeline, which depicted all finance events, unsuccessful finance events and<br />

important facts and conclusions for the individual cases. Within-case analysis allowed us to describe the<br />

finance process in detail as experienced by a single venture. Through this process, we noted patterns<br />

within each case. Next, the conclusions from each individual case were considered information needing<br />

replication by other cases (Yin, 1984).<br />

Cross-case analysis began after all cases were finished (Eisenhardt, 1989a). Using cross-case analysis<br />

techniques, we looked for similar constructs and relationships across cases. We heavily relied on cross-<br />

case synthesis techniques by using tables and graphs that display the data according to a uniform<br />

framework. The tables were used to study whether different groups of cases were more similar and<br />

whether particular subgroups or categories of general cases could be identified (Yin, 1984).<br />

Our analysis led to an emerging framework depicting the finance process as an evolutionary model. It<br />

describes, first, how high- and low-growth ventures differ in their mobilization of financial resources. We<br />

demonstrate how early differences in the experience of investors with whom entrepreneurs connect affect<br />

the amount of follow-on finance raised and venture growth. Second, the framework addresses how early<br />

differences originate. The social context in which entrepreneurs make early finance decisions, and more<br />

specifically venture origin, pushes entrepreneurs towards related investors and this through a local search.<br />

Third, we show that early differences in the finance process are likely to persist across time, because of<br />

venture professionalization, stunted learning and investor syndication. These processes make it difficult<br />

153


for ventures to replicate the successful finance strategies of their peers and may therefore act as isolating<br />

mechanisms.<br />

4.4. How does the Finance Process of <strong>High</strong>-and Low-<strong>Growth</strong> Ventures<br />

Differ?<br />

In this section, we study how the finance process of high- and low-growth ventures differs from startup<br />

through development. We start by focusing on the amount of finance raised. Next, we study the impact of<br />

the type of investor that offers finance. Although high- and low-growth ventures do not differ<br />

systematically in the amount of startup finance raised, the high-growth ventures raise considerably larger<br />

amounts of finance across time compared to their low-growth peers. We show how ventures raising early<br />

finance from highly experienced investors attract more follow-on finance and exhibit high growth, while<br />

ventures raising early finance from relatively inexperienced investors attract less follow-on finance, if any,<br />

and exhibit low growth. We discuss the role of the amount of finance and type of investor in more detail<br />

below.<br />

4.4.1. Amount of Finance<br />

Although financial resources are typically portrayed as a commodity good, the amount of finance raised at<br />

startup might offer startups a competitive advantage (Lee, Lee, and Pennings, 2001). Startups raising more<br />

initial finance are likely to accumulate a larger stock of strategic resources, including intangible assets and<br />

human resources, compared to their finance constrained peers (Dierickx and Cool, 1989; Hubbard, 1998;<br />

Lee, Lee, and Pennings, 2001). Figure 4.1, however, shows how high- and low- growth cases do not differ<br />

systematically in terms of amount of startup finance raised.<br />

154


Cumulative amount of pre-exit finance (in 000 EUR)<br />

100000<br />

10000<br />

1000<br />

100<br />

10<br />

1<br />

5<br />

9<br />

13<br />

17<br />

21<br />

25<br />

<strong>High</strong> <strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong><br />

29<br />

33<br />

37<br />

a Note that a logarithmic scale was used for ease of representation.<br />

41<br />

45<br />

49<br />

53<br />

FIGURE 4.1<br />

Cumulative Amount of Pre-Exit Finance Raised across Time a<br />

Source: Statutory required publications on capital increases, financial statements, interviews.<br />

57<br />

61<br />

IPO<br />

65<br />

69<br />

Time (Months since startup financing)<br />

Aptanomics Genom Theraptosis AC Pharma<br />

M&A<br />

73<br />

77<br />

IPO<br />

81<br />

IPO<br />

85<br />

89<br />

93<br />

97<br />

101<br />

100000<br />

10000<br />

1000<br />

100<br />

10<br />

Low <strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong><br />

Bankruptcy<br />

1 5 9 13 17 21 25 29 33 37 41 45 49 53 57 61 65 69 73 77 81 85 89 93 97 101<br />

Time (Months since startup financing)<br />

Pharmaleads Myosic Irogen I-Zyme Entomed<br />

155


A good illustration is the difference in initial finance between Pharmaleads and Aptanomics. Pharmaleads,<br />

an academic spin-off founded in 2000, raised some €1,100,000 from three university funds. Despite the<br />

relatively large amount of initial finance raised, this venture failed to realize its high growth ambitions.<br />

Aptanomics, founded in 2002, received only €62,000 initial finance from a domestic investor. This<br />

investor decided, in close cooperation with the specialized research institute from which Aptanomics<br />

originated, to first search for an experienced CEO before offering more finance. Once an experienced<br />

CEO was hired, the domestic investor together with the CEO searched for additional finance. They<br />

targeted venture capital investors that typically co-invest with this domestic investor. It is only some 15<br />

months after founding that Aptanomics raised an additional €5,000,000 of finance from domestic and<br />

international investors and started to focus on the development of its operations. This indicates that<br />

ventures do not necessarily require large amounts of finance to startup and exhibit high subsequent<br />

growth.<br />

Nevertheless, the cumulative amount of finance raised and venture growth are related. Figure 4.1 shows<br />

how large differences in the amount of finance raised by high- and low-growth ventures become apparent<br />

some two to four year after raising startup finance. <strong>High</strong>-growth ventures attract large amounts of follow-<br />

on finance. Aptanomics, Genom and Theraptosis raised a cumulative amount of venture capital exceeding<br />

€25,000,000. AC Pharma raised €6,750,000 before it merged with another biotechnology venture. These<br />

ventures are also more likely to conduct an Initial Public Offering (IPO). Aptanomics, Genom and<br />

Theraptosis conducted an IPO between five and seven years after founding. Going public is a momentous<br />

event for biotechnology ventures: it gives access to capital, increases legitimacy and is an important exit<br />

mechanism (Deeds, Decarolis, and Coombs, 1997). This contrasts with low-growth cases, which typically<br />

attracted limited amounts of follow-on finance, if any. Pharmaleads raised the largest cumulative amount<br />

of venture capital, which equals only €2,600,000. Although most low growth companies are still<br />

surviving, recent financial figures demonstrate that these ventures are severely undercapitalized.<br />

156


Pharmaleads, for example, burned nearly all of its capital raised and reported total assets equal to merely<br />

€81,000 at the end of 2006.<br />

4.4.2. Type of Investor<br />

Focusing only on the amount of finance raised ignores the type of investors that offer finance. Table 4.4<br />

shows the type of investors and the finance rounds in which they participated. <strong>High</strong>ly experienced venture<br />

capital firms (VCFs) are investors that (a) actively invest in biotechnology ventures and (b) have a team<br />

dedicated to evaluate and follow-up biotechnology proposals. Relatively inexperienced venture capital<br />

investors comprise university funds, venture capital subsidiaries of banks and other venture capital firms<br />

investing only sporadically in biotechnology ventures without a team dedicated to biotechnology. Next,<br />

business angels (BAs) are defined as wealthy individuals investing their personal funds in privately-held<br />

ventures. Finally, in the case of corporate spin-offs, the parent company is typically involved in startup<br />

finance.<br />

We observe that the high-growth ventures generally raise finance from more experienced investors during<br />

the first or second financing round and raise large amounts of follow-on finance (Table 4.4). Aptanomics<br />

and AC Pharma raised finance from more experienced investors at startup. Genom initially raised<br />

convertible debt from its two parent companies, both successful biotechnology ventures. It further raised<br />

initial venture capital finance from highly experienced venture capital investors some three years after<br />

founding. Theraptosis raised venture capital from an experienced investor in its second finance round.<br />

The low growth ventures typically start with relatively inexperienced investors and raise limited amounts<br />

of follow-on finance, if any (Table 4.4). Pharmaleads and Entomed raised initial finance from relatively<br />

inexperienced venture capital investors. Irogene and I-Zyme were the first spin-offs from their parents,<br />

who also financed these ventures. Myosic raised finance from an inexperienced academic investor and a<br />

157


corporate investor related to a big pharmaceutical company. This last case indicates that receiving initial<br />

finance from a more experienced investor (i.e., the corporate investor) is no guarantee for success.<br />

Case<br />

Domestic<br />

highly<br />

experienced<br />

VCFs<br />

TABLE 4.4<br />

Finance Process by Type of Investor and Venture <strong>Growth</strong> a<br />

Type of investor and finance round in which they participated:<br />

International<br />

(experienced)<br />

VCFs<br />

Other<br />

relatively<br />

Academic<br />

VCFs<br />

inexperienced<br />

Bank VCFs VCFs<br />

<strong>High</strong> <strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong><br />

BAs<br />

Parent<br />

company /<br />

institute<br />

Theraptosis 2,3 2,3 1,2,3 2,3 3 - - 600 28,800<br />

AC Pharma 1,2 - 1,2 1,2 - - - 4,500 6,750<br />

Genom - 2 - - - - 1 4,450 29,400<br />

Aptanomics 1,2,3,4 2,3,4 - 4 - - - 62 70,000<br />

Low <strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong><br />

Pharmaleads - - 1,2 2 - - - 1,100 2,600<br />

Entomed - - 2 - 1, 2,3 2,3 - 470 1,189<br />

Myosic - - 1 - - - 1 1,500 1,500<br />

Irogene - - - - - - 1 350 350<br />

I-Zyme - - - - - - 1 62 62<br />

a The numbers in bold indicate finance rounds that occurred before the main data collection (the interviews). The numbers in<br />

italics indicate finance rounds that occurred afterwards. All cases were monitored in real time up until the end of 2007. If cases<br />

raised new finance, we should notice this in the statutory required publications or financial statements which ventures are obliged<br />

to complete by law. The number of finance rounds in this table do not necessarily correspond with the number of increases in the<br />

cumulative amount of finance raised as depicted in Figure 4.1. This is because investors may decide to stage finance, thereby<br />

gradually offering the finance if milestones are reached instead of offering all finance from the start.<br />

The observation that the high-growth ventures raised early equity finance from experienced investors is<br />

consistent with prior studies, which highlight that affiliation with prominent investors entails benefits to<br />

their portfolio companies (Stuart, Hoang, and Hybels, 1999; Hochberg, Ljungqvist, and Lu, 2007;<br />

Sorensen, 2007). Findings further indicate that with whom ventures connect early-on influences the<br />

resources they subsequently mobilize and venture development. Ventures starting early with more<br />

experienced investors typically attract large amounts of follow-on finance and exhibit high growth, while<br />

ventures starting with relatively inexperienced investors typically attract limited amounts of follow-on<br />

Startup finance<br />

(in 000 EUR)<br />

Pre-exit finance<br />

(in 000 EUR)<br />

158


finance and exhibit poor growth. This extends prior studies by demonstrating how the finance process of<br />

ventures backed by more and less experienced investors evolves differently across time.<br />

4.5. How do Early Differences in the Finance Process Originate?<br />

An important question that emerges is why some ventures raise early finance from highly experienced<br />

investors, while others raise early finance from relatively inexperienced investors. On the surface, it would<br />

seem that initial differences in quality and growth ambition initiate early differences in the finance process<br />

(Sorensen, 2007; Hallen, 2008). Yet, there was no consistent pattern linking quality and initial growth<br />

ambition to growth. Instead, we demonstrate how entrepreneurs engage in local search when mobilizing<br />

early financial resources, which pushes them towards related investors. We expand on the impact of<br />

differences in quality, differences in growth ambition and local search on the origination of early<br />

differences in the finance process below.<br />

4.5.1. Initial Differences in Quality and <strong>Growth</strong> Potential<br />

Prior research indicates experienced investors end up with ventures of high quality, while less experienced<br />

investors end up with ventures of poorer quality (Sorensen, 2007). This is explained as follows. Once<br />

entrepreneurs are willing to attract outside finance they consider the entire range of investors. Conversely,<br />

investors screen the entire pool of ventures that try to raise outside finance (Eckhardt, Shane, and Delmar,<br />

2006; Sorensen, 2007). When entrepreneurs are confronted with multiple offers, they engage in an<br />

optimization exercise, where they rank investors by experience and eventually accept the offer of the most<br />

experienced investor (Hsu, 2004; Sorensen, 2007). An investor with less experience is therefore pushed<br />

down in relative rankings and is left with ventures of worse quality (Sorensen, 2007).<br />

159


In contrast to the image portrayed above, our cases indicate that it is unlikely that experienced investors<br />

have automatic access to high quality startups, while relatively inexperienced investors are generally left<br />

with startups of worse quality. Ventures did not differ systematically in terms of quality and growth<br />

potential when raising their first finance. We looked at four early signals of quality and growth potential<br />

measured at startup: human capital, alliance capital, technology and target market (Baum and Silverman,<br />

2004). Prior organizational studies indicate that investors are more likely to offer finance to ventures<br />

founded by entrepreneurs with prior founding experience (Hallen, 2008; Hsu, 2007). All ventures in our<br />

study, however, are founded by scientists with limited, if no, business experience. If an experienced<br />

manager is recruited, this is typically under the impetus of the early investor. In the case of AC Pharma,<br />

for example, the founders were all pure scientists without any prior business experience. The initial<br />

venture capital investors helped with recruiting an experienced biotech manager before proceeding with<br />

further investments.<br />

Table 4.5 summarizes the configuration of each venture’s alliance capital, the scope and development of<br />

its technology and its target market. All ventures typically start with a single formal R&D collaboration<br />

agreement with a university or a specialized research institute. Furthermore, both in high- and low-growth<br />

cases do ventures start with a technology that is still in the idea phase. For example, the CEO of Genom, a<br />

venture experiencing tremendous growth since its founding, indicated that when the venture was founded<br />

its technology was still in the idea phase: “The idea was rudimentary”. Hence, the image that successful<br />

ventures have a more developed technology at startup is not necessarily true. Also noteworthy is that both<br />

ventures with a broad technology scope and ventures that focus on one product are able to raise finance<br />

from more experienced investors. Finally, both high and low growth ventures target niche markets and<br />

large mainstream markets.<br />

160


TABLE 4.5<br />

Early Signals of <strong>Growth</strong> Potential and Quality: Alliance Capital, Technology and Target Market at Startup a<br />

Case<br />

Alliance capital Technology<br />

market<br />

Technical R&D with<br />

Commercialization development universities or Stage in product<br />

activities activities research institutes development cycle Technology scope Target<br />

<strong>High</strong> <strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong><br />

Theraptosis 0 0 2 Idea Phase 4 Niche market<br />

AC Pharma 0 0 0 Proof of concept 1 Mainstream market<br />

Genom 0 0 0 Idea Phase 5 N.A.<br />

Aptanomics 1 0 1 Proof of concept 5 Mainstream market<br />

Low <strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong><br />

Pharmaleads 0 0 1 Proof of concept 4 Niche market<br />

Entomed 0 0 0 Concrete market-<br />

ready product<br />

2 Niche market<br />

Myosic 0 0 1 Idea Phase N.A. Niche market, move to<br />

mainstream market later<br />

Irogene 0 1 1 Idea Phase 5 Niche market<br />

I-Zyme 0 0 1 Proof of concept 5 Niche market, move to<br />

mainstream market later<br />

a N.A. indicates that data was not available for the case. Technology scope at founding was measured on a five-point scale with<br />

1= focus on one specific product and 5 = very broad technology platform with several applications.<br />

Source: Interviews.<br />

Evaluating venture quality and predicting future growth is extremely difficult in high-tech industries<br />

(Lerner, 1999). It is probably even more difficult in the biotechnology industry where even the more<br />

established ventures operate under considerable uncertainty as they typically lack products and still have<br />

to generate their first revenues (Pisano, 2006). Our findings correspond with this view, as we do not find<br />

systematic differences in early signals of quality and growth potential between the high- and low-growth<br />

cases. Both the more experienced and relatively inexperienced investors contributed startup finance to<br />

ventures which had not yet demonstrated accomplishments and were operating under considerable<br />

uncertainty.<br />

161


4.5.2. Initial Differences in <strong>Growth</strong> Ambition<br />

Another possibility is that early differences in growth ambition between entrepreneurs drive our findings.<br />

Research confirms that growth ambition has a positive impact on realized growth (Wiklund and Shepherd,<br />

2003) and hence will influence the need for financial resources to support this growth (Sapienza,<br />

Korsgaard, and Forbes, 2003). Entrepreneurs in the low-growth cases may have lower growth ambitions<br />

compared to their peers in the high-growth cases and may attract finance from less experienced investors<br />

as they do neither envisage the need to raise significant amounts of follow-on finance nor require active<br />

involvement from their investors. Indeed, the majority of entrepreneurs set up new businesses to provide<br />

an income or support a desired lifestyle (Berger and Udell, 1998). This may even be true for technology-<br />

based startups which raise venture capital finance (Heirman and Clarysse, 2004). <strong>Growth</strong> ambitions will<br />

be lower in these ventures as entrepreneurs sacrifice growth for lifestyle choices (Berger and Udell, 1998).<br />

Nevertheless, this explanation seems unlikely as initial business plans and early internal documents<br />

demonstrate that even entrepreneurs in low-growth cases had high growth ambitions. Entomed, for<br />

example, planned to develop into a professional biotechnology venture in two to three years after<br />

founding, employing 25 to 30 people. In Myosic, the founder envisioned to raise some 10 million euro in<br />

follow-on finance and subsequently conduct an IPO. The CEO of Pharmaleads envisaged the same future<br />

for his venture as that of another academic spin-off from the same university, which experienced dramatic<br />

growth and conducted an IPO. Despite their high growth ambitions at startup, these entrepreneurs were<br />

unable to realize them.<br />

4.5.3. Local Search<br />

We find that early differences in finance are largely explained by the local search behavior of<br />

entrepreneurs. Surprisingly, entrepreneurs are not comprehensive at all in their search for startup finance<br />

and this despite the heightened importance of finance decisions in our setting. Entrepreneurs unexpectedly<br />

162


limit their search to only one or a few investors (Table 4.6). The social context within which financial<br />

resources are mobilized guide entrepreneurs in their search for finance. The pre-founding context has an<br />

important impact on financial resource acquisition at startup. Firm origin and existing contacts of<br />

entrepreneurs through previous employment largely determine which investor is targeted (Table 4.6).<br />

A good illustration is Genom, a corporate spin-off funded by the parent companies at startup. The CEO<br />

indicated that it was not necessary to further search for startup finance when it became clear that the<br />

parent companies were willing to offer startup finance. Hence, the CEO did not search for credible finance<br />

alternatives. Nevertheless, the CEO later indicated that the initial finance decision constrained his venture,<br />

because the venture was “too dependent on its parent companies”. Therefore, the CEO decided to target<br />

independent venture capital investors for the first time in a subsequent round of finance.<br />

Table 4.6 demonstrates that the search for startup finance by entrepreneurs is local. The notion of local<br />

search is a relative term and presumes a broader context (Stuart and Podolny, 1996). We define local<br />

search in the finance process as the search for finance from investors related to the venture through pre-<br />

existing ties as opposed to unrelated investors. Our results offer additional evidence on the importance of<br />

the social context in the finance process and puts nuance to prior studies, which indicate that investors are<br />

more likely to offer finance to entrepreneurs with whom they have pre-existing ties (Uzzi, 1999; Shane<br />

and Cable, 2002; Hallen, 2008). We demonstrate that these results might also be explained by<br />

entrepreneurs, who are more likely to initiate relationships with related investors. The social context<br />

within which finance decisions are embedded determines from whom entrepreneurs will search for<br />

finance. This largely explains early differences in the finance process 23 .<br />

23 Note that we do not argue that entrepreneurs remain local in their search for finance. As ventures mature and uncertainty is -at<br />

least partially- reduced, we observe that entrepreneurs become more comprehensive in their search for follow-on finance. It is not<br />

uncommon that entrepreneurs contact over 50 venture capital investors when preparing follow-on finance rounds. Nevertheless,<br />

although entrepreneurs become more comprehensive in their search for finance across time, other processes enhance and/or limit<br />

the number of viable finance options in the future. These are discussed later in this chapter (§4.6.).<br />

163


TABLE 4.6<br />

Local Search and the Impact of the Social Context on Initial <strong>Financing</strong><br />

Theraptosis -University spin-off getting finance from<br />

university fund.<br />

-Did not look for other potential equity<br />

investors.<br />

AC Pharma -University spin-off getting finance from<br />

university fund and its shareholders.<br />

Genom -Corporate spin-off getting finance from<br />

parent company<br />

-Did not look for other potential equity<br />

investors.<br />

Aptanomics -Aptanomics raised finance from a highly<br />

experienced investor. This experienced<br />

investor has financed nearly all spin-offs from<br />

the research institute.<br />

Pharmaleads -University spin-off getting finance from<br />

university funds.<br />

-No other equity investor looked for besides<br />

the university fund<br />

Facts Illustrative Quotes<br />

<strong>High</strong> <strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong><br />

"It was the logical choice in the case of a<br />

spin-off."<br />

"The firm is a university spin-off and one<br />

of our investors is the university spin-off<br />

fund…All initial investors in our firm are<br />

also shareholders of the university fund."<br />

"The CEO did not need to look for money,<br />

it was provided by the two parent<br />

companies"<br />

Low <strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong><br />

Entomed -CEO contacted a business professor<br />

-There was a friendship between the university<br />

professor contacted by the CEO and the senior<br />

investment manager of the initial investor.<br />

-Relied solely on university professor to locate<br />

an investor.<br />

Myosic -Corporate/University spin-off getting finance<br />

from a corporate fund and university fund.<br />

-No other equity investors considered<br />

Irogene -Corporate spin-off getting finance from<br />

parent company.<br />

- Tried to attract financing from a small<br />

number of investors, besides the mother<br />

company, but was unsuccessful.<br />

I-Zyme -Spin-off getting startup finance from<br />

research institute.<br />

-Did not look for other potential equity<br />

investors.<br />

Source: Interviews.<br />

"It is the norm for spin offs from<br />

universities to start talking to the seed<br />

funds of universities. With the university<br />

fund we had the most obvious link."<br />

"When searching for funding it appeared to<br />

be logical to have resources from the<br />

investors with whom the company and<br />

entrepreneur already had contacts."<br />

"Contacts were first initiated with a<br />

university seed fund. When they were not<br />

willing to invest the parent company<br />

provided financing."<br />

"The institute had the idea to spin-off the<br />

company and was therefore willing to<br />

invest. Afterwards, there were some<br />

contacts with business angels, but not<br />

more, things did not get any further."<br />

Firm Origin<br />

√<br />

√<br />

√<br />

√<br />

√<br />

Other preexisting<br />

relationship<br />

√<br />

√ √<br />

√<br />

√<br />

164


Why do entrepreneurs limit their search for finance to one or a few investors with whom they have pre-<br />

existing ties despite the importance of finance decisions? One possible explanation is that ventures had no<br />

alternative. While possible, this explanation is doubtful. First, entrepreneurs generally do not test the<br />

market for credible alternatives. The CEO of Pharmaleads, for example, did not contact other investors.<br />

The CEO stated:<br />

“The venture did not need to contact other venture capital investors or business angels because we were able to raise<br />

equity from the university fund.”<br />

Second, finance is more readily available during “hot” markets. We might hence logically expect that<br />

entrepreneurs will be less dependent on related investors to mobilize startup capital during these times.<br />

Nevertheless, both ventures raising their initial finance during “hot” and “cold” markets exhibit the same<br />

local search behavior.<br />

The cases suggest that the social context is important as it (a) helps in locating potential investors, (b)<br />

helps in reducing the fear of expropriation and (c) shapes taken-for-granted assumptions about what<br />

constitutes appropriate search behavior. We expand on these three mechanisms below.<br />

Locating investors. Prior research at least implicitly assumes a market with complete information where<br />

entrepreneurs are aware of the full spectrum of finance alternatives (Brealey and Myers, 2000; Eckhardt,<br />

Shane, and Delmar, 2006; Sorensen, 2007). However, the acquisition of finance in imperfect markets is a<br />

function of the amount of information that is available to the entrepreneur: information deficiencies limit<br />

entrepreneurs’ set of choices. Inexperienced entrepreneurs are therefore expected to have a more limited<br />

set of finance choices (Van Auken, 2001). Continental European biotechnology ventures are a typical<br />

example of ventures founded by entrepreneurs with little prior business and finance experience. Social<br />

capital will benefit these entrepreneurs in identifying where the needed resources are available (Hite and<br />

Hesterly, 2001; Rangan, 2000). As a result, entrepreneurs are more likely to search for finance from<br />

165


investors related to the venture, as pre-existing direct or indirect ties increase the likelihood that the<br />

entrepreneur will identify these investors as potential exchange partners. The CEO of AC Pharma, for<br />

example, indicated:<br />

“There are two reasons why the firm found its initial investors relatively easily. One reason is that the firm is a<br />

university spin-off and one of our investors is the university spin-off fund… All initial investors in our firm are also<br />

shareholder of the university fund.”<br />

Reducing the fear of expropriation. It is well-established that informational asymmetries between<br />

entrepreneurs and investors make investors reluctant and even unwilling to provide finance (Stiglitz and<br />

Weiss, 1981). Adverse selection and moral hazard problems, which relate to the existence of informational<br />

asymmetry, are viewed as a major problem for investors when evaluating entrepreneurial ventures<br />

(Eisenhardt, 1989b). Entrepreneurs are depicted as possessing private information, which they may<br />

potentially use to mislead investors (Eisenhardt, 1989b). Nevertheless, entrepreneurs also need to evaluate<br />

investors and informational asymmetry is also a problem for them (Sahlman, 1990). For instance, as an<br />

entrepreneur and venture capitalist interact, the latter becomes more informed and may continue the<br />

project without the entrepreneur (Ueda, 2004). The risk of expropriation makes entrepreneurs reluctant to<br />

disclose information when searching for finance especially when the other party is unknown. The<br />

following quotes illustrate:<br />

“Particularly pre-investment, entrepreneurs are wary to disclose all information to us. Information transfer is always<br />

very delicate. We live in a competitive world and have a large number of portfolio companies. It happens that a<br />

company that looks for financing is a competitor of one of our portfolio companies or that there is at least a partial<br />

overlap. Even when two companies start very differently, they may gradually become more similar over a four to<br />

five year timeframe. Therefore, information transfer is often a problem... However, when we do not receive all the<br />

information, we will not invest.” (Senior investment manager, Investor F, <strong>High</strong>ly Experienced VCF)<br />

“Unwillingness to provide information is something which happens more often with external entrepreneurs. It is less<br />

of a problem if we work with scientist from our own university.” (Managing Partner, Investor A, Academic VCF)<br />

Taken-for-granted assumptions. According to an institutional view, the motives of human behavior<br />

extend beyond economic optimization to social justification (Zukin and DiMaggio, 1990). When<br />

166


managers justify actions with the claim that “everybody does it this way”, they refer to institutionalized<br />

activities (Oliver, 1997). Our cases demonstrate that once entrepreneurs have located an investor through a<br />

network search, they typically do not engage in a broader search. In Pharmaleads and Theraptosis, two<br />

university spin-offs, the CEOs justified why they only searched for finance from university funds at<br />

startup by indicating that it is the norm for spin-offs. The CEO of Pharmaleads, for example, stated: “It is<br />

the norm for university spin-offs to start talking to the seed fund of universities”. This demonstrates that<br />

entrepreneurs take a lot of implicit finance decisions without considering the long-term impact of their<br />

early decisions.<br />

In summary, early differences in the finance process are largely shaped by the social context, which<br />

pushes ventures towards related investors. It indicates that the social context creates a barrier that<br />

precludes perfect competition in the factor market. It is noteworthy that local search is not necessarily<br />

inefficient and may even be a cost effective and speedy way to secure finance and value-added services.<br />

Especially entrepreneurial ventures that are not connected to highly experienced investors may benefit<br />

from a more comprehensive search at startup. In the following section, we demonstrate the importance of<br />

early finance decisions as these may both facilitate and constrain the future finance process.<br />

4.6. How do Early Differences in the Finance Process Persist across Time?<br />

Corporate finance theory generally assumes limited influence from history on the finance process, as<br />

ventures actively rebalance their financial structure towards an optimum (Hovakimian, Opler, and Titman,<br />

2001; Leary and Roberts, 2005). In contrast, we identify a number of processes that may both facilitate<br />

and constrain the subsequent finance process, including venture professionalization, stunted learning and<br />

investor syndication preferences. These processes explain how early differences in the finance process<br />

167


persist across time and suggest it is difficult for ventures to imitate others and duplicate successful finance<br />

strategies. We elaborate on these processes below 24 .<br />

4.6.1. Venture Professionalization<br />

Hellmann and Puri (2002) indicate that venture capitalists as a group play an important role in venture<br />

professionalization by bringing outsiders into the position of CEO. More recently, Beckman and Burton<br />

(2008) suggest that venture capitalists may influence the entire structure and experience of teams within<br />

ventures. Our cases illustrate an important contingency and highlight how especially more experienced<br />

venture capital investors play a vital role in professionalizing ventures by shaping their management team.<br />

Table 4.7 summarizes key changes in management. We focus on changes in the management team<br />

involving the recruitment of new CEOs and CFOs, as these are the most influential positions that shape<br />

the future finance process.<br />

In Aptanomics, the experienced founding venture capital investor played a crucial role in hiring a<br />

professional manager with considerable experience in the biotech industry shortly after founding. This<br />

manager previously held key positions in several biotechnology ventures, both Belgian and foreign, since<br />

the early 1980s. In the beginning of 2006, Aptanomics appointed a new CEO and its first CFO. The<br />

purpose was to further strengthen the management team with international experience in both private and<br />

public financing 25 . The same story holds for AC Pharma. In Genom, an experienced manager was<br />

transferred from one of the highly successful biotechnology parents.<br />

24 Besides venture professionalization, stunted learning and syndication preferences other processes may enforce persistence in<br />

the finance process. Venture capital deals are characterized by extensive contracts and venture capital investors, for example, will<br />

typically insist on rights of first refusal, which give the venture capital investor the right to invest in subsequent rounds (Sahlman,<br />

1990). Such contract clauses add to persistence in the finance process.<br />

25 Interestingly, Aptanomics’ former CEO now took a leading role in a new spin-off from the research institute from which<br />

Aptanomics originated and the investor offering startup capital to this new spin-off was the same as the first round investor in<br />

Aptanomics. It indicates that highly experienced venture capitalists have access to a pool of experienced managers, which they<br />

transfer between their portfolio companies.<br />

168


TABLE 4.7<br />

Key Changes in the Management Team Relating to the CEO and CFO<br />

Professional CEO hired/changes Professional CFO hired/changes<br />

<strong>High</strong> <strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong><br />

Theraptosis Startup year CEO hired with consulting<br />

background in the biotech industry.<br />

AC Pharma Startup year<br />

2 years after<br />

startup<br />

CEO hired under impetus initial<br />

investor with consulting background<br />

in the biotech industry.<br />

New CEO hired with consulting<br />

background in biotech industry.<br />

Previously, informal advisor to<br />

venture capital funds.<br />

Genom Startup year CEO hired from parent company.<br />

Limited experience in raising<br />

financing.<br />

Aptanomics Startup year<br />

4 years after<br />

startup<br />

Pharmaleads None<br />

Entomed None<br />

Myosic 2 years after<br />

startup<br />

Irogene None<br />

I-Zyme None<br />

Source: Interviews, press releases.<br />

CEO hired, with extensive<br />

experience in both European and US<br />

biotechnology startups under<br />

impetus initial investor.<br />

New CEO hired with a successful<br />

track record in creating company<br />

value and attracting finance both in<br />

private and public area.<br />

Low <strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong><br />

New CEO hired under impetus<br />

initial investor. Previously cofounded<br />

an ICT company and a<br />

medical software venture.<br />

7 years after<br />

startup<br />

5 years after<br />

startup<br />

7 years after<br />

startup<br />

4 years after<br />

startup<br />

Professional CFO hired<br />

None<br />

Professional CFO hired<br />

New Professional CFO hired<br />

Professional CFO hired<br />

Although relatively inexperienced investors also initiate changes at startup (see for example Therapthosis),<br />

these changes are not common among the low-growth cases that are backed by inexperienced investors. In<br />

Pharmaleads and Entomed, both ventures backed by inexperienced venture capital investors, no changes<br />

took place in team formation across time. The same holds for Irogene, which was financed by its poorly<br />

None<br />

None<br />

None<br />

None<br />

None<br />

169


performing biotechnology parent company and I-Zyme, the first spin-off from a research institute, which<br />

was financed by this institute.<br />

Furthermore, experienced investors do not necessarily initiate changes in the management team at startup.<br />

In Myosic, for example, the relatively inexperienced academic investor and more experienced corporate<br />

investor had doubts about the management qualities of the founder. Despite these concerns, the investors<br />

accepted that he took the lead over the venture. It was only some two years after founding, once the<br />

scientific founder’s shortcomings became visible through weak progress, that a more experienced CEO<br />

was hired.<br />

Strengthening the founding team with experienced managers and finance specialists is likely to benefit<br />

ventures in their search for follow-on financing. Maurer and Ebers (2006) indicate that high-growth<br />

ventures are more likely to introduce specialization within the entrepreneurial team compared to their low-<br />

growth peers. Our cases are generally consistent with this finding and extend them by indicating that<br />

especially more experienced venture capital investors are at the origin of professionalization within<br />

entrepreneurial teams thereby offering the ventures they back a competitive advantage when mobilizing<br />

subsequent financial resources.<br />

4.6.2. Stunted Learning<br />

Hiring experienced managers and finance specialists is only one path to increase the likelihood of<br />

mobilizing follow-on finance. Learning may be an alternative path. Learning is cumulative in nature and<br />

repetition of the same task will benefit people in performing those tasks (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990). As<br />

a result, knowledge gained from interacting with investors is expected to accumulate across time and<br />

entrepreneurs are likely to learn many facets of dealing with investors through their early experiences with<br />

financiers. As a result, entrepreneurs may develop knowledge based on prior experiences that will benefit<br />

170


them in their search for follow-on financing. The following quote by the CEO-founder of Myosic<br />

illustrates:<br />

“The first financing round helped me to improve the way I present and negotiate with investors. I now feel it will be<br />

easier to locate new financing sources for future financing rounds.” (CEO-founder Myosic)<br />

Nevertheless, learning performance is greatest when the object of learning is related to what is already<br />

known. Conversely, learning will be more difficult in novel domains (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990). In our<br />

cases, founders are typically pure scientists, who lack experience in raising finance. Although some<br />

founders perceive that they have learned more about finance through prior contacts with investors,<br />

investors themselves indicate that many founders fail to fully develop the competencies required to<br />

manage a business, including the ability to negotiate and raise large amounts of follow-on finance.<br />

Investors, for example, often complain that the business plans of biotechnology ventures are not accessible<br />

because they are too focused on the technology, which is the scientific founder’s main line of expertise.<br />

The following quotes illustrate:<br />

“I can give you examples of business plans from ventures that exist for over five years…when you look at those<br />

business plans, which are written to attract follow-on financing, it still looks like these are written by scientists that<br />

work on a scientific paper.” (Investment manager, Investor H, <strong>High</strong>ly Experienced VCF)<br />

“One of the most important shortcomings of biotech business plans is an under developed business model. While<br />

there is often a very interesting scientific concept, people have not thought adequately about how the science can be<br />

translated into an economic model. Inexperience causes that timelines are unrealistic, the financial plan is<br />

unrealistic…” (Senior investment manager, Investor E, Corporate VCF)<br />

Investor heterogeneity compounds learning difficulties. Venture capital investors exhibit significant<br />

heterogeneity in their selection behavior (Muzyka, Birley, and Leleux, 1996), level of experience (Hsu,<br />

2004) and goals for investing in ventures (Hellmann, Lindsey, and Puri, 2008). This will influence the pre-<br />

investment process of venture capital investors, which is a lengthy process containing several hurdles,<br />

such as initial screening, due diligence, valuation and contracting (Fried and Hisrich, 1994). As a result,<br />

approaching different types of investors requires different strategies, knowledge and skills.<br />

171


“In our venture capital firm the investment managers have a technical background and no financial background,<br />

which is different from ‘traditional’ venture capital investors…we evaluate investment opportunities which<br />

‘traditional’ venture capital investors ignore…” (Investment manager, Investor H, <strong>High</strong>ly Experienced VCF)<br />

In an emerging industry where founders generally lack experience, our cases indicate that learning is an<br />

inferior path compared to venture professionalization when developing a business. Ventures where pure<br />

scientists take a leading role are at a competitive disadvantage because of stunted learning, which<br />

constrains scientific founders in their search for follow-on finance. Furthermore, knowledge gained<br />

through prior contacts with investors will not necessarily be suitable to approach new investors due to<br />

different investor profiles. This makes it difficult for ventures backed by relatively inexperienced investors<br />

to attract finance from highly experienced investors in the future, which further causes persistence in the<br />

finance process.<br />

4.6.3. Investor Syndication Preferences<br />

It is common for entrepreneurial ventures to receive finance from multiple investors (a syndicate) over<br />

several investment rounds, where later rounds typically involve continued investments from prior<br />

investors and one or more new investors (Lerner, 1994). Entrepreneurs and investors indicate that<br />

syndication preferences both facilitate and constrain future financing decisions. More specifically,<br />

investors prefer to syndicate with (a) investors known from previous investments and (b) knowledgeable<br />

counterparts.<br />

Consistent with prior organizational studies, our cases indicate that investors are more likely to collaborate<br />

with investors they know from previous investments (Hallen, 2008). We observe how investors<br />

consistently form a syndicate with the same group of local and foreign investors. An investment manager<br />

at a more experienced venture capital firm describes:<br />

172


“You always see particular funds investing together…You almost always see investor F investing first [a domestic<br />

fund] and investors X and Z [other Continental European funds] offering follow-on financing.” (Investor H)<br />

Why do investors prefer to form a syndicate with other investors they know from prior investments? One<br />

possible explanation advanced by prior research is reciprocity, where lead investors invite other investors<br />

to join the syndicate in the hope these investors will return the favor in the future (Sorenson and Stuart,<br />

2001). Reciprocity will thus lead to clusters of investors emerging in different portfolio companies over<br />

time. This picture is incomplete, however. Prior research indicates embedded relationships are preferred<br />

because these reduce the risk and uncertainty associated with interorganizational exchange (Chung, Sing<br />

and Lee, 2000; Wright and Lockett, 2003; Sorenson and Stuart, 2008). Our cases demonstrate that<br />

embedded relationships are chosen as the development of relationship specific heuristics reduces the<br />

uncertainty surrounding the behavior of other investors. One important risk perceived by biotechnology<br />

investors, for example, is that other investors do not allocate sufficient funds for follow-on financing. This<br />

may cause distress and even failure and consequently increases the risk to any single finance provider<br />

(Oakey, 1995). By deciding to co-invest with investors known through previous mutual investments in the<br />

biotechnology sector, investors limit this risk. A senior investment manager at a more experienced venture<br />

capital firm describes his experience:<br />

“It is important to know who your co-investors are…You want to know before you enter a venture how your coinvestors<br />

will react when problems emerge, follow-on financing is needed at a later stage… If you look at our<br />

investment portfolio you will see a number of co-investors emerging frequently…” (Investor F)<br />

<strong>High</strong>ly experienced investors, because of their active involvement in the industry, typically have more ties<br />

to other investors within the biotechnology investment community. This will benefit ventures that raise<br />

finance from more experienced investors when searching for follow-on finance. Ventures connecting with<br />

relatively inexperienced investors early-on will be more constrained in their options for follow-on finance.<br />

Hence, not only the history of the venture itself, but also the history of its investors is likely to influence<br />

the subsequent finance process.<br />

173


Additionally, our cases illustrate how initial investors that have experience with biotechnology ventures<br />

attract other experienced investors in the future. Starting with investors that do not have a track record of<br />

past biotechnology investments, however, makes it more difficult to attract investors with deep knowledge<br />

in the biotech industry in the future. A senior investment manager at a more experienced venture capital<br />

firm indicates his preference:<br />

“Assume we receive two similar proposals: one from company X and one from company Y. However, in company X<br />

we have an experienced investor and in company Y we have a fund that invested for the first time in biotechnology.<br />

We will definitely select company X and I believe we will be very hesitant to invest in company Y.” (Investor F)<br />

Hence, investors prefer to form a syndicate with similar others. Much more than a mere sociological<br />

argument, such as homophily (e.g., Sorenson and Stuart, 2001), results are more likely to be driven by<br />

resource considerations (Brander, Amit, and Antweiler, 2002). Experienced investors typically prefer to<br />

form a syndicate with other experienced investors, as they are more confident in their ability to help build<br />

a venture through the provision of extra-financial services.<br />

“If you start with the wrong investors the company will go nowhere. Everything goes wrong! If you start with good<br />

investors the Board of Directors can be used as a forum. With the wrong investors, the Board becomes an empty<br />

thing…What you ask from investors in a young company is not only the money, but also their expertise… If you<br />

start with experienced and well-networked investors, it is easy to attract similar investors in the future. If you start<br />

with inexperienced and poorly networked investors, nobody wants to join the syndicate later-on.” (CEO Aptanomics)<br />

“If an investor obtains a seat in the Board of Directors, you want investors who can offer an important contribution,<br />

investors who know the sector… In a syndicate you want to have investors that can add value to the firm.”<br />

(Investment manager, Investor H, <strong>High</strong>ly Experienced VCF)<br />

The conditions prompting investors to initiate relationships with more distant investors instead of<br />

investors that are known from prior investments are not well understood (Baum, Rowley, Shipilov, and<br />

Chuang, 2005; Sorenson and Stuart, 2008). Our cases hint that when an investor trusts another investor in<br />

its capacity to build a young biotechnology venture, because of its prior experience, the investor will be<br />

more likely to form a syndicate irrespective of whether the investors know each other from prior<br />

174


investments. Hence, ventures backed by highly experienced investors will find it relatively easier to attract<br />

follow-on finance from other experienced investors compared to their peers backed by relatively<br />

inexperienced investors.<br />

4.7. Discussion<br />

Our study highlights three key findings. First, mobilizing finance from highly experienced investors<br />

during the startup phase affects the ease with which ventures mobilize follow-on finance during the<br />

development phase. Second, entrepreneurs mobilize early finance through a local search thereby limiting<br />

the number of investors they target to one or a few investors that are related to the venture. Third, early<br />

differences in the finance process are likely to persist, as venture professionalization, stunted learning and<br />

investor syndication preferences make it difficult for ventures to replicate successful finance strategies<br />

from their peers. The key findings are summarized in Figure 4.2.<br />

The proposed framework presented in figure 4.2 is not entirely deterministic, however, and does not<br />

suggest that when a venture raises initial finance from a relatively inexperienced venture capital investor it<br />

will automatically be locked-in. It may still be possible for ventures to raise more experienced finance<br />

early-on despite the presence of a relatively inexperienced investor in the venture. Theraptosis is a good<br />

illustration. The venture raised startup finance from a relatively inexperienced venture capital firm at<br />

startup, but raised finance from highly experienced investors in the next finance round. Three elements are<br />

worth noting. First, although the venture started with a relatively inexperienced investor, an experienced<br />

manager was hired early-on working shoulder to shoulder with the scientific founder. Second, with the<br />

startup finance raised, the venture reached all important milestones, hence demonstrating its managerial<br />

and technological abilities. As a result, the initial investor actively supported the venture. Third, the CEO<br />

used a particularly insightful strategy to approach highly experienced investors. While the CEO was in a<br />

weak position to approach highly experienced investors directly, he resorted to network leverage strategies<br />

175


(Gargiulo, 1993). He approached not only the shareholders of the university-related investor (mostly bank-<br />

related venture capital investors), but also approached more experienced investors that frequently co-<br />

invest with the shareholders of the university investor. Therapthosis is the only case, however, which<br />

started with a relatively inexperienced venture capital investor and subsequently raised finance from<br />

highly experienced investors. The case indicates that although possible, it is difficult to change a venture’s<br />

evolutionary path. It requires relatively quick action, demonstration of performance, investor support and<br />

clever management.<br />

Amount of venture<br />

capital finance raised<br />

FIGURE 4.2<br />

Summarizing Framework of the Finance Process of <strong>High</strong>-and Low-<strong>Growth</strong> <strong>Companies</strong><br />

Similar growth<br />

potential and growth<br />

ambitions<br />

LOCAL SEARCH: SELECTION<br />

OF EARLY INVESTOR(S) BY<br />

THE ENTREPRENEUR<br />

Startup Development<br />

<strong>High</strong>-growth company<br />

Early investor: highly experienced<br />

PERSISTENT DIFFERENCES CAUSED BY:<br />

. Venture professionalization<br />

. Stunted Learning<br />

. Investor syndication preferences<br />

Low-growth company<br />

Early investor: relatively inexperienced<br />

Time<br />

176


Although the above indicates that entrepreneurial ventures which demonstrate performance may change<br />

their evolutionary path under some conditions, it is unlikely that performance is entirely driving the<br />

subsequent finance process rather than the type of investor that contributed early finance. First, during the<br />

early startup phase, our cases did not differ systematically in their potential to develop into professional<br />

biotechnology ventures. Nevertheless, in the companies backed by experienced investors much more<br />

effort was put under the impetus of these investors to professionalize, which substantially influenced<br />

subsequent venture development. Second, not all ventures backed by inexperienced investors are<br />

necessarily badly performing ventures. Although Entomed, for example, failed to realize its high growth<br />

ambitions the company was able to raise follow-on finance on two occasions from other relatively<br />

inexperienced investors. This indicates that despite the inherent potential within the venture, Entomed is<br />

unable to translate this potential in high growth.<br />

4.7.1. Reframing the Entrepreneurial Finance Process as an Evolutionary Model<br />

Two of the most influential theories in modern corporate finance that are generally used to frame finance<br />

decisions are the static trade-off and pecking order theory (Cassar, 2004). Most researchers have treated<br />

these theories as competing theories, which resulted in numerous large-sample studies empirically testing<br />

which framework performs best (Fama and French, 2005; Frank and Goyal, 2005; Shyam-Sunder and<br />

Myers, 1999). Nevertheless, the similarities between these theories have typically been ignored. Both<br />

theories are teleological models. First, they depict the finance process as a process where managers make<br />

optimal finance decisions with value maximization as the ultimate goal (Myers, 1984). Second, they<br />

assume limited influence from prior finance decisions on future finance decisions as venture will actively<br />

rebalance their financial structure towards an optimum (Hovakimian, Opler, and Titman, 2001; Leary and<br />

Roberts, 2005). Also popular are life-cycle models. The financial growth cycle is probably the most<br />

influential life-cycle model. It combines pecking order theory and optimal security design and indicates<br />

177


that the availability and suitability of different sources of finance change as a venture develops and grows<br />

(Berger and Udell, 1998).<br />

Although current teleological and life-cycle models advanced our understanding of the finance process<br />

significantly, much remains unknown. Current theories are not able to explain all stylized facts in<br />

corporate finance (Frank and Goyal, 2005). Furthermore, these theories are unable to explain the key role<br />

of the finance process in shaping sustainable differences in venture development (Subrahmanyam, 2007).<br />

Without in any way dismissing the valuable insights offered by teleological and life-cycle models, this<br />

study suggests that we can further increase our knowledge of the finance process -a key organizational<br />

process- by using a different lens. Our findings indicate an evolutionary model may be particularly<br />

insightful. Hence focusing on early differences in the finance process and on the persistence of finance<br />

decisions across time may be a particularly insightful strategy to gain a more comprehensive<br />

understanding of the finance process. It corresponds with the view that organizational processes should be<br />

studied from different lenses, which each focus on different generative mechanisms explaining change<br />

(Van de Ven and Poole, 1995).<br />

An important consideration is whether evolutionary trajectories in the finance process are limited to our<br />

setting of biotechnology startups. We believe our findings relate to a broader set of entrepreneurial<br />

ventures. First, most of the biotechnology entrepreneurs in our cases are scientists with limited finance<br />

experience, which might limit their search for finance. However, the majority of entrepreneurs are<br />

inexperienced and lack networks in the investment community (Westhead, Ucbasaran, and Wright, 2003).<br />

Moreover, entrepreneurs are generally less familiar with finance sources commonly used to fund growth,<br />

such as venture capital, compared to traditional finance sources, such as internal finance and bank debt<br />

(Van Auken, 2001).<br />

178


Second, it is remarkable that biotechnology entrepreneurs limit their search for startup finance to only a<br />

few related investors they happen to know given that finance decisions are very important in the<br />

biotechnology context (Greene, 1999). If in this setting entrepreneurs limit their search for finance, then<br />

what should we expect from entrepreneurs in an average venture, where finance decisions are considered<br />

to be less critical? Indeed, the concept of local search in the search for finance corresponds with the<br />

stylized fact that the majority of entrepreneurs start with finance from known investors, i.e. family and<br />

friends (Berger and Udell, 1998). An important boundary condition for local search behavior is probably<br />

the entrepreneurial setting. Large and quoted corporations typically employ multiple finance specialists.<br />

Hence, we might expect a more comprehensive search for finance that focuses more on value<br />

maximization in these corporations.<br />

Finally, we focus on the mobilization of venture capital finance across time. Recent studies have pointed<br />

out the importance of heterogeneity among venture capital investors (Hsu, 2004; Sorensen, 2007). It is a<br />

common belief that debt financing is more homogenous than equity finance. Nevertheless, recent studies<br />

indicate that debt is also heterogeneous in nature and more importantly that this heterogeneity also has<br />

important implications for R&D investments and firm growth (David, O’Brien, and Yoshikawa, 2008).<br />

Hence, not only differences in the equity finance process are likely to persist, but also differences in the<br />

debt finance process are likely to have a long-term impact on venture development. This implies that our<br />

findings also bear relevance beyond ventures that mobilize venture capital finance.<br />

4.7.2. Resource Mobilization and Initial Network Formation<br />

We contribute to a broader literature on resource mobilization and initial network development by using<br />

the finance process as the research context. Relationships with venture capital investors are one of the<br />

earliest and most critical relationships formed, especially within young technology-based ventures, as<br />

these ventures need swift access to outside finance to support further development (Katila, Rosenberger,<br />

179


and Eisenhardt, 2008). In this context, investors are typically portrayed as the more powerful, desirable<br />

and resource-rich firms, while entrepreneurial ventures are typically portrayed as passive bystanders that<br />

are in need of outside resources.<br />

The mainstream view is that it are the more powerful, established and rich-rich firms that are particularly<br />

likely to contribute resources to ventures headed by entrepreneurs with prior experience and ventures that<br />

have demonstrated outstanding accomplishments since founding (Cable and Shane, 2002; Eckhardt,<br />

Shane, and Delmar, 2006; Sorensen, 2007; Hsu, 2007; Hallen, 2008). Contrary to prior research, our study<br />

indicates that the more established and resource-rich firms do not necessarily have access to the entire<br />

pool of entrepreneurial ventures with high growth potential. Entrepreneurs heavily affect early relationship<br />

formation by not engaging in a comprehensive search for startup resources. They avoid loose contacts<br />

with many potential resource providers and instead target only one or a few related firms to acquire startup<br />

resources.<br />

External relationships with firms create dyadic ties, which are the basic building block of the external<br />

network for new ventures (Hite and Hesterly, 2001). Two opposing views exist on how the use of<br />

embedded ties to mobilize startup resources may influence subsequent resource mobilization and venture<br />

development. Network closure theorists propose that a close-knit network of embedded ties are beneficial<br />

as these ties create an environment of trust and cooperation, which is needed to mobilize critical resources<br />

(Coleman, 1990). Structural hole theorists, however, propose that embedded ties act as a source of inertia<br />

thereby constraining subsequent resource mobilization (Gargiulo and Benassi, 2000). Loose connections<br />

with multiple firms, which offer ventures more diversity in information and brokerage opportunities<br />

created by the lack of connection between separate clusters, are particularly valuable (Burt, 1992).<br />

This paper contributes to bridging the tension between these two views. Our cases indicate how early<br />

embedded ties both constrain and facilitate ventures in their subsequent resource mobilization and<br />

180


development. Both high-growth ventures and low-growth ventures resorted to embedded firms to mobilize<br />

startup resources. Whether early embedded ties foster or hinder ventures in their subsequent development<br />

is likely to be contingent on the compositional quality of these ties. Compositional quality refers to the<br />

extent to which ties can provide the needed resources (Hite and Hesterly, 2001). In our research context,<br />

for example, it refers to an investor’s ability to provide not only tangible financial resources, but also<br />

better-quality services, such as professionalization of the venture and access to a network comprising other<br />

prominent actors.<br />

Our cases demonstrate how early ties to firms that are high in compositional quality facilitate subsequent<br />

resource mobilization and venture development. Experienced investors, for example, typically helped in<br />

raising large amounts of follow-on finance by initiating venture professionalization and offering ventures<br />

access to their network in the financial community. Early ties to firms that are low in compositional<br />

quality, however, constrained subsequent resource mobilization. Relatively inexperienced investors, for<br />

example, generally contribute little to venture professionalization and repel other investors from<br />

contributing financial resources in the future. Our cases demonstrate that not only the history of the<br />

venture itself matters when mobilizing resources. An important factor that may facilitate or hinder a<br />

venture in its ability to mobilize resources is the history of the firms from which the venture mobilized its<br />

early resources.<br />

4.8. Conclusion<br />

Overall, our theoretical contribution lies in reframing the entrepreneurial finance process as an<br />

evolutionary process. We demonstrate persistence in the finance process and the central role of local<br />

search behavior and investor heterogeneity. These ideas stand in stark contrast to current corporate finance<br />

theories in which economic rationality and optimal contracts dominate. More broadly, we add to a dearth<br />

of research on resource mobilization and network formation in new ventures. While entrepreneurial<br />

181


ventures are often depicted as passive in their efforts to mobilize resources from more established<br />

resource-rich firms, we highlight the key role of entrepreneurs in the mobilization of startup resources by<br />

restricting their search to related firms. Moreover, we bring to light the processes explaining why early<br />

affiliation to some firms led to an accumulation of advantages, while early affiliation to other firms led to<br />

an accumulation of disadvantages in subsequent resource mobilization efforts.<br />

References<br />

Ahuja G. and Katila R. (2004) “Where do resources come from? The role of idiosyncratic situations.”<br />

Strategic Management Journal 25: 887-907.<br />

Baum J.A.C., Calabrese T. and Silverman B.S. (2000) “Don't go it alone: Alliance network composition<br />

and startups' performance in Canadian biotechnology.” Strategic Management Journal 21: 267-294.<br />

Baum J.A.C. and Silverman B.S. (2004) “Picking winners or building them? Alliance, intellectual, and<br />

human capital as selection criteria in venture financing and performance of biotechnology startups.”<br />

Journal of Business Venturing 19: 411-436.<br />

Baum J.A.C., Rowley T.J., Shipilov A.V. and Chuang Y. (2005) “Dancing with strangers: Aspiration<br />

performance and the search for underwriting syndicate partners.” Administrative Science Quarterly 50:<br />

536-575.<br />

Beckman C.M. and Burton M.D. (2008) “Founding the future: Path dependence in the evolution of top<br />

management teams from founding to IPO.” Organization Science 19: 3-24.<br />

Berger A.N. and Udell G.F. (1998) “The economics of small business finance: The roles of private equity<br />

and debt markets in the financial growth cycle.” Journal of Banking and Finance 22: 613-673.<br />

Brander J.A., Amit R. and Antweiler W. (2002) “Venture-capital syndication: Improved venture selection<br />

vs. the value-added hypothesis.” Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 11: 423-452.<br />

Brealey R.A. and Myers S.C. (2000) “Principles of Corporate Finance.” 6th edn. McGraw-Hill.<br />

182


Burt R.S. (1992) “Structural holes: The social structure of competition.” Cambridge, MA: Harvard<br />

University Press.<br />

Cassar G. (2004) “The financing of business start-ups.” Journal of Business Venturing 19: 261-283.<br />

Chung S.A., Singh H. and Lee K. (2000) “Complementarity, status similarity and social capital as drivers<br />

of alliance formation.” Strategic Management Journal 21: 1-22.<br />

Cohen W.M. and Levinthal D.A. (1990) “Absorptive-capacity - A new perspective on learning and<br />

innovation.” Administrative Science Quarterly 35: 128-152.<br />

Coleman J.S. (1990) “Foundations of social theory.” Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.<br />

David P., O’Brien J.P. and Yoshikawa T. (2008) “The implications of debt heterogeneity for R&D<br />

investment and firm performance.” Academy of Management Journal 51: 165-181.<br />

Davila A., Foster G. and Gupta M. (2003) “Venture capital financing and the growth of startup firms.”<br />

Journal of Business Venturing 18: 689-708.<br />

Deeds D.L., Decarolis D. and Coombs J.E. (1997) “The impact of firm-specific capabilities on the amount<br />

of capital raised in an initial public offering: Evidence from the biotechnology industry.” Journal of<br />

Business Venturing 12: 31-46.<br />

Dierickx I. and Cool K. (1989) “Asset stock accumulation and sustainability of competitive advantage.”<br />

Management Science 35: 1504-1511.<br />

Eckhardt J.T., Shane S. and Delmar F. (2006) “Multistage selection and the financing of new ventures.”<br />

Management Science 52: 220-232.<br />

Eisenhardt K.M. (1989a) “Building theories from case-study research.” Academy of Management Review<br />

14: 532- 550.<br />

183


Eisenhardt K.M. (1989b) “Agency theory - An assessment and review.” Academy of Management Review<br />

14: 57-74.<br />

European Venture Capital Association, EVCA (2005) “Annual survey of pan-European private equity and<br />

venture capital activity.” Zaventem: EVCA<br />

Fama E.F. and French K.R. (2005) “<strong>Financing</strong> decisions: who issues stock?” Journal of Financial<br />

Economics 76: 549-582.<br />

Frank M.Z. and Goyal V.K. (2005) “Trade-off and pecking order theories of debt.” In: Handbook of<br />

corporate finance: Empirical corporate finance (Ed. by B. Espen Eckbo), Chapter 7, Elsevier/North-<br />

Holland.<br />

Fried V.H. and Hisrich R.D. (1994) “Towards a model of venture capital investment decision making.”<br />

Financial Management 23: 28-37.<br />

Flanders Institute for Biotechnology (2002) “Biotechnology in Flanders: An industrial perspective.”<br />

http://www.vib.be/VIB/EN/ (Last consulted: June 2008).<br />

Gargiulo M. (1993) “Two-step leverage: managing constraint in organizational politics.” Administrative<br />

Science Quarterly 38: 1-19.<br />

Gargiulo M. and Benassi M. (2000) “Trapped in your own net? Network cohesion, structural holes, and<br />

the adaptation of social capital.” Organization Science 11: 183-196.<br />

Gompers P.A. and Lerner J. (1998) “What drives venture capital fundraising.” Brookings Papers on<br />

Economic Activity Sp. Iss.: 149-204.<br />

Greene H.E. (1999) “Picking your VC.” Nature Biotechnology 17: BE25-BE26.<br />

Hallen B. (2008) “The causes and consequences of the initial network positions of new organizations:<br />

<strong>From</strong> whom do entrepreneurs receive investments?” Administrative Science Quarterly 53: 685-718.<br />

184


Heirman A. and Clarysse B. (2004) “How and why do research-based start-ups differ at founding? A<br />

resource-based configurational perspective.” The Journal of Technology Transfer 29: 247-268.<br />

Hellmann T. and Puri M. (2002) “Venture capital and the professionalization of startup firms: Empirical<br />

evidence.” Journal of Finance 57: 169-197.<br />

Hellmann T., Lindsey L. and Puri M. (2008) “Building Relationships Early: Banks in Venture Capital.”<br />

Review of Financial Studies 21: 513-541<br />

Himmelberg C.P. and Petersen B.C. (1994) “Research-and-development and internal finance - a panel<br />

study of small firms in high-tech industries.” Review of Economics and Statistics 76: 38-51.<br />

Hite J.M. and Hesterly W.S. (2001) “The evolution of firm networks: <strong>From</strong> emergence to early growth of<br />

the firm.” Strategic Management Journal 22: 275-286.<br />

Hoang H. and Antoncic B. (2003) “Network-based research in entrepreneurship: A critical review.”<br />

Journal of Business Venturing 18: 165-187.<br />

Hochberg Y.V., Ljungqvist A. and Lu Y. (2007) “Whom you know matters: Venture capital networks and<br />

investment performance.” Journal of Finance 62: 251-301.<br />

Hovakimian A., Opler T. and Titman S. (2001) “The debt-equity choice.” The Journal of Financial and<br />

Quantitative Analysis 36: 1-24<br />

Hsu D.H. (2004) “What do entrepreneurs pay for venture capital affiliation?” Journal of Finance 59: 1805-<br />

1844.<br />

Hsu D.H. (2007) “Experienced entrepreneurial founders, organizational capital, and venture capital<br />

funding.” Research Policy 36: 722-741.<br />

Hubbard,R.G. (1998) “Capital-market imperfections and investment.” Journal of Economic Literature 36:<br />

193-225.<br />

185


Katila R., Rosenberger J.D. and Eisenhardt K.M. (2008) “Swimming with sharks: Technology ventures,<br />

defense mechanisms and corporate relationships.” Administrative Science Quarterly 53: 295-332.<br />

Leary M.T. and Roberts M.R. (2005) “Do firms rebalance their capital structure.” Journal of Finance 60:<br />

2575-2619.<br />

Lee C., Lee K. and Pennings J.M. (2001) “Internal capabilities, external networks, and performance: A<br />

study on technology-based ventures.” Strategic Management Journal 22: 615-640.<br />

Lerner J. (1994) “The syndication of venture capital investments.” Financial Management 23: 16-27.<br />

Lerner J. (1999 ) “The government as venture capitalist: The long-run impact of the SBIR program.”<br />

Journal of Business 72: 285-318.<br />

Lindelof P. and Lofsten H. (2005) “Academic versus corporate new technology-based firms in Swedish<br />

science parks: An analysis of growth, business networks and financing.” International Journal of<br />

Technology Management 31: 334-357.<br />

Maurer I. and Ebers M. (2006) “Dynamics of social capital and their performance implications: Lessons<br />

from biotechnology startups.” Administrative Science Quarterly 51: 262-292.<br />

Miller C.C., Cardinal L.B. and Glick W.H. (1994) “Retrospective reports in organizational research: A<br />

reexamination of recent evidence.” Academy of Management Journal 40: 189-204<br />

Muzyka D., Birley S. and Leleux B. (1996) “Trade-offs in the investment decisions of European venture<br />

capitalists.” Journal of Business Venturing 11: 273-287.<br />

Myers S.C. (1984) “The capital structure puzzle.” Journal of Finance 39: 575-592.<br />

Neisser U. (1982) “Memory Observed: Remembering in Natural Contexts.” San Francisco: Freeman.<br />

Nilsson A. (2001) “Biotechnology firms in Sweden.” Small Business Economics 17: 93-103.<br />

186


Noda T. and Collis D.J. (2001) “The evolution of intraindustry firm heterogeneity: Insights from a process<br />

study.” Academy of Management Journal 44: 897-925.<br />

Oakey R.P. (1995) “<strong>High</strong>-Technology New Firms: Variable Barriers to <strong>Growth</strong>.” London: Paul Chapman.<br />

Oliver C. (1997) “Sustainable competitive advantage: Combining institutional and resource-based views.”<br />

Strategic Management Journal 18: 697-713.<br />

Pisano G.P. (2006) “Can science be a business? Lessons from biotech.” Harvard Business Review 84:<br />

114-+.<br />

Puri M. and Zarutskie R. (2008) “On the lifecycle dynamics of venture-capital- and non-venture-capital-<br />

financed firms.” US Census Bureau Center for Economic Studies Paper No. CES-WP-08-13.<br />

Rangan S. (2000) “The problem of search and deliberation in economic action: When social networks<br />

really matter.” Academy of Management Review 25: 813-828.<br />

Sahlman W.A. (1990) “The structure and governance of venture-capital organizations.” Journal of<br />

Financial Economics 27: 473-521.<br />

Sapienza H.J., Korsgaard M.A. and Forbes D. (2003) “The Self-Determination Motive and Entrepreneurs<br />

Choice of <strong>Financing</strong>.” In: Advances in Entrepreneurship, Firm Emergence and <strong>Growth</strong> (Ed. by J.Katz and<br />

D.Shepherd) Greenwich, JAI Press.<br />

Shane S. and Cable D. (2002 ) “Network ties, reputation, and the financing of new ventures.”<br />

Management Science 48: 364-381.<br />

Shyam-Sunder L. and Myers S. C. (1999) “Testing static tradeoff against pecking order models of capital<br />

structure.” Journal of Financial Economics 21: 219-244.<br />

Sorensen M. (2007) “How smart is smart money? A two-sided matching model of venture capital.”<br />

Journal of Finance 62: 2725-2762.<br />

187


Sorenson O. and Stuart T.E. (2001) “Syndication Networks and the Spatial Distribution of Venture Capital<br />

Investments.” American Journal of Sociology 106: 1546-1588.<br />

Sorenson O. and Stuart T.E. (2008) “Bringing the Context Back In: Settings and the Search for Syndicate<br />

Partners in Venture Capital Investment Networks.” Administrative Science Quarterly 53: 266-294.<br />

Stiglitz J.E. and Weiss A. (1981) “Credit rationing in markets with incomplete information.” American<br />

Economic Review 71: 393-410.<br />

Stinchcombe A.L. (1965) “Social structure and organizations.” In: Handbook of Organizations. (Ed. by<br />

J.G. March) Chicago, Rand McNally.<br />

Stuart T.E. and Podolny J.M. (1996) “Local search and the evolution of technological capabilities.”<br />

Strategic Management Journal 17: 21-38.<br />

Stuart T.E., Hoang H. and Hybels R.C. (1999) “Interorganizational endorsements and the performance of<br />

entrepreneurial ventures.” Administrative Science Quarterly 44: 315-349.<br />

Stuart T.E. (2000) “Interorganizational alliances and the performance of firms: A study of growth and<br />

innovation rates in a high-technology industry.” Strategic Management Journal 21: 791-811.<br />

Subrahmanyam A. (2007) “Behavioural finance: A review and synthesis.” European Financial<br />

Management 14: 12-29.<br />

Ueda M. (2004) “Banks versus venture capital: Project evaluation, screening, and expropriation.” Journal<br />

of Finance 59: 601-621.<br />

Uzzi B. (1999) “Embeddedness in the making of financial capital: How social relations and networks<br />

benefit firms seeking financing.” American Sociological Review 64: 481-505.<br />

Van Auken H.E. (2001) “<strong>Financing</strong> small technology-based companies: The relationship between<br />

familiarity with capital and ability to price and negotiate investment.” Journal of Small Business<br />

Management 39: 240-258.<br />

188


Van de Ven A.H. and Poole M.S. (1995) “Explaining development and change in organizations.”<br />

Academy of Management Review 20: 510-540.<br />

Van de Ven A.H. (2007) “Engaged scholarship: A guide for organizational and social research.” Oxford:<br />

Oxford University Press.<br />

Westhead P., Ucbasaran D. and Wright M (2003) “Differences between private firms owned by novice,<br />

serial and portfolio entrepreneurs: Implications for policy makers and practitioners.” Regional Studies 37:<br />

187-200.<br />

Wiklund J. and Shepherd D. (2003) “Aspiring for, and achieving growth: The moderating role of<br />

resources and opportunities.” Journal of Management Studies 40: 1919-1941.<br />

Wright M. and Lockett A. (2003) “The structure and management of alliances: Syndication in the venture<br />

capital industry.” Journal of Management Studies 40: 2073-2102.<br />

Yin R.K. (1984) “Case study research: Design and Methods.” Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.<br />

Zukin S. and DiMaggio P.J. (1990) “Introduction.” In: Structures of capital: The social organization of the<br />

economy. (Ed. by S. Zukin and P. J. DiMaggio) Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.<br />

189


Chapter 5: Limitations, Avenues for Future Research and<br />

Implications for Practice<br />

The three studies included in this dissertation all investigate the relationship between the entrepreneurial<br />

finance process and company growth in a Continental European setting. Study 1 looks at incremental<br />

finance decisions in high-growth companies. In particular, it investigates the relationship between high-<br />

growth company characteristics and the use of internal finance, debt finance and new equity finance. We<br />

empirically test the pecking order theory and extend the notion of debt capacity. Study 2 focuses on<br />

investor heterogeneity and examines which investors contribute most to company development. I look at<br />

the role of venture capital firm experience and legitimacy on the growth pattern of portfolio companies.<br />

Finally, study 3 offers a dynamic view of the finance process. It demonstrates how the finance process<br />

differs between high- and low-performing entrepreneurial ventures, how those differences originate and<br />

how differences are likely to persist across time.<br />

The lack of longitudinal data on unquoted businesses is an important shortcoming characterizing most<br />

research in entrepreneurship, finance and organizational growth (Davidsson and Wiklund, 2006). Most of<br />

our knowledge relates to companies that have had some successful conditional outcome like going public<br />

and joining a strategic alliance (Puri and Zarutskie, 2008) and research on small company finance is often<br />

subject to a survivorship bias (Cassar, 2004). Each study in this dissertation builds on a different hand-<br />

collected longitudinal dataset comprising high-quality (financial) data on unquoted companies. Moreover,<br />

all datasets comprise companies that eventually fail and hence findings are not subject to survivorship<br />

bias. The datasets permit to provide important insights in the finance process of unquoted companies and<br />

its relationship with company growth in a Continental European research context.<br />

190


The remainder of this chapter is structured as follows. I start by discussing the limitations of this<br />

dissertation and suggest some promising avenues for further research. Next, I discuss the implications for<br />

entrepreneurs, investors and policy makers.<br />

5.1. Limitations and Avenues for Future Research<br />

All studies have their limitations and this is not different for the studies in this dissertation. The first study<br />

used a large database of high-growth companies and focused on financial decision making within this<br />

setting. Although I had access to yearly financial statement data for all Belgian companies, including the<br />

ones identified as high-growth companies, not all companies are required to report sales. This implies that<br />

the group of high-growth companies identified by using the sales concept is likely to be incomplete. To<br />

mitigate this problem, I used added value as an alternative concept, which all companies are required to<br />

report. Sales are an important input variable in the calculation of added value and hence the correlation<br />

between the two growth indicators was rather high.<br />

Another shortcoming of the first study was that it only focused on how high-growth companies are<br />

finance. Hence, this study is unable to distinguish between financial policies in high- and low-growth<br />

companies. Moreover, it does not provide insights into questions such as whether access to finance causes<br />

growth or growth requires finance. Despite its shortcomings, the first study demonstrated that high-growth<br />

companies with low leverage do not necessarily have debt capacity. Prior research has equated high<br />

leverage ratios with limited debt capacity. Scholars have raised doubts about the validity of the pecking<br />

order theory, as high-growth companies with low leverage should be able to attract additional debt<br />

finance, but many of these companies unexpectedly raise new equity (Fama and French, 2005). The first<br />

study demonstrated that such claims reflect a limited view on debt capacity. Not only leverage, but<br />

leverage and cashflows will determine whether companies are able to attract additional debt finance. A<br />

good real-world example is provided by young biotechnology ventures. These ventures have low leverage<br />

191


and despite these low leverage ratios are unable to attract additional debt finance. This is because they<br />

lack the necessary cashflows to fulfill the fixed debt-related payments. The first study calls for more<br />

research, which further develops the notion of debt capacity.<br />

The second study focused on the impact of the experience and legitimacy of the initial lead venture capital<br />

investor on subsequent company development by using appropriate longitudinal techniques. A particular<br />

methodological challenge was to distinguish investor experience from investor legitimacy. Relatively high<br />

correlation between the measures forced me to carefully build models were multicollinearity concerns<br />

were limited. Nevertheless, I reported robust findings indicating that portfolio companies benefited from<br />

receiving finance from investors with high industry experience and legitimate investors (i.e. older<br />

investors and investors that appear more frequently in the media). An interesting observation, however,<br />

was that even within the group of companies backed by similar types of investors there was significant<br />

variability in how firms grow. While some firms backed by a particular type of investor experienced<br />

dramatic growth and went public others backed by the same type of investors were outright failures. This<br />

raises the question if and when the effect of connecting with particular types of investors varies for<br />

different types of firms, and so yields different consequences for firm growth.<br />

One particularly interesting contingency is the effect of founder experience on the relationship between<br />

venture capital and growth. Organizational theory indicates that experienced founders will be particularly<br />

likely to gain access to experienced venture capital finance (Hallen, 2008). However, experienced<br />

entrepreneurs probably require less knowledge-based resources from venture capital investors given their<br />

own background and experience. One might expect that companies founded by inexperienced<br />

entrepreneurs may particularly benefit from the infusion of knowledge-based resources to complement the<br />

lack of founder experience. Moreover, connecting with particular investors, such as highly experienced<br />

venture capital investors is costly (Hsu, 2004). Again especially inexperienced investors will be willing to<br />

pay a premium for the advice and other services provided by more experienced investors, while<br />

192


organizational theory indicates they are less likely to obtain finance from these more experienced<br />

investors. Overall, it remains unclear whether investor experience and entrepreneurial experience will act<br />

as substitutes or complements.<br />

The third study used longitudinal case studies to gain a deeper understanding of the finance process in<br />

high- and low-growth ventures. It demonstrated how early differences originate in the finance process and<br />

how differences persist across time between high- and low-growth ventures. A particular challenge to<br />

generate insights on how the finance process of ventures relates to growth was to select matched pairs of<br />

ventures that operated under similar conditions but differed considerably with respect to their growth.<br />

Although a perfect match was never possible, I believe that consistent findings across multiple comparable<br />

cases increase the reliability and validity of the findings. The third study indicated how early investors<br />

may both facility and constrain ventures in the subsequent mobilization of financial resources.<br />

This third study calls for more research on when ventures resort to existing or new investors to obtain<br />

follow-on finance. Two opposing perspective may be found in the literature. One perspective based on<br />

agency conflicts indicates that insiders may continue to invest in projects with significant probabilities of<br />

destroying value (Admati and Pfleiderer, 1994). Once entrepreneurs have raised venture capital, the early<br />

investors become insiders. The early investors may learn of problems within the company through time.<br />

Nevertheless, these problems are not necessarily visible for outsiders, due to the existence of asymmetric<br />

information. Early investors now have the incentive to spend other investors’ money and hence may help<br />

or force entrepreneurs to search for new finance from other investors. In this perspective, early investors<br />

will keep good companies for their own and try to attract as much finance from colleague investors for<br />

bad quality companies.<br />

A different perspective indicates that early investors will invite colleague investors to join high-quality<br />

companies, in the hope that these investors will return the favor in the future (Sorenson and Stuart, 2001).<br />

193


Additionally, early investors may invite other high-quality investors to invest in their portfolio companies<br />

in order to infuse more (complementary) tangible and intangible resources, which contribute to the<br />

development of these companies (Brander, Amit, and Antweiler, 2002). The case study evidence provided<br />

in the third paper provides limited evidence for the agency perspective. Rather it points more towards the<br />

vision that especially high-quality companies will raise finance from (existing and) new investors.<br />

Moreover, I want to highlight two main limitations of all studies in this dissertation. First, all studies have<br />

a limited geographical coverage and focus on the finance process of unquoted Belgian companies. We<br />

previously argued that this context has many advantages. First, single country studies reduce non-<br />

measured variance and thereby control for country-specific determinants, such as the financial context and<br />

legal context. Second, all Belgian companies are required to file detailed financial statement data with the<br />

National Bank, which implies we have access to high-quality longitudinal data on unquoted companies.<br />

Finally, while most studies have focused on financial policies in market-based economies, Belgium is a<br />

typical example of a bank-based economy. Despite its advantages, a drawback of single-country studies is<br />

that that the external validity of the findings may be low for other regions. Nevertheless, reflecting on this<br />

drawback, I believe that Belgian companies are probably more similar to the average company in many<br />

other regions, compared to prior studies that exclusively focused on quoted U.S. companies (Shyam-<br />

Sunder and Myers, 1999) or entrepreneurial companies operating in very specific, one of a kind<br />

environments, such as Silicon Valley (Hallen, 2008).<br />

Second, while all studies in this dissertation put the finance process on the foreground, they put other<br />

important organizational processes, such as the development of the entrepreneurial management team and<br />

technology in the background. Nevertheless, as indicated in the final study, the finance process may, for<br />

example, influence the structure and experience of the management team and vice versa. A more complete<br />

understanding of the relationship between different organizational processes in high- and low-growth<br />

companies may significantly enhance our understanding of the emergence of high-growth companies.<br />

194


However, we have no choice but to cut down on the complexity of a problem but to cut down on the<br />

complexity of the problem domain by putting some processes in the foreground and others in the<br />

background (Van de Ven, 2007).<br />

Overall, this dissertation offered a broader framework to grasp the complexity of the entrepreneurial<br />

finance process and indicated how the development of evolutionary models -incorporating foundational<br />

behavioral concepts– may be a particularly valuable research strategy to increase our understanding of the<br />

entrepreneurial finance process. It is important to note that I do not argue that evolutionary models are<br />

superior to other models such as teleological models. On the contrary, all models are valuable and direct<br />

researchers’ attention to particular motors of change.<br />

To organizational growth scholars the dissertation indicated that future growth studies should more fully<br />

incorporate other dimensions of the finance process besides the amount of finance raised. More financial<br />

resources at startup are not necessarily better. Other dimensions, such as the type of investor that<br />

contributes finance, might offer ventures a competitive advantage as well. Moreover, future research<br />

should address the temporal pattern of growth. For this purpose, longitudinal dataset will be required. This<br />

will require scholars to become better acquainted with the appropriate longitudinal techniques to study<br />

longitudinal datasets. Recent years have seen considerable progress in the development of statistical<br />

methods for the analysis of longitudinal data. These modern techniques will allow organizational scholars<br />

to focus on different questions, which more fully incorporate the essence of organizational growth; namely<br />

change across time.<br />

5.2. Practical Implications<br />

In this section, I discuss the practical implications of the different studies in this dissertation for<br />

respectively entrepreneurs, investors and policy makers.<br />

195


5.2.1. Entrepreneurs<br />

By studying the finance process of (small) unquoted companies and its relationship with company growth,<br />

growth-oriented entrepreneurs can gain a more thorough understanding of the financial policies related<br />

with high-growth companies. First, despite the media visibility and research attention towards companies<br />

that raise large-amounts of venture capital or raise public equity finance, outside equity is not a<br />

prerequisite to realize high growth across time. Over 80% of finance events in high-growth companies<br />

relate to internally generated funds and debt finance. It is only when debt capacity is exhausted and large<br />

amounts of finance are needed that high-growth companies move to outside equity investors.<br />

Second, many entrepreneurial companies are constantly strapped for cash and hence entrepreneurs are<br />

under pressure to accept finance when and where they can find it irrespective of the source of finance.<br />

Nevertheless, the experience and legitimacy of the investors from whom entrepreneurs raise early finance<br />

has a long-lasting impact on company development. <strong>Companies</strong> that raise finance from investors with<br />

high industry experience and legitimacy in the marketplace are able to recruit more people, mobilize more<br />

assets and raise more follow-on finance to fuel growth.<br />

Third, entrepreneurs are generally local in their search for early finance and target only one or a few<br />

related investors. Although this may be a cost-effective and speedy way to obtain access to well-needed<br />

financial resource, it might also be advisable to conduct a broader search and test the market for credible<br />

alternatives. Especially entrepreneurial companies that are not connected to highly experienced investors<br />

may benefit from a more comprehensive search.<br />

Forth, a common believe among entrepreneurs is that highly experienced and legitimate investors select<br />

larger more mature companies and typically avoid investing in highly risky companies that are still in the<br />

196


seed phase. Our studies indicate that more or less experienced and legitimate investors do not select<br />

different companies in terms of initial size in employment and total assets. Moreover, when studying the<br />

finance process of new biotechnology ventures, we observed that even highly experienced investors<br />

contributed seed finance to new biotechnology ventures.<br />

Finally, early investors will not necessarily facilitate the acquisition of future financial resources, but may<br />

also repel future investors from contributing financial resources to the company. Our interviews indicated<br />

how some entrepreneurs started with relatively inexperienced investors, but wanted to raise finance from<br />

more experienced investors in the future. This is extremely difficult, however, and most companies fail in<br />

this endeavor. When lucky, they can still find additional finance from other inexperienced investors, but<br />

many companies become what may be called “living-death”, i.e. the company survives, but is unlikely to<br />

ever realize its initial ambitions.<br />

5.2.2. Investors<br />

Insights from the different studies in this dissertation are important for professional investors as well.<br />

First, outside equity investors do not have automatic access to all types of companies. <strong>Companies</strong> that<br />

search for outside equity are typically those companies that are unprofitable, have limited debt capacity,<br />

invest significantly in intangible assets and are characterized by a high risk of failure. Moreover,<br />

entrepreneurs are generally local in their search for finance especially during the startup phase. Most<br />

entrepreneurs limit their search for finance to those investors with whom they have at least a superficial<br />

direct or indirect relationship. Hence, active deal origination remains important for those investors that<br />

want to play a key role in building young high-potential companies.<br />

Second, inexperienced venture capital investors sporadically contributing capital to young knowledge-<br />

intensive companies operating in complex industries such as biotechnology may question their current<br />

197


investment strategy. Given the required expertise and network structure to guide these companies through<br />

different stages of development, it might be a better strategy for inexperienced investors to only act as a<br />

non-lead investor in a syndicate. I did note that when large amounts of finance are needed in the later<br />

stages of development, highly experienced venture capital investors invited relatively inexperienced<br />

investors to join an investment syndicate.<br />

5.2.3. Policy makers<br />

The different studies in this dissertation also offer some important insights and recommendations for<br />

public policy. Two important topics are highlighted in this subsection. First, policy makers should be<br />

aware that although outside equity is important to allow companies to grow beyond their debt capacity,<br />

high-growth companies prefer to use retained earnings as an internal source to finance investments<br />

whenever possible. Hence, recent initiatives by the Belgian government, such as the ‘notional interest<br />

deduction’ are probably well-taken. This policy measure reduces the fiscal discrimination between debt<br />

and equity finance by allowing companies to deduct from their taxable income an amount equal to the<br />

interest they would have paid on their capital (including retained earnings) if that capital was long-term<br />

debt. This measure increases the incentive of companies to retain earnings and increase the amount of<br />

internal funds that are available within the company instead of transferring them to government. The value<br />

of the ‘notional interest deduction’ is highly debated. Some politicians call to abolish this measure, as<br />

costs are high for government and taxpayers, while it would especially benefit large and rich corporations<br />

without creating additional investments. I provide evidence that such claims are shortsighted, as retained<br />

earnings are the preferred path used by high-growth companies to finance growth in employment, total<br />

assets, value-added, sales and cash flow.<br />

Second, government officials are increasing the supply of outside equity finance to especially young<br />

innovative and high-growth oriented companies by contributing significant amounts of finance into the<br />

198


venture capital industry. The main rational for this government intervention in the venture capital market<br />

is the role of venture capital in providing funds for companies that find it difficult to attract finance from<br />

more traditional financiers such as banks and hence reduces the finance constraints (Lerner, 1999). It is<br />

further motivated by the observation that a mature venture capital market in the U.S. played a critical role<br />

in the emergence of new industries such as biotechnology (Berger and Udell, 1998). However, policy<br />

makers should realize that venture capital investors not only contribute financial resources. Policy<br />

measures targeting experienced and legitimate investors may have a disproportionate positive effect on<br />

employment generation and asset accumulation in an economy.<br />

References<br />

Admati A.R. and Pfleiderer P. (1994) “Robust financial contracting and the role of venture capitalists.”<br />

Journal of Finance 49: 371-402.<br />

Berger A.N. and Udell G.F. (1998) “The economics of small business finance: The roles of private equity<br />

and debt markets in the financial growth cycle.” Journal of Banking and Finance 22: 613-673.<br />

Brander J.A., Amit R. and Antweiler W. (2002) “Venture-capital firm syndication: Improved venture<br />

selection vs. the value-added hypothesis.” Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 11: 423-452.<br />

Cassar G. (2004) “The financing of business start-ups.” Journal of Business Venturing 19: 261-283.<br />

Davidsson P. and Wiklund J. (2006) “Conceptual and empirical challenges in the study of firm growth”<br />

In: P Davidsson, F Delmar, J Wiklund (ed.), Entrepreneurship and the <strong>Growth</strong> of Firms, 39-61, Edward<br />

Elgar Publishing.<br />

Hallen B. (2008) “The causes and consequences of the initial network positions of new organizations:<br />

<strong>From</strong> whom do entrepreneurs receive investments?” Administrative Science Quarterly 53: 685-718.<br />

Hsu D.H. (2004) “What do entrepreneurs pay for venture capital affiliation?” Journal of Finance 59: 1805-<br />

1844.<br />

199


Lerner J. (1999) “The government as venture capitalist: The long-run impact of the SBIR program.”<br />

Journal of Business 72: 285-318.<br />

Puri M. and Zarutskie R. (2008) “On the lifecycle dynamics of venture capital- and non-venture capital-<br />

financed firms” Working Paper, US Census Bureau Center for Economic Studies.<br />

Shyam-Sunder L. and Myers S.C. (1999) “Testing static tradeoff against pecking order models of capital<br />

structure.” Journal of Financial Economics 21: 219-244.<br />

Van de Ven A.H. (2007) “Engaged scholarship: A guide for organizational and social research.” Oxford:<br />

Oxford University Press.<br />

200

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!