09.08.2013 Views

POSTNUPTIAL AGREEMENTS - UW Law School

POSTNUPTIAL AGREEMENTS - UW Law School

POSTNUPTIAL AGREEMENTS - UW Law School

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

WILLIAMS - FINAL 11/29/2007 4:07 PM<br />

2007:827 Postnuptial Agreements 865<br />

worse job offer from another company. 189 This employee may threaten<br />

to leave his current job, but if the employer refuses to renegotiate, the<br />

employee will not carry out this threat.<br />

But suppose instead that the value of the husband’s outside option is<br />

equivalent to $150,000. This is his new reservation price. This might<br />

occur if the husband receives a promotion or suddenly loses a<br />

significant amount of weight such that his remarriage prospects are<br />

significantly enhanced. Now his divorce threat is credible. The split<br />

will no longer be equal; instead, the spouses will shift responsibilities<br />

within the marriage or shift postmarriage property rights to give the<br />

husband just barely more than $150,000 in utility. Notably, the model<br />

predicts that the husband will never be able to receive more than his<br />

reservation price. That is, he will not be able to appropriate the lion’s<br />

share of the marital assets. As soon as his wife reapportions enough<br />

rights or responsibilities to meet the husband’s new reservation price,<br />

any further threats to divorce are not credible and will not have an<br />

effect on the outcome.<br />

The model predicts that the wife’s low-value outside option will<br />

have only a tangential effect on the bargaining process. If the value of<br />

the husband’s outside option is low, then his divorce threat is not<br />

credible. If his divorce threat is not credible, then the wife will not alter<br />

their current distribution of utility. This is so regardless of how<br />

miserable the wife’s outside option may be. 190 The value of the wife’s<br />

outside option will determine her reservation price. Consider the<br />

illustration above where the couple was bargaining over how to split<br />

$200,000 and the husband’s outside option was $150,000. If the wife’s<br />

reservation price is also $150,000, then they will divorce because there<br />

are no distributions that make both parties better off remaining married.<br />

In short, they would both be happier outside of the marriage than under<br />

any plausible agreement within the marriage. But if the wife’s<br />

reservation price is less than $50,000, perhaps because her home state’s<br />

courts tend to shortchange women in divorce, then they will remain<br />

married because they can redistribute the surplus in such a way that<br />

both are better off staying married. Therefore, the wife’s low outside<br />

189. This example is adapted from Muthoo, Non-Technical Bargaining, supra<br />

note 11, at 155–56.<br />

190. Under current law and settlement practices, her outside option is indeed<br />

worth very little. At most, thirty percent of wives receive alimony and almost no<br />

divorce settlements that occur without an attorney include alimony. SCHNEIDER &<br />

BRINIG, supra note 23, at 329; Daniels et al., supra note 104, at 6 (collecting studies<br />

and noting that spousal support is only awarded in ten to fifteen percent of cases). In<br />

total, women tend to be much poorer after divorce than before. Id. (collecting studies<br />

and noting that ex-wives suffer a larger financial loss at divorce while ex-husbands<br />

realize a gain in their standard of living).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!