09.08.2013 Views

POSTNUPTIAL AGREEMENTS - UW Law School

POSTNUPTIAL AGREEMENTS - UW Law School

POSTNUPTIAL AGREEMENTS - UW Law School

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

WILLIAMS - FINAL 11/29/2007 4:07 PM<br />

876 WISCONSIN LAW REVIEW<br />

after the divorce. 242 They have relied primarily on the argument that the<br />

wife contributed to her husband’s earning capacity and therefore has an<br />

ownership interest in it. 243 The contribution theory of property does not,<br />

however, yield clear results. 244 Of all the experiences that enabled a<br />

husband to achieve a high earning capacity, few of them will depend on<br />

his marriage. For example, the most important elements of success,<br />

such as drive, dedication, emotional stability, and amicability are<br />

probably the product of his upbringing rather than his marriage. As<br />

such, his parents may have a greater claim to his earning capacity than<br />

his wife. Even if a spouse earns a graduate degree while married, it is<br />

not clear that the accompanying increase in earning capacity should be<br />

entirely attributed to the marriage. 245 For example, that spouse’s prior<br />

investments in education—such as his or her success in high school<br />

which enabled enrollment in a prestigious college—may have played a<br />

substantial role in the acceptance to and success within his or her<br />

graduate program. Based on similar reasoning, one scholar concluded<br />

that “the investment in human capital prior to marriage will be so large<br />

and essential relative to the investment after marriage that an<br />

individual’s human capital should be treated as separate property.” 246<br />

This Article does not attempt to resolve the debate surrounding<br />

alimony. The important point is that spousal bargaining occurs in the<br />

shadow of the entitlements that the law of alimony creates. Therefore,<br />

the enforceability of postnuptial agreements increases the ripple effects<br />

of whatever alimony scheme a state has adopted. If a state adopts a<br />

normatively plausible system of postdivorce income sharing, then the<br />

results of postnuptial bargaining should also be normatively<br />

242. See, e.g., Jana B. Singer, Divorce Reform and Gender Justice, 67 N.C.<br />

L. REV. 1103, 1117–18 (1989) (proposing a limited term alimony that would continue<br />

for one year for each two years of marriage); Starnes, supra note 237, at 1551 (urging<br />

an analogy of marriage law and the law of business partnerships and arguing that<br />

income sharing should continue until the tasks of the partnership are completed:<br />

namely, the youngest child reaches the age of majority); Williams, supra note 240, at<br />

2260 (advocating for alimony payments until the youngest child leaves the home and an<br />

arbitrary number of years has passed); Milton C. Regan, Spouses and Strangers:<br />

Divorce Obligations and Property Rhetoric, 82 GEO. L.J. 2303, 2389 (1994)<br />

(“[S]pouses’ lives have been intertwined in ways that the logic of this rhetoric cannot<br />

fully capture. The extent of this interdependence is roughly a function of how long<br />

individuals are married. As a result, we might require that ex-spouses share the same<br />

standard of living for some period of time corresponding to the length of their<br />

marriage.”).<br />

243. See supra notes 235–39.<br />

244. Allen Parkman, The Recognition of Human Capital as Property in<br />

Divorce Settlements, 40 ARK. L. REV. 439, 443–53 (1987).<br />

245. Id. at 447–48.<br />

246. Id. at 448.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!