11.11.2013 Views

Community-based Sectors for the New England Groundfish Fishery

Community-based Sectors for the New England Groundfish Fishery

Community-based Sectors for the New England Groundfish Fishery

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Community</strong>-<strong>based</strong> <strong>Sectors</strong> <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> <strong>Groundfish</strong> <strong>Fishery</strong><br />

Contract No. 4300-003-01<br />

FINAL REPORT SUBMITTED TO:<br />

National Marine Fisheries Service,<br />

Nor<strong>the</strong>ast Fisheries Science Center<br />

PREPARED BY:<br />

Daniel S. Holland, Ph.D.<br />

Gulf of Maine Research Institute<br />

350 Commercial Street, Portland, ME 04101<br />

207-228-1643, dholland@gmri.org<br />

DATE SUBMITTED:<br />

September 27, 2007


Acknowledgements<br />

Support <strong>for</strong> this Study was provided by <strong>the</strong> National Marine Fisheries Service, Office of<br />

Science and Technology and <strong>the</strong> Nor<strong>the</strong>ast Fisheries Science Center.<br />

The author is grateful <strong>for</strong> constructive comments provided by <strong>the</strong> staff of <strong>the</strong> Social<br />

Science Branch of <strong>the</strong> Nor<strong>the</strong>ast Fisheries Science Center. Any remaining errors or<br />

omissions in this report are <strong>the</strong> responsibility of <strong>the</strong> author alone. The opinions expressed<br />

in this report are those of <strong>the</strong> author and do not reflect opinions or positions of <strong>the</strong><br />

National Marine Fisheries Service.<br />

The author is also grateful <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> assistance of several fishermen, business owners,<br />

municipal officials, and bankers <strong>for</strong> providing in<strong>for</strong>mation that was essential to compiling<br />

this report.


Table of Contents<br />

Executive Summary............................................................................................................ 2<br />

1.0 Introduction................................................................................................................... 7<br />

2.0 Background on <strong>the</strong> <strong>Groundfish</strong> <strong>Fishery</strong> and <strong>Sectors</strong> .................................................... 7<br />

2.1 <strong>Sectors</strong> in <strong>the</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> <strong>Groundfish</strong> <strong>Fishery</strong>.................................................... 10<br />

2.2 Experience with Existing <strong>Sectors</strong> in <strong>the</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> <strong>Groundfish</strong> <strong>Fishery</strong> .......... 13<br />

3.0 Case Studies................................................................................................................ 14<br />

3.1 Port Clyde <strong>Community</strong>-<strong>based</strong> <strong>Groundfish</strong> Sector .................................................. 14<br />

3.1.1 Strawman Sector Structure and Operational Plan:........................................... 16<br />

3.1.2 Economic Feasibility ....................................................................................... 18<br />

3.1.3 Matching Catch to ACE................................................................................... 23<br />

3.2 Portland <strong>Community</strong>-<strong>based</strong> <strong>Groundfish</strong> <strong>Sectors</strong> .................................................... 25<br />

3.2.1 Strawman Sector Structure and Operational Plan:........................................... 27<br />

3.2.2 Economic Feasibility ....................................................................................... 30<br />

3.2.3 Matching Catch to ACE................................................................................... 38<br />

3.3 Permit Bank ............................................................................................................ 40<br />

3.3.1 Financing a Permit Bank.................................................................................. 41<br />

3.3.2 Economic Feasibility of a Permit Bank ........................................................... 43<br />

4.0 Operational and Regulatory Issues <strong>for</strong> <strong>Sectors</strong>........................................................... 46<br />

4.1 Sector Implementation............................................................................................ 46<br />

4.2 Rolling Baseline <strong>for</strong> Sector Allocations ................................................................. 46<br />

4.3 Balancing Catches with Allocations ....................................................................... 48<br />

4.4 Communities without Catch History ...................................................................... 49<br />

5.0 Conclusions................................................................................................................. 49<br />

5.1 Recommendations................................................................................................... 52<br />

References......................................................................................................................... 53<br />

Appendix A: Landings and revenue projections............................................................... 55<br />

Appendix B: <strong>Groundfish</strong> Price Model .............................................................................. 57<br />

Appendix C: Sector Proposals Submitted to <strong>the</strong> NEFMC in April and May of 2007...... 59<br />

1


Executive Summary<br />

The Nor<strong>the</strong>ast Multispecies <strong>Fishery</strong> Management Plan contains provisions that allow groups of<br />

permit holders to <strong>for</strong>m self-organized “sectors” that are allocated a share of <strong>the</strong> total allowable<br />

catch of <strong>the</strong> groundfish species <strong>the</strong>y target. Sector management offers a number of potential<br />

advantages to fishermen over <strong>the</strong> current management system which is <strong>based</strong> on a complex set of<br />

regulations that dictate when, where and how much fishermen can fish. <strong>Sectors</strong> offer fishermen<br />

<strong>the</strong> opportunity to: increase efficiency by increasing flexibility of when and where to fish;<br />

manage fishing operations to meet social as well economic objectives of <strong>the</strong> sector; concentrate<br />

on increasing quality and value of fish caught without concern <strong>for</strong> lost fishing time; make<br />

targeting and location decisions without concern <strong>for</strong> lost fishing time; avoid having to return to<br />

port or discard fish because a trip limit is reached <strong>for</strong> one species; and transfer (share, trade or<br />

consolidate) catch privileges among sector members to reduce fishing costs.<br />

Sector provisions offer fishing communities a means to address concerns that reduction and<br />

consolidation of groundfish operations threaten <strong>the</strong> viability of <strong>the</strong>ir current groundfish industry.<br />

A community-<strong>based</strong> sector could provide <strong>the</strong> means <strong>for</strong> a community and its fishermen to retain<br />

or regain access to <strong>the</strong> groundfish fishery and to ensure that <strong>the</strong> community benefits from this<br />

access.<br />

To date <strong>the</strong>re have only been two sectors approved by <strong>the</strong> NEFMC despite <strong>the</strong> potential<br />

advantages <strong>the</strong>y offer. Development of sectors has been constrained by a lack of understanding<br />

or <strong>the</strong> potential advantages of sectors, <strong>the</strong> difficulty and cost of <strong>for</strong>ming a sector, and <strong>the</strong> lack of<br />

technical and financial resources available to potential sector organizers. Despite <strong>the</strong>se<br />

constraints, a large number of sector proposals were submitted to <strong>the</strong> Council in May of 2007.<br />

These sectors have <strong>the</strong> potential to include vessels with catch history representing <strong>the</strong> majority of<br />

groundfish catch in <strong>the</strong> Multispecies fishery.<br />

This report presents a study of <strong>the</strong> feasibility of community-<strong>based</strong> groundfish sectors. The<br />

purpose is to determine <strong>the</strong> objectives of community-<strong>based</strong> sectors, how <strong>the</strong>y can be organized<br />

and implemented, how <strong>the</strong>y can be financed, and whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y are likely to be financially viable.<br />

The concept of a permit bank as a means to enhance <strong>the</strong> viability of a community-<strong>based</strong> sector is<br />

also evaluated. The analysis presented here is <strong>based</strong> largely on two case studies of prospective<br />

community-<strong>based</strong> groundfish sectors, one <strong>for</strong> a potentially larger community sector in Portland,<br />

Maine and ano<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong> a smaller sector <strong>based</strong> in Port Clyde, Maine. However, many of <strong>the</strong><br />

conclusions regarding <strong>the</strong> utility and feasibility of community-<strong>based</strong> groundfish sectors are<br />

applicable to <strong>the</strong> broader <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> region.<br />

The primary interest of <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde and Portland fishermen in developing a community-<strong>based</strong><br />

sector is to improve <strong>the</strong>ir profitability and economic viability. However, <strong>the</strong>y also expressed <strong>the</strong><br />

belief that sectors could improve safety. Some potential sector members envision using <strong>the</strong> sector<br />

to operationalize fishing practices that will minimize bycatch of juvenile or spawning fish<br />

through gear modifications, fleet communication, voluntary closures, or o<strong>the</strong>r management<br />

measures.<br />

2


<strong>Community</strong> leaders in Portland and Port Clyde are supportive of sectors as a means to ensure <strong>the</strong><br />

economic viability of <strong>the</strong>ir local fishermen and related businesses. However, while <strong>the</strong>y are<br />

willing to provide some organizational assistance and possibly assistance in acquiring financing,<br />

<strong>the</strong>y appear unwilling to spend taxpayer dollars to support a community-<strong>based</strong> sector. This could<br />

differ in o<strong>the</strong>r communities.<br />

Port Clyde Case Study<br />

The Port Clyde case study is <strong>based</strong> on a potential sector that includes 17 permits <strong>for</strong> mobile gear<br />

vessels between 36 and 56 feet in length. These 17 permits represent nearly all of <strong>the</strong> groundfish<br />

vessels fishing out of Port Clyde and <strong>the</strong> majority of active groundfish vessels in <strong>the</strong> Mid-coast<br />

region of Maine. A strawman operational structure was developed through consultation with <strong>the</strong><br />

Mid-coast Fishermen’s Association. Under this strawman, <strong>the</strong> sector would receive allocations of<br />

all regulated groundfish species its members regularly encounter. Because <strong>the</strong> rules <strong>for</strong> allocation<br />

to sectors were in flux at <strong>the</strong> time this research was being undertaken, <strong>the</strong> analysis of <strong>the</strong><br />

economic feasibility of <strong>the</strong> sector is done using allocations representing catch history <strong>for</strong> two<br />

periods: (1) from May 1, 2001 through April 30, 2006, and (2) from May 1, 1996 to April 30,<br />

2002. The Port Clyde sector would restrict its operations to <strong>the</strong> Gulf of Maine. It would be<br />

exempt from DAS limits, trip limits, and seasonal closures but its vessels would continue to be<br />

subject to <strong>the</strong> same restrictions on year-round closed areas and gear as o<strong>the</strong>r multispecies vessels.<br />

The Sector envisions assigning each permit-holder in <strong>the</strong> sector a specific percentage of <strong>the</strong><br />

overall allocation of each of <strong>the</strong> species-stocks <strong>for</strong> which <strong>the</strong> sector receives an allocation. Sector<br />

members would be free to utilize <strong>the</strong>se allocations on <strong>the</strong>ir vessels or transfer <strong>the</strong>m to o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

vessels within <strong>the</strong> sector upon notification and approval by <strong>the</strong> sector manager.<br />

The expected annual gain in gross revenues under sector management is estimated by subtracting<br />

<strong>the</strong> projected annual revenues without sectors management from projected revenues under sector<br />

management. The annual gain in net revenues <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector is calculated by subtracting from <strong>the</strong><br />

increase in annual gross revenue, <strong>the</strong> variable operating costs, <strong>the</strong> ongoing costs of sector<br />

management, and loan payments to repay sector establishment costs. The analysis suggests that<br />

sector management can provide substantial gains in net revenues to sector vessels and that <strong>the</strong>se<br />

gains far outweigh <strong>the</strong> costs of establishing and operating a sector. In <strong>the</strong> first year, <strong>the</strong> sector is<br />

projected to increase net revenues by $605 thousand with <strong>the</strong> FY01-05 allocation and by $505<br />

thousand with <strong>the</strong> FY96-01 allocation.<br />

The projected gains <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector are <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> ability of <strong>the</strong> sector to more effectively and<br />

efficiently utilize <strong>the</strong>ir share of <strong>the</strong> overall target TACs by targeting ef<strong>for</strong>t on stocks <strong>for</strong> which<br />

total industry catches have been well below TACs and by landing fish <strong>the</strong>y are now <strong>for</strong>ced to<br />

discard because of trim limits. The ability to do this would be a consequence of exemptions from<br />

DAS restrictions, rolling closures and trip limits. The sector may achieve additional gains beyond<br />

what is calculated here through consolidation of harvesting on <strong>the</strong> most efficient sector vessels<br />

and through higher prices if <strong>the</strong>y are able to improve quality or make direct marketing<br />

arrangements.<br />

Portland Case Study<br />

Analyses are done on two hypo<strong>the</strong>tical Portland sectors. Portland Sector A includes all groundfish<br />

vessels with more than 50% of <strong>the</strong>ir groundfish revenues in fishing year 2005 from landings in<br />

Portland, a total of 76 vessels. Portland Sector B is a subset of Portland Sector A and includes 50<br />

groundfish vessels with more than 90% of <strong>the</strong>ir groundfish revenues in fishing year 2005 coming<br />

from landings in Portland. A strawman operational structure <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sectors was developed and<br />

3


evaluated through discussion with a number of groundfish permit owners and vessel operators in<br />

Portland. Under this strawman, <strong>the</strong> sector would receive allocations of all regulated groundfish<br />

species it regularly encounters as well as monkfish. As was done <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde case study,<br />

<strong>the</strong> analysis of <strong>the</strong> economic feasibility of <strong>the</strong> sectors is done <strong>based</strong> on sector and overall<br />

commercial catches <strong>for</strong> two different allocation periods: (1) from May 1, 2001 through April 30,<br />

2006, and (2) from May 1, 1996 to April 30, 2002. The sector would not restrict <strong>the</strong> operations of<br />

member vessels geographically. It would be exempt from DAS limits, trip limits, and seasonal<br />

closures but would continue to be subject to <strong>the</strong> same restrictions on year-round closed areas and<br />

gear as o<strong>the</strong>r multispecies vessels. Each permit in <strong>the</strong> sector will receive a specific allocation of<br />

<strong>the</strong> overall allocation of each of <strong>the</strong> species-stocks <strong>for</strong> which <strong>the</strong> Sector receives an allocation.<br />

Sector members would be free to utilize <strong>the</strong>se allocations on <strong>the</strong>ir vessels or transfer <strong>the</strong>m to o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

vessels within <strong>the</strong> sector upon notification and approval by <strong>the</strong> sector manager.<br />

The analysis suggests that sector management can provide substantial gains in net revenues to<br />

sector vessels and that <strong>the</strong>se gains far outweigh <strong>the</strong> costs of establishing and operating a sector.<br />

Sector A is projected to increase net revenues by $4.6 million with <strong>the</strong> FY01-05 allocation and by<br />

$4.2 million with <strong>the</strong> FY96-01 allocation. This assumes sector A vessels pay a landing tax of 1%<br />

on groundfish and monkfish landings. The smaller Sector B is projected to increase net revenues<br />

by $2.8 million with <strong>the</strong> FY01-05 allocation and by $2.0 million with <strong>the</strong> FY96-01 allocation.<br />

Since <strong>the</strong> Portland sectors are much larger and have higher projected revenues than <strong>the</strong> Port<br />

Clyde sector <strong>the</strong> percentage of sector revenues required <strong>for</strong> covering operating costs of <strong>the</strong> sector<br />

is much lower. As with <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde sector, <strong>the</strong> projected gains <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector are <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong><br />

ability of <strong>the</strong> sector fishermen to more effectively and efficiently utilize <strong>the</strong>ir share of <strong>the</strong> overall<br />

target TACs by targeting ef<strong>for</strong>t on stocks <strong>for</strong> which total industry catches have been well below<br />

TACs and by landing fish <strong>the</strong>y are now <strong>for</strong>ced to discard because of trim limits. The sector might<br />

achieve additional gains beyond what is calculated here through higher prices or by reducing<br />

costs through consolidation.<br />

Permit Bank<br />

A means <strong>for</strong> communities interested in maintaining or regaining access to <strong>the</strong> groundfish fishery<br />

is to create a permit bank affiliated with a sector. The permit bank would purchase and hold<br />

permits and <strong>the</strong> associated catch history and <strong>the</strong>n include <strong>the</strong>se permits and catch history in <strong>the</strong><br />

community-<strong>based</strong> sector. The share of <strong>the</strong> sector’s annual catch entitlement (ACE) allocation<br />

contributed by <strong>the</strong> permit bank vessels would be leased to sector vessels at rates sufficient to pay<br />

back loans incurred <strong>for</strong> purchasing <strong>the</strong> permits. Once loans were paid back, <strong>the</strong> permit bank might<br />

continue to charge a fee <strong>for</strong> access to this ACE and use <strong>the</strong> revenues to acquire more permits or<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r investments in <strong>the</strong> interest of <strong>the</strong> fishing community and <strong>the</strong> sector members. The permit<br />

bank might also use <strong>the</strong>se revenues to purchase permits of sector members that wished to retire.<br />

The sector could create an apprentice program that would provide young fishermen access to <strong>the</strong><br />

fishery through access to <strong>the</strong> ACE controlled by <strong>the</strong> permit bank.<br />

There are a variety of ways that a permit bank might be financed. The most straight <strong>for</strong>ward way<br />

would be through a loan from a commercial bank. If Finance Authority of Maine (FAME) or<br />

some o<strong>the</strong>r government program could provide loan guarantees, it would enable <strong>the</strong> lenders to<br />

classify <strong>the</strong> assets in a preferred risk category. This would increase <strong>the</strong> likelihood of loan<br />

approval and would increase <strong>the</strong> percent of <strong>the</strong> value that could be financed. An alterative<br />

financing mechanism would be through a bond issue. The least costly bond option is a<br />

government obligation (GO) that puts <strong>the</strong> name of <strong>the</strong> city behind paying back <strong>the</strong> bond. The cost<br />

of capital <strong>for</strong> a GO is currently several points lower than a commercial loan. Direct loans from <strong>the</strong><br />

Federal government would be ano<strong>the</strong>r and potentially superior alternative <strong>for</strong> financing creation<br />

4


of community-<strong>based</strong> permit banks. This would require new legislation, but a program could be<br />

modeled on <strong>the</strong> current legislation <strong>for</strong> industry financed buybacks.<br />

To explore <strong>the</strong> economic feasibility of this concept, I constructed a strawman permit bank <strong>based</strong><br />

on vessels that were listed <strong>for</strong> sale during <strong>the</strong> summer of 2006. A total of 10 vessels were selected<br />

with a combined asking price of $3.8 million. The vessels range in size from 46 to 74 feet with<br />

prices ranging from $150 thousand to $575 thousand. The ratios of asking price to <strong>the</strong> average<br />

annual groundfish revenue <strong>for</strong> those vessels (FY2001 – FY2005) range from 0.85 to 2.49.<br />

ACE allocations <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> use of FY2001-FY2005 catch history of <strong>the</strong> permit bank vessels are<br />

calculated and revenues associated with utilization of those allocations are projected <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong><br />

same target TAC and prices projections used <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> economic feasibility analysis of <strong>the</strong> sectors.<br />

The ACE leasing fee as a percentage of revenues that would pay back a $3.8 million loan <strong>for</strong><br />

vessel acquisition is calculated to be 16.3% of ex-vessel price from <strong>the</strong> catch associated with <strong>the</strong><br />

leased ACE. Assuming variable operating costs equal to 38% of gross revenues (<strong>the</strong> same<br />

assumption used in <strong>the</strong> sector analyses), <strong>the</strong> permit bank yields close to $2 million annually in net<br />

revenues to sector vessels after payment of <strong>the</strong> lease fees necessary <strong>for</strong> loan repayment. The<br />

permit bank <strong>the</strong>n quickly builds a substantial asset base which it could use to purchase additional<br />

permits.<br />

Operational and Regulatory Issues <strong>for</strong> <strong>Community</strong>-<strong>based</strong> <strong>Sectors</strong><br />

Perhaps <strong>the</strong> most important constraint on sector development (community-<strong>based</strong> or o<strong>the</strong>rwise) is<br />

<strong>the</strong> difficulties and cost involved with <strong>for</strong>mation of a sector. There is a need <strong>for</strong> provision of<br />

extension services <strong>for</strong> prospective sectors (particularly <strong>for</strong> preparation of environmental<br />

assessments) and/or <strong>for</strong> a financial facility whereby sectors can apply <strong>for</strong> a loans or grants to<br />

defray <strong>the</strong> costs of sector development.<br />

Currently, approval of a new sector can only be done though a framework or an amendment. This<br />

creates considerable uncertainty as to whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> sector will ultimately be approved and when. A<br />

process could be set up allowing NMFS to authorized new sectors, but <strong>the</strong> Council would<br />

sacrifice some control over sector development in <strong>the</strong> fishery. Alternatively, <strong>the</strong> councils could<br />

initiate some region wide ruling allowing <strong>for</strong> sectors in every fishery with <strong>the</strong> final approval<br />

resting with <strong>the</strong> Councils and NMFS.<br />

Current regulations create a rolling period of catch history to be used <strong>for</strong> allocations. <strong>Sectors</strong> lock<br />

into a catch allocation as a percentage of <strong>the</strong> TAC <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> ratio of <strong>the</strong>ir catches during <strong>the</strong><br />

five years relative to total commercial catches. However, <strong>the</strong> years used <strong>for</strong> allocation to future<br />

sectors continue to change. Rolling baselines have <strong>the</strong> advantage of creating sector allocations<br />

that more closely match recent catch composition of <strong>the</strong> sector vessels but create a number of<br />

potential problems as well. Perhaps most problematic is <strong>the</strong> fact that permit holders within a<br />

sector that make <strong>the</strong>ir catch history available to o<strong>the</strong>r sector members will see <strong>the</strong>ir potential<br />

future allocations eroded. This presents a particular problem <strong>for</strong> sectors that might want to <strong>for</strong>m<br />

permit banks to make additional catch history available to its members since <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong>se<br />

permits would quickly erode. The Council recently passed motions recommending that sector<br />

regulations be changed to create fixed and consistent baselines <strong>for</strong> all sector allocations <strong>for</strong> a<br />

given fishery. This would eliminate much of <strong>the</strong> ambiguity and perverse incentives created by<br />

current rolling baseline allocations. It creates more security <strong>for</strong> individuals who make <strong>the</strong>ir ACE<br />

available to o<strong>the</strong>r members of <strong>the</strong> sector <strong>the</strong>reby facilitating consolidation within <strong>the</strong> sector and<br />

reduction of fixed costs. It also provides more security <strong>for</strong> permit banks that its permits will not<br />

be devalued over time if <strong>the</strong> ACE is made available to o<strong>the</strong>r vessels.<br />

5


Under current sector regulations, sectors can not buy, sell or trade ACE with o<strong>the</strong>r sectors. They<br />

must constrain <strong>the</strong>ir catch of all species <strong>for</strong> which <strong>the</strong>y have sector allocations to those annual<br />

allocations. If more sectors are authorized, substantial gains in profitability <strong>for</strong> sectors may be<br />

realized by allowing sectors to trade ACE.<br />

There are some communities, such as some in Downeast Maine, that had traditionally had some<br />

involvement in <strong>the</strong> groundfish fishery, but no longer have any fishermen with permits with “A”<br />

DAS and catch history. <strong>Sectors</strong> in conjunction with permit banks could provide an opportunity<br />

<strong>for</strong> permit owners and communities without “A” DAS and catch history to reenter <strong>the</strong> groundfish<br />

fishery. Individuals that hold groundfish permits with only “C” DAS could enter a sector without<br />

purchasing a new permit and could have access to that sector’s allocation. A sector could be<br />

created with a permit bank to acquire catch history <strong>for</strong> this purpose.<br />

In sum, although <strong>the</strong>re has not been an explicit program to facilitate development of community<strong>based</strong><br />

sectors, <strong>the</strong> opportunity exists to do so and a number of <strong>the</strong>m are likely to evolve in <strong>the</strong><br />

coming years. These community-<strong>based</strong> sectors can serve dual goals of improving <strong>the</strong> profitability<br />

and safety of groundfish fishermen and also allowing communities to retain or regain <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

involvement in <strong>the</strong> groundfish fishery. However, <strong>the</strong>re a number of barriers that are impeding<br />

development of community-<strong>based</strong> sectors and fuller utilization of sector management in general.<br />

Listed below are a number of recommendations that may facilitate more effective use of sectors<br />

by fishermen and communities. These include actions that could be taken by NMFS<br />

independently, regulatory re<strong>for</strong>ms that may be included by <strong>the</strong> Council in Amendment 16, and<br />

creation of new financing program that would require federal legislation:<br />

Recommendations<br />

1. To facilitate individual permit holders’ evaluation of <strong>the</strong>ir decision of whe<strong>the</strong>r to join a<br />

sector, NMFS should compile <strong>the</strong> catch histories by fish stock of all permitted groundfish<br />

vessels and in<strong>for</strong>m all current permit owners of <strong>the</strong> process of acquiring <strong>the</strong>ir catch history<br />

and <strong>the</strong> specific <strong>for</strong>ms and signatures required <strong>for</strong> release of <strong>the</strong>ir catch history to <strong>the</strong>m and to<br />

a sector organizer and or sector manager.<br />

2. The NEFMC should authorize a streamlined process <strong>for</strong> sector approval that does not require<br />

a Council framework action and reduces <strong>the</strong> burden of documentation and regulatory analysis<br />

that must be done by sector organizers.<br />

3. The NEFMC should allow sectors to trade some proportion of <strong>the</strong>ir ACE allocations with<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r sectors within <strong>the</strong> fishing year to facilitate catch balancing and greater utilization of<br />

ACE portfolios.<br />

4. The NEFMC should fix <strong>the</strong> allocation baseline <strong>for</strong> determining individual permit holders’<br />

contributions to sector allocations and decide how overall sector allocations are adjusted with<br />

movement of individuals in, out and between sectors. Future catch privileges associated with<br />

individual permits, whe<strong>the</strong>r in <strong>the</strong> context of sectors or o<strong>the</strong>r management systems, should be<br />

unaffected by how catch privileges are utilized within sectors.<br />

5. The NEFMC should explicitly authorize community-<strong>based</strong> sectors to <strong>for</strong>m permit banks that<br />

can hold permits and contribute catch history to <strong>the</strong> sector. This recommendation is not meant<br />

to imply that multiple permits from a single vessel could be split.<br />

6. Congress should create financial resources <strong>for</strong> development of community permit<br />

banks through a loan guarantee program or a direct loan program modeled on <strong>the</strong><br />

industry funded buyback structure.<br />

6


1.0 Introduction<br />

The groundfish fishery in <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> has been going through a sustained period of regulatory<br />

and economic change since <strong>the</strong> mid 1990s. These changes have led to substantial reorganization<br />

and consolidation of <strong>the</strong> industry that have and continue to change <strong>the</strong> character and geographic<br />

distribution of <strong>the</strong> industry. Concerns have been raised by fishermen and community leaders in<br />

some ports that landings will eventually be consolidated in a few large ports and that smaller<br />

ports and communities that have traditionally been involved in <strong>the</strong> fishery will no longer have a<br />

place in <strong>the</strong> fishery. Industry and community leaders in Maine are concerned that a trend in<br />

migration of fishing operations toward Massachusetts will leave Maine with few participants in<br />

<strong>the</strong> fishery and insufficient groundfish landings to support <strong>the</strong> Portland Fish Exchange.<br />

The Nor<strong>the</strong>ast Multispecies <strong>Fishery</strong> Management Plan (FMP) contains provisions that allow<br />

groups of permit holders to <strong>for</strong>m self organized harvest cooperatives called “sectors”. <strong>Sectors</strong> can<br />

be granted a share of <strong>the</strong> total allowable catch of regulated groundfish species <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> catch<br />

histories of <strong>the</strong> members of <strong>the</strong> sector. <strong>Sectors</strong> may receive exemptions from many of <strong>the</strong><br />

regulations currently used to limit catch in <strong>the</strong> fishery in return <strong>for</strong> a binding agreement to keep<br />

sector catches within specified limits. While <strong>the</strong>y were not designed specifically <strong>for</strong> this purpose,<br />

sector provisions offer fishing communities a means to address concerns that reduction and<br />

consolidation of groundfish operations threaten <strong>the</strong> viability of <strong>the</strong>ir current groundfish industry.<br />

A community-<strong>based</strong> sector could provide <strong>the</strong> means <strong>for</strong> a community and its fishermen to retain<br />

or regain access to <strong>the</strong> groundfish fishery and to ensure that <strong>the</strong> community benefits from this<br />

access.<br />

This report presents a feasibility study of community-<strong>based</strong> groundfish sectors. The purpose is to<br />

determine <strong>the</strong> objectives of community-<strong>based</strong> sectors, how <strong>the</strong>y can be organized and<br />

implemented, how <strong>the</strong>y can be financed, and whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y are likely to be financially viable. It<br />

identifies benefits, costs and constraints (organizational, financial and regulatory) to development<br />

of community-<strong>based</strong> sectors. The utility and feasibility of a permit bank that would enhance <strong>the</strong><br />

viability of a community-<strong>based</strong> sector is also analyzed. The analysis presented here is <strong>based</strong><br />

largely on two case studies of prospective community-<strong>based</strong> groundfish sectors, one <strong>for</strong> a<br />

potentially larger community sector in Southwestern Maine and ano<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong> a small community in<br />

Midcoast Maine. However, many of <strong>the</strong> conclusions regarding <strong>the</strong> utility and feasibility of<br />

community-<strong>based</strong> groundfish sectors are applicable to <strong>the</strong> entire <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> region.<br />

2.0 Background on <strong>the</strong> <strong>Groundfish</strong> <strong>Fishery</strong> and <strong>Sectors</strong><br />

Following <strong>the</strong> depletion of a number of key groundfish stocks in <strong>the</strong> late 1980s, <strong>the</strong> Conservation<br />

Law Foundation successfully sued <strong>the</strong> Department of Commerce and <strong>for</strong>ced implementation of a<br />

rebuilding plan that implemented a limited access management program <strong>based</strong> on individual<br />

vessel allocations of days at sea (DAS). The series of Amendments and frameworks to <strong>the</strong><br />

Nor<strong>the</strong>ast Multispecies (groundfish) <strong>Fishery</strong> Management Plan (FMP) contains FMP, toge<strong>the</strong>r<br />

with three vessel and permit buybacks, eventually led to reductions in landings and revenues and<br />

some consolidation of <strong>the</strong> limited access fleet. However, a sustained reduction in landings did not<br />

occur until after 2001.<br />

7


Amendment 7, implemented in 1996, accelerated <strong>the</strong> DAS ef<strong>for</strong>t reduction program first<br />

established in Amendment 5, but failed to bring about sufficient reductions in fishing mortality<br />

due to <strong>the</strong> large amount of latent ef<strong>for</strong>t that existed in <strong>the</strong> fishery. Vessel buybacks in 1996 and<br />

1997, using $25 million in government funds targeted at active groundfish vessels, purchased 79<br />

vessels and permits that had accounted <strong>for</strong> approximately 20% of <strong>the</strong> revenues in <strong>the</strong> fishery.<br />

Despite this, <strong>the</strong> SEIS <strong>for</strong> Amendment 13 notes that <strong>the</strong> number of active groundfish vessels<br />

remained relatively constant between 1996 and 2001 (NEFMC 2003) implying that previously<br />

inactive vessels must have been activated following <strong>the</strong> buybacks. In 2001, <strong>the</strong>re were nearly<br />

three times more multispecies permits than vessels that actually reported landings of groundfish<br />

(NEFMC 2003). Ano<strong>the</strong>r federally funded buyback with an appropriation of $10 million was<br />

carried out in 2001 but purchased only permits and was directed at latent ef<strong>for</strong>t. The program<br />

ended up purchasing 245 permits <strong>for</strong> $9.6 million in total. Of <strong>the</strong>se only a few were active<br />

vessels; <strong>the</strong> rest were inactive vessels reflecting <strong>the</strong> programs focus on latent ef<strong>for</strong>t.<br />

Despite <strong>the</strong>se reductions in active capacity and latent ef<strong>for</strong>t, increasingly strict limits on ef<strong>for</strong>t,<br />

and o<strong>the</strong>r measures such as year-round and seasonal closed areas and trip limits, overall<br />

groundfish landings generally trended upward between 1994 and 2001, and fishing mortality on<br />

some key groundfish stocks continued to exceed overfishing thresholds. Substantial latent ef<strong>for</strong>t<br />

still existed. Over 1300 limited access multispecies permits with individual or fleet days at sea<br />

(DAS) allocations remained in <strong>the</strong> fishery as of 2001, but only 861 of <strong>the</strong>m were active in <strong>the</strong><br />

groundfish fishery. Open access permits increased from 1381 to 2140 between 1996 and 2001<br />

though less than 800 of <strong>the</strong>se landed groundfish in 2001 (NEFMC 2003).<br />

In December 2001, <strong>the</strong> Conservation Law Foundation and o<strong>the</strong>r organizations successfully filed<br />

suit against NMFS alleging that <strong>the</strong> rebuilding plans that NMFS implemented were not consistent<br />

with Amendment 9 overfishing definitions (Conservation Law Foundation et al. v. Evans et al.).<br />

After a long series of negotiations among various parties, interim measures were adopted by <strong>the</strong><br />

court, and NMFS was instructed to submit a management plan to comply with <strong>the</strong> law. The<br />

response to this was Amendment 13, which was developed over a four-year period to meet <strong>the</strong><br />

MSA requirement to adopt rebuilding programs <strong>for</strong> stocks that are overfished and to end<br />

overfishing. Amendment 13 was approved by <strong>the</strong> National Marine Fisheries Service in March,<br />

2004 and became effective on May 1, 2004.<br />

Amendment 13 adopted a broad suite of management measures in order to achieve fishing<br />

mortality targets necessary to rebuild overfished stocks and meet o<strong>the</strong>r requirements of <strong>the</strong> M-S<br />

Act. The most important changes were to reduce DAS available to fishermen and to proscribe <strong>the</strong><br />

reactivation of latent permits. Ra<strong>the</strong>r than simply cutting <strong>the</strong> DAS of all permits, Amendment 13<br />

created three categories of DAS (“A”, “B” and “C” DAS). Only “A” DAS can be used to fish <strong>for</strong><br />

groundfish under <strong>the</strong> normal fishery rules. “B” DAS can only be used <strong>for</strong> certain special access<br />

programs designed to allow fishermen to access fish stocks <strong>for</strong> which catches were well below<br />

target TACs if bycatch of o<strong>the</strong>r stocks can be avoided. “C” DAS are unusable at this point. Active<br />

vessels saw 40% of <strong>the</strong>ir DAS turned into “B” DAS and <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r 60% were made “A” DAS. A<br />

large number of vessels with groundfish permits that had not been active in <strong>the</strong> fishery received<br />

no allocation of “A” or “B” DAS and were effectively removed from <strong>the</strong> fishery. Although <strong>the</strong><br />

possibility was left open that “C” DAS might in future be “activated” allowing <strong>the</strong>se boats to<br />

return to <strong>the</strong> fishery, <strong>the</strong> likelihood of this occurring appears remote. However, vessels with only<br />

“C” DAS can regain access to <strong>the</strong> fishery by buying or leasing “A” DAS or through membership<br />

in a sector 1 .<br />

1 A vessel with only “C” DAS would probably not bring any additional allocation to <strong>the</strong> sector, but, could<br />

participate in harvesting a sector’s allocation if <strong>the</strong>y were granted entry to <strong>the</strong> sector.<br />

8


Although Amendment 13 effectively eliminated a large number of permits holders from <strong>the</strong><br />

fishery by allocating <strong>the</strong>m only “C” DAS, it also reduced DAS allocations <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> remaining<br />

vessels to <strong>the</strong> point that <strong>the</strong> economic viability of many operations was threatened, particularly<br />

<strong>for</strong> vessels that did not also have <strong>the</strong> ability to participate in o<strong>the</strong>r fisheries. In recognition of this,<br />

Amendment 13 included programs including DAS leasing, sectors and special access programs<br />

that could allow fishermen to increase profitability without causing additional fishing pressure on<br />

stocks of concern. Both <strong>the</strong> leasing program and <strong>the</strong> sector program create <strong>the</strong> possibility of<br />

increasing profitability by consolidating fishing on fewer plat<strong>for</strong>ms.<br />

The leasing provisions of Amendment 13 allowed both leasing and permanent transfer of DAS<br />

between vessels. The program was authorized initially <strong>for</strong> two years but was extended by<br />

Framework 42. To avoid transfers that would increase effective fishing power, transfer or leases<br />

can only be made between boats of <strong>the</strong> same size or from larger boats to smaller boats. Permanent<br />

transfers of DAS also incur a 20% conservation tax (e.g. 50 DAS on <strong>the</strong> initial boat becomes 40<br />

DAS on <strong>the</strong> boat it is transferred to). Because of this requirement, few permanent transfers have<br />

been made 2 . However, <strong>the</strong> conservation tax has not prevented consolidation as many permit<br />

holders have simply purchased additional permits and leased <strong>the</strong> DAS from those vessels to o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

vessels <strong>the</strong>y own. In some cases <strong>the</strong> permits have been transferred onto skiffs. This allows <strong>the</strong><br />

permit owner to avoid <strong>the</strong> unnecessary costs of maintaining <strong>the</strong> inactive vessels, while <strong>the</strong>y<br />

maintain <strong>the</strong> rights of <strong>the</strong> owner to lease DAS to vessels up to <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> original vessel or to<br />

transfer <strong>the</strong> permit back onto a vessel of that size at a later date. Nearly 15 percent of <strong>the</strong> baseline<br />

allocations were transferred through <strong>the</strong> leasing program in <strong>the</strong> first year and indications were that<br />

<strong>the</strong> percentage increased in <strong>the</strong> second year of <strong>the</strong> program. The leasing program resulted in<br />

significant consolidation of DAS as <strong>the</strong> primary users of <strong>the</strong> program were those vessels that<br />

received <strong>the</strong> highest baseline DAS allocations (NEFMC 2006).<br />

Amendment 13 also contained provisions that allowed groups of fishermen to voluntarily <strong>for</strong>m<br />

“sectors” and create limited self management systems. A sector could apply <strong>for</strong> an allocation of<br />

catch of one or several regulated groundfish species. The allocation would be <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> catch<br />

history of <strong>the</strong> group of vessels relative to <strong>the</strong> total catch <strong>for</strong> that species. The group would <strong>the</strong>n<br />

receive an annual allocation equal to <strong>the</strong> target TAC 3 <strong>for</strong> that species multiplied by <strong>the</strong> ratio of <strong>the</strong><br />

group’s catch to <strong>the</strong> total commercial catch. If a sector requested an allocation <strong>for</strong> all regulated<br />

stocks, and put in place an operations plan that would limit <strong>the</strong>ir catches to <strong>the</strong>ir allocation, <strong>the</strong>y<br />

could, in <strong>the</strong>ory, avoid some of <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r current regulations including DAS limits, trip limits and<br />

seasonal area closures. <strong>Sectors</strong> provide ano<strong>the</strong>r potential means of consolidation since sector<br />

members can, if <strong>the</strong>y choose, fish <strong>the</strong>ir allocation of catch with a subset of <strong>the</strong> vessels/permits that<br />

make up <strong>the</strong> sector.<br />

Since 2001, landings and revenues of groundfish have declined fairly steadily in <strong>the</strong> <strong>New</strong><br />

<strong>England</strong> region as a whole. The decline has occurred throughout <strong>the</strong> region, but has been more<br />

severe in some areas than o<strong>the</strong>rs. Revenues from regulated groundfish in Maine and<br />

Massachusetts, which toge<strong>the</strong>r account <strong>for</strong> over 90% of groundfish revenues, were 29% lower in<br />

2 The author has been told by several individuals that <strong>the</strong>re have recently been a number of purchase and<br />

transfers of vessels with only “C” DAS. These permits do not provide <strong>the</strong> vessel with any additional fishing<br />

opportunity, but <strong>the</strong> increase <strong>the</strong> vessel’s baseline number of DAS which allows <strong>the</strong>m to lease a greater<br />

number of DAS.<br />

3 In cases where a share of <strong>the</strong> TAC is utilized by <strong>the</strong> recreational sector or as bycatch in o<strong>the</strong>r fisheries,<br />

presumably <strong>the</strong> sector’s share would be a percentage of <strong>the</strong> commercial TAC once those o<strong>the</strong>r user groups<br />

were accounted <strong>for</strong>. The regulations are not explicit about this and <strong>the</strong> issue has not yet been dealt with.<br />

9


oth states in 2004 relative to 2001. However, <strong>the</strong> reductions were quite uneven within <strong>the</strong> states.<br />

In Massachusetts, groundfish revenues fell by 45% between 2001 and 2004 <strong>for</strong> Cape and Islands<br />

ports, by 33% <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>New</strong> Bed<strong>for</strong>d coast, but by only 20% <strong>for</strong> Gloucester and only 11% <strong>for</strong><br />

Boston (NEFMC 2006).<br />

During this period, Maine saw a shift of activity toward <strong>the</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn part of <strong>the</strong> state. <strong>Groundfish</strong><br />

revenues <strong>for</strong> ports in upper Midcoast Maine dropped by 64% in this period. <strong>Groundfish</strong> revenues<br />

in lower Midcoast Maine were 28% lower in 2004 than 2001 while revenues in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Maine<br />

were 83% higher. <strong>Groundfish</strong> landings in Downeast Maine have been essentially nonexistent<br />

since 1997. Although overall groundfish revenues in Maine dropped by about <strong>the</strong> same amount as<br />

<strong>for</strong> Massachusetts between 2001 and 2004, concerns have been raised that permit holders are<br />

beginning to move <strong>the</strong>ir base of operations and landings away from Maine to Massachusetts ports<br />

because of proximity to <strong>the</strong> fishing grounds and because boats landing or registered in Maine are<br />

prohibited from landing lobsters which can provide a significant boost to revenues. Revenues<br />

from regulated groundfish landings in Maine did decline by about 2% in <strong>the</strong> 2005 fishing years<br />

relative to 2004 and increased by <strong>the</strong> same percentage in Massachusetts. Representatives of <strong>the</strong><br />

Portland Fish Exchange, which handles <strong>the</strong> great majority of groundfish landings in Maine, have<br />

stated that <strong>the</strong> drop in landing of groundfish in Portland has made <strong>the</strong> exchange unprofitable and<br />

could lead to <strong>the</strong> close of <strong>the</strong> auction which would likely result in additional movement of vessels<br />

to o<strong>the</strong>r ports (Valleau 2007).<br />

2.1 <strong>Sectors</strong> in <strong>the</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> <strong>Groundfish</strong> <strong>Fishery</strong><br />

The concept of self selecting sectors as a management tool <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> groundfish<br />

fishery was first raised by Frank Marachi during <strong>the</strong> initial development of Amendment 13<br />

(Thunberg 2007). The groundfish PDT was tasked with exploring <strong>the</strong> concept fur<strong>the</strong>r. These self<br />

selecting sectors would allow groundfish permit holders to voluntarily join toge<strong>the</strong>r to <strong>for</strong>m a<br />

“sector” that would receive an allocation of <strong>the</strong> species <strong>the</strong>y caught. They would be allowed to<br />

opt out of <strong>the</strong> input control system used to manage <strong>the</strong> fishery in return <strong>for</strong> keeping <strong>the</strong>ir catches<br />

within <strong>the</strong>ir allocation. Permit holders that did not wish to join a sector could continue to fish<br />

under a common set of regulations (i.e., <strong>the</strong> input control system as adapted by Amendment 13).<br />

The concept of sectors that emerged from Amendment 13 remained basically consistent with<br />

what was proposed by <strong>the</strong> PDT. A process was designed to allow groups of permit holders to<br />

<strong>for</strong>m sectors and seek allocations of groundfish in return <strong>for</strong> developing a binding operations plan<br />

that would ensure <strong>the</strong> sector’s catch remained below its allocation. The allocation of catch to <strong>the</strong><br />

sector would be <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> documented accumulated landings of sector members <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> 5-year<br />

period prior to submission of a sector allocation proposal to <strong>the</strong> Council. An exception to that<br />

allocation <strong>for</strong>mula was created <strong>for</strong> Georges Bank (GB) <strong>for</strong> which <strong>the</strong> allocation was <strong>based</strong> on<br />

fishing years 1996 through 2001 <strong>for</strong> any sectors that began operation by 2007. The sector<br />

regulations specified that no sector could be allocated more than 20 percent of a stock’s TAC<br />

unless o<strong>the</strong>rwise authorized by <strong>the</strong> Council.<br />

The regulations spell out clearly <strong>the</strong> method <strong>for</strong> calculating <strong>the</strong> allocation of cod to <strong>the</strong> Georges<br />

Bank Cod Hook Sector which was also implemented with Amendment 13. It states that <strong>the</strong><br />

accumulated landings of GB cod by <strong>the</strong> sector participants from 1996–2001 will <strong>the</strong>n be divided<br />

by <strong>the</strong> accumulated landings of GB cod by all vessels <strong>for</strong> 1996–2001. This ratio is <strong>the</strong> percentage<br />

of <strong>the</strong> GB cod TAC <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> next fishing year that will be allocated to <strong>the</strong> sector. The sector would<br />

<strong>the</strong>n receive that fixed percentage of <strong>the</strong> GB cod TAC in future years as well. The regulations are<br />

10


somewhat vague on how <strong>the</strong> allocations <strong>for</strong> future sectors would be calculated, at least <strong>for</strong><br />

allocations of stocks o<strong>the</strong>r than GB cod. The common presumption was that that allocations will<br />

be a percentage of <strong>the</strong> TAC calculated by dividing <strong>the</strong> sector vessels’ accumulated landings over<br />

<strong>the</strong> five years fishing years prior to submitting <strong>the</strong>ir proposal by <strong>the</strong> total documented<br />

(presumably commercial) landings <strong>for</strong> that stock over <strong>the</strong> same period. This would mean that, <strong>for</strong><br />

a sector submitting its proposal in May of 2007 with plans to begin operation in May of 2008, its<br />

allocation would be <strong>based</strong> on catches in <strong>the</strong> fishing years beginning in 2002-2006. This<br />

allocation <strong>for</strong>mula is likely to change anyway as a result of amendment 16.<br />

The regulations that implemented sectors require sectors to submit a proposal accompanied by an<br />

environmental assessment that satisfies National Environmental Policy Act (NEPA) and o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

requirements <strong>for</strong> regulatory analysis of fishery management actions. The initial allocation of<br />

catch or DAS to <strong>the</strong> sector would require authorization by <strong>the</strong> Council through a framework or<br />

amendment. After <strong>the</strong> initial authorization, <strong>the</strong> sector would be required to submit an operations<br />

plan and a binding contract to <strong>the</strong> NMFS Regional Administrator (RA) along with an updated EA<br />

that evaluates <strong>the</strong> operations plan. The RA <strong>the</strong>n reviews <strong>the</strong> operations plan and seeks public<br />

comment on it be<strong>for</strong>e giving <strong>the</strong> final approval (through a federal rule making) required <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

sector to operate. Submission to and approval by <strong>the</strong> RA of an operations plan and contract with<br />

an updated EA is required each year <strong>the</strong> sector continues to operate, but fur<strong>the</strong>r Council actions<br />

are not required <strong>for</strong> annual authorization of <strong>the</strong> sector unless <strong>the</strong>re are substantial changes to <strong>the</strong><br />

operations plan or membership.<br />

Sector management offers a number of potential advantages over <strong>the</strong> current management system.<br />

By accepting hard limits on total allowable catch (TAC) on all species, <strong>the</strong> regulations suggest<br />

that <strong>the</strong> sector members may be able to exempt <strong>the</strong>mselves from trip limits and a number of<br />

existing management controls including trip limits, seasonal closures and overall limits on days at<br />

sea (DAS). This offers sector members an opportunity to:<br />

• increase efficiency by increasing flexibility of when and where <strong>the</strong>y fish;<br />

• manage fishing operations to meet social as well economic objectives of <strong>the</strong> sector;<br />

• concentrate on increasing quality and value of fish caught without concern <strong>for</strong> lost fishing<br />

time;<br />

• make targeting and location decisions without concern <strong>for</strong> lost fishing time;<br />

• avoid having to return to port or discard fish because a trip limit is reached <strong>for</strong> one species<br />

(this “regulatory discarding” is currently a legal practice but leads to <strong>the</strong> discarding and<br />

mortality of large amounts of marketable fish);<br />

• transfer and potentially consolidate catch privileges between sector members to reduce capital<br />

costs.<br />

The potential benefits of sectors go beyond allowing more effective and efficient use of catch<br />

allocations. They empower fishery stakeholder to develop innovative ways to better manage <strong>the</strong><br />

resources <strong>the</strong>y have access to, and <strong>the</strong>y can create strong incentives <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>se stakeholder to<br />

conserve fishery resources since <strong>the</strong>ir catch allocations in future years are directly related to <strong>the</strong><br />

size and productivity of <strong>the</strong> fish stocks. <strong>Sectors</strong> may also offer an opportunity <strong>for</strong> communities<br />

that have historically participated in <strong>the</strong> groundfish fishery to maintain <strong>the</strong> viability of <strong>the</strong>ir local<br />

fishing fleets, preserve or regain access to <strong>the</strong> fishery, and become actively involved in managing<br />

local fishery resources through creation of community owned permit banks. By purchasing<br />

permits and associated catch history, a community entity could own a share of a sector’s catch<br />

allocation and make it available to sector members as an incentive to retain vessels in <strong>the</strong><br />

community. Such a permit bank might also provide a means <strong>for</strong> communities to provide ongoing<br />

11


access to new fishery entrants, perhaps through an apprenticeship program. <strong>Sectors</strong> may also<br />

offer a vehicle <strong>for</strong> environmental NGOs to negotiate mutually beneficial agreements <strong>for</strong> use of<br />

environmentally friendly fishing practices using market incentives as an alternative to court<br />

actions and regulatory initiatives that are slow, costly and often ineffective.<br />

The industry has been slow to take up sectors despite <strong>the</strong> potential advantages <strong>the</strong>y offer. To date<br />

<strong>the</strong>re have only been two sectors approved. No mobile gear (i.e. trawler) sectors have been<br />

approved, and no sector has requested an allocation of all regulated groundfish species it catches<br />

or been granted exemption from primary input controls (i.e., DAS limitations). The GB Hook<br />

Sector has received some regulatory relief in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>m of exemption from trip limits, <strong>the</strong> May<br />

closures and differential DAS counting.<br />

A primary constraint on <strong>the</strong> adoption of sector management is <strong>the</strong> difficulty involved in <strong>for</strong>mation<br />

of a sector. Prospective sectors must devise an operations plan complete with a legal contract and<br />

system <strong>for</strong> monitoring catch of its members. They must also complete an environmental<br />

assessment. They must submit <strong>the</strong>se at least a year be<strong>for</strong>e <strong>the</strong> sector can be implemented. The<br />

sector can only be implemented through a framework or amendment of <strong>the</strong> Council. The sector<br />

must also bear <strong>the</strong> costs of monitoring catches of its members and ensuring <strong>the</strong>ir compliance with<br />

<strong>the</strong> sector operations plan. There are no publicly provided resources (monetary or advisory)<br />

available to prospective sectors, but <strong>the</strong> expertise and resources necessary to accomplish <strong>the</strong>se<br />

tasks are substantial <strong>for</strong> an industry that is already in severe financial difficulty. To make<br />

development of sectors more feasible, it would be helpful if extension services could be provided<br />

to prospective sectors (particularly <strong>for</strong> preparation of environmental assessments).<br />

Despite <strong>the</strong>se constraints, a large number of sector proposals were submitted to <strong>the</strong> Council in<br />

May of 2007. The two Cape Cod sectors submitted proposals that would substantially change<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir nature – by requesting allocations of all groundfish species as well as monkfish, dogfish and<br />

skates and requesting exemptions from ef<strong>for</strong>t controls and seasonal closures. A small group of<br />

permit holders of mobile gear vessels <strong>based</strong> in Port Clyde, Maine submitted a proposal also<br />

requesting allocations of all groundfish stocks, monkfish and skates and exemptions from ef<strong>for</strong>t<br />

controls. A potentially larger sector that would include primarily mobile gear vessels from Maine,<br />

Massachusetts and Rhode Island submitted a proposal requesting only allocations of species of<br />

concern and exemptions from trip limits, differential DAS counting and seasonal closures. 4 The<br />

Nor<strong>the</strong>ast Seafood Coalition organized submission of ano<strong>the</strong>r 12 sector proposals <strong>for</strong> prospective<br />

fixed gear and mobile gear sectors <strong>based</strong> out of Gloucester and <strong>New</strong> Bed<strong>for</strong>d, Massachusetts,<br />

<strong>New</strong> Hampshire and Point Judith, Rhode Island. A final proposal was submitted by a small group<br />

of permit holders <strong>based</strong> out of Boston. A more detailed summary of <strong>the</strong> proposal is provided in<br />

appendix C. This set of sectors has <strong>the</strong> potential to include vessels with catch history representing<br />

<strong>the</strong> majority of groundfish catch in <strong>the</strong> Multispecies fishery. However, since sector proposals do<br />

not designate member vessels and do not bind prospective members to participation at <strong>the</strong><br />

proposal stage, it is not possible to say at this point what percentage of <strong>the</strong> industry <strong>the</strong>se groups<br />

account <strong>for</strong>.<br />

4 The proposal and EA also includes an option <strong>for</strong> all groundfish, monkfish and skates and exemption from<br />

ef<strong>for</strong>t controls, but this was not chosen as <strong>the</strong> preferred option because <strong>the</strong> sector organizers were in<strong>for</strong>med<br />

that it was highly unlikely <strong>the</strong>y could be granted an allocation of monkfish of skates and thus would have to<br />

remain under DAS controls <strong>for</strong> monkfish on trips with more than incidental catch of monkfish.<br />

12


2.2 Experience with Existing <strong>Sectors</strong> in <strong>the</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong><br />

<strong>Groundfish</strong> <strong>Fishery</strong><br />

The first sector in <strong>the</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> groundfish fishery, The Georges Bank Cod Hook Sector, was<br />

developed along with Amendment 13 and was authorized by Amendment 13. It received an<br />

allocation only of GB cod. Because <strong>the</strong> sector did not seek allocations of all groundfish stocks<br />

<strong>the</strong>y can catch (e.g. haddock), <strong>the</strong>y were unable to completely opt out of <strong>the</strong> ef<strong>for</strong>t control system.<br />

The lack of an ef<strong>for</strong>t constraint would have allowed <strong>the</strong>m an unfair advantage to pursue o<strong>the</strong>r fish<br />

stocks. Consequently GB Hook sector members have been required to use DAS when fishing.<br />

Leasing amongst sector members was allowed and is not constrained by vessel size, but sector<br />

vessels can not lease DAS from non-sector vessels. A primary benefit <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector members is<br />

exemption from <strong>the</strong> trip or possession limits on cod and exemption from <strong>the</strong> May seasonal<br />

closure on Georges Bank. The sector is also assured by regulation that <strong>the</strong>ir allocation will not be<br />

reduced as a result of non sector vessels catch exceeding <strong>the</strong> non-sector proportion of <strong>the</strong> TAC<br />

(though if that led to a reduction in <strong>the</strong> overall TAC <strong>the</strong> sector would take a proportionate cut in<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir allocation). The GB hook sector was reauthorized in 2005, 2006 and 2007 and has continued<br />

to operate in a similar fashion as when it was first created though <strong>the</strong> number of members has<br />

dropped by half.<br />

<strong>Sectors</strong> are free to design <strong>the</strong>ir own system <strong>for</strong> allocating/rationing catch amongst <strong>the</strong>ir members<br />

as long as NMFS is satisfied that this approach will constrain <strong>the</strong> overall sector catch within <strong>the</strong><br />

sector allocation. The approach taken by <strong>the</strong> GB Hook sector was to divide its allocation up into<br />

monthly quotas that would be fished competitively by sector members. If a monthly quota is<br />

caught be<strong>for</strong>e <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> month, all sector vessels are required to stop fishing. If <strong>the</strong> monthly<br />

quota is not taken it is rolled into <strong>the</strong> next monthly quota. In practice catch has never reached <strong>the</strong><br />

monthly quota, and <strong>the</strong> annual catch of <strong>the</strong> Sector remained well below <strong>the</strong> sector allocation in<br />

<strong>the</strong> first two years of operation. In <strong>the</strong> 2004-05 fishing year <strong>the</strong> GB Hook sector was allocated<br />

371 metric tons of cod (12.58% of <strong>the</strong> overall Georges Bank cod TAC), but only caught a total of<br />

130 metric tons. In 2005, 49 vessels in <strong>the</strong> GB Cod Hook Sector (Sector) were allocated 455<br />

metric tons. of GB cod and harvested 125 tons, only approximately 27% of <strong>the</strong> sector allocation.<br />

The fact that <strong>the</strong> Hook sector’s catch was well under it’s allocation was largely due to low catch<br />

rates <strong>for</strong> cod and continued restrictions of DAS, but a delay in authorization that resulted in a late<br />

start of fishing both years also contributed. The sectors participation in a haddock special access<br />

program (SAP) in closed area 1 may also contributed to <strong>the</strong>ir failure to catch <strong>the</strong>ir cod allocation.<br />

A second Georges Bank cod sector <strong>for</strong> fixed gear was authorized under Framework 42 in 2006.<br />

This sector included vessels using sink gillnet gear. Despite <strong>the</strong> fact that prospective members of<br />

this sector had and would continue to catch species o<strong>the</strong>r than cod, <strong>the</strong> sector sought only an<br />

allocation of Georges Bank cod. Like <strong>the</strong> hook sector its members were required to continue to<br />

fish under <strong>the</strong> DAS system. No vessels actually participated in <strong>the</strong> GB fixed gear sector <strong>the</strong> 2006-<br />

07 fishing year because of concern that <strong>the</strong>y would not be able to fish at <strong>the</strong> beginning of <strong>the</strong><br />

fishing year. However, <strong>the</strong> sector was reauthorized and began operation in <strong>the</strong> 2007-08 fishing<br />

year. As of March 7, 2007, 19 prospective Fixed Gear Sector members had signed <strong>the</strong> 2007<br />

Sector Contract (Federal Register Vol. 72, No. 72 / Monday, April 16, 2007 pg. 18940).<br />

The regulations authorizing <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mation of sectors in <strong>the</strong> Nor<strong>the</strong>ast Multispecies groundfish<br />

fishery do not specify that sectors be “community-<strong>based</strong>.” They do not specify that sector<br />

members must be part of a particular geographically defined community nor do <strong>the</strong>y require <strong>the</strong><br />

sector to limit fishing operations to a particular area (though <strong>the</strong> sector would have to have catch<br />

history <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> groundfish stocks in areas <strong>the</strong>y fish in order to receive an allocation of those<br />

13


stocks). In practice <strong>the</strong> only two sectors that have been authorized to date could be characterized<br />

as community-<strong>based</strong> sectors. The members of both sectors fish out of Cape Cod (though this is<br />

not an official restriction of membership) and both sectors voluntarily delineated a fishing area.<br />

To date, both sectors are comprised of individual permit owners whose catch histories each<br />

contribute to <strong>the</strong> overall sector allocation. However <strong>the</strong> Cape Cod Commercial Hook Fishermen’s<br />

Association has begun to explore <strong>the</strong> concept of developing a permit bank owned by <strong>the</strong><br />

Association that would hold permits and associated catch histories that could contribute to <strong>the</strong><br />

sector allocation. The permit bank would enable <strong>the</strong> sector to purchase permits that might<br />

o<strong>the</strong>rwise be sold and migrate to o<strong>the</strong>r regions, and it could allow <strong>the</strong> sector to increase its share<br />

of <strong>the</strong> fishery over time and provide a means <strong>for</strong> new entrants from <strong>the</strong> community to participate<br />

in <strong>the</strong> fishery. To that end, both <strong>the</strong> GB Hook sector and <strong>the</strong> GB Fixed gear sector have included<br />

right-of-first-refusal clauses in <strong>the</strong>ir sector contracts that provide <strong>the</strong> sector entity with <strong>the</strong> option<br />

to purchase <strong>the</strong> permits of any members that are intending to sell <strong>the</strong>ir permits at a price equal to<br />

what <strong>the</strong> individual has been offered by a private buyer.<br />

3.0 Case Studies<br />

The primary objective of this project is to conduct two case studies of potential community-<strong>based</strong><br />

sectors in Maine, one in <strong>the</strong> Midcoast region and one in <strong>the</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn region. Port Clyde is <strong>the</strong><br />

only port with a significant number of active groundfish boats in <strong>the</strong> Midcoast region. These<br />

fishermen have also <strong>for</strong>med an association, <strong>the</strong> Midcoast Fishermen’s Association. For <strong>the</strong>se<br />

reasons, Port Clyde was chosen <strong>for</strong> one of <strong>the</strong> case studies. Portland is, by far <strong>the</strong> largest<br />

groundfish port in Maine in terms of landings and vessels landing <strong>the</strong>re. For that reason Portland<br />

was chosen <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> second case study. Although <strong>the</strong>re is a group working with <strong>the</strong> Portland Fish<br />

Exchange that is developing a sector, <strong>the</strong> sector includes vessels from three states landing in<br />

several ports and does not fit <strong>the</strong> conceptual idea of a community-<strong>based</strong> sector being explored <strong>for</strong><br />

this study (i.e., one tied to a geographically defined community). For that reason, a case study<br />

was conducted on a hypo<strong>the</strong>tical sector including vessels that landed <strong>the</strong> majority of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

groundfish in Portland in <strong>the</strong> 2005/06 fishing year.<br />

The case studies include: discussion of <strong>the</strong> objectives of <strong>the</strong> fishermen and <strong>the</strong> community <strong>for</strong><br />

setting up a community-<strong>based</strong> sector; a description of <strong>the</strong> potential sector including its structure,<br />

potential participants and basic operational plan; and an analysis of <strong>the</strong> economic feasibility of<br />

setting up and operating <strong>the</strong> sector. The port specific case studies are followed by an economic<br />

feasibility analysis of a permit bank that could be developed in conjunction with a community<strong>based</strong><br />

sector. Operational and regulatory issues <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sectors that may present difficulties are<br />

<strong>the</strong>n discussed.<br />

3.1 Port Clyde <strong>Community</strong>-<strong>based</strong> <strong>Groundfish</strong> Sector<br />

The case study of <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde community-<strong>based</strong> sector was facilitated by <strong>the</strong> existence of <strong>the</strong><br />

Midcoast Fisherman’s Association which was established in 2006 by a group of area fishermen<br />

that came toge<strong>the</strong>r to discuss and deliberate <strong>the</strong> future of <strong>the</strong>ir industry. They decided to <strong>for</strong>m an<br />

organization that would be “an active voice <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir interest in preserving a healthy ocean,<br />

balanced with a need to maintain <strong>the</strong> viability of local coastal fishing communities.” I presented<br />

<strong>the</strong> concept of a community-<strong>based</strong> sector to <strong>the</strong> association in June 2006. The members were<br />

uncertain whe<strong>the</strong>r this <strong>for</strong>m of management would suit <strong>the</strong>m but voted unanimously to work with<br />

14


me to explore <strong>the</strong> idea fur<strong>the</strong>r and to participate in a case study. This eventually culminated in <strong>the</strong><br />

group submitting a proposal to <strong>for</strong>m a sector, though <strong>the</strong> group of permit holders that is currently<br />

considering joining <strong>the</strong> sector if it is authorized is not identical to <strong>the</strong> original set of vessels<br />

included in <strong>the</strong> following case study.<br />

The primary interest of <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde fishermen in developing a community-<strong>based</strong> sector is to<br />

improve <strong>the</strong>ir profitability and economic viability. However, <strong>the</strong>y also expressed <strong>the</strong> belief that<br />

sectors could improve safety since vessels would be more likely to return to port if bad wea<strong>the</strong>r<br />

was predicted. The current restrictions on DAS create incentives <strong>for</strong> vessels to stay at sea ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

than using up <strong>the</strong>ir limited fishing time steaming back to port be<strong>for</strong>e completing a full trip. The<br />

sector members also see <strong>the</strong> sector as a way to improve sustainability since <strong>the</strong>y would no longer<br />

have to discard fish when trip limits were reached. They also envision using <strong>the</strong> sector to<br />

operationalize fishing practices that will minimize bycatch of juvenile or spawning fish through<br />

gear modifications, fleet communication, voluntary closures, or o<strong>the</strong>r management measures.<br />

To develop an understanding of whe<strong>the</strong>r and why <strong>the</strong> surrounding community would be<br />

supportive of a community base groundfish sector, Cindy Smith (sector project manager <strong>for</strong><br />

GMRI) interviewed John Falla, who is <strong>the</strong> town manager <strong>for</strong> St. George, Maine and Dave<br />

Schmanska, <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde harbor master. They stated that <strong>the</strong> town is interested in maintaining<br />

<strong>the</strong> groundfish fleet in Port Clyde. The town recognizes <strong>the</strong> importance of fishing to its year<br />

round residents – <strong>the</strong> primary fisheries in St. George are lobster and groundfish, and most of <strong>the</strong><br />

groundfish vessels fish <strong>for</strong> scallops and or shrimp in <strong>the</strong> winter. The St. George comprehensive<br />

plan includes a Commercial Fishing/Maritime Activities District, and language about <strong>the</strong><br />

importance of working waterfront was recently added. Throughout <strong>the</strong> comprehensive plan, it<br />

states repeatedly that “o<strong>the</strong>r uses will not adversely affect existing commercial fishing or<br />

maritime activities in a Commercial Fisheries/Maritime Activities District”.<br />

Falla and Schmanska suggested that <strong>the</strong> town might be interested in managing a permit bank to<br />

supplement catch quota available to boats landing in Port Clyde, particularly if <strong>the</strong> administration<br />

cost is funded by some o<strong>the</strong>r entity such as <strong>the</strong> state. However, <strong>the</strong>y also voiced concern about<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y could administer a permit bank given <strong>the</strong>ir lack of expertise, experience and funds.<br />

Mr. Falla and Mr. Schmanska agreed that any community-<strong>based</strong> sector would have to be able to<br />

stand on <strong>the</strong>ir own without local subsidy. The town is not willing to foot <strong>the</strong> bill <strong>for</strong> a sector<br />

manager unless <strong>the</strong> town will be getting some return on <strong>the</strong>ir ef<strong>for</strong>t. Again, <strong>the</strong>y mentioned that<br />

taxpayer money would not be available, and any sector would need to seek support from some<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r sources if it were needed. Mr. Falla did say that it might be possible to use <strong>the</strong> town’s bond<br />

rating to co-sign or float a bond that <strong>the</strong> sector members would have to pay back. He also<br />

reported that <strong>the</strong> town would not be able to supply taxpayer dollars, but it might be possible to put<br />

<strong>the</strong> concept out as an economic development initiative.<br />

Falla noted that <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> town to provide support to <strong>the</strong> community-<strong>based</strong> sector, <strong>the</strong>re would have<br />

to be a benefit to <strong>the</strong> town. Schmanska suggested that vessels leasing quota would have to<br />

designate Port Clyde as <strong>the</strong>ir homeport, thus requiring <strong>the</strong>m to pay <strong>the</strong>ir annual excise tax to <strong>the</strong><br />

Town of St. George. Requiring <strong>the</strong>m to land in Port Clyde would ensure that <strong>the</strong>y will buy <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

fuel and ice in town as well.<br />

15


3.1.1 Strawman Sector Structure and Operational Plan:<br />

The Port Clyde case study is <strong>based</strong> on a sector that includes 17 permits. The permits/vessels<br />

included were owned by <strong>the</strong> members of <strong>the</strong> Midcoast Fishermen’s Association at <strong>the</strong> time <strong>the</strong><br />

case study was begun in July of 2006. All vessels are mobile gear vessels between 36 and 56 feet<br />

in length (Table 1). Two of <strong>the</strong> permits have been transferred to skiffs and <strong>the</strong> days leased to<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r vessels owned by those individuals. Several of <strong>the</strong>se vessels undertake multiday trips at<br />

certain times of year, but <strong>the</strong>y generally remain within 100 miles of Port Clyde and within <strong>the</strong><br />

Gulf of Maine stock areas (i.e. <strong>the</strong>y do not fish Georges Bank or Sou<strong>the</strong>rn <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> stocks).<br />

Most of <strong>the</strong>se vessels also participate in <strong>the</strong> shrimp fishery in <strong>the</strong> winter and some participate in<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r fisheries such as general category scallops. The permit owners mostly live in <strong>the</strong> town of St.<br />

George which encompasses Port Clyde and Tenants Harbor. Port Clyde is one of <strong>the</strong> five villages<br />

that make up <strong>the</strong> town of St George. These 17 permits represent nearly all of <strong>the</strong> groundfish<br />

vessels fishing out of Port Clyde and <strong>the</strong> majority of active groundfish vessels in <strong>the</strong> Midcoast<br />

region of Maine.<br />

Table 1: List of Vessels Included in <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde Sector Case Study<br />

Permit Vessel Name Length Gross Tons Horsepower Built<br />

250573 SKIPPER 49 48 360 1981<br />

240185 TAYLOR EMILY 48 35 360 1972<br />

230570 SUSAN AND JESSICA 36 16 210 1979<br />

250558 LESLIE & JESSICA 51 34 400 1980<br />

242567 CAPT'N LEE 48 33 230 1998<br />

240423 MEGALTAY 40 25 250 1979<br />

240125 LIBERTY 47 29 250 1949<br />

250387 ELLA CHRISTINE 45 37 250 1975<br />

310354 LAUREN DOROTHY II 47 55 365 1980<br />

250728 ANNA LENA IV 56 73 400 1984<br />

310554 ERIKA LYNN 50 64 330 1987<br />

150043 ADREA & ERIC 14 1 10 1999<br />

149551 FOXY GIRL 14 4 10 1997<br />

121830 SARAH MACKAY 41 5 225 1986<br />

240143 MISTY MAE 52 30 350 1969<br />

240636 HIGH ROLLER 40 24 320 1981<br />

250582 WINDSONG 51 47 360 1981<br />

A strawman operational structure <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector was developed through consultation with <strong>the</strong><br />

Midcoast Fishermen’s Association. Under this strawman, <strong>the</strong> sector would receive allocations of<br />

all regulated groundfish species it regularly encounters as well as monkfish. The groundfish<br />

stocks <strong>for</strong> which allocations would be requested include: GOM cod, GOM haddock, Cape<br />

Cod/GOM yellowtail flounder, witch flounder, American plaice, GOM winter flounder, white<br />

hake, pollock, Acadian redfish, and nor<strong>the</strong>rn windowpane flounder. Regulations state that sector<br />

allocations are to be <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> ratio of <strong>the</strong> Sector members’ total catch by species and stock<br />

relative to <strong>the</strong> total commercial catch of each species <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> five years prior to <strong>the</strong> proposal of <strong>the</strong><br />

sector. However, recent decisions of <strong>the</strong> Council suggest that <strong>the</strong> years used <strong>for</strong> allocation may be<br />

changed and fixed at <strong>the</strong> same years <strong>for</strong> all sectors. At <strong>the</strong> time this research was being<br />

undertaken, it was not clear which catch history years would be used <strong>for</strong> determining allocations.<br />

For this reason, <strong>the</strong> analysis of <strong>the</strong> allocation and economic feasibility of <strong>the</strong> sector is done <strong>based</strong><br />

on sector and overall commercial catches <strong>for</strong> two different allocation periods: (1) from May 1,<br />

2001 through April 30, 2006, and (2) from May 1, 1996 to April 30, 2002. The earlier allocation<br />

16


period is that which was used to determine allocations of cod to <strong>the</strong> two existing sectors. The<br />

shares of total commercial catches landed by Port Clyde vessels <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>se species <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>se two<br />

periods are shown in Table 2 5 . With <strong>the</strong> exception of witch flounder and winter flounder, <strong>the</strong><br />

“current” Port Clyde fleet landed a higher proportion of total commercial catch in fishing years<br />

2001-2005 than in 1996-2001. Consequently <strong>the</strong>ir shares of TACs and ACE allocations would be<br />

higher if <strong>the</strong> 2001-2005 years were used to determine <strong>the</strong>ir allocation. It should be noted that <strong>the</strong><br />

current regulations do not allow sectors to request allocations of monkfish; an amendment to <strong>the</strong><br />

Monkfish FMP will be required to make this possible.<br />

Each year <strong>the</strong> sector would receive annual catch entitlements (ACE) <strong>for</strong> each species. These ACE<br />

allocations become hard TACs <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> overall sector. The ACE allocated to <strong>the</strong> sector each year<br />

would be equal to <strong>the</strong> shares of <strong>the</strong> overall target TACs shown in Table 2.<br />

Table 2: Port Clyde Sector Vessels’ share of landings<br />

<strong>for</strong> two different allocation periods (FY01-05 and FY96-01)<br />

Stock and species<br />

Total FY01-05<br />

Landings<br />

Port Clyde<br />

Sector Share<br />

Total FY96-01<br />

Landings<br />

Port Clyde<br />

Sector Share<br />

GOM COD 42,105,000 1.3% 56,395,433 1.3%<br />

GOM HADDOCK 10,769,000 1.9% 10,209,311 0.7%<br />

GOM/CC WINTER FLOUNDER 6,072,000 0.7% 7,137,377 1.8%<br />

GOM/CC YELLOWTAIL 16,218,000 0.3% 20,140,336 0.1%<br />

GOM/GB WINDOWPANE 274,000 0.1% 3,416,338 0.0%<br />

PLAICE 27,593,000 7.8% 52,992,348 5.6%<br />

POLLOCK 52,853,000 0.8% 56,561,783 0.6%<br />

REDFISH 4,461,000 2.3% 4,061,337 1.4%<br />

WHITE HAKE 37,850,000 2.8% 38,320,463 1.9%<br />

WITCH FLOUNDER 32,599,000 5.1% 30,024,873 6.9%<br />

NFMA MONKFISH 142,821,000 4.1% 147,201,370 3.6%<br />

The actual number of pounds of ACE allocated to <strong>the</strong> Sector each year would increase or<br />

decrease in proportion to increases or decreases in <strong>the</strong> target TACs. Under <strong>the</strong> strawman<br />

operational plan, sector members would be required to retain all legal sized fish of regulated<br />

species <strong>for</strong> which <strong>the</strong> Sector received an allocation of ACE, and all sector members would be<br />

required to stop fishing once total sector catch of any species equaled <strong>the</strong> sector ACE <strong>for</strong> that<br />

species.<br />

The Port Clyde sector would restrict <strong>the</strong> operations of member vessels to <strong>the</strong> Gulf of Maine,<br />

specifically to statistical areas 511, 512, 513, 514 and 515. Because <strong>the</strong> catch of all managed<br />

species would be constrained by hard TACs, <strong>the</strong> sector would request that it be exempted from<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r regulations designed primarily to control fishing mortality. Specifically <strong>the</strong> sector would<br />

request to be exempted from: Nor<strong>the</strong>ast Multispecies Days at Sea (DAS) limits (including<br />

5 The catches <strong>for</strong> sector vessels <strong>for</strong> estimating sector allocations reflect <strong>the</strong> catches in <strong>the</strong> allocation years of<br />

<strong>the</strong> permits associated with <strong>the</strong> current Moratorium Right ID of <strong>the</strong> vessel. The Moratorium Right ID is an<br />

<strong>the</strong> means of tracking <strong>the</strong> catch history of a permit that may have been transferred amongst vessels over<br />

time. The permit number changes with each change of vessel, but <strong>the</strong> Right ID does not. To calculate <strong>the</strong><br />

catch history attributable to <strong>the</strong> current permit, I determined its current Right ID and <strong>the</strong>n determined <strong>the</strong><br />

permit numbers associated with that right ID historically. In some cases <strong>the</strong> catch history attributable to a<br />

particular current permit may have been generated by multiple vessels and permits over time. It may also<br />

be that <strong>the</strong> catch history <strong>for</strong> a current permit does not include all of <strong>the</strong> catches by that vessel in previous<br />

years since its current Right ID may have been associated with a different vessel in previous years and <strong>the</strong>n<br />

transferred to <strong>the</strong> current vessel.<br />

17


differential DAS counting), Monkfish DAS limits 6 , trip limits on cod, yellowtail flounder, winter<br />

flounder and white hake, possession and landing limits on monkfish, and Gulf of Maine rolling<br />

closures. The sector will continue to be subject to <strong>the</strong> same restrictions on year-round closed areas<br />

and gear as o<strong>the</strong>r multispecies vessels. Initially, <strong>the</strong> sector would not propose any additional<br />

restrictions on gear or vessel characteristics beyond current permit restrictions, though it might<br />

create additional rules in <strong>the</strong> future to protect habitat or spawning aggregations or to reduce<br />

bycatch.<br />

The Sector envisions assigning each permit in <strong>the</strong> sector a specific allocation of <strong>the</strong> overall<br />

allocation of each of <strong>the</strong> species-stocks <strong>for</strong> which <strong>the</strong> Sector receives and allocation. These<br />

individual allocations would be <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> contribution of <strong>the</strong> catch history of <strong>the</strong> permit (i.e.,<br />

its contribution to determining <strong>the</strong> overall sector allocation). Sector members would be free to<br />

utilize <strong>the</strong>se allocations on <strong>the</strong>ir vessels or transfer <strong>the</strong>m to o<strong>the</strong>r vessels within <strong>the</strong> sector upon<br />

notification and approval by <strong>the</strong> sector manager. These allocations would be usable only while<br />

operating as part of <strong>the</strong> sector. Should <strong>the</strong>y leave <strong>the</strong> sector or <strong>the</strong> sector not be renewed, <strong>the</strong>se<br />

vessels would again be subject to <strong>the</strong> same ef<strong>for</strong>t controls as <strong>the</strong> rest of <strong>the</strong> multispecies fleet not<br />

enrolled in a sector.<br />

Several of <strong>the</strong> prospective members of <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde <strong>Community</strong> Sector recently set up a<br />

marketing cooperative, <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde Draggermen’s Co-op. The purpose of <strong>the</strong> Co-op is to<br />

increase <strong>the</strong> price Port Clyde fishermen receive <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir groundfish by developing direct<br />

marketing arrangements with retailers and restaurants. It is envisioned that <strong>the</strong> cooperative and<br />

sector would be integrated with <strong>the</strong> goal of organizing <strong>the</strong> harvesting of <strong>the</strong> sector’s groundfish<br />

allocation to service <strong>the</strong> marketing arrangements developed by <strong>the</strong> cooperative. Sector<br />

management would allow <strong>the</strong> sector members to concentrate on producing high quality fish to<br />

meet market demand with less concern about time spent at sea. For example this might result in<br />

more day trips with higher quality fish. However, it might also result in vessels steaming fur<strong>the</strong>r<br />

at times to find larger, more valuable fish or <strong>the</strong> species required to meet specific market<br />

commitments. The sector also allows <strong>the</strong> cooperative to give greater assurance that it can meet<br />

specific market demands since <strong>the</strong> sector has an allocation by species and is not limited by <strong>the</strong><br />

number of days if can fish and o<strong>the</strong>r regulations that constrain fishing at key times.<br />

3.1.2 Economic Feasibility<br />

The economic feasibility analysis <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde <strong>Community</strong>-<strong>based</strong> Sector attempts to answer<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> sector could recover from its members <strong>the</strong> costs of establishing and running <strong>the</strong><br />

sector and whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> profitability of <strong>the</strong> sector vessels (after subtracting <strong>the</strong>se costs) is likely to<br />

be higher under sector management than current management. The analysis to address <strong>the</strong>se<br />

questions entails estimating <strong>the</strong> landings and revenues of <strong>the</strong> sector, estimating <strong>the</strong> costs of<br />

establishing and managing <strong>the</strong> sector, and estimating <strong>the</strong> revenues of sector members without<br />

sector management. The relative gains in revenues or net revenues under sector management are<br />

<strong>the</strong>n compared with additional costs of sector management to calculate <strong>the</strong> net gain to <strong>the</strong> sector<br />

participants.<br />

A starting point <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> analysis is to estimate <strong>the</strong> sectors species-stock allocations and <strong>the</strong><br />

projected sector ACE allocations and revenues. The sector species/stock allocations as shares of<br />

TACs <strong>based</strong> on two separate allocation <strong>for</strong>mulas (using 1996-01 or 2001-05 fishing years) were<br />

6 This would likely require changes to <strong>the</strong> Monkfish FMP<br />

18


shown above in Table 2. Revenue projections are <strong>based</strong> on 50 th percentile estimates of F msy TACs<br />

and prices shown in appendix A. <strong>Sectors</strong> landings and revenues are <strong>the</strong>n calculated <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Sectors</strong> allocation shares of each species. The sector is assumed to catch only 85% of <strong>the</strong>ir ACE<br />

allocations. This 85% figure is arbitrary, but leaves a plausible buffer to account <strong>for</strong> discards of<br />

undersize or unmarketable fish and <strong>for</strong> inability to use <strong>the</strong> entire ACE allocation of some species<br />

without exceeding ACE allocations of o<strong>the</strong>rs 7 . In reality <strong>the</strong> sector is likely to utilize nearly 100%<br />

of some species ACE and less than 85% of o<strong>the</strong>rs; but this is difficult to predict since sector<br />

management is likely to substantially change <strong>the</strong> incentives and fishing patterns of sector<br />

members.<br />

Estimating <strong>the</strong> cost of establishing and operating <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde <strong>Community</strong> Sector is difficult<br />

given <strong>the</strong> uncertainty in <strong>the</strong> regulatory process <strong>for</strong> approval and in <strong>the</strong> requirements <strong>for</strong> reporting<br />

and monitoring <strong>the</strong> sector once in operation. The Cape Cod Commercial Hook Fishermen’s<br />

association estimated that it cost <strong>the</strong>m about $100,000 to establish <strong>the</strong>ir sector (Pappalardo 2006).<br />

This included costs <strong>for</strong> meetings, legal costs and cost of preparation of an environmental<br />

assessment. It does not include <strong>the</strong> opportunity cost of time spent in developing <strong>the</strong> sector by<br />

some of <strong>the</strong> association staff and by sector members. Costs <strong>for</strong> future sectors may be somewhat<br />

lower since <strong>the</strong>y can use existing documents prepared by <strong>the</strong> GB Hook Sector as templates.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> Gulf of Maine Research Institute has hired a sector project manager that can<br />

provide technical assistance to prospective sectors including preparation of operations plans and<br />

environmental assessments. For <strong>the</strong>se reasons, and because <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde Sector is quite small,<br />

<strong>the</strong> estimate of $100,000 <strong>for</strong> sector establishment used <strong>for</strong> this analysis probably errs on <strong>the</strong> high<br />

side of <strong>the</strong> true cost to <strong>the</strong> sector.<br />

The primary ongoing costs <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector are <strong>the</strong> salary of <strong>the</strong> sector manager, administrative<br />

overhead and possibly some legal costs. In <strong>the</strong> case of <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde sector with only 17 boats<br />

and a smaller number of members, it is expected that <strong>the</strong> sector manager will work only part time.<br />

The estimated $75,000 annual operational cost used <strong>for</strong> this analysis would allow <strong>for</strong> $35,000 in<br />

salary to <strong>the</strong> part time sector manager (with no benefits) and an additional $40,000 <strong>for</strong><br />

administrative and legal costs.<br />

Sector revenues are calculated by multiplying projected sector landings by estimated prices that<br />

vary by species. Sector vessel landings are assumed to attract <strong>the</strong> same ex-vessel prices as <strong>the</strong><br />

overall industry (i.e. <strong>the</strong> demand model projects prices <strong>based</strong> on overall commercial landings).<br />

Prices <strong>for</strong> calculation of revenues are <strong>based</strong> on demand models described in Appendix B that<br />

calculate region-wide prices <strong>based</strong> on region-wide landings. Price projections are nominal prices<br />

(not adjusted <strong>for</strong> inflation). These price projections are likely conservative (i.e. biased low) since<br />

<strong>the</strong>y assume landings equal overall target TACs. Landings of many species <strong>the</strong> last few years<br />

have been well below target TACs and may remain below <strong>the</strong>m in <strong>the</strong> near future. 8 Since price<br />

predictions are inversely correlated with landings levels, <strong>the</strong> upward bias in landings predictions<br />

would result in downward bias in price predictions. <strong>Sectors</strong> might also be able to increase prices<br />

by improving quality or changing <strong>the</strong> time of landings if <strong>the</strong>y are freed from DAS restrictions and<br />

rolling closures. Since price predictions are conservative, revenue predictions are also<br />

7 The spreadsheet used to make predictions is available, and <strong>the</strong> percentage of ACE used can easily be<br />

adjusted to explore <strong>the</strong> sensitivity of results to this assumption.<br />

8 Ef<strong>for</strong>t controls and trip limits are designed to keep catches of all regulated species below target TACs<br />

which results in catches of many species be constrained well below target TACs. In addition, landings <strong>for</strong><br />

many species are considerably lower than catches because of substantial discarding.<br />

19


conservative except to <strong>the</strong> extent that <strong>the</strong> sector is unable to land catches equal to at least 85% of<br />

its ACE.<br />

The expected annual gain in revenues under sector management is estimated by subtracting <strong>the</strong><br />

projected annual revenues without sectors management from projected revenues under sector<br />

management (Table 3a,b). The analysis assumes that, without sector management, <strong>the</strong> sector<br />

members will continue to catch <strong>the</strong> same percentage of <strong>the</strong> different groundfish target TACs that<br />

<strong>the</strong>y caught during <strong>the</strong> 2004 and 2005 fishing years. Estimates are provided <strong>based</strong> on two<br />

different sector allocation <strong>for</strong>mulas (e.g. FY01-05 and FY96-01 basis years). The annual gain in<br />

net revenues <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector is calculated by subtracting from <strong>the</strong> increase in annual gross revenue,<br />

<strong>the</strong> variable operating costs (estimated at 38% of <strong>the</strong> increased gross revenues) 9 , <strong>the</strong> ongoing<br />

costs of sector management (assumed to be $75,000), and loan payments to repay sector<br />

establishment costs (which was assumed to be $100,000). These net gains do not account <strong>for</strong><br />

additional labor costs associated with landing additional catch (only costs such as fuel, oil, ice,<br />

water and provisions). Thus <strong>the</strong> gains in net revenues represent additional income that would be<br />

divided between boat/permit owners, captains and crew. Presumably this will be on <strong>the</strong> same<br />

basis as normal crew share which may vary from vessel to vessel.<br />

The analysis suggests that sector management can provide substantial gains in net revenues to<br />

sector vessels and that <strong>the</strong>se gains far outweigh <strong>the</strong> costs of establishing and operating a sector. In<br />

<strong>the</strong> first year, <strong>the</strong> sector is projected to increase net revenues by $605 thousand with <strong>the</strong> FY01-05<br />

allocation and by $505 thousand with <strong>the</strong> FY96-01 allocation. This assumes sector vessels pay a<br />

landing tax of 5% on groundfish and monkfish landings. The 5% landings tax would be sufficient<br />

to cover <strong>the</strong> $75 thousand annual operating cost and to pay off a $100 thousand loan <strong>for</strong><br />

establishment of <strong>the</strong> sector in 5 or 6 years (depending on allocation <strong>for</strong>mula) assuming a 7.5%<br />

interest rate.<br />

If <strong>the</strong> landings tax was continued at 5% indefinitely, <strong>the</strong> sector entity would begin to build capital<br />

which could be used to pay dividends to sector members or to purchase additional permits. The<br />

asset calculations in Tables 3a,b assume that <strong>the</strong> landing tax surplus and 7.5% interest on assets is<br />

simply accumulated by <strong>the</strong> sector entity. Note that <strong>the</strong> column titled interest and management fees<br />

becomes negative in later years once interest on <strong>the</strong> sector’s asset base exceeds <strong>the</strong> management<br />

costs.<br />

9 The estimate of variable operating costs as a percent of revenue is <strong>based</strong> on observer data collected from<br />

observed trawler trips. For each trip <strong>the</strong> ratio of <strong>the</strong> sum of fuel, oil, food, water, ice, and supplies to <strong>the</strong><br />

revenues generated by <strong>the</strong> trip was calculated. A weighted average of this ratio (weighted by revenue) was<br />

calculated to equal 25% of gross revenues. However, <strong>the</strong> average fuel cost in this data was only $1.92 per<br />

gallon. If <strong>the</strong> calculation are redone with a fuel cost of $3 per gallon <strong>the</strong> weighted average variable cost per<br />

dollar of revenue is 38%.<br />

20


Table 3a: Port Clyde Sector Revenues and Gains Over Non Sector Management<br />

<strong>based</strong> on FY01-05 Allocation<br />

Fishing<br />

Year Total Revenue tax (5%)<br />

Interest +<br />

Mgmt fees<br />

Outstanding<br />

Loan or<br />

(Assets)<br />

Sector Revenue<br />

Gain (vs. no sector) % Gain<br />

Sector Net<br />

Rev Gain<br />

2008 $ 2,503,715 $ 125,186 $ 82,500 $ 100,000 $ 1,052,816 79% $ 605,175<br />

2009 $ 2,071,357 $ 103,568 $ 79,299 $ 57,314 $ 830,020 73% $ 475,257<br />

2010 $ 2,103,820 $ 105,191 $ 77,478 $ 33,045 $ 853,683 75% $ 489,311<br />

2011 $ 2,140,039 $ 107,002 $ 75,400 $ 5,332 $ 876,453 76% $ 502,740<br />

2012 $ 2,183,314 $ 109,166 $ 73,030 $ (26,270) $ 901,207 77% $ 517,265<br />

2013 $ 2,233,589 $ 111,679 $ 70,320 $ (62,406) $ 930,631 78% $ 534,553<br />

2014 $ 2,080,694 $ 104,035 $ 67,218 $ (103,765) $ 865,970 78% $ 497,368<br />

2015 $ 2,095,163 $ 104,758 $ 64,456 $ (140,583) $ 870,485 78% $ 499,892<br />

2016 $ 2,116,387 $ 105,819 $ 61,434 $ (180,884) $ 880,369 78% $ 505,618<br />

2017 $ 2,135,157 $ 106,758 $ 58,105 $ (225,270) $ 889,709 78% $ 511,052<br />

2018 $ 2,157,520 $ 107,876 $ 54,456 $ (273,923) $ 898,977 78% $ 516,373<br />

2019 $ 2,176,498 $ 108,825 $ 50,449 $ (327,343) $ 906,731 78% $ 520,820<br />

2020 $ 2,193,566 $ 109,678 $ 46,071 $ (385,719) $ 913,564 78% $ 524,732<br />

2021 $ 2,209,382 $ 110,469 $ 41,301 $ (449,326) $ 919,789 78% $ 528,291<br />

2022 $ 2,224,975 $ 111,249 $ 36,113 $ (518,495) $ 925,921 78% $ 531,796<br />

2023 $ 2,239,365 $ 111,968 $ 30,478 $ (593,631) $ 931,680 78% $ 535,094<br />

2024 $ 2,253,809 $ 112,690 $ 24,366 $ (675,121) $ 938,839 78% $ 539,258<br />

2025 $ 2,267,361 $ 113,368 $ 17,742 $ (763,446) $ 943,970 78% $ 542,181<br />

2026 $ 2,279,730 $ 113,987 $ 10,570 $ (859,072) $ 948,501 78% $ 544,756<br />

2027 $ 2,309,629 $ 115,481 $ 2,813 $ (962,489) $ 957,177 77% $ 549,567<br />

2028 $ 2,318,817 $ 115,941 $ (5,637) $ (1,075,157) $ 960,978 77% $ 551,749<br />

2029 $ 2,329,240 $ 116,462 $ (14,755) $ (1,196,735) $ 965,204 77% $ 554,171<br />

2030 $ 2,339,097 $ 116,955 $ (24,596) $ (1,327,952) $ 969,179 77% $ 556,448<br />

2031 $ 2,349,535 $ 117,477 $ (35,213) $ (1,469,503) $ 973,277 77% $ 558,791<br />

2032 $ 2,359,976 $ 117,999 $ (46,664) $ (1,622,193) $ 977,456 77% $ 561,183<br />

2033 $ 2,370,114 $ 118,506 $ (59,014) $ (1,786,856) $ 981,432 77% $ 563,455<br />

2034 $ 2,380,278 $ 119,014 $ (72,328) $ (1,964,376) $ 985,185 77% $ 565,589<br />

2035 $ 2,390,093 $ 119,505 $ (86,679) $ (2,155,718) $ 988,890 77% $ 567,700<br />

2036 $ 2,400,649 $ 120,032 $ (102,143) $ (2,361,902) $ 992,914 77% $ 569,994<br />

2037 $ 2,409,934 $ 120,497 $ (118,806) $ (2,584,077) $ 996,221 77% $ 571,868<br />

21


Table 3b: Port Clyde Sector Revenues and Gains Over Non Sector Management<br />

Based on FY96-01 Allocation<br />

Fishing<br />

Year Total Revenue tax (5%)<br />

Interest +<br />

Mgmt fees<br />

Outstanding<br />

Loan or<br />

(Assets)<br />

Sector Revenue<br />

Gain (vs. no sector) % Gain<br />

Sector Net<br />

Rev Gain<br />

2008 $ 2,327,858 $ 116,393 $ 82,500 $ 100,000 $ 885,752 67% $ 504,937<br />

2009 $ 1,945,545 $ 97,277 $ 79,958 $ 66,107 $ 710,499 62% $ 403,544<br />

2010 $ 1,897,126 $ 94,856 $ 78,659 $ 48,788 $ 657,324 57% $ 371,496<br />

2011 $ 1,867,019 $ 93,351 $ 77,444 $ 32,591 $ 617,083 53% $ 347,118<br />

2012 $ 1,853,867 $ 92,693 $ 76,251 $ 16,684 $ 588,233 50% $ 329,481<br />

2013 $ 1,853,678 $ 92,684 $ 75,018 $ 242 $ 569,716 48% $ 318,004<br />

2014 $ 1,710,644 $ 85,532 $ 73,693 $ (17,424) $ 514,422 46% $ 286,440<br />

2015 $ 1,714,545 $ 85,727 $ 72,805 $ (29,263) $ 508,898 45% $ 282,940<br />

2016 $ 1,724,433 $ 86,222 $ 71,836 $ (42,185) $ 508,013 45% $ 282,204<br />

2017 $ 1,733,732 $ 86,687 $ 70,757 $ (56,570) $ 508,356 45% $ 282,240<br />

2018 $ 1,748,466 $ 87,423 $ 69,563 $ (72,500) $ 510,375 44% $ 283,212<br />

2019 $ 1,761,293 $ 88,065 $ 68,223 $ (90,360) $ 512,287 44% $ 284,153<br />

2020 $ 1,773,226 $ 88,661 $ 66,735 $ (110,202) $ 514,240 44% $ 285,138<br />

2021 $ 1,784,646 $ 89,232 $ 65,090 $ (132,129) $ 516,290 44% $ 286,191<br />

2022 $ 1,796,297 $ 89,815 $ 63,280 $ (156,271) $ 518,677 44% $ 287,450<br />

2023 $ 1,806,821 $ 90,341 $ 61,290 $ (182,806) $ 520,764 44% $ 288,544<br />

2024 $ 1,816,038 $ 90,802 $ 59,111 $ (211,857) $ 522,957 43% $ 289,729<br />

2025 $ 1,826,499 $ 91,325 $ 56,734 $ (243,548) $ 525,151 43% $ 290,890<br />

2026 $ 1,836,155 $ 91,808 $ 54,140 $ (278,139) $ 527,105 43% $ 291,918<br />

2027 $ 1,864,323 $ 93,216 $ 51,314 $ (315,808) $ 534,137 43% $ 295,743<br />

2028 $ 1,870,897 $ 93,545 $ 48,172 $ (357,709) $ 535,455 43% $ 296,435<br />

2029 $ 1,878,616 $ 93,931 $ 44,769 $ (403,082) $ 537,111 43% $ 297,315<br />

2030 $ 1,885,887 $ 94,294 $ 41,082 $ (452,244) $ 538,629 43% $ 298,118<br />

2031 $ 1,893,707 $ 94,685 $ 37,091 $ (505,457) $ 540,241 43% $ 298,969<br />

2032 $ 1,901,565 $ 95,078 $ 32,771 $ (563,052) $ 541,966 43% $ 299,889<br />

2033 $ 1,909,250 $ 95,462 $ 28,098 $ (625,359) $ 543,610 43% $ 300,763<br />

2034 $ 1,917,265 $ 95,863 $ 23,046 $ (692,723) $ 545,323 43% $ 301,672<br />

2035 $ 1,924,766 $ 96,238 $ 17,584 $ (765,541) $ 546,829 43% $ 302,463<br />

2036 $ 1,932,996 $ 96,650 $ 11,685 $ (844,195) $ 548,643 43% $ 303,432<br />

2037 $ 1,940,250 $ 97,012 $ 5,313 $ (929,159) $ 550,020 43% $ 304,148<br />

The projected gains <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector are <strong>based</strong> solely on <strong>the</strong> ability of <strong>the</strong> sector to land a higher<br />

percentage of <strong>the</strong> target TACs than it is currently catching. The ability to do this would be a<br />

consequence of exemptions from DAS restrictions, rolling closures and trip limits. The sector<br />

may achieve additional gains beyond what is calculated here through higher prices if <strong>the</strong>y are able<br />

to improve quality or make direct marketing arrangements. They may also achieve gains by<br />

reducing fixed costs through consolidation and by having <strong>the</strong> most efficient boats in <strong>the</strong> sector<br />

harvest its allocation. The analysis presented here implicitly assumes <strong>the</strong> same vessels are used to<br />

harvest <strong>the</strong> fish with or without sector management. Under sector management, it would be<br />

possible to consolidate fishing operations on fewer plat<strong>for</strong>ms if <strong>the</strong> sector desired. This would be<br />

expected to reduce fixed costs which would provide an additional boost in profitability.<br />

Although <strong>the</strong> projections are shown through <strong>the</strong> year 2037, <strong>the</strong> relative gains of sector vs. nonsector<br />

management are unlikely to continue as projected. Major changes in management of <strong>the</strong><br />

fishery, including ITQs, are being considered which will presumably increase profitability of nonsector<br />

vessels and erode <strong>the</strong> relative benefits of sector to non-sector management. TAC<br />

projections are also highly uncertain in future years as actual TACs will be heavily dependent on<br />

22


ecruitment and could be ei<strong>the</strong>r higher or lower. Never<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong> analysis suggests that <strong>the</strong> gains<br />

from sector management are sufficiently large to justify <strong>the</strong> difficulty and cost of establishing a<br />

sector even if <strong>the</strong> gains are only realized <strong>for</strong> a few years.<br />

Ano<strong>the</strong>r way to evaluate <strong>the</strong> relative gains from sector management is a retrospective evaluation.<br />

Tables 4a,b show <strong>the</strong> actual catch of <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde sector vessels in fishing years 2004 and 2005<br />

and what <strong>the</strong> sector TACs would have been had <strong>the</strong>y been under sector management in those<br />

years (given <strong>the</strong> two different allocation <strong>for</strong>mulas). The potential <strong>for</strong>gone revenue is calculated by<br />

applying <strong>the</strong> actual average species prices <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector vessels in those years by <strong>the</strong> estimated<br />

<strong>for</strong>gone catch. This likely represents and upper bound on what <strong>the</strong> actual <strong>for</strong>gone revenues would<br />

have been since <strong>the</strong> sector would not have been able to land 100% of all TACs. However, it is<br />

clear that <strong>the</strong> potential gains could have been substantial.<br />

Table 4a: Port Clyde Sector Revenues and Gains Over Non Sector Management<br />

Based on FY01-05 Allocation<br />

04-05 05-06 04-05 05-06 Forgone Forgone Forgone Rev Forgone Rev<br />

Stock and species<br />

Sector TAC Sector TAC Catch Catch Catch FY04 Catch FY05 FY04 FY05<br />

GOM COD 136,657 179,542 75,107 125,373 61,550 54,169 $ 73,249 $ 70,420<br />

GOM HADDOCK 203,097 199,061 22,818 33,295 180,279 165,766 $ 169,936 $ 159,665<br />

GOM WHITE HAKE 239,337 238,277 190,737 161,235 48,600 77,042 $ 23,959 $ 60,690<br />

NFMA MONKFISH 1,548,985 1,201,358 1,087,184 686,196 461,801 515,162 $ 309,226 $ 411,940<br />

GOM PLAICE 631,388 619,427 236,870 173,570 394,518 445,857 $ 361,113 $ 620,755<br />

POLLOCK 195,260 195,260 75,605 120,219 119,655 75,041 $ 76,066 $ 51,428<br />

REDFISH 83,996 88,782 19,078 29,069 64,918 59,713 $ 29,359 $ 36,521<br />

GOM/CC WINTER FLOUNDER 48,103 38,558 1,424 2,000 46,679 36,558 $ 41,762 $ 42,152<br />

WITCH FLOUNDER 580,887 784,994 346,306 257,014 234,581 527,980 $ 247,565 $ 629,963<br />

GOM/CC YELLOWTAIL 5,275 7,383 3 24 5,272 7,359 $ 5,272 $ 3,986<br />

Total 3,672,985 3,552,643 2,055,132 1,587,994 1,617,853 1,964,649 $ 1,337,507 $ 2,087,520<br />

Table 4b: Port Clyde Sector Revenues and Gains Over Non Sector Management<br />

Based on FY96-01 Allocation<br />

04-05 05-06 04-05 05-06 Forgone Forgone Forgone Rev Forgone Rev<br />

Stock and species<br />

Sector TAC Sector TAC Catch Catch Catch FY04 Catch FY05 FY04 FY05<br />

GOM COD 140,613 184,739 75,107 125,373 65,506 59,366 $ 77,956 $ 77,176<br />

GOM HADDOCK 77,143 75,610 22,818 33,295 54,326 42,316 $ 51,209 $ 40,758<br />

GOM WHITE HAKE 162,388 161,669 190,737 161,235 (28,349) 435 $ (13,975) $ 342<br />

NFMA MONKFISH 1,348,610 1,045,952 1,087,184 686,196 261,426 359,756 $ 175,053 $ 287,672<br />

GOM PLAICE 457,496 448,829 236,870 173,570 220,626 275,260 $ 201,945 $ 383,236<br />

POLLOCK 151,298 151,298 75,605 120,219 75,693 31,079 $ 48,119 $ 21,300<br />

REDFISH 50,426 53,299 19,078 29,069 31,348 24,230 $ 14,177 $ 14,819<br />

GOM/CC WINTER FLOUNDER 130,922 104,945 1,424 2,000 129,498 102,945 $ 115,857 $ 118,695<br />

WITCH FLOUNDER 785,041 1,060,883 346,306 257,014 438,735 803,869 $ 463,019 $ 959,142<br />

GOM/CC YELLOWTAIL 1,276 1,786 3 24 1,273 1,762 $ 1,273 $ 954<br />

Total 3,305,213 3,289,010 2,055,132 1,587,994 1,250,081 1,701,016 $ 1,134,633 $ 1,904,094<br />

3.1.3 Matching Catch to ACE<br />

A frequently expressed concern of many fishermen regarding sector management as well<br />

individual quota systems is that fishermen have limited control over <strong>the</strong> species composition of<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir catch and may be unable to match <strong>the</strong>ir catches to <strong>the</strong>ir allocations. This may be particularly<br />

difficult if <strong>the</strong> spatial distribution of different species has shifted over time relative to what it was<br />

in <strong>the</strong> years on which <strong>the</strong>ir allocation was calculated. This imbalance could result in <strong>the</strong>m being<br />

unable to use much of <strong>the</strong>ir allocation of some species because <strong>the</strong>y could not limit <strong>the</strong>ir catch of<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r species and used up those allocations prematurely. In an individual transferable quota<br />

23


system this problem could be mitigated through quota markets. An individual could simply<br />

purchase additional ACE <strong>for</strong> species <strong>for</strong> which <strong>the</strong>ir ACE allocation is inadequate or <strong>the</strong>y could<br />

sell unused ACE. Internal trades within a sector could accomplish <strong>the</strong> same objective; however,<br />

<strong>the</strong> effective market may be thin, particularly <strong>for</strong> small sectors like <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde sector.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>for</strong> a geographically constrained sector, <strong>the</strong> species composition across vessels may<br />

not vary that much, and vessels may have less ability to vary <strong>the</strong> composition through spatial or<br />

temporal shifts of ef<strong>for</strong>t. Allowing trading between sectors (assuming more are created) might<br />

alleviate this problem, but current rules do not allow trading between sectors.<br />

Table 5 shows how <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde sector vessels’ catch by species-stock has changed over time<br />

as a percentage of <strong>the</strong>ir total catch. Table 6 shows how <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde sector vessels’ catch as a<br />

percentage of total commercial catch has changed over time. These percentages are <strong>based</strong> solely<br />

on vessel trip report data which may be quite inaccurate or at least quite different from <strong>the</strong> dealer<br />

data on which sector allocations are <strong>based</strong>. This is particularly true <strong>for</strong> species such as monkfish<br />

that are often landed only as tails. It should also be noted that <strong>the</strong> catches of windowpane flounder<br />

in <strong>the</strong> VTR data are much higher than those reported in <strong>the</strong> dealer data. The allocations to <strong>the</strong><br />

sector, <strong>based</strong> on dealer data, provide virtually no allocation of windowpane flounder to <strong>the</strong> sector,<br />

yet <strong>the</strong> VTR data suggests that <strong>the</strong> sectors account of a relatively large share of windowpane<br />

catch, particularly in fishing years 2000-2002. Never<strong>the</strong>less <strong>the</strong>se tables offer some indication of<br />

<strong>the</strong> relative variability over time of <strong>the</strong> sector vessels species composition and its catch relative to<br />

<strong>the</strong> total commercial catch.<br />

Table 5: Port Clyde Sector’s Species/stock Composition of Catch as a Percentage<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Sector’s Total <strong>Groundfish</strong> Catch by Fishing Year<br />

<strong>Groundfish</strong> Stock FY 1996 FY 1997 FY 1998 FY 1999 FY 2000 FY 2001 FY 2002 FY 2003 FY 2004 FY 2005<br />

GOM cod 16.9% 10.3% 5.5% 3.8% 6.4% 6.7% 4.6% 3.0% 5.0% 10.9%<br />

GOM haddock 0.2% 0.3% 0.3% 0.3% 0.5% 2.5% 1.9% 2.4% 1.8% 3.1%<br />

Hake 6.8% 6.4% 3.8% 2.5% 4.6% 4.7% 8.0% 7.2% 6.9% 6.4%<br />

Nor<strong>the</strong>rn Monkfish 16.4% 17.4% 20.3% 25.4% 27.2% 26.2% 28.3% 29.1% 27.6% 21.4%<br />

Plaice 30.4% 30.3% 38.7% 34.6% 32.2% 30.3% 29.8% 30.3% 19.0% 18.0%<br />

Pollock 0.8% 8.8% 3.6% 2.6% 1.8% 3.0% 4.7% 4.7% 5.5% 10.8%<br />

Redfish 0.2% 0.3% 0.6% 0.7% 0.6% 0.9% 1.0% 2.0% 1.8% 2.7%<br />

GOM/GB windowpane 0.0% 0.0% 0.2% 0.0% 1.3% 0.7% 1.9% 0.5% 0.3% 0.2%<br />

GOM winter flounder 1.3% 1.2% 0.4% 1.8% 1.0% 1.2% 1.0% 0.1% 0.2% 0.0%<br />

Witch flounder 25.2% 23.9% 25.7% 26.5% 21.8% 21.4% 17.9% 20.4% 31.7% 26.3%<br />

Cape Cod Yellowtail flounder 1.5% 0.9% 0.7% 1.4% 2.1% 1.4% 0.5% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0%<br />

GOM Yellowtail flounder 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.1% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0%<br />

Table 6: Port Clyde Sector’s Share of Total Commercial Catch by Stock and Fishing Year<br />

Based on VTR Catch Reports<br />

<strong>Groundfish</strong> Stock FY 1996 FY 1997 FY 1998 FY 1999 FY 2000 FY 2001 FY 2002 FY 2003 FY 2004 FY 2005<br />

GOM cod 1.4% 1.3% 1.2% 2.0% 1.9% 1.8% 1.2% 0.6% 0.8% 1.8%<br />

GOM haddock 0.4% 0.3% 0.2% 0.4% 0.6% 2.3% 1.8% 1.4% 1.1% 2.4%<br />

Hake 1.5% 2.1% 1.6% 1.4% 3.3% 2.9% 3.3% 1.7% 2.1% 2.3%<br />

Nor<strong>the</strong>rn Monkfish 2.1% 3.5% 4.0% 3.3% 3.8% 3.7% 3.2% 3.0% 2.9% 2.3%<br />

Plaice 3.3% 4.6% 6.5% 6.5% 6.2% 6.9% 7.5% 7.5% 5.8% 5.8%<br />

Pollock 0.1% 1.1% 0.4% 0.5% 0.5% 0.8% 1.1% 0.6% 0.6% 0.9%<br />

Redfish 0.3% 0.8% 1.0% 1.5% 1.7% 2.2% 2.5% 3.0% 1.9% 2.2%<br />

GOM/GB windowpane 0.0% 0.0% 0.7% 0.0% 9.3% 10.2% 17.3% 4.2% 3.4% 2.4%<br />

GOM winter flounder 1.1% 1.0% 0.6% 3.1% 1.5% 1.6% 0.9% 0.1% 0.2% 0.0%<br />

Witch flounder 6.1% 7.4% 8.1% 7.2% 7.1% 6.6% 4.5% 3.5% 5.4% 4.3%<br />

Cape Cod Yellowtail flounder 0.7% 0.4% 0.5% 0.6% 0.9% 0.6% 0.2% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0%<br />

GOM Yellowtail flounder 0.2% 0.0% 0.0% 0.2% 1.2% 0.2% 0.1% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0%<br />

The catch composition of <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde sector has shifted toward greater reliance on monkfish<br />

and less reliance on cod over this period. In <strong>the</strong> past few years increases in pollock and redfish<br />

catch have offset decreases in plaice. Since sectors allocate a share of TACs, it is probably more<br />

important to look at how <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde sector’s share of overall commercial catch has changed<br />

over time. Comparing <strong>the</strong> early years to <strong>the</strong> later years, <strong>the</strong> sector’s share of haddock catch has<br />

24


increased. They also have caught a larger share of <strong>the</strong> hake and plaice but a smaller share of witch<br />

flounder and winter flounder. These trends are consistent with <strong>the</strong> dealer data and <strong>the</strong> sector<br />

allocations calculated from it <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> 96-01 vs. 01-05 fishing years which were shown in<br />

Table 2.<br />

These long term trends probably reflect changes in <strong>the</strong> distribution of stocks but also regulatory<br />

changes such as rolling closures and trip limits. They also reflect changes in overall stock levels<br />

and commercial catches. There<strong>for</strong>e it is difficult to say how easily <strong>the</strong> sector could adjust to a set<br />

of TACs that reflect older catch history (e.g. 1996-2001). Elimination of DAS limits, trip limits<br />

and rolling closures and would give sector vessels considerably more flexibility to adjust <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

species composition. If sector allocations were <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> earlier years it might require some<br />

spatial or temporal shifting of <strong>the</strong> sector’s ef<strong>for</strong>t. However, since catches <strong>for</strong> most species have<br />

been well below <strong>the</strong> target TACs, <strong>the</strong> sector TACs are likely to allow <strong>the</strong> sector to increase<br />

catches of most stocks without being constrained by TACs of stocks which <strong>the</strong>y caught a smaller<br />

percentage of in <strong>the</strong> allocation years.<br />

Perhaps a more serious problem <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector will be constraining TACs <strong>for</strong> species that are not a<br />

significant part of <strong>the</strong>ir landings history (as recorded in dealer data) and are probably taken<br />

primarily as incidental catch when targeting o<strong>the</strong>r species. For species such as yellowtail<br />

flounder, windowpane flounder and winter flounder, <strong>the</strong> sector will receive very small TACs.<br />

Their landings, while small in absolute magnitude, have been and are likely to continue to be<br />

quite variable in percentage terms over time. The sector may find itself constrained by <strong>the</strong>se<br />

TACs that are of little importance to <strong>the</strong>ir overall profitability unless <strong>the</strong>y can find ways to avoid<br />

<strong>the</strong>m. Again, spatial and temporal shifts in ef<strong>for</strong>t may mitigate this problem, but this may result in<br />

reductions in efficiency if <strong>the</strong> vessels are required to <strong>for</strong>go high catch rates of <strong>the</strong>ir primary target<br />

species in order to avoid <strong>the</strong>se o<strong>the</strong>r stocks. Allowing sectors to trade ACE during <strong>the</strong> fishing<br />

year could be quite beneficial in this case, particularly if <strong>the</strong> distribution of <strong>the</strong>se stocks is shifting<br />

from year to year causing relative catch rates in different areas to change.<br />

3.2 Portland <strong>Community</strong>-<strong>based</strong> <strong>Groundfish</strong> <strong>Sectors</strong><br />

In my initial discussions with fishermen and boat owners in Portland about <strong>the</strong> idea of a<br />

community-<strong>based</strong> sector and sectors in general, <strong>the</strong>re was limited interest in sectors as a<br />

management system and some misconceptions about how <strong>the</strong>y would operate. Most people I<br />

spoke with were skeptical about whe<strong>the</strong>r sectors would deliver economic benefits sufficient to<br />

outweigh <strong>the</strong> costs and risks associated with developing sectors. Most also assumed sectors would<br />

necessarily operate in a way similar to <strong>the</strong> GB Hook sector which sets monthly TACs that are<br />

fished competitively by its members. They had not contemplated an operational plan that<br />

subdivided <strong>the</strong> sector allocation amongst its individual members on <strong>the</strong> basis of <strong>the</strong> catch history<br />

each brought to <strong>the</strong> sector. The idea of setting up an individual allocation system in <strong>the</strong> sector’s<br />

operating plan with trading of ACE allowed between sector members was deemed a more<br />

desirable or acceptable way of operating <strong>the</strong> sector by most of <strong>the</strong> individuals I spoke with who<br />

expressed interest in this <strong>for</strong>m of management.<br />

The motivations <strong>for</strong> considering sectors expressed by permit holders were primarily related to<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir own profitability. While most of <strong>the</strong> individuals did not express great enthusiasm <strong>for</strong> sector<br />

management, many, though not all, also agreed that <strong>the</strong> current system was seriously undermining<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir economic viability and that sectors might offer <strong>the</strong> possibility of improving <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

profitability through greater ability to access stocks <strong>for</strong> which catches are currently well below<br />

25


target TACs or through consolidating catches on fewer plat<strong>for</strong>ms. One of <strong>the</strong> permit holders<br />

noted that <strong>the</strong> ability to trade ACE freely within <strong>the</strong> sector would have substantial advantages<br />

over <strong>the</strong> current DAS leasing provisions since it would eliminate restrictions on trades between<br />

vessels of different sizes which make it difficult <strong>for</strong> large vessels to find DAS to lease.<br />

To develop an understanding of whe<strong>the</strong>r and why <strong>the</strong> surrounding community would be<br />

supportive of a community base groundfish sector, I spoke with officials from <strong>the</strong> City of<br />

Portland and <strong>the</strong> Portland Fish Exchange including: Ellen Sanborn (Assistant Director of Finance<br />

in <strong>the</strong> Portland City Manager’s Office); Judy Harris (Portland Ports and Waterfront); Tom<br />

Valleau (President of <strong>the</strong> Portland Fish Exchange); and Hank Soule (manager of <strong>the</strong> Portland Fish<br />

Exchange). A key concern of all of <strong>the</strong>se individuals is to increase <strong>the</strong> volume of fish handled by<br />

<strong>the</strong> Portland Fish Exchange or to at least keep it from falling. The Fish Exchange, which is owned<br />

by <strong>the</strong> Portland Fish Pier Authority, is currently losing money and needs to maintain a higher<br />

volume in order to remain solvent. The city will subsidize it <strong>for</strong> a while, but it is in danger of<br />

being shut down in <strong>the</strong> near future. Judy Harris also explained that <strong>the</strong> City has explicitly tried to<br />

maintain a diverse economic base and that <strong>the</strong> fishing industry is an important part of that.<br />

Consequently <strong>the</strong> city has <strong>for</strong>gone potentially higher property taxes by restricting development of<br />

<strong>the</strong> waterfront to maintain working waterfront.<br />

Ellen Sanborn explained that <strong>the</strong> city has a strong interest in supporting <strong>the</strong> groundfish fleet in<br />

Portland and keeping <strong>the</strong>m here but is unlikely to expend substantial taxpayer dollars to do so. A<br />

key factor that <strong>the</strong> City would want to get out of <strong>the</strong>ir support <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> industry is keeping enough<br />

fish going through <strong>the</strong> Portland Fish Exchange to keep it solvent. The Fish Exchange can be<br />

subsidized <strong>for</strong> a time by <strong>the</strong> fish pier authority out of revenues generated by services of <strong>the</strong> fish<br />

pier authority. However, that will run out in a year to 18 months and <strong>the</strong> city is unlikely to be<br />

willing to spend tax dollars subsidizing it after that. Ms. Sanborn thought that <strong>the</strong> city would be<br />

happy to subsidize <strong>the</strong> salary of a sector manager if <strong>the</strong> sector was landing all its catch at <strong>the</strong> Fish<br />

Exchange. Keeping <strong>the</strong> volume of landings up at <strong>the</strong> Fish Exchange also results in more business<br />

<strong>for</strong> ancillary service providers (e.g. ice, fuel, supplies, maintenance, etc.). Many of <strong>the</strong>se<br />

businesses are facing difficult times due to <strong>the</strong> decline in <strong>the</strong> number of groundfish boasts fishing<br />

out of Portland and <strong>the</strong> number of days each is fishing.<br />

Determining <strong>the</strong> make-up and structure of a community-<strong>based</strong> sector in Portland is considerably<br />

more difficult than <strong>for</strong> Port Clyde. The Portland fleet is highly heterogeneous in terms of vessel<br />

size, areas fished and ports of landing. There is no Portland or Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Maine groundfish<br />

fishermen’s association that would sponsor a community-<strong>based</strong> sector. Associated Fisheries of<br />

Maine, whose members recently submitted a sector proposal, includes members from<br />

Massachusetts, <strong>New</strong> Hampshire and Rhode Island. Many of its members land much or all of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

catch in ports o<strong>the</strong>r than Portland. A primary interest of Portland officials involved with fishery<br />

issues is to maintain landings in Portland, so <strong>the</strong> case study was conducted <strong>based</strong> on two<br />

hypo<strong>the</strong>tical sectors with membership determined by <strong>the</strong> percentage of <strong>the</strong> vessels’ groundfish<br />

revenues associated with fish landed in Portland in <strong>the</strong> 2005 fishing year. Discussions with <strong>the</strong><br />

proponents of <strong>the</strong> sector proposed by Associated Fisheries of Maine (called <strong>the</strong> “Sustainable<br />

Harvest Sector) were helpful in preparing this analysis and many of <strong>the</strong> vessels that are likely to<br />

join that sector are members of <strong>the</strong> hypo<strong>the</strong>tical sector analyzed here. However, <strong>the</strong> sector<br />

membership used <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> analysis below is quite different from <strong>the</strong> Sustainable Harvest Sector as<br />

it excludes many vessels that do not land <strong>the</strong> majority of <strong>the</strong>ir fish in Portland and includes many<br />

vessels that are not in <strong>the</strong> Sustainable Harvest Sector.<br />

26


3.2.1 Strawman Sector Structure and Operational Plan:<br />

Analysis is done on two hypo<strong>the</strong>tical Portland sectors. Portland Sector A includes all groundfish<br />

vessels with more than 50% of <strong>the</strong>ir groundfish revenues in fishing year 2005 from landings in<br />

Portland. Portland Sector B is a subset of Portland Sector A that includes only groundfish vessels<br />

with more than 90% of <strong>the</strong>ir groundfish revenues in fishing year 2005 coming from landings in<br />

Portland. The hypo<strong>the</strong>tical sectors included only mobile gear vessels. Table 7 shows <strong>the</strong> vessels<br />

included in <strong>the</strong> two hypo<strong>the</strong>tical sectors along with <strong>the</strong> vessel characteristics. Sector A includes<br />

76 permits while Sector B includes only 50. All vessels are mobile gear vessels between 36 and<br />

85 feet in length (Table 7).<br />

A strawman operational structure <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sectors was developed and evaluated through discussion<br />

with a number of groundfish permit owners and vessel operators in Portland including (Maggie<br />

Raymond, Barbara Stevenson, Jimmy Odlin, Bobby Tetrault, Vincent Balzano, and Yvette<br />

Alexander) . . The strawman does not represent a consensus on how <strong>the</strong>se individuals think a sector<br />

should be structured, but is reflective of many of <strong>the</strong> opinions voiced by <strong>the</strong>m. Under this<br />

strawman, <strong>the</strong> sector would receive allocations of all regulated groundfish species it regularly<br />

encounters as well as monkfish. The groundfish stocks <strong>for</strong> which allocations would be requested<br />

include: GB cod, GB haddock, GB winter flounder, GB yellowtail flounder, GOM Cod, GOM<br />

Haddock, GOM/CC winter flounder, GOM/CC yellowtail flounder, GOM/GB windowpane<br />

flounder, American plaice, pollock, Acadian redfish, SNE/MA haddock, SNE/MA winter<br />

flounder, SNE/MA yellowtail flounder, white hake, witch flounder, nor<strong>the</strong>rn monkfish and<br />

sou<strong>the</strong>rn monkfish. As was done <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde case study, <strong>the</strong> analysis of <strong>the</strong> allocation and<br />

economic feasibility of <strong>the</strong> sector is done <strong>based</strong> on sector and overall commercial catches <strong>for</strong> two<br />

different allocation periods: (1) from May 1, 2001 through April 30, 2006, and (2) from May 1,<br />

1996 to April 30, 2002. The shares of total commercial catches landed by vessels in <strong>the</strong> respective<br />

Portland <strong>Sectors</strong> A and B <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>se species <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>se two periods are shown in Table 8. For <strong>the</strong><br />

hypo<strong>the</strong>tical Portland sectors, allocations <strong>based</strong> on fishing years 2001-2005 (relative to 1996-<br />

2001) result in higher sector shares <strong>for</strong> some species but lower shares <strong>for</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rs. As <strong>the</strong> economic<br />

analysis shows, an allocation <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> 2001-05 years results in an overall portfolio of ACE<br />

that is more valuable. It should be noted that <strong>the</strong> current regulations do not allow sectors to<br />

request allocations of monkfish; an amendment to <strong>the</strong> Monkfish FMP will be required to make<br />

this possible.<br />

Each year <strong>the</strong> sector would receive annual catch entitlements (ACE) <strong>for</strong> each species. These ACE<br />

allocations become hard TACs <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> overall sector. The ACE allocated to <strong>the</strong> sector each year<br />

would be equal to <strong>the</strong> shares of <strong>the</strong> overall target TACs shown in Table 8. The total pounds of<br />

ACE would increase or decrease in proportion to increases or decreases in <strong>the</strong> target TACs.<br />

Under <strong>the</strong> strawman operational plan, sector members would be required to retain all legal sized<br />

fish of regulated species <strong>for</strong> which <strong>the</strong> Sector received an allocation of ACE, and all sector<br />

members would be required to stop fishing once total sector catch of any species equaled <strong>the</strong><br />

sector ACE <strong>for</strong> that species.<br />

27


Table 7: List of Vessels Included in Portland Sector Case studies<br />

Vessel Name Length Gross Tons Horsepower Built Sector A Sector B<br />

JENNIFER K 45 38 400 1987 Yes Yes<br />

PRETENDER 38 22 335 1995 Yes Yes<br />

MISTRESS 40 20 220 1972 Yes Yes<br />

SAFE HAVEN 36 8 430 1997 Yes Yes<br />

WEST HEAD 44 19 300 1988 Yes Yes<br />

KELLY SEA 42 24 250 1996 Yes Yes<br />

HANNAH RUTH 37 20 250 1982 Yes Yes<br />

DANNY BOY II 43 13 220 1992 Yes Yes<br />

SHERRIE MARIE 40 11 454 2005 Yes Yes<br />

BARBARA & LYN 38 17 200 1973 Yes Yes<br />

JANIE B 38 17 350 1972 Yes Yes<br />

SUSAN A 38 17 485 1978 Yes Yes<br />

PERSISTENCE 38 17 250 1978 Yes Yes<br />

JEANNE C 36 21 290 1979 Yes Yes<br />

SUSAN AND JESSICA 36 16 210 1979 Yes Yes<br />

PANDORA 37 19 350 1981 Yes Yes<br />

STELLA G 48 30 300 1948 Yes Yes<br />

NORTH STAR 42 25 335 1955 Yes Yes<br />

SIRIUS 50 31 200 1957 Yes Yes<br />

SOLE TRAIN 45 34 525 1977 Yes Yes<br />

CHRISTINA & REBECCA 41 25 400 1982 Yes Yes<br />

HANNAH JO 38 25 400 1982 Yes Yes<br />

MISTY DAWN II 42 24 480 1997 Yes Yes<br />

PAMELA GRACE 40 23 475 2004 Yes Yes<br />

FOXY LADY 45 34 400 1975 Yes Yes<br />

BETHANY JEAN 48 49 365 1979 Yes Yes<br />

DE DEE MAE II 51 47 365 1980 Yes Yes<br />

AVATAR 49 39 275 1980 Yes Yes<br />

ROBERT MICHAEL 54 73 364 1980 Yes Yes<br />

CHERYL K 50 53 365 1980 Yes Yes<br />

DEBORAH ANN 50 44 375 1981 Yes Yes<br />

MAKAIRA 65 52 400 1977 Yes Yes<br />

JULIE D 56 67 402 1978 Yes Yes<br />

TARA LYNN 54 73 350 1979 Yes Yes<br />

LADY DEE 55 61 550 1980 Yes Yes<br />

FLIGHT 1 60 64 350 1982 Yes Yes<br />

THUNDER BAY 56 56 250 1983 Yes Yes<br />

LESLIE ANN 55 56 360 1978 Yes Yes<br />

FIONA A 64 89 580 1981 Yes Yes<br />

ELIZABETH 70 102 400 1985 Yes Yes<br />

TARA LYNN II 54 73 400 1988 Yes Yes<br />

THERESA & ALLYSON 71 99 443 1989 Yes Yes<br />

ADVENTURER 65 99 542 1993 Yes Yes<br />

EDWARD L MOORE 80 159 625 1978 Yes Yes<br />

DRAKE 78 180 575 1980 Yes Yes<br />

TERESA MARIE III 85 192 620 1984 Yes Yes<br />

HARMONY 85 193 1280 1988 Yes Yes<br />

TERESA MARIE IV 81 193 1280 1988 Yes Yes<br />

HARMONY 85 188 850 1999 Yes Yes<br />

TERESA MARIE IV 81 188 850 1999 Yes Yes<br />

RACHEL T 43 5 235 1981 Yes No<br />

HAYLEY ANN 42 14 300 1987 Yes No<br />

MARCIA LEE 36 21 300 1980 Yes No<br />

KATIE & SARAH 42 27 600 1988 Yes No<br />

ETHEL B 48 27 318 1952 Yes No<br />

TERRI & RUTH 48 28 300 1966 Yes No<br />

MISTY MAE 52 30 350 1969 Yes No<br />

MEGALTAY 40 25 250 1979 Yes No<br />

HIGH ROLLER 40 24 320 1981 Yes No<br />

NOVEMBER GALE 45 32 600 1991 Yes No<br />

BAD PENNY 51 51 250 1979 Yes No<br />

BLUE WATER III 56 45 402 1981 Yes No<br />

ANNA LENA IV 56 73 400 1984 Yes No<br />

CELTIC PRIDE 44 44 600 1986 Yes No<br />

CAVALIER 52 56 350 1978 Yes No<br />

JERRY & JOE 49 61 504 1979 Yes No<br />

SARA KATHRYN 50 64 400 1985 Yes No<br />

CHRISTINA CAROL 50 64 280 1985 Yes No<br />

LYDIA & MAYA 71.5 104 700 1967 Yes No<br />

PAULO MARC 63 77 402 1985 Yes No<br />

JAMIE & ASHLEY 65 74 402 1989 Yes No<br />

BLACK BEAUTY 63 105 503 1980 Yes No<br />

CAROLINE M 71 138 500 1980 Yes No<br />

JAMIE LEIGH 70 138 500 1980 Yes No<br />

CAPT'N MARK 69 130 550 1981 Yes No<br />

CAPT'N JAKE 78 127 550 1982 Yes No<br />

28


Table 8: Portland <strong>Sectors</strong> A and B Vessels’ share of landings<br />

<strong>for</strong> two allocation periods FY01-05 and FY96-01<br />

Stock and species<br />

Total FY01-05<br />

Landings<br />

Portland (A)<br />

Sector Share<br />

Portland (B)<br />

Sector Share<br />

Total FY96-01<br />

Landings<br />

Portland (A)<br />

Sector Share<br />

Portland (B)<br />

Sector Share<br />

GB COD 66,166,000 4.6% 3.5% 112,927,645 3.9% 3.3%<br />

GB HADDOCK 66,001,000 8.3% 7.1% 35,687,670 9.0% 7.0%<br />

GB WINTER FLOUNDER 26,960,000 0.6% 0.5% 18,897,799 0.3% 0.2%<br />

GB YELLOWTAIL 39,925,000 0.5% 0.3% 32,548,287 0.4% 0.3%<br />

GOM COD 42,105,000 11.1% 6.9% 56,395,433 12.2% 7.8%<br />

GOM HADDOCK 10,769,000 21.6% 10.5% 10,209,311 33.8% 18.0%<br />

GOM/CC WINTER FLOUNDER 6,072,000 0.3% 0.2% 7,137,377 0.7% 0.5%<br />

GOM/CC YELLOWTAIL 16,218,000 0.3% 0.3% 20,140,336 0.7% 0.5%<br />

GOM/GB WINDOWPANE 274,000 0.0% 0.0% 3,416,338 0.1% 0.1%<br />

PLAICE 27,593,000 30.5% 17.2% 52,992,348 25.9% 14.5%<br />

POLLOCK 52,853,000 26.8% 16.3% 56,561,783 20.2% 12.4%<br />

REDFISH 4,461,000 30.7% 16.3% 4,061,337 28.8% 16.0%<br />

SNE/MA HADDOCK 76,000 4.8% 2.2% 84,641 5.6% 1.7%<br />

SNE/MA WINDOWPANE 633,000 0.0% 0.0% 1,320,000 0.0% 0.0%<br />

SNE/MA WINTER FLOUNDER 25,217,000 0.3% 0.3% 47,371,788 0.1% 0.1%<br />

SNE/MA YELLOWTAIL 4,118,000 0.0% 0.0% 9,954,000 0.0% 0.0%<br />

WHITE HAKE 37,850,000 38.7% 24.3% 38,320,463 27.5% 18.3%<br />

WITCH FLOUNDER 32,599,000 19.9% 11.4% 30,024,873 22.2% 11.1%<br />

NFMA MONKFISH 142,821,000 22.9% 13.3% 147,201,370 18.1% 10.3%<br />

SFMA MONKFISH 102,724,000 1.7% 1.6% 190,073,556 1.9% 1.8%<br />

The sector would not restrict <strong>the</strong> operations of member vessels geographically since some of <strong>the</strong><br />

member vessels have catch histories <strong>for</strong> Georges Bank and Sou<strong>the</strong>rn <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> stocks and are<br />

capable of taking multiday trips to utilize allocations <strong>for</strong> those areas. Because <strong>the</strong> catch of all<br />

managed species would be constrained by hard TACs, <strong>the</strong> sector would request that it be<br />

exempted from o<strong>the</strong>r regulations designed primarily to control fishing mortality. Specifically <strong>the</strong><br />

sector would request to be exempted from: Nor<strong>the</strong>ast Multispecies Days at Sea (DAS) limits,<br />

Monkfish DAS limits 10 , trip limits on cod, yellowtail flounder, winter flounder and white hake,<br />

possession and landing limits on monkfish, <strong>the</strong> May seasonal closure <strong>for</strong> Georges Banks, and<br />

Gulf of Maine rolling closures. The sectors would continue to be subject to <strong>the</strong> same restrictions<br />

on year-round closed areas and gear as o<strong>the</strong>r multispecies vessels. Initially, <strong>the</strong> sector would not<br />

propose any additional restrictions on gear or vessel characteristics beyond current permit<br />

restrictions.<br />

The strawman envisions assigning each permit in <strong>the</strong> sector a specific allocation of <strong>the</strong> overall<br />

allocation of each of <strong>the</strong> species-stocks <strong>for</strong> which <strong>the</strong> Sector receives an allocation. These<br />

individual allocations would be <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> contribution of <strong>the</strong> catch history of <strong>the</strong> permit (i.e.,<br />

its contribution to determining <strong>the</strong> overall sector allocation). Sector members would be free to<br />

utilize <strong>the</strong>se allocations on <strong>the</strong>ir vessels or transfer <strong>the</strong>m to o<strong>the</strong>r vessels within <strong>the</strong> sector upon<br />

notification and approval by <strong>the</strong> sector manager. These allocations would usable only while<br />

operating as part of <strong>the</strong> sector. Should <strong>the</strong>y leave <strong>the</strong> sector or <strong>the</strong> sector not be renewed, <strong>the</strong>se<br />

vessels would again be subject to <strong>the</strong> same ef<strong>for</strong>t controls as <strong>the</strong> rest of <strong>the</strong> multispecies fleet not<br />

enrolled in a sector. The approach of giving individual allocations was nearly universally<br />

supported by <strong>the</strong> individuals I spoke with. However, <strong>the</strong>se individuals, <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> most part have<br />

relatively large individual catch histories. It is possible that <strong>the</strong> sector might settle on some o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

allocation <strong>for</strong>mula. In any case, <strong>the</strong> economic analysis that follows is not explicitly dependent on<br />

<strong>the</strong> assumption though it implicitly assumes that <strong>the</strong>re is no change in overall fixed costs or<br />

average variable costs as a share of revenues.<br />

10 This would require changes to <strong>the</strong> Monkfish FMP<br />

29


3.2.2 Economic Feasibility<br />

The economic feasibility analysis <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Portland <strong>Community</strong>-<strong>based</strong> <strong>Sectors</strong> evaluates whe<strong>the</strong>r<br />

<strong>the</strong> sector could recover <strong>the</strong> costs of establishing and running <strong>the</strong> sector from its members and<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> profitability of <strong>the</strong> sector vessels (after subtracting <strong>the</strong>se costs) is likely to be higher<br />

under sector management than current management. The analysis to address <strong>the</strong>se questions is<br />

identical to that done <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde sector. It entails estimating <strong>the</strong> landings and revenues of<br />

<strong>the</strong> sector, estimating <strong>the</strong> costs of establishing and managing <strong>the</strong> sector, and estimating <strong>the</strong><br />

revenues of sector members without sector management. The relative gains in revenues or net<br />

revenues under sector management are <strong>the</strong>n compared with additional costs of sector<br />

management to calculate <strong>the</strong> net gain to <strong>the</strong> sector participants.<br />

A starting point <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> analysis is to estimate <strong>the</strong> sectors species allocations and <strong>the</strong> projected<br />

sector ACE allocations and revenues. The sector species-stock allocations <strong>based</strong> on two separate<br />

allocation <strong>for</strong>mulas (using 1996-01 or 2001-05 fishing years) are shown above in Table 8.<br />

Revenue projections are <strong>based</strong> on 50 th percentile estimates of F msy TACs and prices shown in<br />

appendix A. <strong>Sectors</strong> landings and revenues are <strong>the</strong>n calculated <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> <strong>Sectors</strong> allocation<br />

shares of each species. The sectors are assumed to catch only 85% of <strong>the</strong>ir ACE allocations. This<br />

85% figure is arbitrary, but leaves a plausible buffer to account <strong>for</strong> discards of undersize or<br />

unmarketable fish and <strong>for</strong> inability to use <strong>the</strong> entire ACE allocation of some species without<br />

exceeding ACE allocations of o<strong>the</strong>rs 11 . In reality <strong>the</strong> sector is likely to land nearly 100% of some<br />

species ACE and less than 85% of o<strong>the</strong>rs; but this is difficult to predict since sector management<br />

is likely to substantially change <strong>the</strong> incentives and fishing patterns of sector members.<br />

Estimating <strong>the</strong> cost of establishing and operating <strong>the</strong> Portland <strong>Community</strong> Sector is difficult<br />

given <strong>the</strong> uncertainty in <strong>the</strong> regulatory process <strong>for</strong> approval and in <strong>the</strong> requirements <strong>for</strong> reporting<br />

and monitoring <strong>the</strong> sector once in operation. The Portland <strong>Sectors</strong> are quite large and may<br />

required developing monitoring systems that accommodates fishing in multiple stock areas and<br />

allows landings in alternative ports. An estimate of $200,000 <strong>for</strong> sector establishment is used <strong>for</strong><br />

this analysis. This is probably somewhat higher than <strong>the</strong> true cost to <strong>the</strong> sector so that profitability<br />

estimates, once <strong>the</strong>se costs are deducted, are conservative relative to this assumption.<br />

The primary ongoing costs <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector are <strong>the</strong> salary <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector manager, administrative<br />

overhead and possibly some legal costs. Since <strong>the</strong> sector will be relatively large and vessels may<br />

be landing in alternative ports, it is likely <strong>the</strong> sector will require a full time manager. The<br />

estimated $150,000 annual operational cost used <strong>for</strong> this analysis would allow <strong>for</strong> $80,000 in<br />

salary to <strong>the</strong> part time sector manager (with no benefits) and an additional $70,000 <strong>for</strong><br />

administrative and legal costs.<br />

Sector revenues are calculated by multiplying projected sector landings by species specific prices.<br />

Sector landings are assumed to attract <strong>the</strong> same prices as <strong>the</strong> overall industry (i.e. <strong>the</strong> demand<br />

model projects prices <strong>based</strong> on overall commercial landings). Prices <strong>for</strong> calculation of revenues<br />

are <strong>based</strong> on demand models described in Appendix B that calculate region-wide prices <strong>based</strong> on<br />

region-wide landings. Price projections are nominal prices (not adjusted <strong>for</strong> inflation). As was<br />

11 The spreadsheet used to make predictions is available, and <strong>the</strong> percentage of ACE used can easily be<br />

adjusted to explore <strong>the</strong> sensitivity of results to this assumption.<br />

30


discussed earlier <strong>the</strong>se price projections are likely conservative since <strong>the</strong>y assume landings equal<br />

overall target TACs.<br />

The expected annual gain in revenues under sector management is estimated by subtracting <strong>the</strong><br />

projected annual revenues without sectors management from projected revenues under sector<br />

management (Table 9a-d). The analysis assumes that, without sector management, <strong>the</strong> sector<br />

members will continue to catch <strong>the</strong> same percentage of <strong>the</strong> different groundfish target TACs that<br />

<strong>the</strong>y caught during <strong>the</strong> 2004 and 2005 fishing years. Estimates are provided <strong>for</strong> both Portland<br />

<strong>Sectors</strong> A and B <strong>based</strong> on two different sector allocation <strong>for</strong>mulas (e.g. FY01-05 and FY96-01<br />

basis years). The annual gain in net revenues <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector is calculated by subtracting from <strong>the</strong><br />

increase in annual gross revenue, <strong>the</strong> variable operating costs (estimated at 38% of <strong>the</strong> increased<br />

gross revenues) 12 , <strong>the</strong> ongoing costs of sector management (assumed to be $150,000), and <strong>the</strong><br />

loan to repay sector establishment costs (assumed to be $200,000). These net gains do not<br />

account <strong>for</strong> additional labor costs associated with landing additional catch (only costs such as<br />

fuel, oil, ice, water and provisions). Thus <strong>the</strong> gains in net revenues represent additional income<br />

that would be divided between boat/permit owners, captains and crew. Presumably this will be on<br />

<strong>the</strong> same basis as normal crew share which may vary from vessel to vessel.<br />

The analysis suggests that sector management can provide substantial gains in net revenues to<br />

sector vessels and that <strong>the</strong>se gains far outweigh <strong>the</strong> costs of establishing and operating a sector.<br />

Sector A is projected to increase net revenues by $4.6 million with <strong>the</strong> FY01-05 allocation and by<br />

$4.2 million with <strong>the</strong> FY96-01 allocation. This assumes sector A vessels pay a landing tax of 1%<br />

on groundfish and monkfish landings. The smaller Sector B is projected to increase net revenues<br />

by $2.8 million with <strong>the</strong> FY01-05 allocation and by $2.0 million with <strong>the</strong> FY96-01 allocation.<br />

This assumes sector vessels pay a landing tax of 1.1% on groundfish and monkfish landings. The<br />

landings tax would be sufficient to cover <strong>the</strong> $150 thousand annual operating cost and to pay off a<br />

$200 thousand loan <strong>for</strong> establishment of <strong>the</strong> sector in 5 or 7 years (depending on allocation<br />

<strong>for</strong>mula) assuming a 7.5% interest rate. The landings tax <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Portland sectors is much smaller<br />

than that required <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde sector simply because of <strong>the</strong> larger size and revenues of <strong>the</strong><br />

sector.<br />

If <strong>the</strong> landings tax was continued indefinitely at 1% <strong>for</strong> Sector A or 1.1% <strong>for</strong> Sector B, <strong>the</strong> sector<br />

entity would begin to build capital which could be used to pay dividends to sector members or to<br />

purchase additional permits. The asset calculations in Tables 9a-d assume that <strong>the</strong> landing tax<br />

surplus and 7.5% interest on assets is simply accumulated by <strong>the</strong> sector entity. Note that <strong>the</strong><br />

column titled interest and management fees becomes negative in later years once interest on <strong>the</strong><br />

sector’s asset base exceeds <strong>the</strong> management costs.<br />

12 The estimate of variable operating costs as a percent of revenue is <strong>based</strong> on observer data collected from<br />

observed trawler trips. For each trip <strong>the</strong> ratio of <strong>the</strong> sum of fuel, oil, food, water, ice, and supplies to <strong>the</strong><br />

revenues generated by <strong>the</strong> trip was calculated. A weighted average of this ratio (weighted by revenue) was<br />

calculated to equal 25% of gross revenues.<br />

31


Table 9a: Portland Sector A Revenues and Gains Over Non Sector Management<br />

Based on FY01-05 Allocation<br />

Fishing<br />

Year Total Revenue tax (1%)<br />

Interest +<br />

Mgmt fees<br />

Outstanding<br />

Loan or<br />

(Assets)<br />

Sector Revenue<br />

Gain (vs. no sector) % Gain<br />

Sector Net<br />

Rev Gain<br />

2008 $ 31,383,441 $ 313,834 $ 165,000 $ 200,000 $ 7,589,188 32% $ 4,586,039<br />

2009 $ 26,591,149 $ 265,911 $ 153,837 $ 51,166 $ 6,234,328 31% $ 3,764,237<br />

2010 $ 26,448,165 $ 264,482 $ 145,432 $ (60,908) $ 6,340,434 32% $ 3,830,566<br />

2011 $ 26,331,126 $ 263,311 $ 136,503 $ (179,958) $ 6,440,786 33% $ 3,893,229<br />

2012 $ 26,510,043 $ 265,100 $ 126,993 $ (306,766) $ 6,601,893 34% $ 3,992,435<br />

2013 $ 26,729,726 $ 267,297 $ 116,634 $ (444,874) $ 6,791,052 35% $ 4,108,879<br />

2014 $ 25,657,896 $ 256,579 $ 105,335 $ (595,537) $ 6,424,111 34% $ 3,885,449<br />

2015 $ 26,194,093 $ 261,941 $ 93,991 $ (746,781) $ 6,475,013 33% $ 3,914,970<br />

2016 $ 26,338,146 $ 263,381 $ 81,395 $ (914,731) $ 6,448,494 33% $ 3,897,981<br />

2017 $ 26,275,099 $ 262,751 $ 67,746 $ (1,096,717) $ 6,393,021 33% $ 3,863,828<br />

2018 $ 26,802,163 $ 268,022 $ 53,121 $ (1,291,722) $ 6,438,592 32% $ 3,890,079<br />

2019 $ 27,270,332 $ 272,703 $ 37,003 $ (1,506,623) $ 6,470,156 32% $ 3,907,870<br />

2020 $ 27,693,093 $ 276,931 $ 19,326 $ (1,742,323) $ 6,498,113 31% $ 3,923,596<br />

2021 $ 28,086,985 $ 280,870 $ 5 $ (1,999,928) $ 6,521,774 31% $ 3,936,769<br />

2022 $ 28,442,046 $ 284,420 $ (21,059) $ (2,280,792) $ 6,543,838 30% $ 3,949,100<br />

2023 $ 28,773,475 $ 287,735 $ (43,970) $ (2,586,272) $ 6,565,512 30% $ 3,961,278<br />

2024 $ 29,059,736 $ 290,597 $ (68,848) $ (2,917,977) $ 6,587,363 30% $ 3,973,738<br />

2025 $ 29,349,121 $ 293,491 $ (95,807) $ (3,277,423) $ 6,608,725 29% $ 3,985,883<br />

2026 $ 29,608,658 $ 296,087 $ (125,004) $ (3,666,721) $ 6,627,289 29% $ 3,996,406<br />

2027 $ 28,932,015 $ 289,320 $ (156,586) $ (4,087,812) $ 6,798,600 31% $ 4,105,190<br />

2028 $ 29,268,842 $ 292,688 $ (190,029) $ (4,533,718) $ 6,801,639 31% $ 4,105,795<br />

2029 $ 29,590,535 $ 295,905 $ (226,233) $ (5,016,435) $ 6,808,265 30% $ 4,108,680<br />

2030 $ 29,885,830 $ 298,858 $ (265,393) $ (5,538,573) $ 6,817,423 30% $ 4,113,236<br />

2031 $ 30,159,199 $ 301,592 $ (307,712) $ (6,102,824) $ 6,828,781 30% $ 4,119,239<br />

2032 $ 30,415,973 $ 304,160 $ (353,410) $ (6,712,128) $ 6,841,292 29% $ 4,126,021<br />

2033 $ 30,660,759 $ 306,608 $ (402,727) $ (7,369,697) $ 6,853,990 29% $ 4,132,963<br />

2034 $ 30,887,427 $ 308,874 $ (455,927) $ (8,079,032) $ 6,867,273 29% $ 4,140,337<br />

2035 $ 31,095,280 $ 310,953 $ (513,288) $ (8,843,834) $ 6,881,036 29% $ 4,148,080<br />

2036 $ 31,290,340 $ 312,903 $ (575,106) $ (9,668,074) $ 6,897,698 29% $ 4,157,669<br />

2037 $ 31,475,344 $ 314,753 $ (641,706) $ (10,556,083) $ 6,912,651 29% $ 4,166,237<br />

32


Table 9b: Portland Sector A Revenues and Gains Over Non Sector Management<br />

Based on FY96-01 Allocation<br />

Fishing<br />

Year Total Revenue tax (1%)<br />

Interest +<br />

Mgmt fees<br />

Outstanding<br />

Loan or<br />

(Assets)<br />

Sector Revenue<br />

Gain (vs. no sector) % Gain<br />

Sector Net<br />

Rev Gain<br />

2008 $ 30,875,740 $ 308,757 $ 15,000 $ 200,000 $ 7,089,026 30% $ 4,277,868<br />

2009 $ 26,087,669 $ 260,877 $ (7,032) $ (93,757) $ 5,738,175 29% $ 3,458,536<br />

2010 $ 25,884,261 $ 258,843 $ (27,125) $ (361,666) $ 5,784,349 29% $ 3,487,936<br />

2011 $ 25,750,612 $ 257,506 $ (48,573) $ (647,633) $ 5,868,143 30% $ 3,540,396<br />

2012 $ 25,936,817 $ 259,368 $ (71,528) $ (953,712) $ 6,036,446 31% $ 3,644,036<br />

2013 $ 26,189,261 $ 261,893 $ (96,346) $ (1,284,609) $ 6,258,022 32% $ 3,780,454<br />

2014 $ 24,998,416 $ 249,984 $ (123,214) $ (1,642,847) $ 5,772,800 30% $ 3,484,142<br />

2015 $ 25,464,925 $ 254,649 $ (151,203) $ (2,016,045) $ 5,754,821 30% $ 3,471,222<br />

2016 $ 25,545,467 $ 255,455 $ (181,642) $ (2,421,897) $ 5,665,514 29% $ 3,415,546<br />

2017 $ 25,420,802 $ 254,208 $ (214,425) $ (2,858,994) $ 5,549,104 28% $ 3,343,845<br />

2018 $ 25,892,617 $ 258,926 $ (249,572) $ (3,327,627) $ 5,540,025 28% $ 3,336,424<br />

2019 $ 26,307,938 $ 263,079 $ (287,709) $ (3,836,125) $ 5,519,305 27% $ 3,321,999<br />

2020 $ 26,682,917 $ 266,829 $ (329,019) $ (4,386,914) $ 5,499,984 26% $ 3,308,595<br />

2021 $ 27,031,841 $ 270,318 $ (373,707) $ (4,982,761) $ 5,479,147 26% $ 3,294,350<br />

2022 $ 27,346,090 $ 273,461 $ (422,009) $ (5,626,787) $ 5,460,824 25% $ 3,281,796<br />

2023 $ 27,638,090 $ 276,381 $ (474,169) $ (6,322,257) $ 5,443,479 25% $ 3,269,932<br />

2024 $ 27,893,379 $ 278,934 $ (530,461) $ (7,072,807) $ 5,434,678 25% $ 3,263,505<br />

2025 $ 28,149,112 $ 281,491 $ (591,165) $ (7,882,201) $ 5,422,737 24% $ 3,255,131<br />

2026 $ 28,378,578 $ 283,786 $ (656,614) $ (8,754,857) $ 5,411,541 24% $ 3,247,317<br />

2027 $ 27,874,964 $ 278,750 $ (727,144) $ (9,695,257) $ 5,754,159 26% $ 3,461,654<br />

2028 $ 28,161,956 $ 281,620 $ (802,586) $ (10,701,151) $ 5,707,871 26% $ 3,431,865<br />

2029 $ 28,438,736 $ 284,387 $ (883,902) $ (11,785,357) $ 5,670,041 25% $ 3,407,358<br />

2030 $ 28,693,742 $ 286,937 $ (971,523) $ (12,953,647) $ 5,639,320 25% $ 3,387,342<br />

2031 $ 28,931,347 $ 289,313 $ (1,065,908) $ (14,212,107) $ 5,615,281 24% $ 3,371,535<br />

2032 $ 29,154,649 $ 291,546 $ (1,167,550) $ (15,567,329) $ 5,594,663 24% $ 3,357,904<br />

2033 $ 29,368,299 $ 293,683 $ (1,276,982) $ (17,026,425) $ 5,576,542 24% $ 3,345,856<br />

2034 $ 29,567,863 $ 295,679 $ (1,394,782) $ (18,597,090) $ 5,562,999 23% $ 3,336,701<br />

2035 $ 29,750,317 $ 297,503 $ (1,521,566) $ (20,287,550) $ 5,551,624 23% $ 3,328,956<br />

2036 $ 29,923,137 $ 299,231 $ (1,657,996) $ (22,106,620) $ 5,546,278 23% $ 3,324,984<br />

2037 $ 30,087,715 $ 300,877 $ (1,804,789) $ (24,063,848) $ 5,541,012 23% $ 3,321,094<br />

33


Table 9c: Portland Sector B Revenues and Gains Over Non Sector Management<br />

Based on FY01-05 Allocation<br />

Fishing<br />

Year Total Revenue tax (1.1%)<br />

Interest +<br />

Mgmt fees<br />

Outstanding<br />

Loan or<br />

(Assets)<br />

Sector Revenue<br />

Gain (vs. no sector) % Gain<br />

Sector Net<br />

Rev Gain<br />

2008 $ 21,837,304 $ 240,210 $ 165,000 $ 200,000 $ 4,665,595 28% $ 2,801,389<br />

2009 $ 18,367,791 $ 202,046 $ 159,359 $ 124,790 $ 3,821,891 27% $ 2,292,795<br />

2010 $ 18,027,334 $ 198,301 $ 156,158 $ 82,103 $ 3,825,353 27% $ 2,296,365<br />

2011 $ 17,696,919 $ 194,666 $ 152,997 $ 39,960 $ 3,819,286 28% $ 2,293,984<br />

2012 $ 17,600,890 $ 193,610 $ 149,872 $ (1,709) $ 3,853,090 28% $ 2,315,344<br />

2013 $ 17,537,657 $ 192,914 $ 146,591 $ (45,447) $ 3,906,107 29% $ 2,348,479<br />

2014 $ 16,814,655 $ 184,961 $ 143,117 $ (91,770) $ 3,674,898 28% $ 2,208,151<br />

2015 $ 17,180,677 $ 188,987 $ 139,979 $ (133,613) $ 3,688,854 28% $ 2,215,274<br />

2016 $ 17,230,829 $ 189,539 $ 136,303 $ (182,622) $ 3,650,367 27% $ 2,191,203<br />

2017 $ 17,116,401 $ 188,280 $ 132,311 $ (235,858) $ 3,591,892 27% $ 2,155,426<br />

2018 $ 17,480,217 $ 192,282 $ 128,113 $ (291,827) $ 3,606,179 26% $ 2,162,764<br />

2019 $ 17,804,372 $ 195,848 $ 123,300 $ (355,997) $ 3,612,817 26% $ 2,165,524<br />

2020 $ 18,096,991 $ 199,067 $ 117,859 $ (428,545) $ 3,618,596 25% $ 2,167,884<br />

2021 $ 18,369,582 $ 202,065 $ 111,769 $ (509,752) $ 3,622,285 25% $ 2,169,032<br />

2022 $ 18,613,490 $ 204,748 $ 104,996 $ (600,049) $ 3,625,903 25% $ 2,170,256<br />

2023 $ 18,840,810 $ 207,249 $ 97,515 $ (699,801) $ 3,629,835 24% $ 2,171,743<br />

2024 $ 19,036,624 $ 209,403 $ 89,285 $ (809,535) $ 3,636,229 24% $ 2,174,889<br />

2025 $ 19,233,330 $ 211,567 $ 80,276 $ (929,653) $ 3,641,277 24% $ 2,177,197<br />

2026 $ 19,409,164 $ 213,501 $ 70,429 $ (1,060,944) $ 3,645,596 23% $ 2,179,139<br />

2027 $ 18,891,861 $ 207,810 $ 59,699 $ (1,204,016) $ 3,800,959 26% $ 2,277,627<br />

2028 $ 19,126,844 $ 210,395 $ 48,590 $ (1,352,127) $ 3,790,758 25% $ 2,270,319<br />

2029 $ 19,349,947 $ 212,849 $ 36,455 $ (1,513,932) $ 3,783,695 25% $ 2,265,008<br />

2030 $ 19,554,936 $ 215,104 $ 23,226 $ (1,690,326) $ 3,779,776 24% $ 2,261,722<br />

2031 $ 19,743,020 $ 217,173 $ 8,835 $ (1,882,205) $ 3,778,126 24% $ 2,259,913<br />

2032 $ 19,919,302 $ 219,112 $ (6,791) $ (2,090,544) $ 3,777,913 24% $ 2,259,043<br />

2033 $ 20,087,126 $ 220,958 $ (23,734) $ (2,316,447) $ 3,778,388 23% $ 2,258,636<br />

2034 $ 20,241,179 $ 222,653 $ (42,085) $ (2,561,139) $ 3,779,977 23% $ 2,258,978<br />

2035 $ 20,381,684 $ 224,199 $ (61,941) $ (2,825,877) $ 3,782,511 23% $ 2,259,962<br />

2036 $ 20,512,418 $ 225,637 $ (83,401) $ (3,112,017) $ 3,787,592 23% $ 2,262,565<br />

2037 $ 20,637,040 $ 227,007 $ (106,579) $ (3,421,054) $ 3,792,185 23% $ 2,264,892<br />

34


Table 9d: Portland Sector B Revenues and Gains Over Non Sector Management<br />

Based on FY96-01 Allocation<br />

Fishing<br />

Year Total Revenue tax (1.1%)<br />

Interest +<br />

Mgmt fees<br />

Outstanding<br />

Loan or<br />

(Assets)<br />

Sector Revenue<br />

Gain (vs. no sector) % Gain<br />

Sector Net<br />

Rev Gain<br />

2008 $ 20,528,643 $ 225,815 $ 165,000 $ 200,000 $ 3,374,027 20% $ 2,006,087<br />

2009 $ 17,272,757 $ 190,000 $ 160,439 $ 139,185 $ 2,741,413 19% $ 1,627,476<br />

2010 $ 17,004,330 $ 187,048 $ 158,222 $ 109,623 $ 2,815,988 20% $ 1,674,835<br />

2011 $ 16,765,080 $ 184,416 $ 156,060 $ 80,798 $ 2,899,955 21% $ 1,727,894<br />

2012 $ 16,754,783 $ 184,303 $ 153,933 $ 52,442 $ 3,018,524 22% $ 1,801,450<br />

2013 $ 16,782,365 $ 184,606 $ 151,655 $ 22,072 $ 3,161,335 24% $ 1,889,877<br />

2014 $ 16,052,667 $ 176,579 $ 149,184 $ (10,879) $ 2,923,003 23% $ 1,745,161<br />

2015 $ 16,389,064 $ 180,280 $ 147,129 $ (38,274) $ 2,907,780 22% $ 1,734,317<br />

2016 $ 16,424,913 $ 180,674 $ 144,643 $ (71,424) $ 2,855,244 21% $ 1,701,595<br />

2017 $ 16,303,439 $ 179,338 $ 141,941 $ (107,455) $ 2,789,872 21% $ 1,661,572<br />

2018 $ 16,638,788 $ 183,027 $ 139,136 $ (144,852) $ 2,776,056 20% $ 1,651,605<br />

2019 $ 16,936,014 $ 186,296 $ 135,844 $ (188,742) $ 2,756,100 20% $ 1,637,990<br />

2020 $ 17,204,147 $ 189,246 $ 132,060 $ (239,194) $ 2,737,690 19% $ 1,625,455<br />

2021 $ 17,453,783 $ 191,992 $ 127,772 $ (296,379) $ 2,718,700 19% $ 1,612,637<br />

2022 $ 17,676,857 $ 194,445 $ 122,955 $ (360,599) $ 2,701,732 18% $ 1,601,184<br />

2023 $ 17,884,244 $ 196,727 $ 117,593 $ (432,090) $ 2,685,966 18% $ 1,590,543<br />

2024 $ 18,064,903 $ 198,714 $ 111,658 $ (511,223) $ 2,677,383 18% $ 1,584,466<br />

2025 $ 18,244,390 $ 200,688 $ 105,129 $ (598,279) $ 2,665,415 17% $ 1,576,296<br />

2026 $ 18,404,864 $ 202,454 $ 97,962 $ (693,838) $ 2,654,554 17% $ 1,568,891<br />

2027 $ 17,954,037 $ 197,494 $ 90,125 $ (798,330) $ 2,875,672 19% $ 1,707,869<br />

2028 $ 18,165,488 $ 199,820 $ 82,073 $ (905,699) $ 2,842,207 19% $ 1,686,237<br />

2029 $ 18,367,145 $ 202,039 $ 73,242 $ (1,023,446) $ 2,813,944 18% $ 1,667,871<br />

2030 $ 18,552,483 $ 204,077 $ 63,582 $ (1,152,243) $ 2,790,597 18% $ 1,652,621<br />

2031 $ 18,723,086 $ 205,954 $ 53,045 $ (1,292,739) $ 2,771,669 18% $ 1,640,173<br />

2032 $ 18,882,796 $ 207,711 $ 41,576 $ (1,445,648) $ 2,755,075 17% $ 1,629,216<br />

2033 $ 19,035,130 $ 209,386 $ 29,116 $ (1,611,783) $ 2,740,237 17% $ 1,619,380<br />

2034 $ 19,175,643 $ 210,932 $ 15,596 $ (1,792,053) $ 2,728,442 17% $ 1,611,480<br />

2035 $ 19,303,505 $ 212,339 $ 946 $ (1,987,389) $ 2,718,480 17% $ 1,604,769<br />

2036 $ 19,422,791 $ 213,651 $ (14,909) $ (2,198,782) $ 2,712,249 16% $ 1,600,407<br />

2037 $ 19,536,888 $ 214,906 $ (32,051) $ (2,427,341) $ 2,706,436 16% $ 1,596,326<br />

35


The projected gains <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector are <strong>based</strong> solely on <strong>the</strong> ability of <strong>the</strong> sector to catch a higher<br />

percentage of <strong>the</strong> target TACs than its members are currently catching as a consequence of<br />

exemptions from DAS restrictions, seasonal closures and trip limits. The sector may achieve<br />

additional gains beyond what is calculated here through higher prices if <strong>the</strong>y are able to improve<br />

quality or make direct marketing arrangement or through consolidation. The analysis implicitly<br />

assumes <strong>the</strong> same vessels are used to harvest <strong>the</strong> fish with or without sector management. Under<br />

sector management, it would be possible to consolidate fishing operations on fewer plat<strong>for</strong>ms if<br />

<strong>the</strong> sector desired. This would be expected to reduce fixed costs which would provide an<br />

additional boost in profitability.<br />

Although <strong>the</strong> projections are shown through <strong>the</strong> year 2027, <strong>the</strong> relative gains of sector vs. nonsector<br />

management are unlikely to continue as projected. Major changes in management of <strong>the</strong><br />

fishery, including ITQs, are being considered which will presumably increase profitability of nonsector<br />

vessels and erode <strong>the</strong> relative benefits of sector to non-sector management. The TAC<br />

projects are also increasingly uncertain in later years. Never<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong> analysis suggests that <strong>the</strong><br />

gains from sector management are sufficiently large to justify <strong>the</strong> difficulty and cost of<br />

establishing a sector even if <strong>the</strong> gains are only realized <strong>for</strong> a few years.<br />

Ano<strong>the</strong>r way to evaluate <strong>the</strong> relative gains from sector management is a retrospective evaluation.<br />

Tables 10a-d show <strong>the</strong> actual catch of <strong>the</strong> Portland sector vessels in fishing years 2004 and 2005<br />

what <strong>the</strong> sector TACs would have been had <strong>the</strong>y been under sector management in those years<br />

(given <strong>the</strong> two different allocation <strong>for</strong>mulas). The potential <strong>for</strong>gone revenue is calculated by<br />

applying <strong>the</strong> actual average species prices <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector vessels in those years by <strong>the</strong> estimated<br />

<strong>for</strong>gone catch. This likely represents an upper bound on what <strong>the</strong> actual <strong>for</strong>gone revenues would<br />

have been since <strong>the</strong> sector would not have been able to land 100% of all TACs. However, it is<br />

clear that <strong>the</strong> potential gains could have been substantial.<br />

Table 10a: Portland Sector A Revenues and Gains Over Non Sector Management<br />

Based on FY01-05 Allocation<br />

04-05 Sector 05-06 Sector<br />

Forgone Forgone Forgone Rev Forgone Rev<br />

Stock and species<br />

TAC TAC 04-05 Catch 05-06 Catch Catch FY04 Catch FY05 FY04 FY05<br />

GB COD 298,693 414,261 383,080 358,836 (84,386) 55,426 $ (119,529) $ 87,978<br />

GOM COD 1,183,295 1,554,630 999,659 1,027,793 183,636 526,837 $ 260,111 $ 836,255<br />

GB HADDOCK 2,749,827 2,258,334 1,558,108 1,813,648 1,191,720 444,686 $ 1,259,499 $ 555,496<br />

GOM HADDOCK 2,302,499 2,256,744 414,373 219,206 1,888,126 2,037,538 $ 1,932,611 $ 2,603,812<br />

GOM WHITE HAKE 3,272,293 3,257,803 3,152,530 2,291,060 119,764 966,743 $ 78,012 $ 935,488<br />

NFMA MONKFISH 8,559,529 6,638,579 6,131,142 5,123,133 2,428,386 1,515,445 $ 1,864,576 $ 1,311,041<br />

SFMA MONKFISH 254,544 363,585 377,247 11,165 (122,703) 352,421 $ (94,214) $ 304,886<br />

GOM PLAICE 2,485,763 2,438,671 1,123,526 852,294 1,362,237 1,586,378 $ 1,696,901 $ 2,406,709<br />

POLLOCK 6,257,529 6,257,529 3,761,752 4,105,547 2,495,777 2,151,982 $ 1,427,279 $ 1,359,413<br />

REDFISH 1,103,555 1,166,441 320,741 387,830 782,814 778,611 $ 426,309 $ 511,218<br />

GB WINTER FLOUNDER 38,652 38,652 7,455 25,006 31,197 13,646 $ 22,881 $ 22,052<br />

GOM/CC WINTER FLOUNDER 18,860 15,118 17,246 20,727 1,614 (5,609) $ 1,184 $ (9,065)<br />

SNE/MA WINTER FLOUNDER 19,255 23,901 1,283 3,197 17,972 20,704 $ 13,181 $ 33,458<br />

GOM WITCH FLOUNDER 2,269,529 3,066,978 1,463,129 1,357,646 806,399 1,709,332 $ 1,108,847 $ 2,681,675<br />

GOM/CC YELLOWTAIL 6,611 9,253 1,083 1,010 5,528 8,242 $ 2,910 $ 8,977<br />

GB YELLOWTAIL 72,459 51,446 24,889 7,325 47,570 44,121 $ 25,043 $ 48,054<br />

Total 30,892,895 29,811,926 19,737,244 17,605,423 11,155,651 12,206,503 $ 9,905,601 $ 13,697,447<br />

36


Table 10b: Portland Sector A Revenues and Gains Over Non Sector Management<br />

Based on FY96-01 Allocation<br />

Stock and species 04-05 Sector 05-06 Sector 04-05 Catch 05-06 Catch Uncaught_04 Uncaught_05 RevGain04 RevGain05<br />

GB COD 255,534 354,403 383,080 358,836 (127,546) (4,433) $ (180,662) $ (7,037)<br />

GOM COD 1,309,269 1,720,137 999,659 1,027,793 309,610 692,344 $ 438,547 $ 1,098,966<br />

GB HADDOCK 2,954,416 2,426,355 1,558,108 1,813,648 1,396,308 612,707 $ 1,475,724 $ 765,385<br />

GOM HADDOCK 3,598,615 3,527,105 414,373 219,206 3,184,242 3,307,899 $ 3,259,265 $ 4,227,232<br />

GOM WHITE HAKE 2,325,526 2,315,228 3,152,530 2,291,060 (827,004) 24,168 $ (538,695) $ 23,386<br />

NFMA MONKFISH 6,773,086 5,253,054 6,131,142 5,123,133 641,944 129,920 $ 492,901 $ 112,397<br />

SFMA MONKFISH 279,445 399,154 377,247 11,165 (97,802) 387,989 $ (75,095) $ 335,657<br />

GOM PLAICE 2,105,912 2,066,017 1,123,526 852,294 982,386 1,213,723 $ 1,223,731 $ 1,841,351<br />

POLLOCK 4,713,618 4,713,618 3,761,752 4,105,547 951,866 608,071 $ 544,351 $ 384,120<br />

REDFISH 1,036,366 1,095,424 320,741 387,830 715,625 707,594 $ 389,719 $ 464,590<br />

GB WINTER FLOUNDER 20,145 20,145 7,455 25,006 12,690 (4,861) $ 9,307 $ (7,856)<br />

GOM/CC WINTER FLOUNDER 52,457 42,049 17,246 20,727 35,211 21,321 $ 25,824 $ 34,456<br />

SNE/MA WINTER FLOUNDER 7,272 9,026 1,283 3,197 5,988 5,829 $ 4,392 $ 9,419<br />

GOM WITCH FLOUNDER 2,533,677 3,423,941 1,463,129 1,357,646 1,070,548 2,066,296 $ 1,472,068 $ 3,241,695<br />

GOM/CC YELLOWTAIL 13,242 18,533 1,083 1,010 12,159 17,523 $ 6,401 $ 19,085<br />

GB YELLOWTAIL 57,958 41,150 24,889 7,325 33,068 33,825 $ 17,409 $ 36,840<br />

Total 28,036,538 27,425,337 19,737,244 17,605,423 8,299,294 9,819,913 $ 8,565,186 $ 12,579,686<br />

Table 10c: Portland Sector B Revenues and Gains Over Non Sector Management<br />

Based on FY01-05 Allocation<br />

04-05 Sector 05-06 Sector<br />

Forgone Forgone Forgone Rev Forgone Rev<br />

Stock and species<br />

TAC TAC 04-05 Catch 05-06 Catch Catch FY04 Catch FY05 FY04 FY05<br />

GB COD 225,652 312,960 285,188 297,916 (59,536) 15,044 $ (83,566) $ 24,017<br />

GOM COD 734,956 965,596 652,065 658,105 82,892 307,492 $ 116,349 $ 490,913<br />

GB HADDOCK 2,336,256 1,918,683 1,502,291 1,464,477 833,965 454,206 $ 847,809 $ 573,344<br />

GOM HADDOCK 1,120,927 1,098,653 188,692 107,659 932,235 990,993 $ 947,711 $ 1,250,931<br />

GOM WHITE HAKE 2,058,712 2,049,596 1,922,890 1,293,315 135,823 756,281 $ 87,547 $ 728,402<br />

NFMA MONKFISH 4,985,628 3,866,741 3,354,877 2,727,710 1,630,751 1,139,032 $ 1,267,706 $ 981,740<br />

SFMA MONKFISH 235,721 336,700 333,068 6,004 (97,347) 330,696 $ (75,675) $ 285,029<br />

GOM PLAICE 1,397,439 1,370,965 661,763 463,672 735,676 907,293 $ 897,903 $ 1,388,125<br />

POLLOCK 3,792,102 3,792,102 2,306,354 2,338,242 1,485,748 1,453,860 $ 818,641 $ 895,314<br />

REDFISH 586,971 620,420 169,933 200,285 417,038 420,135 $ 226,352 $ 293,267<br />

GB WINTER FLOUNDER 31,839 31,839 3,594 19,653 28,245 12,186 $ 20,890 $ 19,846<br />

GOM/CC WINTER FLOUNDER 12,716 10,193 10,824 18,633 1,893 (8,440) $ 1,400 $ (13,745)<br />

SNE/MA WINTER FLOUNDER 16,712 20,744 1,005 2,936 15,707 17,809 $ 11,617 $ 29,003<br />

WITCH FLOUNDER 1,303,545 1,761,574 857,422 756,448 446,123 1,005,126 $ 614,312 $ 1,608,550<br />

GOM/CC YELLOWTAIL 5,519 7,724 1,104 892 4,415 6,831 $ 2,316 $ 7,286<br />

GB YELLOWTAIL 36,076 25,614 20,009 5,829 16,067 19,785 $ 8,427 $ 21,101<br />

Total 18,880,774 18,190,104 12,271,079 10,361,776 6,609,695 7,828,328 $ 5,709,740 $ 8,583,123<br />

Table 10d: Portland Sector B Revenues and Gains Over Non Sector Management<br />

Based on FY96-01 Allocation<br />

Stock and species 04-05 Sector 05-06 Sector 04-05 Catch 05-06 Catch Uncaught_04 Uncaught_05 RevGain04 RevGain05<br />

GB COD 212,256 294,381 285,188 297,916 (72,932) (3,536) $ (102,370) $ (5,645)<br />

GOM COD 830,391 1,090,980 652,065 658,105 178,326 432,875 $ 250,305 $ 691,089<br />

GB HADDOCK 2,312,823 1,899,438 1,502,291 1,464,477 810,531 434,961 $ 823,987 $ 549,051<br />

GOM HADDOCK 1,913,578 1,875,552 188,692 107,659 1,724,886 1,767,893 $ 1,753,520 $ 2,231,611<br />

GOM WHITE HAKE 1,547,399 1,540,547 1,922,890 1,293,315 (375,491) 247,232 $ (242,029) $ 238,118<br />

NFMA MONKFISH 3,843,546 2,980,968 3,354,877 2,727,710 488,669 253,258 $ 379,879 $ 218,285<br />

SFMA MONKFISH 275,461 393,463 333,068 6,004 (57,607) 387,459 $ (44,782) $ 333,954<br />

GOM PLAICE 1,180,306 1,157,946 661,763 463,672 518,543 694,274 $ 632,889 $ 1,062,213<br />

POLLOCK 2,881,774 2,881,774 2,306,354 2,338,242 575,420 543,532 $ 317,054 $ 334,717<br />

REDFISH 575,160 607,936 169,933 200,285 405,227 407,651 $ 219,941 $ 284,552<br />

GB WINTER FLOUNDER 15,021 15,021 3,594 19,653 11,427 (4,632) $ 8,451 $ (7,544)<br />

GOM/CC WINTER FLOUNDER 37,960 30,428 10,824 18,633 27,137 11,795 $ 20,071 $ 19,210<br />

SNE/MA WINTER FLOUNDER 7,270 9,024 1,005 2,936 6,265 6,089 $ 4,634 $ 9,916<br />

GOM WITCH FLOUNDER 1,265,791 1,710,555 857,422 756,448 408,369 954,107 $ 562,325 $ 1,526,901<br />

GOM/CC YELLOWTAIL 10,166 14,228 1,104 892 9,062 13,336 $ 4,753 $ 14,222<br />

GB YELLOWTAIL 41,425 29,412 20,009 5,829 21,417 23,583 $ 11,233 $ 25,152<br />

Total 16,950,329 16,531,652 12,271,079 10,361,776 4,679,250 6,169,876 $ 4,599,861 $ 7,525,804<br />

37


3.2.3 Matching Catch to ACE<br />

A frequently expressed concern of many fishermen regarding sector management as well as<br />

individual quota systems is that <strong>the</strong>y have limited control over <strong>the</strong> species composition of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

catch and may be unable to match <strong>the</strong>ir catches to <strong>the</strong>ir allocations. The Portland sectors are much<br />

larger than <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde sector and have member vessels that are highly mobile. There<strong>for</strong>e <strong>the</strong>y<br />

may have more ability to change catch composition through spatial and temporal shifts of ef<strong>for</strong>t.<br />

Tables 11a and 11b show how <strong>the</strong> catch by species/stock of Portland <strong>based</strong> sector vessels’ in<br />

<strong>Sectors</strong> A and B have changed over time as a percentage of <strong>the</strong>ir total catch. Tables 12a and 12b<br />

shows how <strong>the</strong> Portland sector vessels’ catch as a percentage of total commercial catch has<br />

changed over time. These percentages are <strong>based</strong> solely on vessel trip report data which, as noted<br />

in <strong>the</strong> discussion <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde sectors, may be quite inaccurate or at least quite different<br />

from <strong>the</strong> dealer data on which sector allocations are <strong>based</strong>. This is particularly true <strong>for</strong> species<br />

such as monkfish that are often landed only as tails. It should also be noted that <strong>the</strong> catches of<br />

windowpane flounder in <strong>the</strong> VTR data are higher than those reported in <strong>the</strong> dealer data. As was<br />

true <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde sector, <strong>the</strong> allocations to <strong>the</strong> sector, <strong>based</strong> on dealer data, provide virtually<br />

no allocation of windowpane flounder to <strong>the</strong> sectors, yet <strong>the</strong> VTR data suggests that <strong>the</strong> sectors<br />

accounts of a relatively large share of windowpane catch, particularly in fishing years 2000-2002.<br />

Never<strong>the</strong>less <strong>the</strong>se tables offer some indication of <strong>the</strong> relative variability over time of <strong>the</strong> sector<br />

vessels species composition and its catch relative to <strong>the</strong> total commercial catch.<br />

Table 11a: Portland Sector A’s Species/stock Composition of Catch as a Percentage of <strong>the</strong><br />

Sector’s Total <strong>Groundfish</strong> Catch by Fishing Year<br />

<strong>Groundfish</strong> Stock FY 1996 FY 1997 FY 1998 FY 1999 FY 2000 FY 2001 FY 2002 FY 2003 FY 2004 FY 2005<br />

GB cod 3.1% 4.2% 7.1% 7.3% 4.9% 6.7% 4.3% 4.9% 2.5% 2.7%<br />

GOM cod 20.4% 13.9% 7.1% 4.5% 6.0% 6.1% 6.1% 6.8% 6.6% 7.7%<br />

GB haddock 0.4% 2.2% 3.1% 6.9% 6.5% 5.7% 4.6% 6.1% 10.3% 15.0%<br />

GOM haddock 1.1% 5.1% 6.9% 4.1% 4.8% 5.2% 3.7% 3.5% 2.7% 1.8%<br />

Hake 9.2% 7.3% 4.3% 5.4% 6.0% 7.2% 10.0% 12.2% 11.3% 7.5%<br />

Nor<strong>the</strong>rn Monkfish 12.2% 11.8% 11.0% 17.8% 17.1% 19.6% 24.4% 19.8% 17.2% 14.6%<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Monkfish 8.8% 4.8% 5.0% 4.5% 3.4% 3.2% 2.0% 1.7% 1.1% 0.0%<br />

Plaice 20.5% 17.9% 19.2% 18.7% 24.8% 20.4% 16.6% 12.2% 8.8% 7.3%<br />

Pollock 11.7% 20.2% 22.3% 15.5% 13.1% 11.3% 15.4% 18.6% 24.2% 28.5%<br />

Redfish 1.1% 1.2% 2.9% 2.0% 1.4% 1.8% 1.2% 1.8% 2.2% 3.0%<br />

GOM/GB windowpane 0.1% 0.2% 0.4% 0.1% 0.5% 0.7% 0.6% 0.4% 0.1% 0.0%<br />

GB winter flounder 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.3% 0.5% 0.1% 0.4%<br />

GOM winter flounder 0.5% 0.2% 0.3% 0.2% 0.5% 0.5% 0.3% 0.2% 0.2% 0.3%<br />

SNE winter flounder 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.1% 0.0% 0.3% 0.0% 0.1% 0.0% 0.0%<br />

Witch flounder 10.3% 10.6% 10.2% 12.1% 10.3% 10.4% 9.5% 10.6% 12.4% 11.0%<br />

Cape Cod Yellowtail flounder 0.2% 0.1% 0.0% 0.1% 0.2% 0.2% 0.1% 0.1% 0.0% 0.0%<br />

GOM Yellowtail flounder 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.0% 0.1% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0%<br />

GB Yellowtail flounder 0.0% 0.1% 0.1% 0.2% 0.3% 0.3% 0.8% 0.4% 0.2% 0.1%<br />

38


Table 11b: Portland Sector B Species/stock Composition of Catch as a Percentage of <strong>the</strong> Sector’s<br />

Total <strong>Groundfish</strong> Catch by Fishing Year<br />

<strong>Groundfish</strong> Stock FY 1996 FY 1997 FY 1998 FY 1999 FY 2000 FY 2001 FY 2002 FY 2003 FY 2004 FY 2005<br />

GB cod 4.4% 5.8% 9.7% 10.0% 6.0% 8.4% 4.5% 5.6% 2.9% 3.6%<br />

GOM cod 22.0% 14.7% 7.6% 4.2% 5.8% 5.4% 6.1% 6.5% 6.6% 7.9%<br />

GB haddock 0.5% 3.2% 3.9% 8.2% 7.6% 7.4% 5.6% 7.2% 14.7% 19.4%<br />

GOM haddock 1.3% 4.5% 6.1% 2.9% 4.7% 3.6% 3.3% 2.8% 1.8% 1.4%<br />

Hake 9.1% 6.9% 5.5% 5.6% 7.0% 9.1% 12.8% 16.0% 13.5% 8.8%<br />

Nor<strong>the</strong>rn Monkfish 10.4% 11.3% 10.3% 15.7% 15.4% 18.9% 23.6% 18.0% 15.2% 12.2%<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Monkfish 14.2% 7.6% 8.0% 6.8% 5.3% 4.9% 3.0% 2.4% 1.5% 0.0%<br />

Plaice 18.0% 15.7% 16.2% 16.2% 22.7% 18.0% 14.8% 10.2% 7.6% 6.1%<br />

Pollock 11.6% 20.0% 21.5% 16.3% 14.3% 11.8% 14.6% 18.0% 23.1% 27.0%<br />

Redfish 1.1% 1.1% 2.1% 2.2% 1.4% 1.4% 1.1% 1.7% 1.9% 2.6%<br />

GOM/GB windowpane 0.0% 0.3% 0.3% 0.1% 0.2% 0.3% 0.2% 0.1% 0.1% 0.0%<br />

GB winter flounder 0.0% 0.0% 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.2% 0.5% 0.6% 0.1% 0.5%<br />

GOM winter flounder 0.4% 0.1% 0.3% 0.3% 0.7% 0.6% 0.4% 0.2% 0.2% 0.4%<br />

SNE winter flounder 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.1% 0.1% 0.5% 0.0% 0.2% 0.0% 0.1%<br />

Witch flounder 6.6% 8.4% 7.8% 10.4% 8.1% 8.8% 8.8% 9.8% 10.6% 9.8%<br />

Cape Cod Yellowtail flounder 0.4% 0.1% 0.1% 0.2% 0.3% 0.3% 0.1% 0.1% 0.0% 0.0%<br />

GOM Yellowtail flounder 0.1% 0.1% 0.1% 0.0% 0.1% 0.0% 0.1% 0.0% 0.0% 0.0%<br />

GB Yellowtail flounder 0.0% 0.1% 0.2% 0.3% 0.3% 0.3% 0.3% 0.5% 0.2% 0.1%<br />

total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 99.7% 100.0% 99.8% 99.9% 100.0% 99.9% 100.0%<br />

Table 12a: Portland Sector A’s Share of Total Commercial Catch by Stock and Fishing Year<br />

Based on VTR Catch Reports<br />

<strong>Groundfish</strong> Stock FY 1996 FY 1997 FY 1998 FY 1999 FY 2000 FY 2001 FY 2002 FY 2003 FY 2004 FY 2005<br />

GB cod 2.2% 3.0% 4.9% 4.6% 3.8% 4.6% 3.3% 5.4% 6.4% 7.1%<br />

GOM cod 13.7% 13.9% 12.2% 17.0% 11.9% 10.5% 10.9% 11.7% 12.9% 15.0%<br />

GB haddock 4.3% 8.0% 8.3% 9.0% 10.1% 7.8% 3.9% 5.7% 9.7% 15.7%<br />

GOM haddock 17.6% 35.9% 39.2% 35.9% 41.3% 30.4% 24.2% 19.2% 20.6% 16.6%<br />

Hake 17.6% 18.6% 13.9% 21.8% 28.3% 28.3% 29.5% 26.7% 39.7% 31.8%<br />

Nor<strong>the</strong>rn Monkfish 13.3% 18.0% 16.7% 16.2% 15.5% 17.7% 19.2% 18.6% 21.3% 18.9%<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Monkfish 6.9% 4.2% 3.5% 3.2% 5.4% 3.6% 2.3% 1.2% 1.8% 0.0%<br />

Plaice 18.9% 20.9% 24.5% 24.9% 31.5% 29.6% 29.5% 27.8% 31.1% 28.2%<br />

Pollock 16.6% 20.0% 20.7% 20.1% 22.8% 19.4% 24.8% 22.9% 30.7% 29.0%<br />

Redfish 15.5% 23.4% 37.4% 30.2% 26.4% 26.5% 21.9% 24.0% 27.8% 29.1%<br />

GOM/GB windowpane 0.6% 1.8% 9.5% 2.0% 25.7% 62.7% 38.1% 27.6% 11.7% 5.2%<br />

GB winter flounder 0.0% 0.0% 0.2% 0.4% 0.4% 0.6% 0.8% 0.8% 0.2% 0.8%<br />

GOM winter flounder 3.8% 1.5% 3.2% 2.8% 4.6% 4.0% 1.9% 1.3% 2.2% 4.9%<br />

SNE winter flounder 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.1% 0.1% 0.4% 0.1% 0.3% 0.1% 0.2%<br />

Witch flounder 20.8% 25.0% 24.4% 23.5% 22.1% 20.5% 17.0% 16.5% 24.8% 21.8%<br />

Cape Cod Yellowtail flounder 0.9% 0.2% 0.2% 0.4% 0.5% 0.5% 0.1% 0.2% 0.0% 0.1%<br />

GOM Yellowtail flounder 4.7% 5.7% 8.5% 7.7% 3.8% 2.4% 3.8% 0.3% 0.3% 0.6%<br />

GB Yellowtail flounder 0.0% 0.4% 0.3% 0.3% 0.5% 0.5% 1.6% 0.7% 0.2% 0.1%<br />

Table 12b: Portland Sector B’s Share of Total Commercial Catch by Stock and Fishing Year<br />

Based on VTR Catch Reports<br />

<strong>Groundfish</strong> Stock FY 1996 FY 1997 FY 1998 FY 1999 FY 2000 FY 2001 FY 2002 FY 2003 FY 2004 FY 2005<br />

GB cod 1.9% 2.6% 4.2% 4.1% 3.0% 3.7% 2.2% 4.1% 4.8% 6.2%<br />

GOM cod 9.2% 9.4% 8.2% 10.7% 7.4% 6.0% 6.9% 7.5% 8.5% 10.2%<br />

GB haddock 3.2% 7.2% 6.5% 7.0% 7.6% 6.4% 3.0% 4.5% 9.2% 13.6%<br />

GOM haddock 12.5% 20.4% 21.8% 17.0% 25.6% 13.3% 13.5% 10.3% 9.2% 8.7%<br />

Hake 10.9% 11.3% 11.1% 15.0% 21.1% 22.8% 24.0% 23.5% 31.6% 24.9%<br />

Nor<strong>the</strong>rn Monkfish 7.1% 11.1% 9.7% 9.5% 8.9% 10.9% 11.7% 11.3% 12.5% 10.5%<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Monkfish 6.9% 4.2% 3.4% 3.2% 5.4% 3.5% 2.2% 1.2% 1.7% 0.0%<br />

Plaice 10.4% 11.7% 12.9% 14.3% 18.4% 16.7% 16.7% 15.5% 17.9% 15.8%<br />

Pollock 10.2% 12.6% 12.5% 14.0% 16.0% 12.9% 14.9% 14.9% 19.3% 18.3%<br />

Redfish 9.6% 14.2% 16.7% 20.9% 17.1% 13.2% 12.3% 16.0% 15.4% 17.1%<br />

GOM/GB windowpane 0.1% 1.6% 5.4% 1.5% 5.1% 19.2% 6.1% 7.6% 5.8% 2.8%<br />

GB winter flounder 0.0% 0.0% 0.2% 0.3% 0.3% 0.4% 0.7% 0.7% 0.1% 0.7%<br />

GOM winter flounder 1.9% 0.5% 2.2% 2.0% 4.0% 3.5% 1.8% 1.1% 1.7% 4.8%<br />

SNE winter flounder 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.1% 0.1% 0.4% 0.1% 0.3% 0.1% 0.2%<br />

Witch flounder 8.4% 12.7% 11.6% 13.3% 11.1% 11.1% 10.0% 10.3% 14.0% 13.0%<br />

Cape Cod Yellowtail flounder 0.9% 0.2% 0.2% 0.4% 0.5% 0.5% 0.1% 0.2% 0.0% 0.1%<br />

GOM Yellowtail flounder 3.1% 4.6% 5.9% 1.7% 2.3% 1.3% 3.7% 0.1% 0.2% 0.6%<br />

GB Yellowtail flounder 0.0% 0.3% 0.3% 0.3% 0.3% 0.3% 0.4% 0.6% 0.1% 0.1%<br />

39


Although plaice, as a percentage of <strong>the</strong> sectors’ groundfish catch has declined over this period,<br />

<strong>the</strong> sector’s share of total commercial plaice landing has increased. The catch composition of <strong>the</strong><br />

Portland sectors has shifted toward greater reliance on monkfish, pollock, hake, and, in recent<br />

years, haddock. The sectors became less reliant on GOM cod and plaice as a percentage of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

catch.<br />

Since sectors allocate a share of TACs, it is probably more important to look at how <strong>the</strong> sector’s<br />

share of overall commercial catch has changed over time. Comparing <strong>the</strong> early years to <strong>the</strong> later<br />

years, <strong>the</strong> sector’s shares of plaice, pollock, hake, Nor<strong>the</strong>rn monkfish and GB cod have increased<br />

while <strong>the</strong>ir shares of GOM cod and GOM haddock have declined. The share of witch flounder <strong>for</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> larger Sector A has also declined somewhat. These trends are consistent with <strong>the</strong> dealer data<br />

and <strong>the</strong> sector allocations calculated from it <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> 96-01 vs. 01-05 fishing years which<br />

were shown in Table 8.<br />

As was true <strong>for</strong> Port Clyde vessels, <strong>the</strong>se long term trends reflect changes in <strong>the</strong> distribution of<br />

stocks but also regulatory changes such as rolling closures and trip limits. They also reflect<br />

changes in overall stock levels and commercial catches. In <strong>the</strong> case of <strong>the</strong> Portland sectors which<br />

include several large vessels, <strong>the</strong> trends also probably reflect changes in where vessels have been<br />

fishing. There<strong>for</strong>e it is difficult to say how easily <strong>the</strong> sector could adjust to a set of TACs that<br />

reflect older catch history (e.g. 1996-2001). Elimination of DAS limits, trip limits and rolling<br />

closures will give <strong>the</strong>m considerably more flexibility to adjust <strong>the</strong>ir species composition. Since<br />

catches <strong>for</strong> most species have been well below <strong>the</strong> target TACs, <strong>the</strong> sector TACs are likely to<br />

allow <strong>the</strong> sector to increase catches of most stocks without being constrained by TACs of stocks<br />

which <strong>the</strong>y caught a smaller percentage of in <strong>the</strong> allocation years.<br />

As was <strong>the</strong> case <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Port Clyde sector, a more serious problem <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector may be<br />

constraining catches of species that are not a significant part of <strong>the</strong>ir landings history (as recorded<br />

in dealer data) and are probably taken primarily as incidental catch when targeting o<strong>the</strong>r species.<br />

For species such as yellowtail flounder, windowpane flounder and winter flounder, <strong>the</strong> sector will<br />

receive very small TACs. Their landings, while small in absolute magnitude, have been and are<br />

likely to continue to be quite variable in percentage terms over time. The sector may find itself<br />

constrained by <strong>the</strong>se TACs that are of little importance to <strong>the</strong>ir overall profitability unless <strong>the</strong>y<br />

can find ways to avoid <strong>the</strong>m. Again, spatial and temporal shifts in ef<strong>for</strong>t may mitigate this<br />

problem, but this may result in reductions in efficiency if <strong>the</strong> vessels are required to <strong>for</strong>go high<br />

catch rates of <strong>the</strong>ir primary target species in order to avoid <strong>the</strong>se o<strong>the</strong>r stocks. Allowing sectors to<br />

trade ACE during <strong>the</strong> fishing year could be quite beneficial in this case, particularly if <strong>the</strong><br />

distribution of <strong>the</strong>se stocks is shifting from year to year causing relative catch rates in different<br />

areas to change.<br />

3.3 Permit Bank<br />

A means <strong>for</strong> communities interested in maintaining or regaining access to <strong>the</strong> groundfish fishery<br />

is to create a permit bank affiliated with a sector. The permit bank would potentially be set up as a<br />

cooperative with ownership and voting shares owned by sector members and perhaps <strong>the</strong> town or<br />

city or some o<strong>the</strong>r entity (e.g. <strong>the</strong> Portland Fish Pier Authority in <strong>the</strong> case of a Portland permit<br />

bank). The cooperative would purchase permits and <strong>the</strong> associated catch history, transfer <strong>the</strong><br />

permits to skiffs if necessary, and <strong>the</strong>n include <strong>the</strong>se permits and catch history in <strong>the</strong> community<strong>based</strong><br />

sector. The share of <strong>the</strong> sector’s annual ACE allocation contributed by <strong>the</strong> permit bank<br />

40


vessels would be leased to sector vessels at rates sufficient to pay back loans incurred <strong>for</strong><br />

purchasing <strong>the</strong> permits. Once loans were paid back, <strong>the</strong> permit bank might continue to charge a<br />

fee <strong>for</strong> access to this ACE and use <strong>the</strong> revenues to acquire more permits or o<strong>the</strong>r investments in<br />

<strong>the</strong> interest of <strong>the</strong> fishing community and <strong>the</strong> sector members. The permit bank might also use<br />

<strong>the</strong>se revenues to purchase permits of sector members that wished to retire. It could create an<br />

apprentice program that would provide young fishermen access to <strong>the</strong> fishery through access to<br />

<strong>the</strong> ACE controlled by <strong>the</strong> permit bank.<br />

There do not appear to be regulations that would explicitly allow or prohibit a cooperative from<br />

owning a set of permits and including <strong>the</strong>m in a sector toge<strong>the</strong>r with privately owned permits.<br />

However, it would be important to get a definitive ruling on <strong>the</strong> legality of this be<strong>for</strong>e making any<br />

investments.<br />

3.3.1 Financing a Permit Bank<br />

There are a variety of ways that a permit bank might be financed. The most straight <strong>for</strong>ward way<br />

would be through a loan from a commercial bank or from a cooperative bank such as Farm<br />

Credit. I spoke with a number of loan officers from Farm Credit in Maine and from TD<br />

Banknorth in Maine and Massachusetts to determine issues associated with acquiring a<br />

commercial loan and <strong>the</strong> likely requirements and terms of such a loan. The responses from both<br />

financial institutions were similar and are described below.<br />

Tim Kelleher of TD Banknorth explained that, when considering loans <strong>for</strong> fishing boats and<br />

permits, <strong>the</strong> personal relationship and personal history of <strong>the</strong> borrower are key. They are lending<br />

to a businessman is <strong>based</strong> on his success in <strong>the</strong> past. It is difficult to project cash flow or to factor<br />

in regulatory risk associated with a groundfish permit, and <strong>the</strong> resale value of <strong>the</strong> permit is<br />

unclear. There<strong>for</strong>e <strong>the</strong> track history of <strong>the</strong> businessmen responsible <strong>for</strong> paying back <strong>the</strong> loan is<br />

highly important. In <strong>the</strong> past, <strong>the</strong> bank would often require onshore collateral (e.g. <strong>the</strong> person’s<br />

house) <strong>for</strong> loan on vessels, but <strong>the</strong>re is less of that now.<br />

Typical terms <strong>for</strong> purchase of a fishing boat and permit are 25% down with a payout over 7-12<br />

years. Valuing permits is difficult but auditors have to agree with estimates. Typically <strong>the</strong>re might<br />

be a fixed interest rate <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> first five years at about 2.5% to 2.75% over <strong>the</strong> cost of funds. Cost<br />

of funds is <strong>the</strong> federal home loan bank rate which is around 5% now so <strong>the</strong> interest rate on <strong>the</strong><br />

loan is likely to be in <strong>the</strong> neighborhood of 7.5% to 8.5%. If loan guarantees were available, it<br />

would not greatly affect lending rates but would affect <strong>the</strong> bank’s decision to lend and might<br />

increase <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>the</strong>y could lend relative to <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong> asset. While loan guarantees<br />

mitigate risk of default <strong>the</strong>y do not affect loan servicing costs and <strong>the</strong>se could be higher <strong>for</strong> more<br />

problematic loans.<br />

I also met with Dick Robertson who is Executive Vice President and Chief Credit Officer <strong>for</strong><br />

Farm Credit of Maine as well as Rob Horne who is Vice President, Commercial Lending Coastal<br />

and Interior Region, and Fred Morton, who is Senior Vice President, Corporate Lending. Farm<br />

Credit of Maine is a federally-chartered cooperatively-owned lending institution — owned and<br />

directed by Maine business owners. Farm Credit of Maine is part of <strong>the</strong> national Farm Credit<br />

system, a $125 billion nationwide network of cooperative banking institutions making loans <strong>for</strong><br />

food and fiber businesses since 1916. Farm Credit sells bonds on <strong>the</strong> money market to finance<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir loans. Farm Credit of Maine used to have a large portfolio of groundfish boat loans but are<br />

now down to 12-15 owners (some with multiple boats). Farm Credit of Maine generally makes<br />

41


loans involving boats and permits. Only recently have <strong>the</strong>y begun to put separate values on <strong>the</strong><br />

hull and <strong>the</strong> permit. They have been making some loans on permits alone, but generally with<br />

customers with whom <strong>the</strong>y already have a relationship and o<strong>the</strong>r loans. They noted that <strong>the</strong>re is a<br />

lack of case law that clarifies whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y can take and sell a permit in <strong>the</strong> case of a loan default.<br />

This makes it difficult to use <strong>the</strong> permit as collateral.<br />

We talked about <strong>the</strong> possibility of loan guarantees through <strong>the</strong> Finance Authority of Maine<br />

(FAME). They said that FAME has not wanted to deal with <strong>the</strong> fishing industry <strong>for</strong> a while. They<br />

would need direction from <strong>the</strong> legislature to do so. If FAME could provide loan guarantees, it<br />

would enable <strong>the</strong> lenders to classify <strong>the</strong> assets in a preferred risk category. This might not affect<br />

<strong>the</strong> rate much but would make it easier <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>m to make <strong>the</strong> loans and would increase <strong>the</strong> percent<br />

of <strong>the</strong> value that could be financed. Generally with <strong>the</strong> FAME guarantee this would be 90% but<br />

could be even higher. However a loan guarantee through FAME can actually add 1% to <strong>the</strong><br />

interest rate on <strong>the</strong> loan because <strong>the</strong>re is need to cover insurance on <strong>the</strong> loan. The officers of Farm<br />

Credit of Maine were negative about <strong>the</strong> idea of setting up a new federal loan guarantee program<br />

saying <strong>the</strong>re are too many already and it would take a long time. They said it would make more<br />

sense to use an existing facility such as <strong>the</strong> USDA’s FSA to provide loan guarantees if that could<br />

be arranged.<br />

The officers of Farm Credit of Maine noted that changes in fishery management that make<br />

permits more of a commodity will make <strong>the</strong>m more valuable and easier to loan against since <strong>the</strong>re<br />

is a thicker market <strong>for</strong> resale. With only permit leasing <strong>the</strong> market is thin because you have to<br />

match up <strong>the</strong> permit’s vessel baseline to a similar boat. If <strong>the</strong> catch history can be used by anyone<br />

in <strong>the</strong> sector regardless of boat size, it becomes easier. ITQ would be even better from that point<br />

of view.<br />

I spoke with Ellen Sanborn, Assistant Director of Finance in <strong>the</strong> Portland City Manager’s Office<br />

about financing of a permit bank. She noted that <strong>the</strong>re are two different types of bonds that could<br />

potentially be used. The first and less costly is a government obligation (GO) that puts <strong>the</strong> name<br />

of <strong>the</strong> city behind paying back <strong>the</strong> bond. The city would not support this unless it was very clear<br />

that <strong>the</strong> money would be paid back, and it is probably not feasible to provide this level of<br />

certainty. The cost of capital <strong>for</strong> a GO is currently around 4.5-5%.The alternative is a revenue<br />

bond. In this case <strong>the</strong> permit bank would have to convince <strong>the</strong> buyers of <strong>the</strong> bonds that <strong>the</strong> permit<br />

bank will be able to repay <strong>the</strong> loan. It could potentially buy its way into a revenue bond by getting<br />

insurance but this would add about a percentage point to <strong>the</strong> financing costs. To get <strong>the</strong> insurance<br />

<strong>the</strong> insurance company has to be convinced that <strong>the</strong> probability of default is low. Revenue bonds<br />

might work <strong>for</strong> a few million but probably not a larger sum. Estimated financing cost with<br />

insurance would be more like 5.5-6.5%. Ms. Sanborn said that this would be a lot easier and <strong>the</strong><br />

city would be a lot more likely to participate if <strong>the</strong>ir investment was leveraged by federal or state<br />

money. State money seems unlikely, so looking <strong>for</strong> federal money might be a better bet. It would<br />

also have to be clear that <strong>the</strong> permit bank, through a sector, could pay back <strong>the</strong> loan required to<br />

purchase permits. The city would need some assurances that <strong>the</strong> management rules <strong>for</strong> use of <strong>the</strong><br />

permits in <strong>the</strong> sector would not change <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> period that it would require to pay back <strong>the</strong> loan. If<br />

<strong>the</strong>re is little assurance that <strong>the</strong> rules won’t change in a way that could undercut <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong><br />

permits, <strong>the</strong>n it would be difficult to get support <strong>for</strong> a bond.<br />

Direct loans from <strong>the</strong> Federal government would be ano<strong>the</strong>r and potentially superior alternative<br />

<strong>for</strong> financing creation of community-<strong>based</strong> permit banks. This would of course require new<br />

legislation, but a program could be modeled on <strong>the</strong> current legislation <strong>for</strong> industry financed<br />

buybacks. That program allows a fishery as a whole to apply <strong>for</strong> a long term, low interest loan to<br />

reduce capacity in <strong>the</strong> fishery and to pay that loan back through a landings tax. While <strong>the</strong> program<br />

42


is ostensibly to reduce excess capacity in fisheries, in practice it is a means <strong>for</strong> consolidation of<br />

<strong>the</strong> fishery to a reduced number of permit holders. A financing mechanism <strong>for</strong> community permit<br />

banks would achieve <strong>the</strong> same end while also addressing objectives of National Standard 8 of <strong>the</strong><br />

Magnuson-Stevens Act.<br />

3.3.2 Economic Feasibility of a Permit Bank<br />

To explore <strong>the</strong> economic feasibility of this concept, I constructed a strawman permit bank <strong>based</strong><br />

on vessels that were publicly listed <strong>for</strong> sale during <strong>the</strong> summer of 2006. The vessels listed in<br />

Table 13 were chosen from a larger set of offered vessels <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> ratio of <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

groundfish revenue history to <strong>the</strong> sale price and <strong>the</strong> percentage of <strong>the</strong>ir groundfish catch from<br />

GOM stocks. Vessels with a large percentage of <strong>the</strong>ir catch history from GB or SNE stocks were<br />

excluded on <strong>the</strong> assumption that <strong>the</strong> Maine community-<strong>based</strong> sector vessels would mainly be<br />

fishing GOM stocks. A total of 10 vessels were selected with a combined asking price of $3.8<br />

million. The vessels range in size from 46 to 74 feet with prices ranging from $150 thousand to<br />

$575 thousand. The ratios of asking price to <strong>the</strong> average annual groundfish revenue (FY2001 –<br />

FY2005) range from 0.85 to 2.49.<br />

Table 13: Vessels included in <strong>the</strong> strawman permit bank with associated list prices, DAS<br />

allocations, and vessel characteristics and percent of FY01-05 GOM groundfish landings<br />

Permit<br />

Moratorium<br />

Right ID Vessel Name List_price<br />

Regulation<br />

Length<br />

NEMS A<br />

DAS<br />

% Landed<br />

Pounds from<br />

GOM Stocks<br />

250305 370 DOLORES LOUISE $150,000 46 49 99%<br />

320541 572 LYDIA & MAYA $435,000 71 53 92%<br />

250483 401 BETHANY JEAN $395,000 48 89 100%<br />

320695 669 MARY AND JOSEPHINE $500,000 67 53 82%<br />

250728 432 ANNA LENA IV $335,000 56 80 100%<br />

310554 1530 ERIKA LYNN $299,000 50 53 100%<br />

320885 684 TARA LYNN II $575,000 54 88 99%<br />

230320 1696 IRENE ALTON $270,000 58 63 100%<br />

320233 490 JANAYA & JOSEPH $395,000 74 53 98%<br />

310331 505 TARA LYNN $525,000 54 66 100%<br />

43


Just as was done <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector analyses, <strong>the</strong> catch history associated with <strong>the</strong> current moratorium<br />

right IDs of <strong>the</strong>se vessels was calculated and a <strong>the</strong> combined share of <strong>the</strong>se vessels catch by<br />

species/stock <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> period from May 2001 through April 2006 was calculated (Table 14).<br />

Table 14: Combined catch history by fish stock of permit bank vessels <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> fishing years 2001-<br />

2005 and <strong>the</strong> proportion of total commercial landings by <strong>the</strong>se vessels.<br />

Stock and species<br />

Total FY01-05<br />

Landings<br />

Permit<br />

BankFY01-05<br />

Total Landings<br />

Proportion of total<br />

landings landed by<br />

permit bank<br />

vessels<br />

GB COD 66,166,000 258,827 0.4%<br />

GB HADDOCK 66,001,000 330,319 0.5%<br />

GB WINTER FLOUNDER 26,960,000 6,647 0.0%<br />

GB YELLOWTAIL 39,925,000 3,576 0.0%<br />

GOM COD 42,105,000 848,299 2.0%<br />

GOM HADDOCK 10,769,000 555,657 5.2%<br />

GOM/CC WINTER FLOUNDER 6,072,000 87,432 1.4%<br />

GOM/CC YELLOWTAIL 16,218,000 155,192 1.0%<br />

GOM/GB WINDOWPANE 274,000 - 0.0%<br />

PLAICE 27,593,000 1,816,007 6.6%<br />

POLLOCK 52,853,000 1,593,109 3.0%<br />

REDFISH 4,461,000 203,158 4.6%<br />

SKATES 160,780,000 - 0.0%<br />

SNE/MA HADDOCK 76,000 - 0.0%<br />

SNE/MA WINDOWPANE 633,000 - 0.0%<br />

SNE/MA WINTER FLOUNDER 25,217,000 3,834 0.0%<br />

SNE/MA YELLOWTAIL 4,118,000 - 0.0%<br />

WHITE HAKE 37,850,000 1,898,262 5.0%<br />

WITCH FLOUNDER 32,599,000 1,966,996 6.0%<br />

NFMA MONKFISH 142,821,000 6,541,841 4.6%<br />

SFMA MONKFISH 102,724,000 8,051 0.0%<br />

Based on <strong>the</strong>se percentages, ACE allocations as a share of target TACs are calculated and<br />

revenues associated with utilization of those allocations are projected <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> same target<br />

TAC and prices projections used <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> economic feasibility analysis of <strong>the</strong> sectors (Table 15).<br />

As with <strong>the</strong> sector analyses, <strong>the</strong> assumption is made that 85% of <strong>the</strong> ACE allocation of <strong>the</strong> permit<br />

bank <strong>for</strong> all stocks is actually leased by sector vessels. The ACE leasing fee as a percentage of<br />

revenues that would pay back a $3.8 million loan <strong>for</strong> vessel acquisition is calculated to be 16.3%<br />

of ex-vessel price from <strong>the</strong> catch associated with <strong>the</strong> leased ACE. This assumes an interest rate of<br />

7.5% and a 10 year repayment period <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> vessel purchase loan. Assuming variable operating<br />

costs equal to 38% of gross revenues (<strong>the</strong> same assumption used in <strong>the</strong> sector analyses), <strong>the</strong><br />

permit bank yields close to $2 million annually in net revenues to sector vessels after payment of<br />

<strong>the</strong> lease fees necessary <strong>for</strong> loan repayment. The permit bank <strong>the</strong>n quickly builds a substantial<br />

asset base which it could use to purchase additional permits. However, <strong>the</strong> growth of <strong>the</strong> asset<br />

base in Table 15 assumes <strong>the</strong> permit bank continues to lease ACE at 16.2% of ex-vessel price and<br />

reinvests its assets in investments that pay a 7.5% return.<br />

44


Table 15: Projected Total Revenue, ACE fee revenue, outstanding loan balance or asset base, and<br />

net gains to sector vessels associated with ACE controlled by <strong>the</strong> permit bank<br />

Fishing<br />

ACE Fee % of<br />

Outstanding Loan Gains To Sector<br />

Year Total Revenue Revenue (16.2%) Interest (7.5%) or (Assets) Vessels<br />

2008 $ 4,160,347 $ 674,753 $ 290,925 $ 3,879,000.00 $ 1,904,662<br />

2009 $ 3,549,007 $ 575,602 $ 262,138 $ 3,495,172.12 $ 1,624,783<br />

2010 $ 3,595,222 $ 583,097 $ 238,628 $ 3,181,708.32 $ 1,645,940<br />

2011 $ 3,657,071 $ 593,128 $ 212,793 $ 2,837,239.40 $ 1,674,256<br />

2012 $ 3,743,172 $ 607,093 $ 184,268 $ 2,456,904.16 $ 1,713,674<br />

2013 $ 3,846,614 $ 623,870 $ 152,556 $ 2,034,079.42 $ 1,761,031<br />

2014 $ 3,666,850 $ 594,714 $ 117,207 $ 1,562,765.78 $ 1,678,733<br />

2015 $ 3,710,814 $ 601,845 $ 81,394 $ 1,085,259.04 $ 1,698,860<br />

2016 $ 3,743,646 $ 607,170 $ 42,361 $ 564,808.84 $ 1,713,891<br />

2017 $ 3,761,560 $ 610,075 $ - $ - $ 1,722,092<br />

2018 $ 3,820,294 $ 619,601 $ (45,756) $ (610,074.87) $ 1,748,982<br />

2019 $ 3,872,052 $ 627,995 $ (95,657) $ (1,275,431.28) $ 1,772,677<br />

2020 $ 3,918,974 $ 635,605 $ (149,931) $ (1,999,083.90) $ 1,794,158<br />

2021 $ 3,962,823 $ 642,717 $ (208,847) $ (2,784,620.54) $ 1,814,233<br />

2022 $ 4,003,480 $ 649,311 $ (272,714) $ (3,636,184.16) $ 1,832,847<br />

2023 $ 4,041,288 $ 655,443 $ (341,866) $ (4,558,209.09) $ 1,850,156<br />

2024 $ 4,083,796 $ 662,337 $ (416,664) $ (5,555,517.83) $ 1,869,616<br />

2025 $ 4,116,892 $ 667,705 $ (497,589) $ (6,634,518.95) $ 1,884,768<br />

2026 $ 4,147,051 $ 672,596 $ (584,986) $ (7,799,812.96) $ 1,898,575<br />

2027 $ 4,109,720 $ 666,542 $ (679,305) $ (9,057,395.27) $ 1,881,485<br />

2028 $ 4,144,383 $ 672,164 $ (780,243) $ (10,403,241.75) $ 1,897,354<br />

2029 $ 4,178,725 $ 677,733 $ (889,174) $ (11,855,648.64) $ 1,913,076<br />

2030 $ 4,210,383 $ 682,868 $ (1,006,692) $ (13,422,555.74) $ 1,927,570<br />

2031 $ 4,240,695 $ 687,784 $ (1,133,409) $ (15,112,115.48) $ 1,941,447<br />

2032 $ 4,269,559 $ 692,466 $ (1,269,998) $ (16,933,308.41) $ 1,954,661<br />

2033 $ 4,297,333 $ 696,970 $ (1,417,183) $ (18,895,772.07) $ 1,967,376<br />

2034 $ 4,323,860 $ 701,273 $ (1,575,744) $ (21,009,925.12) $ 1,979,521<br />

2035 $ 4,348,522 $ 705,272 $ (1,746,521) $ (23,286,942.01) $ 1,990,811<br />

2036 $ 4,372,575 $ 709,173 $ (1,930,405) $ (25,738,734.99) $ 2,001,823<br />

2037 $ 4,394,993 $ 712,809 $ (2,128,374) $ (28,378,313.46) $ 2,012,086<br />

45


4.0 Operational and Regulatory Issues <strong>for</strong> <strong>Sectors</strong><br />

There are a number of factors that inhibit creation of community-<strong>based</strong> groundfish sectors in<br />

Maine and elsewhere in <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong>. There are also a number of factors that constrain <strong>the</strong><br />

benefits that sector management can provide to fishermen and communities. The regulations that<br />

dictate <strong>the</strong> process and requirements <strong>for</strong> sector <strong>for</strong>mation and <strong>the</strong> rules <strong>for</strong> sector operation may<br />

be revised as part of Amendment 16 to <strong>the</strong> Multispecies <strong>Groundfish</strong> FMP. This provides an<br />

opportunity <strong>for</strong> re<strong>for</strong>ms to address some of <strong>the</strong> issues discussed below.<br />

4.1 Sector Implementation<br />

Perhaps <strong>the</strong> most important issue is <strong>the</strong> difficulties and cost involved with <strong>for</strong>mation of a sector.<br />

Prospective sectors must devise an operations plan complete with a legal contract and system <strong>for</strong><br />

monitoring catch of its members. They must also complete an environmental assessment (EA)<br />

that satisfies NEPA requirements <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir initial sector proposal and <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir final operations<br />

plan. The sector must submit <strong>the</strong>ir proposal and initial EA at least a year be<strong>for</strong>e <strong>the</strong> sector can be<br />

implemented. They must develop a system <strong>for</strong> monitoring and reporting that provides NMFS with<br />

assurance that all sector groundfish catches will be counted against <strong>the</strong>ir allocation and fishing<br />

will cease when <strong>the</strong> allocation is exhausted. The sector must also bear <strong>the</strong> costs of this<br />

supplementary monitoring and reporting. There are no government resources (monetary or<br />

advisory) available to prospective sectors to defray <strong>the</strong>se organizational costs, but <strong>the</strong> expertise<br />

and resources necessary to accomplish <strong>the</strong>se tasks are substantial <strong>for</strong> an industry that is already in<br />

severe financial difficulty. To make development of sectors more feasible, it would be extremely<br />

helpful if extension services could be provided to prospective sectors (particularly <strong>for</strong> preparation<br />

of environmental assessments) and/or if a financial facility whereby sectors can apply <strong>for</strong> a loans<br />

or grants to defray <strong>the</strong> costs of sector development.<br />

Currently, approval of a new sector can only be done though a framework or an amendment. This<br />

creates considerable uncertainty as to whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> sector will ultimately be approved and when.<br />

Unless <strong>the</strong> Council is prepared to undertake special frameworks <strong>for</strong> approval of sectors, this may<br />

be a serious hindrance to approval of new sectors. In Amendment 13, <strong>the</strong> Council rejected <strong>the</strong><br />

option of setting up a procedure <strong>for</strong> approving new sectors that would not require a framework<br />

this option. However it may reconsider this in Amendment 16. By doing so, <strong>the</strong> Council would<br />

sacrifice some control over sector development in <strong>the</strong> fishery, but <strong>the</strong> cost of creating new sectors<br />

and adapting existing ones would probably be reduced considerably.<br />

4.2 Rolling Baseline <strong>for</strong> Sector Allocations<br />

Current regulations create a rolling period of catch history to be used <strong>for</strong> allocations. <strong>Sectors</strong> lock<br />

into a catch allocation as a percentage of <strong>the</strong> TAC <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> ratio of <strong>the</strong>ir catches during <strong>the</strong><br />

five years relative to total commercial catches. However, <strong>the</strong> years used <strong>for</strong> allocation to future<br />

sectors continue to change. Rolling baselines have <strong>the</strong> advantage of creating sector allocations<br />

that more closely match recent catch composition of <strong>the</strong> sector vessels. Presumably this<br />

minimizes difficulties in matching catches to sector TACs. Rolling baselines also provide<br />

opportunities <strong>for</strong> vessels with low catch histories to improve <strong>the</strong>ir catch histories and join a sector<br />

46


later. However, rolling baselines create a number of potential problems as new sectors <strong>for</strong>m and<br />

individuals exit and enter sectors with allocations <strong>based</strong> on different baseline periods.<br />

The rolling catch history creates incentives <strong>for</strong> individuals who think <strong>the</strong>y can improve <strong>the</strong>ir catch<br />

histories to remain outside of sectors and fish competitively to increase catch history. The rules<br />

create incentives <strong>for</strong> sectors to <strong>for</strong>go allocations of some species if <strong>the</strong>y think <strong>the</strong>y can increase<br />

allocations of those in future (though <strong>the</strong>ir ability to do so is likely to be limited by continued<br />

ef<strong>for</strong>t controls). Perhaps most problematic is <strong>the</strong> fact that permit holders within a sector that make<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir catch history available to o<strong>the</strong>r sector members will see <strong>the</strong>ir potential future allocations<br />

eroded. There is nothing to stop <strong>the</strong> individuals who have developed larger catch histories inside<br />

<strong>the</strong> sector from simply exiting <strong>the</strong> sector and using those increased catch histories to <strong>for</strong>m a new<br />

sector. This presents a particular problem <strong>for</strong> sectors that might want to <strong>for</strong>m permit banks to<br />

make additional catch history available to its members since <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong> permits held by <strong>the</strong><br />

permit bank would quickly erode.<br />

The Council recognized <strong>the</strong> problems associated with rolling baselines and recently passed<br />

motions recommending that sector regulations be changed to create fixed and consistent baselines<br />

<strong>for</strong> all sector allocations <strong>for</strong> a given fishery. This would eliminate much of <strong>the</strong> ambiguity and<br />

perverse incentives created by current rolling baseline allocations. It creates more security <strong>for</strong><br />

individuals who make <strong>the</strong>ir ACE available to o<strong>the</strong>r member of <strong>the</strong> sector <strong>the</strong>reby facilitating<br />

consolidation within <strong>the</strong> sector and reduction of fixed costs. It also provides more security <strong>for</strong><br />

permit banks that <strong>the</strong>ir permits will not be devalued over time if <strong>the</strong> ACE is made available to<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r vessels. There is, however, still a lack of security <strong>for</strong> individual or permit banks who lease<br />

ACE since <strong>the</strong>re is no guarantee that more recent catch history will not be used in some future<br />

allocative actions (e.g. if ITQs or <strong>the</strong> point system is implemented in Amendment 17 with<br />

allocations <strong>based</strong> on years later than those used <strong>for</strong> sector allocation).<br />

This concern might be alleviated by setting a control date <strong>for</strong> catch and ef<strong>for</strong>t history years that<br />

can be used in future allocative actions (e.g. <strong>the</strong>y would not be <strong>based</strong> on years later than <strong>the</strong><br />

control date which would presumably be ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> current date or a past date). A control date<br />

would increase <strong>the</strong> level of security, though control dates can be rescinded by a future Council.<br />

Ano<strong>the</strong>r option would be to specify by regulation that, <strong>for</strong> vessels enrolled in sectors, <strong>the</strong>ir catch<br />

(or o<strong>the</strong>r historical allocation factors such as ef<strong>for</strong>t or capacity) as a percentage of <strong>the</strong> total<br />

commercial catch (or o<strong>the</strong>r history <strong>based</strong> allocation factors) would be assumed to remain fixed<br />

while <strong>the</strong>y were enrolled in <strong>the</strong> sector. For example, if <strong>the</strong> share of <strong>the</strong> GOM cod TAC <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

permit contributed to a sector’s allocation were 1% of <strong>the</strong> total commercial catch history, <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

purpose of future allocations, it would be recorded as 1% of total commercial catch <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> years<br />

<strong>the</strong>y were in <strong>the</strong> sector. This would protect individuals in sectors whose catch was less (as a<br />

percent of total commercial catch) than it was in <strong>the</strong> baseline period. It would also means that<br />

sectors and individuals in sectors that do not catch <strong>the</strong>ir full ACE will not see <strong>the</strong>ir future<br />

allocation shares reduced. Additionally, it would protect non-sector vessels from <strong>the</strong> possibility<br />

that sector vessels could accumulate greater catch histories (in percentage terms) because of<br />

regulatory advantages such as removal of ef<strong>for</strong>t controls that allow <strong>the</strong>m to catch a higher<br />

percentage of <strong>the</strong>ir ACE allocations.<br />

An alternative would be to require sectors to specify in <strong>the</strong> sector contracts how <strong>the</strong> catch history<br />

of <strong>the</strong> sector as a whole will be distributed amongst its member permits. This, however, would<br />

create a good bit of additional complexity <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> Regional Office and would not protect ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong><br />

sector or <strong>the</strong> common pool vessels from redistributions resulting from ei<strong>the</strong>r sector or non-sector<br />

vessels having an advantage in building catch history.<br />

47


4.3 Balancing Catches with Allocations<br />

Under current sector regulations, sectors cannot buy, sell or trade ACE with o<strong>the</strong>r sectors. They<br />

must constrain <strong>the</strong>ir catch of all species to <strong>the</strong>ir annual allocations. If more sectors are authorized,<br />

substantial gains in profitability <strong>for</strong> sectors may be realized by allowing sectors to trade ACE.<br />

Gains might also be realized by allowing sectors to trade <strong>the</strong> permanent sector shares, but this<br />

may be infeasible.<br />

By altering where, when and possibly how <strong>the</strong>y fish, sector members should have some ability to<br />

control and adjust <strong>the</strong> composition of <strong>the</strong>ir catch (over <strong>the</strong> fishing year) to match <strong>the</strong>ir ACE<br />

allocation. However, if a sector has only a small allocation of a stock taken incidentally (e.g.<br />

GOM or SNE windowpane flounder or SNE yellowtail), and <strong>the</strong> catch rates of that stock are low<br />

but highly variable and/or hard to control, <strong>the</strong> possibility exists that <strong>the</strong> sector will be constrained<br />

from utilizing <strong>the</strong> ACE <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir primary target species due to incidental catch of <strong>the</strong>se o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

species. If o<strong>the</strong>r sectors have surplus ACE, <strong>the</strong> ability to purchase additional ACE <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>se stocks<br />

if <strong>the</strong>y become constraints would alleviate this problem and would likely increase <strong>the</strong> ability of<br />

sectors to utilize a greater percentage of <strong>the</strong>ir allocations of <strong>the</strong>ir primary target species.<br />

More substantial trades of ACE might be desirable in response to shifts in <strong>the</strong> distribution of<br />

primary target species. For example if cod stocks begin to expand into or shift to areas where <strong>the</strong>y<br />

have been less prevalent, it may be beneficial <strong>for</strong> sectors in <strong>the</strong> area where cod has moved to<br />

purchase ACE from sectors in o<strong>the</strong>r areas. The potential gains may be sufficient to increase <strong>the</strong><br />

profits to both sectors. If <strong>the</strong> species shifts are long-term, a shift in permits between sectors may<br />

make sense, but trades of ACE will be useful in <strong>the</strong> interim.<br />

Allowing trading of sector shares could be useful if sectors perceive long term mismatches<br />

between <strong>the</strong>ir share portfolios and desired catches. Under current rules sectors can effectively<br />

trade shares on an annual basis through <strong>the</strong> movement of vessels between sectors. Assuming a<br />

fixed baseline <strong>for</strong> allocation, <strong>the</strong> entire set of shares of catch history associated with a particular<br />

vessel would move with that vessel causing a reduction in <strong>the</strong> allocation to <strong>the</strong> old sector and an<br />

equal addition to <strong>the</strong> new one. However, finding a permit with <strong>the</strong> desired mix of species<br />

allocations may be difficult. Allowing <strong>the</strong> sectors to trade specific amounts of shares of particular<br />

stocks as opposed to <strong>the</strong> entire basket of allocation associated with a permit would make<br />

acquisition of <strong>the</strong> desired portfolio <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector easier, but would have to allow fragmentation of<br />

<strong>the</strong> catch history from a particular permit. It is probably not <strong>the</strong> intent of <strong>the</strong> Council to do this<br />

and would increase <strong>the</strong> likelihood of triggering an ITQ referendum as well. It would also require<br />

a fairly complex registry to track <strong>the</strong> shares associated with particular vessels and sectors.<br />

It may however be useful to design rules that make it simpler <strong>for</strong> vessels to move between<br />

sectors. Currently <strong>the</strong> permit owner must declare into a sector several months in advance of <strong>the</strong><br />

fishing year. With fixed baselines, it may be possible to allow <strong>the</strong>se declarations to be closer to<br />

<strong>the</strong> beginning of <strong>the</strong> fishing year and to allow a permit declared into one sector to declare its<br />

intention to switch into ano<strong>the</strong>r at <strong>the</strong> beginning of <strong>the</strong> next fishing year. However, it may still be<br />

necessary <strong>for</strong> vessels to declare into a sector well be<strong>for</strong>e <strong>the</strong> beginning of <strong>the</strong> fishing year if <strong>the</strong><br />

sector if required to submit a NEPA analysis on <strong>the</strong> final operations plan which NMFS is required<br />

to review this prior to <strong>the</strong> start of fishing. If <strong>the</strong> regulatory review process can be streamlined, it<br />

may be possible to allow declaration of sector membership closer to <strong>the</strong> beginning of <strong>the</strong> fishing<br />

year.<br />

48


4.4 Communities without Catch History<br />

There are a large number of permit holders who have little catch history in recent years. Some of<br />

<strong>the</strong>se permit holders had been inactive <strong>for</strong> some time and were not granted any allocation of “A”<br />

DAS in amendment 13. O<strong>the</strong>rs did receive “A” DAS allocations in 2004 but have not been<br />

actively participating in <strong>the</strong> groundfish fishery since <strong>the</strong>n. Some were leasing out <strong>the</strong>ir DAS to<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r vessels. Additionally <strong>the</strong>re are some communities (including several in Downeast Maine)<br />

that traditionally had some involvement in <strong>the</strong> groundfish fishery, but no longer have any<br />

fishermen with permits with “A” DAS and catch history.<br />

Currently allocation to sectors is <strong>based</strong> solely on catch history. However future sector allocation<br />

may be <strong>based</strong> on factors o<strong>the</strong>r than catch history. For example, allocation of a proportion of TACs<br />

to sectors could be <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> physical characteristics of <strong>the</strong> vessels and <strong>the</strong>ir DAS allocations.<br />

This would provide some allocation to vessels with little or no catch history, but, it is not clear<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r that allocation would be provided to vessels without “A” DAS. There<strong>for</strong>e it may still be<br />

necessary <strong>for</strong> communities without current access to <strong>the</strong> groundfish fishery to buy <strong>the</strong>ir way back<br />

into <strong>the</strong> fishery through acquisition of permits.<br />

<strong>Sectors</strong> in conjunction with permit banks could provide an opportunity <strong>for</strong> permit owners and<br />

communities without “A” DAS and catch history to reenter <strong>the</strong> groundfish fishery. Individuals<br />

that hold groundfish permits with only “C” DAS could enter a sector without purchasing a new<br />

permit and could have access to that sector’s allocation. A sector could be created with a permit<br />

bank to acquire catch history <strong>for</strong> this purpose. However, in order to provide communities or<br />

groups of fishermen with sufficient security to make an investment in a permit bank and to<br />

acquire financing, it would be necessary to provide greater assurance of <strong>the</strong> longevity of<br />

allocations associated with fishing permits held by <strong>the</strong> permit bank and clarity on <strong>the</strong> legality of a<br />

community-<strong>based</strong> entity holding permits.<br />

5.0 Conclusions<br />

The current management system <strong>based</strong> on individual ef<strong>for</strong>t (DAS) limits, year-round and seasonal<br />

closures and trip limits has undermined <strong>the</strong> economic viability of many fishing operations and <strong>the</strong><br />

efficiency of <strong>the</strong> overall fleet. Trip limits result in substantial discarding and waste of marketable<br />

fish. Increasingly restrictive DAS limits and trip limits appear to have reduced fishing mortality<br />

on stocks of concern to a below-overfishing thresholds, but <strong>the</strong>y constrain <strong>the</strong> fleet from catching<br />

a substantial proportion of <strong>the</strong> sustainable yield of o<strong>the</strong>r species. The current system has also<br />

created safety concerns by causing vessels to fish in unsafe conditions in order to maximize<br />

revenues from <strong>the</strong>ir limited DAS.<br />

Although <strong>the</strong> inefficiencies of <strong>the</strong> current management system have affected nearly all active<br />

groundfish permit holders, <strong>the</strong> impacts may have been greater in some areas as evidenced by a<br />

shift of landings toward a few larger ports in Massachusetts. This shift is mainly a result of<br />

vessels moving to or landing at ports closer to <strong>the</strong> most productive fishing grounds. However,<br />

groundfish boats in Maine face additional disadvantages, including a prohibition on landings<br />

lobsters caught by trawl gear and <strong>the</strong> state tax on marine fuel which have contributed to a shift of<br />

activity away from Maine. <strong>Groundfish</strong> landings in Downeast Maine have been essentially<br />

49


nonexistent since 1997, and <strong>the</strong> Midcoast Maine and Portland fleets have been shrinking over <strong>the</strong><br />

last five years. The Portland Fish Exchange is now operating with unsustainable losses. Its<br />

potential closure threatens to fur<strong>the</strong>r undermine <strong>the</strong> viability of <strong>the</strong> Maine groundfish fleet.<br />

Sector management creates opportunities <strong>for</strong> groups of fishermen to develop operating plans that<br />

allow <strong>the</strong>m to fish more efficiently, increase access to stocks <strong>for</strong> which catches are currently well<br />

below TACs, land and sell fish <strong>the</strong>y are currently <strong>for</strong>ced to discard because of trip limits, and<br />

potentially reduce costs by consolidating operations on fewer and <strong>the</strong> most efficient vessels. The<br />

potential benefits of sectors go beyond allowing more effective and efficient use of catch<br />

allocations. They empower sector members to develop innovative ways to better manage <strong>the</strong><br />

resources <strong>the</strong>y have access to, and <strong>the</strong>y can create strong incentives to conserve fishery resources<br />

since <strong>the</strong>ir catch allocations in future years are directly related to <strong>the</strong> size and productivity of <strong>the</strong><br />

fish stocks. <strong>Sectors</strong> may also provide a means <strong>for</strong> communities to retain or regain <strong>the</strong>ir access to<br />

<strong>the</strong> groundfish fishery.<br />

The industry has been slow to take up sectors and has yet to take advantage of <strong>the</strong> full regulatory<br />

relief <strong>the</strong>y offer. Fishermen have lacked a clear understanding of <strong>the</strong> potential benefits of sector<br />

management and whe<strong>the</strong>r those benefits outweigh <strong>the</strong> considerable ef<strong>for</strong>t and costs required <strong>for</strong><br />

sector <strong>for</strong>mation and operation. However, <strong>the</strong> additional restrictions on ef<strong>for</strong>t included in<br />

Framework 42 and <strong>the</strong> looming prospect of hard TACs following reauthorization of <strong>the</strong><br />

Magnuson-Stevens Act appears to have tipped <strong>the</strong> balance. Technical assistance provided by <strong>the</strong><br />

Gulf of Maine Research Institute also facilitated development of proposals by two sectors which<br />

may have spurred development of o<strong>the</strong>rs. There are now up to 19 new sector proposals that could<br />

be authorized by <strong>the</strong> Council under Amendment 16 to <strong>the</strong> Multispecies FMP. It is possible that<br />

sectors could account <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> majority of groundfish activity if <strong>the</strong>se new sectors begin operating<br />

2009, but it is too early to know ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> number or size of <strong>the</strong> sectors that will ultimately be<br />

approved.<br />

The economic evaluation of prospective sectors in Portland and Port Clyde suggest that sectors<br />

can realize substantial increases in profits relative to status quo management. The gains estimated<br />

in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>egoing analysis are more than sufficient to offset <strong>the</strong> costs of establishing and operating<br />

a sector, even <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> comparatively small Port Clyde sector. The gains in revenues and<br />

profitability projected in <strong>the</strong> analysis are due solely to higher rates of utilization of <strong>the</strong> sectors’<br />

shares of TACs <strong>for</strong> species <strong>for</strong> which landings have been well below target TACs and optimal<br />

yield. The projections assume <strong>the</strong> sectors will be able to catch 85% of <strong>the</strong>ir species allocations on<br />

average. These higher utilization rates should be possible as result of relaxation of ef<strong>for</strong>t<br />

constraints including limited DAS and trip limits that currently <strong>for</strong>ce vessels to turn some<br />

marketable fish into discards.<br />

However, <strong>the</strong> ability to fully utilize allocations will depend on <strong>the</strong> sectors’ ability to find fish <strong>for</strong><br />

which <strong>the</strong>y have allocations in <strong>the</strong> specific areas where <strong>the</strong>y fish, and localized depletion of some<br />

species in <strong>the</strong> area fished by a particular sector could prevent this. If sectors are able to trade<br />

ACE, as is currently being considered, sectors may be able to adjust ACE portfolios to more<br />

closely match <strong>the</strong> relative availability of species and <strong>the</strong>reby achieve a higher level of utilization<br />

of <strong>the</strong>ir ACE allocations. Additional gains not included in <strong>the</strong> analysis could be realized by<br />

concentrating through consolidation of fishing onto fewer an <strong>the</strong> most efficient plat<strong>for</strong>ms and by<br />

increasing <strong>the</strong> prices of catch through improved quality and <strong>for</strong>ward contracting.<br />

This move toward sector management presents both risks and opportunities <strong>for</strong> fishing<br />

communities that have been struggling under current management. Overall, sectors have <strong>the</strong><br />

potential to improve profitability of participating fishermen. However, sectors also create<br />

50


opportunities <strong>for</strong> consolidation of <strong>the</strong> industry that could rein<strong>for</strong>ce <strong>the</strong> trend of consolidating<br />

landings in larger ports at <strong>the</strong> expense of smaller fishing communities. Additionally sectors make<br />

it possible to move fishing privileges from smaller boats to larger boats which was not possible<br />

with DAS leasing. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, sectors may also mitigate some of <strong>the</strong> disadvantages faced<br />

by smaller, less mobile boats and even create some potential advantages (e.g. development of<br />

high value markets <strong>for</strong> dayboat fish).<br />

<strong>Sectors</strong> offer an opportunity <strong>for</strong> communities that value <strong>the</strong>ir access to <strong>the</strong> groundfish fishery to<br />

actively maintain it through a partnership with community fishermen. Fishermen will require<br />

organizational and technical assistance to set up and operate a sector. <strong>Community</strong> assistance may<br />

be critical to sector development and also <strong>the</strong> key to retaining an active groundfish fleet in <strong>the</strong><br />

face of incentives and opportunities to move fishing operations or ACE allocations to larger ports.<br />

<strong>Sectors</strong> also offer <strong>the</strong> possibly of establishing some community ownership of fishing rights and<br />

potentially ongoing access to future entrants through creation of a permit bank partially or fully<br />

owned by a community entity. By purchasing permits and associated catch history, a community<br />

entity could own a share of a sector’s catch allocation and make it available to sector members as<br />

an incentive to retain vessels in <strong>the</strong> community. Such a permit bank might also provide a means<br />

<strong>for</strong> communities to provide ongoing access to new fishery entrants, perhaps through an<br />

apprenticeship program. The economic feasibility analysis of permit banks presented in this<br />

report suggests that a permit bank could be a profitable enough investment to finance permit<br />

acquisition with a commercial loan and still provide substantial surplus benefits. However,<br />

uncertainty about <strong>the</strong> security of <strong>the</strong> fishery access right associated with <strong>the</strong> permit and <strong>the</strong> ability<br />

of <strong>the</strong> permit bank to utilize that right may make it difficult <strong>for</strong> communities or groups of<br />

fishermen to find funding to acquire permits due to <strong>the</strong> risk. Establishment of a fixed baseline <strong>for</strong><br />

sector allocations will increase <strong>the</strong> level of security <strong>for</strong> such an investment, but <strong>the</strong> possible<br />

transition of <strong>the</strong> fishery to sector or o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>for</strong>ms of management still creates considerable risk and<br />

uncertainty. A loan guarantee program might be needed to help lenders manage <strong>the</strong> risk<br />

associated with loans <strong>for</strong> permit banks. Alternatively, a mechanism <strong>for</strong> direct government loans to<br />

community permit banks could be created.<br />

Direct involvement by communities in sectors requires a more active role in <strong>the</strong> fishery than most<br />

communities have taken to date. While many communities have created or administered<br />

programs to assist fishermen, <strong>the</strong> concept of direct involvement in marine fisheries management<br />

and particularly of ownership of fishing rights is likely to meet resistance from community<br />

leaders as well as fishermen. Some fishermen express philosophical objections to community<br />

entities owning fishing rights, and communities generally do not have <strong>the</strong> experience or <strong>the</strong><br />

mandate from tax payers to take an active role, never mind equity position, in marine fisheries.<br />

However, community involvement in management of shellfish fisheries in tidal areas is not<br />

uncommon in <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> states and does provide some precedent.<br />

Notwithstanding <strong>the</strong> lack of active participation of communities in establishing groundfish<br />

sectors, several groundfish sectors are likely to be de-facto community-<strong>based</strong>. The two Cape Cod<br />

sectors, which may be re<strong>for</strong>med as new sectors with new allocations, have been community<strong>based</strong><br />

from <strong>the</strong> start and have been exploring <strong>the</strong> development of a permit bank. The Port Clyde<br />

sector is community-<strong>based</strong>, and some of <strong>the</strong> sectors proposed by <strong>the</strong> Nor<strong>the</strong>ast Seafood Coalition<br />

may also be geographically defined community-<strong>based</strong> sectors. A non-profit entity in Gloucester<br />

has been created to administer several million dollars from a settlement process <strong>for</strong> establishment<br />

of an offshore LNG terminal. This money was set aside to provide additional access to Gloucester<br />

fishermen in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>m of leased DAS, but could also fund <strong>the</strong> establishment of a permit bank to be<br />

51


used in conjunction with a community-<strong>based</strong> sector. This idea has not been proposed to date, but<br />

<strong>the</strong> development of one or more Gloucester <strong>based</strong> sectors creates <strong>the</strong> opportunity to do so.<br />

In sum, although <strong>the</strong>re has not been an explicit program to facilitate development of community<strong>based</strong><br />

sectors, <strong>the</strong> opportunity exists to do so and a number of <strong>the</strong>m may evolve in <strong>the</strong> coming<br />

years. These community-<strong>based</strong> sectors can serve dual goals of improving <strong>the</strong> profitability and<br />

safety of groundfish fishermen and also allowing communities to retain or regain <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

involvement in <strong>the</strong> groundfish fishery. However, <strong>the</strong>re a number of barriers that are impeding<br />

development of community-<strong>based</strong> sectors and fuller utilization of sector management in general.<br />

Listed below are a number of recommendations that may facilitate more effective use of sectors<br />

by fishermen and communities. These include actions that could be taken by NMFS<br />

independently, regulatory re<strong>for</strong>ms that may be included by <strong>the</strong> Council in Amendment 16, and<br />

creation of new financing program that would require federal legislation:<br />

5.1 Recommendations<br />

1. To facilitate individual permit holders’ evaluation of <strong>the</strong>ir decision of whe<strong>the</strong>r to join a<br />

sector, NMFS should compile <strong>the</strong> catch histories by fish stock of all permitted groundfish<br />

vessels and in<strong>for</strong>m all current permit owners of <strong>the</strong> process of acquiring <strong>the</strong>ir catch history<br />

and <strong>the</strong> specific <strong>for</strong>ms and signatures required <strong>for</strong> release of <strong>the</strong>ir catch history to <strong>the</strong>m and to<br />

a sector organizer and or sector manager.<br />

2. The NEFMC should authorize a streamlined process <strong>for</strong> sector approval that does not require<br />

a Council framework action and reduces <strong>the</strong> burden of documentation and regulatory analysis<br />

that must be done by sector organizers.<br />

3. The NEFMC should allow sectors to trade some proportion of <strong>the</strong>ir ACE allocations with<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r sectors within <strong>the</strong> fishing year to facilitate catch balancing and greater utilization of<br />

ACE portfolios.<br />

4. The NEFMC should fix <strong>the</strong> allocation baseline <strong>for</strong> determining individual permit holders’<br />

contributions to sector allocations and decide how overall sector allocations are adjusted with<br />

movement of individuals in, out and between sectors. Future catch privileges associated with<br />

individual permits, whe<strong>the</strong>r in <strong>the</strong> context of sectors or o<strong>the</strong>r management systems, should be<br />

unaffected by how catch privileges are utilized within sectors.<br />

7. The NEFMC should explicitly authorize community-<strong>based</strong> sectors to <strong>for</strong>m permit banks that<br />

can hold permits and contribute catch history to <strong>the</strong> sector. This recommendation is not meant<br />

to imply that multiple permits from a single vessel could be split.<br />

5. Congress should create financial resources <strong>for</strong> development of community permit<br />

banks through a loan guarantee program or a direct loan program modeled on <strong>the</strong><br />

industry funded buyback structure.<br />

52


References<br />

Alexander, Yvette 2006.Maine Fishermen's Wives Association and Maine Vessel Owner.<br />

Personal Communication, June 14, 2006<br />

Conservation Law Foundation 2006. The Road to <strong>Groundfish</strong> Collapse and Turning <strong>the</strong><br />

Corner to Recovery: A Brief History of <strong>the</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> Fisheries Crisis (1976-1997).<br />

http://www.clf.org/programs/cases.asp?id=406<br />

Conservation Law Foundation 2006. Rebuilding <strong>Groundfish</strong>: Timeline of CLF's Advocacy.<br />

http://www.clf.org/programs/cases.asp?id=344<br />

Harris, Judy 2006. City of Portland, Transportation and Ports, Personal Communication,<br />

May 24, 2006.<br />

Horne, Robert 2007. Vice Pres, Commercial Lending Coastal and Interior Region, Farm<br />

Credit of Maine. Personal Communication, May 11, 2007<br />

Kelleher, Tim 2007. Loan Officer, TD Banknorth. Personal Communication, April 10, 2007<br />

LaPointe, George 2006. Commissioner, Maine Department of Marine Resources.<br />

Personal Communication June 20, 2006.<br />

Midcoast Fisherman’s Association 2006. Association Meeting. Town Hall Tennant’s<br />

Harbor. June 20, 2006.<br />

Morton, Frederick 2007. Senior Vice President, Corporate Lending. Farm Credit of<br />

Maine. Personal Communication, May 11, 2007<br />

<strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> <strong>Fishery</strong> Management Council (NEFMC) in consultation with NMFS.1996.<br />

Final Amendment #7 to <strong>the</strong> Nor<strong>the</strong>ast Multispecies <strong>Fishery</strong> Management Plan Including a<br />

Final Supplemental Environmental Impact Statement. February 7, 1996.<br />

<strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> <strong>Fishery</strong> Management Council (NEFMC) in consultation with NMFS.2003.<br />

Final Amendment #13 to <strong>the</strong> Nor<strong>the</strong>ast Multispecies <strong>Fishery</strong> Management Plan Including a<br />

Final Supplemental Environmental Impact Statement and an Initial Regulatory Flexibility<br />

Analysis. December 18, 2003<br />

<strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> <strong>Fishery</strong> Management Council (NEFMC) in consultation with NMFS.2006.<br />

Final Framework 42 to <strong>the</strong> Nor<strong>the</strong>ast Multispecies FMP. April 21, 2006.<br />

53


Odlin, Jimmy, Portland Vessel Owner, Member <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> <strong>Fishery</strong> Management<br />

Council. Personal Communication, June 27, 2006<br />

Pappalardo, John 2006. Sector Manager, Cape Cod Hook Sector and Chair, <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong><br />

<strong>Fishery</strong> Management Council. Personal Communication, October 16, 2006<br />

Spies, Charlie 2007. Coastal Enterprises, Inc. Managing Director Capital Management<br />

LLC (CCML)). Personal Communication, May 3, 2007<br />

Sanborn, Ellen 2007. City of Portland, Assistant Director of Finance and Member of<br />

Board of Portland Fish Exchange. Maine Fishermen's Wives Assn May 29, 2006 and<br />

May 17, 2007.<br />

Stevenson, Barbara 2006.Vessel owner and seller representative, Personal<br />

Communication, May 24, 2006<br />

Raymond, Maggie 2006. Executive Director, Associated Fisheries of Maine and Vessel<br />

Owner. Personal Communication, May 25 th 2006<br />

Roberston, Richard 2007. Executive Vice President and Chief Credit Officer <strong>for</strong> Farm<br />

Credit of Maine. Personal Communication, May 11, 2007<br />

Tetrault, Bobby 2006. Portland Vessel Owner. Personal Communication, June 27, 2006.<br />

Thunberg, Eric 2007. Economist with Nor<strong>the</strong>ast <strong>Fishery</strong> Sciences Center and Member of<br />

<strong>Groundfish</strong> Plan Development Team. Personal Communication May 2007.<br />

Valleau, Tom 2007. President, Portland Fish Exchange. Personal Communication,<br />

March 15, 2007<br />

Walden, J.B., J.E. Kirkley and A.W. Kitts. A limited economic assessment of <strong>the</strong> Nor<strong>the</strong>ast<br />

<strong>Groundfish</strong> <strong>Fishery</strong> Buyout Program. Land Economics 79(3):426-439.<br />

Williams, Cathy 2007. Vice President, TD Banknorth. Personal Communication, April<br />

10, 2007<br />

54


Appendix A: Landings and revenue projections<br />

Landings and revenue projects are <strong>based</strong> on 50 th percentile estimates of F msy TACs projected by Steve Correa. These projections were updated<br />

from GARM II projections to be used in <strong>the</strong> analysis of <strong>the</strong> industry funded buyback program. The projections were provided to me by Chad<br />

Demarest who had been responsible <strong>for</strong> estimating <strong>the</strong> expected landings tax and payback period <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> industry funded buyback.<br />

Table A1: Fmsy TACs Used <strong>for</strong> Economic Analyses<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn <strong>New</strong> Georges<br />

<strong>England</strong> Bank<br />

Yellowtail Yellowtail<br />

Flounder Founder<br />

Gulf of<br />

Maine<br />

Winter<br />

Flounder<br />

<strong>New</strong><br />

<strong>England</strong><br />

Winter<br />

Flounder<br />

Cape Cod<br />

Georges<br />

Nor<strong>the</strong>rn Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Gulf of<br />

Witch<br />

Yellowtail<br />

American<br />

Bank Winter Gulf of Georges Georges Bank Windowpane Windowpane<br />

Maine<br />

Nor<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Year Flounder<br />

Flounder<br />

Plaice<br />

Flounder Maine Cod Bank Cod Haddock Flounder Flounder Redfish Haddock Pollock White Hake Monkfish<br />

2006 12,771,248 7,352,341 7,215,524 1,624,790 6,199,335 8,172,452 4,886,981 2,927,709 9,007,775 14,273,956 73,121,181 858,217 380,566 4,283,538 2,820,636 24,608,020 4,145,859 17,052,348<br />

2007 11,710,835 13,364,285 8,344,850 2,524,267 5,119,081 9,113,816 5,913,266 3,366,424 16,364,305 18,523,860 149,872,125 858,217 365,151 4,567,931 2,764,888 35,838,402 3,456,321 11,000,000<br />

2008 9,980,224 18,324,635 10,027,090 3,192,261 4,475,338 11,358,099 7,003,573 3,805,140 17,015,544 22,221,663 175,847,935 858,217 350,360 4,772,959 2,710,242 38,800,960 2,881,468 11,000,000<br />

2009 8,143,792 14,365,174 9,731,281 2,885,821 4,104,965 7,506,663 9,461,614 4,228,423 17,274,805 21,251,356 134,185,184 956,760 216,882 4,865,552 2,615,970 38,800,960 2,402,223 11,000,000<br />

2010 6,604,982 16,757,165 11,508,898 3,163,601 3,899,937 8,187,884 11,102,895 4,625,251 18,322,651 24,539,403 118,225,974 1,268,720 658,697 4,947,122 4,772,842 38,800,960 4,116,497 11,000,000<br />

2011 5,458,590 18,562,732 13,178,698 3,370,833 3,688,296 8,595,735 12,588,971 4,986,805 19,855,069 28,776,644 102,163,589 1,580,680 1,100,511 5,057,352 6,929,715 38,800,960 5,830,772 11,000,000<br />

2012 4,618,637 19,885,492 14,317,700 2,735,909 3,639,795 8,888,947 13,915,964 5,306,472 21,131,311 33,393,076 89,882,865 1,892,640 1,542,326 5,086,012 9,086,587 38,800,960 7,545,046 11,000,000<br />

2013 4,049,850 20,892,994 15,080,721 2,903,458 3,602,316 9,104,998 15,134,314 5,582,047 22,106,627 38,009,509 78,656,821 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,119,081 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2014 3,670,659 24,515,152 15,592,166 3,029,120 2,777,796 8,099,700 16,839,617 5,813,530 18,833,457 42,612,713 71,536,294 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,167,582 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2015 3,408,312 24,638,610 19,530,293 2,200,191 2,971,801 8,313,547 17,654,437 6,007,535 20,000,131 47,297,488 71,973,356 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,196,242 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2016 3,229,739 24,506,334 19,081,051 2,319,239 3,115,100 8,492,119 18,323,753 6,164,062 20,983,162 51,975,650 67,856,375 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,174,196 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2017 3,108,486 24,431,377 18,700,923 2,409,628 3,216,511 8,631,009 18,894,127 6,291,928 21,781,007 56,479,647 61,843,549 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,194,038 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2018 3,026,916 24,369,648 18,420,319 2,482,380 3,284,854 8,734,625 19,381,080 6,393,340 22,412,184 60,712,479 62,472,632 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,271,199 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2019 2,969,596 24,279,260 18,239,240 2,535,290 3,333,355 8,811,786 19,761,329 6,472,706 22,873,607 64,753,511 62,913,993 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,275,608 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2020 2,929,913 24,338,784 18,113,452 2,577,177 3,364,220 8,864,697 20,054,276 6,536,639 23,217,745 68,324,963 63,285,137 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,277,812 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2021 2,903,458 24,398,308 18,033,280 2,608,042 3,386,266 8,902,175 20,289,022 6,536,639 23,486,265 71,669,341 63,584,632 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,268,994 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2022 2,888,026 24,354,216 17,987,664 2,630,088 3,401,698 8,935,244 20,481,087 6,536,639 23,702,316 74,608,073 63,740,828 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,251,357 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2023 2,872,594 24,312,329 17,940,667 2,647,725 3,414,925 8,961,699 20,613,010 6,536,639 23,835,033 77,293,276 63,864,065 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,255,766 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2024 2,863,775 24,299,101 17,910,256 3,772,071 3,421,539 8,974,927 20,739,113 6,536,639 23,963,120 79,707,313 63,885,560 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,280,017 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2025 2,857,162 24,169,030 17,897,816 3,661,841 3,430,358 8,990,359 20,845,816 6,536,639 24,055,713 81,801,683 63,925,684 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,286,631 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2026 2,852,752 24,228,554 17,883,993 3,578,066 3,434,767 8,994,768 20,917,598 6,536,639 24,123,615 83,576,386 63,908,488 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,280,017 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2027 2,848,343 24,173,439 17,890,904 3,518,542 3,436,971 9,001,382 20,964,159 6,536,639 24,191,517 65,167,976 63,944,313 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,271,199 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2028 2,848,343 24,255,009 17,906,110 3,474,450 3,439,176 9,003,586 21,024,300 6,536,639 24,219,295 68,812,180 63,970,107 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,262,380 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2029 2,848,343 24,363,035 17,897,816 3,443,585 3,441,381 9,010,200 21,047,581 6,536,639 24,268,678 72,057,351 63,988,735 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,255,766 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2030 2,848,343 24,363,035 17,868,788 3,421,539 3,439,176 9,012,405 21,082,502 6,536,639 24,267,135 74,808,692 64,057,519 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,253,562 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2031 2,846,139 24,398,308 17,871,552 3,401,698 3,443,585 9,016,814 21,107,722 6,536,639 24,294,912 77,172,023 64,070,416 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,251,357 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2032 2,846,139 24,329,966 17,890,904 3,388,470 3,445,790 9,023,428 21,111,602 6,536,639 24,290,283 79,277,416 64,081,880 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,246,948 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2033 2,846,139 24,356,421 17,885,375 3,381,856 3,443,585 9,025,632 21,119,363 6,536,639 24,285,653 81,186,600 64,091,911 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,244,743 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2034 2,848,343 24,277,055 17,896,434 3,370,833 3,443,585 9,021,223 21,146,523 6,536,639 24,318,061 82,806,981 64,051,787 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,242,539 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2035 2,846,139 24,182,257 17,883,993 3,366,424 3,443,585 9,019,019 21,158,163 6,536,639 24,322,690 84,187,060 63,983,004 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,242,539 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2036 2,846,139 24,186,667 17,863,259 3,362,015 3,447,994 9,021,223 21,152,343 6,536,639 24,333,493 85,273,928 63,914,220 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,242,539 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

2037 2,843,934 24,067,618 17,863,259 3,359,810 3,443,585 9,012,405 21,154,283 6,536,639 24,345,839 86,235,134 63,875,529 2,204,600 1,984,140 5,238,130 11,243,460 38,800,960 9,259,320 11,000,000<br />

55


Table A2: Prices Projections Used <strong>for</strong> Economic Analyses<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

<strong>New</strong><br />

<strong>England</strong><br />

Georges<br />

Bank<br />

Gulf of<br />

Cape Cod Maine<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

<strong>New</strong><br />

<strong>England</strong><br />

Georges<br />

Bank<br />

Georges Nor<strong>the</strong>rn Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Gulf of<br />

Witch Yellowtail Yellowtail Yellowtail Winter American Winter Winter Gulf of Georges Bank Windowpane Windowpane<br />

Maine<br />

White<br />

Year Flounder Flounder Founder Flounder Flounder Plaice Flounder Flounder Maine Cod Bank Cod Haddock Flounder Flounder Redfish Haddock Pollock Hake Monkfish<br />

2006 1.43 1.28 1.28 1.28 1.21 1.25 1.21 1.21 1.61 1.61 1.02 0.54 0.54 0.54 1.02 0.57 0.86 0.80<br />

2007 1.45 1.18 1.18 1.18 1.21 1.25 1.21 1.21 1.69 1.69 0.97 0.54 0.54 0.54 0.97 0.59 0.91 0.76<br />

2008 1.46 1.11 1.11 1.11 1.21 1.25 1.21 1.21 1.69 1.69 0.96 0.53 0.53 0.54 0.96 0.60 0.96 0.75<br />

2009 1.48 1.18 1.18 1.18 1.23 1.28 1.23 1.23 1.65 1.65 0.99 0.55 0.55 0.54 0.99 0.55 1.01 0.76<br />

2010 1.50 1.15 1.15 1.15 1.23 1.28 1.23 1.23 1.58 1.58 1.01 0.58 0.58 0.54 1.01 0.54 0.90 0.75<br />

2011 1.52 1.14 1.14 1.14 1.23 1.28 1.23 1.23 1.50 1.50 1.02 0.60 0.60 0.54 1.02 0.54 0.84 0.74<br />

2012 1.54 1.15 1.15 1.15 1.23 1.28 1.23 1.23 1.44 1.44 1.04 0.62 0.62 0.55 1.04 0.54 0.79 0.73<br />

2013 1.55 1.15 1.15 1.15 1.23 1.28 1.23 1.23 1.39 1.39 1.05 0.63 0.63 0.55 1.05 0.55 0.76 0.73<br />

2014 1.56 1.14 1.14 1.14 1.24 1.29 1.24 1.24 1.37 1.37 1.07 0.64 0.64 0.55 1.07 0.54 0.76 0.73<br />

2015 1.57 1.10 1.10 1.10 1.24 1.29 1.24 1.24 1.34 1.34 1.07 0.63 0.63 0.55 1.07 0.56 0.77 0.72<br />

2016 1.58 1.11 1.11 1.11 1.24 1.30 1.24 1.24 1.31 1.31 1.08 0.63 0.63 0.55 1.08 0.57 0.78 0.72<br />

2017 1.59 1.13 1.13 1.13 1.25 1.30 1.25 1.25 1.28 1.28 1.10 0.64 0.64 0.56 1.10 0.57 0.79 0.72<br />

2018 1.59 1.14 1.14 1.14 1.25 1.31 1.25 1.25 1.27 1.27 1.10 0.64 0.64 0.56 1.10 0.59 0.80 0.71<br />

2019 1.60 1.15 1.15 1.15 1.26 1.32 1.26 1.26 1.27 1.27 1.11 0.64 0.64 0.56 1.11 0.60 0.81 0.71<br />

2020 1.61 1.15 1.15 1.15 1.26 1.33 1.26 1.26 1.26 1.26 1.11 0.65 0.65 0.56 1.11 0.61 0.82 0.71<br />

2021 1.61 1.16 1.16 1.16 1.27 1.33 1.27 1.27 1.26 1.26 1.12 0.65 0.65 0.56 1.12 0.62 0.83 0.71<br />

2022 1.62 1.16 1.16 1.16 1.27 1.34 1.27 1.27 1.26 1.26 1.12 0.65 0.65 0.57 1.12 0.63 0.83 0.72<br />

2023 1.62 1.17 1.17 1.17 1.28 1.35 1.28 1.28 1.26 1.26 1.13 0.65 0.65 0.57 1.13 0.64 0.84 0.72<br />

2024 1.63 1.16 1.16 1.16 1.28 1.35 1.28 1.28 1.26 1.26 1.13 0.66 0.66 0.57 1.13 0.65 0.85 0.72<br />

2025 1.63 1.16 1.16 1.16 1.29 1.36 1.29 1.29 1.26 1.26 1.14 0.66 0.66 0.57 1.14 0.66 0.86 0.72<br />

2026 1.63 1.17 1.17 1.17 1.29 1.37 1.29 1.29 1.27 1.27 1.14 0.66 0.66 0.57 1.14 0.66 0.86 0.72<br />

2027 1.64 1.17 1.17 1.17 1.30 1.38 1.30 1.30 1.33 1.33 1.15 0.67 0.67 0.57 1.15 0.64 0.87 0.76<br />

2028 1.64 1.18 1.18 1.18 1.30 1.38 1.30 1.30 1.33 1.33 1.15 0.67 0.67 0.58 1.15 0.65 0.88 0.75<br />

2029 1.65 1.18 1.18 1.18 1.31 1.39 1.31 1.31 1.32 1.32 1.16 0.67 0.67 0.58 1.16 0.66 0.89 0.75<br />

2030 1.65 1.18 1.18 1.18 1.31 1.40 1.31 1.31 1.32 1.32 1.16 0.68 0.68 0.58 1.16 0.67 0.89 0.76<br />

2031 1.66 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.32 1.40 1.32 1.32 1.33 1.33 1.16 0.68 0.68 0.58 1.16 0.67 0.90 0.76<br />

2032 1.66 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.32 1.41 1.32 1.32 1.33 1.33 1.17 0.68 0.68 0.58 1.17 0.68 0.91 0.76<br />

2033 1.66 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.33 1.42 1.33 1.33 1.33 1.33 1.17 0.68 0.68 0.58 1.17 0.69 0.91 0.76<br />

2034 1.67 1.19 1.19 1.19 1.33 1.42 1.33 1.33 1.33 1.33 1.18 0.69 0.69 0.59 1.18 0.69 0.92 0.76<br />

2035 1.67 1.20 1.20 1.20 1.33 1.43 1.33 1.33 1.34 1.34 1.18 0.69 0.69 0.59 1.18 0.70 0.93 0.77<br />

2036 1.67 1.20 1.20 1.20 1.34 1.43 1.34 1.34 1.34 1.34 1.19 0.69 0.69 0.59 1.19 0.71 0.93 0.77<br />

2037 1.68 1.20 1.20 1.20 1.34 1.44 1.34 1.34 1.35 1.35 1.19 0.70 0.70 0.59 1.19 0.71 0.94 0.77<br />

56


Appendix B: <strong>Groundfish</strong> Price Model<br />

Projection of revenues <strong>for</strong> groundfish sectors and permit banks requires a projection of <strong>the</strong><br />

TACs <strong>the</strong> sector will be allocated, an estimate of <strong>the</strong> percentage of those TACs <strong>the</strong> sector will<br />

actually land, and an estimate of <strong>the</strong> prices sector members will receive. While sectors may<br />

be able to realize premium prices <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> fish <strong>the</strong>y land by improving quality or contracting<br />

directly with retailers or restaurants, it is difficult to project how large this premium might be.<br />

At <strong>the</strong> same time <strong>the</strong>re are o<strong>the</strong>r factors that are likely to affect prices, particularly changes in<br />

overall landings of various species that result from changes in target TACs. Since some of<br />

<strong>the</strong>se species are rebuilding and TACs are expected to rise, this may create downward<br />

pressure on prices. Secular upward trends in prices over time can also be expected and are<br />

likely to correlate with increases in disposable income of consumers. This is likely to result in<br />

increases in real prices independent of change in quantity landed and even greater increases<br />

in nominal prices be<strong>for</strong>e adjustment <strong>for</strong> inflation. Since a primary use of <strong>the</strong>se price<br />

projections is to estimate <strong>the</strong> repayment period required <strong>for</strong> a permit bank to pay back a loan<br />

to acquire a permit, nominal ra<strong>the</strong>r than real prices are modeled.<br />

Prices are projected <strong>based</strong> on demand models <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> regulated groundfish species and<br />

monkfish estimated with landings and revenue data from <strong>the</strong> Nor<strong>the</strong>ast <strong>Fishery</strong> Science<br />

Center’s commercial fisheries data <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> years 1983 to 2005. Since <strong>the</strong> intent is to predict<br />

nominal prices, nominal prices are used to estimate demand models. Per capita disposable<br />

income (PCDI) <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> region is used as an explanatory variable to capture<br />

secular temporal trends in prices. For future price predictions this requires predicting PCDI<br />

which is done on <strong>the</strong> using a simple OLS model of PCDI growth over time.<br />

The specifications used <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> individual equations were linear-log (i.e. price per kilogram is<br />

regressed against <strong>the</strong> natural logs of <strong>the</strong> regressors). This allows <strong>for</strong> a non-linear demand<br />

curve without imposing constant elasticity. With <strong>the</strong> exception of ocean pout, <strong>the</strong> natural log<br />

of PCDI was used in place of an intercept. The demand equations are estimate using a<br />

seemingly unrelated regression that includes price equations <strong>for</strong> monkfish, cod, haddock,<br />

winter flounder, witch flounder, yellowtail flounder, plaice, sand dab, white hake, pollock,<br />

ocean pout and redfish. In addition to own quantity landed, <strong>the</strong> models use combined<br />

roundfish or combined flatfish landings as explanatory variables in some equations. Import<br />

quantities and prices were not used in <strong>the</strong>se models. An investigation of price relationships<br />

with imports suggested that import quantities are driven by domestic prices and landings but<br />

<strong>the</strong> reverse is not true.<br />

Despite parsimonious specifications with only two or three regressors, <strong>the</strong> price equations are<br />

highly significant. All regressors in all equations are significant at <strong>the</strong> 0.01 level with <strong>the</strong><br />

exception of own quantity <strong>for</strong> witch flounder which had a p-value of 0.07. First order<br />

autocorrelation was present and corrected <strong>for</strong> in both systems of equations. The estimated<br />

equations used to predict prices in <strong>the</strong> simulations and summary statistics <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>m are given<br />

in <strong>the</strong> equations below


System of equations <strong>for</strong> roundfish (A1-A6)<br />

Eq. 1: Monkfish; R 2 =0.76<br />

P = 0.284* ln( PCDI )-0.129* ln( Q )<br />

cod,t t cod,t<br />

Eq. 2: Cod; R 2 =0.96<br />

P = 0.467* ln( PCDI )-0.480* ln( Q ) + 0.472* ln( Q ) − 0.225* ln( Q )<br />

cod,t t cod,t crf,t cff,t<br />

Eq. 3: haddock; R 2 =0.81<br />

P = 0.260* ln( PCDI )-0.094* ln( Q )<br />

haddock,t t haddock,t<br />

Eq. 4: White Hake; R 2 =0.86<br />

P = 0.403* ln( PCDI )-0.221* ln( Q )<br />

w.hake,t t w.hake,t<br />

Eq. 5: Pollock; R 2 =0.69<br />

P = 0.229* ln( PCDI )-0.471* ln( Q ) + 0.332* ln( Q )<br />

pollock,t t pollock,t crf,t<br />

Eq. 6: Ocean Pout; R 2 =0.51<br />

P = -3.444 -0.135* ln( Q ) + 0.295*ln( Q )<br />

redfish,t ocean pout,t crf , t<br />

Eq. 7: Redfish; R 2 =0.49<br />

P = 0.095* ln( PCDI )-0.030* ln( Q )<br />

redfish,t t redfish,t<br />

Eq. 8: Witch Flounder; R 2 =0.77<br />

P = 0.234* ln( PCDI )-0.062* ln( Q )<br />

witch,t t witch,t<br />

Eq. 9: Winter Flounder; R 2 =0.69<br />

P = 0.270* ln( PCDI )-0.092* ln( Q )<br />

winter,t t cff,t<br />

Eq. 10: Yellowtail Flounder; R 2 =0.73<br />

P = 0.162* ln( PCDI )-0.464* ln( Q ) + 0.401* ln( Q )<br />

yellowtail,t t yellowtail,t cff,t<br />

Eq. 9: Plaice; R 2 =0.80<br />

P = 0.391* ln( PCDI )-0.162* ln( Q )<br />

plaice,t t cff,t<br />

Eq. 10: windowpane flounder; R 2 =0.63<br />

P = 0.179* ln( PCDI ) + 0.074* ln( Q ) − 0.135* ln( Q )<br />

windowpane,t t windowpane,t cff,t<br />

58


Appendix C: Sector Proposals Submitted to <strong>the</strong> NEFMC<br />

in April and May of 2007<br />

Sustainable Harvest Sector<br />

Hank Soule<br />

Alternative 1: No Action<br />

Alternative 2: Preferred: Hard TAC on groundfish stocks of concern (GOM cod, GB<br />

cod, CC/GOM YT, GB YT, SNE/MA YT, GB Winter flounder, white hake), and DAS<br />

<strong>for</strong> all else<br />

Alternative 3: Allocation and hard TAC <strong>for</strong> all stocks of GF, monkfish, skates and<br />

dogfish<br />

Requests<br />

• Implementation in 2008<br />

• Full retention of legal sized groundfish<br />

• Allocation <strong>based</strong> on May 1, 2002 – April 30, 2007<br />

• Alternative 2 Preferred: Allocation of 7 groundfish stocks (GOM cod, GB cod,<br />

CC/GOM YT, GB YT, SNE/MA YT, GB Winter flounder, white hake) with Hard<br />

TAC backstop on <strong>the</strong>se stocks<br />

• Alternative 2 Preferred: Maintain input controls and DAS except as requested<br />

below<br />

• Alternative 3: Allocation and Hard TAC backstop <strong>for</strong> all stocks of GF, monkfish,<br />

skates and dogfish<br />

Requested Exemptions<br />

• Alternative 2 Preferred: Trip limits on GB and GOM cod, CC/GOM, GB and<br />

SNE Yellowtail, GB Winter flounder and white hake<br />

• Alternative 2 Preferred: Rolling closures in GOM and May seasonal closure on<br />

GB<br />

• Alternative 2 Preferred: Differential DAS counting<br />

• Alternative 3: DAS and reporting controls<br />

• Alternative 3: Differential DAS counting<br />

• Alternative 3: Monkfish DAS and reporting controls<br />

• Alternative 3: trip limits on GOM, GB cod, CC/GOM, GB, SNE yellowtail, GB<br />

winter, and white hake<br />

• Alternative 3: possession and trip limits on monkfish, skates and dogfish<br />

• Alternative 3: GOM rolling closures<br />

• Alternative 3: GB Seasonal (May) closure<br />

Necessary Policy Changes<br />

• Alternative 2: 20% cap of <strong>the</strong> allocation <strong>for</strong> white hake<br />

• Alternative 3: allocation of monkfish, skates and dogfish<br />

59


Members:<br />

• 60+ permits using trawl, gillnet and hook gear,<br />

• operating from most of <strong>the</strong> major ports of <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> (ME, MA, NH, and RI)<br />

60


Port Clyde <strong>Community</strong> Sector<br />

Glen Libby<br />

Alternative 1: No action<br />

Alternative 2: Hard TAC on groundfish stocks of concerns and continuing to operate<br />

under DAS <strong>for</strong> all o<strong>the</strong>r stocks.<br />

Alternative 3 Preferred: Hard TACs on all GOM stocks, monkfish, skates and dogfish,<br />

and exempt from DAS, rolling closures and trip limits.<br />

Requests<br />

• Implementation in 2008<br />

• Alternative 2: Hard TAC on GOM cod, CC/GOM yellowtail and white hake;<br />

DAS to control fishing on all o<strong>the</strong>r stocks including monkfish and skates.<br />

• Alternative 3 (Preferred): Allocation of all GOM groundfish stocks, monkfish,<br />

skates and dogfish (GOM cod, GOM haddock, CC/GOM YT, witch flounder,<br />

GOM winter flounder, white hake, pollock, redfish, ocean pout, nor<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

windowpane and halibut) (11 stocks of groundfish, monkfish, skates and dogfish);<br />

• Alternative 3 (Preferred): Hard TAC backstop <strong>for</strong> all species<br />

• Both alternatives: Limited to fishing in <strong>the</strong> GOM only – (areas 511, 512, 513,<br />

514, 515)<br />

• Both alternatives: Full retention of all legal sized fish<br />

• Both alternatives: Allocations <strong>based</strong> on catch in fishing years 2002-2006<br />

• Both alternatives: Lease DAS from within <strong>the</strong> sector under existing leasing<br />

restrictions<br />

Requested Exemptions – Alternative 2:<br />

• Trip limits on GOM cod, CC/GOM yellowtail, and white hake<br />

• Differential DAS counting<br />

• Rolling and seasonal closures in <strong>the</strong> GOM<br />

Requested Exemptions – Alternative 3(Preferred):<br />

• DAS<br />

• Trip and possession limits<br />

• Rolling and seasonal closures<br />

• Differential DAS counting<br />

• Landing and possession limits on monkfish, skates and dogfish<br />

Required Policy Changes<br />

• Allocation of monkfish, skates and dogfish<br />

• Maintain <strong>the</strong> flexibility to not take Hard TACs on EVERY stock?<br />

Suggested Management Measures To Prevent Derby Fishing<br />

• Sector may allocate a quota of each species to each individual vessel<br />

Members<br />

12 vessels owned by 8 people - all use trawl gear<br />

61


Hook Sector Proposal <strong>for</strong> 2008<br />

Erik Brazer<br />

Requests:<br />

• Implementation in 2008<br />

• Hard TAC backstop <strong>for</strong> all species;<br />

• Allocation of all species (GF (20 stocks), monkfish (2 stocks), dogfish, skates (7<br />

species);<br />

• 2,000 pounds min allocation <strong>for</strong> every stock (allow <strong>for</strong> incidental catch);<br />

• Trading quota between sectors if both sectors have an allocation and if it would<br />

not result in violating <strong>the</strong> 20% cap;<br />

• Qualifying / Baseline years of 1996-2006;<br />

• If NMFS or <strong>the</strong> NEFMC regulatory bureaucracy prevents timely implementation,<br />

existing sectors will be allowed to fish under <strong>the</strong> previous year's operations plan<br />

and allocations.<br />

• The sector will land all catch; but that discards would be counted against <strong>the</strong> TAC<br />

<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector;<br />

• “Future catch histories associated with <strong>the</strong> sector are proposed to remain constant<br />

regardless of whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> vessels land <strong>the</strong> fish; and<br />

• sectors will be credited with <strong>the</strong>ir actual TAC percentage, instead of actual<br />

percentage of TAC achieved<br />

• “<strong>Sectors</strong> will be credited with <strong>the</strong> maximum TAC amount (up to 20%), ra<strong>the</strong>r than<br />

<strong>the</strong> actual amount of fish caught.<br />

• Increasing observer coverage,<br />

• Moving into electronic catch reporting<br />

• Will comply w/ <strong>the</strong> requirement <strong>for</strong> 20 day spawning block out of <strong>the</strong> fishery<br />

between March and May and any spawning closures<br />

• Not limited to fishing in any areas<br />

Requested Exemptions<br />

• paper reporting;<br />

• DAS;<br />

• seasonal, rolling, habitat and mortality closures;<br />

• minimum fish sizes<br />

• trip limits;<br />

• hook and gillnet limits;<br />

Necessary Policy Changes<br />

• qualifying baseline years;<br />

• trading quota between sectors;<br />

• future catch history remain constant regardless of actual catch;<br />

• Increasing observer coverage,<br />

• Moving into electronic catch reporting<br />

Reasons <strong>for</strong> Existence:<br />

62


Full Retention<br />

All fish caught<br />

1. end overfishing,<br />

2. reduce bycatch,<br />

3. ensure economic viability,<br />

4. measure and minimize bycatch of marine mammals and undersize /<br />

juveniles via fleet communication, voluntary closures, or o<strong>the</strong>r measures<br />

5. retain shoreside infrastructure<br />

Members:<br />

• 21 vessels (24-42 ft) and 4 skiffs (8-13 ft)<br />

• at least 23 different owners<br />

• 9 – 10 % of GB cod<br />

63


Fixed Gear Sector Proposal <strong>for</strong> 2008<br />

Erik Brazer<br />

Requests:<br />

• Implementation in 2008<br />

• Hard TAC backstop <strong>for</strong> all species;<br />

• Allocation of all species (GF (20 stocks), monkfish (2 stocks), dogfish and skates<br />

(7 sp);<br />

• Monthly TACs <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector to reduce derby<br />

• 2,000 pounds min allocation <strong>for</strong> every stock (allow <strong>for</strong> incidental catch);<br />

• Trading quota between sectors if both sectors have an allocation and if it would<br />

not result in violating <strong>the</strong> 20% cap;<br />

• Qualifying / Baseline years of 1996-2006;<br />

• If NMFS or <strong>the</strong> NEFMC regulatory bureaucracy prevents timely implementation,<br />

existing sectors will be allowed to fish under <strong>the</strong> previous year's operations plan<br />

and allocations.<br />

• The sector will land catch of all legal sized multispecies, monkfish, and skates;<br />

but discards would be counted against <strong>the</strong> TAC <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> sector;<br />

• “Future catch histories associated with <strong>the</strong> sector are proposed to remain constant<br />

regardless of whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> vessels land <strong>the</strong> fish; and<br />

• sectors will be credited with <strong>the</strong>ir actual TAC percentage, instead of actual<br />

percentage of TAC achieved.”<br />

• “<strong>Sectors</strong> will be credited with <strong>the</strong> maximum TAC amount (up to 20%), ra<strong>the</strong>r than<br />

<strong>the</strong> actual amount of fish caught.<br />

• Increasing observer coverage,<br />

• Moving into electronic catch reporting<br />

• Will comply w/ <strong>the</strong> requirement <strong>for</strong> 20 day spawning block out of <strong>the</strong> fishery<br />

between March and May and any spawning closures<br />

• Not limited to fishing in any areas<br />

Requested Exemptions<br />

• paper reporting;<br />

• DAS;<br />

• seasonal, rolling, habitat and mortality closures;<br />

• trip limits;<br />

• minimum fish sizes<br />

• hook and gillnet limits;<br />

• gillnet mesh size limits<br />

Necessary Policy Changes<br />

• qualifying baseline years;<br />

• trading quota between sectors;<br />

• future catch history remain constant regardless of actual catch;<br />

• Increasing observer coverage,<br />

• Moving into electronic catch reporting<br />

64


Reasons <strong>for</strong> Existence:<br />

1. end overfishing (Hard TACs on all species)<br />

2. reduce bycatch (full retention of legal sized regulated species)<br />

3. ensure economic viability and stability<br />

4. measure and minimize bycatch of marine mammals and undersize /<br />

juvenile fish via gear modifications, fleet communication, voluntary<br />

closures, or o<strong>the</strong>r measures<br />

5. retain shoreside infrastructure<br />

Full Retention<br />

• All legal sized regulated species including groundfish, monkfish and skates<br />

Members:<br />

• 19 vessels (ft)<br />

• at least ___ of which are skiffs (ft)<br />

• at least ___ different owners<br />

• _____ % of GB cod<br />

65


Tri-State Sector<br />

Erik Brazer<br />

Requests<br />

• Implementation in 2008<br />

• Allocation of all GF species, monkfish, skates and dogfish (29 stocks)<br />

• Full retention of legal size groundfish, monkfish, skates, and dogfish<br />

• Will use monthly quotas<br />

• 2,000 pounds minimum allocation <strong>for</strong> every stock (allow <strong>for</strong> incidental catch);<br />

• Trading quota between sectors if both sectors have an allocation and if it would<br />

not result in violating <strong>the</strong> 20% cap;<br />

• Qualifying / Baseline years of 1996-2006??<br />

• If NMFS or <strong>the</strong> NEFMC regulatory bureaucracy prevents timely implementation,<br />

existing sectors will be allowed to fish under <strong>the</strong> previous year's operations plan<br />

and allocations.<br />

• “Future catch histories associated with <strong>the</strong> sector are proposed to remain constant<br />

regardless of whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> vessels land <strong>the</strong> fish; and<br />

• sectors will be credited with <strong>the</strong>ir actual TAC percentage, instead of actual<br />

percentage of TAC achieved<br />

• “<strong>Sectors</strong> will be credited with <strong>the</strong> maximum TAC amount (up to 20%), ra<strong>the</strong>r than<br />

<strong>the</strong> actual amount of fish caught.<br />

• Increasing observer coverage,<br />

• Moving into electronic catch reporting<br />

• Will comply w/ <strong>the</strong> requirement <strong>for</strong> 20 day spawning block out of <strong>the</strong> fishery<br />

between March and May and any spawning closures<br />

• Not limited to fishing in any areas<br />

Requested Exemptions<br />

• paper reporting;<br />

• DAS;<br />

• seasonal, rolling, habitat (anything less than level 3) and mortality closures;<br />

• minimum fish sizes<br />

• trip limits;<br />

• non-spawning blocks<br />

• hook number and size, gillnet number and mesh size, trawl mesh size and shape<br />

Necessary Policy Changes<br />

• qualifying baseline years;<br />

• trading quota between sectors;<br />

• future catch history remain constant regardless of actual catch;<br />

• Increasing observer coverage,<br />

• Moving into electronic catch reporting<br />

Members:<br />

List of 51 vessels (15 trawl, 4 hook, 1 scottish seine, 31 gillnet)<br />

66


Gloucester Fixed Gear Sector<br />

Peter Libro<br />

Reason <strong>for</strong> Existence:<br />

• Securing a placeholder<br />

Requests:<br />

• Allocation of GOM cod and CC/GOM YT<br />

• DAS <strong>for</strong> all o<strong>the</strong>r stocks, including monkfish and skates<br />

• 7% - 20% of <strong>the</strong> TAC<br />

Requested Exemptions<br />

• GOM differential DAS counting<br />

• Seasonal rolling closures<br />

• GOM cod trip limits<br />

• CC/ GOM YT trip limits<br />

Members<br />

• Small to medium sized day and trip gillnet and hook vessels that fish in <strong>the</strong> GOM<br />

• 10-60 vessels<br />

Gloucester / Boston GOM and GB Trawl Sector Proposal<br />

Enzo Russo<br />

Reason <strong>for</strong> Existence:<br />

• Securing a placeholder<br />

Requests:<br />

• Allocation of GOM cod, GB cod and CC/GOM YT<br />

• DAS <strong>for</strong> all o<strong>the</strong>r stocks, including monkfish and skates<br />

• 7% - 20% of <strong>the</strong> TAC<br />

Requested Exemptions<br />

• GOM differential DAS counting<br />

• Seasonal rolling closures<br />

• GOM cod trip limits<br />

• GOM YT trip limits<br />

Members<br />

• 55 - 95 ft trawl vessels that fish in <strong>the</strong> GOM and GB<br />

• 10-60 vessels<br />

67


Gloucester / Western Gulf of Maine Trawl Sector<br />

Joe Orlando<br />

Reason <strong>for</strong> Existence:<br />

• Securing a placeholder<br />

Requests:<br />

• Allocation of GOM cod and CC/GOM YT<br />

• DAS <strong>for</strong> all o<strong>the</strong>r stocks, including monkfish and skates<br />

• 7% - 20% of <strong>the</strong> TAC<br />

Requested Exemptions<br />

• GOM differential DAS counting<br />

• Seasonal rolling closures<br />

• GOM cod trip limits<br />

• GOM YT trip limits<br />

Members<br />

• 36 – 70 ft trawl vessels that fish in <strong>the</strong> GOM<br />

• 10-60 vessels<br />

<strong>New</strong> Bed<strong>for</strong>d and Sou<strong>the</strong>rn <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> Fixed Gear Sector<br />

William McCann<br />

Reason <strong>for</strong> Existence:<br />

• Securing a placeholder<br />

Requests:<br />

• Allocation of GB cod,<br />

• DAS <strong>for</strong> all o<strong>the</strong>r stocks, including monkfish and skates<br />

• 7% - 20% of <strong>the</strong> TAC<br />

Requested Exemptions<br />

• GB Seasonal rolling closures<br />

• GB cod trip limits<br />

Members<br />

• Vessels that fish GB and GOM<br />

• 10-60 vessels<br />

68


<strong>New</strong> Bed<strong>for</strong>d Channel Trawl Sector<br />

Richard Canastra<br />

Reason <strong>for</strong> Existence:<br />

• Securing a placeholder<br />

Requests:<br />

• Allocation of GB cod, GB YT and GB Winter flounder<br />

• DAS <strong>for</strong> all o<strong>the</strong>r stocks, including monkfish and skates<br />

• 7% - 20% of <strong>the</strong> TAC<br />

Requested Exemptions<br />

• GB seasonal rolling closures<br />

• GB cod trip limits<br />

• GB YT trip limits<br />

• GB Winter flounder trip limits<br />

Members<br />

• Medium to large Trawl vessels that fish GB and SNE<br />

• 10-60 vessels<br />

<strong>New</strong> Bed<strong>for</strong>d Deep Water Trawl Sector<br />

Richard Canastra<br />

Reason <strong>for</strong> Existence:<br />

• Securing a placeholder<br />

Requests:<br />

• Allocation <strong>for</strong> GB cod, GB YT and GB Winter flounder<br />

• DAS <strong>for</strong> all o<strong>the</strong>r stocks, including monkfish and skates<br />

• 7% - 20% of <strong>the</strong> TAC<br />

Requested Exemptions<br />

• GB Seasonal rolling closures<br />

• GB cod trip limits<br />

• GB YT trip limits<br />

• GB Winter flounder trip limits<br />

Members<br />

• Medium to large Trawl vessels that fish GB and SNE<br />

• 10-60 vessels<br />

69


<strong>New</strong> Hampshire and Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Maine Fixed Gear Sector<br />

Erik Anderson<br />

Reason <strong>for</strong> Existence:<br />

• Securing a placeholder<br />

Requests:<br />

• None<br />

• DAS <strong>for</strong> all stocks, including monkfish and skates<br />

• 7% - 20% of <strong>the</strong> TAC<br />

Requested Exemptions<br />

• GOM differential DAS counting<br />

• Seasonal rolling closures<br />

• GOM cod trip limits<br />

• GOM YT trip limits<br />

Members<br />

• Small to medium sized gillnet and hook vessels that fish in <strong>the</strong> GOM<br />

• 10-60 vessels<br />

<strong>New</strong> Hampshire and Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Maine Trawl Gear Sector<br />

Dennis Robillard<br />

Reason <strong>for</strong> Existence:<br />

• Securing a placeholder<br />

Requests:<br />

• Allocation of GOM cod<br />

• DAS <strong>for</strong> all stocks, including monkfish and skates<br />

• 7% - 20% of <strong>the</strong> TAC<br />

Requested Exemptions<br />

• GOM differential DAS counting<br />

• Seasonal rolling closures<br />

• GOM cod trip limits<br />

• GOM YT trip limits<br />

Members<br />

• Small to medium sized trawl vessels that fish in <strong>the</strong> GOM<br />

• 10-60 vessels<br />

70


Point Judith / Sou<strong>the</strong>rn <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> Offshore Trawl Sector<br />

Fred Mattera<br />

Reason <strong>for</strong> Existence:<br />

• Securing a placeholder<br />

Requests:<br />

• Allocations of GB cod, GB yellowtail, GB winter, SNE/MA yellowtail<br />

• DAS <strong>for</strong> all o<strong>the</strong>r stocks, including monkfish and skates<br />

• 7% - 20% of <strong>the</strong> TAC<br />

Requested Exemptions<br />

• SNE differential DAS counting<br />

• GB Seasonal rolling closures<br />

• GB cod trip limits<br />

• GB YT trip limits<br />

• SNE YT trip limits<br />

Members<br />

• Medium to large sized trawl vessels that fish in GB and SNE<br />

• 10-60 vessels<br />

Point Judith Sou<strong>the</strong>rn <strong>New</strong> <strong>England</strong> Trawl Sector<br />

Chris Brown<br />

Reason <strong>for</strong> Existence:<br />

• Securing a placeholder<br />

Requests:<br />

• Allocations of SNE/MA yellowtail flounder<br />

• DAS <strong>for</strong> all o<strong>the</strong>r stocks, including monkfish and skates<br />

• 7% - 20% of <strong>the</strong> TAC<br />

Requested Exemptions<br />

• SNE differential DAS counting<br />

• SNE YT trip limits<br />

Members<br />

• Small to medium sized trawl vessels that fish in SNE<br />

• 10-60 vessels<br />

71


South Shore Fixed Gear<br />

Edward Barrett<br />

Reason <strong>for</strong> Existence:<br />

• Securing a placeholder<br />

Requests:<br />

• Allocation of GOM cod<br />

• DAS <strong>for</strong> all o<strong>the</strong>r stocks, including monkfish and skates<br />

• 7% - 20% of <strong>the</strong> TAC<br />

Requested Exemptions<br />

• GOM differential DAS counting<br />

• Seasonal rolling closures<br />

• GOM cod trip limits<br />

• GOM YT trip limits<br />

Members<br />

• Gillnet and hook vessels that fish in <strong>the</strong> GOM<br />

• 10-60 vessels<br />

South Shore Trawl Sector<br />

Edward Barrett<br />

Reason <strong>for</strong> Existence:<br />

• Securing a placeholder<br />

Requests:<br />

• Allocation of GOM cod and CC/GOM YT<br />

• DAS <strong>for</strong> all o<strong>the</strong>r stocks, including monkfish and skates<br />

• 7% - 20% of <strong>the</strong> TAC<br />

Requested Exemptions<br />

• GOM differential DAS counting<br />

• Seasonal rolling closures<br />

• GOM cod trip limits<br />

• GOM YT trip limits<br />

Members<br />

• Small to medium sized trawl vessels that fish in <strong>the</strong> GOM<br />

• 10-60 vessels<br />

72


Pier 6 Initiative<br />

Michael Walsh<br />

Request<br />

“For <strong>the</strong> purposes of prospectively entering into a voluntary multispecies fisheries sector,<br />

… we request that <strong>the</strong> Council initiate a framework to authorize an allocation of catch or<br />

ef<strong>for</strong>t …” <strong>based</strong> on our catch histories as reported by dealers.<br />

73

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!