21.01.2014 Views

THE CONSEQUENCES OF MR KEYNES.pdf - Institute of Economic ...

THE CONSEQUENCES OF MR KEYNES.pdf - Institute of Economic ...

THE CONSEQUENCES OF MR KEYNES.pdf - Institute of Economic ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

spending or tax cuts, therefore, would not be costless, for it<br />

would destroy the benefits that would result from the control <strong>of</strong><br />

inflation.<br />

These direct and indirect consequences act quite differently<br />

on the choices <strong>of</strong> typical citizens. The direct consequences <strong>of</strong>the<br />

surplus take the form <strong>of</strong> reductions in presently enjoyed consumption.<br />

If taxes are raised, the consumption <strong>of</strong> private services<br />

is reduced. If government spending is lowered, the consumption<br />

<strong>of</strong> government services is reduced. In either case, a budget<br />

surplus requires citizens to sacrifice services they are consuming.<br />

The indirect consequences, on the other hand, are <strong>of</strong> an altogether<br />

different nature. The benefit side <strong>of</strong> a budget surplus<br />

is not directly experienced, but rather must be imagined. It takes<br />

the form <strong>of</strong> the hypothetical or imagined gains from avoiding<br />

what would otherwise have been an inflationary experience. 1<br />

A variety <strong>of</strong> evidence suggests that these two types <strong>of</strong> choices<br />

are psychologically quite different. Moreover, appreciation <strong>of</strong><br />

the benefits from a budget surplus would require a good deal <strong>of</strong><br />

information and understanding. The task is not a simple matter<br />

<strong>of</strong> choosing whether to bear $ i oo more in taxes this year in<br />

exchange for $120 <strong>of</strong> benefits in two years, and then somehow<br />

comparing the two, historically distinct, situations. The<br />

imagining process requires an additional step. The person must<br />

form some judgement <strong>of</strong> how he, personally, will be affected by<br />

the surplus; he must reduce his estimate <strong>of</strong>the total ('macroeconomic')<br />

impact <strong>of</strong> the surplus to a personal ('microeconomic')<br />

level. As such future gains become more remote<br />

and less subject to personal control, however, there is strong<br />

evidence to suggest that such future circumstances tend to be<br />

neglected. 'Out <strong>of</strong> sight, out <strong>of</strong> mind' is the commonsense<br />

statement <strong>of</strong> this effect. 2<br />

1 This point about the categorical difference between present and future has<br />

been a theme <strong>of</strong> many <strong>of</strong> the writings <strong>of</strong> G. L. S. Shackle. A terse statement<br />

appears in his Epistemics and <strong>Economic</strong>s, Cambridge University Press, 1972, p. 245:<br />

'We cannot have experience <strong>of</strong> actuality at two distinct "moments". The<br />

moment <strong>of</strong> actuality, the moment in being, "the present", is solitary. Extended<br />

time, beyond "the moment", appears in this light as a figment, a product <strong>of</strong><br />

thought' (Shackle's italics).<br />

• And even to the extent that citizens do creatively imagine such alternative,<br />

conjectural futures, democratic budgetary processes may produce a different<br />

form <strong>of</strong> bias against the surplus. To the extent that budgetary institutions<br />

permit fragmented appropriations, for instance, a 'prisoner's dilemma' (in<br />

which choices made by each person individually will produce undesirable<br />

[Continued on page 22]<br />

[21]

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!