05.02.2014 Views

BDS market development guide.pdf - PACA

BDS market development guide.pdf - PACA

BDS market development guide.pdf - PACA

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>BDS</strong> Market<br />

Development:<br />

A Guide for Agencies<br />

on the Emerging<br />

Market Development<br />

Approach to<br />

Business<br />

Development<br />

Services


<strong>BDS</strong> Market Development:<br />

A Guide for Agencies<br />

by<br />

Alan Gibson<br />

Rob Hitchins<br />

Marshall Bear<br />

For the <strong>BDS</strong> 2000 Training Programme, Glasgow, Scotland (UK)<br />

The Springfield Centre for Business in Development, UK<br />

June 2001<br />

This work was supported by the U.S. Agency for International Development, Bureau for<br />

Global Programs, Center for Economic Growth and Agricultural Development, Office of<br />

Microenterprise Development, through funding to the Microenterprise Best Practices (MBP)<br />

Project, contract number PCE-C-00-96-90004-00.


Alan Gibson is a co-founder of The Springfield Centre for Business in Development. With a<br />

background in economic and business consultancy, he has particular expertise in business<br />

<strong>development</strong> services (<strong>BDS</strong>). In 1996–1997, he led the consultancy assignment that led to the<br />

Committee of Donor Agencies’ publication <strong>BDS</strong> for SMEs: Preliminary Guidelines for Donor-<br />

Funded Interventions, which established the basic principles of good practice that have underpinned<br />

the recent revival of interest in <strong>BDS</strong>. Since then, Mr. Gibson has been responsible for managing and<br />

editing seven major case studies on <strong>BDS</strong> practice, advised many agencies on <strong>BDS</strong> design and<br />

<strong>development</strong>, and has co-facilitated real and virtual conferences on <strong>BDS</strong>. He is co-director of the<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> 2000 Training Programme, for which this publication was written.<br />

Rob Hitchins is a member of The Springfield Centre for Business in Development. He has worked<br />

with <strong>BDS</strong> programs in a range of countries in Africa, Asia, and Latin America and has written<br />

extensively on <strong>BDS</strong>. Recent works include a major issues paper on the implications of “good<br />

practice” principles and the emerging <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> approach for the Swiss Agency for<br />

Development and Co-operation (SDC); assessing business centers in Asia and Latin America;<br />

advising on the introduction of incentive-based support for <strong>BDS</strong> providers in Pakistan; and assisting<br />

agencies in southern Africa on applying <strong>BDS</strong> good practice principles in their projects. An<br />

economist by training, Mr. Hitchins worked for the accountancy and audit firm KPMG before setting<br />

up his own tourism business in Indonesia. He is co-director of the <strong>BDS</strong> 2000 Training Programme.<br />

Marshall Bear has worked in international <strong>development</strong> for 27 years as a manager, microenterprise<br />

specialist, trainer, and author. Most recently, he coordinated the MBP project initiative on <strong>BDS</strong>, in<br />

which he explored various topics, including how to build <strong>market</strong>s for <strong>BDS</strong> and how to measure the<br />

performance of donor- supported <strong>BDS</strong> projects. His most recent publication explores the use of<br />

information and communication technologies for small and medium-sized enterprise <strong>development</strong>.<br />

Mr. Bear is one of the three core trainers for the <strong>BDS</strong> 2000 Training Programme.


i<br />

TABLE OF CONTENTS<br />

CHAPTER ONE<br />

WHY <strong>BDS</strong> MARKET DEVELOPMENT?<br />

WHY IT’S IMPORTANT AND WHAT IT IS 1<br />

WHY <strong>BDS</strong> FOR SMES?..............................................................................................................1<br />

Common Starting Point................................................................................................1<br />

Business Need for Services .........................................................................................2<br />

Traditionally a Low Priority…....................................................................................4<br />

….Despite their Obvious (and Increasing) Importance.............................................4<br />

Focusing on Business Services....................................................................................4<br />

WHY <strong>BDS</strong> MARKET DEVELOPMENT?.......................................................................................7<br />

WHAT’S NEW ABOUT <strong>BDS</strong> MARKET DEVELOPMENT?............................................................8<br />

What <strong>BDS</strong> Is.................................................................................................................9<br />

Main Objective ...........................................................................................................10<br />

Approach ....................................................................................................................11<br />

CHAPTER TWO<br />

WHERE WE ARE NOW—A FRAMEWORK FOR MARKET<br />

ASSESSMENT AND INTERVENTION CHOICE 13<br />

FRAMEWORK FOR <strong>BDS</strong> MARKET ANALYSIS ..........................................................................13<br />

WHY ISN’T THE MARKET WORKING?.....................................................................................14<br />

KEY CHARACTERISTICS OF EFFECTIVE DEMAND...................................................................17<br />

KEY CHARACTERISTICS OF EFFECTIVE SUPPLY .....................................................................18<br />

DETERMINING BOUNDARIES AND LEVEL OF EFFORT IN ANALYZING A MARKET.................19<br />

Market Boundaries.....................................................................................................19<br />

Level of Effort ............................................................................................................21<br />

IS THERE POTENTIAL FOR INTERVENTION?.............................................................................22<br />

WHERE SHOULD INTERVENTIONS FOCUS? .............................................................................23<br />

WHAT TYPE OF INTERVENTION IS USEFUL?...........................................................................24<br />

CONCLUDING COMMENTS .......................................................................................................25<br />

CHAPTER THREE<br />

WHERE DO WE WANT TO GO?—DEVELOPING A CLEAR<br />

PICTURE OF SUSTAINABILITY 27<br />

WHAT DOES SUSTAINABILITY MEAN IN <strong>BDS</strong> MARKET DEVELOPMENT?.............................27<br />

WHY IS CLARITY IN SUSTAINABILITY SO IMPORTANT? .........................................................29<br />

WHY HAS IT BEEN SO DIFFICULT TO DEVELOP CLEAR VIEWS OF SUSTAINABILITY<br />

IN <strong>BDS</strong>?.......................................................................................................................29<br />

A TRANSPARENT FRAMEWORK FOR SUSTAINABILITY IN <strong>BDS</strong>..............................................30<br />

What Needs to Be Done?—Key Supply-side Functions.........................................31<br />

Who Are the Main Players?—Main Potential Actors on the<br />

Supply-side of a Market..................................................................................32<br />

Who Will Undertake the Function (who does)? Who Will Pay for This to<br />

Happen (who pays)?—Linking Actors with Functions.................................35<br />

WHAT WOULD A SUSTAINABILITY PICTURE LOOK LIKE? .....................................................36


ii<br />

CHAPTER FOUR<br />

HOW DO WE GET THERE?—CORE IMPLEMENTATION CHALLENGES 39<br />

COMMON SIGNS OF MARKET DEVELOPMENT OR DISTORTION IN <strong>BDS</strong> INTERVENTIONS .....39<br />

HOW SUPPORT FOR <strong>BDS</strong> SHOULD BE STRUCTURED? ............................................................40<br />

Invasiveness of Support.............................................................................................40<br />

Intensity of Support....................................................................................................43<br />

Intervention Leverage ................................................................................................48<br />

Factors to Take Account of in Pursuing Poverty Reduction/Equity Objectives....53<br />

WITH WHOM SHOULD WE WORK?.........................................................................................56<br />

Criteria for Selecting Partners ...................................................................................57<br />

Selection of Partners ..................................................................................................57<br />

WHAT ARE THE IMPLICATIONS FOR THE CAPACITIES OF DONORS AND FACILITATORS?......59<br />

CHAPTER FIVE<br />

HOW DO WE ASSESS OUR PERFORMANCE?—MONITORING AND<br />

EVALUATION <strong>BDS</strong> INTERVENTIONS 61<br />

COMMON BASIS OF MONITORING AND EVALUATION: SOME THINGS DON’T CHANGE........61<br />

Dimensions of Performance ......................................................................................61<br />

Questions to Be Answered ........................................................................................62<br />

Factors to Consider in Developing Indicators ..........................................................62<br />

Big Problems that Don’t Go Away...........................................................................63<br />

WHAT’S NEW IN MONITORING AND EVALUATION: WHAT IS MEASURED ............................64<br />

New Focus on the Marketplace for <strong>BDS</strong>..................................................................65<br />

Providers—Commercial Players Means Commercially Based Indicators .............65<br />

SMEs—Getting “Real” over Assessing Performance .............................................66<br />

Beyond SMEs—Unchanged Indicators....................................................................67<br />

WHAT’S NEW IN MONITORING AND EVALUATION: HOW WE MEASURE..............................67<br />

Market-Level—The Same Tools in Evaluation as in Design..................................67<br />

Providers—Using Standard Business-Analysis Tools.............................................67<br />

SMEs—Practical and More-Market Focused Approaches......................................69<br />

WHAT’S NEW IN MONITORING AND EVALUATION: WHY WE MEASURE..............................70<br />

OUTSTANDING ISSUES .............................................................................................................71<br />

ANNEX A: REFERENCES A-1


iii<br />

LIST OF FIGURES, BOXES, AND TABLES<br />

Figure<br />

1 Bringing Coherence to <strong>BDS</strong>: Needs, Services, and Providers ..................................3<br />

2 Flows of Services in the Economy..............................................................................5<br />

3 What We Believe..........................................................................................................7<br />

4 Framework for Understanding the Effectiveness of <strong>BDS</strong> Markets.........................12<br />

5 Anatomy of a <strong>BDS</strong> Transaction ................................................................................13<br />

6 Quadrant of Demand-side Conditions ......................................................................16<br />

7 Quadrant of Supply-side Conditions.........................................................................17<br />

8 <strong>BDS</strong> Market Development and the Potential for Intervention................................20<br />

9 The Process of Overcoming a Supply Constraint ....................................................22<br />

10 Matching Market Analysis to Intervention Options ................................................23<br />

11 Sustainability in <strong>BDS</strong>.................................................................................................29<br />

12 Functions of the State.................................................................................................33<br />

13 Where to Intervene to Reduce the Risk of Distortion..............................................39<br />

14 Options for Support: Support Existing or Develop New.........................................49<br />

15 Indicators in <strong>BDS</strong>: Emerging Trends........................................................................60<br />

16 Measurement Methods in <strong>BDS</strong> Monitoring and Evaluation: Emerging Trends....64<br />

17 Why We Measure in <strong>BDS</strong>: Emerging Trends..........................................................66<br />

Box<br />

1 What’s in a Name?.....................................................................................................10<br />

2 Some Rudimentary Economics .................................................................................12<br />

3 Influences on Demand and Supply ...........................................................................14<br />

4 Market-Analysis Tools...............................................................................................19<br />

5 Matching Intervention to Identified Market Weakness in Gaza .............................21<br />

6 Interventions Affecting Demand and Supply Sides.................................................23<br />

7 Key Conditions in Assessing the Role of the State in <strong>BDS</strong> ....................................31<br />

8 Key Considerations in Assessing the Role of Business Membership<br />

Organizations in <strong>BDS</strong>..........................................................................................32<br />

9 Key Considerations in Assessing the Role of Not-for-Profit Organizations<br />

in <strong>BDS</strong>...................................................................................................................32<br />

10 Overloading a Provider in Kenya..............................................................................42<br />

11 Overloading Training in Uganda...............................................................................43<br />

12 Using a Portfolio Approach to Achieve Cross-cutting Development<br />

Objectives.............................................................................................................44<br />

13 Using Incentive-based Support .................................................................................47<br />

14 Changing Views of the Meso-level in Nepal............................................................52<br />

15 The Problem with Employment as an Indicator in <strong>BDS</strong>..........................................62


iv<br />

Table<br />

1 Implications of Different Market Conditions for Interventions..............................18<br />

2 Sustainability Framework in Matrix Form ...............................................................35<br />

3 Common Signs of Market Development and Market Distortion............................38<br />

4 Possible Justifications for Direct-Delivery Subsidies..............................................40


v<br />

INTRODUCTION<br />

A revival of interest among <strong>development</strong> agencies in business <strong>development</strong> services (<strong>BDS</strong>)<br />

for small and medium-sized enterprise (SME) <strong>development</strong> has resulted in agreement on<br />

guiding principles of sound practice and the <strong>development</strong> of more rigorous performance<br />

frameworks, mirroring earlier <strong>development</strong>s in microfinance. It is now clear that the priority<br />

of organizations in the <strong>BDS</strong> industry globally is to turn this wave of interest and learning into<br />

improved practice in the design and management of effective <strong>BDS</strong>.<br />

This <strong>guide</strong> seeks to contribute to this challenge by laying out a set of core skills and<br />

frameworks that take these guiding principles and move them closer to foundation<br />

practices when the goal—and this is the key difference compared with “traditional”<br />

approaches—is to make <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong>s work for SMEs. The pursuit of this goal requires a<br />

new, or at least modified, set of core skills and practices in conceptualizing <strong>BDS</strong> in the new<br />

<strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> paradigm; diagnosing <strong>market</strong> problems as the basis for intervention;<br />

making informed decisions on strategy, intervention options, and partners and their roles;<br />

financing interventions with the right type of incentives and subsidies; and evaluating desired<br />

changes and monitoring the impact of <strong>BDS</strong> interventions.<br />

This <strong>guide</strong> draws on recent experience from <strong>BDS</strong> projects, case study research, workshops,<br />

and seminars that have identified the critical gaps in what we know and what we need to<br />

know to turn these guiding principles into best practices. To date, there is no body of<br />

practical experience in the <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> approach that could provide irrefutable<br />

evidence that <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong>s are working better for SMEs as a result of specific interventions.<br />

However, a body of practical experience is emerging, as pioneering initiatives are launched<br />

that focus on developing new <strong>BDS</strong> products, managing voucher schemes, fostering business<br />

networks and linkages, and experimenting with cost-effective management information<br />

systems, to name a few.<br />

This <strong>guide</strong> is a call to action for relevant parties—donors, providers, facilitators, and<br />

researchers—that have as their goal to make <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong>s work for SMEs. The authors<br />

hope that the concepts, frameworks, and tools presented serve as useful and practical <strong>guide</strong>s<br />

in the pursuit of this goal.


vi<br />

How to Use This Guide: A Quick Road Map<br />

Section<br />

1. Why <strong>BDS</strong> Market<br />

Development?<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong><br />

<strong>development</strong>: why it is<br />

important and what is<br />

new about it<br />

Key Questions<br />

• Why is <strong>BDS</strong> so important for privatesector<br />

<strong>development</strong>?<br />

• Why should we think of <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong><br />

<strong>development</strong>?<br />

• What is so new about <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong><br />

<strong>development</strong> compared with how we<br />

have done things in the past?<br />

Go Here If You<br />

Want to…<br />

…find out about the basic<br />

rationale for <strong>market</strong><br />

<strong>development</strong> and how this<br />

links with wider<br />

<strong>development</strong> goals<br />

2. Where Are We<br />

Now?<br />

Market assessment and<br />

intervention choice<br />

• What overall framework can we use to<br />

make sense of <strong>market</strong>s?<br />

• What tools can we use to assess <strong>market</strong>s<br />

and identify constraints?<br />

• How does <strong>market</strong> analysis feed into<br />

intervention design?<br />

…ensure that the design and<br />

management of interventions<br />

are shaped by a practical<br />

understanding of <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong><br />

conditions<br />

3. Where Do We<br />

Want to Go?<br />

Sustainability:<br />

developing a clear picture<br />

of the way ahead<br />

• Everyone agrees sustainability is<br />

“important,” but what does it mean in the<br />

context of <strong>BDS</strong>?<br />

• What are the key <strong>market</strong> functions, and<br />

who are the key players who make up a<br />

picture of sustainability?<br />

• What kind of picture of sustainability<br />

should we aim for?<br />

…operationalize<br />

sustainability as an<br />

objective in <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong><br />

<strong>development</strong><br />

4. How Do We Get<br />

There?<br />

Core implementation<br />

challenges<br />

• How should support be structured to<br />

minimize distortion and maximize<br />

<strong>development</strong>?<br />

• Who should we work with in <strong>BDS</strong><br />

interventions?<br />

• What are the implications for donor and<br />

facilitator capacities?<br />

…focus specifically on the<br />

range of design and<br />

management issues that need<br />

to be confronted in any<br />

successful intervention<br />

5. How Do We<br />

Assess Our<br />

Performance?<br />

M&E in <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong><br />

<strong>development</strong><br />

• Given the emergence of the <strong>BDS</strong><br />

<strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> approach, what<br />

should we measure?<br />

• What changes in measurement methods<br />

are necessary?<br />

• What outstanding issues still remain in<br />

monitoring and evaluation in <strong>BDS</strong>?<br />

…develop more practical<br />

and appropriate<br />

approaches to monitoring<br />

and evaluation that are<br />

consistent with a <strong>market</strong><br />

<strong>development</strong> focus<br />

Annex<br />

Key References • Where do I go to find out more?<br />

…… delve deeper into<br />

any aspect of the <strong>BDS</strong><br />

<strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong><br />

approach


1<br />

CHAPTER ONE<br />

WHY <strong>BDS</strong> MARKET DEVELOPMENT?<br />

WHY IT IS IMPORTANT AND WHAT IS NEW ABOUT IT<br />

Previously, we saw business <strong>development</strong> services (<strong>BDS</strong>) as a small, leftover bundle of activities<br />

to be filled primarily by government—the kind of services we thought businesses needed even if<br />

they did not know it themselves. Now we know that a broad range of services is increasingly<br />

important in every economy and that such services are best offered in a business-oriented<br />

manner within the context of functioning <strong>market</strong>s. Most previous interventions have actually<br />

undermined the <strong>development</strong> of these <strong>market</strong>s. Difficult though it may be to accept, we have often<br />

made things worse. Learning from past mistakes, we now focus interventions on helping <strong>market</strong>s<br />

work more effectively.<br />

This chapter provides a rationale for <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> interventions. It summarizes key<br />

reasons for the growth of services globally and outlines the main conclusions reached by<br />

<strong>development</strong> agencies through intensive review of their own experience supporting <strong>BDS</strong> in recent<br />

years. It concludes by highlighting the key differences between <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> and<br />

previous approaches with regard to the beliefs that underpin <strong>BDS</strong>, its definition, objectives, and<br />

overall approach.<br />

Key Questions:<br />

1. Why is <strong>BDS</strong> so important for private-sector <strong>development</strong>, especially the <strong>development</strong> of small<br />

and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs)?<br />

2. Even if <strong>BDS</strong> is important, why should we think of <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong>?<br />

3. Given that <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> is important, what is so new about it in relation to how<br />

we have done things in the past?<br />

WHY <strong>BDS</strong> FOR SMES?<br />

Common Starting Point<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong>—as with all interventions supported with aid—needs to be<br />

justified with respect to its ability to reduce poverty. Before looking at <strong>BDS</strong> in depth, we<br />

need to set out clearly the common starting point for this link between poverty and <strong>BDS</strong>. In<br />

brief, this is based on a mainstream view of <strong>development</strong> articulated most coherently by the<br />

World Bank but, with minor reservations from some, espoused by all major bilateral<br />

agencies. The starting point essentially is built on the following core tenets:<br />

• Poverty, although complex, is primarily about people’s lack of access to and limited<br />

capacity to respond to income-earning opportunities.<br />

Chapter One—Why <strong>BDS</strong> Market Development?<br />

Why It Is Important and What Is New about It


2<br />

• To address poverty, governments and <strong>development</strong> agencies need to pursue a <strong>market</strong>friendly<br />

approach to <strong>development</strong>, based on sound macroeconomic management,<br />

competent delivery of public services, structural reform, and open trade.<br />

• Inherent in this approach are two implications: that government focus on its areas of core<br />

competence and that the private sector be recognized and encouraged as the prime engine<br />

of economic growth. 1<br />

• Private-sector <strong>development</strong>—of which SME <strong>development</strong> is an important part—is<br />

therefore an intrinsic part of any effective poverty-reduction strategy.<br />

Business Need for Services<br />

A focus on private-sector and SME <strong>development</strong> grows directly from <strong>development</strong> agencies’<br />

commitment to an environment promoting the private sector. Key aspects of this<br />

environment are the macroeconomic context and public investment in people. However,<br />

more immediately for SMEs, access to services is a vitally important dimension in their<br />

business environment (see Figure 1) and a key factor in determining the competitiveness of<br />

economies.<br />

• SMEs have a range of different “needs” that are critical to their survival and growth. 2 The<br />

nature of these needs will be influenced by sector and stage of SME <strong>development</strong> but will<br />

also relate to their ability to, for example, find customers, design products, enhance<br />

productivity, reduce fixed costs, improve administration, communicate effectively, and<br />

access new technology. The degree to which these needs are met will have a major<br />

influence on business success.<br />

• Although business needs differ, needs can be understood as basic, practical questions<br />

(such as how to, with whom, where to, and what about) in relation to essential business<br />

functions. These are questions faced by all businesses. Indeed, businesses, and SMEs in<br />

particular, are associated with independence. Yet, to a considerable degree, success as a<br />

small business stems from the owner–manager’s ability to manage his or her business in<br />

an interdependent manner and to develop appropriate working relationships with<br />

providers of services (and other stakeholders) in the environment.<br />

• Financial services are a critical part of this immediate environment but cannot meet all<br />

business needs.<br />

• Environments that are conducive to SME <strong>development</strong> provide relevant, differentiated<br />

services to meet these needs on an informal or formal basis.<br />

1<br />

Economic growth is not seen as a guarantee of poverty reduction but as a necessary condition for it.<br />

2<br />

Needs are concerned with inputs to (administration, people, technology) and outputs from (access to <strong>market</strong>s,<br />

customers) SMEs.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


3<br />

Figure 1: Bringing Coherence to <strong>BDS</strong>: Needs, Services, and Providers<br />

PROVIDERS<br />

FAMILY<br />

FRIENDS<br />

CUSTOMERS<br />

BUSINESS<br />

NETWORKS<br />

NETWORKS<br />

(FORMAL AND<br />

INFORMAL)<br />

INSPECTION AND<br />

TESTING<br />

TECHNOLOGY<br />

SERVICES<br />

NEEDS<br />

IN RELATION TO:<br />

PRODUCTION<br />

FOR-PROFIT<br />

PRIVATE<br />

SECTOR<br />

FINANCE<br />

BANKS<br />

FINANCE COMPANIES<br />

ACCOUNTANTS<br />

CONSULTANTS<br />

DESIGNERS<br />

OTHER SUPPLIERS<br />

(EQUIPMENT +<br />

SERVICES)<br />

ACCOUNTANCY/<br />

AUDIT<br />

TRAINING<br />

PERSONNEL<br />

BUSINESS<br />

SPACE<br />

SMEs<br />

RAW<br />

MATERIALS<br />

SECURITY<br />

MARKETS<br />

TECHNICAL<br />

INFORMATION<br />

COURIER DELIVERY<br />

STATE<br />

NATIONAL GOVT.<br />

LOCAL GOVT.<br />

PARASTATALS<br />

CONSULTANCY<br />

REPAIR AND<br />

MAINTENANCE<br />

LINKAGES<br />

LAWS/<br />

REGULATIONS<br />

COMPUTER SERVICES<br />

BROKERING/<br />

LINKING<br />

ADMINISTRATION<br />

TRANSPORT<br />

TELECOMMUNICATION<br />

SERVICES<br />

WEB-SITE DESIGN<br />

AND MANAGEMENT<br />

LEGAL SERVICES<br />

ASSOCIATIONS<br />

UNIVERSITIES/<br />

COLLEGES<br />

MUTUAL GUARANTEE<br />

ASSOCIATIONS<br />

NOT-FOR-<br />

PROFIT<br />

SECTOR<br />

NGOs<br />

CLUBS<br />

Chapter One—Why <strong>BDS</strong> Market Development?<br />

Why It Is Important and What Is New about It


4<br />

• Potentially, a range of providers offers these services to SMEs. In the most<br />

entrepreneurial situations, private-sector companies and formal and informal networks<br />

are the most important players.<br />

Traditionally a Low Priority…<br />

• The crucial role of services in successful economies is now beginning to be appreciated<br />

after a history of neglect. Services are referred to conventionally as the tertiary sector<br />

following the primary (extractive—agriculture, fishing, mining, and so on) and secondary<br />

(manufacturing) sectors. 3<br />

• The implied priority—with services least important—has been commonly accepted.<br />

Economic writers from Smith to Marx have labeled services as unproductive. They were<br />

referred to as residual—a leftover category of minimal importance compared with the<br />

“real” endeavor of producing commodities and manufacturing goods.<br />

• This sense of what was important has been one that <strong>development</strong> agencies and<br />

governments have often adopted without much critical attention. The perceived<br />

intangibility of services can be easily (and understandably) interpreted as nebulous and<br />

weak in comparison with the tangible certainties of physical commodities and goods. For<br />

many, production is associated with a kind of moral wholesomeness that renders it<br />

positive—sometimes irrespective of its cost, quality, or appropriateness.<br />

…Despite Their Obvious (and Increasing) Importance<br />

• This lack of priority for services is especially surprising, given their importance in successful<br />

economies. In 1998, services accounted for 61 percent of value added in the world economy<br />

(up from 56 percent in 1980). In high-income countries, this figure was 65 percent (up from<br />

59 percent); in low-income economies, it was 38 percent (up from 30 percent). 4<br />

Focusing on Business Services<br />

• One main reason for agencies’ and governments’ reluctance to make services a priority is<br />

the absence of a pleasingly tight definition. Figure 2 shows one common classification<br />

using the following services:<br />

− Public Administration Services—“core” state functions, such as health, education,<br />

security, and some types of infrastructure;<br />

3<br />

4<br />

The discussion on services draws considerably from Riddle (1992).<br />

Figures are from the World Bank (1999).<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


5<br />

Chapter One—Why <strong>BDS</strong> Market Development?<br />

Why It Is Important and What Is New about It


6<br />

Figure 2: Flows of Services in the Economy<br />

The Primary<br />

Sector—Extractive<br />

(commodities)<br />

Public<br />

Administration<br />

Services<br />

Business<br />

Services<br />

Consumer<br />

Services<br />

Service<br />

Sector<br />

The Secondary<br />

Sector—<br />

Manufacturing<br />

(goods)<br />

Source: Adapted from Riddle (1992)<br />

− Business Services—these are supplied from business to business and aimed at<br />

improving business performance through, for example, improved <strong>market</strong> access,<br />

operational efficiency, reduced costs, better designs, and greater skill levels; and<br />

− Consumer Services—such as leisure, tourism, retail, and household services—many<br />

of which are related to personal wealth.<br />

• Business services are the focus of attention here. It is difficult to be precise about how<br />

much of the wider service sector is accounted for by business services, but it has been<br />

estimated to be one-half in high-income economies and one-third in low-income<br />

countries.<br />

• Business services are an increasing proportion of overall service-sector activity. Indeed,<br />

business services are among the highest growth areas in many economies. Why is this so?<br />

Several points can be made:<br />

− There is increasing recognition that services add value to commodities and goods that<br />

allow businesses in these sectors to compete more effectively, access new <strong>market</strong>s,<br />

and operate efficiently.<br />

− In an increasingly complex and competitive global environment, and even at a local<br />

level, businesses have to focus on their core areas of competence, staying with what<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


7<br />

they know best rather than trying to do everything in-house. This means developing<br />

effective working relationships with a range of external specialists.<br />

− This trend has been hastened by technology <strong>development</strong>s and the opportunities (and<br />

threats) posed by them. Business service specialization is particularly evident, for<br />

example, in Internet services in which services increasingly need to be highly<br />

specific.<br />

Although some of these trends may appear distant from the hard realities of low-income<br />

economies, they are equally relevant here. A conducive environment for business<br />

<strong>development</strong> offers appropriate services to businesses to enable them to survive, develop, and<br />

grow. This has always been the case but is becoming even more important now.<br />

The World Bank (1999) highlights this trend concisely:<br />

Economic output has traditionally been visualized as commodities and goods—<br />

wheat, coffee, shirts, or automobiles. This economic vision grows less accurate<br />

each year… . The growing importance of services means that knowledge—how<br />

to do things, how to communicate, how to work with other people—is becoming<br />

ever more important, overshadowing the natural resource base.<br />

WHY <strong>BDS</strong> MARKET DEVELOPMENT?<br />

Many donors have long held the view that SMEs need more than finance and so have<br />

intervened to support the provision of nonfinancial services to SMEs. But why has this<br />

understanding led to a new, different focus on <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong>?<br />

The origins of <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> lie in the early-to-mid-1990s, when it became clear<br />

to many <strong>development</strong> agencies that—in comparison with the results of microfinance—<strong>BDS</strong>,<br />

after many years of funding and endeavor, had disappointing results, specifically with regard<br />

to the following:<br />

• Outreach—Only a small number of SMEs were being reached with officially supported<br />

services. Most were untouched.<br />

• Sustainability—Public organizations supported to deliver services consumed resources<br />

but, with little or no income from their SME clients, depended on aid. The apparatus of<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> required never-ending subsidization.<br />

• Impact—There were few signs of major impact—although, in the absence of a price-based<br />

transactional relationship and the signals this would send about client satisfaction, this was<br />

difficult to judge. Certainly, there seemed to be little perceived value on the part of SME<br />

clients.<br />

Chapter One—Why <strong>BDS</strong> Market Development?<br />

Why It Is Important and What Is New about It


8<br />

• Efficiency—The cost bases of providers and their ways of working seemed more<br />

appropriate to the world of donors than did those of SMEs.<br />

Drawing on the microfinance experience, in which open comparison and learning had been a<br />

key foundation of progress, practitioners instigated a major review, resulting in, in the first<br />

instance, preliminary <strong>guide</strong>lines based on core principles of good practice. 5 Among the key<br />

conclusions reached were the following:<br />

• A key cause of poor performance had been a supply-led orientation, by which<br />

<strong>development</strong> agencies decreed what was good for SMEs (rather than listening<br />

intelligently to them).<br />

• The key general points in a “<strong>market</strong>-friendly” environment had not been transferred to<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> for SMEs; the prevailing view had been that many <strong>BDS</strong> should be an extension of<br />

the state. Indeed, many donor-supported interventions, especially in low-income<br />

countries, had contributed to massive <strong>market</strong> distortion and led to governments playing<br />

inappropriate roles and to the <strong>development</strong> of “fat” providers.<br />

• Donors failed to learn key lessons from microfinance—notably that poor people (and<br />

SMEs) are prepared to pay realistic prices for useful services and that they are discerning<br />

consumers, desirous of good services, not charity.<br />

• The best providers of <strong>BDS</strong> were close to SMEs in terms of their systems, values, and people.<br />

The lesson emerging from this process was clear: The basis for effective and sustainable<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> is business and <strong>market</strong> relationships between providers and SMEs. On the basis of this<br />

finding, a new approach has evolved.<br />

WHAT IS NEW ABOUT <strong>BDS</strong> MARKET DEVELOPMENT?<br />

The above rationale encapsulates four major differences between the new approach of <strong>BDS</strong><br />

<strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> and “conventional” approaches to <strong>BDS</strong>. 6<br />

Figure 3: What Is Believed (stated or implied)<br />

SMEs as:<br />

Key providers:<br />

The Old<br />

Thankful beneficiaries of<br />

charity<br />

Government/government<br />

organizations<br />

The New<br />

Discerning consumers<br />

of services<br />

Private sector in<br />

functioning <strong>market</strong>s<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> as: Primarily public goods Private services<br />

5<br />

6<br />

Committee of Donor Agencies for Small Enterprise Development (January 1998).<br />

In reality, there have been gradations of change among agencies over several years rather than the sudden,<br />

dramatic shift implied here.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


9<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> financed: Primarily by the state Through provider–<br />

consumer transactions<br />

What <strong>BDS</strong> Is<br />

The Old: Previously, definitions of <strong>BDS</strong>, reflecting the above beliefs, emphasized donors’<br />

(supply-side) view of what was good for SMEs, focusing on training and counseling.<br />

The New: From a <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> perspective, the new definition of <strong>BDS</strong> reflects<br />

SMEs’ own views (demand-side) and is therefore much broader, in keeping with the breadth<br />

of services suggested by Figure 3. <strong>BDS</strong> is:<br />

any nonfinancial service to business, offered on either a formal or an informal basis.<br />

This definition requires further clarification. Included in the definition are services such as<br />

training/skills <strong>development</strong>, design, advertising, network brokering, courier delivery,<br />

computer services, business consultancy, security services, legal services, commission sales,<br />

accounting/auditing, <strong>market</strong> research, technical information, Web-site design and<br />

management, equipment repair and maintenance, and conference organizing.<br />

These correspond to intermediate or producer services (within the broad tertiary, or services,<br />

sector) as defined in the standard industrial classification—that is, services that are sold from<br />

one business to another (and not to the final consumer).<br />

Also included are services in which no formal fee-paying transaction takes place and services<br />

that are hidden in economic statistics but that nonetheless are important. 7 Especially<br />

important are services offered formally or informally from one business to another—such as<br />

advice, training, introductions, and <strong>market</strong> information.<br />

Excluded from the definition are:<br />

• Financial services; 8<br />

• Physical products: manufactured goods or raw materials;<br />

• Utilities: water, electricity, and gas;<br />

• Government services aimed at the wider community, including infrastructure, community<br />

and social services, and basic health care and education;<br />

7 Anderson (April 2000) presents findings from a survey he conducted on the access to and use of <strong>BDS</strong> in these<br />

countries by microenterprises. The revealing finding of this study is that many <strong>BDS</strong> are embedded in<br />

existing trade relationships or in informal networks, and that these are the primary channels for service access<br />

for small firms. This finding requires <strong>BDS</strong> practitioners to look beyond fee-for-service transactions to a<br />

range of different service-delivery channels and payment options.<br />

8<br />

These are business services but are the subject of many other <strong>guide</strong>s and are not the focus here.<br />

Chapter One—Why <strong>BDS</strong> Market Development?<br />

Why It Is Important and What Is New about It


10<br />

• Advocacy: for the business community as a whole (rather than for individual businesses);<br />

and<br />

• Buying services: in which the provider buys products from SMEs (rather than the other way<br />

around).<br />

[stopped 8/2]<br />

There are some exceptions to the above discussion. Although the definition above provides a<br />

basis for understanding <strong>BDS</strong>, it would be foolhardy to strive for a “watertight” definition of<br />

<strong>BDS</strong>. When services are such a vital component of economies, linked closely with<br />

manufacture and trade, there will always be blurred edges around any definition. For<br />

example:<br />

• Some services are part of a trading relationship in physical goods—for example, design<br />

advice and <strong>market</strong> information between retailers and manufacturers or the advice and<br />

services offered in a managed workspace environment. To unbundle services from<br />

products in these situations may be pointless.<br />

• Technology <strong>development</strong> (and privatization) has allowed a range of new services to be<br />

developed associated with utilities.<br />

It is also important to distinguish between buyer-seller relationships for goods—which we<br />

have classified here as not <strong>BDS</strong>—and commission-sales relationships—which we have<br />

classified as <strong>BDS</strong>. In the former, the buyer pays the money, takes title and ownership of a<br />

product; in the latter, products are sold on behalf of a producer without title passing to the<br />

other party. Clearly, this is a fine line—but while the latter is providing a service (and being<br />

paid for it) the former is buying a product (and paying for it). 9<br />

This element of looseness in definition is inevitable (and to be welcomed) if our notion of<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> is one that has practical meaning in business environments. This sets the context for<br />

donor interventions. However, it is important that this is not interpreted as a blanket<br />

justification for donor interventions “everywhere”; on the contrary, interventions need to be<br />

justified on the basis of rigorous analysis and criteria.<br />

Main Objective<br />

The Old: donor-supported approaches to <strong>BDS</strong> have focused on building the capacity of<br />

organizations—partners of donor agencies—to deliver improved services or on delivering<br />

services directly.<br />

The New: from a <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> perspective, the main objective of interventions<br />

should be improved functioning of <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong>s.<br />

9<br />

A further complication arises here because often buyers of products provide services—design, <strong>market</strong><br />

information, and access—bundled within their purchase. However, this does not contradict the basic<br />

difference between providing a service and buying a product.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


11<br />

Approach<br />

The Old: previously, approaches have supported<br />

organizations—usually government-related—in<br />

designing and delivering <strong>BDS</strong> with an implicit<br />

assumption of continued subsidy and often<br />

standardized <strong>BDS</strong>.<br />

The New: above all, the <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong><br />

<strong>development</strong> paradigm demands a different<br />

approach to intervention on the part of donors. It<br />

is one built on four related ideas: 10<br />

1. The starting point for intervention design<br />

should be a rigorous understanding of <strong>BDS</strong><br />

<strong>market</strong>s; <strong>market</strong>-research tools can be a<br />

valuable means of achieving this—that is,<br />

where are we now? (Chapter Two)<br />

2. Interventions need to develop a clear view of<br />

how <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong>s will operate in a<br />

sustainable manner by linking key <strong>market</strong><br />

functions with actors —that is, where do we<br />

want to go? (Chapter Three)<br />

3. In their design and implementation,<br />

interventions need to observe, interpret, and<br />

give more specific meaning to the <strong>BDS</strong><br />

principles of good practice—that is, how do<br />

we get there? (Chapter Four)<br />

4. Given a <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> approach, we<br />

need to determine what defines success in a<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> intervention and what can and cannot be<br />

usefully measured to improve or prove<br />

success needs to be determined—that is, how<br />

do we assess our performance? (Chapter<br />

Five)<br />

10 These issues form the basis of the remainder of this <strong>guide</strong>.<br />

Box 1: What’s in a Name?<br />

Ten years ago, <strong>BDS</strong> was an unknown<br />

abbreviation in the <strong>development</strong> world. Its<br />

birth and <strong>development</strong> in many ways<br />

represent the underlying changes that have<br />

taken place in <strong>development</strong> agencies’<br />

thinking in this field.<br />

First, donors talked about non-financial<br />

services. The problem is that it described<br />

what services weren’t rather than what they<br />

were and—obviously—these services to a<br />

rather unimportant, leftover second place<br />

behind financial services. It was hardly a<br />

name to inspire.<br />

Second came <strong>BDS</strong>. This is an improvement,<br />

but the reason for the inclusion of<br />

“<strong>development</strong>” is unclear. Some donors try to<br />

make a distinction between <strong>development</strong><br />

services and other services, but what this<br />

means is far from clear. From a business<br />

perspective—the consumer of services—<br />

”<strong>development</strong>” is a meaningless term;<br />

consumers purchase services that are useful,<br />

and are unlikely to want services that do not,<br />

in some way, contribute to the <strong>development</strong><br />

of their business. Businesses are much more<br />

likely to define services with regard to the<br />

benefits they gain from it. Once again, it<br />

seems that <strong>development</strong> here means some<br />

services are deemed by the supply-side<br />

(donors, governments, etc.) to be good and<br />

correspond to a public goods view of services<br />

rather than private services in <strong>market</strong>s.<br />

Third, <strong>BDS</strong> is where we are but business<br />

services is where we are going. Faced with<br />

the above arguments, it would be consistent<br />

and logical now for agencies to drop<br />

“<strong>development</strong>” and embrace terminology that<br />

is consistent with <strong>market</strong> realities.<br />

Do names matter? It depends. No, because<br />

substance matters more than labels. Yes,<br />

because inaccurate titles can prevent us from<br />

confronting the full implications of the <strong>BDS</strong><br />

<strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> approach.<br />

Chapter One—Why <strong>BDS</strong> Market Development?<br />

Why It Is Important and What Is New about It


13<br />

CHAPTER TWO<br />

WHERE WE ARE NOW—A FRAMEWORK FOR MARKET ASSESSMENT<br />

AND INTERVENTION CHOICE<br />

In the past, we designed projects by talking with SMEs. We learned they faced numerous constraints<br />

to growth, assumed there was no <strong>market</strong> to meet their needs, and from this level of understanding,<br />

we designed <strong>BDS</strong> interventions to unblock these constraints. But, when you take a closer look at how<br />

SMEs solve problems, who they turn to, what services they use, what they spend, three core design<br />

assumptions change: SMEs have much fewer wants than service needs; SMEs do pay—in one form<br />

or another—for services they want, and the <strong>market</strong> may be weak but it’s there. SMEs live and die<br />

within a <strong>market</strong> context. Few are actually touched by donors. Designers need to ask why the <strong>market</strong><br />

fails to serve SMEs with services they want. This requires that some form of <strong>market</strong> analysis should<br />

precede intervention.<br />

This chapter presents a framework to analyze <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong>s, focusing on demand and supply-side<br />

constraints that may prevent effective <strong>market</strong> operations. Building on this, the chapter identifies<br />

options to delineate <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong>s for study and appropriate research tools. It concludes by linking<br />

<strong>market</strong> diagnosis to intervention choice. 11<br />

Key Questions:<br />

1. What makes <strong>market</strong>s effective?<br />

2. Why don’t <strong>market</strong>s work for SMEs?<br />

3. Is there potential for intervention?<br />

4. Where should interventions focus?<br />

5. What type of intervention is appropriate?<br />

FRAMEWORK FOR <strong>BDS</strong> MARKET ANALYSIS<br />

The starting point for interventions pursuing a <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> approach is an in-depth<br />

understanding of <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> conditions and, in particular, of the factors preventing <strong>market</strong>s<br />

from working effectively. Figure 4 presents a framework for understanding the relative<br />

effectiveness of the <strong>market</strong> for a <strong>BDS</strong>.<br />

Markets can be seen to be effective when transactions take place—that is, where there is<br />

exchange between supply and demand at a <strong>market</strong> price. 12 For this to happen, customers must<br />

be ready to purchase something (let’s call this “effective demand”) and providers must have<br />

something to sell (let’s call this “effective supply”). Understanding the dynamics of this<br />

interaction or transaction is the key to <strong>market</strong> analysis.<br />

11 This chapter is drawn from the MBP publication, “Designing <strong>BDS</strong> Interventions as if Markets Matter,” by M.<br />

Field, R. Hitchins, and M. Bear, November 2000. Available on www.mip.org.<br />

12 The price at which suppliers are prepared to sell and consumers are prepared to buy, in an unsubsidized<br />

situation.<br />

Chapter Two—Where We Are Now—A Framework for<br />

Market Assessment and Intervention Choice


14<br />

Figure 4: Framework for Understanding the Effectiveness of <strong>BDS</strong> Markets<br />

Non-existent <strong>market</strong><br />

No transactions between<br />

consumer and providers<br />

No<br />

demand<br />

Weak<br />

demand<br />

Effective<br />

demand<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> MARKET<br />

Level of Market<br />

Development<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> TRANSACTION<br />

Provider has something to<br />

sell<br />

AND<br />

Consumer is ready to buy<br />

Effective <strong>market</strong><br />

Extensive transactions between<br />

consumers and providers<br />

Effective<br />

supply<br />

Weak<br />

supply<br />

No supply<br />

WHY ISN’T THE MARKET WORKING?<br />

Figure 5 shows the anatomy of an effective<br />

interaction—transaction—between a consumer<br />

and a service provider. The consumer (follow the<br />

black arrow) recognizes the causes of<br />

underperformance, concludes that a solution is<br />

required, and is willing to pay for a problemsolving<br />

service. The provider (follow the white<br />

arrow) has the ability to present an attractive offer<br />

that the consumer wants, and has the technical<br />

know-how to solve the problem with demonstrated<br />

positive impact on business performance.<br />

The elements of an effective transaction can also<br />

help explain why <strong>market</strong> mechanisms fail to serve<br />

SMEs: consumers may confuse symptoms with<br />

causes, they may not know about the existence of<br />

solutions or services or seek the wrong solutions;<br />

providers may not have presented offers SMEs<br />

value or want, or if they do, they may lack the<br />

technical know-how to deliver the results<br />

promised in their offer. The core rationale for an<br />

intervention is to address the demand and/or<br />

supply-side constraints that prevent <strong>market</strong>s from<br />

serving the service demands of SMEs.<br />

Box 2: Some Rudimentary<br />

Economics<br />

Economic theory describes a <strong>market</strong> as<br />

a set of arrangements by which buyers<br />

and sellers are in contact to exchange<br />

goods or services.* The level or volume<br />

of exchange or transaction that occurs<br />

between the sellers and buyers of a<br />

given good or service determines a<br />

<strong>market</strong>’s effectiveness. Theory also tells<br />

us that transactions between demand<br />

and supply are determined by an<br />

equilibrium price—that is, the price at<br />

which quantity supplied equals the<br />

quantity demanded. In trying to<br />

understand <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> failure, we<br />

need to look beyond price (which in<br />

effect causes movements along demand<br />

and supply curves). We need to look at<br />

the other underlying factors, described<br />

below, which actually shift demand and<br />

supply curves—determining their<br />

position or shape—and thus determine<br />

the nature of demand for and supply of<br />

<strong>BDS</strong>.<br />

*Begg, D., Fischer, S., and Dornbusch, R.<br />

Economics (1987). McGraw-Hill Book<br />

Company (UK) Ltd.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


15<br />

The flow diagram of an effective transaction shows that demand and supply for <strong>BDS</strong> are<br />

composed of different elements, each of which in turn can be influenced by a range of<br />

internal and external factors (see Box 3). Demand and supply must be considered separately<br />

to understand how the two interact for a transaction to take place. Based on this assessment<br />

of demand- and supply-side weaknesses (or strengths), it is possible to ascertain the level of<br />

<strong>market</strong> effectiveness and determine which interventions (<strong>market</strong>-based instruments and<br />

incentives) are consistent with the goal of developing more effective <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong>s for SMEs.<br />

Figure 5: Anatomy of a <strong>BDS</strong> Transaction<br />

SME UNDER-<br />

PERFORMANCE A<br />

• low profits<br />

• high fixed costs<br />

• low value-added<br />

• stagnant sales<br />

• zero growth<br />

• insufficient <strong>market</strong><br />

• excessive indebtedness<br />

• bankruptcy and failure<br />

• etc.<br />

Impact on SME<br />

performance<br />

Causes of underperformance<br />

are<br />

recognized<br />

SME CONSTRAINTS<br />

& PROBLEMS<br />

• skills deficiencies<br />

• limited <strong>market</strong> information<br />

• poor financial & inventory<br />

control<br />

• inadequate processes,<br />

systems, equipment<br />

• inefficient resource use<br />

• etc.<br />

B<br />

Demand-side flow<br />

Supply-side flow<br />

Solution is<br />

required<br />

Technical<br />

know-how to<br />

solve SME<br />

problems<br />

SOURCES OF SERVICES D<br />

Market mechanisms<br />

that can make a 'service'<br />

available:<br />

• friends & family<br />

• informal networks<br />

• other businesses<br />

• fee-for- service providers<br />

• etc.<br />

Willingness to<br />

purchase a service<br />

Ability to present an<br />

‘offer’ that SMEs want<br />

SOLUTIONS &<br />

REQUIREMENTS C<br />

Specific 'services' such as<br />

• training<br />

• advice<br />

• information media<br />

• accounting services<br />

• after sales product support<br />

• product distribution (e.g.<br />

courier services)<br />

• etc.<br />

Chapter Two—Where We Are Now—A Framework for<br />

Market Assessment and Intervention Choice


16<br />

Box 3: Influences on Demand and Supply<br />

Demand<br />

Recognition of need for a solution can be affected by a variety of internal and external factors. For<br />

example:<br />

Internal: SMEs’ education, physical location, and exposure to peers and competition may all affect<br />

awareness of business problems and available solutions.<br />

External: In most low-income countries, <strong>market</strong> information is limited or distorted; subsidies to reduce<br />

service price below <strong>market</strong> rate can encourage an SME to use a service that may not be appropriate;<br />

difficult economic and political environment may discourage use of a service (such as financial<br />

management in a tax harsh setting) and disguise internal problems within the business; donor<br />

programs to promote other activities (e.g. credit) may distort businesses’ preferences for and<br />

recognition of services.<br />

Willingness to pay can be similarly affected. For example:<br />

Internal: SMEs’ education, physical location, exposure to peers and competition, and their networks<br />

(access to informal sources) may all affect their valuation of services.<br />

External: Subsidies to reduce service price may stimulate consumption of services in the short term,<br />

but, if those services fail to address business requirements or expectations, willingness to pay can be<br />

adversely affected. Equally, willingness to pay for the services of an unsubsidized provider will be<br />

reduced (see below). The prestige of the donor can also affect businesses’ willingness to pay: SMEs<br />

may expect to receive cheap or free services, and they may perceive donor-supported services to be<br />

superior to those offered by local competitors. In fact, continuous donor subsidy may indicate lack of<br />

any real <strong>market</strong> value for the service.<br />

Supply<br />

Ability to present an attractive offer that consumers want can be affected by a variety of internal and<br />

external factors. For example:<br />

Internal: Service providers’ <strong>market</strong>ing skills and information are highly influential, but, equally if the<br />

service provider has a high cost base (arising from expensive staff, premises, or equipment), this<br />

feeds through into a high price, undermining the attractiveness of its service offer, no matter how<br />

good it is. An inconvenient location or staff with the wrong culture or background can have the same<br />

effect.<br />

External factors: Donor support for competitors (for example, in the form of subsidized services) can<br />

weaken an unsubsidized provider offer. Equally intensive donor support for capacity building can<br />

develop the kind of inappropriate structures described above, with adverse effects on costs, price,<br />

and the like.<br />

Technical know-how to solve business problems can be similarly affected. For example:<br />

Internal: The technical and experience of key people, the networks, and the ability of service provider<br />

to access new information, technology, and develop products are important.<br />

External: There are wider constraints to information and knowledge, such as inadequate education;<br />

donor support for capacity <strong>development</strong> that is inappropriate for SMEs; and donor support for<br />

importing generic products from advanced economies (this does not develop service providers’<br />

capacity to develop their own products on an ongoing basis in response to changing and evolving<br />

local requirements.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


17<br />

KEY CHARACTERISTICS OF EFFECTIVE DEMAND<br />

Effective demand, as defined in this paper, is when recognition of the need to solve a<br />

problem intersects with willingness to pay for a solution to the problem. We choose<br />

“recognition of the need to solve a problem” to indicate the consumer’s readiness to act on a<br />

problem: the consumer may not know the best solution to his or her business or <strong>market</strong><br />

problem, for example, but she or he knows there is a problem that needs to be solved by<br />

outside sources. 13 We are looking to determine if customers have no knowledge of their<br />

problem (lost), whether there is knowledge of a problem but not sure which one (searching),<br />

or whether they know their specific problem and want to solve it (found). This is not static;<br />

this can be influenced by both internal and external factors including education, experience,<br />

actions of peers, and supplier promotion. We choose “willingness to pay” as the second key<br />

characteristic of demand. Willingness to pay is indicative of the buyers’ motivation to seek<br />

outside assistance to effect a change. Willingness to pay ranges from no willingness, some<br />

willingness (skeptical), to high willingness (has the money and is ready to put it on the<br />

table). 14 Again external factors can be highly influential, particularly in terms of consumers’<br />

attitude to valuation and price (Figure 6).<br />

When SMEs exhibit a high level of recognition of need to solve a problem and a high<br />

willingness to pay for a solution, demand is effective—they are ready to purchase something.<br />

This presents a strong <strong>market</strong> opportunity for the <strong>BDS</strong> supplier. Conversely, if both<br />

recognition of a need to solve a problem and willingness to pay are very low or absent,<br />

demand is non-existent and <strong>market</strong> opportunities are negligible. A weak-demand situation<br />

might be when recognition of a need to solve a problem is well established, but willingness<br />

to pay is low or conversely when there is willingness to pay but little or no recognition of a<br />

problem, or a combination of both. The <strong>market</strong> opportunity in a weak-demand situation is<br />

limited, unless the service provider can overcome the willingness to pay problem or assist<br />

consumers to increase awareness of business problems and the availability (and value) of<br />

relevant solutions.<br />

13 Modern <strong>market</strong>ing teaches us that the purchase decision goes through different stages, starting with need<br />

recognition, the search for information on options, and the weighing of alternatives. In many developingcountry<br />

<strong>market</strong>s, consumers have a difficult time assessing options because of the information-poor<br />

environments in which they operate.<br />

14 Capacity to pay is not tracked separately. Willingness is a better proxy for motivation than capacity.<br />

Willingness is a precondition for a successful <strong>market</strong> transaction. Low capacity to pay is something that can<br />

be fixed—for example, through credit or different payment terms.<br />

Chapter Two—Where We Are Now—A Framework for<br />

Market Assessment and Intervention Choice


18<br />

Figure 6: Quadrant of Demand-side Conditions<br />

Recognition<br />

of a need for<br />

a solution<br />

high<br />

low<br />

WEAK<br />

DEMAND<br />

NO DEMAND<br />

EFFECTIVE<br />

DEMAND<br />

WEAK<br />

DEMAND<br />

low<br />

high<br />

Willingness to pay for a solution<br />

KEY CHARACTERISTICS OF EFFECTIVE SUPPLY<br />

We choose two factors to define effective supply: the ability to present an attractive offer<br />

(such as products) that SMEs want and the technical know-how to solve problems. Like the<br />

demand side of the <strong>market</strong> equation, these factors must be present and they are likely to<br />

evolve along separate paths. Specifically, one could imagine a situation where a <strong>BDS</strong><br />

supplier is very good at packaging an attractive offer—convincing the consumer to purchase<br />

a service—but is unable to deliver a solution to the SME’s problem. The supplier may be<br />

effective at <strong>market</strong>ing a training product, for example, but is unable to deliver a business<br />

solution as advertised. The converse is also true when a supplier has the technical know-how<br />

to solve the problem (it has skills, a track record), but it lacks the ability to package an<br />

attractive offer, perhaps because it lacks <strong>market</strong>ing skills or because of more fundamental<br />

structural problems like cost base or location (see Box 3). Suppliers may begin to sell their<br />

service below costs, or may not be able to develop repeat clients because the client did not<br />

perceive the benefit to be worth the cost even though the problem was actually solved. Both<br />

of these factors—an attractive offer consumers want and the technical know-how to<br />

deliver—must be present to develop effective supply over time.<br />

When service providers have both the offer and the technical know-how, supply is effective.<br />

If, in contrast, a service provider has the technical know-how but lacks the ability to package<br />

and present attractive offers, supply is weak. The converse also describes weak supply—<br />

suppliers are good at <strong>market</strong>ing but are unable to solve problems with their products. (In<br />

reality, a combination of both scenarios often lies behind supply-side weakness.) Nonexistent<br />

supply results from service providers lacking both appropriate skills and the ability to<br />

make an attractive offer to SMEs.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


19<br />

Figure 7: Quadrant of Supply-side Conditions<br />

Technical<br />

know how to<br />

solve SME<br />

problems<br />

high<br />

low<br />

WEAK<br />

SUPPLY<br />

NO SUPPLY<br />

EFFECTIVE<br />

SUPPLY<br />

WEAK<br />

SUPPLY<br />

low<br />

high<br />

Ability to present an offer<br />

consumers want<br />

The objective of analyzing demand and supply is to identify specific constraints to the<br />

availability of effective <strong>BDS</strong> for SMEs, which can then be the basis for designing an<br />

intervention. Table 1 considers the implications of various demand- and supply-side<br />

characteristics on intervention rationale.<br />

Separate analysis of <strong>BDS</strong> demand and supply generates an understanding of the overall<br />

<strong>market</strong> dynamics and level of <strong>development</strong> of a given <strong>market</strong> situation.<br />

DETERMINING BOUNDARIES AND LEVEL OF EFFORT IN ANALYZING A MARKET<br />

Market Boundaries<br />

This generic picture of a <strong>market</strong> needs to get more specific when conducting an analysis. An<br />

important first step is to identify the boundaries of a <strong>market</strong> analysis. This will determine the<br />

nature of analysis and its outcome. For example, if the <strong>market</strong> is defined narrowly (for<br />

example, small business users of public calling offices), analysis can be much more specific<br />

and detailed. It will probably be more manageable too. In contrast, a broader <strong>market</strong><br />

definition (all <strong>BDS</strong> consumption nationwide by all enterprises) will generally yield only an<br />

overview-level of analysis.<br />

Market parameters are frequently pre-determined by governments or donors and include:<br />

• Geography—such as a neighborhood, postal area, town, province, and country;<br />

• Products—such as consumers of specific types of service such as telecommunications or<br />

newspaper advertising;<br />

Chapter Two—Where We Are Now—A Framework for<br />

Market Assessment and Intervention Choice


20<br />

Table 1: Implications of Different Market Conditions for Interventions<br />

DEMAND<br />

Analysis Consumer Profile (SMEs) Implications for Intervention<br />

SMEs know what their problems are and will Rationale for demand-side<br />

pay for solutions. They are looking for a intervention is limited. However,<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> provider to deliver a solution at a rationale may be justified to stimulate<br />

reasonable price.<br />

specific parts of the population where<br />

Effective Demand<br />

• High recognition of<br />

problem<br />

• High willingness to<br />

pay<br />

Weak Demand<br />

• High recognition of<br />

problem<br />

• Low willingness to<br />

pay<br />

Weak Demand<br />

• Low recognition of<br />

problem<br />

• High willingness to<br />

pay<br />

Non-existent Demand<br />

• Low recognition of<br />

problem<br />

• Low willingness to<br />

pay<br />

Effective Supply<br />

• High skills to solve<br />

business problems<br />

• High offer to<br />

businesses<br />

Weak Supply<br />

• High skills to solve<br />

business problems<br />

• Low offer to<br />

businesses<br />

SMEs know what the problems are and are<br />

looking for solutions but are skeptical about<br />

the value of existing services and are,<br />

therefore, unwilling to pay.<br />

SMEs seek some form of assistance to<br />

solve a problem and will to pay for this.<br />

However, they are uncertain what the actual<br />

problem is, often resulting in wrong choice of<br />

solution. This, in turn, can lead to SME<br />

dissatisfaction and unwillingness to use or<br />

pay for <strong>BDS</strong> in the future.<br />

This is not uncommon among<br />

entrepreneurs. SMEs do not see there is a<br />

problem to be solved, and are not prepared<br />

to pay for any form of external assistance.<br />

Often, firms externalize their problems and<br />

conclude there is nothing they can do to fix<br />

them because it is out of their control.<br />

SUPPLY<br />

demand is weaker.<br />

Rationale for demand-side<br />

intervention is to increase SME<br />

perception or awareness of service<br />

benefit and value, such as through<br />

demonstration or trial. Note that<br />

unwillingness to pay may be related<br />

to weak supply offer.<br />

The rationale for demand-side<br />

intervention is to improve business<br />

diagnosis and improve consumer<br />

access to information about what<br />

benefits specific services can deliver.<br />

Rationale for any intervention when<br />

demand is entirely absent is limited.<br />

Analysis Provider Profile Implications for Intervention<br />

The service provider has good capacity to Rationale for supply-side intervention<br />

solve business problems and the ability to is limited. It may be justified by equity<br />

package that into an offer that consumers concerns—for example, stimulate<br />

want.<br />

expansion into underserved <strong>market</strong><br />

Weak Supply<br />

• Low skills to solve<br />

business problems<br />

• High offer to<br />

businesses<br />

Non-existent Supply<br />

• Low skills to solve<br />

business problems<br />

• Low offer to<br />

businesses<br />

Despite having sound skills, the service<br />

provider lacks <strong>market</strong>ing know-how; It is<br />

unable to demonstrate the value of its<br />

service, a common problem for suppliers<br />

because of the difficulty of showing the<br />

value of a product prior to its use. The offer<br />

is not attractive.<br />

This scenario is not as strange as it seems!<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> providers in many cases promise<br />

results but lack the technical capacity to<br />

deliver effective solutions.<br />

Such a scenario is damaging for service<br />

provision as it undermines credibility and<br />

damages demand.<br />

The service provider lacks any capacity to<br />

sell business solutions. Effectively the<br />

service provider is nothing more than an<br />

empty shell.<br />

areas.<br />

Rationale for supply-side intervention<br />

is to develop the capacity of service<br />

providers to develop and <strong>market</strong><br />

appropriate products—develop the<br />

offer. Note that weak supply offer<br />

might be exacerbated by low<br />

willingness to pay on the demand<br />

side.<br />

The rationale for intervention is to<br />

develop provider technical skills.<br />

However the question must be asked<br />

why support service providers lack<br />

the ability to solve business problems<br />

in the first place?<br />

Rationale for intervention when<br />

supply-side capacity is non-existent is<br />

dubious: there is nothing to work with!<br />

Intervention may be warranted if<br />

demand is particularly strong.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


21<br />

• Consumers—such as female-owned businesses and formally registered businesses; and<br />

• Sub-sector—such as small-scale manufacturing, textile production, and agro-processing.<br />

The <strong>market</strong> may also be delineated by the criteria of the intervening agency, based on:<br />

• Strategic focus—such as priority groups and environmental protection; and<br />

• Capacity of Intervening Agency—that is, what the agency can do; its experience and<br />

competence in certain types of intervention (for example, vouchers) or with specific subsectors<br />

(such as metal workshops).<br />

Although it is sensible to delineate the <strong>market</strong> in terms<br />

of a facilitators’ core competence, there is a risk of<br />

shaping the view of the <strong>market</strong> problem (and thus the<br />

intervention) by what we want it to be, not what it<br />

really is. We need to guard against this risk by looking<br />

at both sides of the <strong>market</strong> equation—what consumers<br />

want and what providers can do—and developing an<br />

accurate <strong>market</strong> picture on the basis of a more wellrounded<br />

view.<br />

Level of Effort<br />

How much research is required is typically a function<br />

of two variables: who’s doing the assessment, and the<br />

relative closeness of the assessor to the <strong>market</strong>. The<br />

further away from the <strong>market</strong> an organization is and<br />

the bigger—and more complex—it is, the more formal<br />

and extensive should be the <strong>market</strong> assessment.<br />

Donors are typically far from <strong>market</strong>s and should rely<br />

on formal research techniques as the basis for making<br />

decisions on intervention options. Large commercial<br />

providers of services—and because of their <strong>market</strong><br />

reach and organizational complex—perform formal<br />

and structure <strong>market</strong> research as the basis for business<br />

decisions. In contrast, the closer to the <strong>market</strong> (or in<br />

the <strong>market</strong>) and the smaller the organization or firm<br />

(less complex), the more <strong>market</strong> analysis can be based<br />

Box 4: Market-Analysis Tools<br />

The nature of this analysis lends itself to<br />

<strong>market</strong>-research-style studies, rather<br />

than more conventional <strong>development</strong>al<br />

assessments. A usage, attitude, and<br />

image (UAI) survey is a <strong>market</strong>-research<br />

tool used by firms to take a broad look<br />

at the current <strong>market</strong> for a specific<br />

service from known suppliers. It can<br />

also be used to assess demand of<br />

multiple <strong>BDS</strong> products from different<br />

<strong>market</strong>s. Focus-group discussions is a<br />

qualitative <strong>market</strong> research tool used to<br />

better understand how consumers<br />

experience the use of services by<br />

exploring with “qualified respondents”<br />

how they perceive, choose, evaluate,<br />

and value <strong>BDS</strong>. When used in<br />

combination, these <strong>market</strong>-research<br />

tools can be used to form a picture of<br />

the <strong>market</strong> and to better pinpoint <strong>market</strong><br />

weaknesses. The information permits an<br />

analysis of demand but also offers a<br />

consumer’s perspective on supply by<br />

looking at sources of services,<br />

satisfaction by different providers, and<br />

the use of substitutes. Consumer<br />

research methods can ‘prepare the<br />

ground’ for a closer look at the supply<br />

side of the <strong>market</strong> using tailored<br />

institutional assessment tools. 15<br />

15 For more detail on the UAI and other <strong>market</strong> research tools, see MBP publication, “Applying Market<br />

Research Tools to the Design and Improvement of Business Development Services,” Alexandra Overy<br />

Miehlbradt, July 1999.<br />

Chapter Two—Where We Are Now—A Framework for<br />

Market Assessment and Intervention Choice


22<br />

on learning by doing and on more informal <strong>market</strong> assessment tools. Facilitators are better<br />

positioned in the <strong>market</strong> than donors but not in it; the <strong>market</strong> research they do should be<br />

systematic and appropriate to the context. Small commercial providers—by virtue of their<br />

<strong>market</strong> position—can rely more on customer feedback and test <strong>market</strong>ing than on formal, upfront<br />

<strong>market</strong> assessment because they are in frequent contact with customers. They receive<br />

regular feedback both in the comments of customers and their willingness to pay for services.<br />

The outcome of a <strong>market</strong> analysis will be used to answer the following questions:<br />

• Is there potential for intervention?<br />

• Where should interventions focus?<br />

• What type of intervention is appropriate?<br />

IS THERE POTENTIAL FOR INTERVENTION?<br />

The forgoing analysis looked separately at the relative effectiveness of demand and supply<br />

for a service. What makes a <strong>market</strong> is the interaction between the two: the greater the<br />

overlap, the more developed the <strong>market</strong>. The relative <strong>development</strong> of the <strong>market</strong> informs the<br />

potential for intervention. Figure 8 shows the relationship between the analysis of demand<br />

and supply and the potential for outside intervention. At either ends of the <strong>market</strong> continuum,<br />

there is little potential for intervention for different reasons. In a non-existent <strong>market</strong>, there is<br />

little to build on, especially for higher-end services such as training and consulting. There is<br />

also limited potential for intervention in effective <strong>market</strong>s because intervention might do<br />

more to distort than develop the <strong>market</strong>. Potential is greatest for intervention when there is<br />

some overlap, however weak, between demand or supply.<br />

Figure 8: <strong>BDS</strong> Market Development and the Potential for Intervention<br />

NON-EXISTENT<br />

LEVEL OF MARKET DEVELOPMENT<br />

EFFECTIVE<br />

No Supply<br />

No Demand<br />

Effective Supply/Weak, No Demand<br />

Effective Demand/Weak, No Supply<br />

Weak Supply/Weak Demand<br />

Effective Supply<br />

Effective Demand<br />

LIMITED POTENTIAL<br />

FOR INTERVENTION<br />

There is nothing to build<br />

on.<br />

In practice, total absence<br />

of demand and supplyside<br />

activity is rare:<br />

- Remote rural areas<br />

- Survival level<br />

microenterprises<br />

- Disaster situations.<br />

GOOD POTENTIAL FOR<br />

INTERVENTION<br />

Interventions have the ability<br />

to 'leverage' existing activity.<br />

In practice, this is a common<br />

situation in most developing<br />

economies.<br />

NEED FOR INTERVENTION<br />

IS LIMITED<br />

Markets are effective and<br />

the private sector is vibrant.<br />

Intervention may distort<br />

private sector behavior.<br />

However, intervention may<br />

be justified for expansion and<br />

equity reasons.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


23<br />

WHERE SHOULD INTERVENTIONS FOCUS?<br />

Where potential does exist to develop <strong>market</strong>s for <strong>BDS</strong>, interventions should focus on<br />

overcoming the most critical constraints—on either the supply or demand side—that prevent<br />

the <strong>market</strong> from functioning more effectively for<br />

SMEs. Box 5 provides an illustrative real life<br />

example of matching interventions to an<br />

identified <strong>market</strong> weakness; it describes a case—<br />

an export promotion project in West Bank and<br />

Gaza—where effective demand for export<br />

services existed but supply of services was weak<br />

or non-existent.<br />

The Venn diagram in Figure 9 shows<br />

conceptually how this example illustrates the<br />

link between <strong>market</strong> diagnosis and intervention<br />

focus. The <strong>market</strong> evolves from a non-existent to<br />

an effective <strong>market</strong> as supply enlarges and aligns<br />

itself with demand. Demand for quality export<br />

services is high and is depicted by the large size<br />

of the ‘D’ circle. Supply ‘S’, however, is weak<br />

because there are few if any suppliers with the<br />

right type of export <strong>market</strong>ing services. Supply is<br />

depicted by the smaller ‘S’ circle. This scenario<br />

shows supply enlarging over time and eventually<br />

aligning itself with demand. The enlarged supply<br />

circle was the result of different interventions,<br />

including:<br />

• Supplier capacity building through links with<br />

foreign firms;<br />

• Information provision about requirements for<br />

exporters;<br />

• Bottom-line performance criteria to assess<br />

value; and<br />

• Matching grants for suppliers to overcome<br />

high initial start-up costs of developing the<br />

appropriate offer for exporters.<br />

Box 5: Matching Intervention to<br />

Identified Market Weakness in Gaza<br />

The Small Business Support Project<br />

(SBSP), working in the West Bank and<br />

Gaza, identified the service-supply<br />

constraint as the weak <strong>market</strong> factor<br />

and initiated a commercial approach to<br />

develop a reliable consulting service<br />

capacity locally for quality assurance<br />

services—such as ISO 9000 series<br />

manufacturing processes. Through a<br />

competitive procurement process, the<br />

project identified and selected three<br />

local companies that had the potential to<br />

deliver these services. With local<br />

demand in place and local service<br />

providers ready to team up with<br />

international experts, the project<br />

negotiated and facilitated commercial<br />

relationships between the local service<br />

providers and local manufacturers to<br />

cement the relationships and promote<br />

quality export services. Bottom-line<br />

targets, such as reduction in waste,<br />

increases in profitability and efficiency,<br />

and improved production management<br />

systems, changed perceived customer<br />

value over time. The initial ISO<br />

consulting project in 1996 took 12<br />

months and cost $35,000, with the<br />

project financing 75 percent of the cost.<br />

By the end of the project in 1999, ISO<br />

projects took 6 months and cost only<br />

$16,000 on average. Today, more than<br />

60 firms have achieved ISO certification<br />

with improved competitive performance.<br />

By focusing on the specific <strong>market</strong><br />

weakness—attractive offers to SME<br />

exporters—the project was able to build<br />

the <strong>market</strong> for export consulting<br />

services. Three local consulting firms<br />

report continuing demand for ISO<br />

services without SBSP financial or<br />

technical involvement.<br />

Chapter Two—Where We Are Now—A Framework for<br />

Market Assessment and Intervention Choice


24<br />

As supply expands, the overlap becomes larger, and it is this overlap that is defined as an<br />

effective <strong>market</strong>—supply and demand meeting each other’s needs, causing many transactions<br />

to take place at <strong>market</strong> prices.<br />

Figure 9: The Process of Overcoming a Supply Constraint<br />

Non-Existent<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> Market<br />

Effective<br />

S<br />

D<br />

S<br />

D<br />

S<br />

D S D<br />

WHAT TYPE OF INTERVENTION IS USEFUL?<br />

The goal of intervention is to develop <strong>market</strong>s so they can provide solutions to SME business<br />

service needs. Figure 10 shows intervention options that have been used to overcome<br />

consumer demand and/or supplier constraints to effective <strong>market</strong>s. Interventions options such<br />

as vouchers, matching grants, and information (including media campaigns and directories<br />

listing service providers) have been used to stimulate consumer demand by overcoming<br />

problems of awareness and understanding and the valuation of benefits and costs or their<br />

willingness to pay for business services. Intervention options such as product <strong>development</strong>,<br />

skills and management <strong>development</strong>, and venture finance have been used to remove supply<br />

constraint by addressing provider skills deficiencies, motivating entrepreneurial behavior,<br />

providing information on consumer preferences on products and features, and joint-funding<br />

to innovate and test new <strong>market</strong>s and products. Business linkages is both a demand-side and<br />

a supply-side intervention that tries to foster a culture of inter-firm linkages between SMEs<br />

(suppliers) and larger-firm buyers (providers of <strong>BDS</strong>). 16<br />

16 Emerging Good Practices in Business Development Services, The First Annual Seminar<br />

Turin Italy, 4-8 September, 2000, <strong>BDS</strong> Seminar Reader by Mary McVay and Alexandra<br />

Overy Meihlbradt provides case examples of the different interventions options noted here.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


25<br />

Figure 10: Matching Market Analysis to Intervention Options<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> Providers<br />

Constrained by:<br />

Limited Information—<br />

about <strong>market</strong><br />

opportunities<br />

Skills Deficiencies—<br />

technical or business<br />

Operational<br />

Deficiencies—resources,<br />

systems, structures<br />

Inappropriate Products<br />

Environment—distortions<br />

and barriers to activity<br />

Intervention Options<br />

Supply-side<br />

Product<br />

<strong>development</strong><br />

Venture finance<br />

Technical<br />

assistance<br />

Training<br />

EFFECTIVE<br />

MARKET<br />

Supply =<br />

Demand<br />

Market provides<br />

solutions that<br />

SMEs want<br />

Demand-side<br />

Vouchers<br />

Matching<br />

grants<br />

Information<br />

Business Linkages<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> Consumers<br />

Constrained by:<br />

Limited Information<br />

or Awareness—about<br />

problems or solutions<br />

Valuation Problems—<br />

affecting willingness to<br />

pay<br />

Limited Resources—<br />

to assess or purchase<br />

services<br />

Environment—<br />

pervasive subsidy<br />

reduces willingness to<br />

pay<br />

Figure 10 is necessarily simplistic. In reality,<br />

interventions will often affect both supply and demand<br />

sides. Box 6 provides an example from a pilot voucher<br />

project in the Ukraine.<br />

CONCLUDING COMMENTS<br />

From the preceding discussion, and the conceptual<br />

framework for <strong>market</strong> analysis presented, four key<br />

points emerge:<br />

1. SMEs live and die within a <strong>market</strong> context. Few are<br />

actually touched by donors 18 . Designers need to<br />

first ask why the <strong>market</strong> fails to serve SMEs with<br />

Box 6: Interventions Affecting Demand<br />

and Supply Sides<br />

In a post-test survey, 17 voucher users said<br />

that they would have paid the full cost of<br />

training in computers and business<br />

accounting had they known that these<br />

services were available. This finding<br />

indicates that vouchers were able to<br />

overcome a demand-side problem of limited<br />

information, which inhibited SMEs to<br />

recognize a business problem and seek an<br />

appropriate solution. The value of the<br />

voucher was as much in the information it<br />

conveyed as the discount it offered<br />

consumers to try to services once<br />

consumers learned about their availability.<br />

The same survey revealed that providers of<br />

computer training were encouraged to<br />

develop new courses based on the feedback<br />

they received from the trainees. The<br />

injection of demand stimulated and<br />

17 Field et al., Report on NewBizNet Pilot Voucher Scheme, 1999. motivated suppliers to develop products,<br />

18 “The Application of Market Led Tools in the Design of <strong>BDS</strong> Interventions enter new (Influencing <strong>market</strong>s, the and Price develop of Soup new in<br />

Nepal)” by Jim Tomecko of GTZ presented at the Donor Committee’s relationships. Asia conference The in survey Hanoi results reported illustrates the<br />

finding from a nationwide survey of <strong>BDS</strong> consumption across multiple the sectors twin effects and learned of some that instruments.<br />

“free<br />

services” – those offered by donor partners – were a fraction of the overall <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> estimated at<br />

$320,000 per year.<br />

Chapter Two—Where We Are Now—A Framework for<br />

Market Assessment and Intervention Choice


26<br />

services they want. This requires that some form of <strong>market</strong> analysis should precede<br />

intervention.<br />

2. Markets are formed through the interaction of supply and demand, which, even though<br />

they affect each other, are independent. This means that to understand why a <strong>market</strong> fails<br />

to serve SME one must understand the weaknesses in both supply and demand.<br />

3. Interventions should be tailored to the weaknesses of supply and/or demand, and should<br />

minimize long-term distortions by limiting subsidies and planning exit strategies.<br />

4. Sustainable access to <strong>BDS</strong> is not organization driven, but <strong>market</strong> driven. This means that<br />

measuring sustainability should be based on a dynamic <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> where transactions<br />

are ongoing and increasing, not on the success or failure of an individual organization.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


27<br />

CHAPTER THREE<br />

WHERE DO WE WANT TO GO?—DEVELOPING A CLEAR<br />

PICTURE OF SUSTAINABILITY<br />

We’ve always been interested in generating longer-term SME sector change and growth through<br />

our short-term interventions. The picture of <strong>BDS</strong> sustainability was clear: the state would continue<br />

to offer and pay for services because it was good for the country. Or is it: the picture depends on<br />

continued subsidy, and it blurs expectations between SMEs and suppliers. A more-focused picture<br />

for the future is one where the capacity of <strong>market</strong>s is strengthened to ensure sustainable access to<br />

<strong>BDS</strong>. Developing sustainable <strong>market</strong>s is not just concerned with transactions between <strong>BDS</strong><br />

consumers and suppliers but with a range of functions—information, research, product<br />

<strong>development</strong>, and regulation—without which transactions won’t take place.<br />

This chapter defines sustainability in <strong>BDS</strong> and sets out the reasons why an explicit view of<br />

sustainability in <strong>BDS</strong> is so important. The chapter sets out a framework for sustainability, linking key<br />

actors (and their core areas of competence) with supply-side functions, and summarizes what this<br />

sustainability picture might look like.<br />

Key Questions:<br />

1. What are core <strong>market</strong> functions?<br />

2. Who are the key <strong>market</strong> players?<br />

3. Which player performs what function best?<br />

4. Who pays for this function to be performed?<br />

WHAT DOES SUSTAINABILITY MEAN IN <strong>BDS</strong> MARKET DEVELOPMENT?<br />

The starting point in any intervention is an understanding of the <strong>market</strong> in which we’re<br />

interested and, in particular, of the constraints that inhibit <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong>. Parallel with<br />

this analysis, however, it is important to develop a clear view of where an intervention is<br />

going—that is, of how it is envisaged that <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong>s will operate in a sustainable manner<br />

in the longer term. Although sustainability has long-held a prominent place in <strong>development</strong><br />

vocabulary and is generally seen to be important, it is seldom defined tightly or<br />

operationalized into tangible objectives and activities. This has been especially so in <strong>BDS</strong><br />

interventions, and it is a flaw that needs to be remedied if <strong>BDS</strong> interventions, are to become<br />

more successful.<br />

To make sense of sustainability, we need to think through the implications flowing from a<br />

general definition. In general, sustainability is: 19<br />

19 From Sustainability in NGO <strong>development</strong> projects; ODA, 1995.<br />

Chapter Three—Where Do We Want to Go?—<br />

Developing a Clear Picture of Sustainability


28<br />

the capacity to ensure that benefits continue beyond the period of an initial intervention.<br />

Capacity is concerned with the <strong>market</strong><br />

capability to continue to offer services, and<br />

this is likely to be a combination of different<br />

actors performing different supply-side<br />

functions.<br />

“Capability” can include a wide range of<br />

factors—skills, motivations, systems, finances<br />

etc.—but in a simplified way can be reduced<br />

to two issues:<br />

⇒ The ability to do; and<br />

⇒ The ability to pay for/finance services.<br />

Beyond the period of an intervention:<br />

usefully, this reminds donors and facilitators<br />

they are there to be transient facilitators of<br />

change and not permanent fixtures on the<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> landscape.<br />

Benefits for SMEs are implied by their demand<br />

for services from providers—that is,<br />

demand/transactions is a proxy measure for<br />

benefits.<br />

Since SMEs need change and to become more<br />

differentiated, for benefits to continue services<br />

must also change; they cannot simply be a<br />

standardized, unchanging product offer.<br />

From this broad view, a general definition of sustainability in the context of <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong><br />

<strong>development</strong> is:<br />

The <strong>market</strong> capacity to ensure that relevant, differentiated <strong>BDS</strong> continue to<br />

be offered to and consumed by SMEs beyond the period of an intervention.<br />

Building on this, more specifically, we can say that:<br />

A transparent view of long-term sustainability in <strong>BDS</strong> therefore is one that<br />

defines <strong>market</strong> capacity in more depth, linking <strong>market</strong> players with <strong>market</strong><br />

functions by addressing the core questions of who does and who pays.<br />

Central to this definition is an institutional rather than organizational view of <strong>development</strong>.<br />

Although the terms “institution” and “organization” are often used inter-changeably, strictly<br />

speaking they are different.<br />

• Organizations are collections of individuals in a specific, recognizable entity and formal<br />

structure with internal rules.<br />

• Institutions are wider structures of individuals and organizations—formal and<br />

informal—in society or economy defined by mechanisms, relationships, values, and<br />

skills.<br />

Organizations are important and contribute to <strong>development</strong> objectives, but, ultimately, only<br />

institutional change can bring about lasting improvement. Although organizational<br />

<strong>development</strong> is concerned with developing individuals, managerial effectiveness, and<br />

systems and investing in physical assets, institutional <strong>development</strong> is aimed at overcoming<br />

the constraints that prevent people and organizations from working effectively together—<br />

such as information and linkages.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


29<br />

Markets are institutions. Developing sustainable <strong>market</strong>s, therefore, is not just concerned<br />

with individual organizations in a <strong>market</strong>place or only with the delivery and consumption of<br />

services—although this is the central activity in any <strong>market</strong>—but with the other functions<br />

that are needed to support core transactions. We return to these support functions in Chapter<br />

Five.<br />

WHY IS CLARITY IN SUSTAINABILITY SO IMPORTANT?<br />

Development agencies are interested in generating longer-term change and benefits through<br />

their short-term interventions. 20 If, however, the nature of this longer-term picture is not<br />

clear, it can permit inconsistency between what projects do and what they are trying to<br />

achieve. A clear view of sustainability imposes discipline and direction on interventions.<br />

Conversely, a vague and ill-considered view allows interventions to drift aimlessly.<br />

The contrast with microfinance is instructive. Whereas in microfinance the drive toward<br />

financially sustainable microfinance institutions is consistent with tight cost control, positive<br />

real interest rates, and rigorous repayment collection, in <strong>BDS</strong> imprecise views about payment<br />

for services (from SME clients) and subsidies (from under-resourced governments) in the<br />

longer-term allow interventions to:<br />

• Develop products that are too expensive or inappropriate for SMEs;<br />

• Let the cost base of providers rise so they become out of tune with SMEs (and in tune<br />

with donor money);<br />

• Corrupt SMEs with the expectation of large subsidies and <strong>BDS</strong> as a donor creation rather<br />

than a normal product in a <strong>market</strong>; and<br />

• Lure governments into involvements that are beyond their capacity.<br />

WHY HAS IT BEEN SO DIFFICULT TO DEVELOP CLEAR VIEWS OF SUSTAINABILITY IN <strong>BDS</strong>?<br />

This characteristic problem of lack of clarity about sustainability in <strong>BDS</strong> interventions stems<br />

from a number of factors:<br />

• Not a Neat Organization, an Unruly Market: whereas in microfinance our focus is on<br />

specific organizations and this provides real boundaries for analysis, in <strong>BDS</strong> we deal with<br />

<strong>market</strong>s that, inevitably, are more elusive, being characterized by many more players,<br />

multiple relationships, and loose boundaries.<br />

20 As opposed to relief agencies whose goals are inherently more short term.<br />

Chapter Three—Where Do We Want to Go?—<br />

Developing a Clear Picture of Sustainability


30<br />

• A Failure to Place <strong>BDS</strong> in a Market Context: related to the above point, most <strong>BDS</strong><br />

interventions have not tried to place their work in a <strong>market</strong> context and their view of<br />

sustainability, therefore, is inappropriate.<br />

• The Breadth of the Term: <strong>BDS</strong> as defined here covers a wide variety of services. This<br />

means that interventions need to be clear about what kind of services are being<br />

considered.<br />

• Some Areas of Legitimate Government Involvement …….: there are some services<br />

and functions that are likely to remain within the legitimate remit of governments. For<br />

example, basic research and <strong>development</strong> and some types of information provision are<br />

close to the education and knowledge base justifying state involvement. More capable<br />

governments may see themselves as the only actor capable of wider cluster <strong>development</strong><br />

or network coordination and brokering. However, the list is not especially long.<br />

• ……… But a History of Messy Government Involvement: partially stemming from<br />

public goods arguments but more often for other social and political factors, governments<br />

have been (and are) involved in <strong>BDS</strong> as subsidizers or organizers. The often-troubled<br />

history of interventions that have supported government in this role has been a key factor<br />

in leading agencies to <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong>. Governments in industrialized countries do<br />

often intervene extensively in <strong>BDS</strong>, and this agreement is sometimes used for continued<br />

efforts to raise low-income country governments’ capacity to provide <strong>BDS</strong> directly<br />

(rather than facilitate <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong>s). However, as we discuss below, this argument is<br />

fundamentally flawed. 21<br />

The above factors complicate the <strong>BDS</strong> context but none excuse failure to develop a<br />

sustainability picture for <strong>BDS</strong>. On the contrary, it is precisely because of this prevailing<br />

complexity that striving for a transparent view of the future in <strong>BDS</strong> is so important.<br />

A TRANSPARENT FRAMEWORK FOR SUSTAINABILITY IN <strong>BDS</strong><br />

To overcome these problems, interventions should develop explicit, transparent views of<br />

sustainability in <strong>BDS</strong>. Figure 11 offers a simple framework for a transparent sustainability<br />

picture. This graphic builds on the earlier definition in <strong>BDS</strong> and in particular on four key<br />

questions: what needs to be done, who are the main players, who does, and who pays. 22 Each<br />

is discussed below.<br />

21 See R. Bennett and P. Robson (1999); The <strong>market</strong> for external business advice services in Britain; ESRC.<br />

The Centre for Business Research for an example of a <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> in a high-income country where the<br />

rationale for government involvement is very unclear.<br />

22 There are some parallels here with mapping exercises in sub-sector analysis.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


31<br />

What Needs to Be Done?—Key Supply-side Functions<br />

Markets are dynamic because the factors influencing them are changing and SMEs needs and<br />

circumstances change. For <strong>market</strong>s to be sustainable—to meet the changing needs of and to<br />

deliver benefits to their SME consumers through transactions—a number of support<br />

functions need to be undertaken. In thinking about what needs to be done in a <strong>market</strong>, we<br />

need to identify these key functions. Our perspective here is supply side; the demand-side<br />

function is consumption of services. In reality, most interventions focus on the supply side.<br />

Figure 11: Sustainability in <strong>BDS</strong><br />

1. Market Functions<br />

Delivery of Services Product Development<br />

Coordination Research and Development<br />

Information<br />

Skills Enhancement Regulation Advocacy<br />

Facilitating<br />

interventions<br />

from<br />

government<br />

or donors<br />

3. Who Does?<br />

4. Who Pays?<br />

State<br />

Private<br />

sector<br />

(for-profit)<br />

Not-for-profit<br />

sector<br />

2. Key Supply-side Players<br />

Business<br />

membership<br />

organization<br />

s<br />

Business<br />

networks<br />

In order of priority, the main supply-side functions that need to be undertaken in any <strong>market</strong> are:<br />

• Delivery of Services: the supply-side of the transaction—the central function in any<br />

<strong>market</strong>;<br />

• Product Development: ranging from adaptation of products to existing <strong>market</strong>s to new<br />

products for new <strong>market</strong>s; responding to new customer requirements or using new<br />

information to pro-actively offer services in advance of customer recognition;<br />

• Skills/Capacity Enhancement: for providers of <strong>BDS</strong>, services to ensure that skills and<br />

knowledge in developing and delivering <strong>BDS</strong> are updated and refreshed;<br />

Chapter Three—Where Do We Want to Go?—<br />

Developing a Clear Picture of Sustainability


32<br />

• Research and Development: to develop new insights into <strong>market</strong> mechanisms,<br />

underlying <strong>market</strong> trends, and changes in SMEs that may eventually be useful in applied<br />

product <strong>development</strong> work; and<br />

• Regulation and Policy-making: the overarching framework of rules and policies within<br />

which <strong>market</strong>s operate. Often, regulation requires only a light touch to ensure that<br />

<strong>market</strong>s work effectively and reasonably freely.<br />

In addition, there are other functions that are possibly less important but may be useful in<br />

some situations. These include:<br />

• Basic Information Provision, which, for example, supports the <strong>development</strong> of <strong>market</strong>s<br />

generally rather than specific products (and providers). In many <strong>market</strong>s, information will<br />

be contained within products. Moreover, advances in technology, in urban and more<br />

developed economies, have created information-rich environments that reduce the need<br />

for a separate effort to provide information.<br />

• Advocacy, which, it could be argued, is important to ensure appropriately balanced<br />

government involvement in <strong>market</strong>s; and<br />

• Coordination: for some <strong>BDS</strong>, initial coordinating work might be necessary to develop<br />

the supply-demand relationship or to break down organizational barriers to cooperation<br />

(such as in cluster <strong>development</strong> or networks involving universities and the private sector).<br />

In many <strong>market</strong>s, of course, there is no coordination or any need for coordination.<br />

Who Are the Main Players?—Main Potential Actors on the<br />

Supply-side of a Market<br />

Having identified the key supply-side functions in the <strong>market</strong>place, we then need to think<br />

about who may undertake these. There are only a few options:<br />

a) Government and Government Organizations: this can be broken down further (local<br />

or regional government, etc.) but is essentially the public sector;<br />

b) For-profit Businesses, of any size or ownership form, ranging from self-employed to<br />

substantial corporations;<br />

c) Networks: formal or informal, business networks can be a powerful source of services—<br />

advice, contacts, skills, and the like;<br />

d) Business Membership Organizations: sector associations, chambers of commerce, and<br />

employers’ organizations whose principal role is advocacy; and<br />

e) Not-for-Profit Business: this could include nongovernmental organizations but also<br />

universities and educational institutions that may have some autonomy from government.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


33<br />

Box 7: Key Considerations in Assessing the Role of the State in <strong>BDS</strong><br />

Any valid picture of sustainability in <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong>s has to consider the role of government—what governments should and should<br />

not do. In doing so, a number of factors need to be taken into account.<br />

Key Principles and Issues: from the broad consensus on a <strong>market</strong>-friendly approach, the key priorities for governments<br />

pursuing poverty reduction are those functions that only they can do or that they can do better than others—meaning health,<br />

education, security, macroeconomic management, etc. Focus on core competence and subsidiary—delegating to the lowest<br />

possible level—is the key principle.<br />

Rationale: governments’ involvement in <strong>market</strong>places (such as <strong>BDS</strong>) can be justified on two grounds: <strong>market</strong> failure and equity<br />

concerns. Within these two headings, governments should focus on:<br />

• Public Goods—which are non-rival and non-excludable, meaning that consumption by one user doesn’t reduce supply to<br />

another and users can’t be prevented from consuming the good. These are regarded as a top priority for state intervention.<br />

• Markets Where Externalities and Imperfect Information Are Particularly Evident—where there are wider benefits to society<br />

from the consumption of a good beyond the individual consumer and where consumers and/or suppliers don’t have enough<br />

information to make the right decisions. These <strong>market</strong>s—where there are public goods aspects—are regarded as a<br />

secondary priority for state intervention.<br />

In fact, there are very few pure public goods. There are many more goods that fall into the second category—such as training—<br />

where there may be positive externalities, but the case is hardly clear-cut. There can be major information constraints in some<br />

<strong>market</strong>s, such as training—benefits from training are often not immediate or tangible. However, although public subsidy for<br />

training is common, there are also vigorous and completely private training <strong>market</strong>s in many low-income countries.<br />

The key problem here is that these arguments for intervention—drawn from economic theory—can be used to justify state<br />

intervention in most <strong>market</strong>s. Markets are never perfect, and there’s always inequality. Does this mean we should always<br />

intervene? Clearly not!<br />

Capacity: a more practical way of thinking through governments’ potential role is to consider a hierarchy of functions of the<br />

state (Figure 11). From this, governments with limited capacities should focus on doing a small number of basic things well,<br />

rather than many things badly. In terms of <strong>BDS</strong>, this might mean, for example, only appropriate regulation or funding for core<br />

research.<br />

What About the Example of High-income Economies? In many wealthy countries, government involvement in <strong>BDS</strong> is<br />

widespread, posing the question of whether low-income countries should seek to emulate this role. Several points need to be<br />

made here:<br />

• In some countries, there is a historic, relatively close relationship between competent states and the private sector that<br />

allows governments to play a more active role in <strong>BDS</strong>. More commonly, governments intervene for a variety of social and<br />

political reasons that have little to do with improved <strong>market</strong> functioning. Unfortunately, it is often this latter approach that is<br />

exported to low-income countries through aid-funded projects.<br />

• Despite the efforts of governments, for most businesses in most industrialized economies, <strong>BDS</strong> is provided through the<br />

<strong>market</strong>place. In the United Kingdom, for example, one study showed that only 14 percent of business advice—a<br />

cornerstone of SME policy—is provided by official government-supported agencies.<br />

• The quality and effectiveness of much officially supported <strong>BDS</strong> in these countries is highly questionable and, at its worst,<br />

akin to a welfare state for struggling enterprise. In the United Kingdom, there is a negative correlation between usage of<br />

public sector sources of advice and profitability; in other words, subsidized advice has been taken up by badly performing<br />

SMEs (many of which were actually seeking financial assistance).<br />

• The resource base of industrialized countries dwarfs that of low-income countries, and the practices that have developed<br />

are those of rich states where sustainability concerns press only lightly.<br />

In short, the role of governments in <strong>BDS</strong> often followed in high-income countries are typically ineffective and/or hugely<br />

expensive and depend on subsidies. <strong>BDS</strong> projects that are modeled on these approaches are inappropriate—and indeed<br />

damaging—for low-income countries.<br />

Chapter Three—Where Do We Want to Go?—<br />

Developing a Clear Picture of Sustainability


34<br />

Box 8: Key Considerations in Assessing the Role of Business Membership Organizations in <strong>BDS</strong><br />

Business membership organizations (BMOs) are a fixture on the business and <strong>BDS</strong> scene in most countries. Although in Europe<br />

some BMOs have a public law status that makes business membership compulsory, more commonly they are voluntary<br />

organizations formed to serve their members’ interests.<br />

What’s Unique About BMOs?<br />

BMOs are the only collective organizations owned by and for business and representing business. Although local traditions vary<br />

greatly, from a donor perspective BMOs can offer an extensive presence and outreach to businesses, a good understanding of<br />

business needs, a means of tapping into business talents, and good connections with state decision-makers.<br />

Donor Experience<br />

Drawn by the apparent potential of BMOs to provide demand-oriented services to their members, considerable resources have<br />

been focused on BMOs over recent years. Overall, this experience has not been especially positive. It is clear now that<br />

businesses join BMOs for a variety of reasons—social, political, and personal; that relations between BMOs and members are<br />

often not strictly business-like or transactional; that capacity varies hugely; and that often BMOs don’t wish to expand their core<br />

roles beyond that which they know and own.<br />

Core Roles?<br />

In general, BMOs’ comparative advantage is around the roles of advocacy (first priority), information, and networking. Roles<br />

beyond these core areas—such as developing new ideas, enhancing skills, and assuming delegated government functions—are<br />

dependent on capacity and <strong>market</strong> considerations, but there is nothing in BMOs that makes them inherently suited for these. 23<br />

Box 9: Key Considerations in Assessing the Role of Not-for-Profit Organizations in <strong>BDS</strong><br />

Not-for-profit organizations include a wide range of voluntary, semi-state, and other organizations (including BMOs). Our focus<br />

here is on two of these; higher educational organizations and nongovernmental organizations (NGOs). Both have a wider public<br />

purpose (beyond profit) similar to government but, it is argued, without the bureaucracy and other disadvantages of governments.<br />

The core roles of higher educational organizations are concerned with teaching students and undertaking research—that is, with<br />

developing and disseminating knowledge for society as a whole. In many countries, educational organizations like business<br />

schools are active as providers of <strong>BDS</strong>—especially training—to business. This role is valid only if they can develop the right skills<br />

and culture to develop and deliver on a commercial basis to the private sector—that is, to extend their core knowledge role to<br />

include training to business. However, in many instances, traditional academic culture has been shown to be even more distant<br />

from business than government and to be completely unsuited to <strong>BDS</strong> provision.<br />

Less controversially, it is clearly within the natural role of higher educational organizations to undertake basic research, which<br />

ultimately should feed into new and better <strong>BDS</strong>.<br />

NGOs, although highly diverse, are commonly seen to posses an advantage because of their driven and informal culture, their<br />

commitment to reach disadvantaged groups and their flexibility (in part, stemming from their lack of accountability). Although<br />

difficult to prove, NGOs may be able to reach difficult (peripheral, socially excluded, etc.) groups better than others. However,<br />

although some NGOs have developed a business-like culture that allows them to work in a <strong>market</strong>-oriented manner, others bring<br />

with them less-helpful welfare-oriented attitudes that hinder <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong>.<br />

In the longer-term, as direct providers of <strong>BDS</strong> there is probably a limited role for NGOs. More likely, their longer-term role will draw<br />

on their core strengths of closeness to and understanding of disadvantaged groups and of innovation and flexibility to enable them<br />

to test and develop new ideas. In the short term, they can—if they have suitable capacity—act as <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong><br />

facilitators.<br />

23 A 1999 survey of BMOs in Nepal showed that more than three-quarters of members saw BMOs’ most<br />

important function as advocacy, information provision, or networking.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


35<br />

Figure 12: Functions of the State<br />

Minimal<br />

Functions<br />

Intermediate<br />

Functions<br />

Activist<br />

Functions<br />

Addressing<br />

Externalities:<br />

Basic education<br />

Environmental<br />

protection<br />

Addressing Market Failure<br />

Providing Pure Public Goods:<br />

Defense<br />

Law and order<br />

Property rights<br />

Macroeconomic management<br />

Public health<br />

Regulating<br />

Monopoly:<br />

Utility regulation<br />

Antitrust policy<br />

Coordinating Private Activity:<br />

Fostering <strong>market</strong>s<br />

Cluster initiatives<br />

Overcoming<br />

Imperfect<br />

Information:<br />

Insurance (health,<br />

life, pensions)<br />

Financial regulation<br />

Consumer protection<br />

Improving Equity<br />

Protecting the Poor:<br />

Antipoverty programs<br />

Disaster relief<br />

Providing Social<br />

Insurance:<br />

Redistributive<br />

pensions<br />

Family allowances<br />

Unemployment<br />

insurance<br />

Redistribution:<br />

Asset redistribution<br />

Source: World Development Report 1997.<br />

Donor agencies are not included here; their role is perceived to be facilitative and short term<br />

without a valid longer-term rationale. It may be that foreign-funded donor agencies will<br />

continue to be active in low-income countries, but to build them into one’s picture of<br />

sustainability as long-term players is to run the risk of cementing countries into debilitating<br />

dependence.<br />

Similarly, we don’t here include SMEs—they are clearly important but are on the demandside<br />

of the <strong>market</strong>. The focus here is on supply-side functions.<br />

Who Will Undertake the Function (who does)? Who Will Pay for This to Happen<br />

(who pays)?—Linking Actors with Functions<br />

In developing a transparent picture of sustainability for the future, 24 the core task for each<br />

main function is to develop—in as much detail as possible—a clear view of:<br />

• Who will undertake this function? (who does?); and<br />

• Who will pay for this to happen? (who pays?).<br />

24 The period of time to be considered will clearly vary from one situation to another, but the end of a project period is the<br />

obvious time horizon to consider.<br />

Chapter Three—Where Do We Want to Go?—<br />

Developing a Clear Picture of Sustainability


36<br />

In answering these questions, we need to assess the comparative advantage of each key<br />

player in the local context and their realistic capacity to do and to pay (Boxes 7-9).<br />

Considered responses to these deceptively simple questions provide a transparent basis for<br />

rational analysis of the future of particular <strong>BDS</strong> and for the <strong>development</strong> of a consensus—<br />

among donors and with government and other players—over longer-term objectives.<br />

Currently, neither the transparency nor the consensus is often in evidence.<br />

One structured way in which to organize information related to sustainability is to use a<br />

matrix (Table 2). This involves direct comparison of a current situation with an ideal at some<br />

point in time and sets the specific direction in which interventions should go. However, there<br />

are no easy or formulaic answers to questions of sustainability; Table 2 is a convenient<br />

means of gathering and presenting information; it is not a prescriptive tool. There is no<br />

substitute for wrestling with the hard issues that a candid, rigorous assessment of<br />

sustainability poses.<br />

WHAT WOULD A SUSTAINABILITY PICTURE LOOK LIKE?<br />

Given the above framework for developing transparency in sustainability, what should this<br />

picture look like for <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> interventions? First, it is important to point<br />

out that it won’t always be the same. There are factors that might lead to legitimate<br />

differences between countries:<br />

• Business Membership Organization Traditions: in some countries, BMOs have<br />

considerable strength and may be able to play a role in, for example, information<br />

provision as well as the more traditional advocacy function. In other countries, this is<br />

more common, they have a limited but important advocacy-focused role.<br />

• Government Capacity: wealthier governments (say, in middle-income countries) with a<br />

stronger human resource base can potentially play a more active role in supporting<br />

functions such as research and <strong>development</strong> and coordination. For most low-income<br />

countries, however, governments’ priority should be to focus on core roles only.<br />

• Entrepreneurial Character of NGOs: business-like NGOs have developed in some<br />

countries that, in their culture and capacity, are similar to competent for-profit players. In<br />

other cases, NGOs continue to be loaded with a welfare legacy and anti-business<br />

sentiment, and have few relevant skills.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


37<br />

Table 2: Sustainability Framework in Matrix Form<br />

Functions<br />

Players<br />

Who Does?<br />

Who Pays?<br />

Current Future Current Future<br />

Delivery<br />

Product<br />

<strong>development</strong><br />

Skills<br />

enhancement<br />

Research and<br />

<strong>development</strong><br />

Information<br />

Advocacy<br />

Regulation<br />

Coordination<br />

• The Strength of Networks: more-entrepreneurial economies often have networks of<br />

businesses (SMEs and larger firms) that have higher potential for an active role.<br />

• The Degree of Market Openness: <strong>market</strong>s that are open to foreign investment and trade<br />

are more likely to graduate toward a functioning, primarily private sector <strong>market</strong> than one<br />

where there are constraints to global, external <strong>market</strong> influences.<br />

Second, notwithstanding these differences, the general shape of <strong>BDS</strong> in the future will be<br />

characterized by:<br />

• The For-Profit Sector: the key providers of <strong>BDS</strong> and responsible for product<br />

<strong>development</strong> financed directly from revenues from fee-paying SME clients. Increasingly<br />

also, one should expect that support functions in <strong>market</strong>s—skills provision, product<br />

<strong>development</strong>, information flows, etc.—become internalized within <strong>market</strong>s, with<br />

advocacy and regulation the principal non-traded functions;<br />

• Business Networks: supplementing the private sector, through a variety of selfsustaining<br />

arrangements; should develop to provide services informally and formally;<br />

• Government: policy maker and regulator, financed by the state (government therefore<br />

should essentially not be a provider of <strong>BDS</strong>). In some instances, government may also<br />

play a role in basic research and <strong>development</strong> and in coordination;<br />

Chapter Three—Where Do We Want to Go?—<br />

Developing a Clear Picture of Sustainability


38<br />

• Business Membership Organizations: providers of an articulate advocacy voice for the<br />

business community and of information through their networks; and<br />

• Not-For-Profit Organizations: building on core strengths in research and/or knowledge<br />

of peripheral and disadvantaged groups; may develop as product testers/developers,<br />

researchers, and specialist skills <strong>development</strong> providers.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


39<br />

CHAPTER FOUR<br />

HOW DO WE GET THERE?—CORE IMPLEMENTATION CHALLENGES<br />

All forms of outside support are a subsidy in one way or another. A <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> approach to<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> does not mean no subsidy, no way, no how. Instead, it means how much subsidy, in what form,<br />

and how long so that SMEs future service needs can be met through the private provision of <strong>BDS</strong> in<br />

sustainable <strong>market</strong>s. All subsidies will distort <strong>market</strong>s in some way—we to need to anticipate future<br />

implementation challenges so our subsidy develops more than it distorts the <strong>market</strong>. And, finally, we<br />

need to ask ourselves, as managers of short-term subsidies, how must we change to be effective<br />

practitioners of <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> interventions.<br />

This chapter outlines common issues that need to be confronted in designing and managing<br />

interventions. It focuses particularly on how support should be structured to enhance <strong>market</strong><br />

<strong>development</strong> and minimize <strong>market</strong> distortion and on the selection and management of partner<br />

relationships. It concludes by listing some key implications for donors and facilitators inherent within<br />

the <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> approach.<br />

Key Questions:<br />

1. Where should we intervene in the project cycle to minimize the risk of distortion?<br />

2. Is there any justification for subsidizing the transaction between <strong>BDS</strong> consumer and supplier?<br />

3. How much intervention—in terms of time and resources—is enough? How much is too much?<br />

4. How do we leverage additional private sector investment in <strong>BDS</strong>?<br />

5. How do we identify and select implementation partners?<br />

6. How do we assess donor skills and capacities to be effective?<br />

COMMON SIGNS OF MARKET DEVELOPMENT OR DISTORTION IN <strong>BDS</strong> INTERVENTIONS<br />

The overall shape of interventions in <strong>BDS</strong> is <strong>guide</strong>d by:<br />

1. Analysis of the <strong>market</strong> in which we are interested and the constraints to <strong>market</strong><br />

<strong>development</strong> revealed by this analysis; and<br />

2. Our view of sustainability in the longer term.<br />

Clearly, interventions built on these foundations may take different forms and each of these<br />

raises its own distinctive problems. However, there are more general issues that commonly<br />

need to be confronted in <strong>BDS</strong> interventions if they are to be successful. These fall under<br />

three broad categories:<br />

• How support for <strong>BDS</strong> should be structured;<br />

• Whom we should work with; and<br />

• What are the implications for the capacities of donors and facilitators?<br />

Before assessing these issues, we must be clear about what we mean by <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong><br />

and, its converse, <strong>market</strong> distortion. We need to know what these mean and recognize signs<br />

Chapter Four—How Do We Get There?—<br />

Core Implementation Challenges


40<br />

of both. All donor-financed support is a form of subsidy and has some impact on the <strong>BDS</strong><br />

<strong>market</strong>place and therefore the potential to be positive or negative (that is, distorting) with<br />

regard to the objective of <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong>. Any <strong>BDS</strong> provider or facilitator will<br />

recognize this reality. One typical response from <strong>BDS</strong> programs when justifying subsidies to<br />

reduce the price of <strong>BDS</strong> to SMEs is that SMEs are not prepared to pay a higher price because<br />

they are used to free services from other <strong>development</strong> programs or government. This is a<br />

classic illustration of intervention distortion at work. Table 3 highlights some obvious signs<br />

of both <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> and distortion.<br />

Table 3: Common Signs of Market Development and Market Distortion<br />

Services<br />

Providers<br />

Consumers<br />

Develop<br />

The acid test: increased transaction<br />

volume; larger <strong>market</strong> size<br />

Range of products for different<br />

consumers; innovation to meet new<br />

needs<br />

Greater number of differentiated<br />

providers; financed by consumer fees;<br />

cost base appropriate to financial<br />

realities of <strong>market</strong><br />

Assertive consumers demanding good<br />

value from providers; prepared to pay the<br />

right price for the right product<br />

Distort<br />

Lower transaction volume; smaller<br />

<strong>market</strong> size; standardized products;<br />

minimal differentiation or innovation<br />

Small number of providers; existence of<br />

parallel providers (official subsidized and<br />

unofficial <strong>market</strong>-based); increasing or<br />

prevailing high degree of subsidy<br />

dependence; bloated cost base from high<br />

donor support and (expectation of more)<br />

Continued expectations of subsidy;<br />

reluctance to consider <strong>BDS</strong> as any other<br />

product; low value placed on <strong>BDS</strong><br />

HOW SUPPORT FOR <strong>BDS</strong> SHOULD BE STRUCTURED?<br />

There are three critical factors to consider in structuring support for <strong>BDS</strong> provision:<br />

1. Invasiveness of Support: Where should we direct our support?<br />

2. Intensity of Support: How much support and what nature of support is required?<br />

3. Leverage of Support: How do we make (limited) support more effective?<br />

Invasiveness of Support<br />

There is a fine line between developing and distorting. Where we focus our intervention or<br />

support partly determines this balance. We refer to this where as invasive: the closer or more<br />

direct an intervention is in relation to the transaction between consumer and service provider,<br />

the more invasive it is (Figure 13).<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


41<br />

Figure 13: Where to Intervene to Reduce the Risk of Distortion<br />

Feedback and Change<br />

Ideas<br />

Development:<br />

Products<br />

Development:<br />

People &<br />

Organizations<br />

Marketing<br />

&<br />

Promotion<br />

Information<br />

for<br />

Consumers<br />

Delivery:<br />

Supplyside<br />

Delivery:<br />

Demand<br />

-side<br />

Assessment<br />

of<br />

Markets/<br />

Products<br />

Pre-delivery<br />

less invasive<br />

Delivery<br />

more invasive<br />

Postdelivery<br />

less invasive<br />

MINIMIZE<br />

POTENTIAL<br />

FOR<br />

DISTORTION<br />

Artificially reducing the price that consumers have to pay for a service and artificially<br />

reducing service providers’ cost of delivery are highly invasive types of interventions that<br />

have relatively high potential for <strong>market</strong> distortion. These types of interventions impinge<br />

directly on the transaction between supplier and consumer, influencing the motivations,<br />

behavior, dynamics, and price signals that lie at the heart of a functioning <strong>market</strong>. In doing<br />

so, they have the potential to distort:<br />

• Consumers’ Willingness to Pay: for example, price expectations are lowered below the<br />

<strong>market</strong> norm; and<br />

• Providers’ Ability to Develop an Offer: for example, fee or margin expectations are raised<br />

if delivery is subsidized; unsubsidized providers’ normal-service price becomes<br />

unattractive to consumers in the face of subsidized competition.<br />

This characteristic high risk of distortion does not imply that direct delivery subsidies can’t<br />

be justified (see Table 4). However, it does mean that we need to be aware of the potential<br />

downside risk of such interventions as well as the possible upsides.<br />

Chapter Four—How Do We Get There?—<br />

Core Implementation Challenges


42<br />

Table 4: Possible Justifications for Direct-Delivery Subsidies<br />

Typical Justifications<br />

Necessary to provide tangible incentives and to<br />

change behavior<br />

To overcome risk—there can’t be real change<br />

without risk<br />

If delivered correctly, can reinforce <strong>market</strong> forces<br />

and <strong>development</strong><br />

They’re poor—they can’t afford to pay and<br />

therefore need subsidy!<br />

Direct support is highly visible<br />

We need to find a way to spend our money<br />

Comment<br />

Where subsidy dependence is entrenched, an<br />

idea is new, or similar barriers exist, limited<br />

delivery subsidies to test ideas, demonstrate<br />

value, or lure SMEs into consumption, may be<br />

effective.<br />

Danger: limited can become longer term; largescale<br />

subsidies undermine connection between<br />

price and value, and crowd out unsubsidized<br />

activities<br />

Possibly, if used sparingly, to reinforce<br />

transactional relationship and address specific<br />

constraints. For example, vouchers, matching<br />

grants<br />

Many dangers here:<br />

Potential for endless subsidy<br />

How is service provision to continue in the long<br />

term?<br />

Limited outreach or replication.<br />

Price-value link is undermined: if people value a<br />

service they’ll pay for it.<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> provision becomes confused with social<br />

protection.<br />

Direct-delivery subsidies have higher visibility and<br />

permit proportionately greater disbursements. But<br />

this is bureaucratic rationale triumphing over<br />

<strong>development</strong> rationale.<br />

General lessons can be drawn for those considering direct-delivery support:<br />

• Finite Period of Support: there has to be a clear end-point to support related to<br />

measurable and achievable objectives. For example, this might focus on volume of<br />

transactions taking place between consumers and suppliers without any subsidy.<br />

• Limited in Scale: there are real dangers of flooding a <strong>market</strong>place with funds, causing<br />

long-term <strong>market</strong> distortion.<br />

• How Delivered Is Important: careful consideration needs to be given to the structure of<br />

the support, what incentives it creates, and how support is expected to achieve objectives<br />

(see below).<br />

• Justified Openly in Relation to Market Constraints: support has to have clear<br />

justification and objectives for overcoming <strong>market</strong> constraints and developing sustainable<br />

access to services 25 .<br />

25 See Biggs, T; "A Microeconometric Evaluation of the Mauritius Technology Diffusion Scheme"; World<br />

Bank, November 1999 as an example of a project that may not have matched an analysis of real <strong>market</strong><br />

constraints with intervention design.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


43<br />

• Consistent Policies and Approaches Need to Be Developed with Other Facilitators and<br />

Providers: learning from microfinance, widely differing approaches and policies on<br />

direct delivery among <strong>development</strong> agencies hinder progress toward sustainable,<br />

effective <strong>market</strong>s and institutions. There is a prerogative for openness and coordination<br />

between agencies to develop consensus and avoid undercutting between agencies.<br />

Intensity of Support<br />

In addition to where we intervene, a second important factor impinging on <strong>market</strong><br />

<strong>development</strong> and distortion is intervention intensity—how much intervention and what kind<br />

of intervention.<br />

Interventions are more likely to distort if they are intensive. Typically, this means focusing<br />

relatively high levels of resources on a single provider, product, or even target group. Lessintensive<br />

interventions try to intervene more lightly or broadly and have a lower potential to<br />

distort. Less-intensive interventions might include product <strong>development</strong>, information<br />

provision, or venture-capital support to numerous providers. The effect of excessive<br />

intervention intensity can be overloading.<br />

Overloading refers to the (unintended) distorting effects of excessively intensive donor<br />

support, creating an unrealistic or unviable pressure on the intended recipient, be that a<br />

service provider or a product. The effects of overloading can be separated as follows:<br />

1. On providers: strategic or operational burdens; and<br />

2. On <strong>BDS</strong> products: over-engineering.<br />

Overloading: Providers<br />

Strategic Burden = Forcing Multiple or Unrealistic Objectives on a Provider.<br />

Donor agencies are required to balance objectives for sustainability with <strong>development</strong>al<br />

priorities. However, it can be counterproductive to force or constrain <strong>BDS</strong> providers to work<br />

only with certain target groups, while trying to promote business-like behavior and financial<br />

sustainability. The danger is that partners are burdened with twin objectives, possibly<br />

achieving neither. This can be damaging for providers, undermining their viability by moving<br />

them away from their natural <strong>market</strong> and competence, and is inconsistent—expecting<br />

providers to be <strong>market</strong> oriented while telling them which <strong>market</strong> they should focus on.<br />

Operational Burden: Control and Cost Burdens.<br />

# Control Burden = Excessive Reporting and Monitoring and Evaluation<br />

Requirements Imposed on Provider. Donor reporting requirements may not be<br />

Chapter Four—How Do We Get There?—<br />

Core Implementation Challenges


44<br />

relevant to the provider’s priorities. Adhering to these requirements may entail<br />

developing systems and procedures that are not relevant to providers’ needs. This can:<br />

— Reduce flexibility and responsiveness and increase costs; and<br />

— Undermine ownership if the provider feels it has to do want the donor wants.<br />

# Cost Burden = Excessive Investment in Service Provider. Excessive investment in<br />

equipment, staff, products, or systems develops inappropriate cost and price structures<br />

that reduce providers’ potential for viability (from revenues from SMEs).<br />

The problem is that donor funds and work<br />

practices may impact adversely on a partner<br />

organization, driving a wedge between it and its<br />

clients in terms of systems, culture, costs, and<br />

scale. The challenge for donors is to develop<br />

approaches for intervention that account for such<br />

artificiality. This may involve, for example,<br />

building a transactional, financial relationship<br />

around conditions and performance targets.<br />

Alternatively, given the complications of building<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> organizations, there is increasing focus on<br />

developing <strong>BDS</strong> products, rather than<br />

organizations, as an appropriate focus for<br />

interventions.<br />

Overloading: Products<br />

Attempts to develop <strong>BDS</strong> products either for<br />

specific providers or for wider <strong>market</strong> distribution<br />

have frequently suffered from over-engineering.<br />

Typically, these interventions involve importing<br />

and adapting products from developed economies<br />

(such as business growth training from the United<br />

Kingdom) or committing considerable resources to<br />

developing new generic products such as<br />

International Labour Organization’s Start and<br />

Improve Your Business. Although these products<br />

may be of high technical quality, there are often<br />

criticisms that they are over-engineered because<br />

they:<br />

Box 10: Overloading a Provider in<br />

Kenya 26<br />

In 1987, a service provider was started<br />

by a local entrepreneur to provide<br />

training and counseling services to<br />

SMEs, receiving modest amounts of<br />

subsidy from local sources. In 1998, it<br />

was operating at 48 percent financial<br />

sustainability (based on full costs). The<br />

service provider was regarded as having<br />

good potential and attracted additional<br />

international donor funding: from 1989<br />

(199-percent annual increase) and then<br />

a major new injection in the period<br />

1994-95 (194-percent and 55-percent<br />

annual increases).<br />

In those same periods, the service<br />

provider’s cost base increased<br />

dramatically: 20-40 percent annually<br />

during 1989-91; and 1994-96, by 32-98<br />

percent annually. At the same time,<br />

financial sustainability fell to 30 percent<br />

or less for much of the 1989-96 period,<br />

only recovering to 53 percent in 1997.<br />

Donor investment had financed<br />

additional facilities, systems, and<br />

capacity that added dramatically to<br />

operational expenditure, without a<br />

commensurate effect on revenues. The<br />

result was an operating deficit that<br />

threatened the viability of the service<br />

provider.<br />

26 Hitchins, R and Gibson, A; "The Kenya Management Assistance Programme - innovative delivery of<br />

counselling and training"; Paper presented to the workshop on <strong>BDS</strong> for SMEs, "How sustainable can<br />

business <strong>development</strong> services really be?"; Harare, 29 th September - 1 st October, 1998<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


45<br />

• Have been developed to be perfect products but are:<br />

C Overly comprehensive and unwieldy, and<br />

C Expensive and resource dependent; and<br />

• Are overly generic and inappropriate to the specific, ever-changing requirements of<br />

SMEs.<br />

The effects of over-engineering have been:<br />

• Products that do not reflect <strong>market</strong> in terms of<br />

cost, price and delivery mechanisms;<br />

• Difficulty in developing future products<br />

because providers lack resources or capacity to<br />

do so in the absence of resource-intensive<br />

external support; and<br />

• Crowding-out of indigenous products and<br />

product <strong>development</strong>.<br />

Why Does Overloading Occur? One reason<br />

for overly intensive interventions is the pressure on<br />

donors to achieve results and disburse funds.<br />

Naturally, there is a belief that bigger is better and<br />

more rather than less. A second factor is that often<br />

intervention design is not grounded in the reality of<br />

local <strong>market</strong> conditions and constraints: donors and<br />

facilitators projects have a tendency to develop<br />

projects based on their own expectations,<br />

experiences, and views, and not what works in the<br />

<strong>market</strong> in question. Typical examples include:<br />

• Making large front-end investments to develop<br />

prestigious <strong>BDS</strong> organizations 27 , but in the<br />

process developing capacity (and a cost base)<br />

that is far in advance of organization<br />

requirement, consumer purchasing power, and<br />

<strong>market</strong> demand, with very little consideration<br />

of future commercial viability; and<br />

Box 11: Overloading Training in Uganda<br />

A project was designed to enhance the<br />

technical capacity of SMEs involved in the<br />

food-processing sector (bakery, dairy, and<br />

fruit and vegetable products). Initially threeweek<br />

training courses were delivered via the<br />

project and its partner (a business<br />

membership organization). Because of<br />

concerns about sustainability of training<br />

services after project end, support was<br />

subsequently re-focused to develop a pool<br />

of local trainer-consultants who would<br />

deliver training to SMEs on a commercial<br />

basis.<br />

Unfortunately, although the training products<br />

were of a high technical standard and many<br />

of the potential trainer-consultants were well<br />

qualified, no trainer-consultants were a<br />

commercial success. The causes of this<br />

failure attributed to:<br />

• Overly sophisticated products, they were<br />

too costly and resource intensive to be<br />

viable in local conditions;<br />

• The training was too comprehensive and<br />

theoretical—it did not offer quick and<br />

practicable solutions to business<br />

problems; and<br />

• Inappropriate delivery mechanisms:<br />

because of their qualifications and income<br />

from more lucrative areas, trainerconsultants<br />

found fees from SMEs<br />

unattractive.<br />

Ironically, there was an unintended output<br />

from the project. One initial project trainee—<br />

a baker, not a trainer-consultant—<br />

27 successfully operated a training business on<br />

“Business Service Centers in Ukraine” an MBP study conducted<br />

the<br />

by<br />

side,<br />

Yoo-Mi<br />

offering<br />

Lee reported<br />

very short<br />

how<br />

focused<br />

excessive<br />

training<br />

upfront<br />

support within business service centers created cost structures<br />

(1-2<br />

that<br />

hours)<br />

could<br />

addressing<br />

only be supported<br />

specific<br />

by<br />

baking<br />

serving<br />

larger firms. The conflict between business center financial viability<br />

problems<br />

and outreach<br />

to other<br />

to<br />

small<br />

small<br />

bakeries,<br />

firms was<br />

on<br />

partly<br />

a<br />

due to high – and largely unnecessary – donor investments in existing<br />

profitable<br />

providers<br />

basis.<br />

to create them more in the<br />

image of Western business center models.<br />

Chapter Four—How Do We Get There?—<br />

Core Implementation Challenges


46<br />

• Developing conceptually and technically complete or perfect products, rather than<br />

products that are more suited to local preferences and delivery mechanisms. 28<br />

28 Low-quality products and organizations are often given as reasons for intervention. The question is quality<br />

for whom? Although low quality by the standards of advanced economies, indigenous products may often be<br />

far more appropriate (and viable) for local conditions. See “Sustainable MSE training through grassroots<br />

training business”, a paper presented by Enoth Mbiene and Gavin Anderson at the Donor Committee’s<br />

Harare conference for insight on low priced training courses --$4 to $12 /course -- with high demand in rural<br />

communities.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


47<br />

Avoiding overloading may involve different approaches:<br />

• Use <strong>market</strong> assessment and consumer research in intervention design:<br />

C Understanding the characteristics and norms of the <strong>market</strong> in question allows<br />

intervention to be geared to developing appropriate, viable products, organizations,<br />

people, and mechanisms in terms of cost, price, features, location, and the like.<br />

• Forget cost recovery, think about profit. The term “cost recovery” not helpful to<br />

developing sustainable, demand-led <strong>BDS</strong><br />

because it is a manifestation of one key<br />

weakness of many <strong>BDS</strong> interventions:<br />

building organizations in advance of need:<br />

Box 12: Using a Portfolio Approach to<br />

Achieve Cross-cutting Development<br />

Objectives<br />

C Large front-end investments are made in<br />

facilities, equipment, and staff, which<br />

result in a bloated cost base that bears no<br />

relation to the earning capacity of the <strong>BDS</strong><br />

provider.<br />

C The concept of cost recovery promotes an<br />

artificial culture of clawing back revenues<br />

to finance these cost bases and<br />

unproductive investments, in response to<br />

donor demands for sustainability.<br />

C Small businesses do not have this luxury;<br />

they grow in response to increasing<br />

demand and invest, when they can afford<br />

to, for productive purposes, to make a<br />

profit.<br />

• Use a portfolio approach (see Box 12). A<br />

portfolio approach entails working with<br />

multiple partners—a portfolio—rather than<br />

just one. Like an investment or lending<br />

portfolio, the performance of the entire<br />

portfolio is more critical than any single<br />

constituent part. The benefits of such an<br />

approach are:<br />

C This approach reduces investment in any<br />

single organization (by default, it is less<br />

intensive); and<br />

In a typical project, a partner service provider<br />

is given multiple objectives—for example, to<br />

achieve financial sustainability (based on<br />

revenues from SMEs) in two years and also<br />

that 65 percent of clientele must be female.<br />

A portfolio approach would be to work with 10<br />

service providers, all of which have a<br />

financial-sustainability objective. The donor or<br />

facilitator does not assign individual service<br />

providers with a gender-outreach objective,<br />

however. Instead, an aggregate objective for<br />

the whole portfolio of the service provider is<br />

assigned—for example, gender outreach<br />

target of 65 percent. Thus, if there are 1,000<br />

current clients for whole portfolio, 650 have to<br />

be female. The donor/facilitator then<br />

manages the portfolio on basis of both<br />

objectives:<br />

• Partner service providers are selected,<br />

assessed, or dropped on the basis of<br />

financial performance.<br />

• Partners are also selected on the basis of<br />

their offer to female entrepreneurs or<br />

<strong>market</strong> segments. Sufficient partners with<br />

such an offer are maintained in the<br />

portfolio to ensure aggregate gender<br />

objective is achieved.<br />

Key Points:<br />

Don’t impose that all service providers have<br />

to have 65 percent of clientele female; select<br />

those whose natural offer is to female clients<br />

or <strong>market</strong>s and then measure gender<br />

outreach of project as a whole.<br />

C A portfolio of partners means that donor<br />

Chapter Four—How Do We Get There?—<br />

Core Implementation Challenges


48<br />

strategic objectives can be assigned on the portfolio in aggregate, rather than multiple<br />

objectives for individual service providers.<br />

Intervention Leverage<br />

Concerns about distortion should not lead <strong>development</strong> agencies to adopt interventions that<br />

are so minimalist they achieve nothing. The challenge is to design interventions find ways to<br />

leverage the private sector into investing, trading, and developing products (using relatively<br />

few resources), rather than replacing private sector activity (through intensive or invasive<br />

intervention) 29 . Leverage might mean attracting matching investment from private sector<br />

providers, developing new products for licensing or franchising, or increasing private sector<br />

provision in a new <strong>market</strong> through some form of information provision. Ideally, interventions<br />

should try and use the lowest appropriate level of intensity possible while maintaining<br />

effectiveness. 30 Six key factors need to be taken account of in designing interventions to<br />

achieve leverage:<br />

1. Choosing the right instrument;<br />

2. Using a portfolio approach: a range of partners;<br />

3. Making support transactional;<br />

4. Developing a clear support offer;<br />

5. Building on existing ownership; and<br />

6. Investing in potential.<br />

Choosing the Right Instrument<br />

Certain types of intervention instruments are more likely to achieve leverage than others—<br />

notably, those that have the ability for wider replication or to attract private sector funds to<br />

multiply the effects of intervention. Intervention instruments that offer the potential for<br />

leverage include:<br />

• Product <strong>development</strong> for distribution, franchising 31 or licensing to a range of service<br />

providers;<br />

• Social venture capital: matching private sector investment;<br />

29 IDE’s work with treadle pumps – described in the Polak/Downing paper “The Development and<br />

Commercialization of the Treadle Pump in Bangladesh presented at the Donor Committee’s Asia <strong>BDS</strong><br />

workshop -- illustrates how the introduction of a new technology leveraged an almost 3 to 1 response from<br />

the private sector.<br />

30 This is similar to the subsidiary principle discussed in <strong>BDS</strong> good practice <strong>guide</strong>lines.<br />

31 Franchising of <strong>BDS</strong> appears attractive—that is, the idea of being able to develop reputable branded products<br />

or methodologies, which can then be sold or distributed under license to large numbers of service providers,<br />

possibly with an accompanying technical support agreement. However, there is little experience to date of<br />

true franchising (with revenue flowing back from the franchisee to the franchiser). GTZ's CEFE has some of<br />

the elements of a franchised product. Like all product <strong>development</strong>, franchising may face challenges of overstandardization<br />

and cost, as well as concerns about developing enforceable brands and preventing pirating.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


49<br />

C For new product <strong>development</strong>, and<br />

C For new <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong>;<br />

# Information provision;<br />

C Market information for service providers—new <strong>market</strong>/product <strong>development</strong>; and<br />

C Service or service provider information for consumers.<br />

Portfolio Approach: Working with More than One Partner<br />

Elsewhere reference has been made to a portfolio approach to working with partners.<br />

Working with more than one partner reduces the danger of distortion and unfair competition,<br />

but an equally important benefit is that it permits leverage:<br />

• Project support is spread more widely across the <strong>market</strong>; and<br />

• An intervention’s risk is spread: the intervention is not tied to a single organization or<br />

mechanism, so this approach can be more innovative and experimental without the fear of<br />

losing everything if a partner fails to deliver.<br />

Making Support Transactional (see Box 13)<br />

If the objective of <strong>BDS</strong> intervention is to foster more effective, business-like <strong>BDS</strong> provision,<br />

intervening agencies themselves must be more business-like in their approach to support,<br />

making support more transactional to replicate conventional business relationships. Soft<br />

support sends entirely the wrong messages to <strong>BDS</strong> providers, their clients, and the<br />

<strong>market</strong>place; it undermines <strong>market</strong> signals or incentives and is more likely to distort rather<br />

than develop demand-led service provision. The benefits of transactional support are that it:<br />

• Requires reciprocity and thus has potential for leverage;<br />

• Fosters business-like incentives, behavior, and attitudes;<br />

• Links support to performance; and<br />

• Attaches a value to support—that is, it encourages prudent and effective utilization.<br />

Ultimately, any form of support, transactional or not, is artificial and carries the potential to<br />

distort service provision away from business and toward the donor. One solution is to<br />

transfer support itself to the <strong>market</strong>place, using <strong>market</strong> mechanisms and pricing. Some<br />

initiatives have experimented with mechanisms such as leasing of equipment, debt or equity<br />

financing for investment, and priced technical assistance.<br />

Developing a Clear Offer<br />

Chapter Four—How Do We Get There?—<br />

Core Implementation Challenges


50<br />

If a donor/facilitator is to achieve leverage through a limited intervention, the intervention<br />

must be shaped into an offer to partners that is clear, unambiguous, and attractive. As with<br />

any other transaction, each party has to know what it is going to get if the offer is going to<br />

work. Often, interventions have an extremely ill-defined offer, partly because the range of<br />

potential support is extremely broad and partly because there is a genuine absence of<br />

transparency about roles and capabilities. Key questions to be asked when ascertaining an<br />

offer to partners are:<br />

• What is our distinctive core competence (especially in contrast with other agencies,<br />

government, and private sector)?<br />

• Why should someone want our support?<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


51<br />

• Precisely, what are they going to get?<br />

Box 13: Using Incentive-based Support 32<br />

Some agencies make their support to partners conditional, based on explicit performance criteria; the objective is to<br />

replicate <strong>market</strong> behavior. Using incentive-based support effectively can present numerous challenges.<br />

Link support to performance:<br />

Some form of conditionality has to be established, whereby funding or technical assistance is extended based on the<br />

achievement of performance criteria, such as outreach, activities, and financial performance. This may be on an<br />

organization or product-by-product basis. Choosing the right conditionality is the principal challenge here.<br />

• How will the chosen incentive work?<br />

• What is the objective of the incentive mechanism?<br />

• Does the incentive motivate the desired behavior?<br />

Define the package of support:<br />

Recognizing that just as there is a transaction between service provider and consumer, so there is a transaction between<br />

donor/facilitator and service provider. What does the partner get from the donor/facilitator? It is particularly important that<br />

consistency and clarity are maintained over time with respect to both the offer of support and the incentive mechanism.<br />

Shifting the goal-posts can be extremely damaging.<br />

Develop performance targets:<br />

Mutually agreed performance targets must be established in advance. Targets need to be realistic and achievable, but<br />

should also present enough of a challenge to stimulate change: too low, behavior or performance is unchanged; too high,<br />

the target is de-motivating.<br />

A more difficult challenge for many <strong>development</strong> agencies is that performance-based support also means walking away<br />

when partners consistently fail to deliver (rather than keeping them on life-support). If the sanction for under-performance<br />

is not credible, incentives will not work.<br />

Implement rigorous measurement systems:<br />

Because funding and technical support are dependent on performance, measuring performance has to be transparent<br />

and credible if disputes, manipulation, and fraud are to be avoided. The challenge for the donor/facilitator is to minimize<br />

distorting effects while maintaining accountability.<br />

Problems with Incentive Mechanisms:<br />

• Inappropriate conditionality motivates undesired behavior—for example, basing funding only on outreach or sales<br />

income can cause a service provider to maximize sales, without considering the profitability of sales. When support<br />

ends, the service provider finds both a large operating deficit and inappropriate cost and price structures.<br />

• Loose conditionality and measurement can encourage fraud and manipulation.<br />

• Incentive schemes, if they are well run, place considerable demands on donors/facilitators in terms of skills, systems<br />

and procedures, and staff time.<br />

Building on Existing Ownership<br />

The most distinctive characteristic of a small business is its ownership structure—usually a<br />

single individual who drives the organization. There is an emerging consensus that the most<br />

32 See Hitchins, R; "Assessing the experience of Swisscontact's business centre approach in Latin America and<br />

Asia"; Swisscontact; SDC Issue paper No.3, 1999<br />

Chapter Four—How Do We Get There?—<br />

Core Implementation Challenges


52<br />

effective institutions or mechanisms to support SMEs are those that look like SMEs. 33 The<br />

challenge for interventions is to build on (or create) this ownership, rather than displacing it<br />

through external initiatives and control. Stimulating individual ownership requires exposure<br />

to risk and reward, ideally in the form of the partner’s personal investment and equity. This is<br />

difficult territory for <strong>development</strong> agencies that are more familiar with giving assistance and<br />

reducing risk, and that have a tendency to work with partners most similar to their own<br />

institutional culture, often a very different culture from that of entrepreneurs and business.<br />

Building on existing ownership (what’s there) is an effective of way of leveraging an<br />

intervention because:<br />

• Not starting from scratch can be less expensive;<br />

• An existing owner should be able to match investment from a facilitator; and<br />

• An existing owner has a strong stake, which creates:<br />

C Commitment; and<br />

C Incentives: the risk and reward, which is at the heart of entrepreneurial behavior.<br />

Investing in Potential<br />

Leveraging intervention is similar to investment; donor agencies are looking for a return<br />

(achievement of objectives) on their investment (project inputs). The decision of where to<br />

invest or who to invest in should be based on identifying winners or potential (either<br />

demonstrated potential or latent potential). Donor support is not best utilized propping up<br />

failing organizations and individuals who see donor support as a last respite.<br />

The challenge for agencies (aside from actually finding potential investments) is to ascertain<br />

whether they should support existing potential (which may create nothing additional or be<br />

distorting) or support new potential (which carries more risk, but may have less potential for<br />

distortion). The options for the donor are somewhat like a business (Figure 14).<br />

Figure14: Options for Support: Support Existing or Develop New<br />

33 This point is at the core of the <strong>BDS</strong> good practice principles.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


53<br />

Existing<br />

MARKET<br />

(sub-sector, enterprise, location)<br />

New<br />

PRODUCTS<br />

(services, providers)<br />

1 2<br />

3 4<br />

New<br />

Agencies can adopt four basic strategies (or combine several):<br />

# Work more intensively within existing sectors and existing services and providers,<br />

perhaps to reach disadvantaged groups (<strong>market</strong> share or <strong>market</strong> penetration);<br />

# Increase the range of sectors in which they try to work (new <strong>market</strong> strategy);<br />

# Introduce new services and providers (product <strong>development</strong> strategy); and<br />

# Move into entirely new sectors with new services and providers (diversification).<br />

The further donors move from square 1 toward square 4—into new <strong>market</strong>s, services, and<br />

providers—the more risk increases. The potential for distortion decreases, however,<br />

assuming that the general level of <strong>BDS</strong> activity is weak in these new areas.<br />

Factors to Take Account of in Pursuing Poverty Reduction/Equity Objectives<br />

All of the preceding analysis applies equally to the poor as it does to the non-poor. These<br />

challenges need to be addressed generally if <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong>s are to be developed and,<br />

specifically, if the poor are to be included within <strong>market</strong>s and poverty/inequity addressed.<br />

The approach is all about making <strong>market</strong>s work more effectively for the poor—as well as for<br />

everybody else—rather than isolating them in enclaves of welfare and charity.<br />

Yet, commonly, intervention responses that seek to be especially poverty-focused are often<br />

based on direct subsidy of service provision or consumption. Projects are designed to reach<br />

disadvantaged groups using, for example, subsidized services for microenterprises or target<br />

quotas for coverage of female-owned businesses.<br />

Intervening in this fashion is a non-<strong>market</strong> response. The risk is that solutions are artificial,<br />

delivering short-term benefits but ultimately doing little to incorporate the disadvantaged into<br />

Chapter Four—How Do We Get There?—<br />

Core Implementation Challenges


54<br />

mainstream <strong>market</strong>s; in a sense, solutions can be exclusive rather than inclusive. Several<br />

concerns arise:<br />

• These mechanisms all require some form of control or subsidy that can be achieved only<br />

by government or <strong>development</strong> agencies. Resource and time constraints limit their scale<br />

and longevity. With no clear picture of sustainability, interventions become, at best,<br />

short-term welfare for the disadvantaged.<br />

• Subsidizing or directing services weakens demand signals, the strongest indication that<br />

services are useful or appropriate to the consumer. Deprived of this, consumers become<br />

recipients of welfare.<br />

• Subsidy and control can distort and discourage private sector service provision of<br />

services. Many interventions fail to observe that disadvantaged groups may already have<br />

access to some services, which can be damaged by invasive or intensive intervention.<br />

Even if services are not available, how is it anticipated that consumers will progress from<br />

highly subsidized services to full-cost services in the future?<br />

Inequity in itself is not a constraint to <strong>market</strong> provision of services (poor people buy and sell<br />

a variety of goods and services all the time). The constraint is that the supply side (service<br />

providers or products) is unable or inappropriate to serve certain segments of the <strong>market</strong>,<br />

defined by income level, gender, ethnicity, ability, and geographic location.<br />

Microenterprises that Cannot Afford to Pay for Services<br />

This may be the case for some ‘high-end’ services, but for other services, what is it they can’t<br />

afford? Is it services or the service provider?<br />

• Many providers (particularly partners of <strong>development</strong> agencies) will have offices,<br />

equipment, a vehicle, and well-educated staff, all of which translate into considerable<br />

overhead. It is unrealistic to expect that revenues from SMEs will cover these costs.<br />

Therefore, attempts to incentivize providers to focus downward to microenterprises<br />

inevitably see service providers creeping upward again, to their natural level, as they<br />

strive to make money. This is hardly surprising; if your M.B.A. degree gives you the<br />

capacity to sell services to large businesses or donors for a generous fee, why would you<br />

work with microenterprises for a fraction of the income?<br />

• Services themselves might be over-engineered. Aside from the cost of such services, they<br />

may well not be what the microenterprise actually needs. Evidence suggests that services<br />

that are extremely focused and can be immediately practicable in the business are most<br />

valued by SMEs and they will pay for them.<br />

The challenge is to work with providers who are much closer to their clients in terms of<br />

people, service offers, cost bases, and expectations of remuneration and to develop products<br />

and delivery mechanisms based on local resources, solutions, and <strong>market</strong>s.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


55<br />

To Reach Female-Owned Businesses<br />

Interventions may adopt quotas of female-owned businesses to be reached. For the <strong>development</strong><br />

agency, there is nothing wrong with this. However, it is unrealistic and damaging to try and force<br />

a client group on a service provider. As in the case of trying to incentivize service providers to<br />

focus on low-income segments of the <strong>market</strong>, service providers will ultimately gravitate to the<br />

clientele that best matches their capacity and experience. It makes little sense to encourage a<br />

service provider specializing in small-scale metal manufacturing to serve more female-owned<br />

businesses, for example, if women are not represented in that sector. More effective interventions<br />

try to identify and develop people and organizations with genuine offers to segments of the<br />

<strong>market</strong> where women are well represented.<br />

In general, in considering how to push out the frontiers for providing <strong>BDS</strong> to disadvantaged<br />

groups, a number of points need to be considered.<br />

• Adopt a portfolio approach to partners (Box 12): by working with a range of providers<br />

an intervention can pick partners who correspond to relevant <strong>market</strong> segments or target<br />

groups rather than trying to develop a single one-size-fits-all partner.<br />

• Develop efficient, low-cost and appropriate institutions, mechanisms and products to<br />

reach the disadvantaged rather than simply subsidising services. As in microfinance, this<br />

will require that far greater attention is paid to measurement and costs, if the frontier of<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> is to be extended 34 .<br />

• This means that, from the beginning, services have to be designed to be profitable for the<br />

provider……<br />

• …….. And also immediately practicable with the shortest possible pay-back period for<br />

the SME consumer.<br />

• View disadvantaged groups as potential <strong>market</strong> niches for private sector providers rather<br />

than as pliant charity cases.<br />

Be realistic: recognize that <strong>BDS</strong> is not a solution to all problems. In some cases, people will<br />

not have the ability to pay, their situation will be too adverse. It is unlikely that <strong>BDS</strong> is the<br />

solution to their problems at that point in time.<br />

34 See Newnham, J, "BRAC Poultry programme in Bangladesh"; Paper presented to conference on "Business<br />

services for small enterprises in Asia: developing <strong>market</strong>s and measuring performance"; Hanoi, 3 rd -6 th April,<br />

2000. The origins of BRAC’s poultry project was to replace a targeted subsidies for the very poor with an<br />

intervention designed to integrate rural women into viable occupations within a growing subsector, BRAC<br />

filled gaps in critical services – hatchery and veterinary – by moving rural women to fill these gaps.<br />

Chapter Four—How Do We Get There?—<br />

Core Implementation Challenges


56<br />

WITH WHOM SHOULD WE WORK?<br />

A shift in the focus of intervention to <strong>development</strong> of <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong>s calls for a similar shift in<br />

thinking about the partners 35 with whom we work. What has changed? Essentially thinking<br />

about developing <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong>s has led us to recognize that:<br />

# The spectrum is broader: we are starting to understand that the range of actual or<br />

potential service providers is much more diverse<br />

and different than we originally believed.<br />

# Our intervention objectives will be different:<br />

switching from assisting SMEs directly to ensuring<br />

sustainable access to services, via functioning<br />

<strong>market</strong>s, changes the nature and objectives of our<br />

interventions and, by extension, influences partner<br />

choice.<br />

The combination of these two factors gives us a much<br />

less rigid picture of who partners should be. The mesolevel<br />

(Box 16) can no longer be thought of a distinct<br />

institutional layer made up of organizations with<br />

specific characteristics or structures. Overall, we are<br />

faced with a much messier choice regarding <strong>market</strong><br />

<strong>development</strong>, from which the following trends are<br />

emerging:<br />

Box 14: Changing Views of the<br />

Meso-level in Nepal<br />

There is a long history of donor agency<br />

support for <strong>BDS</strong> in Nepal. In the early-<br />

1980s, GTZ undertook pioneering work<br />

on training and counseling that<br />

eventually led to the <strong>development</strong> of the<br />

well-known CEFE model. By the 1990s,<br />

a wide range of donors, including SDC,<br />

were involved in supporting <strong>BDS</strong>. During<br />

this period, there has been a discernible<br />

evolution in how agencies perceive the<br />

meso-level in <strong>BDS</strong>:<br />

• 1980s-Early-1990s: government and<br />

quasi-government organizations as<br />

the key deliverers of services (with<br />

donor and government subsidy for<br />

almost everything);<br />

• Focusing less on any single provider;<br />

• Working with more service providers; 36<br />

• Working with a greater diversity of service<br />

provider types;<br />

• Focusing more on private sector service providers;<br />

• Increasingly specialized, differentiated, nichefocused<br />

service providers; and<br />

• Smaller service providers:<br />

• Early-Late 1990s: business<br />

membership organizations as the<br />

main players (with significant donor<br />

support for delivery); and<br />

• Late-1990s-Now: private sector and<br />

other <strong>market</strong>-oriented providers with<br />

<strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> as the<br />

overarching objective (and with<br />

donor support more focused on<br />

<strong>development</strong> rather than delivery).<br />

Although perhaps less obvious in some<br />

countries, this shift in thinking that is so<br />

evident in Nepal is representative of a<br />

wider trend that has major implications<br />

for partner choice.<br />

35 “Partners” here refers to service providers.<br />

36 See McKenzie, J, "Creating a <strong>market</strong> in management training for Vietnam's private firms: MPDF's<br />

experience"; Paper presented to conference on "Business services for small enterprises in Asia: developing<br />

<strong>market</strong>s and measuring performance"; Hanoi, 3 rd -6 th April, 2000. Leila Webster reported at an April 2001<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> workshop that the new business management training products stimulated by the project is resulting in a<br />

new range of tailored management courses offered by a range of local providers.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


57<br />

C Informal, and<br />

C Individuals.<br />

The move toward <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong>, therefore, often means that agencies need to<br />

work with different kinds of organizations. In particular, agencies may need to consider<br />

working with for-profit private sector companies as the main providers of <strong>BDS</strong>.<br />

Criteria for Selecting Partners<br />

Criteria for selection should draw on the key design principles in <strong>BDS</strong> relating to factors<br />

such as ownership, commercial orientation, offer, people, resources and capacity, and<br />

systems. These should be formulated as questions or, if possible, as specific indicators. For<br />

example, the key questions might be the following:<br />

1. Do the people have the right skills and motivations, personal ownership, and working<br />

culture to enable them to work in a business-like manner?<br />

2. Does the structure—legal and operational—allow organizations to behave in an<br />

entrepreneurial way?<br />

3. Are internal systems—for example, payment structures, systems of performance<br />

assessment, and cost control—appropriate?<br />

4. Do partners have transactional relationships with their clients, manifested, for example,<br />

in their approach to pricing and client selection?<br />

5. Is the cost base of the organization consistent with the client group it seeks to serve?<br />

6. Are partners’ current approaches to product pricing fed by accurate cost information and<br />

consistent with longer-term sustainability?<br />

7. Do partners allocate costs to their products and activities to allow a clear view of the real<br />

costs of delivering products?<br />

8. Is the client base clearly defined?<br />

9. Is there consistency between the product offer and the client base?<br />

Although developing clear and specific criteria for selection is essential, it is important to<br />

recognize that—as with any business investment—this is not a full-proof process and, like<br />

business investors, personal factors (such as belief in the providers) play an important role in<br />

selection, even if they are difficult to capture in a list of criteria.<br />

Selection of Partners<br />

Chapter Four—How Do We Get There?—<br />

Core Implementation Challenges


58<br />

Unfortunately, there is no ideal organizational or institutional form for <strong>BDS</strong> provision, the<br />

<strong>market</strong> is complex and will vary widely from place to place. Therefore, selecting partners<br />

almost inevitably has a considerable element of trial and error and needs to be grounded on<br />

the basis of what works in any given context.<br />

Partner selection can be of the following types:<br />

# Relationship-based (personal knowledge and recommendation);<br />

# Tendering process; and<br />

# Market research.<br />

Relationship-based Selection<br />

Partners can be identified through the personal knowledge, existing networks, and<br />

acquaintances of donors and facilitators. This approach has much to commend it; it is cheap,<br />

working relations may already exist, and uncertainty can be reduced. It does have drawbacks:<br />

• It limits the field of selection both in terms of geographic area and the range of potential<br />

partners—you only work with those known to you.<br />

• There is some risk of continuing established relationships and expectations. This is<br />

particularly problematic if a donor or facilitator has a high profile or a history of more<br />

conventional or social <strong>development</strong> assistance 37 .<br />

This approach to partner selection also underlines the importance of donor/facilitators being<br />

business-like themselves, developing linkages and maintaining networks in the <strong>market</strong>place,<br />

and not operating from the confines of a <strong>development</strong>al vacuum.<br />

Tender-based Selection<br />

Borrowed from the corporate world, a tender-based approach invites applications to bid for<br />

donor/facilitator support. In an open or competitive tender, opportunities to apply are<br />

advertised, tender documents are drawn up and made available for a fee payable on<br />

application, selection criteria and processes are established, and selections are made on the<br />

basis of information provided and qualitative assessments. This kind of selection process<br />

allows a wider range of applicants to be considered and is particularly suitable when<br />

knowledge of an area or field is limited. It can also allow the donor/facilitator to project a<br />

business-like, focused image and reduce the scope for unrealistic expectations on the part of<br />

partners, which is often a risk when donor funds are involved. 38<br />

37 Many traditional <strong>BDS</strong> partners of donor agencies accustomed to working in a particular way and at a<br />

particular pace will certainly not be able to change to play the demand-oriented role necessary for success in<br />

a <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong>.<br />

38 Tenders or work orders have used by DAI in its <strong>BDS</strong> program in the Ukraine to induce trial of services and<br />

stimulate new provider entrants into serving SMEs instead of larger firms. DAI’s experience with work<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


59<br />

The drawbacks of tender-based selection include:<br />

• If done properly, it can be expensive and time consuming (although charging for tender<br />

documents can re-coup significant amounts of the cost, as well as testing the commitment<br />

of applicants).<br />

• If criteria selection and assessment are not rigorous, the success of the process will be<br />

jeopardized.<br />

• It often requires sifting through a large number of poor applicants to identify a few good<br />

ones. Even then tendering is not infallible, a 100 percent strike rate of perfect partners<br />

will never be achieved.<br />

A closed tender strikes a balance between the two approaches, where invitations to bid are<br />

extended to potential partners, most or all of which are relatively well known to the<br />

donor/facilitator. Application fees are usually not required for this type of tender.<br />

Using Market Analysis for Partner Selection<br />

As a result of <strong>market</strong> or consumer research (described earlier), information on service<br />

providers can come to light. This may either be via consumers or directly from industry<br />

surveys and can also generate useful information on service-provider strengths and<br />

weaknesses.<br />

WHAT ARE THE IMPLICATIONS FOR THE CAPACITIES OF DONORS AND FACILITATORS?<br />

The change, from more traditional approaches to the <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> paradigm, is<br />

significant. Built on a different view of SME <strong>development</strong> and <strong>BDS</strong>, it envisages new types<br />

of intervention, often with new partners and based on new relationships. For many agencies<br />

seeking to follow this approach, the change inherent within it will have major implications<br />

for their internal capacities and systems. Indeed, it is likely that for some agencies the kind of<br />

change required to pursue <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> may be beyond their capability. 39<br />

Among the potential key challenges to be faced are:<br />

# Organizational Structure: facilitating agencies dealing with providers and other <strong>market</strong><br />

players need to be able to develop transactional, business-like relations with them. This<br />

may need a degree of closeness and entrepreneurial flexibility that is difficult to achieve<br />

orders is described in a forthcoming paper by Mike Field entitled From Concept to Project Implementation -<br />

A Market Development Strategy for <strong>BDS</strong> in a Transition Economy.<br />

39 In these cases, if structural reasons prevent donors playing a valid role, their focus should move to other<br />

areas—such as the policy environment.<br />

Chapter Four—How Do We Get There?—<br />

Core Implementation Challenges


60<br />

within the confines of a formal and accountable donor agency. In these circumstances,<br />

working with a buffer facilitator (probably a business or an NGO) may be necessary.<br />

# Accountability and Flexibility in Project Designs: inherent within any move toward a<br />

more facilitative approach (and arguably any move towards institutional rather than<br />

organizational <strong>development</strong>) is a need for greater flexibility in project designs. Although<br />

<strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> projects will still have activities and outputs that aim to achieve<br />

positive impacts (so logframes are still applicable), when dealing with something as<br />

elusive as a dynamic <strong>market</strong>, planning frameworks need to take account of this reality by<br />

giving facilitators themselves an opportunity to be pro-active and entrepreneurial.<br />

# People: intervening to support <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> requires a good understanding of<br />

business and <strong>market</strong>s that is often foreign to people from a conventional <strong>development</strong><br />

background. Staff selection and <strong>development</strong> therefore need to focus on building this<br />

capacity.<br />

# Scale of Support: many of the failings of the past in <strong>BDS</strong> have stemmed from donors’<br />

priority to spend budgets efficiently rather than to have a positive impact on <strong>market</strong>s. The<br />

history of <strong>BDS</strong> is littered with severe and lasting distortions caused by too much donor<br />

money in the wrong place at the wrong time. Unlike say, microfinance, where large-scale<br />

disbursements (for on-lending) are possible, 40 interventions that achieve <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong><br />

<strong>development</strong> will usually be relatively small-scale, with multiple partners, and,<br />

inevitably, involve hands-on management. Using umbrella project structures as well as<br />

facilitators may help to overcome this problem.<br />

# Criteria for Assessment: measuring performance in relation to <strong>market</strong> indicators has<br />

clear implications for approaches to evaluation. Furthermore, in some instances, as part<br />

of a transactional relationship, provider rewards may be based on performance against<br />

agreed targets.<br />

# Beyond the Mantra of Donor Collaboration: <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong>s in developing countries,<br />

especially those that are poorest and least developed, are often fragile, having been<br />

subject to a variety of more or less (usually less) positive influences over many years.<br />

The <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong>-<strong>development</strong> approach cannot hope to work if donors don’t agree to its<br />

basic tenets and, if not in harmony, agree not to undermine one another’s efforts. This<br />

places greater pressure on donors to work meaningfully with one another and with<br />

governments to create a consensus over the long-term picture and how to get there.<br />

40 Although many would argue that this is also distorting capital <strong>market</strong>s.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


61<br />

CHAPTER FIVE<br />

HOW DO WE ASSESS OUR PERFORMANCE?—MONITORING AND<br />

EVALUATION <strong>BDS</strong> INTERVENTIONS<br />

Common approaches to monitoring and evaluation in <strong>BDS</strong> aren’t of much value to anyone. They<br />

neither help organizations improve their performance nor prove impact in a rigorous manner. New<br />

approaches need to reflect the different focus of <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> interventions and practice a<br />

more-balanced realism about what why we measure and what we can and cannot measure.<br />

This chapter outlines some distinctive features of approaches to monitoring and evaluation from a<br />

<strong>market</strong>-<strong>development</strong> perspective. The chapter first summarizes key common characteristics of<br />

monitoring and evaluation but then focuses on major differences with regard to what is measured, how<br />

we measure, and why we measure. The chapter concludes by highlighting some outstanding issues in<br />

monitoring and evaluation that are the subject of current debates.<br />

Key Questions:<br />

1. The basics of monitoring and evaluation don’t change—so what are they?<br />

2. Given the emergence of the <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> approach, what should we measure? What<br />

should be our priority indicators?<br />

3. What changes in measurement methods are necessary?<br />

4. What are the implications of this new approach on the reasons for measurement?<br />

5. What outstanding issues still remain in monitoring and evaluation in <strong>BDS</strong>?<br />

COMMON BASIS OF MONITORING AND EVALUATION:<br />

SOME THINGS DON’T CHANGE<br />

Although many things are significantly different from a <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong><br />

perspective, much remains the same. This applies particularly in monitoring and evaluation<br />

—a “standard” function in all <strong>development</strong> interventions. Although <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong><br />

<strong>development</strong> poses major challenges for monitoring and evaluation practices, much else is<br />

shared with the “old” approaches. The basics of monitoring and evaluation are unchanged,<br />

and these need to be summarized briefly before we focus on key differences between the<br />

“old” and the “new.”<br />

Dimensions of Performance<br />

Monitoring and evaluation is about assessing performance according to four broad<br />

dimensions or criteria. Together, these offer a comprehensive picture of an intervention’s<br />

characteristics—a filter with which to assess performance:<br />

Chapter Five—How do We Assess Our Performance?—<br />

Monitoring and Evaluation <strong>BDS</strong> Interventions


62<br />

1. Outreach: how many (breadth) and who are they (depth)?—the quantitative scale of a<br />

project and the identity of people, SMEs, and providers touched by it.<br />

2. Efficiency: are we doing things right?—the rate at which inputs are turned into outputs.<br />

3. Effectiveness: are we doing the right thing?—the extent to which higher-order<br />

impacts—related to changes in the real world of SMEs—have been achieved.<br />

4. Sustainability: will it last?—as previously defined, this refers to the <strong>market</strong> capacity to<br />

ensure that relevant, differentiated <strong>BDS</strong> continue to be offered and consumed by SMEs<br />

beyond the period of an intervention.<br />

Questions to Be Answered<br />

As in any business <strong>development</strong> project, in designing monitoring and evaluation systems the<br />

big questions to be asked (and answered) are the same here:<br />

• What do we need to know?—(defined in the form of indicators).<br />

• Who needs to know?—(understanding the needs of different stakeholders such as donors,<br />

facilitators, and providers).<br />

• When do they need to know? (timely availability of information for decision making).<br />

• How will this information be collected and analyzed? (methods and tools of analysis).<br />

• Who will be responsible for this process? (who does what in a donor-supported<br />

intervention).<br />

Factors to Consider in Developing Indicators<br />

Again, as in any business <strong>development</strong> project, the process of developing indicators needs to<br />

take into account a checklist of other factors such as 41 :<br />

• Relevant?—throwing light on the right area: indicators need to relate directly to the<br />

objective they seek to measure.<br />

• How much?—ambitious yet achievable: indicators should contain targets. How much<br />

these should be is a matter of discussion and, in the absence of benchmark “industry<br />

standards,” can be assessed only within the confines of an individual project.<br />

41 See Gibson, A; "Developing indicators in small enterprise <strong>development</strong> (SED) - a tool for people involved in<br />

designing, implementing and evaluating SED projects"; SDC-SED Working Paper No. 1; SDC, May 2001<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


63<br />

• How well?—the quality dimension to performance: indicators should offer insight into<br />

the quality of the change they have helped to bring about.<br />

• Is it feasible to measure? there really is a difference between what we would like to learn<br />

and what can be learned: indicators need to be set that can be measured given the<br />

practical limitations of resources and expertise available.<br />

• Are there “intermediate indicators”?- a plausible pathway to the bottom line: indicators<br />

should reflect changes closer to the point of consumption of <strong>BDS</strong> and not rely only on<br />

bottom-line changes in SME performance that may be influenced by many other factors.<br />

• Precise?—”tightness” in definition: without real specificity in the definition of indicators,<br />

interventions lack focus.<br />

• Is it business-like?—the overarching need to “think business”: indicators need to reflect<br />

SMEs and providers own priorities and business realities. Anything else undermines the<br />

general business-like message of <strong>BDS</strong>.<br />

Big Problems that Don’t Go Away<br />

The world of small businesses that <strong>BDS</strong> interventions seek to improve in some way is<br />

inherently complicated. SMEs do not exist by themselves; they compete in <strong>market</strong>s against<br />

other businesses, have relationships with a range of suppliers, are influenced by government<br />

actions, and are subject to the whims of <strong>market</strong> trends. Their world is complex. Indeed, often<br />

in small informal businesses where the distinction between business and household is<br />

blurred, this complexity is greater than in the formal sector.<br />

This complexity poses great challenges for monitoring and evaluation. A question illustrates<br />

this point: if an SME has changed positively apparently as a result of a project, how do we<br />

know that?<br />

• This change would not have happened without us; all the other myriad influences on a<br />

business have not caused change, rather than our project alone; and<br />

• This change is not at the expense of another SME nearby; it does not merely displace<br />

economic activity from one place to another without any real net addition.<br />

These issues of attribution are always relevant in business <strong>development</strong> situations, and<br />

(regrettably) there is no magical fix to call on to address them 42 .<br />

42 See Oldsman, E; "Evaluation as an effective management toool"; Paper presented to conference on "Business<br />

services for small enterprises in Asia: developing <strong>market</strong>s and measuring performance"; Hanoi, 3 rd -6 th April,<br />

2000 for a more detailed analysis of fundamental challenges inherent in rigorous approaches to evaluation.<br />

Chapter Five—How do We Assess Our Performance?—<br />

Monitoring and Evaluation <strong>BDS</strong> Interventions


64<br />

WHAT’S NEW IN MONITORING AND EVALUATION: WHAT IS MEASURED<br />

The key differences between the new and the old are summarized in Figure 15. This presents<br />

key indicators in relation to different levels within <strong>BDS</strong>: the <strong>market</strong> as a whole, providers,<br />

and SME consumers (its key actors) and the wider social/economic change that arises from<br />

enhanced <strong>BDS</strong> provision. 43<br />

Figure 15: Indicators in <strong>BDS</strong>: Emerging Trends<br />

Level The Old The New<br />

The major focus. Key indicators<br />

include change in:<br />

The Market for<br />

<strong>BDS</strong><br />

Providers of<br />

<strong>BDS</strong><br />

SMEs—<br />

Consumers of<br />

<strong>BDS</strong><br />

Beyond SME—<br />

Wider Social or<br />

Economic<br />

Change<br />

Not assessed<br />

Tend to focus on:<br />

• Delivery of subsidized<br />

outputs versus targets<br />

• Qualitative assessment of<br />

provider capacity<br />

• Cost recovery<br />

• Outreach<br />

• Qualitative feedback from<br />

SMEs<br />

Based on change in “bottom-line”<br />

performance:<br />

• Employment<br />

• Sales<br />

Seldom assessed<br />

Standard poverty indicators<br />

defined by the Development<br />

Assistance Committee (DAC)<br />

such as the proportion of the<br />

population living below $1 per<br />

• Market size: number of<br />

SMEs purchasing services<br />

• Volume of transactions:<br />

amount of sales by <strong>BDS</strong><br />

providers<br />

• number of <strong>BDS</strong> providers<br />

• the proportion of potential<br />

SME <strong>market</strong> reached by a<br />

<strong>BDS</strong><br />

Priority is:<br />

• Finance-based ratios<br />

assessing profitability<br />

• Outreach<br />

• Productivity ratios<br />

Based on SMEs’ own<br />

perceptions of <strong>BDS</strong> (more than<br />

project assisted), for example,<br />

change in:<br />

• Customer satisfaction<br />

• Customer awareness<br />

• Customer usage<br />

• Customer retention<br />

Seldom assessed directly—<br />

greater acceptance of <strong>market</strong>based<br />

proxies<br />

43 Donors or facilitators, of course, may be interested in change and performance at different levels. Providers<br />

also, as well as their own performance, may benefit from knowledge of the wider <strong>market</strong> and of SME<br />

perceptions of the <strong>market</strong>.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


65<br />

day income<br />

* This highlights key differences between old and new only: it is not an exhaustive list.<br />

Underpinning these differences are several factors.<br />

New Focus on the Marketplace for <strong>BDS</strong><br />

Previously, <strong>BDS</strong> interventions focused only on developing individual organizations; the<br />

wider <strong>market</strong> was a secondary contextual consideration only. Here, <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong><br />

becomes a major focus for intervention objectives and therefore for measurement. This<br />

<strong>market</strong> theme runs through all the indicators highlighted in Figure 15. Just as the main thrust<br />

of interventions should be to address <strong>market</strong> constraints, so indicators should also be <strong>market</strong>related.<br />

For example:<br />

Constraint/Problem<br />

Lack of information among SMEs of<br />

available <strong>BDS</strong><br />

Low levels of confidence and satisfaction<br />

among SMEs in available <strong>BDS</strong><br />

Inappropriate and/or low levels of<br />

product quality among <strong>BDS</strong> providers<br />

Low levels of business skills and<br />

knowledge among providers<br />

Possible Indicator<br />

Change in proportion of SMEs aware of<br />

particular <strong>BDS</strong> and providers<br />

Change in proportion of SMEs satisfied<br />

with particular <strong>BDS</strong><br />

Change in SME customers’ perception of<br />

quality of <strong>BDS</strong> available<br />

Change in providers’ awareness and use<br />

of new sources of technical/product<br />

information<br />

Providers—Commercial Players Means Commercially Based Indicators<br />

Previously, indicators of provider performance tended to be based on the delivery of<br />

(subsidized) outputs—for example, number of training programs and number of <strong>market</strong>ing<br />

events—with cost recovery as an afterthought. The new focus is on business and <strong>market</strong>based<br />

ratios that place the provider as a commercial entity in a <strong>market</strong>.<br />

Chapter Five—How do We Assess Our Performance?—<br />

Monitoring and Evaluation <strong>BDS</strong> Interventions


66<br />

SMEs—Getting “Real” over Assessing Performance<br />

Donors and facilitators spend inordinate amounts of time trying to assess change within<br />

SMEs that may (or may not) result from interventions. In the complex world of businesses,<br />

many factors affect performance and to isolate the influence of one of these—a <strong>BDS</strong><br />

supported by donor funds—is difficult and of questionable value. Moreover, one of donors’<br />

favorite indicators—employment—is inherently (and severely) problematic (Box 17).<br />

Markets presume that a <strong>BDS</strong> offers benefits and real value to the SME. A more realistic and<br />

practical approach to assessing impact at the level of the firm is based on SMEs’ own<br />

perceptions and experiences of services. Although some may complain that this is not<br />

objective, what matters ultimately—in a <strong>market</strong> context—is what consumers think.<br />

Box 15: The Problem with Employment as an Indicator in <strong>BDS</strong><br />

Although employment change is perhaps the most common indicator used by <strong>development</strong> agencies<br />

to assess performance, in practice it is a flawed indicator. Aside from the pervasive difficulties of<br />

attribution, there are three main problems associated with it:<br />

1. What is a job? The value of employment—jobs created—as a useful indicator for comparative<br />

analysis rests on an assumption that the unit of comparison (a job) is broadly similar from one place<br />

to another. In fact, there are a number of factors that mean what is termed “a job,” and these may<br />

vary greatly.<br />

• Income—how much is earned? In many family-owned businesses, family members working receive<br />

nothing. Informal sector trainees may have to pay to be trained and pay for the opportunity to work.<br />

In most developing economies, minimum wage legislation is widely ignored.<br />

• Job “size”: is there a minimum length of time per week that employment needs to reach before it can<br />

be regarded as a job? The ILO has used a threshold of 1 hour per week—but clearly this is very<br />

different from someone working a 40 or 50 hours week.<br />

• Job duration: for how long will a job last? In informal sector enterprises, in particular, there is great<br />

volatility in employment patterns that makes it difficult to ascertain job duration.<br />

• Other issues include working conditions with regard to safety and health, working hours, employee<br />

rights, satisfaction, and opportunities for further training.<br />

2. Employment is not an indicator shared by SMEs: despite the insistence of many <strong>development</strong><br />

agencies, most businesses do not exist to employ people. Using employment as an indicator of<br />

business <strong>development</strong> can be misleading. Businesses may expand and become more competitive<br />

and in the process lose labor.<br />

3. The pressures of political manipulation: no other indicator has been abused so much by agencies<br />

and their sponsors. Employment is an emotive subject; unemployment is seen to be a major<br />

symptom and cause of poverty. Organizations are under pressure to produce politically pleasing<br />

numbers and few questions are asked about their accuracy. The supposedly hard numbers of<br />

employment have an alluring certainty and precision surrounding them, encouraging the belief that<br />

they have a rigorous, scientific basis—a belief that is usually false.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


67<br />

Beyond SMEs—Unchanged Indicators<br />

The emergence of the <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> approach to <strong>BDS</strong> does not affect the ultimate<br />

objectives of interventions or the indicators applied to them. 44 However, in practice, because<br />

of the difficulty of measuring these, greater acceptance of proxy indicators may be necessary.<br />

For example, growing usage of <strong>BDS</strong> by SMEs owned by priority groups (such as women—<br />

characteristically relatively poor) may be used as proxy indicator for poverty reduction.<br />

Market-based monitoring and evaluation means greater use and acceptance of proxy<br />

indicators. Underpinning the entire approach to performance measurement in <strong>BDS</strong> is a<br />

practical recognition that greater reliance on proxy indicators is inevitable, necessary, and to<br />

be welcomed. Proxies are, of course, not new in <strong>development</strong>—they are an inherent part of<br />

the flow of cause and effect that interventions seek to initiate. 45 However, here we place<br />

proxy <strong>market</strong>-based indicators at the forefront of monitoring and evaluation because:<br />

• The analysis at the heart of <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> is explicit—better-functioning<br />

<strong>market</strong>s are good for business and ultimately good for the poor; and<br />

• There is growing acceptance that either (1) we can’t or (2) it’s too expensive to know<br />

directly the final impact of interventions on business and on people.<br />

For many in <strong>development</strong> agencies, this assertion may be difficult to accept. But anything<br />

else is less than realistic.<br />

WHAT’S NEW IN MONITORING AND EVALUATION: HOW WE MEASURE<br />

Differences in approaches to measurement follow on from the different emphasis in<br />

indicators, as shown in Figure 16. Some of factors should be noted.<br />

Market-Level—The Same Tools in Evaluation as in Design<br />

A <strong>market</strong> focus requires that we use the same kind of tools—UAI, FGDs, etc.—throughout<br />

the cycle of an intervention (see Chapter Two).<br />

Providers—Using Standard Business-Analysis Tools<br />

Assessing the performance in-depth of providers—as commercial players in a <strong>market</strong>place—requires<br />

use of the kind of approaches used in “normal” business (outside the<br />

44<br />

Development agencies increasingly agree on what these are through the DAC.<br />

45<br />

This causal flow is, of course, the logic at the heart of key planning tools such as the logframe.<br />

Chapter Five—How do We Assess Our Performance?—<br />

Monitoring and Evaluation <strong>BDS</strong> Interventions


68<br />

<strong>development</strong> domain) analysis. For agencies, this requires a level of business knowledge and<br />

skill that many currently do not possess and this is clearly a challenge to be faced. 46<br />

46 There are similarities here with the sea-change in agency capacities required by the microfinance revolution.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


69<br />

Figure 16: Measurement Methods in <strong>BDS</strong> Monitoring and Evaluation:<br />

Emerging Trends<br />

Level The Old The New<br />

The Market for<br />

<strong>BDS</strong><br />

Providers of<br />

<strong>BDS</strong><br />

SMEs—<br />

Consumers of<br />

<strong>BDS</strong><br />

Beyond SME—<br />

Wider Social or<br />

Economic<br />

Change<br />

Not assessed<br />

Range of methods such as<br />

• Simple comparison of planned<br />

versus actual outputs<br />

• Training assessment sheets<br />

• Comparison of direct costs<br />

versus revenues<br />

Follow-up surveys or meeting<br />

with SMEs to assess change.<br />

However:<br />

• Often no baseline<br />

• Attribution issues commonly<br />

ignored or dangerously<br />

simplified<br />

Case studies add strong<br />

qualitative understanding of<br />

dynamics of business change<br />

and use of services<br />

Requiring very large-scale,<br />

resource-intensive methods<br />

Adapting <strong>market</strong>-research tools<br />

such as usage, attitude, and<br />

image (UAI) surveys and focus<br />

group discussions to the <strong>BDS</strong><br />

context<br />

Ideally, these should be used in<br />

any case in identifying <strong>market</strong><br />

constraints and shaping the<br />

nature of an intervention.<br />

“Standard” business-analysis<br />

tools, for example, allocation of<br />

costs and revenues to profit<br />

centers and use of timesheets<br />

for staff<br />

Based on surveys of SMEs’ own<br />

perceptions (thereby reducing<br />

the attribution problem)<br />

Similar use of case studies<br />

“Objective” assessment of<br />

change (proving impact) left to<br />

full-scale experimental, quasiexperimental<br />

approaches<br />

Same<br />

SMEs—Practical and More-Market Focused Approaches<br />

Until now, common methods have been based on follow-up surveys with samples of SME<br />

clients. However, in practice, these ignore basic rules on survey design, have no valid<br />

baseline and other comparative data, and generate information that neither proves anything<br />

nor is useful in improving performance. The issue is not simply that rough approaches<br />

Chapter Five—How do We Assess Our Performance?—<br />

Monitoring and Evaluation <strong>BDS</strong> Interventions


70<br />

produce roughly accurate data—they may be wildly misleading. 47 Although case studies may<br />

generate valuable qualitative insights, in general there is widespread dissatisfaction with the<br />

usefulness of monitoring and evaluation for project managers. Responding to this situation,<br />

<strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> perspective assesses change within SMEs by:<br />

# Using common <strong>market</strong>-research tools to assess their perception and use of services as<br />

consumers;<br />

# Using case studies to gain a deeper understanding of how <strong>BDS</strong> can impact on business<br />

processes and performance; and<br />

# Leaving rigorous impact assessment to “one-off” scientific approaches (these will usually<br />

need to be instigated and resourced externally).<br />

WHAT’S NEW IN MONITORING AND EVALUATION: WHY WE MEASURE<br />

Although monitoring and evaluation generally is concerned with performance measurement<br />

for management decision-making, accountability, and learning purposes, in specific terms it<br />

has two objectives:<br />

• Improving Performance: helping organizations (and their managers)—donors,<br />

facilitators, and providers—improve what they do, that is, offering them the right kind of<br />

information at the right time so they can make the right decisions.<br />

• Proving Impact: helping prove that a <strong>BDS</strong> intervention has led to positive and significant<br />

change.<br />

Both of these reasons—improving performance and proving impact—are important and<br />

valid. But it is also important to realize they are different. The first serves an operational and<br />

business-oriented interest; the second is associated with a wider, strategic, economic, and<br />

social (and political) perspective—especially those of <strong>development</strong> agency funders. Knowing<br />

why monitoring and evaluation information is required leads to different conclusions about<br />

what should be measured and therefore on how they are measured. For example:<br />

• Providers’ direct interest is the profitability of services and the direct feedback from<br />

SMEs on quality and satisfaction; with this knowledge, they can make appropriate<br />

improvements.<br />

• Facilitators are also interested in the above but, pursuing the overall objective of <strong>market</strong><br />

<strong>development</strong>, want to know about the volume of transactions, number of providers, and<br />

the like.<br />

47 Commonly (if privately) <strong>development</strong> professionals will admit to having little confidence in the data<br />

generated through such surveys.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


71<br />

• Donors may be interested in both of these perspectives but, given their immediate<br />

exposure to more political pressures, may also want to prove that public funds are<br />

generating employment gains in SMEs or having a wider positive impact on society.<br />

A major problem associated with monitoring and evaluation in <strong>BDS</strong> (and in other spheres) is<br />

a blurring of improve and prove agendas. Practical management decision-making,<br />

accountability, and learning purposes are lumped uncomfortably together. Characteristically,<br />

this can lead, on the one hand, to organizations not getting the information they need to make<br />

rational decisions and, on the other, to half-hearted (and doomed) attempts to measure impact<br />

that do not prove impact because there are so many caveats associated with the data.<br />

Underpinning new approaches to monitoring and evaluation in <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong><br />

(Figure 17) is a new and candid transparency over why we measure.<br />

• Most monitoring and evaluation is concerned with improving performance; this should be<br />

the immediate priority and be used on a regular basis. Common methods— <strong>market</strong>research<br />

tools, case studies, provider financial analysis, and surveys—are focused on this<br />

goal.<br />

• Monitoring and evaluation methods that can result in valid, generalizable findings—<br />

proving impact—that take account of attribution are difficult and expensive. If one is<br />

serious about proving impact there is no real alternative to these; for most organizations,<br />

these kinds of studies will not be possible or justifiable.<br />

Figure 17: Why We Measure in <strong>BDS</strong>: Emerging Trends<br />

The Old<br />

The purposes of monitoring and<br />

evaluation often ill-defined and<br />

ambiguous<br />

In particular, the objectives of<br />

improving performance and<br />

proving impact often blurred<br />

Result?—neither objective is<br />

achieved<br />

Recognition that:<br />

The New<br />

• Prove and improve objectives<br />

are both valid but are different<br />

• Reasons for monitoring and<br />

evaluation (why) “drive” choice<br />

of indicators (what) and<br />

methods (how)<br />

Consequently we need:<br />

• Greater clarity in monitoring and<br />

evaluation objectives<br />

• Separation of improve and<br />

prove approaches to monitoring<br />

and evaluation<br />

OUTSTANDING ISSUES<br />

Although the general trends and overall direction in monitoring and evaluation in <strong>BDS</strong> are<br />

clear, there are still many aspects where there is no consensus among agencies and where<br />

Chapter Five—How do We Assess Our Performance?—<br />

Monitoring and Evaluation <strong>BDS</strong> Interventions


72<br />

substantial questions remain unanswered. Many of these are the subject of applied research,<br />

and this should generate useful insights in the coming period. In particular, under the<br />

auspices of USAID Microenterprise Best Practices (MBP) Project, the performance<br />

measurement framework developed in 1999 is being tested in different situations by a team<br />

of researchers. 48 Many of these are also important considerations for the design of<br />

interventions. Among the key issues where further work is required are the following:<br />

1. How should <strong>market</strong>s be defined? Setting parameters—as outlined in Chapter Two—by<br />

geography, product, consumer, or sub-sector or a combination of these brings with it<br />

advantages and disadvantages. What <strong>guide</strong>lines should agencies follow in developing<br />

such boundaries?<br />

2. What are the most cost-effective indicators for assessing <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong>?<br />

Potentially, <strong>market</strong>s are very large and trying to track changes in them may be expensive.<br />

Are there useful proxies more immediately measurable through the supply-side, or is it<br />

always necessary to go directly to the demand-side?<br />

3. How can monitoring and evaluation methods be adapted to make sure that hidden<br />

<strong>BDS</strong> are still captured as part of the overall <strong>market</strong> picture? Many important<br />

services—often concerned with advice and knowledge—are offered without a financial<br />

transaction but still within the confines of a transactional relationship. They are still <strong>BDS</strong>;<br />

what tools make sure that we include them?<br />

4. Can benchmarks be used in <strong>BDS</strong> in the same way as in normal industries? The<br />

potential benefits of benchmarks are clear: they offer standard, objective ways of<br />

comparing the performance of different organizations in different places. Under what<br />

circumstances can benchmarking be pursued for providers (or others), and what<br />

indicators should be used?<br />

5. How can changes in organizations—who may not be direct partners of a project—<br />

be assessed? Inherent in a facilitating approach to <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong> is the view that a<br />

range of actors will be encouraged to behave differently—influenced by interventions if<br />

not the focus of direct investments: how can we understand change here?<br />

6. How can the ultimate impact of <strong>BDS</strong> on bottom-line indicators of SME<br />

performance—profitability and productivity—as well as employment be assessed?<br />

Methodologies to assess this relationship will be expensive, but can general, valid rules<br />

about the relationship between <strong>BDS</strong> interventions and SME performance be developed<br />

that obviate the (expensive) need to always try to measure this step of the chain from<br />

intervention to final change? 49<br />

7. How can the relationship among <strong>BDS</strong>, SME <strong>development</strong>, and poverty reduction be<br />

assessed? Can valid proxy relationships be established between, for example, use of <strong>BDS</strong><br />

48 See www.mip.org and follow links to <strong>BDS</strong> Performance Framework Field Research.<br />

49 ILO, supported by other bilateral donors, plans to assess impact of <strong>BDS</strong> on SMEs, employment, and poverty<br />

reduction.<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices<br />

Development Alternatives, Inc.


73<br />

and poverty reduction? Or is the relationship one that is more indirect (if still valid)<br />

through the contribution of more efficient <strong>market</strong>s to firm competitiveness and economic<br />

growth.<br />

8. Can costs-benefit analysis be adapted appropriately to <strong>BDS</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>development</strong>?<br />

Although a comparison of costs and benefits is clearly important, in practice, cost-benefit<br />

analysis has proved a difficult and impractical methodology; it is not yet clear how it<br />

might be adapted for wider use.<br />

Chapter Five—How do We Assess Our Performance?—<br />

Monitoring and Evaluation <strong>BDS</strong> Interventions


A-1<br />

ANNEX A<br />

REFERENCES


A-3<br />

KEY REFERENCES<br />

Anderson, Gavin, “The Hidden MSE Service Sector – Research Into Commercial <strong>BDS</strong><br />

Provision to Micro and Small Enterprises in Vietnam and Thailand”, International<br />

Labour Organisation. Prepared for the Donors Committee Conference on Business<br />

Services for Small Enterprises in Asia: Developing Markets and Measuring<br />

Performance, Hanoi, April 2000.<br />

Bennett R. and P. Robson; The Market for External Business Advice Services in Britain;<br />

ESRC, 1999.<br />

Biggs, Tyler; "A microeconomic evaluation of the Mauritius Technology Diffusion Scheme";<br />

RPED Discussion Paper, The World Bank, November 1999<br />

Botelho, Caren Addis and Lara Goldmark, “Paraguay Vouchers Revisited: Strategies for the<br />

Development of Training Markets”, United States Agency for International<br />

Development Microenterprise Best Practices managed by Development Alternatives,<br />

Inc.. Prepared for the Donors Committee Conference on Business Services for Small<br />

Enterprises in Asia: Developing Markets and Measuring Performance, Hanoi, April<br />

2000.<br />

Ceglie, Giovanna and Marco Dini, “Clusters and Network Development in Developing<br />

Countries” in Levitsky, Jacob (ed.), Business Development Services: A Review of<br />

International Experience. IT Publications, London, 2000.<br />

Committee of Donor Agencies for Small Enterprise Development (Jim Tanburn – ILO,<br />

Gabriele Trah – GTZ and Kris Hallberg – Word Bank), “Business Development<br />

Services for Small Enterprises: Guidelines for Donor Interventions”. Revision 15,<br />

June, 2000.<br />

Committee of Donor Agencies for Small Enterprise Development (Alan Gibson, Springfield<br />

Center) “Business Development Services for SMEs: Preliminary Guidelines for<br />

Donor-Funded Interventions,” January 1998.<br />

Crisafulli, Daniel, “Matching Grant Schemes” in Levitsky, Jacob (ed.), Business<br />

Development Services: A Review of International Experience. IT Publications,<br />

London, 2000.<br />

Field, Michael, Rob Hitchins and Marshall Bear, “Designing <strong>BDS</strong> Interventions as if<br />

Markets Matter.” United States Agency for International Development<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices managed by Development Alternatives, Inc., July<br />

2000.<br />

Gibson, Alan, “The Development of Markets for Business Development Services: Where<br />

We Are Now and How to Go Further”, Springfield Centre for Business in<br />

Development, for the International Labour Organisation. Prepared for the Donors


A-4<br />

Committee Conference on Business Services for Small Enterprises in Asia:<br />

Developing Markets and Measuring Performance, Hanoi, April 2000.<br />

Gibson, Alan; "Developing Indicators in Small Enterprise Development Projects"; Swiss<br />

Agency for Development and Cooperation, 2000.<br />

Gibson, A; "Developing Indicators in Small Enterprise Development (SED) - A Tool For<br />

People Involved in Designing, Implementing and Evaluating SED Projects"; SDC-<br />

SED Working Paper No. 1; SDC, May 2001.<br />

Gibson, Alan and Robert Hitchins, “Swisscontact: Business Centre Approach in Indonesia<br />

and the Philippines” in Levitsky, Jacob (ed.), Business Development Services: A<br />

Review of International Experience. IT Publications, London, 2000.<br />

Goldmark, Lara, “Sorting Out the Truth: Financial Viability of <strong>BDS</strong>,” IDB. Prepared for the<br />

Donors Committee Conference on Business Development Services: Building a<br />

Modern and Effective Business Service Sector for Small Enterprises. Rio de Janeiro<br />

Brazil, 1999.<br />

Goldmark, Lara, “Voucher Programs: What Next After Paraguay,” IDB. Prepared for the<br />

Donors Committee Conference on Business Development Services: Building a<br />

Modern and Effective Business Service Sector for Small Enterprises. Rio de Janeiro<br />

Brazil, 1999.<br />

Hagblade, Steve and Matt Gamser, “A Field Manual for Subsector Practitioners,” a USAID<br />

GEMINI publication, Pact Publication, 1991.<br />

Hallberg, Kristin, “A Market-Oriented Strategy for Small and Medium Scale Enterprises”.<br />

IFC Discussion Paper, February 2000.<br />

Hanna, James and Ton de Wilde, “Jamaica MicroNET,” World Bank. Prepared for the<br />

Donors Committee Conference on Building a Modern and Effective Business<br />

Development Services Industry for Small Enterprises, Brazil, April 1999.<br />

Havers, Mark, “ApproTEC: Developing Technology Based Business Opportunities,” DFID,<br />

Prepared for the Donors Committee Conference on Business Development Services:<br />

How sustainable can they really be?” Zimbabwe, 1998.<br />

Hitchins, Rob, "Developing Markets for <strong>BDS</strong>: Designing and Implementing More Effective<br />

Interventions"; SDC Issue Paper No. 5; Swiss Agency for Development and<br />

Cooperation, 2000.<br />

Hitchins, R; "Assessing the Experience of Swisscontact's Business Centre Approach in Latin<br />

America and Asia"; Swisscontact; SDC Issue paper No.3, 1999.


A-5<br />

Hitchins, R and Gibson, A; "The Kenya Management Assistance Program- Innovative<br />

Delivery of Counseling and Training"; Paper presented to the Workshop on <strong>BDS</strong> for<br />

SMEs, "How sustainable Can Business Development Services Really Be?"; Harare,<br />

29 th September - 1 st October, 1998.<br />

Hileman, Milena and Jim Tanburn, The Wheels of Trade – Developing Markets for Business<br />

Services. IT Publications, London, 2000.<br />

Lee, Yoo-Mi, and Marshall Bear, “Business Service Centers in Ukraine: A Study of the<br />

Agency for the Development of Enterprise, the L'viv NewBizNet Business Service<br />

Center, and the Vinnytsia Consulting Center,” Development Alternatives, Inc. August<br />

1999.<br />

Lusby, Frank, “Sector Approach to Enterprise Development, Action for Enterprise, August,<br />

1999.<br />

McKenzie, John, “Creating a Market in Management Training for Vietnamese’s Private<br />

Firms: MPDF’s Experience”, Mekong Project Development Facility (IFC). Prepared<br />

for the Donors Committee Conference on Business Services for Small Enterprises in<br />

Asia: Developing Markets and Measuring Performance, Hanoi, April 2000.<br />

McVay, Mary, “Measuring the Performance of Business Development Services for Small<br />

Enterprises: Guide to the Preparation of Case Studies for the <strong>BDS</strong> Conference in<br />

Hanoi, Vietnam 2000. USAID Microenterprise Best Practices Project and ILO’s<br />

ISEP programme. September, 1999.<br />

McVay, Mary, “Micorenterprise Marketing: Trends, Lessons Learned and Challenges,”<br />

SEEP 1999.<br />

Miehlbradt, Alexandra Overy with contributions from Ronald T. Chua, “Technical Note:<br />

Applying Marketing Research Tools to the Design and Improvement of Business<br />

Development Services”. United States Agency for International Development<br />

Microenterprise Best Practices managed by Development Alternatives, Inc., June<br />

1999.<br />

Mikkelsen, Lene, “Good Practice in Microenterprise <strong>market</strong>ing: Cases from Latin America,”<br />

IDB, Prepared for the Donors Committee Conference on Business Development<br />

Services: Building a Modern and Effective Business Service Sector for Small<br />

Enterprises. Rio de Janeiro Brazil, 1999.<br />

Newnham Jack,“BRAC Poultry Programme in Bangladesh,” DFID, Donors Committee<br />

Conference on Business Services for Small Enterprises in Asia: Developing Markets<br />

and Measuring Performance, April 2000.


A-6<br />

Oldsman, E: "Evaluation as an Effective Management Tool," Paper prepared for the Donor<br />

Committee Conference on Business Services for Small Enterprises in Asia:<br />

Developing Markets and Measuring Performance, Hanoi, April 2000.<br />

Riddle, Dorothy; "Service-Led Growth: The Role of the Service Sector in World<br />

Development," Praeger Publications (USA); 1992.<br />

Riddle, Dorothy, “What Do We Know About <strong>BDS</strong> Markets?” Service-Growth Consultants<br />

Inc., sponsored by the Mekong Project Development Facility (IFC). Prepared for the<br />

Donors Committee Conference on Business Services for Small Enterprises in Asia:<br />

Developing Markets and Measuring Performance, Hanoi, April 2000.<br />

Sandee, Henry and Sandra C. van Hulsen, “Business Development Services for Small and<br />

Cottage Industry Clusters in Indonesia: A Review of Case Studies from Central<br />

Java”, Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam, sponsored by the Ministry of Foreign Affairs of<br />

The Netherlands. Prepared for the Donors Committee Conference on Business<br />

Services for Small Enterprises in Asia: Developing Markets and Measuring<br />

Performance, Hanoi, April 2000.<br />

Schor, Gabriel and Lara Goldmark, “Voucher Programs: Potential, Problems and Prospects”.<br />

Prepared for the Donors Committee Conference on Building a Modern and Effective<br />

Business Development Services Industry in Latin America and the Caribbean, Rio de<br />

Janeiro, March 1999.<br />

Tomecko, Jim, “The Application of Market Led Tools in the Design of <strong>BDS</strong> Interventions Or<br />

(Influencing the Price of Soup in Nepal)”, GTZ/IEDI Nepal. Prepared for the Donors<br />

Committee Conference on Business Services for Small Enterprises in Asia:<br />

Developing Markets and Measuring Performance, Hanoi, April 2000.<br />

World Bank; "World <strong>development</strong> report: the state in a changing world"; Oxford University<br />

Press (1999).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!