08.04.2015 Views

The Inflation Cycle of 2002 to 2015 - Uhlmann Price Securities

The Inflation Cycle of 2002 to 2015 - Uhlmann Price Securities

The Inflation Cycle of 2002 to 2015 - Uhlmann Price Securities

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

For a printed copy <strong>of</strong> this report, contact your Legg Mason account representative.<br />

Equity Research<br />

Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong><br />

We Began With “Do Commodity-Serving Companies Deserve Your Capital?”<br />

• We believe that inflation versus deflation is underappreciated as a determinant <strong>of</strong> sec<strong>to</strong>r selection success.<br />

• In the past century, s<strong>to</strong>cks and commodities have alternated leadership in regular cycles averaging 18 years.<br />

• During commodity deflation, s<strong>to</strong>cks rose 11.6% per year, but during inflation s<strong>to</strong>cks rose 3.4% per year.<br />

• Although war contributes <strong>to</strong> inflation, s<strong>to</strong>cks <strong>of</strong>ten faltered in the pre-war decade for a variety <strong>of</strong> reasons.<br />

• We see strong developing country (China, FSU, etc.) usage relative <strong>to</strong> supply boosting commodity prices.<br />

• Or, if oil deflates, we see Persian Gulf instability leading <strong>to</strong> major conflict that disrupts oil supply.<br />

• By <strong>2015</strong>, we expect $60/bbl. oil, $4.50/bu. corn, and a 5.8% S&P 500 annual <strong>to</strong>tal return over the period.<br />

• Commodity strength may benefit machinery EPS, while inflation reduces real capital costs.<br />

• This potential widening <strong>of</strong> the EVA ® spread may be a reason for the machinery s<strong>to</strong>cks’ high P/Es.<br />

April 19, <strong>2002</strong><br />

• We upgraded our rating on Caterpillar, Deere and Joy Global shares from Market Performance <strong>to</strong> Buy.<br />

100<br />

U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index Performance Relative <strong>to</strong> <strong>The</strong> Commodity Market Index, 1870 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E<br />

Rising red bars = S<strong>to</strong>cks are beating commodity returns.<br />

Falling blue bars = Commodities are beating s<strong>to</strong>ck returns.<br />

10<br />

S<strong>to</strong>cks and commodities have alternated leadership seven<br />

times since 1877 for periods averaging 18 years in length.<br />

1<br />

<strong>2002</strong><br />

<strong>to</strong><br />

<strong>2015</strong><br />

are Legg<br />

Mason<br />

Estimates<br />

0<br />

1870<br />

1880<br />

1890<br />

1900<br />

1910<br />

1920<br />

1930<br />

1940<br />

1950<br />

1960<br />

1970<br />

1980<br />

1990<br />

2000<br />

U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Composite <strong>Price</strong> index divided by the PPI Commodities <strong>Price</strong> Index, years 1871 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E<br />

2010E<br />

Source: NBER, Standard & Poor’s Corporation, U.S. Dept. <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Legg Mason format and estimates<br />

Barry B. Bannister, CFA<br />

Paul Forward<br />

(410) 454-4496 Associate Analyst<br />

bbbannister@leggmason.com (410) 454-4138<br />

pforward@leggmason.com<br />

Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc. - Legg Mason Headquarters - P.O. Box 1476 Baltimore, MD 21203 - Member New York S<strong>to</strong>ck Exchange, Inc. - (410) 539-0000


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -2- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Table <strong>of</strong> Contents<br />

Executive Summary……………………………………………………………………………….……… 5 – 6<br />

Report Conclusion: “His<strong>to</strong>ry Doesn’t Repeat Itself, But It Does Rhyme” – Mark Twain………7 – 25<br />

S<strong>to</strong>ck Rating Changes……………………………..…………………………………………… 8 – 15<br />

<strong>Inflation</strong> As a Trade-Off Between Hard Assets and Financial Assets……………………….. 16 – 23<br />

<strong>The</strong> Structure <strong>of</strong> This Report ..….……………………………………………………………..… 24 – 25<br />

Scenario (1) Continued Deflation, the U.S. Equity Bull Market, and Strong “Tech”<br />

Capital Spending: Probability: 15%……………………………………………………………………26 – 38<br />

Continued Deflation?………………………………………………………………………...… 26<br />

<strong>The</strong> His<strong>to</strong>rical Parallels in Monetary Policy His<strong>to</strong>ry………………...…………………….. 26 – 27<br />

Money Supply Growth and Deteriorating Velocity as Precursors <strong>of</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> ..…………. 27 – 29<br />

<strong>The</strong> Outlook for Domestic Productivity as An Offset To Loose Monetary Policy……….. 29 – 30<br />

<strong>The</strong> Outlook for Productivity Improvement Overseas That Affects U.S. Competitiveness. 30 – 32<br />

<strong>The</strong> Commodity <strong>Price</strong> Sensitivity <strong>of</strong> the U.S. Economy…………………………………….… 32 – 35<br />

Continuation <strong>of</strong> the Bull Market and Strong “Tech” Spending (?)...………………………… 35 – 37<br />

<strong>The</strong> End <strong>of</strong> the Status Quo?……………...…………………………………………………..… 38<br />

Scenario (2) Rapid Developing Country Modernization And Global Economic Growth Leading<br />

To a Sustained and <strong>Inflation</strong>ary Boom in Commodity Demand: Probability: 60%…….…….39 – 62<br />

Will Surging Demand Create Peacetime Commodity <strong>Inflation</strong>?…….……………………… 39 – 40<br />

<strong>The</strong> Energy <strong>Price</strong> Drivers, 1870 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E………………………...…………….…………… 40 – 43<br />

<strong>The</strong> Demand Side <strong>of</strong> the Oil Equation – <strong>The</strong> 2001 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> Environment……. ..………..… 43<br />

<strong>The</strong> China Example – Pushing the Oil Demand Envelope…………………….…………… 43 – 45<br />

<strong>The</strong> Supply Side <strong>of</strong> the Oil Equation – <strong>The</strong> 2001 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> Environment.…………………… 45 – 48<br />

Substitute Fuels – Promising, But Enough <strong>to</strong> Make a Difference?…………………………... 49 – 50<br />

U.S. Farm Commodity Export and <strong>Inflation</strong> Prospects, <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E…………………... 51 – 62<br />

U.S. Farm Commodity <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong>s…………………...…………….……………………..… 51 – 53<br />

<strong>The</strong> U.S. Farm Export Outlook………….………………………...…………….…………… 53 – 57<br />

U.S. Agricultural Exports and Deere S<strong>to</strong>ck……………………………….…. ..…………… 57 – 58<br />

<strong>The</strong> Global Competitiveness <strong>of</strong> the U.S. Farm Economy….…………………….…………. 58 – 62<br />

Scenario (3) Middle East War(s) in the Period <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> That Result in Extended Oil<br />

Supply Disruptions: Probability: 25%………………………………………………………...… 63 – 81<br />

<strong>The</strong> Risk <strong>of</strong> U.S. Military Action <strong>to</strong> Change the Iraqi Regime That May<br />

Lead <strong>to</strong> a Destabilized Region…………………………………………….………………….. 65 – 66<br />

<strong>The</strong> Risk That Iraq Has or Will Soon Succeed in the Development<br />

<strong>of</strong> Nuclear Weapons………………………………………………...……………….….…….66 – 69<br />

<strong>The</strong> Risk <strong>of</strong> Civil War That Targets Saudi Arabia's Ruling al-Saud Monarchy ..…………..69 – 74<br />

<strong>The</strong> Risk <strong>of</strong> Conventional (Non-Nuclear) War Between States in the Region……………... 74 – 77<br />

<strong>The</strong> Risk <strong>of</strong> Terrorists Obtaining Nuclear Weapons Developed in the Soviet Union……...78


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -3- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Non-Economic Contrasts Between East and West That Affect the Investment Outlook... 79 – 81<br />

Political and Cultural Differences Between East and West………………………………..… 79 – 80<br />

Areas <strong>of</strong> Instability in the Political and Cultural Relations Between East and West………. 80 – 81<br />

<strong>The</strong> Fork in the Road – Inves<strong>to</strong>rs are Along For the Ride………………….…. ..…………. 81<br />

Index <strong>of</strong> Exhibits<br />

Exhibit 1 – <strong>The</strong> S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Versus Machinery and the S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Versus Commodities,<br />

1945 <strong>to</strong> 2001 - Is this a new, secular bull market for machinery?…………..…………………. 8<br />

Exhibit 2 – Machinery Index (CAT+DE+IR+PH) <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong>s, January 1981 <strong>to</strong> Present…...…….…. 9<br />

Exhibit 3 – Machinery Index (CAT+DE+IR+PH) <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong>s, January 1965 <strong>to</strong> April 1981.…….…. 10<br />

Exhibit 4 – CAT Financial His<strong>to</strong>ry and Our Projections <strong>to</strong> 2006, including EVA…….……………….. 11<br />

Exhibit 5 – CAT <strong>Price</strong>-<strong>to</strong>-Sales Multiple Versus EVA, 1970 <strong>to</strong> 2006P…………………....……………. 12<br />

Exhibit 6 – DE s<strong>to</strong>ck Versus U.S. Farm Exports, 1962 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E…………………………….……….….. 13<br />

Exhibit 7 – U.S. Electricity Generation By Fuel Source, 1920-2001, Total and % Share By Fuel.…... 15<br />

Exhibit 8 – Coal <strong>Price</strong>s Versus S<strong>to</strong>ck <strong>Price</strong>s, real (index year 2000) prices, 1901 <strong>to</strong> 2001….………… 15<br />

Exhibit 9 – <strong>Inflation</strong> and Deflation <strong>Cycle</strong>s, 1898 <strong>to</strong> 2001……………………………………….…….…... 16<br />

Exhibit 10 – PPI All Commodities Index Y/Y % Change Compared <strong>to</strong> the PPI Subindices for<br />

Energy, Farm Products and Metals, 1870 <strong>to</strong> 2001…….…………………………………………... 17<br />

Exhibit 11 – Machinery Purchasers XOM, PD, IP and HM Fixed Asset Replacement Rate Versus<br />

Average Remaining Useful Life Of Property, Plant and Equipment, 1950 <strong>to</strong> 2001…..………. 18<br />

Exhibit 12 – PPI for All Commodities Index, 1870 <strong>to</strong> 2001, With Our Forecast <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>……………... 19<br />

Exhibit 13 – U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index, 1870 <strong>to</strong> 2001, With Our Forecast <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>…………………….. 19<br />

Exhibit 14 – U.S. CPI <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong>s, 1880 <strong>to</strong> 2001, With Our <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> Estimates………….…. 20<br />

Exhibit 15 – S<strong>to</strong>ck Returns Minus <strong>Inflation</strong>, 1880 <strong>to</strong> 2001, with our <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> Estimates………... 21<br />

Exhibit 16 – <strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong>-Adjusted U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index, M2 Money Supply, and U.S. Consumer<br />

<strong>Price</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong>, <strong>The</strong> 1901 and 1933 <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> Turning Points +/- 12 Years……………... 22<br />

Exhibit 16 Cont’d. – <strong>Inflation</strong>-Adjusted U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index, M2 Money Supply, and U.S.<br />

Consumer <strong>Inflation</strong>, <strong>The</strong> 1963 and 2001(E) <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> Turning Points +/- 12 Years…….. 23<br />

Exhibit 17 – Return and Growth Table for Commodities, S<strong>to</strong>cks and <strong>Inflation</strong>, <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E……….. 25<br />

Exhibit 18 – M2 Money Supply Vs. Consumer <strong>Inflation</strong>, 10-Year Moving Avg., 1880 <strong>to</strong> 2001……….. 28<br />

Exhibit 19 – M2 Velocity Versus Consumer <strong>Inflation</strong>, 10-Year Moving Average, 1880 <strong>to</strong> 2001………. 28<br />

Exhibit 20 – M2 Velocity Versus CPI <strong>Inflation</strong>, 1960 <strong>to</strong> 2001………………………………………………. 29<br />

Exhibit 21 – U.S. Productivity Growth Versus Demographic Measures: <strong>The</strong> Ratio <strong>of</strong> Experienced Workers<br />

<strong>to</strong> Less Experienced Workers as a Driver For U.S. Productivity Growth………………………. 30<br />

Exhibit 22 – Comparative Demographic Trends That We Believe Shape Productivity, the Ratio <strong>of</strong> 35-49<br />

Year Olds <strong>to</strong> 20-34 Year Olds, China, Japan and the U.S., 1950 <strong>to</strong> 2050E………………...…….. 31<br />

Exhibit 23 – U.S. End-Use Energy as a Percentage <strong>of</strong> GDP……………………………………………..…... 32<br />

Exhibit 24 – U.S. Home Size Versus Energy Costs……………………………………………………………. 33<br />

Exhibit 25 – Long-Term Temperature Trends And Energy <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong>……………………………….... 34<br />

Exhibit 26 – S&P Composite P/E Ratios And <strong>Inflation</strong> Based On the Experience <strong>of</strong> the Period 1927<br />

<strong>to</strong> 2001..…………………………………………………………………………………………………... 35<br />

Exhibit 27 – S&P S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Composite Average Annual P/E, 1927 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>(E)……………………... 36<br />

Exhibit 28 – U.S. Financing Gap, 1952 <strong>to</strong> Present……………………………………………………………. 37<br />

Exhibit 29 – <strong>The</strong> Declining Ability Of Debt <strong>to</strong> Underpin U.S. GDP Growth……………………………... 39<br />

Exhibit 30 – Raw Materials Intensity At Different Stages <strong>of</strong> Economic Development………………….. 39


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -4- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Exhibit 31 – PPI Energy <strong>Price</strong> His<strong>to</strong>ry and Supply/Demand Drivers, 1870 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E...………………... 41<br />

Exhibit 32 – Oil Consumption Per Capita Versus Oil Intensity <strong>of</strong> GDP, 62 Nations, As Of Year 2000 42<br />

Exhibit 33 – Oil Consumption Per Capita for Japan, South Korea, and China, 1950-2001……………. 44<br />

Exhibit 34 – U.S. Oil Consumption vs. GDP, 1902 <strong>to</strong> 2001, and for China, 1975 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E…………... 45<br />

Exhibit 35 – World Oil Supply And Demand His<strong>to</strong>ry and Our Projection <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>……………………... 46<br />

Exhibit 36 – Oil Export-Based Economies as Share <strong>of</strong> World Oil Production, 1965-<strong>2015</strong>E…………… 47<br />

Exhibit 37 – Non-OPEC Reserve-To-Production Ratio, 1952 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E…………………………………... 47<br />

Exhibit 38 – Net Exports and Imports <strong>of</strong> Oil, and Oil <strong>Price</strong>s, 1965-<strong>2015</strong>E..……………………………… 48<br />

Exhibit 39 – Deere S<strong>to</strong>ck Is Driven By Food Exports………………………………………………………. 51<br />

Exhibit 40 – <strong>The</strong> PPI <strong>Price</strong> His<strong>to</strong>ry and Our Estimates For U.S. Agriculture, 1870 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E…………. 52<br />

Exhibit 41 – Deere S<strong>to</strong>ck Is Not Driven By Farm Aid……………………………………………………… 53<br />

Exhibit 42 – Grain Import Hubs Shift Over Time………………………………………………………….. 54<br />

Exhibit 43 – <strong>The</strong> Transition from Old <strong>to</strong> New Grain Markets……………………………………………. 54<br />

Exhibit 44 – U.S. Grain Trade Market Share……………………………………………………………….. 55<br />

Exhibit 45 – Key Drivers In Meat Product Trade…………………………………………………………... 56<br />

Exhibit 46 – Deere S<strong>to</strong>ck Follows Trac<strong>to</strong>r Sales Trends…………………………………………………... 58<br />

Exhibit 47 – U.S. Farm Acres and Farm Commodity Pricing……………………………………………... 58<br />

Exhibit 48 – Food Exports Help Drive Food <strong>Price</strong>s………………………………………………………... 59<br />

Exhibit 49 – Currency Moves Inversely <strong>to</strong> Food Exports………………………………………………….. 59<br />

Exhibit 50 – U.S. Corn Yields, +/(-) 10% From Trend…………………………………………………….. 60<br />

Exhibit 51 – U.S. Corn Yields and Fertilizer Usage………………………………………………………... 60<br />

Exhibit 52 – Deere S<strong>to</strong>ck and Corn <strong>Price</strong>s…………………………………………………………………... 62<br />

Exhibit 53 – Persian Gulf Oil as a Percentage <strong>of</strong> U.S. Consumption, 1970 <strong>to</strong> 2001……………………. 64<br />

Exhibit 54 – Persian Gulf Oil Exports in Real (Year 2000) U.S. Dollars, 1970 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E…………….. 64<br />

Discussion: Iraq’s Potential Approach <strong>to</strong> Nuclear Weapons………………………………………………. 66<br />

Exhibit 55 – Cumulative Effect <strong>of</strong> Oil <strong>Price</strong> Swings on Wealth Transfer, 1970 <strong>to</strong> 2001E……………... 70<br />

Discussion: A Brief His<strong>to</strong>ry <strong>of</strong> Saudi Arabia and the al Saud Royal Family…………………………….. 71<br />

Exhibit 56 – Saudi Arabian GNP Per Capita and Urbanization………………………………………..…... 73<br />

Exhibit 57 – Saudi Arabia Youth Wave, 1974 <strong>to</strong> 2040E……………………………………………….……. 73<br />

Exhibit 58 – Middle East Map………………………………………………………………………………….. 74<br />

Exhibit 59 – <strong>The</strong> Persian Gulf Military Balance in 2001 ………………………………………………….... 75<br />

Exhibit 60 – Military Quality versus Quantity in the Persian Gulf, 2001….………………………….…... 75<br />

Appendix A – U.S. <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong>s From a Monetary His<strong>to</strong>ry Perspective, 1898 <strong>to</strong> 2001……….... ….. 82<br />

Appendix B – Caterpillar Inc. Data Used To Build EVA Model, 1970 <strong>to</strong> 2006E………………………... 85


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -5- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Executive Summary<br />

By <strong>2015</strong>, we estimate prices <strong>of</strong> $60 per barrel for oil, $4.50 per bushel for corn, and a 5.8% S&P 500<br />

annual <strong>to</strong>tal return (0.4% after inflation) point-<strong>to</strong>-point from <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>. Since a reduction <strong>of</strong> S&P<br />

500 prospective returns lowers the opportunity cost <strong>of</strong> capital for machinery companies, and machinery EPS<br />

are <strong>of</strong>ten enhanced when the commodity producers they serve have pricing power, we upgraded our rating<br />

on the shares <strong>of</strong> Caterpillar Inc. (CAT), Deere and Company (DE) and Joy Global Inc. (JOYG) from<br />

Market Performance <strong>to</strong> Buy. In short, we believe that a secular bull market has begun for commodities<br />

and commodity-serving companies, with the normal peaks and valleys along the way. We are keeping some<br />

powder dry and deferring a Strong Buy rating on the basis <strong>of</strong> current valuation, the seasonality <strong>of</strong> machinery<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ck performance (which <strong>of</strong>ten peaks in May and bot<strong>to</strong>ms in Oc<strong>to</strong>ber), as well as our concern that gradually<br />

but steadily rising inflation, which is the view we describe in this report, ultimately will destabilize the<br />

prevailing market sentiment, which we believe retains a long-duration asset bias. <strong>The</strong> Fed has allowed a<br />

money supply “mountain” <strong>to</strong> build in recent years, and investments that benefit from even modest inflation,<br />

such as machinery s<strong>to</strong>cks, have a small capitalization relative <strong>to</strong> the liquidity that now seeks them. For that<br />

reason, as well as the positive spread between commodity industry-leveraged machinery company EPS and<br />

declining machinery company real capital costs as a result <strong>of</strong> inflation, we would expect machinery valuation<br />

multiples <strong>to</strong> remain high even as EPS recover, rather than compress rapidly as EPS rise, which is the<br />

his<strong>to</strong>rical norm. We believe that the machinery s<strong>to</strong>cks we upgraded would be especially attractive if they<br />

were <strong>to</strong> retrench, all else being equal, but despite their recent price run, CAT and DE s<strong>to</strong>cks are still within<br />

the multiyear trading range that began after the previous earnings peak in 1997 <strong>to</strong> 1998. We expect the<br />

s<strong>to</strong>cks we upgraded <strong>to</strong> lurch out <strong>of</strong> that multiyear trading range sometime in 2003.<br />

For a sense <strong>of</strong> his<strong>to</strong>ry, many commodity producers and the machinery s<strong>to</strong>cks serving them enjoyed a<br />

“secular” bull market from June 1970 <strong>to</strong> April 1981, but the festivities ended with the collapse <strong>of</strong> a commodity<br />

bubble around 1980, just as the Fed moved <strong>to</strong> break inflation, and OPEC overplayed its pricing<br />

hand, causing commodity prices <strong>to</strong> tumble. After a painful economic adjustment in 1980–82, the old inflation<br />

beneficiaries <strong>of</strong> the 1970s attempted a false rally in 1982–83, but quickly yielded price leadership <strong>to</strong><br />

the new “disinflation” plays. S<strong>to</strong>cks received a further boost around 1990 when the U.S.S.R. collapsed in a<br />

heap around the same time the U.S. military defeated Iraq in the Gulf War, creating a decade-long peace<br />

dividend, fiscal policy cover for an “easy money” Fed, and U.S. hegemony in the Persian Gulf that ensured<br />

cheap oil for years <strong>to</strong> come. We believe that the post-Gulf War “New World Order” began <strong>to</strong> unravel<br />

in 2000, signaled by the NASDAQ composite and then the S&P 500 rolling over, and we do not believe<br />

it was a coincidence that commodity prices and machinery s<strong>to</strong>cks beginning <strong>to</strong> rise around the<br />

same time.<br />

Commodity-serving machinery generally underperformed in the 1982 <strong>to</strong> 2000 period we described. But in<br />

his<strong>to</strong>rical terms, a shift from the 1982 <strong>to</strong> 2000 equity bull market <strong>to</strong> a new period <strong>of</strong> stronger commodity<br />

prices and, presumably, machinery s<strong>to</strong>ck performance, is completely normal. S<strong>to</strong>cks and commodities, in<br />

fact, have alternated relative and absolute price leadership in cycles averaging 18 years for over a century.<br />

Since 1870, and excluding dividends, U.S. s<strong>to</strong>ck prices rose 11.6% per year during deflation cycles and<br />

3.4% per year during inflation cycles. Commodity price bubbles tend <strong>to</strong> burst (ca. 1920, 1950, 1980) after<br />

military (or economic) warfare and before equity bull markets, the latter <strong>of</strong> which usually feature declining<br />

commodity input costs that improve business pr<strong>of</strong>it margins, falling inflation that increases the P/E multiple<br />

applied <strong>to</strong> those earnings, and rising debt ratios facilitated by cheaper credit. We do not find those "growth"


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -6- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

markets <strong>to</strong> be receptive <strong>to</strong> machinery s<strong>to</strong>ck investing, generally speaking. Alternatively, when s<strong>to</strong>ck price<br />

bubbles begin <strong>to</strong> deflate or burst (ca. 1909, 1929, 1968, 2000), inflation cycles usually follow, largely because<br />

legacy debt must be reduced via some combination <strong>of</strong> inflation, increased export growth, or default,<br />

and the dislocation <strong>of</strong> this transition <strong>of</strong>ten leads <strong>to</strong> an “easy” monetary policy and, unfortunately, <strong>to</strong> military<br />

or economic warfare. <strong>The</strong> U.S. was embroiled in major (lengthy and global) periods <strong>of</strong> hot or economic<br />

warfare for 26% <strong>of</strong> the 20th century. Although war contributed greatly <strong>to</strong> inflation, s<strong>to</strong>cks <strong>of</strong>ten faltered in<br />

the pre-war decade for several reasons, the most common <strong>of</strong> which was excessive money supply growth<br />

relative <strong>to</strong> GDP as the central bankers sought <strong>to</strong> assuage debt problems or fight <strong>of</strong>f wars.<br />

We embarked on our report because we believe that the greatest rewards for inves<strong>to</strong>rs accrue <strong>to</strong> those who<br />

are best positioned for the era's big winners, not the occasional cyclical or product growth s<strong>to</strong>ry. This report<br />

is organized as a probability array <strong>of</strong> expected values, based on what we believe are the three most plausible<br />

<strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> outcomes that shape the inflation and market returns picture, which, in turn, shapes the machinery<br />

sales outlook, in our view. We use over 100 years <strong>of</strong> his<strong>to</strong>rical precedent (since 1898) as the<br />

“effect,” and our assessment <strong>of</strong> facts and our forecasts as the “cause.” For such a long forecast period, we<br />

would expect some combination <strong>of</strong> these events, so a probability analysis seems the best approach, in our<br />

view. Of course, the scenarios are not mutually exclusive; for example, increased trade could forestall the<br />

risk <strong>of</strong> war. <strong>The</strong> scenarios we analyze are as follows.<br />

Scenario (1) Continued price disinflation/deflation, the Western-dominated status quo, resumption <strong>of</strong><br />

the technology capital expenditure boom, and prolonged strength for U.S. equity index returns<br />

(probability 15%). In the current cycle, we believe that a reliance on short-term debt has developed, and<br />

we also note the unsustainable divergence between rising debt as a percentage <strong>of</strong> U.S. GDP and the falling<br />

nominal GDP growth derived from that debt, which causes us <strong>to</strong> believe that the Fed will not be as aggressive<br />

raising rates this cycle. That is bullish for machinery, in our view, because the Fed's aggressive rate<br />

hikes in the mid-1990s helped cap the recovery in machinery s<strong>to</strong>cks despite generally strong EPS at the<br />

time.<br />

Scenario (2) Rapid developing country modernization and recovering U.S. growth that results in<br />

strong and sustained commodity demand relative <strong>to</strong> more inelastic supply (probability 60%). We analyze<br />

commodity supply and demand cycles since 1870, as well as the intensity <strong>of</strong> commodity use during<br />

those phases in which economies modernize and then mature. We believe that the world is in a transition<br />

from slack <strong>to</strong> generally tight oil supply, the result <strong>of</strong> strong Asian oil demand, recovering Former Soviet<br />

Union internal usage despite rising production, and the absence <strong>of</strong> any new “North Sea-sized” non-OPEC,<br />

price-spoiling, discoveries. Whereas OPEC's ability <strong>to</strong> constrict supply was the “oil weapon” <strong>of</strong> the 1970s,<br />

we believe that the key <strong>to</strong> OPEC's strength in the coming years will be its rising share in filling world demand<br />

for oil.<br />

Scenario (3) Major wars produce high inflation, and even minor wars can interrupt trade, so we devote<br />

a section <strong>of</strong> this report <strong>to</strong> analyzing the potential for major conflict in the Persian Gulf that may<br />

constrict oil supply (probability 25%). New<strong>to</strong>n's Third Law <strong>of</strong> Motion states, "For every action, there is<br />

an equal and opposite reaction.” We believe that the downward force applied <strong>to</strong> the Persian Gulf as a result<br />

<strong>of</strong> oil deflation may lead <strong>to</strong> an upward explosion <strong>of</strong> war, fueled by the unfortunate recruitment <strong>of</strong> increasingly<br />

young, disenfranchised male populations by radical leaders making a bid for power. We analyze the<br />

Persian Gulf risks we see, <strong>to</strong> include those involving Iraq, civil war risk in Saudi Arabia, and other threats.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -7- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Report Conclusion: “His<strong>to</strong>ry Doesn’t Repeat Itself, But It Does<br />

Rhyme” – Mark Twain<br />

This report began with the question “Do commodity-serving companies, which have generally been<br />

poor investments since the early 1980s, deserve inves<strong>to</strong>rs’ capital in the coming decade?” Commodityserving<br />

companies generally perform best when commodity supply is tight and/or demand is strong, which<br />

generally has not been the case since 1981. <strong>The</strong> chart on the cover <strong>of</strong> this report shows that the U.S. s<strong>to</strong>ck<br />

market and the Producer <strong>Price</strong> Index for commodities have alternated leadership seven times since 1877, in<br />

cycles averaging 18 years, and the hard asset versus financial asset trade-<strong>of</strong>f is clearly driven by inflation.<br />

From 1982 <strong>to</strong> 2000, commodity prices deflated relative <strong>to</strong> the S&P 500, and the commodity-serving industries<br />

generally underperformed in that period.<br />

After deliberating on this subject since the growth s<strong>to</strong>ck bubble burst in 1Q00, we have come <strong>to</strong> the<br />

conclusion that the inflation cycle is currently turning up, and we further conclude that this is generally<br />

bullish for the s<strong>to</strong>cks <strong>of</strong> companies that serve the commodity producers (and, <strong>of</strong> course, the producers themselves).<br />

We believe signs include surging real estate prices, strong money supply growth, oil and gold<br />

strength, increasing geopolitical instability that may lead <strong>to</strong> inflationary warfare, and a potential peaking <strong>of</strong><br />

the trade-weighted U.S. dollar. While deflation benefits companies with high unit growth and negative pricing<br />

(e.g., computers, s<strong>of</strong>tware), inflation benefits companies with operating leverage and pricing power.<br />

Throughout this report we use the term deflation in lieu <strong>of</strong> “disinflation,” but the intent is the same.<br />

We believe a forward-looking approach, if correct, allows inves<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>to</strong> position themselves for outsized<br />

investment returns. Positioning is the key word, because analysts are one- or two-trick ponies ins<strong>of</strong>ar<br />

as they are generally “wedded” (for richer or poorer) <strong>to</strong> one or two narrow industry groups, and even<br />

non-specialist inves<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>of</strong>ten require several years <strong>to</strong> build sec<strong>to</strong>r expertise. Foresight is, <strong>of</strong> course, difficult,<br />

but adversity <strong>of</strong>ten has commensurate reward. For example, in 1970, when Middle East troubles were<br />

brewing (after the 1967 war but before the 1973 war) and OPEC (founded in Iraq in 1960) was little known,<br />

a forecast that called for oil <strong>to</strong> rise tenfold <strong>to</strong> $30 per barrel within a decade would have been outlandish. In<br />

1980, near the height <strong>of</strong> inflation, a prediction <strong>of</strong> double-digit real bond yields in less than a decade would<br />

have seemed absurd. In 1990, when technology s<strong>to</strong>cks were “value” s<strong>to</strong>cks because their earnings were<br />

volatile (sound familiar?), a prediction <strong>of</strong> a greater-than-tenfold increase <strong>to</strong> over 5,000 for the NASDAQ<br />

composite within a decade would have seemed ludicrous. But in each <strong>of</strong> those cases, inves<strong>to</strong>rs able <strong>to</strong> anticipate<br />

the environment were well positioned <strong>to</strong> capitalize on the changes. For the period <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>,<br />

we expect a macro-backdrop for our s<strong>to</strong>cks (and the market) with the following features.<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

Strong nominal GDP growth, with a large real (ex-inflation) GDP component in the first half <strong>of</strong><br />

the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period, and a larger inflation component in the second half <strong>of</strong> the period.<br />

Sharply rising GDP leading <strong>to</strong> Fed rate hikes, but the Fed may have little choice but <strong>to</strong> return <strong>to</strong><br />

an accommodative stance due <strong>to</strong> the “hangover” <strong>of</strong> past financial excesses and, potentially, war.<br />

Strong global commodity demand and commodity prices; poor pr<strong>of</strong>its have discouraged commodity<br />

producer investment since around 1981, and Persian Gulf instability may constrict supply.<br />

Commodity price pressure that contributes <strong>to</strong> higher consumer inflation, or, in the case <strong>of</strong> commodity-consuming<br />

industries with excess capacity, cost pressure may compress pr<strong>of</strong>it margins.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -8- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

We expect the PPI All Commodities index <strong>to</strong> outpace the S&P 500 over the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period;<br />

we see commodity outperformance particularly strong later in the period.<br />

We see single-digit compounded S&P 500 price returns over the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period, as the focus<br />

shifts from liquidity plus rising P/Es <strong>to</strong> falling P/Es plus EPS growth driving earnings “power.”<br />

<strong>Inflation</strong> could be made significantly worse if increasing geopolitical instability leads <strong>to</strong> wars in<br />

the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period, possibly in the volatile Middle East where pressures are intense.<br />

S<strong>to</strong>ck Rating Changes<br />

As a result <strong>of</strong> our research and the preparation <strong>of</strong> this report, we have upgraded our rating on Caterpillar<br />

Inc. (CAT – $54.92), Deere & Company (DE – $43.25), and Joy Global (JOYG – $16.25) shares<br />

from Market Performance <strong>to</strong> Buy, since machinery tracks the relative strength <strong>of</strong> commodity prices,<br />

shown in Exhibit 1. Although none <strong>of</strong> the s<strong>to</strong>cks appear inexpensive <strong>to</strong> us on our 2003 estimates, they are<br />

Exhibit 1 – <strong>The</strong> S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Versus Machinery (Black Line) and the S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Versus<br />

Commodities (Green Line), 1945 <strong>to</strong> 2001 - Is this a new, secular bull market for machinery?<br />

3.00<br />

2.50<br />

2.00<br />

Note the red and blue lines <strong>of</strong> alternating s<strong>to</strong>ck<br />

market and commodity price leadership correspond<br />

<strong>to</strong> the cover chart <strong>of</strong> this report.<br />

S&P beats machinery<br />

and<br />

S&P beats commodities<br />

12.00<br />

?<br />

10.00<br />

8.00<br />

6.00<br />

1.50<br />

S&P beats machinery<br />

and<br />

S&P beats commodities<br />

Machinery beats S&P<br />

and<br />

Commodities beat S&P<br />

4.00<br />

1.00<br />

2.00<br />

0.50<br />

0.00<br />

1945<br />

1950<br />

1955<br />

1960<br />

1965<br />

1970<br />

1975<br />

1980<br />

1985<br />

1990<br />

1995<br />

2000<br />

S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Relative <strong>to</strong> Machinery<br />

S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Relative <strong>to</strong> Commodities<br />

Source: U.S. Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Standard & Poor’s Corporation


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -9- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

moderately attractive because <strong>of</strong> their leverage <strong>to</strong> the environment we expect in the coming years. For example,<br />

Caterpillar is the leading provider <strong>of</strong> engines used in the production and movement <strong>of</strong> hydrocarbons, as<br />

well as the leading provider <strong>of</strong> heavy machinery used <strong>to</strong> extract minerals or build basic infrastructure in<br />

many emerging markets, a number <strong>of</strong> which are commodity producers. Deere & Company is the leading provider<br />

<strong>of</strong> farm machinery in the world, and Joy Global has a leading position in electric shovels and underground<br />

coal mining equipment. Our posture since 2000 with respect <strong>to</strong> CAT and DE has been <strong>to</strong> trade the<br />

s<strong>to</strong>cks within a price range until EPS began <strong>to</strong> recover. Both CAT and DE have performed well since 3Q00,<br />

around the same time the price <strong>of</strong> the S&P 500 began <strong>to</strong> decline, which we do not believe is coincidental<br />

since that is around the same time the secular changes we outline in this report began <strong>to</strong> emerge. We turned<br />

neutral on CAT and DE in December 2001 as a result <strong>of</strong> macroeconomic “balance sheet” concerns that have<br />

since been overshadowed by aggressive (preinflationary?) policy bandages applied <strong>to</strong> the “cash flow” side <strong>of</strong><br />

the economy.<br />

Exhibit 2 – Machinery Index (CAT+DE+IR+PH) <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong>s, January 1981 <strong>to</strong> Present<br />

250.00<br />

200.00<br />

150.00<br />

100.00<br />

50.00<br />

Secular<br />

peak<br />

Apr. 1981<br />

Trading<br />

Range<br />

CAT+DE+IR+PH Combined S<strong>to</strong>ck <strong>Price</strong> Jan-1981 <strong>to</strong> Present<br />

A pull-back is possible,<br />

our view.<br />

"Cyclical"<br />

+150%<br />

July 1984 <strong>to</strong><br />

May 1990<br />

vs. S&P 500 up<br />

140% in the same<br />

period.<br />

Trading<br />

Range<br />

"Cyclical"<br />

+293%<br />

Aug. 1992 <strong>to</strong><br />

Mar. 1998 vs. S&P<br />

500 up 223% in the<br />

same period.<br />

Trading<br />

Range<br />

0.00<br />

1981<br />

1982<br />

1983<br />

1984<br />

1985<br />

1986<br />

1987<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

<strong>2002</strong><br />

Source: S&P CompuStat, Legg Mason<br />

<strong>The</strong> machinery s<strong>to</strong>cks have enjoyed a considerable rally since they bot<strong>to</strong>med in 3Q00, although the<br />

group has not yet broken out <strong>of</strong> the roughly four-year trading range in which it has been locked. As shown in<br />

Exhibit 2, if there is “only” a post-recession, cyclical recovery in s<strong>to</strong>re for machinery, similar <strong>to</strong> the July<br />

1984 <strong>to</strong> May 1990 period (+150% absolute performance and +10% relative <strong>to</strong> the S&P 500), or perhaps<br />

August 1992 <strong>to</strong> March 1998 (+293% absolute and +70% relative), then we may see a mild pullback before a<br />

multiyear recovery begins. As a result, we are keeping some powder dry and deferring a Strong Buy rating<br />

until we see lower s<strong>to</strong>ck prices or a more sustainable EPS recovery on the horizon, all else being<br />

equal.<br />

Our greater interest, and the subject <strong>of</strong> this report, is a secular, long-term s<strong>to</strong>ry that may be brewing<br />

for commodities. Since such a s<strong>to</strong>ry is tied <strong>to</strong> the inflation outlook, we are mindful that there may be numerous<br />

market dislocations if the inflation mentality changes, and those dislocations may provide lower prices


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -10- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Exhibit 3 – Machinery Index (CAT+DE+IR+PH) <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong>s, January 1965 <strong>to</strong> April 1981<br />

55.00<br />

50.00<br />

45.00<br />

40.00<br />

CAT+DE+IR+PH Combined S<strong>to</strong>ck <strong>Price</strong> Jan-1965 <strong>to</strong> Apr-1981<br />

"Secular"<br />

+221% Machinery<br />

Jun. 1970 <strong>to</strong> Apr. 1981<br />

vs. S&P S<strong>to</strong>ck Composite +83% in<br />

same period.<br />

35.00<br />

30.00<br />

25.00<br />

Trading<br />

Range<br />

20.00<br />

15.00<br />

1965<br />

1966<br />

1967<br />

1968<br />

1969<br />

1970<br />

1971<br />

1972<br />

1973<br />

1974<br />

1975<br />

1976<br />

1977<br />

1978<br />

1979<br />

1980<br />

1981<br />

Source: S&P CompuStat, Legg Mason<br />

for new inves<strong>to</strong>rs in machinery s<strong>to</strong>cks, even though the group may outperform on a relative basis since it<br />

has his<strong>to</strong>rically benefited from commodity inflation. For example, in Exhibit 3 we show the secular bull<br />

market for the machinery s<strong>to</strong>cks in our index during the 1970s, when the group rose 221% from June 1970<br />

<strong>to</strong> April 1981, versus only an 83% increase for the S&P 500. We note in the chart the sharp price decline<br />

for our machinery index after the 1973 <strong>to</strong> 1974 OPEC oil embargo and related recession/bear market, and<br />

the sharp rebound when markets realized that machinery s<strong>to</strong>cks were a beneficiary <strong>of</strong> the inflation that was<br />

created. Potential dislocations may include falling bond prices if <strong>2002</strong> GDP growth is sharply higher, some<br />

Fed rate hikes, commodity and CPI inflation pressure, Middle East political instability, and overseas economic<br />

woes. In addition, as an element <strong>of</strong> caution, machinery s<strong>to</strong>cks are seasonal, <strong>of</strong>ten peaking in May and<br />

bot<strong>to</strong>ming in Oc<strong>to</strong>ber, per our research, so we are cautious in a seasonal sense. Lastly, Exhibit 3 shows<br />

that machinery s<strong>to</strong>cks in bullish cycles do have price dips along the way, so we are patient. But we believe<br />

that a longer-term horizon justifies a Buy rating, however, and if there is a pullback in the interim, it may<br />

warrant a Strong Buy rating for CAT, DE or JOYG s<strong>to</strong>ck, all else being equal.<br />

Caterpillar’s vertical integration makes it the quintessential operating leverage play in machinery, in<br />

our view. Our approach <strong>to</strong> CAT and all machinery s<strong>to</strong>cks is <strong>to</strong> separate the “P” from the “E” in the P/E ratio.<br />

In Exhibit 4, we provide a long-term analysis <strong>of</strong> CAT in terms <strong>of</strong> sales, pr<strong>of</strong>it margins, EPS and, most<br />

importantly in our view, Economic Value Added (EVA ® ), which is the excess <strong>of</strong> return on capital over the<br />

cost <strong>of</strong> capital employed. (Supporting data for these charts are contained in Appendix B.) Starting from the<br />

<strong>to</strong>p left, we forecast that by 2006, CAT’s consolidated sales and revenue growth should climb <strong>to</strong> the<br />

his<strong>to</strong>rical average. In the <strong>to</strong>p right chart, our view is that CAT’s net pr<strong>of</strong>it margin as a percent <strong>of</strong> sales and<br />

revenues should benefit from cost reduction and recovering commodity markets, with a potentially weaker


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -11- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Exhibit 4 – CAT Financial His<strong>to</strong>ry and Our Projections <strong>to</strong> 2006, including EVA<br />

25.0%<br />

21.0%<br />

17.0%<br />

13.0%<br />

9.0%<br />

5.0%<br />

1.0%<br />

-3.0%<br />

-7.0%<br />

-11.0%<br />

-15.0%<br />

CAT Sales & Revenue, 3-Year Growth, 1950-2006E<br />

We estimate<br />

moderate sales<br />

growth <strong>to</strong> 2006.<br />

50<br />

52<br />

54<br />

56<br />

58<br />

60<br />

62<br />

64<br />

66<br />

68<br />

70<br />

72<br />

74<br />

76<br />

78<br />

80<br />

82<br />

84<br />

86<br />

88<br />

90<br />

92<br />

94<br />

96<br />

98<br />

00<br />

02E<br />

04E<br />

06E<br />

CAT Sales and Revenues, 3-Year Moving Average Growth Rate<br />

LM<br />

Ests.<br />

13.0%<br />

11.0%<br />

9.0%<br />

7.0%<br />

5.0%<br />

3.0%<br />

1.0%<br />

-1.0%<br />

-3.0%<br />

-5.0%<br />

-7.0%<br />

CAT Consolidated Net Pr<strong>of</strong>it Margin, 1950 <strong>to</strong> 2006E<br />

We estimate net margin<br />

<strong>to</strong> recover substantially<br />

by 2006.<br />

50<br />

52<br />

54<br />

56<br />

58<br />

60<br />

62<br />

64<br />

66<br />

68<br />

70<br />

72<br />

74<br />

76<br />

78<br />

80<br />

82<br />

84<br />

86<br />

88<br />

90<br />

92<br />

94<br />

96<br />

98<br />

00<br />

02E<br />

04E<br />

06E<br />

CAT Consolidated Net Pr<strong>of</strong>it Percent <strong>of</strong> Sales and Revenues<br />

LM<br />

Ests.<br />

$10.00<br />

$1.00<br />

$0.10<br />

CAT EPS (Excl. Loss Years), 1963 <strong>to</strong> 2006E<br />

We expect EPS <strong>to</strong><br />

recover on a log scale<br />

<strong>to</strong> a <strong>to</strong>p-<strong>of</strong>-trend level<br />

by 2006.<br />

L<br />

O<br />

S<br />

S<br />

E<br />

S<br />

63<br />

65<br />

67<br />

69<br />

71<br />

73<br />

75<br />

77<br />

79<br />

81<br />

83<br />

85<br />

87<br />

89<br />

91<br />

93<br />

95<br />

97<br />

99<br />

01<br />

03E<br />

05E<br />

L<br />

O<br />

S<br />

S<br />

E<br />

S<br />

LM<br />

Ests.<br />

NOPAT ROIC Minus WACC<br />

12.00%<br />

10.00%<br />

8.00%<br />

6.00%<br />

4.00%<br />

2.00%<br />

0.00%<br />

(2.00%)<br />

(4.00%)<br />

(6.00%)<br />

(8.00%)<br />

(10.00%)<br />

(12.00%)<br />

(14.00%)<br />

(16.00%)<br />

(18.00%)<br />

Caterpillar EVA (%) Each Year, 1970 <strong>to</strong> 2001 Actual<br />

With Our <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> 2006 Estimates and Projections<br />

EVA finally recovers significantly<br />

through 2006 in our model.<br />

1970<br />

1972<br />

1974<br />

1976<br />

1978<br />

1980<br />

1982<br />

1984<br />

1986<br />

1988<br />

1990<br />

1992<br />

1994<br />

1996<br />

1998<br />

2000<br />

<strong>2002</strong>E<br />

2004E<br />

2006E<br />

Caterpillar EPS (Log Scale, Excludes Loss Years)<br />

(20.00%)<br />

Source: Company reports, Moody’s Industrial Manuals, Standard and Poor’s Corporation, Legg Mason estimates. EVA is a registered<br />

U.S. dollar as well. As a result, by 2006, we foresee a 9.6% net pr<strong>of</strong>it margin, eclipsing the 8.8% peak<br />

achieved in 1997, thus rivaling the best <strong>of</strong> the post-World War II years, since CAT is significantly more<br />

lean and well managed after 20 years <strong>of</strong> surviving hardship, in our view. Multiplying the results from the<br />

preceding charts, and dividing by shares outstanding, in the bot<strong>to</strong>m left chart we show CAT’s EPS tracking<br />

<strong>to</strong> a potential “cyclical peak” level <strong>of</strong> about $8.00 by 2006. In the bot<strong>to</strong>m right chart, we show the net<br />

operating pr<strong>of</strong>it after taxes (NOPAT) return on invested capital (ROIC) comfortably rising above the<br />

weighted average cost <strong>of</strong> capital (WACC), generating positive EVA in the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> 2006 period.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is a clear relationship between CAT’s s<strong>to</strong>ck price as a multiple <strong>of</strong> consolidated sales and<br />

revenues per share (i.e., P/S) and CAT’s EVA, shown in Exhibit 5. By analyzing the period 1970 <strong>to</strong><br />

2006E in our chart, we capture most <strong>of</strong> one entire inflation cycle (the 1970s), one deflation cycle (1980s<br />

and 1990s), and the beginnings <strong>of</strong> what we view <strong>to</strong> be another moderate inflation cycle (the first five years


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -12- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Exhibit 5 – CAT <strong>Price</strong>-<strong>to</strong>-Sales Multiple Versus EVA, 1970 <strong>to</strong> 2006E<br />

1.30<br />

CAT <strong>Price</strong>/Sales vs. Annual EVA , 1970 <strong>to</strong> 2006P<br />

(1997 (Prior EPS Peak) = Black Circle; 2000 (Cyclical Trough <strong>Price</strong>) = Blue Triangle; Current <strong>Price</strong>/Sales Multiple on<br />

2003E = Red Circle, Current <strong>Price</strong>/Sales on 2006P Potential Cyclical Peak = Green Square)<br />

<strong>Price</strong> / Sales Multiple<br />

1.20<br />

1.10<br />

1.00<br />

0.90<br />

0.80<br />

0.70<br />

0.60<br />

0.50<br />

0.40<br />

0.30<br />

0.20<br />

0.10<br />

CAT's price/sales multiple versus<br />

EVA guides our full-cycle trading<br />

range expectations.<br />

0.00<br />

(18.00%) (15.00%) (12.00%) (9.00%) (6.00%) (3.00%) 0.00% 3.00% 6.00% 9.00% 12.00%<br />

Caterpillar Annual EVA % (NOPAT ROIC minus WACC)<br />

2003E<br />

2000<br />

1997<br />

2006P<br />

Source: Moody’s Industrial Manual, Company reports, Legg Mason <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> 2006 estimates<br />

<strong>of</strong> 2001 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>). Of course, part <strong>of</strong> Caterpillar’s improvement in EVA since the absolute trough in 1984 is<br />

that CAT has developed a large finance company, which tends <strong>to</strong> lower the WACC but increase debt leverage.<br />

Largely for that reason, Caterpillar’s consolidated debt divided by the market value <strong>of</strong> equity rose from<br />

48% in 1984 <strong>to</strong> 97% in 2001. At CAT’s prior cyclical peak EPS ($4.37) in 1997, the company’s EVA was<br />

584 basis points, and the P/S multiple was 0.97x, shown in Exhibit 5 as a black circle. By 2000, at what we<br />

believe <strong>to</strong> be the cyclical trough for CAT’s average annual s<strong>to</strong>ck price ($37.90), CAT inves<strong>to</strong>rs were<br />

positioned for only about 100 basis points, on average, <strong>of</strong> EVA in the subsequent two years, and the P/S in<br />

2000 was only 0.65x, shown by a blue triangle. Currently, CAT s<strong>to</strong>ck trades at a P/S <strong>of</strong> 0.89x our 2003<br />

expectation for sales and revenues per share, with an EVA <strong>of</strong> 100 basis points, shown by a red circle. In<br />

our view, CAT’s 2003 P/S multiple is a bit rich, but does not negate the likelihood <strong>of</strong> positive absolute<br />

returns if one sees CAT nearing cyclical peak EPS in the year 2006. If CAT’s results track as we expect<br />

<strong>to</strong> 2006, then the EPS <strong>of</strong> $8.00 and consolidated sales and revenues <strong>of</strong> $28.9 billion in that year produce a<br />

current P/S multiple (using the current price divided by sales and revenues per share in 2006E) <strong>of</strong> 0.66x,<br />

and an EVA <strong>of</strong> 552 basis points that year.<br />

<strong>The</strong> purchase decision with respect <strong>to</strong> CAT s<strong>to</strong>ck is, <strong>of</strong> course, tied <strong>to</strong> what sort <strong>of</strong> return expectations<br />

satisfy the buyer <strong>of</strong> the shares. We believe CAT s<strong>to</strong>ck could earn a P/S multiple <strong>of</strong> 1.00x in 2006, a<br />

premium <strong>to</strong> the regression line in Exhibit 5, as a result <strong>of</strong> then-expected cyclical optimism, equating <strong>to</strong> a<br />

price <strong>of</strong> $83 in our model ($28.9 billion 2006E sales and revenues divided by 348.5 million shares). This<br />

price is also a P/E just over 10x our “peak” projected level <strong>of</strong> $8.00. From the current price <strong>of</strong><br />

approximately $54.92, that is a price return potential <strong>of</strong> about 11% and a <strong>to</strong>tal return potential <strong>of</strong> 13%<br />

including dividends on an annual basis. We prefer a 20% annual <strong>to</strong>tal return for a Strong Buy rating, which<br />

equates <strong>to</strong> a price <strong>of</strong> $43 for CAT s<strong>to</strong>ck now, all else being equal. Returns are <strong>of</strong>ten relative, however, and


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -13- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

our previous WACC calculations contained a S&P 500 “opportunity cost” price return projection. For the<br />

period <strong>of</strong> this writing <strong>to</strong> 2006, we forecast an annual <strong>to</strong>tal return for the S&P 500 <strong>of</strong> approximately 8.0%<br />

(2.1% dividend reinvested, 5.9% price). CAT s<strong>to</strong>ck appears <strong>to</strong> <strong>of</strong>fer a superior relative <strong>to</strong>tal return <strong>of</strong> over<br />

300 basis points, warranting a Buy rating, in our view. In addition <strong>to</strong> the normal retinue <strong>of</strong> cyclical<br />

economic indica<strong>to</strong>rs in recovery mode, as a nonstandard indica<strong>to</strong>r we also cite the recent strength <strong>of</strong> gold.<br />

Recall that in February 1993 gold prices began <strong>to</strong> rise sharply, and CAT s<strong>to</strong>ck also continued a strong,<br />

cyclical recovery in that year. Later in this report we outline a view that the Greespan Fed depends upon the<br />

U.S. consumer <strong>to</strong> sustain the economic recovery, and since the consumer appears <strong>to</strong> require low interest<br />

rates <strong>to</strong> avoid a painful and abrupt decline in consumer activity, we doubt the Fed will pursue an<br />

aggressive rate policy in <strong>2002</strong>–2003 as it did in the earlier, mid-1990s cyclical economic recovery.<br />

Deere s<strong>to</strong>ck is the quintessential farm economy “macro-play,” in our view. Despite diversification efforts<br />

that <strong>of</strong>ten have proven fruitless, Deere, fortunately, has enhanced its leadership position in farm machinery.<br />

In Exhibit 6, we show that DE s<strong>to</strong>ck tracks U.S. agricultural exports, the latter being driven by a<br />

complex mix <strong>of</strong> global GDP, dietary enrichment, foreign exchange, hydrocarbon input costs, weather, free<br />

trade practices, interest rates, and government payments <strong>to</strong> farmers. But a 20-year period <strong>of</strong> hardship has a<br />

way <strong>of</strong> warping the mindset <strong>of</strong> an industry, and we believe most analyses <strong>of</strong> agriculture are not sufficiently<br />

Exhibit 6 – DE s<strong>to</strong>ck Versus U.S. Farm Exports, 1962 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E<br />

Real U.S. Agricultural Exports ($ Mil.)<br />

$110,000<br />

$100,000<br />

$90,000<br />

$80,000<br />

$70,000<br />

$60,000<br />

$50,000<br />

$40,000<br />

$30,000<br />

$20,000<br />

Deere Performance Tracks U.S. Food Exports<br />

Real Export<br />

CAGR 1962 <strong>to</strong><br />

1996 =<br />

2.7%/year<br />

Machinery industry and farmer over-capacity<br />

plagued pr<strong>of</strong>its, but consolidation resulted.<br />

1962<br />

1964<br />

1966<br />

1968<br />

1970<br />

1972<br />

1974<br />

1976<br />

1978<br />

1980<br />

1982<br />

1984<br />

1986<br />

1988<br />

1990<br />

1992<br />

1994<br />

1996<br />

1998<br />

2000<br />

<strong>2002</strong>E<br />

2004E<br />

LM<br />

Ests.<br />

Real Export<br />

CAGR 1996 <strong>to</strong><br />

<strong>2015</strong>E =<br />

2.4%/year<br />

2006E<br />

2008E<br />

2010E<br />

2012E<br />

2014E<br />

14.0%<br />

12.0%<br />

10.0%<br />

8.0%<br />

6.0%<br />

4.0%<br />

2.0%<br />

Deere Relative <strong>to</strong> the S&P 500<br />

Real U.S. Farm Product Exports, U.S. $ Mil. (Left)<br />

Deere S<strong>to</strong>ck Relative <strong>to</strong> the S&P Composite (Right)<br />

Source: USDA, S&P Compustat, Legg Mason <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> estimates


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -14- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

open <strong>to</strong> the improving conditions. <strong>The</strong> actual trend for real U.S. agricultural exports was 2.7% growth (PPI<br />

index year 2000) from 1962 <strong>to</strong> 1996, and we see real growth <strong>of</strong> only 2.4% from 1996 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E, or from<br />

$64.3 billion <strong>of</strong> real U.S. agricultural exports in 1996 ($52.3 billion in current, 2001 dollars) <strong>to</strong> $100 billion<br />

in <strong>2015</strong>. U.S. agricultural exports have been volatile, with inflation-adjusted U.S. agricultural exports rising<br />

from $27 billion in 1969 <strong>to</strong> a peak <strong>of</strong> $67.2 billion in 1980, but then plunging <strong>to</strong> $32.4 billion in 1986. Exports<br />

then climbed <strong>to</strong> a peak <strong>of</strong> $64.3 billion in 1996, on the strength <strong>of</strong> developing country demand and<br />

weather-related supply disruptions, but fell <strong>to</strong> $50.8 billion in 2000 before beginning a gradual recovery.<br />

Generally speaking, we see higher commodity prices, a weaker U.S. dollar, and improved emerging<br />

market economies, all <strong>of</strong> which support export prospects for U.S. farmers, in our view. <strong>The</strong> diminution<br />

<strong>of</strong> European Union (EU) and Former Soviet Union (FSU) grain and meat import markets, which had been<br />

the “s<strong>to</strong>ry” <strong>of</strong> the 1970s and 1980s but burst in the 1990s, is key. While the EU and FSU have contracted,<br />

the “new” markets in the Atlantic, Pacific and Middle East have continued <strong>to</strong> expand, which we believe is<br />

key <strong>to</strong> U.S. export prospects. A weaker U.S. dollar cycle also would assist U.S. farm exports, since U.S. agricultural<br />

exports fell 14.1% from 1995 <strong>to</strong> 2000, as the U.S. farm trade-weighted dollar rose 18.9% in that<br />

period. Since the U.S. farmer competes with currencies that may appreciate along with commodity prices (e.<br />

g., those <strong>of</strong> Canada, Australia, and the FSU), as well as against the low-priced European euro, the stage may<br />

be set for stronger U.S. agricultural exports in the coming decade. <strong>The</strong> U.S. Department <strong>of</strong> Agriculture<br />

(USDA) estimates agricultural exports <strong>of</strong> $54.5 billion in <strong>2002</strong>, up 10.8% from the trough <strong>of</strong> $49.2 billion<br />

in 1998, which we see as the beginning <strong>of</strong> a long-term recovery for various reasons outlined later in this report.<br />

As a result, we expect DE s<strong>to</strong>ck <strong>to</strong> outperform the S&P 500 more frequently in the period from <strong>2002</strong><br />

<strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>.<br />

Although conditions have been less rosy for Deere in terms <strong>of</strong> U.S. agricultural trade since 1981, a favorable<br />

side effect has been farm machinery industry capacity rationalization. As <strong>to</strong>tal U.S. row crop<br />

trac<strong>to</strong>r plus combine harvester unit sales fell from 94,700 units in 1979 <strong>to</strong> 23,482 units in 2001, the farm<br />

machinery industry consolidated <strong>to</strong> a handful <strong>of</strong> global players. Also, the number <strong>of</strong> U.S. farms fell 10.9%<br />

from 1979 <strong>to</strong> 2001, and U.S. planted acreage fell 7.9%. Were it not for farm subsidies, capacity would have<br />

been reduced further, but we note that Deere targets larger, more pr<strong>of</strong>itable farms that tend <strong>to</strong> purchase and<br />

turn over equipment fleets more frequently. We discuss the farm outlook in greater detail later in this report.<br />

We view Joy Global (JOYG) as the quintessential coal play; seeking <strong>to</strong> participate in those cycles, we<br />

upgraded our rating on JOYG s<strong>to</strong>ck from Market Performance <strong>to</strong> Buy. We view JOYG s<strong>to</strong>ck as a<br />

prime beneficiary <strong>of</strong> the recovery <strong>of</strong> the worldwide coal, copper, and steel (via iron ore) prices, as well as<br />

the recent strength in gold mining, since the company is a dominant niche producer <strong>of</strong> electric shovels and<br />

underground coal mining machines. Having emerged from bankruptcy on July 12, 2001, with greatly reduced<br />

debt, Joy Global (formerly known as Harnischfeger Inc.) has been buffeted by an unusually warm<br />

winter that depressed electric utility output, and thus coal mining, since approximately 90% <strong>of</strong> U.S. coal is<br />

used <strong>to</strong> provide electricity, and utilities have accumulated coal inven<strong>to</strong>ry left over from the mild winter. We<br />

note, however, that coal inven<strong>to</strong>ry at electricity producers as a percentage <strong>of</strong> trailing 5-year average annual<br />

usage was 13.9% in 2001, versus 11.1% in 2000, but still below the 10-year average <strong>of</strong> 14.6%. In addition,<br />

electricity utility industrial production has begun <strong>to</strong> recover from the recession. Weak housing, au<strong>to</strong> and<br />

electronics markets also have depressed the copper and steel (iron ore) markets <strong>to</strong> which Joy Global sells,<br />

but those markets appear <strong>to</strong> be resilient and, as we said, we do not wish <strong>to</strong> fight the Fed anymore with respect<br />

<strong>to</strong> those early cycle groups, at least for the time being. Given that Joy’s wagon is tied <strong>to</strong> coal, in Exhibit<br />

7 we show that coal has provided 52% <strong>of</strong> growing U.S. electric power for the past 80 years with an an-


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -15- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

nual standard deviation <strong>of</strong> only 3%, and coal’s<br />

outlook as a domestic, thermally efficient, increasingly<br />

clean source <strong>of</strong> power remains solid,<br />

in our view.<br />

Exhibit 7 – U.S. Electricity Generation By Fuel<br />

Source, 1920-2001, Total and % Share By Fuel<br />

100%<br />

Other<br />

Joy Global has more “low-hanging fruit” costreduction<br />

potential than most machinery makers,<br />

in our opinion, such as inven<strong>to</strong>ry turns <strong>of</strong> only<br />

1.9x (FIFO basis), the improvement <strong>of</strong> which could<br />

reduce Joy Global’s modest 30% net debt <strong>to</strong> capital.<br />

Whether management will improve the company<br />

is difficult <strong>to</strong> say, but the cycle is our main<br />

interest, and the cycle is largely beyond management’s<br />

control, in our opinion. In Exhibit 8, we<br />

show that the inflation-adjusted price <strong>of</strong> coal and<br />

the U.S. s<strong>to</strong>ck market move in opposite directions,<br />

and appear <strong>to</strong> be converging yet again. For more<br />

information on JOYG s<strong>to</strong>ck, we refer inves<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>to</strong><br />

our basic report on the company dated September<br />

10, 2001.<br />

90%<br />

80%<br />

70%<br />

60%<br />

50%<br />

40%<br />

30%<br />

20%<br />

10%<br />

0%<br />

1920<br />

1925<br />

1930<br />

1935<br />

1940<br />

1945<br />

1950<br />

Hydroelectric<br />

Gas<br />

Coal<br />

1955<br />

1960<br />

Petroleum<br />

Nuclear<br />

1965<br />

1970<br />

1975<br />

1980<br />

1985<br />

1990<br />

1995<br />

2000<br />

Source: Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labor Statistics;.EIA; U.S. Census Bureau, His<strong>to</strong>rical<br />

Statistics <strong>of</strong> the United States, Colonial Times <strong>to</strong> 1970<br />

Exhibit 8 – Coal <strong>Price</strong>s Versus S<strong>to</strong>ck <strong>Price</strong>s, real (index year 2000) prices, 1901 <strong>to</strong> 2001.<br />

$100.00<br />

Good for coal = bad for s<strong>to</strong>ck prices:<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is a 100 year precedent showing an inverse<br />

relationship between coal prices and the S&P<br />

S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Composite price.<br />

10,000<br />

1,000<br />

Average<br />

2001 coal<br />

spot price<br />

100<br />

$10.00<br />

10<br />

1901<br />

1905<br />

1909<br />

1913<br />

1917<br />

1921<br />

1925<br />

1929<br />

1933<br />

1937<br />

1941<br />

1945<br />

1949<br />

1953<br />

1957<br />

1961<br />

1965<br />

1969<br />

1973<br />

1977<br />

1981<br />

1985<br />

1989<br />

1993<br />

1997<br />

2001<br />

Bituminous Coal FOB Mine, $ per Short Ton, Real (year 2000) <strong>Price</strong>s, Left<br />

S&P S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Composite, Real (year 2000) <strong>Price</strong>s, Right<br />

Source: EIA; U.S. Census Bureau, His<strong>to</strong>rical Statistics <strong>of</strong> the United States, Colonial Times <strong>to</strong> 1970


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -16- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

<strong>Inflation</strong> As a Trade-Off Between Hard Assets and Financial Assets<br />

Until now, we have discussed our conclusions, but now it is time <strong>to</strong> discuss the reasoning behind those<br />

conclusions. Exhibit 9 shows the three U.S. commodity inflation (pre-war and wartime) and deflation periods<br />

<strong>of</strong> the 20th century. We note the following cyclical characteristics and similarities.<br />

<br />

<strong>The</strong> commodity inflation periods averaged 19 years in length, but have grown shorter, and regardless <strong>of</strong><br />

whether the pre-war or war years are examined, the entire period featured generally high money supply<br />

(M2) growth, moderately high or high inflation, and uniformly low s<strong>to</strong>ck market returns.<br />

Exhibit 9 – <strong>Inflation</strong> and Deflation <strong>Cycle</strong>s, 1898 <strong>to</strong> 2001<br />

<strong>Inflation</strong> (Pre-War and War) <strong>Cycle</strong>s CAGR <strong>of</strong> CAGR <strong>of</strong> CAGR <strong>of</strong> CAGR <strong>of</strong> CAGR <strong>of</strong> CAGR <strong>of</strong> CAGR <strong>of</strong><br />

PPI - All PPI PPI M2 Money Real U.S. CPI U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck<br />

Com- Farm Fuels Supply Economic Urban Market<br />

Start End Yrs. modities Products & Power Growth Growth (1) <strong>Inflation</strong> Index (2)<br />

<strong>Cycle</strong> One 1898 <strong>to</strong> 1920 22 5.4% 5.7% 7.3% 7.6% 3.4% 4.1% 2.2%<br />

Pre-war period was: 1898 <strong>to</strong> 1914 16 2.2% 2.9% 3.1% 6.5% 3.9% 1.2% 3.0%<br />

War years were (3) : 1914 <strong>to</strong> 1920 6 14.6% 13.3% 19.4% 10.8% 1.1% 12.2% 0.1%<br />

<strong>Cycle</strong> Two 1933 <strong>to</strong> 1951 18 5.6% 7.9% 3.6% 8.2% 5.4% 4.0% 5.6%<br />

Pre-war period was: 1933 <strong>to</strong> 1939 6 2.6% 4.1% 1.6% 7.7% 5.7% 1.2% 5.8%<br />

War years were (4) : 1939 <strong>to</strong> 1951 12 7.1% 9.9% 4.7% 8.5% 5.5% 5.3% 5.5%<br />

<strong>Cycle</strong> Three 1965 <strong>to</strong> 1981 16 7.2% 8.1% 13.2% 8.4% 3.4% 6.8% 2.3%<br />

Pre-Oil Embargo (5) was: 1965 <strong>to</strong> 1973 8 4.3% 4.1% 4.4% 7.7% 4.2% 4.4% 2.3%<br />

Oil Embargo(es) were: 1973 <strong>to</strong> 1981 8 10.2% 12.2% 22.8% 9.2% 2.9% 9.4% 2.3%<br />

<strong>Cycle</strong> One, Two, and Three Average:<br />

<strong>of</strong> which the pre-war average was:<br />

and the war-related (6) average was:<br />

19 6.1% 7.2% 8.1% 8.1% 4.1% 5.0% 3.4%<br />

10 3.0% 3.7% 3.0% 7.3% 4.6% 2.3% 3.7%<br />

9 10.7% 11.8% 15.6% 9.5% 3.2% 9.0% 2.6%<br />

Deflation (Post-War) <strong>Cycle</strong>s<br />

CAGR <strong>of</strong> CAGR <strong>of</strong> CAGR <strong>of</strong> CAGR <strong>of</strong> CAGR <strong>of</strong> CAGR <strong>of</strong> CAGR <strong>of</strong><br />

PPI - All PPI PPI M2 Real U.S. CPI U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck<br />

Com- Farm Fuels Y/Y % Economic Urban Market<br />

Start End Yrs. modities Products & Power Growth Growth (1) <strong>Inflation</strong> Index (2)<br />

<strong>Cycle</strong> One 1920 <strong>to</strong> 1933 13 ( 6.3 )% ( 8.0 )% ( 6.7 )% 1.0% 0.1% ( 3.3 )% ( 0.1 )%<br />

Roaring 20s were: 1920 <strong>to</strong> 1929 9 ( 5.2 )% ( 4.0 )% ( 7.2 )% 4.3% 3.6% ( 1.7 )% 12.8%<br />

<strong>Cycle</strong> Two 1951 <strong>to</strong> 1965 14 0.4% ( 1.6 )% 0.4% 5.6% 4.0% 1.4% 10.4%<br />

<strong>Cycle</strong> Three 1981 <strong>to</strong> 2001 20 1.6% 1.8% 0.4% 5.8% 3.1% 3.4% 11.8%<br />

<strong>Cycle</strong> One, Two, and Three Average (7): 14 ( 1.1 )% ( 1.3 )% ( 2.2 )% 5.2% 3.6% 1.0% 11.7%<br />

(1) For U.S. economic growth, we use real GNP prior <strong>to</strong> 1947, and GDP thereafter, indexed <strong>to</strong> year 2001 U.S. dollars.<br />

(2) This is the U.S. s<strong>to</strong>ck market composite index price return only, and does not include reinvested dividends.<br />

(3) Though World War I ended in 1918, we include 1919 <strong>to</strong> 1920 because the war's commodity bubble and deficit spending continued.<br />

(4) We include the post-World War Two period since price controls were lifted after the war, and the Korean Conflict had some impact.<br />

(5) <strong>The</strong> Great Society "war" on poverty, plus Vietnam, were more regional rather that global in focus, in our view.<br />

(6) Average <strong>of</strong> World Wars I and II, as well as the global economic warfare <strong>of</strong> the Middle East war-related Oil Embargoes <strong>of</strong> the 1970s.<br />

(7) Average <strong>of</strong> Roaring 20s, <strong>Cycle</strong> Two and Three; the deflationary calamity <strong>of</strong> the early 1930s renders comparable analysis meaningless.<br />

Source: Legg Mason, data from U.S. Dept. <strong>of</strong> Commerce, U.S. Census publication “His<strong>to</strong>rical Statistics <strong>of</strong> the United States, Colonial<br />

Times <strong>to</strong> 1970,” Standard and Poor’s Corporation, National Bureau <strong>of</strong> Economic Research macroeconomic database


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -17- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

<strong>The</strong> commodity inflation cycles were followed by deflation (peace dividend) cycles that averaged 14<br />

years in length, but have grown longer, and featured moderate M2 and real GDP growth, low inflation<br />

and high equity returns.<br />

We foresee a period in the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> time frame in which M2 growth generally maintains its current,<br />

high growth rate, inflation gradually begins <strong>to</strong> accelerate, and s<strong>to</strong>ck market returns moderate. We also believe<br />

that the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period may feature either a “pre-war” phase, or a new type <strong>of</strong> global<br />

“growth explosion” phase, and that issue is the subject <strong>of</strong> this report.<br />

Even though commodities have different applications, inflation is a uniting fac<strong>to</strong>r, and in Exhibit 10<br />

we show that their prices tend <strong>to</strong> rise and fall in unison. <strong>The</strong> three major commodity inflation periods highlighted<br />

in Exhibit 10 are labeled “A” for inflation <strong>Cycle</strong> One (1898 <strong>to</strong> 1920), “B” for <strong>Cycle</strong> Two (1933 <strong>to</strong><br />

1951), and “C” for <strong>Cycle</strong> Three (1965 <strong>to</strong> 1981). <strong>The</strong> fourth expected cycle, <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>, is the subject <strong>of</strong><br />

this report. Note that in addition <strong>to</strong> the PPI for All Commodities, shown as a red line in Exhibit 10, we provide<br />

the subindices for Fuels and Electricity, Farm Products, and Metals, all <strong>of</strong> which are <strong>of</strong> interest in our<br />

machinery research. <strong>The</strong> polarizing inflation effect <strong>of</strong> major wars is clear, but we observe that the commodity<br />

inflation periods generally began before the “hot” or economic warfare began in earnest. For the years<br />

<strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>, we forecast a 6.1% compound annual growth rate for the PPI for All Commodities index.<br />

Exhibit 10 – PPI All Commodities Index Y/Y % Change Compared <strong>to</strong> the PPI Subindices for<br />

Energy, Farm Products and Metals, 1870 <strong>to</strong> 2001<br />

25%<br />

Commodity inflations tend <strong>to</strong> occur in unison.<br />

20%<br />

y/y %, 10-year moving average<br />

15%<br />

10%<br />

5%<br />

0%<br />

A<br />

B<br />

C<br />

LM forecast<br />

for PPI All<br />

Commodities<br />

<strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong><br />

-5%<br />

-10%<br />

1880<br />

1890<br />

1900<br />

1910<br />

1920<br />

1930<br />

1940<br />

1950<br />

1960<br />

1970<br />

1980<br />

1990<br />

2000<br />

2010E<br />

PPI All Commodities 10-Yr. Moving Average<br />

PPI Fuels and Electric Power 10-Yr. Moving Average<br />

PPI Farm Products 10-Yr. Moving Average<br />

PPI Metals and Metal Products 10-Yr. Moving Average<br />

Source: U.S. Dept. <strong>of</strong> Commerce, U.S. Census publication “His<strong>to</strong>rical Statistics <strong>of</strong> the United States, Colonial Times <strong>to</strong> 1970,” Standard<br />

and Poor’s Corporation, National Bureau <strong>of</strong> Economic Research macroeconomic database, Legg Mason estimates for <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong>


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -18- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Companies that produce commodities spend more on capital assets when they are pr<strong>of</strong>itable, which<br />

occurs when commodity prices and demand are strong. In Exhibit 11, for the half-century period 1950<br />

<strong>to</strong> 2001, we show the fixed asset replacement rate relative <strong>to</strong> annual depreciation, depletion and amortization<br />

(DD&A), as well as the remaining useful (book) life <strong>of</strong> fixed assets, for four consumers <strong>of</strong> various<br />

types <strong>of</strong> machinery produced by Caterpillar, Deere, or Joy Global. Those companies are Exxon Mobil<br />

(XOM), Phelps Dodge (PD), International Paper (IP), and the former Homestake Mining (HM is latest 12<br />

months through September 2001). Note the way in which those companies spent capital when they had pricing<br />

and volume, circa 1965 <strong>to</strong> 1980. Times have changed, and we expect those companies, as well as other<br />

survivors in their industries, <strong>to</strong> be more careful with respect <strong>to</strong> spending than they were in the commodity<br />

bubble <strong>of</strong> the 1970s. Nevertheless, we find it interesting that capital spending is currently at a his<strong>to</strong>rically<br />

low level relative <strong>to</strong> DD&A, and there is room <strong>to</strong> increase the remaining useful life <strong>of</strong> the producers’ net<br />

fixed assets if pr<strong>of</strong>its allow for capital spending, which we believe would require demand and pricing for<br />

commodities <strong>to</strong> surprise on the upside. Even without a repeat <strong>of</strong> the 1970s aberration, our goal is <strong>to</strong> position<br />

inves<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>to</strong> take advantage <strong>of</strong> the demand and pricing recovery cycle we see from <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>.<br />

Exhibit 11 – Machinery Purchasers XOM, PD, IP and HM Fixed Asset Replacement Rate<br />

Versus Average Remaining Useful Life Of Property, Plant and Equipment, 1950 <strong>to</strong> 2001<br />

Capital Exp. Divided by DD&A (%<br />

400%<br />

300%<br />

200%<br />

100%<br />

0%<br />

1950<br />

<strong>The</strong> Average Fixed Asset Replacement And <strong>The</strong> Remaining Useful (Book) Life Of Fixed<br />

Assets, For Several Major Commodity Producers, 1950 <strong>to</strong> 2001<br />

18 Yrs.<br />

<strong>The</strong> prior<br />

commodity<br />

16 Yrs.<br />

inflation.<br />

1955<br />

1960<br />

1965<br />

1970<br />

1975<br />

1980<br />

1985<br />

Capital Expenditures Divided By DD&A for XOM, PD, HM, and IP, Straight Average (Left Axis)<br />

Net PP&E Divided By DD&A for XOM, PD, HM, and IP, Straight Average (Right Axis)<br />

1990<br />

1995<br />

2000<br />

2005E<br />

?<br />

2010E<br />

<strong>2015</strong>E<br />

14 Yrs.<br />

12 Yrs.<br />

10 Yrs.<br />

8Yrs.<br />

Net PP&E Divided By DD&A<br />

(Average Remaining Life <strong>of</strong> Net<br />

PP&E), years<br />

Source: Company reports<br />

<strong>The</strong> relative performance <strong>of</strong> commodities versus s<strong>to</strong>cks, shown on the cover <strong>of</strong> this report, is an interesting<br />

concept, but inves<strong>to</strong>rs cannot “spend relative performance.” In Exhibit 12, we drill deeper in<strong>to</strong><br />

our cover page chart, and show the actual values for the PPI All Commodities index in the years 1870 <strong>to</strong><br />

2001, with our forecast for the period <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>. In Exhibit 13, we show the same for the U.S. s<strong>to</strong>ck<br />

market.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -19- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Exhibit 12 – PPI for All Commodities Index, 1870 <strong>to</strong> 2001, With Our Forecast <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong><br />

1000<br />

100<br />

Note the trade-<strong>of</strong>f between<br />

commodity and s<strong>to</strong>ck price<br />

leadership.<br />

1898 <strong>to</strong><br />

1920<br />

+219%<br />

(57)%<br />

1933<br />

<strong>to</strong><br />

1951<br />

+167%<br />

+6%<br />

1965<br />

<strong>to</strong><br />

1981<br />

+204%<br />

+38%<br />

2001 <strong>to</strong><br />

<strong>2015</strong>?<br />

+130%<br />

LM<br />

Ests.<br />

10<br />

1<br />

1870<br />

1880<br />

1890<br />

1900<br />

1910<br />

1920<br />

1930<br />

1940<br />

1950<br />

1960<br />

1970<br />

1980<br />

1990<br />

2000<br />

2010E<br />

PPI- All Commodities Index<br />

Source: U.S. Dept. <strong>of</strong> Commerce, U.S. Census publication “His<strong>to</strong>rical Statistics <strong>of</strong> the United States, Colonial Times <strong>to</strong> 1970,” Standard<br />

and Poor’s Corporation, National Bureau <strong>of</strong> Economic Research macroeconomic database, Legg Mason estimates for <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong><br />

Exhibit 13 – U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index, 1870 <strong>to</strong> 2001, With Our Forecast <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong><br />

10000<br />

1000<br />

100<br />

Note the trade-<strong>of</strong>f between<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ck and commodity price<br />

leadership.<br />

1898 <strong>to</strong><br />

1920<br />

61%<br />

+196%<br />

1920<br />

<strong>to</strong><br />

1929<br />

1933<br />

<strong>to</strong><br />

1951<br />

+167%<br />

1933-51<br />

+299%<br />

1965<br />

<strong>to</strong><br />

1981<br />

+45%<br />

+798%<br />

2001 <strong>to</strong><br />

<strong>2015</strong>?<br />

+83%<br />

LM<br />

Ests.<br />

10<br />

1<br />

1870<br />

1880<br />

1890<br />

1900<br />

1910<br />

1920<br />

1930<br />

1940<br />

1950<br />

1960<br />

1970<br />

1980<br />

1990<br />

2000<br />

2010E<br />

S&P S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Composite (Log Scale)<br />

Source: U.S. Dept. <strong>of</strong> Commerce, U.S. Census publication “His<strong>to</strong>rical Statistics <strong>of</strong> the United States, Colonial Times <strong>to</strong> 1970,” Standard<br />

and Poor’s Corporation, National Bureau <strong>of</strong> Economic Research macroeconomic database, Legg Mason estimates for <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong>


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -20- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

We believe inflation cycles are more regular and pronounced when viewed through the lens <strong>of</strong> longterm<br />

his<strong>to</strong>ry. In Exhibit 14, we show the 10-year moving average <strong>of</strong> consumer price inflation, with our<br />

forecast for the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period. <strong>The</strong> trough years for the inflation index cycles were 1901, 1933, 1963<br />

and, we believe, 2001. Bonds are usually the first <strong>to</strong> react <strong>to</strong> those inflation concerns, and thus far we note<br />

that there is little reason for alarm. For example, Treasury <strong>Inflation</strong>-Protected <strong>Securities</strong> (TIPS) spreads<br />

have widened, but no differently than they did in the Spring <strong>of</strong> 2001 when there was also economic recovery<br />

optimism. <strong>The</strong> fact that so little inflation risk is embedded in market expectations only raises the risk <strong>to</strong><br />

inves<strong>to</strong>rs if we are correct about the direction change.<br />

Exhibit 14 – U.S. CPI <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong>s, 1880 <strong>to</strong> 2001, With Our <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> Estimates<br />

CPI - Urban <strong>Inflation</strong> Rate, 10-Yr. Moving Average<br />

10%<br />

8%<br />

6%<br />

4%<br />

2%<br />

0%<br />

-2%<br />

-4%<br />

Periods <strong>of</strong> commodity inflation have similar implications for consumer inflation, as well<br />

as the s<strong>to</strong>ck market via compression <strong>of</strong> valuation and pr<strong>of</strong>it margins.<br />

1901<br />

1933<br />

CPI <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong>s<br />

1880<br />

1885<br />

1890<br />

1895<br />

1900<br />

1905<br />

1910<br />

1915<br />

1920<br />

1925<br />

1930<br />

1935<br />

1940<br />

1945<br />

1950<br />

1955<br />

1960<br />

1965<br />

1970<br />

1975<br />

1980<br />

1985<br />

1990<br />

1995<br />

2000<br />

2005E<br />

2010E<br />

<strong>2015</strong>E<br />

1963<br />

CPI Urban <strong>Inflation</strong> Rate, 10-Yr. Moving Average<br />

2001<br />

<strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong><br />

<strong>2015</strong><br />

LMWW<br />

Ests.<br />

Repeat<br />

<strong>of</strong> the<br />

<strong>Cycle</strong>?<br />

Source: U.S. Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, U.S. Bureau <strong>of</strong> the Census, Standard and Poor’s Corp., Legg Mason estimates for <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong><br />

For inves<strong>to</strong>rs with a long-term horizon, acknowledging the inflation cycle enables them <strong>to</strong> position<br />

portfolios by better understanding the real return cycles <strong>of</strong> the inflating and deflating assets. In Exhibit<br />

15, we show the 10-year moving average <strong>of</strong> the real (after consumer inflation) price return <strong>of</strong> the U.S.<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ck market composite for the 1880 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E period. We note the way in which the real price return <strong>of</strong><br />

s<strong>to</strong>cks fluctuates around 0% plus-or-minus 10%. After a fairly normal retrace from negative-<strong>to</strong>-positive returns<br />

in the 1982 <strong>to</strong> 2000 period, we believe the recent market break foreshadows a period <strong>of</strong> declining real<br />

returns, with the greatest adversity felt later in the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -21- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Exhibit 15 – S<strong>to</strong>ck Returns Minus <strong>Inflation</strong>, 1880 <strong>to</strong> 2001, with our <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> Estimates<br />

S<strong>to</strong>ck <strong>Price</strong> Return Minus CPI <strong>Inflation</strong>, 10-Year M.A.<br />

15%<br />

10%<br />

5%<br />

0%<br />

-5%<br />

-10%<br />

-15%<br />

CPI inflation cycles shown in boxes. Note that s<strong>to</strong>cks follow a +/- 10% real return track.<br />

1880<br />

1885<br />

1890<br />

1895<br />

1900<br />

1905<br />

1910<br />

1915<br />

1920<br />

1925<br />

1930<br />

1935<br />

1940<br />

1945<br />

1950<br />

1955<br />

1960<br />

1965<br />

1970<br />

1975<br />

1980<br />

1985<br />

1990<br />

1995<br />

2000<br />

2005E<br />

2010E<br />

<strong>2015</strong>E<br />

S&P S<strong>to</strong>ck Composite Return Minus Consumer <strong>Inflation</strong> 10-yr. Moving Average<br />

<strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong><br />

<strong>2015</strong><br />

LMWW<br />

Ests.<br />

Source: U.S. Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, U.S. Bureau <strong>of</strong> the Census, Standard & Poor’s Corp., Legg Mason estimates for <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong><br />

Although we have stated that war and inflation are linked, we observe that rapid money supply<br />

growth typically has begun several years before wars. In Exhibit 16, we walk through the quantitative<br />

side <strong>of</strong> the macro-his<strong>to</strong>ry <strong>of</strong> U.S. inflation and s<strong>to</strong>ck market cycles, and demonstrate the effect each has on<br />

the s<strong>to</strong>ck market. <strong>The</strong> chart pairs are displayed as follows:<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

Each <strong>of</strong> the chart pairs in Exhibit 16 is centered on the trough year for the inflation cycle previously<br />

identified as 1901, 1933, 1963 and, we believe, 2001.<br />

For each <strong>of</strong> those years, we show the inflation-adjusted U.S. s<strong>to</strong>ck market index versus M2 money supply<br />

growth (left chart) and versus the U.S. consumer price inflation index (right chart), in the 12 years<br />

before and after the inflation cycle trough year. Each point is a 12-month average.<br />

<strong>The</strong> charts show the way in which, approximately every one-third <strong>of</strong> a century, (1) M2 rises, (2) s<strong>to</strong>cks<br />

rise, (3) inflation rises, (4) s<strong>to</strong>cks go flat in real terms, and (5) war in one form or another ensues.<br />

Not shown in the charts, but discussed later in this report, is the fact that there <strong>of</strong>ten has been a deterioration<br />

<strong>of</strong> the velocity <strong>of</strong> M2 (rearranged as M2 divided by real GDP or GNP in our analysis).<br />

Regardless <strong>of</strong> the “New Era” thinking <strong>of</strong> the time, or the transi<strong>to</strong>ry effects <strong>of</strong> liquidity preferences,<br />

we believe that money supply growth is at the core <strong>of</strong> inflation cycles. Later in this report we discuss<br />

recent trends in M2, real U.S. GDP and CPI inflation growth.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -22- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Exhibit 16 – <strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong>-Adjusted U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index, M2 Money Supply, and U.S.<br />

Consumer <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong>, <strong>The</strong> 1901 and 1933 <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> Turning Points +/- 12 Years<br />

Note the way in which rising money supply precedes and then feeds inflation, ultimately causing<br />

real s<strong>to</strong>ck prices <strong>to</strong> enter a secular bear market, and then, finally, war results.<br />

M2 Money Supply $ Bil.<br />

25<br />

23<br />

21<br />

19<br />

17<br />

15<br />

13<br />

11<br />

9<br />

7<br />

5<br />

(2)<br />

S<strong>to</strong>cks<br />

rise.<br />

1901 +/- 12 yrs.<br />

(1) M2<br />

rises.<br />

210<br />

190<br />

170<br />

150<br />

130<br />

110<br />

90<br />

70<br />

50<br />

U.S. <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> Index, 2000 = 100.00<br />

6.00<br />

5.75<br />

5.50<br />

5.25<br />

5.00<br />

4.75<br />

1901 +/- 12 yrs.<br />

(4) S<strong>to</strong>cks<br />

flatten.<br />

(3) <strong>Inflation</strong><br />

rises.<br />

210<br />

190<br />

170<br />

150<br />

130<br />

110<br />

90<br />

(5)<br />

70<br />

War<br />

begins.<br />

50<br />

U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index<br />

1889<br />

1891<br />

1893<br />

1895<br />

1897<br />

1899<br />

1901<br />

1903<br />

1905<br />

1907<br />

1909<br />

1911<br />

1913<br />

U.S. <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> Index, Year 2000 = 100.00 (Left Axis)<br />

<strong>Inflation</strong>-adjusted U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index (Right Axis)<br />

M2 Money Supply $ Bil.<br />

195<br />

175<br />

155<br />

135<br />

115<br />

95<br />

75<br />

55<br />

35<br />

1933 +/- 12 yrs.<br />

1921<br />

1923<br />

1925<br />

1927<br />

1929<br />

1931<br />

1933<br />

1935<br />

1937<br />

1939<br />

1941<br />

1943<br />

1945<br />

(2)<br />

S<strong>to</strong>cks<br />

rise.<br />

(1) M2<br />

rises.<br />

300<br />

250<br />

200<br />

150<br />

100<br />

50<br />

US. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index<br />

10.75<br />

10.50<br />

10.25<br />

10.00<br />

9.75<br />

9.50<br />

9.25<br />

9.00<br />

8.75<br />

8.50<br />

8.25<br />

8.00<br />

7.75<br />

7.50<br />

7.25<br />

7.00<br />

1921<br />

1923<br />

1925<br />

1927<br />

1929<br />

1931<br />

1933<br />

1935<br />

1937<br />

1939<br />

1941<br />

1943<br />

1945<br />

1889<br />

1891<br />

1893<br />

1895<br />

1897<br />

1899<br />

1901<br />

1903<br />

1905<br />

1907<br />

1909<br />

1911<br />

1913<br />

US. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index<br />

U.S. M2 Money Supply (Left Axis)<br />

<strong>Inflation</strong> Adjusted U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index (Right Axis)<br />

U.S. <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> Index, 2000 = 100.00<br />

1933 +/- 12 yrs.<br />

(4) S<strong>to</strong>cks<br />

flatten.<br />

(3) <strong>Inflation</strong><br />

rises.<br />

300<br />

250<br />

200<br />

150<br />

100<br />

(5) War<br />

begins.<br />

50<br />

U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index<br />

U.S. M2 Money Supply (Left Axis)<br />

<strong>Inflation</strong>-adjusted U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index (Right Axis)<br />

U.S. <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> Index, Year 2000 = 100.00 (Left Axis)<br />

<strong>Inflation</strong>-adjusted U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index (Right Axis)<br />

Source: NBER, Standard & Poor’s Corporation, U.S. Dept. <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Legg Mason format and estimates


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -23- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Exhibit 16 Cont’d. – <strong>Inflation</strong>-Adjusted U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index, M2 Money Supply, and<br />

U.S. Consumer <strong>Inflation</strong>, <strong>The</strong> 1963 and 2001(E) <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> Turning Points +/- 12 Years<br />

1,035<br />

1963 +/- 12 yrs.<br />

525<br />

37.00<br />

1963 +/- 12 yrs.<br />

525<br />

M2 Money Supply $ Bil.<br />

935<br />

835<br />

735<br />

635<br />

535<br />

435<br />

335<br />

235<br />

135<br />

(2)<br />

S<strong>to</strong>cks<br />

rise.<br />

(1) M2<br />

rises.<br />

1951<br />

1953<br />

1955<br />

1957<br />

1959<br />

1961<br />

1963<br />

1965<br />

1967<br />

1969<br />

1971<br />

1973<br />

1975<br />

U.S. M2 Money Supply (Left Axis)<br />

<strong>Inflation</strong>-adjusted U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index (Right Axis)<br />

475<br />

425<br />

375<br />

325<br />

275<br />

225<br />

175<br />

125<br />

US. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index<br />

U.S. <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> Index, 2000 = 100.00<br />

32.00<br />

27.00<br />

22.00<br />

17.00<br />

12.00<br />

(4)<br />

S<strong>to</strong>cks<br />

flatten.<br />

(3) <strong>Inflation</strong><br />

rises.<br />

1951<br />

1953<br />

1955<br />

1957<br />

1959<br />

1961<br />

1963<br />

1965<br />

1967<br />

1969<br />

1971<br />

1973<br />

1975<br />

475<br />

425<br />

375<br />

325<br />

275<br />

225<br />

(5) Economic<br />

warfare. 175 *<br />

U.S. <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> Index, Year 2000 = 100.00 (Left Axis)<br />

<strong>Inflation</strong>-adjusted U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index (Right Axis)<br />

7,000<br />

2001 +/- 12 yrs.<br />

1,525<br />

6,500<br />

6,000<br />

5,500<br />

5,000<br />

4,500<br />

4,000<br />

3,500<br />

3,000<br />

2,500<br />

1989<br />

1991<br />

1993<br />

1995<br />

1997<br />

1999<br />

2001<br />

2003E<br />

2005E<br />

2007E<br />

2009E<br />

2011E<br />

2013E<br />

* This report makes a case that the OPEC embargo w as global economic w arfare.<br />

125<br />

U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index<br />

200.00<br />

2001 +/- 12 yrs.<br />

1,525<br />

M2 Money Supply $ Bil.<br />

(2)<br />

S<strong>to</strong>cks<br />

rise.<br />

(1) M2<br />

rises.<br />

1,325<br />

1,125<br />

925<br />

725<br />

525<br />

US. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index<br />

U.S. <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> Index, 2000 = 100.00<br />

175.00<br />

150.00<br />

125.00<br />

100.00<br />

75.00<br />

(4)<br />

S<strong>to</strong>cks<br />

flatten.<br />

(3) <strong>Inflation</strong><br />

rises.<br />

1,325<br />

1,125<br />

925<br />

725<br />

(5) War 525<br />

risk.<br />

325<br />

50.00<br />

1989<br />

1991<br />

1993<br />

1995<br />

1997<br />

1999<br />

2001<br />

2003E<br />

2005E<br />

2007E<br />

2009E<br />

2011E<br />

2013E<br />

U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index<br />

325<br />

U.S. M2 Money Supply (Left Axis)<br />

<strong>Inflation</strong>-adjusted U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index (Right Axis)<br />

U.S. <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> Index, Year 2000 = 100.00 (Left Axis)<br />

<strong>Inflation</strong>-adjusted U.S. S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Index (Right Axis)<br />

Source: NBER, Standard & Poor’s Corporation, U.S. Dept. <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Legg Mason format and estimates


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -24- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Structure <strong>of</strong> This Report<br />

This report is constructed as a probability array <strong>of</strong> expected values, based on what we believe are the<br />

three most plausible <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> outcomes; we use his<strong>to</strong>rical precedent as the “effect,” and our objective<br />

assessment <strong>of</strong> the facts presented in the remainder <strong>of</strong> this report as the “cause.” For a long period<br />

such as <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>, we would expect some combination <strong>of</strong> the <strong>of</strong>ten mutually exclusive events we<br />

cite, so a probability-weighted analysis seems the best approach, in our view. <strong>The</strong> scenarios we describe are<br />

as follows.<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

Scenario (1) Continued deflation and a continuation <strong>of</strong> the western-dominated status quo, <strong>to</strong> include<br />

the (technology) capital spending boom and sustained, double-digit U.S. equity bull market returns in<br />

the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period. (Probability 15%)<br />

Scenario (2) Rapid developing country modernization, combined with synchronous G-7 economic recovery,<br />

leading <strong>to</strong> a sustained boom in commodity demand relative <strong>to</strong> more inelastic supply. <strong>The</strong>re is<br />

the potential for Persian Gulf conflict that may periodically constrict supply, further tilting the supply/<br />

demand equation in favor <strong>of</strong> commodity inflation in the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period. (Probability 60%)<br />

Scenario (3) Middle East war(s) that result in large oil supply disruptions. Because major wars produce<br />

high inflation and low real s<strong>to</strong>ck price gains, and even minor wars can interrupt trade, we devote a<br />

section <strong>of</strong> this report <strong>to</strong> analyzing the potential for conflict in the Persian Gulf. (Probability 25%)<br />

As a result <strong>of</strong> this probability matrix, for the period <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>, we see the PPI All Commodities as<br />

outpacing the price return <strong>of</strong> the broad U.S. s<strong>to</strong>ck market (S&P 500) index, and we expect gradually<br />

rising CPI inflation. As Exhibit 17 shows, we expect the following:<br />

• 6.1% CAGR for the PPI commodities (back-half higher),<br />

• 4.4% price only CAGR for the U.S. s<strong>to</strong>ck market (front-half higher),<br />

• 5.4% CAGR for consumer price inflation (back-half higher), and<br />

• CPI-urban inflation cresting at a rate <strong>of</strong> almost 8% late in the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period.<br />

This is not a forecast for specific years, in which leadership may alternate from one year <strong>to</strong> the next, but<br />

rather, it is a full-cycle view meant <strong>to</strong> position long-term inves<strong>to</strong>rs, as well as guide short-term inves<strong>to</strong>rs<br />

who may employ a trading discipline. His<strong>to</strong>ry and probability assessments based on current events are imperfect<br />

as forecasting <strong>to</strong>ols, but using the <strong>to</strong>ols <strong>to</strong> the best <strong>of</strong> our ability is our purpose as an analyst. Our<br />

report concludes that Caterpillar, Deere, and Joy Global would be beneficiaries <strong>of</strong> the environment<br />

we foresee <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>, which is a marked change from the environment <strong>of</strong> the last two decades.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -25- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Exhibit 17 – Return and Growth Table for Commodities, S<strong>to</strong>cks and <strong>Inflation</strong>, <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E<br />

<strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong><br />

PPI All Commodities Expected Growth, <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E <strong>2015</strong>E PPI <strong>2015</strong>E PPI<br />

Com- Com-<br />

Prob- modities modities<br />

ability Growth Est. CAGR%<br />

Status Quo 15.0% x ( 1.1 )% = ( 0.2 )%<br />

Sharply Higher World GDP Growth, Some Warfare 60.0% x 6.1% = 3.6%<br />

Major Middle East Conflicts That Disrupt Oil Supply 25.0% x 10.7% = 2.7%<br />

Sum or Average 100.0% nmf 6.1%<br />

<strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong><br />

S&P 500 Expected <strong>Price</strong> Return, <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E<br />

<strong>2015</strong>E S&P <strong>2015</strong>E S&P<br />

Composite Composite<br />

Prob- <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Price</strong><br />

ability Growth Est. CAGR%<br />

Status Quo 15.0% x 11.7% = 1.7%<br />

Sharply Higher World GDP Growth, Some Warfare 60.0% x 3.4% = 2.0%<br />

Major Middle East War 25.0% x 2.6% = 0.7%<br />

Sum or Average 100.0% nmf 4.4%<br />

<strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong><br />

U.S. Consumer <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong>, <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E<br />

<strong>2015</strong>E CPI <strong>2015</strong>E CPI<br />

Urban Urban<br />

Prob- <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong><br />

ability Growth Est. CAGR%<br />

Status Quo 15.0% x 1.0% = 0.2%<br />

Sharply Higher World GDP Growth, Some Warfare 60.0% x 5.0% = 3.0%<br />

Major Middle East War 25.0% x 9.0% = 2.2%<br />

Sum or Average 100.0% nmf 5.4%<br />

Source: Legg Mason estimates and format


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -26- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Scenario (1) Continued Deflation, the U.S. Equity Bull Market, and<br />

Strong “Tech” Capital Spending: Probability: 15%<br />

Continued Deflation?<br />

To gauge the potential for continued deflation, a corners<strong>to</strong>ne <strong>of</strong> the status quo and a negative for Caterpillar,<br />

Deere and Joy Global, in our view, we highlight the following five issues.<br />

(1) <strong>The</strong> his<strong>to</strong>rical parallels in monetary policy his<strong>to</strong>ry.<br />

(2) Money supply growth and deteriorating velocity as precursors <strong>of</strong> inflation.<br />

(3) <strong>The</strong> outlook for domestic productivity as an <strong>of</strong>fset <strong>to</strong> loose monetary policy.<br />

(4) <strong>The</strong> outlook for productivity improvement overseas that affects U.S. competitiveness.<br />

(5) <strong>The</strong> commodity price sensitivity <strong>of</strong> the U.S. economy.<br />

<strong>The</strong> His<strong>to</strong>rical Parallels in Monetary Policy His<strong>to</strong>ry<br />

To frame the issue in a his<strong>to</strong>rical context, in Appendix A we provide a brief review <strong>of</strong> the 20th<br />

century monetary his<strong>to</strong>ry <strong>of</strong> the United States, which we believe shows several parallels <strong>to</strong> current<br />

events. Although no two cycles are exactly alike, as Mark Twain said, they do rhyme. <strong>The</strong> following are examples.<br />

• All <strong>of</strong> the major “hot” or economic wars <strong>of</strong> the past century were preceded by high growth in reserve<br />

currencies. This was the case with gold supplies before World War I, the U.S. dollar and the U.<br />

K. pound in the 1930s as the world struggled <strong>to</strong> shake <strong>of</strong>f the Great Depression, and during the 1960s<br />

and 1970s as the U.S. pursued a “guns and butter” policy <strong>of</strong> domestic spending and foreign war, but<br />

was ultimately roiled by the economic warfare <strong>of</strong> the OPEC oil embargoes.<br />

• <strong>The</strong> type <strong>of</strong> asset bubble that bursts has been a reliable predic<strong>to</strong>r <strong>of</strong> the future inflation or deflation<br />

cycle, and the future potential <strong>of</strong> warfare. <strong>The</strong> asset price inflation/deflation phenomenon has<br />

been repeated several times, with commodity price bubbles occurring and then bursting after wars and<br />

before deflation, and equity price bubbles occurring and then bursting after peace and before inflation.<br />

Examining the decades, bubbles burst for commodities around 1920, 1950 and 1980, and for s<strong>to</strong>cks<br />

around 1909, 1929, 1968, and 2000.<br />

• <strong>The</strong> Fed places the support <strong>of</strong> war and/or avoidance <strong>of</strong> panic ahead <strong>of</strong> price stability in its mission,<br />

a point that is sometimes lost on inves<strong>to</strong>rs since wars and panics are separated by long intervals.<br />

When war arrives, dollars are furnished <strong>to</strong> the strained financial system. <strong>The</strong> aggressive response by the<br />

current Fed <strong>to</strong> recent world crises stems from a desire not <strong>to</strong> repeat past mistakes caused by Fed lethargy,<br />

or <strong>to</strong> be caught in a liquidity trap that renders the Fed impotent, in our view.<br />

• Also sparking inflation, his<strong>to</strong>ry shows that reserve currency devaluation has been employed as a<br />

policy <strong>to</strong>ol. In 1933, President Roosevelt devalued the dollar versus gold <strong>to</strong> escape from the Great Depression.<br />

In 1971, President Nixon abandoned the Bret<strong>to</strong>n Woods Agreement. In the modern period <strong>of</strong>


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -27- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

currency “blocs,” perhaps the competitive devaluation <strong>of</strong> the European euro, Japanese yen, Brazilian<br />

real and Argentine peso mark a return <strong>to</strong> economic unilateralism, since we believe those countries seem<br />

unwilling <strong>to</strong> make structural adjustments and thus avoid devaluation. Is the U.S. dollar next?<br />

• Social costs are again on the rise, and inflation expectations are low, reminiscent <strong>of</strong> the 1960s. <strong>The</strong><br />

“Great Society” <strong>of</strong> President Johnson proved more costly than expected, and we believe that the aging<br />

<strong>of</strong> the baby boomer generation may eclipse the cost <strong>of</strong> the Great Society. U.S. government forecasts for<br />

medical price inflation are below what recent trends would indicate, and government CPI inflation projections<br />

are below what his<strong>to</strong>rical precedent would suggest. Also, 70% <strong>of</strong> federal debt matures by February<br />

28, 2007, heightening the financing roll-over rate risk, in our view.<br />

• Open-ended wars like the current War on Terrorism and Vietnam have a meaningful inflation<br />

impact. In his Third Law <strong>of</strong> Motion, Sir Isaac New<strong>to</strong>n said "For every action, there is an equal and<br />

opposite reaction.” We believe that the downward force applied <strong>to</strong> the Persian Gulf as a result <strong>of</strong> oil deflation<br />

may lead <strong>to</strong> an upward explosion <strong>of</strong> war, fueled by the recruitment <strong>of</strong> young, disenfranched male<br />

populations by radical leaders making a bid for power. In past wars, we observe that the seeds <strong>of</strong> the<br />

future conflict were planted a decade or more before the outbreak <strong>of</strong> hostilities.<br />

Money Supply Growth and Deteriorating Velocity as Precursors <strong>of</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong><br />

Excessive monetary growth relative <strong>to</strong> GDP growth has his<strong>to</strong>rically been inflationary. In Exhibit 18,<br />

we compare U.S. M2 money supply growth <strong>to</strong> consumer price inflation, with annual data for the period<br />

1870 <strong>to</strong> 2001 used <strong>to</strong> calculate 10-year moving averages. We use M2, which required some reconstruction<br />

prior <strong>to</strong> 1959, as a compromise between narrow M1 and broad M3. Although the charts show a close relationship<br />

between money supply and inflation, what matters is the rate <strong>of</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> money relative <strong>to</strong> GDP<br />

(GNP prior <strong>to</strong> 1947), which is the velocity equation. Money supply growth has his<strong>to</strong>rically turned inflationary<br />

when the rate <strong>of</strong> expansion exceeded real GDP for a prolonged period, and in Exhibit 19, we show velocity<br />

versus inflation turning up in recent years (note that we rearrange the velocity formula <strong>to</strong> be M2 divided<br />

by real GDP). In Exhibit 20, we take a closer look at the upturn in M2 growth relative <strong>to</strong> GDP in the<br />

past few decades, and note that the rise in money supply relative <strong>to</strong> GDP began in 1994, at the same time<br />

the second leg <strong>of</strong> the 1990s bull market began, which we do not believe is coincidental. Our view is that<br />

money supply growth initially provides an aura <strong>of</strong> prosperity, but comes home <strong>to</strong> roost via higher inflation.<br />

Money supply growth was instrumental in facilitating the 1990s’ consumer spending and corporate<br />

capital spending surge that was funded, in large part, by debt and equity <strong>of</strong>ferings in the case <strong>of</strong> corporations,<br />

and balance sheet inflation and low-cost credit in the case <strong>of</strong> consumers. <strong>The</strong> surge in money supply<br />

required safety valves <strong>to</strong> mitigate the inflation impact, and two <strong>of</strong> those valves were labor productivity and<br />

tight fiscal policy. We discuss productivity later in this section, for which the news may be favorable in the<br />

near term, in our view. But on the subject <strong>of</strong> fiscal policy, we believe that the brief U.S. federal budget surplus<br />

<strong>of</strong> former President Clin<strong>to</strong>n’s second term provided the fiscal cover (surplus = tight fiscal policy, and<br />

deficit = loose fiscal policy) that gave the Fed some room <strong>to</strong> pursue an expansionary monetary policy. But<br />

with the rapidly eroding fiscal discipline in Washing<strong>to</strong>n, D.C., the War On Terrorism (and possibly Iraq’s<br />

political leadership), as well as the mounting Medicare and Social Security burden on society, we would<br />

contend that we have seen the end <strong>of</strong> federal budget surpluses for the foreseeable future.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -28- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Exhibit 18 – M2 Money Supply Vs. Consumer <strong>Inflation</strong>, 10-Year Moving Avg., 1880 <strong>to</strong> 2001<br />

12.0%<br />

10.0%<br />

Money supply growth and inflation are inexorably linked.<br />

10.0%<br />

8.0%<br />

M2 Y/Y % Growth<br />

8.0%<br />

6.0%<br />

4.0%<br />

2.0%<br />

0.0%<br />

U.S. Federal<br />

Reserve Act <strong>of</strong> 1913<br />

Too much money<br />

supply?<br />

6.0%<br />

4.0%<br />

2.0%<br />

0.0%<br />

-2.0%<br />

-4.0%<br />

1880<br />

1890<br />

1900<br />

1910<br />

1920<br />

1930<br />

CPI <strong>Inflation</strong> Rate<br />

1940<br />

1950<br />

1960<br />

1970<br />

1980<br />

1990<br />

2000<br />

M2 Money Supply, 10-Yr. Moving Avg. <strong>of</strong> y/y % Growth, (Left axis)<br />

U.S. CPI <strong>Inflation</strong>, 10-Yr. Moving Avg. <strong>of</strong> y/y % Growth (Right axis)<br />

Source: National Bureau <strong>of</strong> Economic Research macroeconomic database, U.S. Federal Reserve for M2 1970 <strong>to</strong> present, for M2 prior<br />

<strong>to</strong> 1970 we add M1 + time deposits in banks + bank vault cash + monetary gold s<strong>to</strong>ck + mutual savings bank deposits + S&L deposits<br />

as provided in the U.S. Census publication “His<strong>to</strong>rical Statistics <strong>of</strong> the United States, Colonial Times <strong>to</strong> 1970”<br />

Exhibit 19 – M2 Velocity Versus Consumer <strong>Inflation</strong>, 10-Year Moving Average, 1880 <strong>to</strong> 2001<br />

8.0%<br />

We believe the upturn in M2relative <strong>to</strong> real GDP growth (Left axis, green)<br />

is a catalyst for rising CPI inflation (Right axis, red)<br />

10.0%<br />

6.0%<br />

8.0%<br />

M2 / Real GDP, Y/Y%<br />

4.0%<br />

2.0%<br />

0.0%<br />

-2.0%<br />

6.0%<br />

4.0%<br />

2.0%<br />

0.0%<br />

CPI <strong>Inflation</strong> Rate<br />

-4.0%<br />

-6.0%<br />

1880<br />

1890<br />

1900<br />

1910<br />

1920<br />

1930<br />

1940<br />

1950<br />

1960<br />

1970<br />

1980<br />

1990<br />

2000<br />

Too much money supply<br />

relative <strong>to</strong> GDP?<br />

-2.0%<br />

-4.0%<br />

M2 Divided by Real GDP, y/y% Chg., 10-Yr. Moving Avg., (Left)<br />

U.S. CPI <strong>Inflation</strong> 10-Yr. Moving Avg. <strong>of</strong> y/y % Growth (Right)<br />

Source: Note that we use GDP data from 1947 <strong>to</strong> present, and U.S. GNP 1870 <strong>to</strong> 1946, U.S. Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce, Standard &<br />

Poor’s Corporation, National Bureau <strong>of</strong> Economic Research macroeconomic database, U.S. Federal Reserve for M2 1970 <strong>to</strong> present,<br />

for M2 prior <strong>to</strong> 1970 we add M1 + time deposits in banks + bank vault cash + monetary gold s<strong>to</strong>ck + mutual savings bank deposits +<br />

S&L deposits as provided in the U.S. Census publication “His<strong>to</strong>rical Statistics <strong>of</strong> the United States, Colonial Times <strong>to</strong> 1970”


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -29- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Exhibit 20 – M2 Velocity Versus CPI <strong>Inflation</strong>, 1960 <strong>to</strong> 2001<br />

16.0%<br />

14.0%<br />

12.0%<br />

M2 growth is back <strong>to</strong> the 1960s<br />

<strong>to</strong> 1970s level. Future inflation<br />

trouble?<br />

10.0%<br />

8.0%<br />

6.0%<br />

4.0%<br />

2.0%<br />

0.0%<br />

-2.0%<br />

-4.0%<br />

Mar-60<br />

Mar-62<br />

Mar-64<br />

Mar-66<br />

Mar-68<br />

Mar-70<br />

Mar-72<br />

Mar-74<br />

Mar-76<br />

Mar-78<br />

Mar-80<br />

Mar-82<br />

Mar-84<br />

Mar-86<br />

Mar-88<br />

Mar-90<br />

Mar-92<br />

Mar-94<br />

Mar-96<br />

Mar-98<br />

Mar-00<br />

M2 money supply, SA, y/y% change<br />

CPI Urban inflation, all items, y/y% change<br />

Real U.S. GDP, y/y% change<br />

Source: U.S. Dept. <strong>of</strong> Commerce, U.S. Bureau <strong>of</strong> the Census, U.S. Federal Reserve<br />

Although inves<strong>to</strong>rs have benefited from the 1990s’ monetary policy, we would not confuse benefit<br />

with benevolence. As an <strong>of</strong>fset <strong>to</strong> inflation, we do expect a cyclical bounce in productivity in the next few<br />

years, as the demographics that support labor productivity are now at their zenith, in our view. Later, however,<br />

if productivity loses momentum as we expect, prompting unit labor costs <strong>to</strong> climb, we ask rhe<strong>to</strong>rically<br />

“Will the Fed tighten and risk bringing lingering balance sheet problems <strong>to</strong> the fore, possibly laying waste<br />

<strong>to</strong> a leveraged global financial system?” We do not think so. Despite a rise in liquidity preferences, asset<br />

inflation and debt are less fleeting, in our view, and we know <strong>of</strong> no example in which prolonged money<br />

supply growth above the rate <strong>of</strong> GDP expansion, or borrowing based on inflated assets, did not invite<br />

financial difficulties and, as a response, Fed over-accommodation that reduces real equity values.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Outlook for Domestic Productivity as An Offset To Loose Monetary Policy<br />

<strong>The</strong> outlook for domestic productivity as an <strong>of</strong>fset <strong>to</strong> loose monetary policy is favorable, in our view,<br />

but may be peaking in terms <strong>of</strong> beneficial impact in the next few years. Productivity quantifies output<br />

per hour, and if a case can be made for exceptionally strong real GDP growth via productivity and/or labor<br />

force expansion, inflation may be kept at bay. Taking a longer view, employers in the next decade may be<br />

forced <strong>to</strong> pay more for workers, health benefits packages, and the commodity inputs <strong>to</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> goods sold,<br />

which has the effect <strong>of</strong> squeezing pr<strong>of</strong>it margins unless prices and/or productivity can be raised <strong>to</strong> <strong>of</strong>fset the<br />

pressure. In Exhibit 21, we show U.S. productivity growth in relation <strong>to</strong> the experience pr<strong>of</strong>ile <strong>of</strong> the U.S.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -30- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

work force. <strong>The</strong> huge influx <strong>of</strong> young and less experienced people joining the U.S. work force in the 1970s<br />

contributed <strong>to</strong> low productivity, as well as the political expediency <strong>of</strong> higher inflation for the purposes <strong>of</strong> job<br />

creation, in our view. <strong>The</strong> subsequent rebound <strong>of</strong> older, more experienced workers relative <strong>to</strong> young people<br />

since 1981 has boosted productivity, but that is nearing a peak, as Exhibit 21 shows. Perhaps it is the glacial<br />

pace at which demographic changes progress that causes population trends <strong>to</strong> be downplayed as a key driver<br />

<strong>of</strong> productivity. But if human capital is related <strong>to</strong> human experience, then it follows that human capital is cumulative,<br />

net <strong>of</strong> deletions (the retirement or death rate). As a result, our view is that human experience is the<br />

base from which productivity grows. Furthermore, we believe that the age 35 <strong>to</strong> 49 group forms the heart <strong>of</strong><br />

the economy <strong>of</strong> any country, since they tend <strong>to</strong> invest in homes, families, and retirement savings. Our outlook<br />

calls for the level <strong>of</strong> productivity growth <strong>to</strong> be favorable in the next few years, but then slow appreciably<br />

as demographic headwinds emerge.<br />

Exhibit 21 – U.S. Productivity Growth Versus Demographic Measures: <strong>The</strong> Ratio <strong>of</strong> Experienced<br />

Workers <strong>to</strong> Less Experienced Workers as a Driver For U.S. Productivity Growth<br />

1.25x<br />

1961 age<br />

wave<br />

peak and<br />

productivity peak<br />

2001 age wave peak<br />

4.5%<br />

4.0%<br />

3.5%<br />

Ratio <strong>of</strong> 35 - 49 <strong>to</strong> 20 - 34 Year Olds<br />

1.00x<br />

0.75x<br />

Three-year centered<br />

average<br />

through 12/31/01<br />

U.S. Census<br />

Bureau population<br />

estimates <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> 2020<br />

3.0%<br />

2.5%<br />

2.0%<br />

1.5%<br />

1.0%<br />

0.5%<br />

0.50x<br />

Dec-48<br />

Dec-53<br />

Dec-58<br />

Dec-63<br />

Dec-68<br />

Dec-73<br />

Dec-78<br />

Dec-83<br />

Dec-88<br />

U.S. Productivity Growth<br />

Dec-93<br />

Dec-98<br />

Dec-03<br />

Dec-08<br />

Dec-13<br />

Dec-18<br />

1981 = age wave<br />

trough and<br />

productivity trough<br />

0.0%<br />

-0.5%<br />

U.S. Ratio <strong>of</strong> Experienced People Age 35-49 To Less Experienced People Age 20-34 (Left axis)<br />

Nonfarm Business Output Per Hour y/y % Change 3-Year Centered Avg. (Right axis)<br />

Source: U.S. Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labor Statistics, U.S. Bureau <strong>of</strong> the Census<br />

<strong>The</strong> Outlook for Productivity Improvement Overseas That Affects U.S. Competitiveness<br />

On an international basis, the demographics <strong>of</strong> productivity have implications for inflation cycles, pr<strong>of</strong>its<br />

growth and thus, s<strong>to</strong>ck market performance. As we show in Exhibit 22, both Japan and the United<br />

States began <strong>to</strong> show strong economic gains and robust s<strong>to</strong>ck markets at precisely the same time that the ratio<br />

<strong>of</strong> 35–49 year olds <strong>to</strong> 20–34 year olds began <strong>to</strong> rise rapidly. Japan’s postwar baby boom crested 10 years be-


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -31- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

fore that <strong>of</strong> the United States, and peaked around 1990, which was the same year that the Nikkei s<strong>to</strong>ck index<br />

peaked. Since that time, Japan’s economy has had the twin demographic burdens <strong>of</strong> a rising retiree population<br />

and the absorption <strong>of</strong> a second wave <strong>of</strong> younger workers in<strong>to</strong> the economy. Currently, we believe most<br />

inves<strong>to</strong>rs focus on Japan’s large retiree population. But on an optimistic note, we observe that the ratio <strong>of</strong><br />

older and presumably more productive workers <strong>to</strong> younger and presumably less productive workers in Japan<br />

is projected <strong>to</strong> bot<strong>to</strong>m in <strong>2002</strong> and rise through 2019, perhaps signaling that a demographic corners<strong>to</strong>ne is<br />

in place <strong>to</strong> help bring Japan back from the economic brink. In contrast, as Exhibit 22 shows, the U.S. demographic<br />

situation in the period <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> emerges as a headwind, by this measure. Although we expect the<br />

situation <strong>to</strong> be less severe than the Japanese experience <strong>of</strong> the 1990s, or the U.S. experience <strong>of</strong> the late<br />

1960s <strong>to</strong> early 1980s, the implication is clear <strong>to</strong> us: the need <strong>to</strong> absorb a wave <strong>of</strong> young workers in<strong>to</strong> the<br />

economy at the same time that the most experienced hands are preparing for retirement has his<strong>to</strong>rically not<br />

been a recipe for strong economic or s<strong>to</strong>ck price performance.<br />

Also on the subject <strong>of</strong> rising powers, we observe in Exhibit 22 that China already has entered a favorable,<br />

rising demographic tide <strong>of</strong> mature workers relative <strong>to</strong> younger workers. China’s great baby boom did<br />

not occur until 1963–1975, due <strong>to</strong> the postwar shocks <strong>of</strong> the 1949 revolution and the severe 1959–1962<br />

famine. <strong>The</strong> period from the beginning <strong>of</strong> famine recovery in 1963 <strong>to</strong> the widespread implementation <strong>of</strong><br />

family planning in the early 1970s created a baby boom in China, and by 2012 the U.S. Census Bureau proj-<br />

Exhibit 22 – Comparative Demographic Trends That We Believe Shape Productivity, the Ratio<br />

<strong>of</strong> 35-49 Year Olds <strong>to</strong> 20-34 Year Olds, China, Japan and the U.S., 1950 <strong>to</strong> 2050E<br />

Ratio 35-49 Year Olds <strong>to</strong> 20-34 Year Olds<br />

150%<br />

140%<br />

130%<br />

120%<br />

110%<br />

100%<br />

90%<br />

80%<br />

70%<br />

60%<br />

50%<br />

Nikkei 225 and<br />

Japan age wave<br />

peak (1990)<br />

DJIA and U.S. age<br />

wave bot<strong>to</strong>m (1982)<br />

DJIA and U.S.<br />

age wave peak<br />

(2000)<br />

Japan rebounds?<br />

U.S. Census Bureau Projections<br />

China markets<br />

strong through <strong>2015</strong>?<br />

1950<br />

1960<br />

1970<br />

1980<br />

1990<br />

2000<br />

2010<br />

2020<br />

2030<br />

2040<br />

2050<br />

Japan United States China<br />

Source: U.S. Bureau <strong>of</strong> the Census., Bureau <strong>of</strong> the Census International Database


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -32- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

ects that China will have 349 million people aged 35 <strong>to</strong> 49. In addition <strong>to</strong> economic growth implications, we<br />

believe that China is a developing country with a greater propensity <strong>to</strong> consume raw materials and foreign<br />

capital. This situation may aggravate the U.S. current account deficit in the coming years by reducing the<br />

succor provided by the capital account surplus, and weakening the U.S. dollar, in our view.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Commodity <strong>Price</strong> Sensitivity <strong>of</strong> the U.S. Economy<br />

<strong>The</strong> commodity price sensitivity <strong>of</strong> the U.S. economy may be greater than most inves<strong>to</strong>rs expect, even<br />

though energy usage as a percentage <strong>of</strong> U.S. GDP declined from 14% in 1978 <strong>to</strong> only 6% in 1999, as shown<br />

in Exhibit 23. We discuss the energy price outlook later in this report, but our focus in this section is the inflation<br />

consequences <strong>of</strong> higher domestic energy costs. According <strong>to</strong> Energy Information Administration<br />

(EIA) data, energy consumption (measured in British <strong>The</strong>rmal Units) per dollar <strong>of</strong> real GDP (1996 dollars)<br />

fell from 18.1 Btu in 1974 <strong>to</strong> 13.0 Btu in 1987, a decline <strong>of</strong> 28% that was prompted by the oil price inflation<br />

<strong>of</strong> that era, with the cus<strong>to</strong>mary lag for conservation programs already in place. From 1987 <strong>to</strong> 2000, however,<br />

the decline was from 13.0 Btu <strong>to</strong> 10.6 Btu, or just 18%, with two-thirds <strong>of</strong> the drop occurring in the<br />

1996 <strong>to</strong> 2000 period, when GDP was stimulated by a consumer and capital markets bubble, in our view.<br />

This trend is evident in the <strong>to</strong>ols <strong>of</strong> day-<strong>to</strong>-day life. For example, by 1985, a new U.S. refrigera<strong>to</strong>r used only<br />

54% <strong>of</strong> the electricity <strong>of</strong> one in 1972, and the average new car in 1981 was 65% more fuel-efficient than<br />

one in 1970. Even as fuel prices began <strong>to</strong> fall after 1981, the continued penetration <strong>of</strong> long-lead-time technologies<br />

kept downward pressure on energy consumption, until prolonged, low energy prices removed a<br />

good portion <strong>of</strong> the economic motivation <strong>to</strong> conserve and locate new energy sources. We make the following<br />

four observations about energy intensity and the importance <strong>of</strong> low energy prices <strong>to</strong> U.S. GDP growth.<br />

• Although the amount <strong>of</strong> petroleum<br />

used in the U.S. economy has declined,<br />

the types <strong>of</strong> uses are a<br />

more important fac<strong>to</strong>r, in our<br />

view. For example, transportation<br />

consumed 53% <strong>of</strong> all petroleum<br />

supplied in the U.S. in 1978, but<br />

in 2000 that proportion was 67%.<br />

Oil demand in the U.S. may therefore<br />

be more inelastic now than it<br />

was in the late 1970s, which<br />

means that the price <strong>of</strong> energy has<br />

more impact than a simplistic “oil<br />

intensity <strong>of</strong> GDP” analysis would<br />

imply.<br />

Exhibit 23 – U.S. end-use energy as a percentage <strong>of</strong> GDP<br />

14%<br />

12%<br />

10%<br />

8%<br />

6%<br />

4%<br />

2%<br />

• Most readers are aware <strong>of</strong> the<br />

popularity <strong>of</strong> large sport utility<br />

vehicles and vans. In the earlier<br />

era, U.S. mo<strong>to</strong>r vehicle fuel efficiency<br />

bot<strong>to</strong>med in 1973 at 11.9 Source: EIA for energy expenditures, BEA for GDP figures<br />

0%<br />

1970<br />

1972<br />

1974<br />

1976<br />

1978<br />

1980<br />

1982<br />

1984<br />

1986<br />

1988<br />

1990<br />

1992<br />

1994<br />

1996<br />

Coal/Other Gas Electricity Oil<br />

1998


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -33- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

miles per gallon, after a decline <strong>of</strong> over three decades, and the U.S. consumer was ill-prepared for the<br />

1973–1974 OPEC oil embargo. In the current period, despite a 1.2% annual rise in average U.S. vehicle<br />

fuel efficiency from 1981 <strong>to</strong> 2000, the mileage <strong>of</strong> new U.S. light vehicles hit a 20-year low in 2001 due<br />

mainly <strong>to</strong> the substitution <strong>of</strong> light trucks for cars. In our view, this is indicative <strong>of</strong> a U.S. consumer that<br />

is ill-prepared for higher fuel prices.<br />

• <strong>The</strong> energy intensity <strong>of</strong> GDP did not decline as much after energy prices went in<strong>to</strong> free fall in the<br />

1980s. We believe that the reason was a reduction <strong>of</strong> the market imperative for conservation, alternative<br />

energy development, or new oil and gas exploration and development. Our view is that it will take several<br />

years for the marketplace <strong>to</strong> react in a meaningful way <strong>to</strong> a sudden and steady rise in energy costs<br />

in the future, having experienced only deflation with occasional price spikes since 1981.<br />

• <strong>The</strong> U.S. merchandise trade deficit as a percentage <strong>of</strong> GDP has expanded from approximately neutral in<br />

3Q 1980 <strong>to</strong> minus 2.9% <strong>of</strong> GDP as <strong>of</strong> 3Q 2001. Since oil is priced in U.S. dollars, and imports <strong>of</strong> goods<br />

from developing countries <strong>of</strong>ten require more energy in their manufacture, we would expect a rise in<br />

energy costs <strong>to</strong> produce broad-based import price inflation.<br />

<strong>The</strong> effect <strong>of</strong> rising energy prices does not always show up in standard U.S. economic releases. In Exhibit<br />

24 we show that the average size <strong>of</strong> U.S. single-family homes has increased almost one-third since energy<br />

costs began <strong>to</strong> plummet in the early 1980s. U.S. demographics led <strong>to</strong> a need for larger homes, but we<br />

believe cheap energy made it possible <strong>to</strong> afford those residences, and with large homes <strong>to</strong> heat and cool, we<br />

reiterate that energy demand in the U.S. may be more inelastic now than it was in the late 1970s.<br />

Exhibit 24 – U.S. Home Size Versus Energy Costs<br />

105<br />

2,300<br />

Residential energy prices (1983=100)<br />

95<br />

85<br />

75<br />

65<br />

55<br />

Demographics made larger homes<br />

desirable, but cheap energy made<br />

larger homes possible, in our view.<br />

2,100<br />

1,900<br />

1,700<br />

45<br />

1970<br />

1972<br />

1974<br />

1976<br />

1978<br />

1980<br />

1982<br />

1984<br />

1986<br />

1988<br />

1990<br />

1992<br />

1994<br />

1996<br />

1998<br />

2000<br />

New U.S. Sing. Fam. Home Size (sq. ft.)<br />

1,500<br />

Residential natural gas price (1983=100, left axis)<br />

Average size <strong>of</strong> new U.S. single-family homes (right axis)<br />

Residential electricity price per kWh (1983=100, left axis)<br />

Source: EIA


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -34- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Given that Western energy demand is mature, we show in Exhibit 25 the way in which energy use<br />

and weather are linked in the long term. <strong>The</strong> <strong>to</strong>p half <strong>of</strong> the exhibit shows that Northern Hemisphere<br />

temperatures rose in the 1880 <strong>to</strong> 1940 timeframe, fell from 1940 <strong>to</strong> the late 1970s, and have increased<br />

sharply since that time. <strong>The</strong> relationship is not tight, but below the temperature chart we show that warming<br />

trends produced low energy inflation, and for cold trends the effect is the opposite. A reversal <strong>of</strong> the twodecade<br />

trend <strong>of</strong> higher temperatures could be a catalyst for higher energy prices.<br />

Exhibit 25 – Long-Term Temperature Trends And Energy <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong><br />

N. Hemisphere Surface Temperatures,<br />

Degrees Celsius deviation from normal, 5-<br />

yr moving average<br />

0.8<br />

0.6<br />

0.4<br />

0.2<br />

0<br />

-0.2<br />

-0.4<br />

-0.6<br />

-0.8<br />

1880<br />

(1) Rising<br />

temperatures...<br />

1890<br />

1900<br />

1910<br />

1920<br />

1930<br />

1940<br />

(3) Falling<br />

temperatures...<br />

1950<br />

1960<br />

1970<br />

(5) Rising<br />

temperatures...<br />

1980<br />

1990<br />

2000<br />

PPI Fuels and Electric Power Index (2000<br />

= 100)<br />

100<br />

10<br />

1<br />

1880<br />

1890<br />

(2) …equals<br />

modest prices.<br />

1900<br />

1910<br />

1920<br />

1930<br />

1940<br />

(4) …equals<br />

rising prices.<br />

1950<br />

1960<br />

(6) …equals flat prices.<br />

1970<br />

1980<br />

1990<br />

2000<br />

Temperature source: http://co2science.org data from Jones, P.D., Parker, D.E., Osborn, T.J. and Briffa, K.R. 1999. Global and hemispheric<br />

temperature anomalies -- land and marine instrument records. In Trends: A Compendium <strong>of</strong> Data on Global Change. Carbon<br />

Dioxide Information Analysis Center, Oak Ridge National Labora<strong>to</strong>ry, U.S. Department <strong>of</strong> Energy, Oak Ridge, TN, USA. Data presented<br />

are the 5-year average <strong>of</strong> temperature deviations from the 1961-1990 average for latitudes 10 through 60 <strong>of</strong> the Northern Hemisphere<br />

(where most <strong>of</strong> the world's population and the vast majority <strong>of</strong> fuel consumption for heating purposes are located). PPI Fuels and Electric<br />

Power 1880 <strong>to</strong> 1889 Warren & Pearson study, 1890 <strong>to</strong> 1969 PPI is the shipment-weighted annual averages <strong>of</strong> monthly prices prepared<br />

by the U.S. BLS, 1970 <strong>to</strong> Present is the PPI Fuels and Electric Power (NSA), from the U.S. BLS; PPI index has been placed in a<br />

continuous reweighted series so that the 12-month average <strong>of</strong> 2000 = 100.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -35- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Since inflation is relative, it follows that deflation is as well, so perhaps the net effect <strong>of</strong> commodity<br />

inflation will be pr<strong>of</strong>it margin compression if excess capacity constrains pricing power for the commodity<br />

end users. <strong>The</strong>re is currently a low level <strong>of</strong> capacity utilization in U.S. industry, and there is excess<br />

capacity in the consumer and manufacturing sec<strong>to</strong>rs. As a result, it is possible that strength in commodity<br />

markets could lead <strong>to</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it margin compression rather than consumer price inflation. <strong>The</strong> way we describe<br />

this phenomenon is <strong>to</strong> think <strong>of</strong> the Producer <strong>Price</strong> Index as a large part <strong>of</strong> “cost <strong>of</strong> goods sold” in nonservice<br />

industries. <strong>The</strong> price at which those items are sold may influence the Consumer <strong>Price</strong> Index, but if a<br />

company is forced <strong>to</strong> pay more for its cost <strong>of</strong> goods sold, but receives little pricing relief as a result <strong>of</strong> excess<br />

capacity, then pr<strong>of</strong>it margins will suffer. Since inflation <strong>of</strong> corporate pr<strong>of</strong>its and P/E multiples were<br />

leading contribu<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>to</strong> the bull market that began in its various phases after the 1981 <strong>to</strong> 1982 recession, it<br />

follows that deflation <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it margins and thus common s<strong>to</strong>cks may be a natural “mean reversion” result<br />

<strong>of</strong> pricing power shifting from the CPI <strong>to</strong> the PPI. Although there has been a shake-out <strong>of</strong> capacity in<br />

many <strong>of</strong> Caterpillar, Deere and Joy Global’s markets, some <strong>of</strong> which is an ongoing process, we believe<br />

it is necessary <strong>to</strong> moni<strong>to</strong>r the potential for margin pressure if the companies pay more for inputs<br />

than their pricing power can <strong>of</strong>fset in the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period.<br />

Continuation <strong>of</strong> the Bull Market and Strong “Tech” Spending (?)<br />

To estimate the relative performance<br />

prospects for CAT and DE s<strong>to</strong>cks, we<br />

must first estimate the return <strong>of</strong> the<br />

S&P 500 benchmark. Based partly on<br />

the matrix in Exhibit 26, we see a mere<br />

4.4% annual price return for the S&P<br />

500 through <strong>2015</strong>, equal <strong>to</strong> a cumulative<br />

gain <strong>of</strong> 83% from the 2001 average price<br />

<strong>of</strong> $1,186 <strong>to</strong> a <strong>2015</strong> forecast level <strong>of</strong><br />

$2,173. To that price return we add the<br />

S&P 500 current dividend yield <strong>of</strong> 1.4%,<br />

<strong>to</strong> derive an approximate annual <strong>to</strong>tal<br />

return estimate <strong>of</strong> 5.8% for the period.<br />

With P/E ratios restrained or compressed<br />

by inflation, one <strong>of</strong> the best ways <strong>to</strong> outperform<br />

the S&P 500 may be <strong>to</strong> locate<br />

s<strong>to</strong>cks with consistent dividend growth<br />

and superior dividend yields. To address<br />

questions <strong>of</strong> whether a 4.4% price return<br />

forecast is realistic, we consider the two<br />

elements <strong>of</strong> price movement, which are<br />

EPS and the P/E. Since 1962, S&P 500<br />

Exhibit 26 – S&P Composite P/E Ratios And <strong>Inflation</strong><br />

Based On the Experience <strong>of</strong> the Period 1927 <strong>to</strong> 2001<br />

Consumer<br />

S&P 500 <strong>Price</strong><br />

LTM Avg. <strong>Inflation</strong><br />

Annual P/E Yrly. Avg.<br />

Ratio Y/Y%<br />

During deflation: Midpoint 14.9x -3.2%<br />

During inflation, in the following ranges:<br />

<strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>The</strong> Avg. And <strong>Inflation</strong><br />

From To P/E Was Averaged<br />

0.0% 1.9% 1.0% 16.2x 1.2%<br />

2.0% 3.9% 3.0% 18.3x 3.0%<br />

4.0% 5.9% 5.0% 14.6x 4.9%<br />

6.0% 7.9% 7.0% 11.0x 7.1%<br />

During high inflation, the following occurred:<br />

<strong>Inflation</strong><br />

Produced a And <strong>Inflation</strong><br />

Over P/E <strong>of</strong> Averaged<br />

8.0% + 9.2x 11.5%<br />

Source: Standard & Poor’s Corp.<br />

EPS have grown at an average year-over-year rate <strong>of</strong> 7.4%, and CPI inflation has averaged 4.7% in the same<br />

period, so real S&P 500 EPS growth has been 2.7% (7.4% minus 4.7%). Our view is that the CPI index<br />

from <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> will compound at a rate <strong>of</strong> 5.4% per annum (back-end loaded), so by adding the his<strong>to</strong>rical<br />

real (after inflation) EPS growth <strong>of</strong> 2.7% <strong>to</strong> 5.4% inflation we derive an estimate <strong>of</strong> nominal S&P 500<br />

EPS growth <strong>of</strong> 8.1% for the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period. Because <strong>of</strong> favorable near-term productivity trends, we


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -36- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

decided <strong>to</strong> increase the S&P 500 nominal EPS growth forecast <strong>to</strong> 9.0%. To calculate potential S&P 500<br />

EPS in <strong>2015</strong>, we begin with the First Call consensus for <strong>2002</strong> “operating” EPS <strong>of</strong> $50.25, and grow that figure<br />

by 9% per year for 13 years, producing estimated S&P 500 EPS <strong>of</strong> $154 per unit in <strong>2015</strong>.<br />

Although $154 <strong>of</strong> S&P 500 EPS in <strong>2015</strong> sounds impressive, higher inflation produces a lower P/E, and<br />

in Exhibit 27 we show that if we expect inflation <strong>to</strong> range from approximately 6.4% <strong>to</strong> 7.9% in the 2010 <strong>to</strong><br />

<strong>2015</strong> period, the P/E normally associated with that level <strong>of</strong> inflation is 9.3x <strong>to</strong> 12.1x. In Exhibit 27, we combine<br />

our forecast for inflation and the P/E ratios associated with each level <strong>of</strong> inflation, and derive a hypothetical<br />

1927 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E S&P 500 P/E chart. A glance at that chart causes us <strong>to</strong> believe that our 4.4% S&P<br />

500 projected price return may be on the high side. Given that the chart implies an inflation-penalized P/E<br />

<strong>of</strong> only 11.2x for the S&P 500 in <strong>2015</strong>, and we have estimated EPS <strong>of</strong> $154, the hypothetical S&P 500<br />

would be only $1,725 in <strong>2015</strong>, well below the $2,173 implied by our matrix.<br />

<strong>The</strong> “New Economy” or “New Paradigm” thinking <strong>of</strong> the second half <strong>of</strong> the 1990s that we believe<br />

underpinned much <strong>of</strong> the inves<strong>to</strong>r exuberance in that period was not unprecedented. Even the creation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Federal Reserve System in 1913 was hailed in the 1920s bull market (before the 1930s Great<br />

Depression) as the beginning <strong>of</strong> “New Era” economics that would remove the “boom and bust” cycle <strong>of</strong> the<br />

U.S. economy. When we look back on the characteristics and drivers <strong>of</strong> the “tech” s<strong>to</strong>ry <strong>of</strong> the 1990s, we<br />

believe that many <strong>of</strong> the catalysts are no longer present, since they were based on the following chain: (1)<br />

rising inflation-adjusted labor costs and real sales led businesses <strong>to</strong> ask “Can I raise prices?” or “Do I<br />

Exhibit 27 – S&P S<strong>to</strong>ck Market Composite Average Annual P/E, 1927 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>(E)<br />

S&P Composite Average Annual P/E<br />

35x<br />

30x<br />

25x<br />

20x<br />

15x<br />

10x<br />

5x<br />

0x<br />

(3)<br />

Much has changed <strong>to</strong> affect comparability, but restraining<br />

upside may be the fact that the S&P 500 year 2001 average P/E<br />

<strong>of</strong> 26.3x is almost 50% above the"normal" P/E <strong>of</strong> 17.7x that is<br />

associated with <strong>2002</strong> inflation <strong>of</strong> only 2.4%.<br />

(1)<br />

<strong>The</strong> 2001 P/E<br />

<strong>of</strong> 26.3x is the<br />

2001 average<br />

S&P 500 price<br />

<strong>of</strong> $1,186<br />

divided by 2001<br />

S&P 500<br />

Operating EPS<br />

<strong>of</strong> $45.16A.<br />

(2)<br />

<strong>The</strong> fair value P/E <strong>of</strong> 17.7x for the S&P 500 in <strong>2002</strong> is based on a CPI inflation estimate <strong>of</strong> 2.4%, and the "normal" P/E<br />

associated with that level <strong>of</strong> his<strong>to</strong>rical inflation. Rising inflation from <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> a crest in 2013 <strong>of</strong> 7.9% produces the lower<br />

P/E ratios. As inflation abates in 2014 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>, the P/E rebounds somewhat, as it has in past cycles.<br />

1927<br />

1930<br />

1933<br />

1936<br />

1939<br />

1942<br />

1945<br />

1948<br />

1951<br />

1954<br />

1957<br />

1960<br />

1963<br />

1966<br />

1969<br />

1972<br />

1975<br />

1978<br />

1981<br />

1984<br />

1987<br />

1990<br />

1993<br />

1996<br />

1999<br />

<strong>2002</strong>E<br />

2005E<br />

2008E<br />

2011E<br />

2014E<br />

Composite Average Annual P/E (Left)<br />

Source: Standard & Poor’s Corp., Legg Mason estimates for <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -37- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

substitute capital for labor <strong>to</strong> improve productivity?”; (2) central bank inflation vigilance increased the<br />

value <strong>of</strong> financial assets (claims on cash flow streams) by lowering interest rates; (3) the resulting bull<br />

market in capital lowered the cost <strong>of</strong> capital spending relative <strong>to</strong> labor; (4) a decline in pricing power<br />

(inflation) made the price option untenable or undesirable, and industries (technology, etc.) actually causing<br />

deflation were at the <strong>to</strong>p <strong>of</strong> the economic food chain; (5) government budget surpluses (tight fiscal policy)<br />

and rising productivity made loose monetary policy possible; (6) U.S. hegemony in the world after the Gulf<br />

War and the collapse <strong>of</strong> the Soviet Union boosted the U.S. dollar and encouraged domestic consumption;<br />

(7) the returns <strong>to</strong> capital increased in the U.S., attracting foreign capital, as well as more U.S. capital; (8)<br />

capital was reallocated from public <strong>to</strong> private hands; (9) private hands chose <strong>to</strong> spend while letting foreign<br />

capital substitute for the lack <strong>of</strong> domestic savings, and businesses chose <strong>to</strong> invest in productivity-enhancing<br />

technology; (10) <strong>to</strong>o much capital began <strong>to</strong> chase productivity-enhancing companies, and inves<strong>to</strong>rs became<br />

skittish as returns were diluted; (11) the NASDAQ and other markets that were dominated by companies<br />

selling productivity-enhancing wares fell sharply; and (12) capital costs rose as s<strong>to</strong>ck markets declined and<br />

bond market spreads widened. <strong>The</strong> virtuous circle previously described then went in<strong>to</strong> reverse.<br />

In our view, one <strong>of</strong> the<br />

greatest obstacles <strong>to</strong> a resumption<br />

<strong>of</strong> the capital expenditure<br />

growth rate <strong>of</strong> the<br />

second half <strong>of</strong> the 1990s is<br />

the poor state <strong>of</strong> the U.S. financing<br />

gap, shown in Exhibit<br />

28 as a percentage <strong>of</strong><br />

GDP. <strong>The</strong> financing gap<br />

measures the degree <strong>to</strong> which<br />

corporate capital spending<br />

exceeds or lags the sum <strong>of</strong><br />

internally generated funds<br />

plus the change in the value<br />

<strong>of</strong> inven<strong>to</strong>ries. Internally generated<br />

funds are further defined<br />

as after-tax pr<strong>of</strong>its minus<br />

dividends plus capital<br />

consumption, or, essentially,<br />

free cash flow before growthoriented<br />

capital spending. <strong>The</strong><br />

U.S. financing gap as a percentage<br />

<strong>of</strong> GDP reached a 20-<br />

year high <strong>of</strong> 3.0% in the third<br />

quarter <strong>of</strong> 2000. That was<br />

Exhibit 28 – U.S. Financing Gap, 1952 <strong>to</strong> Present<br />

4.0%<br />

3.5%<br />

3.0%<br />

2.5%<br />

2.0%<br />

1.5%<br />

1.0%<br />

0.5%<br />

0.0%<br />

-0.5%<br />

-1.0%<br />

-1.5%<br />

Dec-52<br />

<strong>The</strong> financing gap<br />

measures the amount by<br />

which capital expenditures<br />

exceed internally generated<br />

funds + inven<strong>to</strong>ry valuation<br />

changes.<br />

Dec-55<br />

Dec-58<br />

Dec-61<br />

Dec-64<br />

Source: U.S. Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labor Statistics, U.S. Bureau <strong>of</strong> the Census<br />

also the peak <strong>of</strong> the S&P 500 index, which is not coincidental, in our opinion. We believe that a resumption<br />

<strong>of</strong> robust technology capital spending growth faces two head winds in the near term: (1) difficult capital<br />

markets conditions and strained corporate balance sheets, and (2) overcapacity after years <strong>of</strong> exceptionally<br />

strong capital spending, which is not solved by more investment.<br />

Dec-67<br />

Dec-70<br />

Dec-73<br />

Dec-76<br />

Dec-79<br />

Dec-82<br />

Dec-85<br />

Dec-88<br />

Financing Gap % <strong>of</strong> GDP, 4-Qtr. Avg.<br />

A financing gap must be funded by<br />

capital markets activities such as<br />

borrowing or equity <strong>of</strong>ferings.<br />

Dec-91<br />

Dec-94<br />

Dec-97<br />

Dec-00


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -38- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

<strong>The</strong> End Of <strong>The</strong> Status Quo?<br />

<strong>The</strong>re are signs that the status quo, as we have described it, has deteriorated in the past two years <strong>to</strong><br />

such a degree that its continuation is highly unlikely, in our view. <strong>Price</strong> inflation is an insidious and efficient<br />

destroyer <strong>of</strong> capital, and the ratio <strong>of</strong> the U.S. s<strong>to</strong>ck market <strong>to</strong> nominal GDP, which may be one way <strong>to</strong><br />

measure the over- or undercapitalization <strong>of</strong> the U.S. economy, turned down from a record level two years<br />

ago. In contrast, the inflation cycle inversely follows the ratio <strong>of</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ck market capitalization <strong>to</strong> nominal<br />

GDP, and we expect the new inflation regime <strong>to</strong> gradually come in<strong>to</strong> focus, becoming the “new” status quo<br />

late in the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period. Inves<strong>to</strong>rs have grown accus<strong>to</strong>med <strong>to</strong> the current status quo, which we’ve<br />

summarized as deflation via productivity growth, the U.S. equity bull market, and strong “tech” capital<br />

spending. As we have stated, we estimate the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period will feature 6.1% compound annual commodity<br />

inflation (back-end loaded in the period), 5.4% consumer price inflation (also back-end loaded), and<br />

a 4.4% annual price return for the U.S. s<strong>to</strong>ck market (with great volatility). <strong>The</strong>se percentages are based on<br />

the subtle changes in his<strong>to</strong>rical cycles that “rhyme” with what we believe are coming events. We feel confident<br />

that the probability <strong>of</strong> maintaining the status quo in the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period is only about 15%, if not<br />

lower. <strong>The</strong> next section examines our second scenario <strong>of</strong> rapid developing country modernization and<br />

global economic growth leading <strong>to</strong> a sustained and inflationary boom in commodity demand. <strong>The</strong> third<br />

probability scenario, which is one or more major Persian Gulf intra-country (civil) or cross-border conflicts<br />

that may constrict commodity supply for more prolonged periods, is discussed later in this report. Throughout<br />

this report we highlight the potential positive and negative aspects <strong>of</strong> this environment for Caterpillar,<br />

Deere and Joy Global.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -39- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Scenario (2) Rapid Developing Country Modernization And Global Economic<br />

Growth Leading <strong>to</strong> a Sustained and <strong>Inflation</strong>ary Boom in Commodity<br />

Demand: Probability: 60%<br />

Will Surging Demand Create Peacetime Commodity <strong>Inflation</strong>?<br />

In a peacetime scenario, we believe that the U.S.’s need for sustainable growth <strong>to</strong> service its debts will<br />

require the creation <strong>of</strong> new markets <strong>to</strong> sell its goods and services, primarily in the developing world.<br />

In an unusual twist versus the his<strong>to</strong>rical norm <strong>of</strong> trade-based deflation, we believe that there is a 60% probability<br />

that the post-Communist, World Trade Organization-inspired, fertile mix <strong>of</strong> cheap labor, freeflowing<br />

capital, and technology transfer will create extraordinarily rapid global economic growth that<br />

places stresses on key raw material markets. Many raw materials producers have scaled back their internal<br />

investment as they have incurred poor returns since the previous inflation cycle, which ended approximately<br />

20 years ago. <strong>The</strong> combination <strong>of</strong> sustained, strong demand plus relatively inelastic supply, along with a<br />

Fed that remains somewhat accommodative as a result <strong>of</strong> the financial and political stresses discussed earlier,<br />

could spur a demand-led price inflation cycle in the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period.<br />

Change is difficult, but pain is the ultimate catalyst. In addition <strong>to</strong> the well-known U.S. propensity <strong>to</strong><br />

consume in excess <strong>of</strong> domestic savings (the current account deficit), and U.S. reliance on declining input<br />

costs (via falling commodity prices) <strong>to</strong> boost producer pr<strong>of</strong>its, we highlight in Exhibit 29 what we believe <strong>to</strong><br />

be a much more insidious problem, which is that incremental U.S. debt is no longer having the desired ef-<br />

Exhibit 29 – <strong>The</strong> Declining Ability Of Debt <strong>to</strong><br />

Underpin U.S. GDP Growth<br />

U.S. Total Debt / Nominal GDP<br />

3.0x<br />

2.5x<br />

2.0x<br />

1.5x<br />

1.0x<br />

0.5x<br />

<strong>Inflation</strong><br />

Deflation<br />

New GDP<br />

from new<br />

debt is<br />

declining.<br />

1962<br />

1965<br />

1968<br />

1971<br />

1974<br />

1977<br />

1980<br />

1983<br />

1986<br />

1989<br />

1992<br />

1995<br />

1998<br />

2001<br />

17.0%<br />

15.0%<br />

13.0%<br />

11.0%<br />

9.0%<br />

7.0%<br />

5.0%<br />

3.0%<br />

1.0%<br />

U.S. Total Debt Divided By Nominal GDP (Left)<br />

Y/Y Change U.S. Nominal GDP (Right)<br />

Source: U.S. Federal Reserve, U.S. Census, U.S. Department <strong>of</strong><br />

Commerce, Legg Mason format<br />

U.S. Nominal GDP Yr./Yr. % Change<br />

Exhibit 30 – Raw Materials Intensity At Different<br />

Stages <strong>of</strong> Economic Development<br />

Growth in Materials Consumption<br />

Minus Real GDP growth, 10-Yr. Avg.<br />

7%<br />

6%<br />

5%<br />

4%<br />

3%<br />

2%<br />

1%<br />

0%<br />

-1%<br />

-2%<br />

-3%<br />

-4%<br />

Emerging Economy<br />

Maturing Economy<br />

1910<br />

1915<br />

1920<br />

1925<br />

1930<br />

1935<br />

1940<br />

1945<br />

1950<br />

1955<br />

1960<br />

1965<br />

1970<br />

1975<br />

1980<br />

1985<br />

1990<br />

1995<br />

U.S. Raw Materials * Consumption Growth Minus U.S. Real GDP<br />

Growth, 10-Yr. Moving Avg.<br />

* Average <strong>of</strong> fuel, metals, other minerals, organics, paper.<br />

Sources: EIA; Department <strong>of</strong> Commerce; for pre-1947 period, GNP is<br />

used as a substitute for GDP; U.S. Geological Survey data materials<br />

data updated through 1998


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -40- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

fect <strong>of</strong> producing meaningful incremental U.S. growth. <strong>The</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> U.S. <strong>to</strong>tal debt <strong>to</strong> nominal GDP is rising<br />

sharply, but nominal GDP is falling just as quickly, and the only solutions we envision are a combination <strong>of</strong><br />

(global) growth, (moderate) inflation, and (private) default. From 1980 <strong>to</strong> the present, the U.S. ratio <strong>of</strong> aggregate<br />

debt <strong>to</strong> GDP has risen from 1.56x <strong>to</strong> 2.74x, and the growth rate <strong>of</strong> nominal GDP has fallen from<br />

8.9% <strong>to</strong> 3.4% in the same period. In order <strong>to</strong> grow the economy out <strong>of</strong> this situation, we expect U.S. business<br />

and policymakers <strong>to</strong> increasingly emphasize exports and foreign market development, but a side-effect<br />

<strong>of</strong> fostering strong emerging market growth is that it hyperstimulates raw materials usage. As Exhibit 30<br />

shows, the early stage <strong>of</strong> economic ascendancy, such as the U.S. enjoyed in the first half <strong>of</strong> the 20th century,<br />

is highly natural resources-intensive. As the emerging market per capita GDP bell curve shifts from<br />

left <strong>to</strong> right with growing income, the percentage change along the horizontal axis with respect <strong>to</strong> income is<br />

dwarfed by the number <strong>of</strong> new, materials-intensive consumers it creates in the area under the curve.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re were signs <strong>of</strong> this commodity intensity phenomenon prior <strong>to</strong> the Asia-Pacific Crisis, when many<br />

commodity prices rose in unison, and the s<strong>to</strong>cks <strong>of</strong> commodity-producing and -serving companies reflected<br />

the pricing prosperity. But as emerging economies fell like dominos, and commodity markets and related<br />

equities capitulated, the U.S. Fed turned more accommodative and global savings fled <strong>to</strong> the U.S., acting as<br />

a catalyst for the U.S. equity price bubble <strong>of</strong> the late 1990s. <strong>The</strong> subsequent collapse <strong>of</strong> U.S. equity indices<br />

that began in 2000 (earlier, if deteriorating breadth is counted), and the relative outperformance <strong>of</strong> many<br />

commodities and commodity-serving companies such as Caterpillar versus the broad s<strong>to</strong>ck market since that<br />

time, may foreshadow an inflationary turn in the price cycle. As we noted earlier in this report, bursting equity<br />

bubbles have preceded every major inflation (and war) <strong>of</strong> the past century, just as bursting commodity<br />

bubbles have preceded every major s<strong>to</strong>ck price inflation (i.e., bull market) for a century.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Energy <strong>Price</strong> Drivers, 1870 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E<br />

<strong>The</strong>re have been seven price cycles for the U.S. PPI for Fuels and Electric Power since 1870, averaging<br />

approximately 18 years in length. Shown in Exhibit 31, the three energy inflation cycles produced average<br />

annual energy price growth <strong>of</strong> 8.0%, whereas the four deflationary periods produced an average annual<br />

decline <strong>of</strong> 2.1%. <strong>The</strong> energy inflation cycles largely coincided with inflation in the broad PPI All<br />

Commodities Index, although the timing was not always exact.<br />

We cite some <strong>of</strong> the supply and demand drivers in those cycles, highlighting the “rhymes” over time.<br />

• Deflation 1870 <strong>to</strong> 1898: Post-Civil War peace dividend, and enhanced coal mining and drilling technology.<br />

Coal replaced wood as the primary source <strong>of</strong> energy for homes and industrial uses.<br />

• <strong>Inflation</strong> 1898 <strong>to</strong> 1920: Demand-led; 10 million au<strong>to</strong>s were registered by 1920, contributing <strong>to</strong> oil<br />

price inflation <strong>of</strong> 6.3% annually. Later, World War I helped triple energy prices from the years 1915 <strong>to</strong><br />

1920.<br />

• Deflation 1920 <strong>to</strong> 1933: Post-war peace dividend, then the collapsing demand <strong>of</strong> the Great Depression,<br />

as per capita energy use fell 2.5%, on average.<br />

• <strong>Inflation</strong> 1933 <strong>to</strong> 1951: Demand-led; real power plant building rose 13% annually in the period. Later,<br />

World War II constricted supply, but vehicle ownership grew 4.3% per year over the entire period.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -41- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Exhibit 31 – PPI Energy <strong>Price</strong> His<strong>to</strong>ry and Supply/Demand Drivers, 1870 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E<br />

1,000<br />

100<br />

10<br />

Coal replaces wood;<br />

oil drilling ramp.<br />

1870 <strong>to</strong> 1898 CAGR<br />

(2.5)%<br />

1898 <strong>to</strong><br />

1920<br />

CAGR<br />

7.3%<br />

World<br />

War I,<br />

U.S.<br />

GNP<br />

growth,<br />

au<strong>to</strong>s.<br />

1920 <strong>to</strong><br />

1933<br />

CAGR<br />

(6.7)%<br />

1933 <strong>to</strong><br />

1951<br />

CAGR<br />

3.6%<br />

Deflation,<br />

depression.<br />

Electric<br />

power<br />

growth,<br />

World War<br />

II.<br />

1951<br />

<strong>to</strong> 1965<br />

CAGR<br />

0.4%<br />

1965 <strong>to</strong><br />

1981<br />

CAGR<br />

13.2%<br />

Cheap oil<br />

imports, coal<br />

mechanization.<br />

OPEC embargo,<br />

U.S. well<br />

depletion, more<br />

coal, nuclear.<br />

2001 <strong>to</strong><br />

<strong>2015</strong>E<br />

CAGR<br />

6.1%<br />

1981 <strong>to</strong> Non-<br />

2001 OPEC<br />

CAGR production<br />

0.4% increase,<br />

fuel<br />

efficiency<br />

measures.<br />

FSU,<br />

China,<br />

shift.<br />

1<br />

1870<br />

1880<br />

1890<br />

1900<br />

1910<br />

1920<br />

1930<br />

1940<br />

1950<br />

1960<br />

1970<br />

1980<br />

1990<br />

2000<br />

2010E<br />

PPI Fuels and Electric Power<br />

SUPPLY-SIDE ISSUES<br />

DEMAND-SIDE ISSUES<br />

U.S. U.S. Power<br />

PPI- Fuels CAGR % U.S. U.S. Oil U.S. Light Plant Per<br />

and Electric <strong>of</strong> PPI Crude Crude Output Coal (2) U.S. U.S. Duty Construc. Capita<br />

Power Fuels and Oil Oil per Output World Real Mo<strong>to</strong>r Vehicles Expend- Energy<br />

<strong>Inflation</strong> or Electric Imports Cost/bbl Well (1) per Miner War? GDP (3) Vehicles MPG itures Cons.<br />

Deflation Power Growth Growth Growth Growth YES Growth Growth Growth Growth Growth<br />

Period Yrs. Index Rate Rate Rate Rate or NO Rate Rate (4) Rate (5) Rate (6) Rate (7)<br />

1870 <strong>to</strong> 1898 28 (2.5)% na (5.5)% na (1.5)% NO 5.0% na na na 4.4%<br />

1898 <strong>to</strong> 1920 22 7.3% na 6.3% na 1.4% YES 3.3% 42.3% na na 3.2%<br />

1920 <strong>to</strong> 1933 13 (6.7)% (8.9)% (11.1)% 1.3% (0.8)% NO 0.1% 7.7% na (4.4)% (2.5)%<br />

1933 <strong>to</strong> 1951 18 3.6% 10.1% 7.7% 3.0% 3.3% YES 5.6% 4.3% (0.5)% 13.1% 3.5%<br />

1951 <strong>to</strong> 1965 14 0.4% 6.8% 0.9% 0.2% 7.3% NO 3.7% 4.0% (0.2)% 3.2% 1.1%<br />

1965 <strong>to</strong> 1981 16 13.2% 8.2% 16.2% 0.9% (0.8)% NO 3.2% 3.6% 0.5% 5.6% 1.1%<br />

1981 <strong>to</strong> 2001 20 0.4% 3.7% (2.0)% (1.8)% 7.6% NO 3.1% 1.7% 1.2% (4.0)% 0.4%<br />

2001 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E 14E 6.1%E 3.2%E 7.4%E ne ne 25%E 3.0%E 1.0%E 0.2%E ne 0.7%E<br />

(1) Period 1920 <strong>to</strong> 1933 is restated as 1925 <strong>to</strong> 1933, and period 1981 <strong>to</strong> 2001 is restated as 1981 <strong>to</strong> 2000, due <strong>to</strong> data constraints.<br />

(2) Anthracite coal for 1870-1898 period; bituminous coal for other periods.<br />

(3) Real GNP prior <strong>to</strong> 1947.<br />

(4) Period 1898 <strong>to</strong> 1920 is restated as 1900 <strong>to</strong> 1920, and period 1981 <strong>to</strong> 2001 restated as 1981 <strong>to</strong> 1998, due <strong>to</strong> data constraints.<br />

(5) Period 1933 <strong>to</strong> 1951 is restated as 1936 <strong>to</strong> 1951, and period 1981 <strong>to</strong> 2001 restated as 1981 <strong>to</strong> 1999, due <strong>to</strong> data constraints.<br />

(6) Used three-year centered average. Period 1981 <strong>to</strong> 2001 is restated as 1981 <strong>to</strong> 1999, due <strong>to</strong> data constraints.<br />

(7) Period 1981 <strong>to</strong> 2001 is restated as 1981 <strong>to</strong> 2000, due <strong>to</strong> data constraints.<br />

Source: PPI - Fuels and Electric Power 1870 <strong>to</strong> 1889 Warren & Pearson study, 1890 <strong>to</strong> 1969 PPI is the shipment-weighted annual averages <strong>of</strong> monthly prices<br />

prepared by the U.S. BLS, 1970 <strong>to</strong> Present is the PPI Fuels and Electric Power (NSA), from the U.S. BLS, all Indices have been placed in a continuous re-weighted<br />

series so that the 12-month average <strong>of</strong> 2000 = 100; Crude oil imports 1920 <strong>to</strong> 1948: American Petroleum Institute (API); 1949 <strong>to</strong> 2001: EIA Annual Energy Review<br />

Tables; Crude Oil price: 1870-1905: U.S. Census, His<strong>to</strong>rical Statistics <strong>of</strong> the United States, Colonial Times <strong>to</strong> 1970; 1906-1948: API, average price <strong>of</strong> crude oil in the<br />

United States. 1949-2001: EIA, Annual Energy Review Tables, Domestic Crude First Purchase <strong>Price</strong>. U.S. oil and coal production: 1870 <strong>to</strong> 1948: U.S. Census,<br />

His<strong>to</strong>rical Statistics <strong>of</strong> the United States, Colonial Times <strong>to</strong> 1970; 1949-2001: 1949-2001: EIA, Annual Energy Review Tables. Oil Wells: 1925 <strong>to</strong> 1948: API, 1949 <strong>to</strong><br />

2000: EIA, Annual Energy Review Tables; Coal miners: 1870 <strong>to</strong> 1970: U.S. Census, His<strong>to</strong>rical Statistics <strong>of</strong> the United States, Colonial Times <strong>to</strong> 1970; 1971- present:<br />

Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labor Statistics; GNP (1870 <strong>to</strong> 1947) and GDP (1947 <strong>to</strong> 2001) per capita based upon NBER and U.S. Census data. Mo<strong>to</strong>r vehicle registrations: 1900 <strong>to</strong><br />

1970: U.S. Census, His<strong>to</strong>rical Statistics <strong>of</strong> the United States, Colonial Times <strong>to</strong> 1970; 1971 <strong>to</strong> 1998: Bureau <strong>of</strong> Transportation Statistics. Includes all highway<br />

vehicles except mo<strong>to</strong>rcycles. Vehicle Fuel Economy: 1936 <strong>to</strong> 1948: U.S. Census, His<strong>to</strong>rical Statistics <strong>of</strong> the United States, Colonial Times <strong>to</strong> 1970; 1949 <strong>to</strong> 1999:<br />

EIA, Annual Energy Review Tables; Utility Construction Expenditures: Census Bureau; Per capita energy consumption: 1870 <strong>to</strong> 1948: U.S. Census, His<strong>to</strong>rical<br />

Statistics <strong>of</strong> the United States, Colonial Times <strong>to</strong> 1970; 1949 <strong>to</strong> 2000: EIA, Annual Energy Review Tables. 2001 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> estimates are Legg Mason estimates based<br />

on EIA, International Energy Outlook <strong>2002</strong>, and Annual Energy Outlook <strong>2002</strong>. World War risk is a Legg Mason estimate.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -42- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

• Deflation 1951 <strong>to</strong> 1965: Postwar peace dividend, with overseas oil production growth that caused<br />

U.S. oil imports <strong>to</strong> grow at a rate <strong>of</strong> 6.8% per year. Also, U.S. vehicle growth matured.<br />

• <strong>Inflation</strong> 1965 <strong>to</strong> 1981: OPEC supply embargoes, U.S. oil output peaked in 1970, U.S. oil imports<br />

grew 8.2% annually, there were cold winters. Energy prices rose 13.2% per annum from 1965 <strong>to</strong> 1981.<br />

• Deflation 1981 <strong>to</strong> 2001: Conservation, non-OPEC supply, a utility power glut, Gulf and Cold War<br />

peace dividends; $1 million <strong>of</strong> real GDP in 2000 used 765 barrels <strong>of</strong> oil, versus 1,537 barrels in 1972.<br />

We believe that the price mechanism still drives the energy market, and prices periodically inflate<br />

and deflate. For one <strong>to</strong> accept the argument that oil prices will perennially deflate (recall that disinflation is<br />

relative deflation) from the last cyclical peak in 1981 <strong>to</strong> infinity, then one must also believe that the price<br />

mechanism resulting from the push-pull relationship <strong>of</strong> supply and demand, and the effect it has on oil producer<br />

investment in new technologies,<br />

has been suspended.<br />

Our view is that crude oil is a<br />

form <strong>of</strong> wealth, and wealth<br />

flows <strong>to</strong> where it can obtain the<br />

highest return. If we consider<br />

gross domestic product <strong>to</strong> be the<br />

return that is gained from the<br />

“investment” <strong>of</strong> crude oil (among<br />

other inputs) in an economy, we<br />

would expect higher rates <strong>of</strong> oil<br />

consumption by economies that<br />

produce the most GDP output from<br />

each barrel <strong>of</strong> oil. This is shown in<br />

Exhibit 32, which contrasts per<br />

capita oil consumption rates on the<br />

vertical axis with the oil intensity<br />

<strong>of</strong> GDP on the horizontal axis, for<br />

62 countries for which oil consumption<br />

and GDP information<br />

were available for the year 2000.<br />

<strong>The</strong> upper-left quadrant <strong>of</strong> the chart<br />

contains most <strong>of</strong> the world’s advanced<br />

economies, which are the<br />

largest oil consumers, yet justify<br />

Exhibit 32 – Oil Consumption Per Capita Versus Oil<br />

Intensity <strong>of</strong> GDP, 62 Nations, As Of Year 2000<br />

Barrels <strong>of</strong> oil per capita, 2000<br />

100<br />

10<br />

1<br />

Lower oil intensity,<br />

higher oil<br />

consumption.<br />

Higher oil intensity<br />

<strong>of</strong> GDP, yet lower oil<br />

consumption rates.<br />

0<br />

100 1,000 10,000<br />

Barrels <strong>of</strong> oil per $1 million <strong>of</strong> GDP, 2000<br />

Source: Oil consumption: BP Statistical Review <strong>of</strong> World Energy June 2001; Population:<br />

this consumption through more energy-efficient GDP output. Poorer countries tend <strong>to</strong> occupy the lower<br />

right portion <strong>of</strong> the graph, where low levels <strong>of</strong> oil consumption are associated with the inefficient use <strong>of</strong> oil<br />

in producing GDP output. (Many <strong>of</strong> the outliers in the upper-right portion <strong>of</strong> the graph are oil-producing nations<br />

that consume a disproportionate amount <strong>of</strong> oil in relation <strong>to</strong> their size).<br />

Our view is that as the world economy becomes more integrated over time, then we would expect<br />

greater global energy efficiency, which would manifest itself in a clustering around the trend line in Exhibit<br />

32. <strong>The</strong> alternative <strong>to</strong> that clustering would be a migration <strong>to</strong> the upper-right quadrant <strong>of</strong> Exhibit 32, or<br />

U.S.A.<br />

China


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -43- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

high energy consumption per capita with low efficiency in relation <strong>to</strong> GDP, which we view as unlikely unless<br />

there is a discovery <strong>of</strong> some civilization-changing new source <strong>of</strong> low-cost energy. Unless that occurs,<br />

our view is that normal supply and demand forces will result in a periodic inflation <strong>of</strong> oil prices, and<br />

we believe that the economic adjustment <strong>to</strong> the next energy inflation, in terms <strong>of</strong> substitutes and conservation,<br />

may be shorter than the 1970s <strong>to</strong> 1980s experience but longer than a few years.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Demand Side <strong>of</strong> the Oil Equation – <strong>The</strong> 2001 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> Environment<br />

We view the change in the location <strong>of</strong> world GDP growth <strong>to</strong> be more critical than the makeup <strong>of</strong> GDP<br />

growth. From 1980 <strong>to</strong> 2000, North America, Western Europe, and Japan combined accounted for 73% <strong>of</strong><br />

the world’s incremental GDP growth, measured in constant U.S. dollars. We project that those highly<br />

developed economies will only account for 54% <strong>of</strong> incremental GDP growth from 2001 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>, and we<br />

also estimate that China alone, which accounted for 8.8% <strong>of</strong> world GDP growth from 1980 <strong>to</strong> 2000, should<br />

contribute 14.4% <strong>of</strong> incremental world GDP growth in that period. In terms <strong>of</strong> raw materials intensity, as<br />

developing economies become a greater component <strong>of</strong> world GDP growth, we look for those consumers <strong>to</strong><br />

add “plumbing <strong>to</strong> the home” or even a “better home” long before “fiber <strong>to</strong> the home” becomes much <strong>of</strong> a<br />

desire.<br />

<strong>The</strong> experience <strong>of</strong> the U.S. in the 20th century is instrumental in gauging the future for developing<br />

world raw materials usage. According <strong>to</strong> the Second Law <strong>of</strong> <strong>The</strong>rmodynamics, the amount <strong>of</strong> disorder in<br />

the universe always increases. Since economic growth is the creation <strong>of</strong> order out <strong>of</strong> disorder, it follows that<br />

the consumption <strong>of</strong> energy (and materials) is required <strong>to</strong> <strong>of</strong>fset nature’s tendency <strong>to</strong>ward disorder. <strong>The</strong> experience<br />

<strong>of</strong> the U.S. in its early growth stages is instructive in that regard. In the period 1900 <strong>to</strong> 1950, U.S.<br />

real GNP grew at a rate <strong>of</strong> 3.1%, compared <strong>to</strong> 3.5% GDP growth in the 1950 <strong>to</strong> 2000 period. As we noted<br />

previously, however, per capita material consumption was far higher in the first half <strong>of</strong> the century than in<br />

the second half. U.S. per capita GDP growth from 1900 <strong>to</strong> 1950 grew by 128%, but per capita materials<br />

usage grew 2700% for petroleum, 890% for non-fuel organics, 400% for paper and board products, 310%<br />

for metals, and 220% for industrial minerals. Although U.S. real GDP per capita grew 183% from 1950 <strong>to</strong><br />

1998, a larger gain than in the first half <strong>of</strong> the century, per capita usage grew only 64% for petroleum, 143%<br />

for non-fuel organics, 93% for paper and board products, 13% for metals, and 37% for industrial minerals.<br />

Material consumption growth correlates closely with living standards improvements; desiring the<br />

latter, developing nations can be expected <strong>to</strong> ramp up demand for the former as a means <strong>to</strong> an end.<br />

Life expectancy at birth in the U.S. grew from 47 years in 1900 <strong>to</strong> 68 years in 1950, and then <strong>to</strong> 77 years in<br />

2000. <strong>The</strong> average U.S. work week fell from 59 hours in 1900 <strong>to</strong> 40.5 hours in 1950, and then <strong>to</strong> 34.5 hours<br />

in 1999. Since poor sanitation has been the leading cause <strong>of</strong> death in human his<strong>to</strong>ry, it is noteworthy that<br />

10% <strong>of</strong> U.S. households had flush <strong>to</strong>ilets in 1900, versus 76% in 1950 and 98% in 2000. For these and<br />

countless other reasons, we believe the first half <strong>of</strong> the 20th century in the United States represented the<br />

steep part <strong>of</strong> the curve for U.S. living standards. Our view is that much <strong>of</strong> the developing world and the<br />

former communist countries <strong>of</strong> the FSU and Eastern Europe are following – or soon will be<br />

following – a similar trajec<strong>to</strong>ry <strong>to</strong> the United States in the first half <strong>of</strong> the 20th century.<br />

<strong>The</strong> China Example – Pushing <strong>The</strong> Oil Demand Envelope - 2001 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong><br />

By several measures, Chinese economic development matches that <strong>of</strong> the U.S. in the late 19th and<br />

early 20th centuries. Both in terms <strong>of</strong> real per capita income and urbanization rate, China’s economic de-


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -44- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

velopment compares <strong>to</strong> that <strong>of</strong> the U.S. in the last decade <strong>of</strong> the 19th century. <strong>The</strong> U.S. currently has four<br />

times more inland freight transport avenues (paved roads, railways, and navigable waterways) per square<br />

mile than China does. So, typical <strong>of</strong> a developing country, China’s freight capabilities are heavily skewed<br />

<strong>to</strong>ward inland waterways, which handle 51% <strong>of</strong> freight traffic versus only 14% in the U.S. As a result,<br />

China has embarked on a major road-building campaign, the scale <strong>of</strong> which has not been seen since the<br />

building <strong>of</strong> the Eisenhower U.S. Interstate network, and if the U.S. experience is a guide, China plans <strong>to</strong><br />

populate those highways with au<strong>to</strong>mobiles rapidly. China built 8,000 miles <strong>of</strong> expressway in the past three<br />

years, with plans <strong>to</strong> build seven additional east-west and five north-south expressways by 2008. Using those<br />

roads will be 72 million mo<strong>to</strong>r vehicles (excluding mo<strong>to</strong>rcycles) by 2010, according <strong>to</strong> a recent Chinese<br />

government study, up from only 20 million in 2001, for a growth rate <strong>of</strong> over 15% annually, similar <strong>to</strong> the<br />

U.S. experience <strong>of</strong> the first half <strong>of</strong> the 20th century. China imposes a tariff <strong>of</strong> 80% <strong>to</strong> 100% on imported<br />

au<strong>to</strong>s, but WTO entrance requires China <strong>to</strong> lower that rate <strong>to</strong> 25% by July 2006. Many <strong>of</strong> the world’s major<br />

au<strong>to</strong>makers are establishing manufacturing facilities in China, with the main purpose <strong>of</strong> selling cars <strong>to</strong> the<br />

domestic market rather than exporting them.<br />

Economic expansion can produce tremendous gains in oil consumption. Exhibit 33 shows the way in<br />

which Japan in the 1960s and South Korea in the 1990s made rapid gains in oil consumption around the<br />

same time that their economies became manufacturing powerhouses. In a recent interview, U.S. Treasury<br />

Secretary Paul O’Neill stated that South Korea transformed itself from a “13th century economy” <strong>to</strong><br />

“middle- class prosperity” in the space <strong>of</strong> 40 years, and wondered aloud why that model could not be replicated<br />

more frequently. Point “A” in Exhibit 33 represents Chinese oil demand at the Japanese/South Korean<br />

level, equivalent <strong>to</strong> 69 million barrels per day (18 barrels per capita annually). Since that level is equal <strong>to</strong><br />

88% <strong>of</strong> current global oil production, we believe it is beyond our forecast horizon. Point “B” is Chinese oil<br />

demand <strong>of</strong> 10 million barrels per day<br />

(2.6 barrels per capita per year) in<br />

<strong>2015</strong>, versus 4.9 million barrels per<br />

day in 2001, equal <strong>to</strong> EIA’s “high<br />

economic growth” case for China.<br />

EIA projects that China’s domestic<br />

oil production will decline slightly <strong>to</strong><br />

just over three million barrels per day<br />

through <strong>2015</strong>, so China must increase<br />

oil imports over current levels<br />

by 5.3 million barrels per day by<br />

<strong>2015</strong>, an amount greater than the<br />

<strong>to</strong>tal <strong>of</strong> Iraq’s + Kuwait’s + Qatar’s<br />

2001 exports, simply <strong>to</strong> bring<br />

China’s per capita oil consumption<br />

<strong>to</strong> one-tenth the current U.S. level.<br />

Again, the U.S. experience in the first<br />

half <strong>of</strong> the 20th century is instructive.<br />

In Exhibit 34, we compare U.S. oil<br />

consumption <strong>to</strong> real GDP on a per<br />

capita basis for the 1902 <strong>to</strong> 2001 period,<br />

and overlay data for China for<br />

the period 1975 <strong>to</strong> 2000, with our<br />

Exhibit 33 – Oil consumption per capita for Japan, South<br />

Korea, and China, 1950-2001<br />

Oil consumption per capita (barrels/yr.)<br />

25<br />

20<br />

15<br />

10<br />

5<br />

0<br />

1950<br />

1955<br />

1960<br />

1965<br />

1970<br />

Tremendous surges in oil<br />

consumption and quality <strong>of</strong> life<br />

Cost differential<br />

drives manufacturing<br />

<strong>to</strong> "Asia Tigers"<br />

1975<br />

1980<br />

Source: Oil consumption: 1950-1964: U.N Energy Statistics Database; 1965-2000: BP<br />

Statistical Review <strong>of</strong> World Energy. 2001: EIA<br />

1985<br />

1990<br />

1995<br />

2000<br />

Japan South Korea China<br />

Cost differential<br />

drives manufacturing<br />

<strong>to</strong> China<br />

2005<br />

2010<br />

A<br />

B<br />

<strong>2015</strong>


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -45- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

forecast <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> for China (China<br />

amounts are purchasing power<br />

parity, in an effort <strong>to</strong> improve<br />

comparability.)<br />

Exhibit 34 – U.S. Oil Consumption vs. GDP, 1902 <strong>to</strong> 2001,<br />

And For China, 1975 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E<br />

100 bbl.<br />

<strong>The</strong> energy s<strong>to</strong>ry is much the<br />

same throughout Asia. In 2000,<br />

Asia (outside <strong>of</strong> the Middle East<br />

and the former Soviet Union) accounted<br />

for 28% <strong>of</strong> the world’s<br />

oil consumption, yet produced<br />

only 11% <strong>of</strong> the world’s oil supply<br />

and had only 4% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

world’s oil reserves. <strong>The</strong> region’s<br />

population <strong>of</strong> 3.5 billion, 56% <strong>of</strong><br />

the world <strong>to</strong>tal, presents a tremendous<br />

labor resource for the<br />

world’s manufacturers and potentially<br />

the world’s largest consumer<br />

market. Of course, the<br />

abundance <strong>of</strong> even less expensive<br />

labor in China is a concern<br />

among those who feel that China<br />

will come <strong>to</strong> dominate regional<br />

trade in much the way it already<br />

Oil Consumption Per Capita<br />

10 bbl.<br />

1 bbl.<br />

China in 1975<br />

0 bbl.<br />

China Forecast<br />

through <strong>2015</strong><br />

China in<br />

2000<br />

USA in 1902<br />

USA in 2001<br />

$100 $1,000 $10,000 $100,000<br />

U.S. oil consumption Real vs. GDP GDP Per per Capita Capita, (PPP 1902 for <strong>to</strong> 2001 China)<br />

China's oil consumption vs. Real (PPP) GDP, Per Capita, 1975 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E<br />

Source: U.S.: pre-1970: U.S. Census publication “His<strong>to</strong>rical Statistics <strong>of</strong> the United<br />

States, Colonial Times <strong>to</strong> 1970.” GNP used in place <strong>of</strong> GDP pre-1947. 1970-2001: GDP:<br />

BEA. Oil: EIA. China: Oil: 1965-2000: BP Statistical Review <strong>of</strong> World Energy. 2001: EIA;<br />

<strong>2002</strong>-<strong>2015</strong>: LM projection. GDP <strong>to</strong> 2000: World Bank; Projection uses GDP growth rate<br />

from EIA, International Energy Outlook <strong>2002</strong>, high growth case<br />

dominates foreign direct investment flows. But we are optimistic that the successful U.S. bilateral experience<br />

with Mexico in the post-NAFTA period is more applicable <strong>to</strong> the Asian situation than a “crowdingout”<br />

assumption, the latter <strong>of</strong> which does not adequately account for an expanding economic pie, in our<br />

view. We anticipate that rising Asian demand for energy will stretch the world’s ability <strong>to</strong> meet its vast<br />

needs, and demand-pull inflation for commodities could result.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Supply Side <strong>of</strong> the Oil Equation – <strong>The</strong> 2001 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> Environment<br />

Our projection <strong>of</strong> near-zero growth in production in the world’s major industrial nations makes the<br />

supply situation in oil-exporting regions critical <strong>to</strong> continued world economic growth. Our oil supply<br />

and demand forecast, summarized in Exhibit 35, is largely EIA’s model, cus<strong>to</strong>mized <strong>to</strong> account for our<br />

higher demand estimates in certain oil-producing and Asia-Pacific markets. Our adjustments add 4.6 million<br />

barrels per day <strong>to</strong> demand in <strong>2015</strong>, a 4% increase over EIA’s reference case. On the supply side, we use<br />

EIA’s reference case forecast through <strong>2015</strong>, adjusted upward <strong>to</strong> account for the added demand. We believe<br />

several striking developments in this forecast, including the following.<br />

• Middle East sources account for 47% <strong>of</strong> the incremental growth in oil supply in the 2001 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period,<br />

an increase from the 37% Middle Eastern share <strong>of</strong> incremental supply in the 1981 <strong>to</strong> 2001 period.<br />

Our projection assumes that Saudi Arabian production capacity alone will rise from 9.4 million barrels<br />

per day in 2000 <strong>to</strong> 18.2 million barrels per day by <strong>2015</strong>, enriching the Kingdom and, potentially, enabling<br />

the al-Saud family <strong>to</strong> continue its his<strong>to</strong>rical practice <strong>of</strong> employing financial largesse <strong>to</strong> fund domestic<br />

development, and thus maintain power.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -46- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

• European share <strong>of</strong> new oil supply growth falls from 24% in 1981 <strong>to</strong> 2001 <strong>to</strong> 1% in the 2001 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong><br />

period. This is caused by maturing North Sea fields, which were major non-OPEC producers after 1981.<br />

• FSU and Eastern European demand collapsed after 1981, subtracting 41% from the change in world<br />

oil supply, but rebounding post-Communist demand in those countries adds 15% <strong>to</strong> 2001–15 estimated<br />

growth. Although we expect FSU oil production in <strong>2015</strong> <strong>of</strong> 14.4 million barrels per day <strong>to</strong> eclipse the<br />

prior production peak <strong>of</strong> 12.7 million barrels per day in 1987, the rebound in FSU demand <strong>to</strong> 8.3 million<br />

barrels per day we forecast in <strong>2015</strong> is still below the 9.1 million barrels per day consumed in the<br />

peak year <strong>of</strong> 1982, 33 years earlier, for perspective.<br />

• African oil production, 66% <strong>of</strong> which comes from three OPEC members, Nigeria, Algeria, and Libya,<br />

could be joined by newly discovered oilfields in <strong>of</strong>fshore Angola, which is not an OPEC member. Development<br />

<strong>of</strong> these fields should add about 2 million barrels per day by <strong>2015</strong>, representing about onethird<br />

<strong>of</strong> Africa’s incremental growth in production over that time per EIA estimates.<br />

Whereas OPEC’s ability <strong>to</strong> periodically constrict supply was the “oil weapon” <strong>of</strong> the 1970s, we believe<br />

that the key <strong>to</strong> OPEC’s strength in the coming years will be its rising market position filling incremental<br />

world demand for oil. In our view, this shift in market power from the western oil-consuming nations<br />

<strong>to</strong> the generally eastern and southern oil-producing ones will probably have widespread economic and<br />

political ramifications that lead <strong>to</strong> still more developing country modernization. In Exhibit 36, we show the<br />

percent <strong>of</strong> world oil production held by oil export-based countries recovering from 57% in 2001 <strong>to</strong> 66% in<br />

<strong>2015</strong>, and even though this is a sharp rebound, it is still below the 1976 peak <strong>of</strong> 70%. In Exhibit 37, we<br />

Exhibit 35 – World Oil Supply And Demand His<strong>to</strong>ry and Our Projection <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong><br />

World<br />

2001 / 1981 <strong>2015</strong> / 2001 World<br />

2001 / 1981 <strong>2015</strong> / 2001<br />

Oil Demand Demand As Demand As Oil Supply Supply As Supply As<br />

(million bbl/day) % <strong>of</strong> Total % <strong>of</strong> Total (million bbl/day) % <strong>of</strong> Total % <strong>of</strong> Total<br />

Incremental Incremental Incremental Incremental<br />

1981 2001 <strong>2015</strong> Demand Demand 1981 2001 <strong>2015</strong> Production Production<br />

Net importers:<br />

USA/Canada 17.8 21.7 27.4 26% 16% 12.4 11.9 13.3 -3% 4%<br />

W. Europe 12.3 13.8 15.5 10% 5% 2.9 6.7 6.9 24% 1%<br />

E. Europe 2.3 1.4 2.0 -6% 2% 0.5 0.2 0.3 -1% 0%<br />

Japan 4.8 5.4 6.6 4% 3% 0.0 0.1 0.1 0% 0%<br />

China 1.8 4.9 10.0 21% 14% 2.0 3.3 3.1 8% -1%<br />

India 0.7 2.0 4.1 9% 6% 0.3 0.7 0.7 3% 0%<br />

Other East Asia 2.5 7.4 11.7 33% 12% 2.2 3.2 3.3 6% 0%<br />

Australasia 0.8 1.1 1.8 2% 2% 0.5 0.8 0.8 2% 0%<br />

Net exporters:<br />

Middle East 2.5 5.2 8.6 18% 9% 16.5 22.3 38.8 37% 47%<br />

Africa 1.6 2.4 4.5 6% 6% 4.9 8.2 14.4 21% 18%<br />

Latin America 4.9 6.8 11.3 13% 13% 6.4 10.3 15.6 24% 15%<br />

Former Soviet U. 8.9 3.7 8.3 -35% 13% 12.2 8.8 14.4 -21% 16%<br />

World<br />

60.9 75.8 111.8 100% 100% 60.7 76.6 111.7 100% 100%<br />

Source: 1981: BP Statistical Review <strong>of</strong> World Energy 2001; 2001: EIA Monthly Energy Review, March <strong>2002</strong>; <strong>2015</strong>: EIA’s International<br />

Energy Outlook <strong>2002</strong> reference case forecast, except high economic growth forecast was used <strong>to</strong> estimate demand in China, Japan,<br />

Middle East, FSU, and Australasia. EIA IEO <strong>2002</strong> reference case supply forecast was used. Because demand forecast exceed reference<br />

case supply forecast, incremental supply increases were added <strong>to</strong> each region, with the regional shares based on 2001-<strong>2015</strong><br />

reference case supply growth as a percentage <strong>of</strong> the world <strong>to</strong>tal.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -47- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Exhibit 36 – Oil export-based economies as<br />

share <strong>of</strong> world oil production, 1965-<strong>2015</strong>E<br />

Exhibit 37 – Non-OPEC Reserve-To-<br />

Production Ratio, 1952 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E<br />

Percent <strong>of</strong> World Oil Production Held<br />

By Oil-Export-Based Countries<br />

70%<br />

65%<br />

60%<br />

55%<br />

LM<br />

Estimate<br />

Non-OPEC Reserve/Production<br />

24<br />

22<br />

20<br />

18<br />

16<br />

14<br />

12<br />

10<br />

Major new non-OPEC discoveries 1968-<br />

1975 in North Sea, Alaska, Siberia, but<br />

rate <strong>of</strong> new discoveries has declined.<br />

Forecast assumes<br />

non-OPEC reserve<br />

additions continue at<br />

1986-2001 rate.<br />

LM<br />

Estimate<br />

50%<br />

1965<br />

1969<br />

1973<br />

1977<br />

1981<br />

1985<br />

1989<br />

1993<br />

1997<br />

2001<br />

2005<br />

2009<br />

2013<br />

8<br />

1952<br />

1956<br />

1960<br />

1964<br />

1968<br />

1972<br />

1976<br />

1980<br />

1984<br />

1988<br />

1992<br />

1996<br />

2000<br />

2004<br />

2008<br />

2012<br />

Source: BP Statistical Review <strong>of</strong> World Energy June 2001, 1965-<br />

2000. 2001 data: EIA. <strong>2002</strong>-<strong>2015</strong>: Legg Mason projection based<br />

on EIA, international Energy Outlook <strong>2002</strong>, March <strong>2002</strong>. “Oil<br />

export-based economies” include OPEC, FSU, and non-OPEC<br />

Africa and Middle East.<br />

Source: Production: Source: UN 1952-1964; BP 1965-2000. EIA<br />

2001. Reserves: 1952-<strong>2002</strong>: OGJ Energy Statistics Sourcebook, Oil<br />

& Gas Journal. Legg Mason projection<br />

show the reserve-<strong>to</strong>-production ratio <strong>of</strong> non-OPEC producers falling from 13.3 in 2001 <strong>to</strong> 8.2 in <strong>2015</strong>, far<br />

below the 1975 peak <strong>of</strong> 22.3. Although higher oil prices, if they occur, would prompt increased exploration<br />

and reserve additions, the cost <strong>of</strong> those wells may rise as an <strong>of</strong>fsetting fac<strong>to</strong>r. For example, successful experiences<br />

in Brazil, Argentina, and Angola demonstrate that deepwater drilling at water depths that test the<br />

limits <strong>of</strong> available exploration technologies can result in new discoveries, but at great expense.<br />

To summarize, we believe that the world appears <strong>to</strong> be in a transition phase from generally slack <strong>to</strong><br />

generally tight oil supply, thanks <strong>to</strong> Asian oil demand and recovering FSU and satellite usage in excess<br />

<strong>of</strong> rising production, with no North Sea-sized non-OPEC price spoiling discoveries expected. Exhibit<br />

38 summarizes the global import/export balance <strong>of</strong> petroleum from 1965 through our <strong>2015</strong> estimate,<br />

with net oil exporters shown on the <strong>to</strong>p half <strong>of</strong> the graph and net importers shown on the bot<strong>to</strong>m half. From<br />

2001 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>, we project that 62% <strong>of</strong> the incremental growth in net imports by region will be in Asia/<br />

Pacific ex-Japan. On the supply side, 69% <strong>of</strong> the growth in net exports is seen coming from the Middle<br />

East, followed by 21% from Africa and the rest from FSU and Latin America. <strong>The</strong> major s<strong>to</strong>ry is the increasing<br />

reliance <strong>of</strong> Asia on Middle East oil on a scale that reorients economic and security alliances.<br />

Exhibit 38 also contains our oil price forecast, in both real (2000$) and nominal terms. We project that<br />

U.S. crude oil prices, expressed in real 2000 dollars, will rise from $22.40 in 2001 <strong>to</strong> $26.11 in <strong>2015</strong> (with<br />

sharply higher inflation that accrues <strong>to</strong> oil producers), and that the U.S. average nominal crude price will<br />

rise from $23.01 in 2001 <strong>to</strong> $62.81 in <strong>2015</strong>, in line with our estimate <strong>of</strong> growth for the PPI for All Commodities<br />

index, shown in Exhibit 31.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -48- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Exhibit 38 – Net Exports and Imports <strong>of</strong> Oil, 1965-<strong>2015</strong>E. Oil prices shown below.<br />

60<br />

Projection<br />

Net oil exports (imports), Million barrels per day<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

(20)<br />

(40)<br />

Latin America<br />

Fm r. Sovie t U.<br />

Africa<br />

Middle East<br />

US/Canada<br />

Europe<br />

Japan<br />

Asia/Pacific<br />

ex-Japan<br />

(60)<br />

1965<br />

1968<br />

1971<br />

1974<br />

1977<br />

1980<br />

1983<br />

1986<br />

Crude oil price per barrel<br />

1989<br />

1992<br />

1995<br />

1998<br />

2001<br />

2004<br />

2007<br />

2010<br />

2013<br />

$80<br />

$60<br />

$40<br />

$20<br />

$0<br />

Projection<br />

Nominal<br />

$/barrel<br />

Real<br />

2000$/barrel<br />

1965<br />

1968<br />

1971<br />

1974<br />

1977<br />

1980<br />

1983<br />

1986<br />

1989<br />

1992<br />

1995<br />

1998<br />

2001<br />

2004<br />

2007<br />

2010<br />

2013<br />

Source: 1965 <strong>to</strong> 2000 data: 2001 BP Statistical Review <strong>of</strong> World Energy. Projection: 2001 and <strong>2002</strong> net exports from International Energy Agency<br />

and EIA Monthly Energy Review, March <strong>2002</strong>. 2001 price: EIA, Monthly Energy Review March <strong>2002</strong>. <strong>2002</strong> and later net export projections from<br />

Legg Mason based on EIA International Energy Annual <strong>2002</strong>. Oil price projections for 2003 and later are Legg Mason projections.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -49- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Substitute Fuels – Promising, But Enough <strong>to</strong> Make a Difference?<br />

We believe that the use <strong>of</strong> substitutes first requires an inflation in the “old” fuel <strong>to</strong> stimulate the<br />

switch. <strong>The</strong> world has migrated in patterns from solid fuels (wood, coal), <strong>to</strong> liquid fuels (kerosene, oil,<br />

gasoline) and then <strong>to</strong> gasses (natural gas, hydrogen fuel cells in the future). For now, however, crude oil is,<br />

in many ways, the ideal fuel, and the only catalyst we see for developing a new energy infrastructure and<br />

encouraging fuel switching is prolonged, high prices for crude oil, which fulfills our thesis, anyway. Crude<br />

oil has an energy density that is over 50% higher than high-grade coal and 1,000 times greater than natural<br />

gas at atmospheric pressure; it can be transported cheaply via tanker or pipeline; it can be refined in<strong>to</strong> a<br />

range <strong>of</strong> products from jet fuel <strong>to</strong> home heating oil <strong>to</strong> petrochemicals; when refined in<strong>to</strong> gasoline, it burns<br />

cleanly and just 90 pounds <strong>of</strong> gasoline can fuel a 3,000 pound vehicle for hundreds <strong>of</strong> miles; and most importantly,<br />

it is available in very large quantities. More than for other commodities such as food or metals,<br />

the demand for energy and petroleum by-products <strong>of</strong>ten expands <strong>to</strong> utilize available supply. As early as<br />

1901, the oil gusher at Spindle<strong>to</strong>p, Texas, instantly doubled world oil supplies, and within a decade, au<strong>to</strong>s<br />

and trucks in the U.S. had soared from 8,000 vehicles fueled by a variety <strong>of</strong> fuels <strong>to</strong> a mass-produced, gasoline-powered<br />

fleet <strong>of</strong> 640,000 vehicles growing at over 40% per year.<br />

On the demand side <strong>of</strong> consumption, fuel switching is likely <strong>to</strong> occur, moving oil users away from<br />

low-value applications and more <strong>to</strong>ward high-value transportation uses. Low-value applications include<br />

power plants, industrial use <strong>of</strong> distillate and residual fuel oils, and residential/commercial use <strong>of</strong> distillate<br />

fuel. <strong>The</strong> U.S. has already made major strides in reducing low-value uses, but some developing markets<br />

are lagging behind. For example, U.S. non-transportation oil consumption went from 48% <strong>of</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal U.S.<br />

oil consumption in 1965 <strong>to</strong> 41% in 1981 and then <strong>to</strong> only 33% in 2000. Low-value oil consumption in the<br />

U.S. went from 23% <strong>of</strong> U.S. oil demand in 1965 <strong>to</strong> 18% in 1981 and then <strong>to</strong> only 10% in 2000. <strong>The</strong> rest <strong>of</strong><br />

the world presents more opportunities for replacing oil with other fuels such as coal or natural gas in lowvalue<br />

applications. In 1999, global oil consumption in low-value applications was 25% <strong>of</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal petroleum<br />

demand, representing substantial “low-hanging fruit” if high oil prices force all nations <strong>to</strong> use oil more efficiently.<br />

And on the supply side, we do see the door opening for a host <strong>of</strong> energy supply alternatives,<br />

but they face a chicken and egg conundrum. <strong>The</strong> modern petroleum market has a highly efficient system<br />

<strong>of</strong> delivering around 76 million barrels <strong>of</strong> oil <strong>to</strong> consumers around the world every day, so even those crude<br />

oil substitutes that are able <strong>to</strong> prove some cost or performance advantage must reckon with the fact that a<br />

new retail distribution infrastructure will require many years <strong>to</strong> develop fully, and the development <strong>of</strong> that<br />

infrastructure will not come, in our view, unless crude oil prices are high for a similar period. Still, there are<br />

promising alternatives, such as liquefied natural gas (LNG) and the oil sands <strong>of</strong> Canada.<br />

<strong>The</strong> growing use <strong>of</strong> LNG solves two problems: what <strong>to</strong> do with excess natural gas in oil-producing regions<br />

with low domestic energy demand needs, and how <strong>to</strong> expand fuel consumption in areas with little native<br />

fossil fuel resources, such as Japan and China. LNG is natural gas that has been liquefied through pressurization<br />

and cooling <strong>to</strong> low temperatures in a liquefaction plant located close <strong>to</strong> a natural gas source. <strong>The</strong><br />

liquefied gas is loaded on<strong>to</strong> a special double-hulled refrigerated tanker, transported across the water <strong>to</strong> an<br />

unloading terminal, and converted back <strong>to</strong> gaseous form in a regasification plant. <strong>The</strong> process is energyintensive<br />

and capital-intensive, but LNG provides a supply option that bypasses the use <strong>of</strong> gas pipelines,<br />

which may be impractical (e.g., distance) or nearly impossible (e.g., distant islands). Depending on the gas<br />

production cost and the distance between source and destination, <strong>to</strong>tal costs <strong>of</strong> natural gas via LNG range<br />

from about $2.50 <strong>to</strong> $4.00 per million Btu (MMBtu), making it very competitive with natural gas supplied<br />

via pipelines. For comparison purposes, the average U.S. city gate natural gas price in 1999 was $3.01/


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -50- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

MMBtu, and in 2000 the average was $4.49/MMBtu. <strong>The</strong> average for the first 11 months <strong>of</strong> 2001 was<br />

$5.91/MMBtu, but prices in recent months have dropped below $4.00/MMBtu as the natural gas shortages<br />

<strong>of</strong> early 2001 have eased in the record warm winter <strong>of</strong> 2001/02.<br />

Asia has made extensive use <strong>of</strong> LNG where pipelines are not as feasible, but the capital investments<br />

for LNG are large. LNG is competitive in the U.S., but its greatest potential is in serving areas such as<br />

East Asia with very limited gas supplies and almost no pipeline infrastructure. LNG currently accounts for<br />

6% <strong>of</strong> the world’s natural gas consumption and 26% <strong>of</strong> cross-border gas flows. <strong>The</strong> largest importers <strong>of</strong><br />

LNG are the island nation <strong>of</strong> Japan (53% <strong>of</strong> the world <strong>to</strong>tal), South Korea (14%), France (8%) and Spain<br />

(6%), and the largest LNG exporters are Indonesia (29%), Algeria (19%), Malaysia (15%), and Qatar<br />

(10%). Well over 90% <strong>of</strong> Japan’s and South Korea’s natural gas supply is provided by LNG, and China is<br />

preparing <strong>to</strong> follow suit by building its own LNG terminals, beginning with a $600 million, 3 million metric<br />

<strong>to</strong>n per year terminal in Shenzhen (Guangdong Province) scheduled <strong>to</strong> be completed in 2005. Three million<br />

metric <strong>to</strong>ns is the equivalent <strong>of</strong> 146 billion cubic feet, or about 17% <strong>of</strong> China’s natural gas consumption in<br />

2000. <strong>The</strong> capital cost differential between LNG projects such as this and a planned $18 billion PetroChina<br />

gas development and pipeline project <strong>to</strong> connect Shanghai with western China gas resources, providing only<br />

three <strong>to</strong> five times as much gas as the Shenzhen LNG terminal, illuminates LNG’s attractiveness. <strong>The</strong> presence<br />

<strong>of</strong> some <strong>of</strong> the world’s largest known gas deposits in Irkutsk, Siberia, less than 2,000 miles from Beijing,<br />

creates another option for China in lieu <strong>of</strong> LNG, but such a pipeline requires many years <strong>to</strong> build.<br />

Canadian oil sands are another intriguing alternative supply option, but high capital costs and long<br />

project lead times hinder the growth potential for the next decade. In a remote section <strong>of</strong> Alberta, Canada<br />

lies a viscous mixture <strong>of</strong> sand, bitumen, clay and water with the consistency <strong>of</strong> cold molasses known as<br />

“oil sands,” which contains at least 300 billion barrels <strong>of</strong> economic reserves <strong>of</strong> oil, and <strong>to</strong>tal deposits (most<br />

<strong>of</strong> which are beyond current economic limits) <strong>of</strong> 1.7 trillion barrels <strong>of</strong> oil. <strong>The</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> 300 billion barrels<br />

<strong>of</strong> recoverable oil reserves — greater than the 262 billion barrels <strong>of</strong> proved reserves in Saudi Arabia —<br />

in the oil sands <strong>of</strong> Alberta, Canada, is attracting substantial investment. Engineering News Record magazine<br />

estimates that there are now 34 oil sands projects either planned or under construction, with a <strong>to</strong>tal cost <strong>of</strong><br />

U.S. $28.9 billion and 2.9 million barrels per day <strong>of</strong> planned oil production. <strong>The</strong> new planned or in-process<br />

projects detailed by ENR average $10,000 <strong>of</strong> capital investment per barrel per day <strong>of</strong> oil production, compared<br />

with $5,500 for Persian Gulf OPEC nations, so we believe their construction is more likely <strong>to</strong> occur<br />

on schedule if oil prices inflate. Of the new capacity for which extraction methods are known, 80% use<br />

truck-and-shovel mining, which is a key potential market for Joy Global’s shovels and Caterpillar’s mining<br />

trucks, while 20% use in-situ (drilling) extraction. To put the oil sands in perspective, however, the incremental<br />

oil supply that would be provided by 2010 if all <strong>of</strong> the known projects are completed represents<br />

only 8% <strong>of</strong> our forecast <strong>of</strong> incremental growth in world oil demand over that period. Like LNG<br />

projects, investment in the oil sands requires very long lead times and high capital investments. Some<br />

planned projects will not begin oil production until 2010, so they will have little ability <strong>to</strong> influence oil<br />

prices over the next decade, in our view. However, the decline in production costs and the location in a secure<br />

non-OPEC location ensure that oil sands production will attract investment in the coming years if our<br />

thesis is correct.<br />

<strong>The</strong> security <strong>of</strong> OPEC oil supply, which has implications for supply, demand, and substitutes within the energy<br />

markets, is an issue we address later in this report. But next, we discuss the outlook for agricultural<br />

commodities, which are driven by many <strong>of</strong> the same global supply and demand fac<strong>to</strong>rs as oil, and consume<br />

substantial energy in their production.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -51- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

U.S. Farm Commodity Export and <strong>Inflation</strong> Prospects, <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E<br />

U.S. Farm Commodity <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong>s<br />

In Exhibit 40, we show the seven inflationary or deflationary price cycles <strong>of</strong> the PPI for Farm Products<br />

(PPI-Farm) index from 1870 <strong>to</strong> present. <strong>The</strong> cycles have lasted an average <strong>of</strong> 19 years, with prices<br />

in the average inflation cycle rising 8.0% per year, in a range <strong>of</strong> 6.2% <strong>to</strong> 9.8% per year. <strong>Price</strong>s in the average<br />

deflation cycle declined 2.6% per year, in a range <strong>of</strong> minus 8.7% <strong>to</strong> positive 1.6%. We find it interesting<br />

that inflation cycles are more uniform and regular than cycles <strong>of</strong> deflation in the farm industry. As Exhibit<br />

40 shows, some <strong>of</strong> the determinants <strong>of</strong> those cycles have been rising or falling input costs, farm productivity,<br />

and acreage, but one <strong>of</strong> the most important determinants has been the growth <strong>of</strong> exports. For clues as <strong>to</strong><br />

the direction <strong>of</strong> U.S. agricultural export growth we turn <strong>to</strong> the U.S. dollar. <strong>The</strong> declines in the agricultural<br />

trade-weighted U.S. dollar from 1970 <strong>to</strong> 1978 and 1985 <strong>to</strong> 1993 were associated with a surge in the export<br />

<strong>of</strong> U.S. agricultural products, just as U.S. dollar strength in 1978 <strong>to</strong> 1985 and 1995 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2002</strong> pressured U.S.<br />

food exports. An important difference between agricultural exports and oil exports is that the latter is denominated<br />

in U.S. dollars worldwide, whereas the fluctuations in home currency have a disproportionate<br />

effect on farmers (and numerous other commodity producers, for that matter).<br />

We show in Exhibit 39 that the s<strong>to</strong>ck price <strong>of</strong> Deere & Company (DE) has a close, positive relationship<br />

with U.S. agricultural exports, and that is the primary focus <strong>of</strong> this section <strong>of</strong> our report. Noted agricultural<br />

analyst and his<strong>to</strong>rian Bill Hudson <strong>of</strong> the ProExporter Network in Olathe, Kansas, states that the U.<br />

S. has about 5% <strong>of</strong> the world's population, but about one-fifth <strong>of</strong> the world's farmland capacity, a fact that<br />

underscores exports as the key <strong>to</strong> farmer success. In Exhibit 41, we dismiss the current controversy surrounding<br />

U.S. Farm Bill delays, showing that from an inves<strong>to</strong>r's viewpoint, DE s<strong>to</strong>ck moves inversely <strong>to</strong><br />

government assistance. Since most<br />

farm aid flows <strong>to</strong> either very small<br />

or very large farms, our view has<br />

been that smaller farmers are not<br />

Deere's cus<strong>to</strong>mer base, and larger<br />

farms tend <strong>to</strong> maintain and turn<br />

over their fleets on a more regular<br />

schedule.<br />

We see another food price inflation<br />

on the horizon. If the world<br />

becomes a more dangerous place<br />

in the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period, we<br />

doubt food security will be subordinated<br />

<strong>to</strong> the WTO-inspired<br />

movement <strong>to</strong> lower state support<br />

and protectionism for agriculture.<br />

If, on the other hand, the world<br />

experiences an explosion <strong>of</strong><br />

growth, the combination <strong>of</strong> higher<br />

input costs and strong demand<br />

Exhibit 39 – Deere S<strong>to</strong>ck Is Driven By Food Exports<br />

Real U.S. Ag-Exports ($ Mil.)<br />

$110,000<br />

$100,000<br />

$90,000<br />

$80,000<br />

$70,000<br />

$60,000<br />

$50,000<br />

$40,000<br />

$30,000<br />

$20,000<br />

1962<br />

1967<br />

Deere Performance Tracks U.S. Food<br />

Exports<br />

1972<br />

1977<br />

Source: USDA, S&P Compustat, Legg Mason estimates <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong><br />

1982<br />

Real Export CAGR<br />

1962 <strong>to</strong> 1996 =<br />

2.7%/year<br />

1987<br />

1992<br />

1997<br />

<strong>2002</strong>E<br />

LM<br />

Ests.<br />

Real U.S. Farm Product Exports, U.S. $ Bil. (Left)<br />

2007E<br />

Deere S<strong>to</strong>ck Relative <strong>to</strong> the S&P Composite (Right)<br />

Real<br />

CAGR 1996 <strong>to</strong><br />

<strong>2015</strong>E = 2.4/year<br />

2012E<br />

14.0%<br />

12.0%<br />

10.0%<br />

8.0%<br />

6.0%<br />

4.0%<br />

2.0%<br />

Deere Relative <strong>to</strong> the S&P 500


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -52- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Exhibit 40 – <strong>The</strong> PPI <strong>Price</strong> His<strong>to</strong>ry and Our Estimates For U.S. Agriculture, 1870 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E<br />

1,000<br />

100<br />

10<br />

1870 <strong>to</strong><br />

1896<br />

CAGR<br />

(2.6)%<br />

1896 <strong>to</strong><br />

1919<br />

CAGR<br />

6.2%<br />

Horses, land grants,<br />

larger farms.<br />

U.S. Agricultural <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong>s, 1870 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E<br />

U.S. urban<br />

migration,<br />

farm exports,<br />

W.W. I.<br />

1919 <strong>to</strong><br />

1932<br />

CAGR<br />

(8.7)%<br />

1932 <strong>to</strong><br />

1951<br />

CAGR<br />

7.9%<br />

Supply<br />

controls,<br />

machinery,<br />

W.W. II.<br />

Mechanization, postwar<br />

deflation, trade<br />

barriers.<br />

1951<br />

<strong>to</strong> 1969<br />

CAGR<br />

(1.1)%<br />

1969 <strong>to</strong><br />

1982<br />

CAGR<br />

9.8%<br />

Exports<br />

<strong>to</strong> EU<br />

and<br />

USSR,<br />

costly<br />

fertilizer<br />

and fuel.<br />

Post-war<br />

price<br />

support overproduction,<br />

more<br />

fertilizer.<br />

1982 <strong>to</strong><br />

2001<br />

CAGR<br />

1.6%<br />

2001 <strong>to</strong><br />

<strong>2015</strong>E<br />

CAGR<br />

6.1%<br />

Export<br />

decline,<br />

lower<br />

U.S.<br />

export<br />

market<br />

share,<br />

strong<br />

U.S. $.<br />

Exports,<br />

costly<br />

fuel and<br />

fertilizer,<br />

weak $.<br />

1<br />

1870<br />

1880<br />

1890<br />

1900<br />

1910<br />

1920<br />

1930<br />

1940<br />

1950<br />

1960<br />

1970<br />

1980<br />

1990<br />

2000<br />

2010E<br />

PPI Farm Products<br />

SUPPLY-SIDE ISSUES<br />

DEMAND-SIDE ISSUES<br />

U.S. Growth Comm'l. U.S. U.S. U.S. Nominal Real<br />

PPI- Farm CAGR % Farm U.S. Rate Fertilizer Corn Real Meat (3) Growth Growth<br />

Products <strong>of</strong> PPI Horses Farm <strong>of</strong> U.S. Used Yield World GDP (2) Con- Rate <strong>of</strong> Rate (4)<br />

<strong>Inflation</strong> and Farm and Trac<strong>to</strong>r Acreage Lbs/Acre Bu./acre War? Per sumption U.S. <strong>of</strong> Farm<br />

Deflation Products Mules Unit All Major Growth Growth (1) YES Capita Growth Food & Food<br />

Period Yrs. Index Growth Growth Crops Rate Rate or NO Growth Rate Exports Exports<br />

1870 <strong>to</strong> 1896 26 (2.6)% 3.3% na 3.2% 3.7% 0.2% NO 2.7% na 1.7% 4.3%<br />

1896 <strong>to</strong> 1919 23 6.2% 1.1% na 1.7% 3.9% (0.1)% YES 2.1% na 5.2% (1.0)%<br />

1919 <strong>to</strong> 1932 13 (8.7)% (3.0)% 15.4% 0.2% (3.6)% (0.7)% NO (1.4)% 0.9% (11.3)% (2.6)%<br />

1932 <strong>to</strong> 1951 19 7.9% (4.4)% 7.0% (0.4)% 9.1% 2.5% YES 4.0% 1.9% 9.3% 1.4%<br />

1951 <strong>to</strong> 1969 18 (0.7)% nmf 1.5% (1.0)% 4.5% 4.0% NO 2.3% 3.6% 2.2% 3.0%<br />

1969 <strong>to</strong> 1982 13 9.8% nmf -0.5% 1.7% 0.02% 1.9% YES (5) 1.4% 1.0% 14.9% 5.1%<br />

1982 <strong>to</strong> 2001 19 1.6% nmf na (0.6)% 1.2% 1.6% NO 2.5% 1.6% 1.9% 0.4%<br />

2001 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E 14E 6.1% nmf ne ne 0.0%E 1.0%E 25%E ne ne 11.2%E 5.0%E<br />

(1) To reduce the effect <strong>of</strong> weather, we compare three-year centered averages for each period, with a <strong>2002</strong> corn yield estimate from PRX ProExporter.<br />

(2) Real GNP prior <strong>to</strong> 1947.<br />

(3) Red meat, pork and poulty; per-capita values multiplied by U.S. resident population annually; CAGR between periods.<br />

(4) Growth rate <strong>of</strong> real U.S. food exports is nominal exports minus the PPI for agricultural products; trade-weighted defla<strong>to</strong>r data were not available.<br />

(5) <strong>The</strong> Great Society “war” on poverty, Vietnam, and the Oil Embargoes <strong>of</strong> the 1970s, the latter being more global in their effect.<br />

Source: PPI - Farm Products 1870 <strong>to</strong> 1889 Warren & Pearson study, 1890 <strong>to</strong> 1969 PPI is the shipment-w eighted annual averages <strong>of</strong> monthly prices prepared by<br />

the U.S. BLS, 1970 <strong>to</strong> Present is the PPI Farm Products (NSA), from the U.S. BLS, all Indices have been placed in a continuous rew eighted series so that the 12-<br />

month average <strong>of</strong> 2000 = 100; horses, mules and trac<strong>to</strong>rs from USDA and U.S. Census; acreage is from the USDA and data include corn , w heat, oats, barley,<br />

flaxseed, soybeans, sorghum, rye, pota<strong>to</strong>es, sw eet pota<strong>to</strong>es, rice, sugarcane, sugarbeets, peanuts, hay, cot<strong>to</strong>n, and <strong>to</strong>bacco; fertilizer usage, corn yield; meat<br />

consumption and food exports are from USDA, NASS and predecessor bureaus; food exports 1901 <strong>to</strong> 1933 is from the FATUS section <strong>of</strong> the USDA and the U.S.<br />

Census, agricultural exports from 1934 <strong>to</strong> 2000 data are from the USDA, older food exports data for the years 1870 <strong>to</strong> 1900 are the dollar value <strong>of</strong> U.S. exports<br />

<strong>of</strong> cot<strong>to</strong>n, <strong>to</strong>bacco, w heat, flour, animal fats and oils, fruits, nuts, and 1870 <strong>to</strong> 1880 are cot<strong>to</strong>n, <strong>to</strong>bacco and w heat only; GNP (1870 <strong>to</strong> 1947) and GDP (1947 <strong>to</strong><br />

2001) per capita based upon NBER and U.S. Census data


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -53- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

may strain supply long enough<br />

<strong>to</strong> create a somewhat typical<br />

PPI-Farm inflation cycle. Lost in<br />

20 years <strong>of</strong> energy deflation<br />

thinking, in our view, is the fact<br />

that higher energy costs have a<br />

significant bearing on farm<br />

prices. According <strong>to</strong> the USDA,<br />

fertilizer, fuel and electricity account<br />

for 40% <strong>to</strong> 45% <strong>of</strong> the <strong>to</strong>tal<br />

variable costs in the production<br />

<strong>of</strong> corn, and about 20% <strong>of</strong><br />

the variable cost <strong>of</strong> soybean production.<br />

Corn is an especially<br />

heavy user <strong>of</strong> anhydrous ammonia<br />

(natural gas derived) fertilizer,<br />

but soybeans receive most<br />

<strong>of</strong> their nitrogen needs from the<br />

atmosphere.<br />

Exhibit 41 – Deere S<strong>to</strong>ck Is Not Driven By Farm Aid<br />

Real U.S. Farm Aid ($Bil.) (INVERSE)<br />

$0<br />

$5<br />

$10<br />

$15<br />

$20<br />

$25<br />

1962<br />

1967<br />

Source: USDA, S&P Compustat, Legg Mason estimates <strong>2002</strong>.<br />

Another fuel-price spillover<br />

effect could be in the ethanol markets. Each billon gallons <strong>of</strong> ethanol fuel oxygenate requires approximately<br />

365 million bushels <strong>of</strong> corn, and from a level <strong>of</strong> just 300 million bushels in the 1980s, corn used <strong>to</strong><br />

produce ethanol rose <strong>to</strong> 565 million bushels in 1999 <strong>to</strong> 2000 (6% <strong>of</strong> production). If all <strong>of</strong> California's fuel<br />

oxygenation needs were eventually <strong>to</strong> be met by ethanol, 350 million additional bushels <strong>of</strong> corn would be<br />

needed. Furthermore, if New York and Connecticut eventually turn <strong>to</strong> 100% ethanol, then 250 million bushels<br />

<strong>of</strong> corn would be needed.<br />

Our forecast <strong>of</strong> food price inflation is not without controversy. In fact, his<strong>to</strong>ry <strong>of</strong>ten suggests that increased<br />

grain trade leads <strong>to</strong> lower prices. Agricultural analyst Bill Hudson reminds us that when the U.K.<br />

repealed the Corn Laws in 1846, British imports <strong>of</strong> grain grew 4% per year for the next 68 years, but the<br />

price <strong>of</strong> grain actually declined as new acreage expanded in the U.S., which was then a developing country.<br />

Robert Malthus (b. 1766, d.1834), in his Principle <strong>of</strong> Population series, failed <strong>to</strong> recognize the ability <strong>of</strong><br />

technology <strong>to</strong> address the supply side constraints on agricultural production, and analysts have fallen in<strong>to</strong><br />

the Malthusian trap ever since. Mr. Hudson also states that a reduction <strong>of</strong> world subsidies could be deflationary,<br />

since world economies spend about $350 billion per year on farm support, causing expenditures <strong>to</strong><br />

be 47% above the true world price <strong>of</strong> food. Our view is that hydrocarbon inflation plus a positive demand<br />

shock could be catalysts for a food price inflation.<br />

<strong>The</strong> U.S. Farm Export Outlook<br />

<strong>The</strong> modern grain trade s<strong>to</strong>ry is one <strong>of</strong> shifting grain demand “hubs,” shown in Exhibit 42. We note<br />

that combined world imports <strong>of</strong> corn, wheat and soybeans grew at an annual rate <strong>of</strong> 8.6% from 1970 <strong>to</strong><br />

1980, but stagnated at a rate <strong>of</strong> minus 0.1% from 1980 <strong>to</strong> 1995 as the decline <strong>of</strong> EU and FSU imports overshadowed<br />

growth in the rest <strong>of</strong> the world. But from 1995 <strong>to</strong> 2000, after the roles <strong>of</strong> the EU and FSU were<br />

minimized in terms <strong>of</strong> their effect on the world grain import markets, world grain trade increased 3.7% per<br />

1972<br />

1977<br />

1982<br />

1987<br />

Deere Performs Inversely <strong>to</strong><br />

Farm Aid Payments<br />

Real U.S. Gov. Pmnt. <strong>to</strong> Farms, INVERTED AXIS, U.S. $96 Bil. (Left)<br />

Deere S<strong>to</strong>ck Relative <strong>to</strong> the S&P Composite (Right)<br />

1992<br />

1997<br />

<strong>2002</strong>E<br />

14.0%<br />

12.0%<br />

10.0%<br />

8.0%<br />

6.0%<br />

4.0%<br />

2.0%<br />

0.0%<br />

Deere Relative <strong>to</strong> the S&P


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -54- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

year despite rolling recessions.<br />

We look for a continuation <strong>of</strong><br />

trend growth at a 3.2% rate from<br />

<strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>, shown in Exhibit<br />

43. We believe the key is growth<br />

in markets outside the EU and<br />

FSU, <strong>to</strong> include Central and<br />

South America, Africa, the Middle<br />

East and, <strong>of</strong> course, Asia-<br />

Pacific. For example, higher petroleum<br />

prices would stimulate<br />

food demand in the predominantly<br />

Islamic countries, which<br />

account for about 27% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

world corn trade. As we have<br />

stated, we believe that U.S. farmers<br />

have been priced out <strong>of</strong> many<br />

markets by the strong U.S. dollar,<br />

but the fac<strong>to</strong>rs we outline in this<br />

report may change that situation.<br />

<strong>The</strong> U.S. grain export share<br />

also has been affected by competition.<br />

Total U.S. corn, wheat<br />

and soybean exports from 1970<br />

<strong>to</strong> 1979 were 805 million metric<br />

<strong>to</strong>nes (MMT), and the s<strong>to</strong>cks-<strong>to</strong>use<br />

averaged 18%. U.S. grain<br />

exports <strong>to</strong> the EU and FSU were<br />

particularly strong in the 1970s,<br />

as well as part <strong>of</strong> the 1980s in the<br />

case <strong>of</strong> the FSU. From 1980 <strong>to</strong><br />

1989, grain import demand from<br />

the EU collapsed, and though <strong>to</strong>tal<br />

U.S. exports for that period<br />

were 1.05 billion metric <strong>to</strong>nnes,<br />

the average s<strong>to</strong>cks-<strong>to</strong>-use was<br />

about 37%. In the 1990s, <strong>to</strong>tal<br />

U.S. corn, wheat and soybean<br />

exports were 982 MMT, continuing<br />

a period <strong>of</strong> stagnation as<br />

Exhibit 42 – Grain Import Hubs Shift Over Time<br />

Bushels Per Capita Imported<br />

Source: PRX ProExporter data and format, Legg Mason estimates <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong><br />

Exhibit 43 – <strong>The</strong> Transition from Old <strong>to</strong> New Grain Markets<br />

Millions <strong>of</strong> Metric Tonnes Per Year<br />

12.00<br />

10.00<br />

8.00<br />

6.00<br />

4.00<br />

2.00<br />

0.00<br />

(2.00)<br />

(4.00)<br />

350<br />

300<br />

250<br />

200<br />

150<br />

100<br />

50<br />

0<br />

Grain Import Hubs Through His<strong>to</strong>ry Drive Exports; Is Non-EU/FSU Next?<br />

1970<br />

1850<br />

1860<br />

1870<br />

Source: USDA, PRX ProExporter format, Legg Mason estimates <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong><br />

the grain imports <strong>of</strong> the FSU collapsed, and Brazil became a major competi<strong>to</strong>r <strong>to</strong> the U.S. in soybeans.<br />

European imports had previously collapsed in the 1980s as Common Agricultural Policy turned the EU<br />

from a net importer <strong>to</strong> an exporter <strong>of</strong> heavily subsidized grain, although the trend for EU soybean imports<br />

has since been higher. <strong>The</strong> effect on U.S. grain export share is shown in Exhibit 44. Although we look for<br />

continued pressure on U.S. soybean export market share, we believe that U.S. farmers are well positioned <strong>to</strong><br />

1880<br />

1890<br />

1900<br />

1910<br />

1920<br />

1930<br />

1940<br />

1950<br />

1960<br />

Grain Imports Bu./Capita Western Europe<br />

Grain Imports Bu./Capita FSU<br />

1970<br />

1980<br />

1990<br />

World Excluding the EU and FSU Grain + Meat Equivalent<br />

Grain Impurts Bu./Capita United Kingdom<br />

World Imports <strong>of</strong> Corn, Wheat & Soybeans<br />

<strong>The</strong> effect <strong>of</strong> the EU and FSU import decline<br />

is over, and the other world trade continues<br />

unabated.<br />

1970 <strong>to</strong><br />

1980 =<br />

8.6%<br />

CAGR<br />

1975<br />

EU-15<br />

1980<br />

FSU<br />

1985<br />

1980 <strong>to</strong><br />

1995 =<br />

(0.1)%<br />

CAGR<br />

1990<br />

1995<br />

1995 <strong>to</strong><br />

2000 =<br />

3.7%<br />

CAGR<br />

2000<br />

Asia Rest <strong>of</strong> World EU-15 FSU<br />

2005E<br />

2000<br />

2000 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong><br />

= 3.2%E<br />

CAGR<br />

Asia<br />

LM<br />

Ests.<br />

2010<br />

Rest <strong>of</strong> World<br />

2010E<br />

2020<br />

LM<br />

Ests.<br />

<strong>2015</strong>E


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -55- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

hold on<strong>to</strong> and improve corn<br />

share, and wheat share should<br />

stabilize, in our view.<br />

Exhibit 44 – <strong>The</strong> U.S. Grain Trade Market Share<br />

100%<br />

90%<br />

80%<br />

70%<br />

60%<br />

50%<br />

40%<br />

30%<br />

20%<br />

U.S. Grain Export Market Share: Major competi<strong>to</strong>rs include<br />

Argentina & Brazil (Soybeans, Corn) and Europe & Canada<br />

(Wheat)<br />

1970<br />

1972<br />

1974<br />

1976<br />

1978<br />

1980<br />

1982<br />

1984<br />

1986<br />

1988<br />

1990<br />

1992<br />

1994<br />

1996<br />

1998<br />

2000<br />

<strong>2002</strong>E<br />

2004E<br />

2006E<br />

2008E<br />

2010E<br />

2012E<br />

2014E<br />

U.S. Export Share <strong>of</strong> Corn+Wheat+Soybeans By Weight<br />

U.S. Corn Share By Weight<br />

U.S. Soybean Share By Weight<br />

U.S. Wheat Share By Weight<br />

Source: USDA, Legg Mason estimates <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong><br />

LM Ests.<br />

China holds long-term promise<br />

as an importer <strong>of</strong> U.S.<br />

foodstuffs, in our view.<br />

China's GDP grew by an amazing<br />

340% in the 1990s. According<br />

<strong>to</strong> the Scowcr<strong>of</strong>t Group, 490<br />

million Chinese are poised <strong>to</strong><br />

achieve true "middle class"<br />

status or better by 2010, implying<br />

dietary enrichment and urban<br />

migration. We are careful,<br />

however, not <strong>to</strong> set great expectations<br />

for U.S. agricultural exports<br />

<strong>to</strong> the Chinese market,<br />

largely because China has<br />

shown such great ingenuity in<br />

supplying its own food needs<br />

internally. But our view is that<br />

three facts will weigh on<br />

China’s food self-sufficiency in<br />

the long term: (1) China's ratio<br />

<strong>of</strong> arable acreage <strong>to</strong> population<br />

is one <strong>of</strong> the lowest among fastgrowing<br />

countries in the developing world, (2) China’s per capita GDP growth is among the highest in the developing<br />

world, and (3) China is not endowed with the hydrocarbon resources that will enable low-cost production<br />

<strong>of</strong> food if we are correct about the upward trend in fuel and fertilizer input costs. Water scarcity may<br />

also be a fac<strong>to</strong>r affecting grain production in the Asia Pacific region, as rapid urbanization and related demands<br />

for water compete with agriculture. Contradicting reports that exaggerate the problem in Asia, however,<br />

USDA states that farming accounts for 64% <strong>of</strong> Asia Pacific water use versus 79% globally.<br />

In the near term, we believe that China has no intention <strong>of</strong> disclosing its food import needs, or destabilizing<br />

its agricultural sec<strong>to</strong>r. Not unlike most countries with a long his<strong>to</strong>ry and a record <strong>of</strong> success, we see<br />

China as forthright when it is in a position <strong>of</strong> strength, passive when it is weakened, and cunning as it begins<br />

ascendancy, and we believe China is currently in a period <strong>of</strong> ascendancy. We further believe China’s task <strong>to</strong>day<br />

is <strong>to</strong> encourage reform and commercialization, while s<strong>of</strong>tening the blow <strong>of</strong> competition for the agricultural<br />

and state-owned enterprise (SOE) sec<strong>to</strong>rs. For example, according <strong>to</strong> China's agriculture ministry, the<br />

country's 800 million agricultural residents earned an average 2,300 yuan ($278) per capita last year, and a<br />

majority had never even heard <strong>of</strong> the WTO. In addition, about 78 million rural workers, mostly from agricultural<br />

backgrounds, migrated <strong>to</strong> the cities <strong>to</strong> find work last year. Chinese Minister <strong>of</strong> Agriculture Du Quinglin<br />

has stated that China will "try every means WTO allows" <strong>to</strong> protect the post-WTO Chinese agricultural sec<strong>to</strong>r<br />

from upheaval. Nevertheless, the new tariff-rate quota system resulting from WTO accession slowly scales<br />

back the power <strong>of</strong> the State Trading Enterprises, leading <strong>to</strong> more private import company control over im-


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -56- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

ports, where demand is believed <strong>to</strong> be<br />

greater and less subject <strong>to</strong> political<br />

considerations.<br />

Despite the competitive pressure,<br />

we believe Chinese agriculture<br />

should not be underestimated. Chinese<br />

production <strong>of</strong> corn, wheat and<br />

rice grew from about 100 MMT in the<br />

early 1960s, just before a disastrous<br />

famine, <strong>to</strong> 200 MMT in the late 1970s,<br />

as labor and land were applied <strong>to</strong> the<br />

shortage problem. Since China introduced<br />

certain agricultural market reforms<br />

in 1978, followed by an additional<br />

round in the mid-1990s termed<br />

the "Governor's Grain Bag" policy,<br />

<strong>to</strong>tal agricultural staples production<br />

rose <strong>to</strong> about 390 MMT in the late<br />

1990s, an increase <strong>of</strong> 90% in two decades.<br />

China set its tariff rate quotas<br />

(TRQs) high enough for corn and<br />

wheat that they are unlikely <strong>to</strong> be a<br />

problem for exporters <strong>to</strong> China in<br />

FY02, and notably absent is a TRQ<br />

for soybeans, <strong>of</strong> which China has<br />

been a prodigious importer. In fact,<br />

Chinese imports <strong>of</strong> soybeans represent<br />

about 20% <strong>of</strong> the global oilseed<br />

trade, and China imported approximately<br />

14 MMT <strong>of</strong> soybeans last<br />

year. China has maintained a liberal<br />

import policy with respect <strong>to</strong> soybean<br />

imports <strong>to</strong> feed its growing domestic<br />

needs, so we are not alarmed by the<br />

genetically modified organism (GMO)<br />

talk, which may simply be posturing<br />

<strong>to</strong> protect other segments <strong>of</strong> the Chinese<br />

farming sec<strong>to</strong>r.<br />

Exhibit 45 – Key Drivers In Meat Product Trade<br />

U.S. Meat Consumed Per Capita<br />

25,000<br />

20,000<br />

15,000<br />

10,000<br />

200 lbs.<br />

180 lbs.<br />

160 lbs.<br />

140 lbs.<br />

120 lbs.<br />

100 lbs.<br />

Meat Consumption Is Income-Dependent<br />

1935<br />

80 lbs.<br />

$5,000 $10,000 $15,000 $20,000 $25,000 $30,000 $35,000<br />

Real GDP Per Capita ($96, Uses GNP pre-1947)<br />

Meat remains one <strong>of</strong> the most exciting<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ries in agricultural trade. In 0<br />

Exhibit 45 we show that meat consumption<br />

is income-driven, the world<br />

U.S. Meat Exports, 000s Tons (Left)<br />

meat market is growing, and we believe<br />

U.S. market share should benefit Source: USDA, Legg Mason estimates <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong><br />

5,000<br />

0<br />

12,000<br />

10,000<br />

8,000<br />

6,000<br />

4,000<br />

2,000<br />

1980<br />

1980<br />

1982<br />

1984<br />

1986<br />

1988<br />

1990<br />

1971<br />

1992<br />

2001<br />

As previous commodity charts have shown, the peak<br />

rate <strong>of</strong> consumption growth in the U.S. occurred at<br />

roughly the same time, from the mid-1930s <strong>to</strong> the early<br />

1970s, or from about $7,500 <strong>of</strong> per capita real GDP <strong>to</strong><br />

about $17,500 per capita. This may have implications<br />

overseas, in our view.<br />

<strong>The</strong> World Meat Trade (000s <strong>of</strong> Tonnes) Is Strong<br />

LM Estimates<br />

Dietary enrichment has boosted the<br />

2001 <strong>to</strong><br />

migration from grain <strong>to</strong> poultry. Typically, the<br />

<strong>2015</strong> =<br />

next step is <strong>to</strong> pork, then beef.<br />

5.3%<br />

CAGR<br />

1983<br />

1980 <strong>to</strong><br />

2001 =<br />

5.8%<br />

CAGR<br />

U.S. Meat<br />

Exports<br />

1980-01<br />

= 10.3%/yr.<br />

1986<br />

1994<br />

1996<br />

1998<br />

2000<br />

<strong>2002</strong>E<br />

Beef Pork Poultry<br />

2004E<br />

We See U.S. Meat Exports Rising<br />

1989<br />

1992<br />

1995<br />

1998<br />

2001<br />

2004E<br />

2006E<br />

2008E<br />

LM<br />

Estimates<br />

2007E<br />

2010E<br />

Poultry<br />

2010E<br />

Beef<br />

2013E<br />

Pork<br />

2012E<br />

U.S. Meat Exports 2001<br />

<strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E<br />

= 5.9%/yr.<br />

U.S. Meat Market Share % (Right)<br />

2014E<br />

60%<br />

50%<br />

40%<br />

30%<br />

20%<br />

10%<br />

0%


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -57- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

now that competi<strong>to</strong>rs’ currency-related advantages in market share have begun <strong>to</strong> run their course. Agricultural<br />

analyst Bill Hudson has stated that in 1900 only 5% <strong>of</strong> the world could afford fresh meat every day, by<br />

1950 the number was 20%, and <strong>to</strong>day it is about 35%. We believe that the worldwide meat intensity <strong>of</strong> use<br />

penetration rate should rise <strong>to</strong> approximately 60% <strong>to</strong> 70% by 2050, almost doubling from the current level,<br />

with global population growth added <strong>to</strong> that figure. High-value products, which include meats, are approximately<br />

two-thirds <strong>of</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal U.S. agricultural exports, and have been the lifting force for U.S. farm exports for<br />

the last two years. High-value products added $2.1 billion more than the prior year <strong>to</strong> U.S. agricultural exports<br />

<strong>of</strong> $53 billion this year, versus a $77 million decline in bulk grain exports. Currently, exports account<br />

for 10% <strong>of</strong> U.S. beef production, 7% <strong>of</strong> pork and 17% <strong>of</strong> poultry. In the 1990s alone, the grain and oilseed<br />

equivalent <strong>of</strong> U.S. meat and poultry exports has increased by about 400 million bushels, since one unit <strong>of</strong><br />

additional meat trade is equal <strong>to</strong> approximately 3.6 units <strong>of</strong> grain as feed (although poultry is less grainintensive<br />

than beef or pork).<br />

Meat stimulates feed grain consumption, but at a decreasing rate. Greater meat production efficiencies<br />

and the popularity <strong>of</strong> the less grain-intensive poultry industry have had a moderating effect on feed-grain<br />

demand, and from 1964 <strong>to</strong> 1999, the global production <strong>of</strong> meat and poultry rose by 450%, with only a 110%<br />

feed grain consumption increase. Of course, the increased share <strong>of</strong> poultry in the meat diet was a fac<strong>to</strong>r. In<br />

fact, poultry has been the star attraction <strong>of</strong> U.S. agricultural exports, with U.S. poultry export growth <strong>of</strong><br />

10.6% from 1980 <strong>to</strong> 2001, and 2001 exports <strong>of</strong> 6.2 billion pounds, or about 20% <strong>of</strong> U.S. production, with<br />

over one-half <strong>of</strong> that volume going <strong>to</strong> China and the FSU. We look for U.S. poultry exports <strong>to</strong> grow at a rate<br />

<strong>of</strong> 6.8% per year from 2001 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>, perhaps assisted by a weaker U.S. dollar that allows for greater export<br />

cost advantage. In recent years, U.S. <strong>to</strong>tal meat exports have been hurt by animal disease concerns the world<br />

over, and economic recessions, and the USDA expects <strong>to</strong>tal U.S. meat exports <strong>to</strong> increase only 0.5% in the<br />

current fiscal year. <strong>The</strong>re are short-term impediments on the supply side. For example, if the liquidation<br />

phase <strong>of</strong> the cattle cycle were <strong>to</strong> come <strong>to</strong> a close this year, it is possible that animals bred in 2003 would not<br />

be ready for beef production until 2005, possibly restraining beef exports in the intervening period, and<br />

leading <strong>to</strong> substitution.<br />

Still, the long-term export picture is exciting if developing countries continue <strong>to</strong> embrace meat in<br />

their diets. From 1997 <strong>to</strong> 2001, Chinese beef imports rose 50% <strong>to</strong> 90,000 metric <strong>to</strong>nnes, pork imports rose<br />

206% <strong>to</strong> 450,000 metric <strong>to</strong>nnes, and poultry imports rose 31% <strong>to</strong> 1.9 MMT. Using 1995 data, if we index<br />

the U.S. <strong>to</strong> equal 1.00 and examine <strong>to</strong>tal annual meat plus fish consumption in various countries, the Japanese<br />

consume 0.81x the U.S. level, South Korea 0.74x, and China only 0.23x. Fish is less <strong>of</strong> a fac<strong>to</strong>r in the<br />

U.S. and, <strong>to</strong> the surprise <strong>of</strong> many, China. China's increasing preference for meat shows up in the substitution<br />

numbers as well. From 1990 <strong>to</strong> 2000, Chinese consumption <strong>of</strong> food grains (rice and wheat) declined<br />

13%, while China's population expanded 11%. A lack <strong>of</strong> cold s<strong>to</strong>rage and transportation infrastructure in<br />

China may restrain growth in the import <strong>of</strong> meats, but given that China has abundant labor and restrictive<br />

land and water resources, we are optimistic that China's competitive advantage will gravitate <strong>to</strong>ward laborintensive<br />

crops such as fruits, vegetables, and specialty crops rather than field crops and certain meats.<br />

U.S. Agricultural Exports and Deere S<strong>to</strong>ck<br />

<strong>The</strong> implications <strong>of</strong> greater farm industry prosperity are favorable for machinery sales, and thus<br />

Deere & Company. North American industry farm machinery inven<strong>to</strong>ries as a percentage <strong>of</strong> forward-12-<br />

month sales for 100+ horsepower, two-wheel drive (row crop) trac<strong>to</strong>rs are currently 29%, which is well be-


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -58- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

low the 10-year average <strong>of</strong> 48%,<br />

and combine harvester inven<strong>to</strong>ries<br />

are 17% versus a 38% 10-<br />

year average. In Exhibit 46, we<br />

show the sharp recoveries in row<br />

crop trac<strong>to</strong>r sales in the 1987 <strong>to</strong><br />

1988 and 1992 <strong>to</strong> 1994 periods<br />

coincided with sharp periods <strong>of</strong><br />

outperformance for DE s<strong>to</strong>ck<br />

versus the S&P 500. <strong>The</strong> row<br />

crop trac<strong>to</strong>r sales recovery in<br />

this cycle has been more mild<br />

than in those prior cycles, we<br />

believe, because <strong>of</strong> the reduced<br />

incidences <strong>of</strong> steep discounting<br />

and lower dealer inven<strong>to</strong>ries,<br />

which have reduced the "fire<br />

sale" mentality. A recovery in<br />

the fortunes <strong>of</strong> farmers would be<br />

a bullish event for Deere s<strong>to</strong>ck,<br />

in our view. We believe that the<br />

key <strong>to</strong> more trac<strong>to</strong>r sales over<br />

the long term may be acreage,<br />

and in Exhibit 47 we show that<br />

acreage and farm commodity<br />

prices are related.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Global Competitiveness<br />

<strong>of</strong> the U.S. Farm Economy<br />

Exhibit 46 – Deere S<strong>to</strong>ck Follows Trac<strong>to</strong>r Sales Trends<br />

35,000<br />

30,000<br />

25,000<br />

20,000<br />

15,000<br />

10,000<br />

5,000<br />

Jan-85<br />

Deere S<strong>to</strong>ck Relative <strong>to</strong> the S&P 500 Tracks Trac<strong>to</strong>r Sales<br />

Jan-86<br />

Jan-87<br />

Jan-88<br />

Jan-89<br />

Jan-90<br />

Source: Equipment Manufacturers Institute<br />

Exhibit 47 – U.S. Farm Acres and Farm Commodity Pricing<br />

It has been two decades since<br />

all was rosy on the U.S. farm,<br />

so the sec<strong>to</strong>r can be forgiven a<br />

pessimistic mindset. As we<br />

have stated, in the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong><br />

period, we foresee higher exports<br />

<strong>of</strong> U.S. agricultural product,<br />

265,000<br />

245,000<br />

225,000<br />

-5%<br />

-10%<br />

-15%<br />

a weaker U.S. dollar versus<br />

the primary competi<strong>to</strong>r nations<br />

U.S. Acreage Harvested, Thousands <strong>of</strong> Acres, (Left)<br />

PPI Agri-Products, Y/Y % Chng., 5-Yr. Moving Avg., (Right)<br />

in the world food trade, and<br />

Source: Equipment Manufacturers Institute, S&P CompuStat<br />

higher hydrocarbon prices that<br />

raise agricultural inputs (<strong>of</strong>ten globally) and lead <strong>to</strong> food commodity inflation. In Exhibit 48, we show that<br />

real food exports help drive prices, and in Exhibit 49, we show that currency facilitates food exports. Hardship<br />

related <strong>to</strong> both supply and demand fac<strong>to</strong>rs caused U.S. government direct payments <strong>to</strong> farmers <strong>to</strong> average<br />

$21.5 billion per year each <strong>of</strong> the past three years, resulting in stable net cash income averaging $58 billion<br />

in the same period. In addition <strong>to</strong> income statement stability, we believe that the U.S. farm balance<br />

Jan-91<br />

Jan-92<br />

Jan-93<br />

Jan-94<br />

Jan-95<br />

12-mo. trailing sum, N.A. 100+ hp. trac<strong>to</strong>r sales (Left)<br />

365,000<br />

345,000<br />

325,000<br />

305,000<br />

285,000<br />

1945<br />

1950<br />

Machinery<br />

discounting<br />

boosted<br />

demand in the<br />

past.<br />

1955<br />

1960<br />

Discounting<br />

is more mild<br />

with reduced<br />

capacity.<br />

Jan-96<br />

Jan-97<br />

Jan-98<br />

Pricing Helps Drive Acreage<br />

1965<br />

1970<br />

1975<br />

1980<br />

1985<br />

1990<br />

Jan-99<br />

Jan-00<br />

Jan-01<br />

Jan-02<br />

L<br />

M<br />

e<br />

s<br />

t<br />

s.<br />

8.00%<br />

7.00%<br />

6.00%<br />

5.00%<br />

4.00%<br />

3.00%<br />

2.00%<br />

1.00%<br />

Deere s<strong>to</strong>ck rel. <strong>to</strong> S&P 500 (Right)<br />

1995<br />

2000<br />

2005E<br />

LM<br />

Ests.<br />

2010E<br />

<strong>2015</strong>E<br />

15%<br />

10%<br />

5%<br />

0%


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -59- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

sheet is well positioned for a resumption<br />

<strong>of</strong> growth and machinery<br />

purchases. Again, it was not<br />

always so. Leverage has <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

proved <strong>to</strong> be the enemy <strong>of</strong> farming,<br />

and we note that the farm<br />

debt-<strong>to</strong>-asset ratio peaked in<br />

1985 at 23%, but it is only<br />

15.6% currently. In the 1970s,<br />

farmland asset values inflated,<br />

and borrowing was based more<br />

on asset collateral than on sustainable<br />

cash flow. <strong>The</strong> natural<br />

result was the agricultural bust<br />

<strong>of</strong> the 1980s, and the sec<strong>to</strong>r has<br />

been careful not <strong>to</strong> repeat past<br />

mistakes.<br />

Exhibit 48 – Food Exports Help Drive Food <strong>Price</strong>s<br />

$1,000,000<br />

$100,000<br />

$10,000<br />

$1,000<br />

1895<br />

1905<br />

1915<br />

1925<br />

1935<br />

1945<br />

1955<br />

1965<br />

1975<br />

1985<br />

1995<br />

LM<br />

Ests.<br />

2005E<br />

U.S. Agri-Exports in Real (Yr. 2000) U.S.$ Mil., (Left, Log)<br />

PPI Agricultural Products (Year 2000 = 100), (Right, Log)<br />

<strong>2015</strong>E<br />

1,000<br />

100<br />

10<br />

1<br />

Land is the farmer's largest<br />

asset, and it has steadily appreciated<br />

during this agricultural<br />

recession, which should<br />

benefit the sentiment that supports<br />

the purchase <strong>of</strong> farm<br />

machinery <strong>of</strong> the sort manufactured<br />

by Deere. Real estate accounts<br />

for 79% <strong>of</strong> farm assets<br />

but only 53% <strong>of</strong> farm debt, and<br />

farmland values rose about 61%<br />

in Iowa in the past decade, with<br />

about 3% increases for farms<br />

nationwide in each <strong>of</strong> the past<br />

three years. Reasons for the<br />

strength in farmland values are<br />

many, but we note that 62% <strong>of</strong><br />

program cropland in the U.S. is<br />

owned by non-operating landlords,<br />

and those owners have had<br />

<strong>to</strong> bid in the thin market for<br />

Source: USDA, Legg Mason estimates <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong><br />

Exhibit 49 – Currency Moves Inversely <strong>to</strong> Food Exports<br />

130<br />

125<br />

120<br />

115<br />

110<br />

105<br />

100<br />

95<br />

90<br />

85<br />

80<br />

1970<br />

Source: USDA<br />

1975<br />

farmland <strong>to</strong> settle like-kind exchanges and postpone capital gains taxation. <strong>The</strong>se exchanges occur when<br />

farmland is sold <strong>to</strong> other farmers seeking economies <strong>of</strong> scale, or <strong>to</strong> developers who convert the farmland <strong>to</strong><br />

alternative uses, or even <strong>to</strong> nature conservancy funds that leave the land fallow.<br />

Oversupply caused largely by ideal growing weather has overshadowed improving demand trends.<br />

Corn yields in the U.S., measured in bushels per acre, have been at or above trend for six consecutive years,<br />

1996 <strong>to</strong> 2001. In fact, those six years were the first time since the years 1902 <strong>to</strong> 1908 that corn yields have<br />

1980<br />

1985<br />

1990<br />

1995<br />

2000<br />

$75,000<br />

$70,000<br />

$65,000<br />

$60,000<br />

$55,000<br />

$50,000<br />

$45,000<br />

$40,000<br />

$35,000<br />

$30,000<br />

$25,000<br />

Real U.S. Agricultural Trade-Weighted Dollar, 1995 = 100, (Left)<br />

Real U.S. Agricultural Exports, $U.S. Million, (Right)


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -60- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

been at or above trend six consecutive<br />

years. In Exhibit 50, we<br />

show that it is highly unusual for<br />

U.S. corn yields not <strong>to</strong> be adversely<br />

weather-affected. If <strong>2002</strong><br />

corn yields fell 10% from the<br />

trend (i.e., <strong>to</strong> 124.2 bu./acre), we<br />

estimate about 62% <strong>of</strong> U.S. corn<br />

s<strong>to</strong>cks (inven<strong>to</strong>ry in s<strong>to</strong>rage)<br />

would be eliminated <strong>to</strong> make up<br />

the shortfall, and, <strong>of</strong> course, corn<br />

prices would likely rise in that<br />

environment. Despite the nearterm<br />

worries about oversupply,<br />

however, the USDA states that in<br />

the 2001 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2002</strong> crop year, the<br />

s<strong>to</strong>cks-<strong>to</strong>-use (inven<strong>to</strong>ry-<strong>to</strong>-sales)<br />

ratio for corn is 15.7%, below<br />

the five-year average s<strong>to</strong>cks-<strong>to</strong>use<br />

<strong>of</strong> 17.5%. For the <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong><br />

2003 crop year, ProExporter estimates<br />

the corn, wheat and soybean<br />

combined s<strong>to</strong>cks-<strong>to</strong>-use <strong>to</strong><br />

be down further, <strong>to</strong> 16.9%. On<br />

the world stage, U.S. yields relative<br />

<strong>to</strong> those <strong>of</strong> export competi<strong>to</strong>rs<br />

are increasing strongly for<br />

feedgrains and modestly for oilseeds,<br />

but wheat yields in the U.<br />

S. are in a relative downtrend.<br />

Also on the subject <strong>of</strong> yields, if<br />

we are correct and hydrocarbon<br />

prices rise in the coming years,<br />

the reduced application <strong>of</strong> nitrogen<br />

fertilizer would probably<br />

reduce yield growth, as shown in<br />

Exhibit 51.<br />

Exhibit 50 – U.S. Corn Yields, +/(-) 10% From Trend<br />

Bushels Per Acre<br />

Source: USDA<br />

Exhibit 51 – U.S. Corn Yields and Fertilizer Usage<br />

1000<br />

Fertilizer Use Affects Yields<br />

100<br />

10<br />

165<br />

155<br />

145<br />

135<br />

125<br />

115<br />

105<br />

95<br />

85<br />

75<br />

65<br />

55<br />

1900<br />

Higher natural gas prices from<br />

<strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> may impact grain<br />

yields by inhibiting fertilizer use.<br />

1910<br />

U.S. Average Corn Yield in Bushels Per Acre<br />

Volatile, weather-driven corn yields are the norm. <strong>The</strong> recent string<br />

<strong>of</strong> excellent yields is highly unusual. A 10% yield decline in <strong>2002</strong> (<strong>to</strong><br />

124.2 bu./acre) would reduce U.S. corn inven<strong>to</strong>ry by 62% <strong>to</strong> 600 mil.<br />

bu., all else being equal.<br />

1962<br />

1964<br />

1966<br />

1968<br />

1970<br />

1972<br />

1974<br />

1976<br />

1978<br />

1980<br />

1982<br />

1984<br />

1986<br />

1988<br />

1990<br />

1992<br />

1994<br />

1996<br />

1998<br />

2000<br />

Corn Yield bu./acre Corn Trend Plus 10%<br />

Corn Yield Minus 10%<br />

Corn Yield 10-yr. Centered Average<br />

1920<br />

By far, we believe that the<br />

Source: USDA<br />

greatest competitive threats <strong>to</strong><br />

the U.S. farmer are in South America, although we note that Deere and other farm equipment makers<br />

have incorporated that region in<strong>to</strong> their acquisition and marketing strategy for many years. Brazil's strength<br />

is soybeans, and the country exported almost 75% <strong>of</strong> its year 2000 soybean production in raw beans or finished<br />

products, equivalent <strong>to</strong> about 1 billion bushels. We doubt that Brazil will emerge as a major corn exporter<br />

because <strong>of</strong> the absence <strong>of</strong> suitable tropical corn varieties, and the rapid growth <strong>of</strong> Brazil's poultry industry<br />

which consumes domestic feed corn. Despite Argentina's complementary strengths in soybeans, soy-<br />

1930<br />

1940<br />

1950<br />

1960<br />

1970<br />

U.S. Fertilizer Applied, Lbs./Acre, (Left, Log)<br />

1980<br />

U.S. Corn Yields, Bushels/Acre, (Right, Log)<br />

1990<br />

2000<br />

1000<br />

100<br />

10


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -61- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

bean meal and soybean oil, and though Argentina also has emerged as export competi<strong>to</strong>r in corn, we believe<br />

that Argentina's economic difficulties will give a moderate lift <strong>to</strong> U.S. corn export market share in the coming<br />

years. Total shipments <strong>of</strong> soybeans and soybean products from Brazil and Argentina eclipsed the U.S.<br />

around 1996, and the gap has continued <strong>to</strong> widen. In addition <strong>to</strong> soybean products, Brazil has about 107 million<br />

acres under cultivation, versus 226 million in the U.S. But by adding the vast "Cerrados" region's potential<br />

acreage, Brazil eventually could reach 353 million planted acres. Brazil's corn yields in 2000 were<br />

about one-third those <strong>of</strong> the U.S., and soybean yields are comparable <strong>to</strong> those in the U.S. heartland.<br />

Our view is that South America has used the devaluation bullet, and now it must stand on its own. It<br />

was an unfortunate act <strong>of</strong> timing (for them) that Argentina tied the peso, and Brazil tied the real, <strong>to</strong> the U.S.<br />

dollar in the mid-1990s, since both suffered through a multiyear bull market for the U.S. currency. Now that<br />

both Brazil (1999) and Argentina (2001) have removed their dollar pegs, their farm product exports have<br />

become more competitive, although the financial and infrastructure inefficiencies in both countries still<br />

exist, in our view. To be sure, however, Brazil has made great strides in stabilizing its economy, improving<br />

farmer access <strong>to</strong> credit, enhancing the country's grain logistics network, globalizing its farm input sources<br />

and technology, and streamlining its taxation and export policies. But Argentina is mired in debt, and<br />

paying devalued pesos for dollar-denominated imports <strong>of</strong> farm inputs is not a recipe for agricultural<br />

success, in our view. As an <strong>of</strong>fset, Argentina's farmers have increasingly turned <strong>to</strong> barter systems <strong>to</strong><br />

purchase needed inputs such as seed, fertilizer and chemicals.<br />

South America is not immune from a reversal <strong>of</strong> agricultural fortunes, in our view. <strong>The</strong> Cerrados land<br />

in Brazil requires heavy doses <strong>of</strong> lime and phosphorus <strong>to</strong> reduce aluminum <strong>to</strong>xicity and acidity, so our view<br />

is that the Cerrados’ lands will be brought in<strong>to</strong> production slowly, and only in response <strong>to</strong> strong world demand<br />

for soybeans. In addition, some <strong>of</strong> the Cerrados’ soil is fragile, being subject <strong>to</strong> significant erosion in<br />

the frequent, tropical rains. Although Brazil does not suffer a major weed problem, the country's farmers<br />

have largely made the switch <strong>to</strong> no-till (i.e., avoids the use <strong>of</strong> plows <strong>to</strong> till the land after harvest) <strong>to</strong> avoid<br />

erosion, and weeds <strong>of</strong>ten follow no-till with a lag. In fact, our view is that this eventually may lead Brazil <strong>to</strong><br />

abandon its "GMO-free" policy, which is <strong>of</strong>ficial in name only, in our view, since there are widespread reports<br />

<strong>of</strong> Brazilian farmers already using “Roundup Ready ® ” soybeans. Combined with the pressing need <strong>to</strong><br />

continue increasing crop yields, we see Brazil's GMO-free soybean export price premium eroding over time.<br />

Currency is only part <strong>of</strong> the issue, as cost differentials <strong>of</strong>ten go much deeper in world food production<br />

and competition. Equalizing North and South America for differences in land cost, an Agroconsult<br />

study provides data that Midwestern U.S. farmers’ variable costs per bushel <strong>of</strong> soybeans produced are about<br />

15% below those in Brazil and Argentina, and for corn the U.S. advantage is about 45% <strong>to</strong> 50% below Brazil<br />

and Argentina. Where the South Americans have an advantage is <strong>to</strong>tal capitalized costs including land,<br />

as that causes U.S. <strong>to</strong>tal costs <strong>to</strong> be 63% higher for soybeans and 5% higher for corn. A recent Iowa State<br />

University study put Brazil's all-in soybean production costs at port <strong>of</strong> exit at $4.60 per bushel, and for the<br />

U.S. the figure is $6.38 per bushel. What is interesting is that if we exclude the capitalized cost <strong>of</strong> land, then<br />

the U.S. cost is only $3.58 per bushel and for Brazilian it is $4.09. Since U.S. farmland <strong>of</strong>ten has no other<br />

use but farming, we believe its value is <strong>of</strong>ten situation-dependent on farming. As a result, we view non-land<br />

costs as a better measure <strong>of</strong> relative costs. Also on the subject <strong>of</strong> other costs, the Agroconsult study shows<br />

that Brazil's grain production has risen at a compound rate <strong>of</strong> 5.5% per year in the past decade, but its fertilizer<br />

consumption has risen at an annual rate <strong>of</strong> 6%, and usage <strong>of</strong> ag-chemicals has risen at 8% per year. If<br />

input costs rise, we would expect Brazil’s all-in cost advantage <strong>to</strong> shrink, all else being equal.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -62- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

We see the EU slowly fading as an export competi<strong>to</strong>r, but not overnight or without a fight. <strong>The</strong> devaluation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the European euro and the EU export <strong>of</strong> subsidized agricultural overproduction have been competitive<br />

issues for U.S. farmers in the past. Also, the EU has quietly built a network <strong>of</strong> preferential trade<br />

agreements with all but 10 countries in the world, and many <strong>of</strong> these agreements have bilateral trade terms<br />

that lock in food markets. Unfortunately for Deere and its cus<strong>to</strong>mers, the U.S. has typically had a less organized<br />

public/private cooperative effort <strong>to</strong> facilitate exports. <strong>The</strong> EU is not without export competition<br />

worries, however, because it faces its own "Brazil-like" competi<strong>to</strong>rs for regional export market share in the<br />

form <strong>of</strong> the rapidly recovering FSU grain sec<strong>to</strong>r, and the enlargement <strong>of</strong> the EU Common Agricultural Policy<br />

(CAP) <strong>to</strong> include central and eastern European candidates. <strong>The</strong> EU proposes a phased-in subsidy for its<br />

Eastern European neighbors, whereby the new members <strong>of</strong> the CAP would receive only 25% <strong>of</strong> the Western<br />

subsidy level in 2004, rising <strong>to</strong> 100% by 2013. From 2004 <strong>to</strong> 2006, the subsidies would cost the CAP $36<br />

billion in <strong>to</strong>tal, a heady sum for the EU budget. <strong>The</strong> combination <strong>of</strong> low-cost competi<strong>to</strong>rs in the back yard<br />

<strong>of</strong> a higher-cost producer, and the liability <strong>of</strong> bringing some emerging market competi<strong>to</strong>rs with large farm<br />

populations in<strong>to</strong> a generous subsidy scheme, is not favorable for Western EU agricultural production in the<br />

long term, in our opinion.<br />

Though we like DE s<strong>to</strong>ck for<br />

macro-reasons, the valuation<br />

should give pause. Currently,<br />

DE s<strong>to</strong>ck trades at a P/E <strong>of</strong> 19.7x<br />

the First Call consensus for<br />

FY03, and earnings “power”<br />

given the mix <strong>of</strong> businesses is<br />

less than clear, in our view. In<br />

addition, using a less orthodox<br />

scale that we sometimes use, DE<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ck appears <strong>to</strong> be ahead <strong>of</strong> itself<br />

relative <strong>to</strong> corn prices,<br />

shown in Exhibit 52. As a result,<br />

we are keeping some powder<br />

dry, deferring a Strong Buy rating<br />

until we see some sign that<br />

the DE s<strong>to</strong>ck price and the company’s<br />

EPS potential have<br />

moved closer <strong>to</strong>gether, or that<br />

industry conditions (including<br />

the outlook for corn prices) are<br />

markedly higher in the near<br />

term, all else being equal.<br />

Exhibit 52 – Deere S<strong>to</strong>ck and Corn <strong>Price</strong>s<br />

$50.000<br />

$48.000<br />

$46.000<br />

$44.000<br />

$42.000<br />

$40.000<br />

$38.000<br />

$36.000<br />

$34.000<br />

$32.000<br />

$30.000<br />

3/1/00<br />

Deere S<strong>to</strong>ck Vs. Corn <strong>Price</strong>s March 2000 <strong>to</strong> March <strong>2002</strong><br />

6/1/00<br />

Source: S&P Compustat<br />

9/1/00<br />

12/1/00<br />

Deere S<strong>to</strong>ck <strong>Price</strong> (Left)<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is a relationship between<br />

Deere s<strong>to</strong>ck and corn prices,<br />

although a divergence has developed<br />

in <strong>2002</strong>.<br />

3/1/01<br />

6/1/01<br />

9/1/01<br />

12/1/01<br />

Corn Near Futures <strong>Price</strong> Per Bushel (Right)<br />

3/1/02<br />

$2.50<br />

$2.40<br />

$2.30<br />

$2.20<br />

$2.10<br />

$2.00<br />

$1.90<br />

$1.80<br />

$1.70


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -63- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Scenario (3) Middle East War(s) in the Period <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> That<br />

Result in Extended Oil Supply Disruptions: Probability: 25%<br />

Analyzing the potential for major war is key <strong>to</strong> determining the outlook for inflation, as well as the<br />

allocation <strong>of</strong> public versus private resources, both <strong>of</strong> which affect s<strong>to</strong>ck market returns. Earlier in this<br />

report we showed that 26% <strong>of</strong> the 20th century featured major (lengthy and global) periods <strong>of</strong> hot or economic<br />

warfare that involved the U.S. Those periods produced mean annual inflation <strong>of</strong> 10.7% for commodities,<br />

9.0% for consumer prices, and 2.6% annual (minus 6.4% real) U.S. s<strong>to</strong>ck market price returns. We believe<br />

that the “peace dividend” <strong>of</strong> the 1990s was the end <strong>of</strong> the Soviet Union that reduced U.S. defense<br />

spending as a percentage <strong>of</strong> GDP, combined with the post-Gulf War implicit agreement with Saudi Arabia<br />

that America would provide a defense umbrella in exchange for Saudi Arabia, as OPEC “swing producer,”<br />

enforcing reasonable world oil prices. Both peace dividends appear <strong>to</strong> be spent, in our view, and since we<br />

believe the Middle East is the most unstable region in the world <strong>to</strong>day, this section describes the Persian<br />

Gulf war risk under various scenarios. Our opinion is that as inves<strong>to</strong>rs we must be keen, disciplined and impartial<br />

observers, and our investment view is that the “New World Order” created after the Gulf War and<br />

the fall <strong>of</strong> the Soviet Union is crumbling. If the transition <strong>to</strong> the next world order goes badly, then we<br />

note that major wars in U.S. his<strong>to</strong>ry have, without exception, been inflationary.<br />

A key risk we see is that the economic pressure on the oil producers resulting from renewed oil price<br />

deflation could light the powder keg in the Middle East and lead <strong>to</strong> inflation via major war. Earlier in<br />

this report we described our view that the voracious appetite we expect for oil from Asia/Pacific net oil importers<br />

can only be met by expanded production from the Persian Gulf. Competing with Asia, however, are<br />

the U.S. and other developed and developing countries. Even without disruption in Middle East oil flow,<br />

our view is also that U.S. oil import demands are likely <strong>to</strong> collide with sharply rising Asia/Pacific demands<br />

in the coming decade, leading <strong>to</strong> higher prices for all, and outstripping the capability <strong>of</strong> alternative fuels and<br />

oil sources <strong>to</strong> overtake demand for several years. In Exhibit 53, we show Persian Gulf oil as a percentage <strong>of</strong><br />

U.S. oil consumption, and observe that the Persian Gulf’s share <strong>of</strong> U.S. oil consumption was 13.9% in<br />

2001, above the prior peak <strong>of</strong> 13.5% in 1977. More importantly, U.S. oil imports as a percentage <strong>of</strong> U.S.<br />

consumption were 46.5% in 2001, hovering at a post-World War II high. In our opinion, analysts who cite<br />

decreased U.S. reliance on Persian Gulf oil as a percentage <strong>of</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal oil imports conveniently overlook the<br />

fact that <strong>to</strong>tal U.S. oil imports as a percentage <strong>of</strong> consumption are sharply higher than two decades ago. Our<br />

view is that oil is like a game <strong>of</strong> musical chairs among the importers: if several chairs (producers) are removed,<br />

and given that all oil importing nations must sit down (consume oil), then the price <strong>of</strong> the remaining<br />

chairs rises substantially once the music (steady oil flow) s<strong>to</strong>ps. Past oil shocks include the 1973 <strong>to</strong> 1974<br />

Oil Embargo, the Iranian Revolution <strong>of</strong> 1979, and the period after the start <strong>of</strong> the Iran/Iraq War <strong>of</strong> 1980 <strong>to</strong><br />

1988. In Exhibit 54, we show the <strong>to</strong>tal Persian Gulf oil exports in real U.S. dollars for the period 1970 <strong>to</strong><br />

<strong>2015</strong>E. <strong>The</strong> bubble <strong>of</strong> the 1970s is evident, but the prolonged bust that followed may resume an upward direction<br />

<strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>, if our estimates are correct.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Persian Gulf war risks we see, in descending order <strong>of</strong> likelihood, are as follows.<br />

(1) U.S. military action <strong>to</strong> change the Iraqi regime which may lead <strong>to</strong> a destabilized region.<br />

(2) <strong>The</strong> risk that Iraq currently has or will soon succeed in the development <strong>of</strong> nuclear weapons.<br />

(3) <strong>The</strong> risk <strong>of</strong> civil war that targets Saudi Arabia's ruling al-Saud monarchy.<br />

(4) <strong>The</strong> risk <strong>of</strong> conventional (non-nuclear) warfare within the Persian Gulf region.<br />

(5) <strong>The</strong> risk <strong>of</strong> terrorists obtaining nuclear weapons developed in the former Soviet Union.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -64- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Exhibit 53 - Persian Gulf Oil as a Percentage <strong>of</strong> U.S. Consumption, 1970 <strong>to</strong> 2001<br />

Persian Gulf and Total Imports as a % <strong>of</strong> U.S. Oil Consumption<br />

50.0%<br />

45.0%<br />

All-time high dependence on the world oil "bucket"<br />

40.0%<br />

35.0%<br />

30.0%<br />

25.0%<br />

20.0%<br />

15.0%<br />

Back up <strong>to</strong> mid-1970s level.<br />

10.0%<br />

5.0%<br />

0.0%<br />

1950<br />

1952<br />

1954<br />

1956<br />

1958<br />

1960<br />

1962<br />

1964<br />

1966<br />

1968<br />

1970<br />

1972<br />

1974<br />

1976<br />

1978<br />

1980<br />

1982<br />

1984<br />

1986<br />

1988<br />

1990<br />

1992<br />

1994<br />

1996<br />

1998<br />

2000<br />

Persian Gulf imports % <strong>of</strong> U.S. Consumption<br />

All Imports % <strong>of</strong> U.S. Consumption<br />

Source: U.S. EIA<br />

Exhibit 54 - Persian Gulf Oil Exports in Real (Year 2000) U.S. Dollars, 1970 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>E<br />

$450<br />

$400<br />

Projection<br />

Persian Gulf Oil Exports, Real $ (2000) Bil<br />

$350<br />

$300<br />

$250<br />

$200<br />

$150<br />

$100<br />

$50<br />

$0<br />

1970<br />

1971<br />

1972<br />

1973<br />

1974<br />

1975<br />

1976<br />

1977<br />

1978<br />

1979<br />

1980<br />

1981<br />

1982<br />

1983<br />

1984<br />

1985<br />

1986<br />

1987<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

<strong>2002</strong><br />

2003<br />

2004<br />

2005<br />

2006<br />

2007<br />

2008<br />

2009<br />

2010<br />

2011<br />

2012<br />

2013<br />

2014<br />

<strong>2015</strong><br />

Saudi Arabia Iran Iraq Other Gulf<br />

Source: U.S. EIA. Legg Mason projection based on EIA’s International Energy Outlook <strong>2002</strong>


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -65- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Our approach is <strong>to</strong> watch actions rather than statements, and we believe the Bush Administration<br />

has adopted a far more pervasive wartime footing than is currently recognized by the markets. <strong>The</strong><br />

distinct shift in budget priorities and deficit spending <strong>to</strong>lerance, as well as the risk <strong>to</strong> energy commodity<br />

trade, have significant implications for inves<strong>to</strong>rs. For example, the movement <strong>of</strong> the U.S. <strong>to</strong> a “shadow government”<br />

is an unusual step. <strong>The</strong> shadow government concept originated in the Cold War, and requires a<br />

group <strong>of</strong> senior federal government <strong>of</strong>ficials <strong>to</strong> rotate in a secure, <strong>of</strong>f-site location <strong>to</strong> ensure government,<br />

and particularly executive branch, continuity in case <strong>of</strong> an attack on Washing<strong>to</strong>n, D.C. In addition, on December<br />

13, 2001, the U.S. pulled out <strong>of</strong> the Anti-Ballistic Missile treaty, and on January 8, <strong>2002</strong>, the U.S.<br />

modified its nuclear strategy, called the Single Integrated Operational Plan (SIOP), by lowering the bar for<br />

first-use <strong>of</strong> nuclear weapons and shifting the focus from Cold War thinking <strong>to</strong> an increased awareness <strong>of</strong><br />

China, Iran, Iraq, Libya, North Korea, Syria and Russia. <strong>The</strong> revised plan appears <strong>to</strong> loosen the traditional<br />

restraints the U.S. had in place with regard <strong>to</strong> its use <strong>of</strong> nuclear arms. We believe that this was not a budget<br />

ploy, or a belated update <strong>of</strong> outdated Cold War strategy, but rather a deliberate decision by the Administration<br />

that the 1970 Nuclear Nonproliferation Treaty (NNPT) has failed. We believe that the Bush Administration<br />

weighed the risk <strong>of</strong> existing and emerging nuclear threats (including the proliferation risk presented<br />

by Iraq, a NNPT signa<strong>to</strong>ry) against the risk <strong>of</strong> sending a signal <strong>to</strong> non-nuclear countries (in contravention <strong>to</strong><br />

the NNPT implicit guarantee) that simply because they are non-nuclear they are no longer protected from a<br />

nuclear response <strong>to</strong> their hostile actions. After considering all <strong>of</strong> the ramifications, we believe the Administration<br />

decided that the increased wartime footing <strong>of</strong> the U.S. justified the shift, and we interpret the shift<br />

as added risk that is underappreciated by inves<strong>to</strong>rs for the potential impact it may have.<br />

Nuclear weapons are a complex subject, but they present a risk with potential repercussions for inves<strong>to</strong>rs<br />

that must be analyzed. In the box on page 66 we provide a primer on nuclear weapons, with an<br />

emphasis on the sort that we believe the Bush Administration fears may be now or in the near future in<br />

Iraq’s possession. We believe inves<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>of</strong>ten receive incorrect information regarding the highly complex<br />

world nuclear threat, and since misinformation is the enemy <strong>of</strong> markets, we believe that it obscures the appropriate<br />

equity risk premium as well as commodity price reactions. For example, media reports have occasionally<br />

failed <strong>to</strong> differentiate between weapons-grade highly enriched uranium-235 (HEU, having >80%<br />

U-235 content) and ordinary low-enriched uranium (LEU, having 3% <strong>to</strong> 5% U-235 content) nuclear reac<strong>to</strong>r<br />

fuel. Later in this report we express our doubts about the widely reported “suitcase nuke” threat, for example,<br />

in terms <strong>of</strong> the devices’ reputed destructive capabilities, and the likelihood that terror groups could obtain<br />

or use them even if they ever existed in the Former Soviet Union or were ever misplaced.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Risk <strong>of</strong> U.S. Military Action <strong>to</strong> Change the Iraqi Regime Which May Lead<br />

<strong>to</strong> a Destabilized Region<br />

An emerging war scenario that we believe is underestimated by inves<strong>to</strong>rs involves U.S.-led efforts <strong>to</strong><br />

oust Saddam Hussein <strong>of</strong> Iraq, possibly with conventional military force. Since the expulsion <strong>of</strong> United<br />

Nations (UNSCOM) weapons inspec<strong>to</strong>rs in late 1998, the only checks on Iraq’s WMD nuclear program<br />

have come from International A<strong>to</strong>mic Energy Administration (IAEA) visits <strong>to</strong> Iraq, but we feel those inspections<br />

are <strong>to</strong>o limited <strong>to</strong> be <strong>of</strong> value, and note that other countries have developed nuclear weapons despite<br />

being subject <strong>to</strong> IAEA inspections. Former Iraqi nuclear scientists and UNSCOM inspec<strong>to</strong>rs have provided<br />

statements and evidence <strong>of</strong> a long-standing WMD nuclear program, possibly one that was revitalized<br />

after the expulsion <strong>of</strong> the inspection regimen. In addition, former UNSCOM inspec<strong>to</strong>rs have uncovered evidence<br />

that Iraq employed an elaborate scheme for hiding its WMD programs from inspec<strong>to</strong>rs. Although we


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -66- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

do not believe any <strong>of</strong> the major<br />

Persian Gulf leaders would regret<br />

the removal <strong>of</strong> Saddam Hussein,<br />

the reality <strong>of</strong> the current political<br />

situation in the Persian Gulf as it<br />

differs from the Gulf War period a<br />

decade earlier is that such a move<br />

could easily play in<strong>to</strong> the hands <strong>of</strong><br />

the radical factions that threaten<br />

moderate regimes, including Saudi<br />

Arabia. In our view, the Gulf War<br />

<strong>of</strong> 1991 was successful precisely<br />

because <strong>of</strong> the scope and size <strong>of</strong><br />

the coalition forces build-up and<br />

bombing campaign before the<br />

ground war began. <strong>The</strong> difficulty<br />

in assembling a coalition <strong>to</strong> conducting<br />

a similar size operation<br />

<strong>to</strong>day, and the risk that Iraq may<br />

have improved its nuclear counterattack<br />

capabilities, are other risks<br />

<strong>to</strong> consider. In this period <strong>of</strong> uncertainty,<br />

we hope <strong>to</strong> leave inves<strong>to</strong>rs<br />

more prepared for whatever<br />

may occur. Rather than speculate<br />

on operational details, we focus on<br />

the motivation for such a U.S.-led<br />

operation in the following section.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Risk that Iraq Has or<br />

Will Soon Succeed in the<br />

Development <strong>of</strong> Nuclear<br />

Weapons<br />

We believe that Iraq’s nuclear<br />

weapons program is the primary<br />

Middle East concern <strong>of</strong> the Bush<br />

Administration. Our research<br />

concludes that a combination <strong>of</strong><br />

four principal items have kept Iraq<br />

from successfully developing a nuclear<br />

weapon (or limited the number<br />

<strong>of</strong> such weapons if one or<br />

more exist) despite billions <strong>of</strong> dollars<br />

<strong>of</strong> expenditures and over a<br />

Iraq’s Potential Approach <strong>to</strong> Nuclear Weapons<br />

We believe that the U.S. fears development in Iraq <strong>of</strong> nuclear fissiontype<br />

weapons, which use the energy released from splitting a<strong>to</strong>ms. Fission<br />

occurs when fissile nuclear material is forcibly combined in a critical mass<br />

capable <strong>of</strong> sustaining the free release <strong>of</strong> a<strong>to</strong>mic particles called neutrons,<br />

which leads <strong>to</strong> the splitting <strong>of</strong> still more a<strong>to</strong>mic nuclei, releasing energy in a<br />

chain reaction. We believe that if Iraq is close <strong>to</strong> developing nuclear weapons,<br />

or has a few <strong>of</strong> them, they are probably larger in physical size (thus difficult<br />

<strong>to</strong> deliver), and lower-yielding (in a explosive equivalent sense, expressed<br />

as 1 kilo<strong>to</strong>n = 1,000 <strong>to</strong>ns <strong>of</strong> high explosive TNT-equivalent) fissiononly<br />

devices, possibly using a simple “gun” assembly approach that fires <strong>to</strong>gether<br />

two subcritical masses <strong>of</strong> highly enriched Uranium-235 (HEU, generally<br />

containing >80% U-235) <strong>to</strong> create a super-critical mass and a fission<br />

chain reaction. <strong>The</strong> weapon we have described is similar <strong>to</strong> “Little Boy,”<br />

which was one <strong>of</strong> two nuclear device designs developed by the U.S. in the<br />

Manhattan Project <strong>of</strong> World War II, albeit smaller in dimensions than Little<br />

Boy as a result <strong>of</strong> technological progress <strong>to</strong>-date. <strong>The</strong> other Manhattan Project<br />

nuclear weapon was called “Fat Man,” which used Plu<strong>to</strong>nium-239 (Pu-<br />

239) as a more efficient-by-weight fissile material, and a design that imploded<br />

a core <strong>of</strong> Pu-239 <strong>to</strong> produce a chain reaction (although either U-235<br />

or Pu-239 can be used in a implosion design). Having found PU-239 reprocessing<br />

more difficult than U-235 enrichment, we believe Iraq may have chosen<br />

– and may be well on the way <strong>to</strong> producing – a Manhattan Projecttype,<br />

U-235-based, Fat Man or Little Boy weapon. Though we do not<br />

minimize it, Little Boy, for example, was “only” about 1/100th as powerful<br />

as many <strong>of</strong> the modern thermonuclear devices currently in western and Russian<br />

arsenals, it weighed 8,900 pounds (far heavier than any Iraqi ballistic<br />

missile payload capability), and it was 120 inches in length (far <strong>to</strong>o long for<br />

any Iraqi combat aircraft <strong>to</strong> carry). To maximize its effect by minimizing<br />

blast deflection resulting from ground clutter, Little Boy was de<strong>to</strong>nated at<br />

1,800 feet above Hiroshima, Japan. But given the advanced state <strong>of</strong> modern<br />

air defenses, such an air-burst would be a difficult feat for Iraq, in our view,<br />

given the difficulty Iraq has faced in continuing its ballistic missile or tactical<br />

aircraft training programs since the Gulf War. Although ground delivery<br />

would greatly reduce the weapon’s lethal range, more radioactive fallout<br />

would be created, a problem for surrounding countries. We have no doubt<br />

that Iraq’s potential device(s) would differ sharply from the much more<br />

powerful and sophisticated arsenals <strong>of</strong> the long-standing nuclear powers,<br />

the latter <strong>of</strong> which employ a three-stage fission, fusion, and then secondary<br />

fission thermonuclear process <strong>of</strong> much greater – <strong>of</strong>ten 100x and in a few<br />

cases over 1,000x greater – explosive equivalent yield, with superior missile,<br />

aircraft or submarine delivery systems. Basically, these fusion-based weapons<br />

use the energy released in fission as only a first-stage “trigger” <strong>to</strong> fuse <strong>to</strong>gether<br />

(as opposed <strong>to</strong> fission, which is <strong>to</strong> split) a<strong>to</strong>mic nuclei, releasing far<br />

greater energy in the process, which then can be used <strong>to</strong> create a large secondary<br />

fission reaction <strong>of</strong> the casing <strong>of</strong> the device itself. Such yields can be arbitrarily<br />

high; for example, the Soviet Union de<strong>to</strong>nated a 58 mega<strong>to</strong>n (58 million<br />

<strong>to</strong>ns <strong>of</strong> TNT) fusion weapon in 1961.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -67- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

quarter century <strong>of</strong> effort. Those reasons are: (1) the effectiveness <strong>of</strong> previous UNSCOM inspections and U.<br />

S. bombing in the Gulf War, (2) a lack <strong>of</strong> focus by Iraqi nuclear scientists with regard <strong>to</strong> first taking the<br />

easiest path <strong>to</strong> build a basic fission bomb before embarking on more sophisticated devices, (3) Saddam<br />

Hussein’s own handling <strong>of</strong> his nuclear scientists which may have contributed <strong>to</strong> problem (#2), and finally<br />

(4) Israeli military and security force preventive actions since the mid-1970s <strong>to</strong> sabotage Iraq’s nuclear program.<br />

We believe that if Iraq is close <strong>to</strong> developing nuclear weapons, or has a small number <strong>of</strong> them, they<br />

are probably <strong>of</strong> the type described in the box on the preceding page, which is similar in design <strong>to</strong> one <strong>of</strong> the<br />

two nuclear weapons the U.S. developed in the Manhattan Project <strong>of</strong> World War II.<br />

We have no doubt that Iraq’s potential or prospective device would differ sharply from the much<br />

larger and more powerful arsenals <strong>of</strong> the long-standing nuclear powers. To date, we believe that the<br />

Iraqi nuclear program has probably obtained or produced many <strong>of</strong> the components for a fission-only nuclear<br />

device using HEU, but may lack some <strong>of</strong> the components as well as a critical mass <strong>of</strong> the much more difficult<br />

<strong>to</strong> obtain HEU fissile material. <strong>The</strong> distinction in terms <strong>of</strong> Iraq’s nuclear ambitions and capabilities by<br />

weapon type is important, because it has implications for delivery method, use, damage and threat level. Although<br />

a Plu<strong>to</strong>nium-239 (Pu-239) fission device is smaller, for example, and thus more easily delivered <strong>to</strong> a<br />

target, we doubt that Iraq has a Pu-239 device because those tend <strong>to</strong> be a more sophisticated second-step<br />

weapon for proliferants. In fact, it may have been a quest for Pu-239 from Iraq’s Tammuz-1/Osirak nuclear<br />

reac<strong>to</strong>r fiasco <strong>of</strong> 20 years ago that contributed <strong>to</strong> delays in Iraqi nuclear success <strong>to</strong> date. For a sense <strong>of</strong> his<strong>to</strong>ry,<br />

beginning in 1974, Iraq pursued the purchase from France <strong>of</strong> a nuclear research reac<strong>to</strong>r (a materials<br />

test reac<strong>to</strong>r) that was fueled by weapon’s grade HEU rather than LEU. Such a reac<strong>to</strong>r could quickly produce<br />

weapon’s grade Pu-239 (U-238 “targets” would become Pu-239 by capturing an additional neutron), and<br />

since a critical mass <strong>of</strong> Pu-239 weighs only 11 kilograms, as opposed <strong>to</strong> a critical mass <strong>of</strong> U-235 weighing<br />

56 kilograms (less if using a component known as a neutron reflec<strong>to</strong>r in either case; Iraq reportedly has experimented<br />

with reflec<strong>to</strong>rs), a Pu-239 fission bomb using explosives <strong>to</strong> implode the Pu-239 core in<strong>to</strong> a fissile<br />

mass would be easier <strong>to</strong> conceal and deliver via a small missile. But Iraq’s compact Pu-239-based bomb<br />

plans, which may have been sought, in our view, <strong>to</strong> accommodate Iraq’s limited missile delivery technology,<br />

proved <strong>to</strong>o l<strong>of</strong>ty a goal, since such a large research reac<strong>to</strong>r provided an easy target. In less than two<br />

minutes, on June 7, 1981, Israeli F-16 jets destroyed the Tammuz-1/Osirak reac<strong>to</strong>r before it was fueled for<br />

operation. Questions <strong>of</strong> whether Israel had inside help with the French team on-site have been raised but<br />

never publicly acknowledged. Since Iraq was already embroiled in a war with Iran that begun in September<br />

1980, the Iraqi nuclear program may have been set back several years.<br />

After the Tammuz-1/Osirak setback, we believe that Iraq switched <strong>to</strong> a simpler U-235 based nuclear<br />

weapon design, and began <strong>to</strong> employ large but relatively simple electromagnetic separation devices called<br />

calutrons <strong>to</strong> slowly refine the non-weapons-grade uranium compound feed down <strong>to</strong> weapons grade U-235.<br />

Analysts and Iraqi defec<strong>to</strong>rs report that centrifuges and other methods also have been used in the Iraqi U-<br />

235 refinement effort, but we are most aware <strong>of</strong> the fact that it was the calutron approach that the UN-<br />

SCOM inspec<strong>to</strong>rs documented in Iraq in the period immediately after the Gulf War. This slow but simple<br />

calutron process had been employed by the U.S. during the World War II Manhattan Project <strong>to</strong> create the<br />

“Little Boy” 15-kilo<strong>to</strong>n gun-assembly type a<strong>to</strong>m bomb that was dropped on Hiroshima, Japan.<br />

We view Israel’s suspected (but never formally acknowledged) nuclear deterrent as a defensive regional<br />

peace-keeper, but its existence probably has prompted Iraq <strong>to</strong> pursue a nuclear strategy. Israel<br />

is the only generally accepted, indigenous nuclear power in the Middle East, with weapons that were probably<br />

developed in close cooperation between French and Israeli nuclear researchers beginning in the 1950s,


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -68- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

after the construction <strong>of</strong> the Pu-239-producing underground nuclear research reac<strong>to</strong>r facility at Dimona in<br />

the Negev Desert. Israel is suspected <strong>of</strong> possessing about 200 nuclear weapons, mostly <strong>of</strong> a tactical<br />

(battlefield applicability, as opposed <strong>to</strong> strategic, or intercontinental) size. Some <strong>of</strong> the weapons are believed<br />

<strong>to</strong> be “neutron bombs,” capable <strong>of</strong> large and fatal bursts <strong>of</strong> short-lived radiation without quite as<br />

much <strong>of</strong> a blast effect or any meaningful radioactive fallout. Though little is publicly known <strong>of</strong> Israeli defensive<br />

nuclear alerts, two are believed <strong>to</strong> have occurred in the past three decades. <strong>The</strong> first probably happened<br />

during the Oc<strong>to</strong>ber 1973 Egyptian and Syrian attacks on Israel. <strong>The</strong> second alert is believed <strong>to</strong> have<br />

occurred during the Gulf War, when Iraq fired "Scud" missiles on Tel Aviv and Haifa. This raised the threat<br />

<strong>of</strong> chemical and biological attacks on Israel that may have led <strong>to</strong> an Israeli nuclear response had U.S. antimissile<br />

(Patriot and other) units and aircraft sorties not been diverted <strong>to</strong> protect Israel by locating and destroying<br />

Scud launchers. Israel's longest-known range ballistic missile is the 1,500 kilometer (932 mile),<br />

1,000 kilogram payload, Jericho-2 (J-2), but since Iran’s capital city <strong>of</strong> Tehran is 1,600 kilometers and<br />

Saudi Arabia’s Riyadh is 1,400 kilometers from Israel, we believe that Israel’s nuclear forces are defensive<br />

in nature. <strong>The</strong>re are reports that Israel is developing a J-2B successor missile with a 2,500 kilometer (1,553<br />

mile) range, but we do not believe that this move alters Israel’s defensive posture. In all, the nuclear deterrent<br />

and the potential for a disproportionate response probably have kept the peace for Israel since the 1973<br />

War, and may have helped keep the Gulf War from expanding, in our opinion.<br />

We believe the Bush Administration has adopted the goal <strong>of</strong> a regime change in Iraq because it fears<br />

the Iraq <strong>of</strong> the future much more than the Iraq <strong>of</strong> the present. <strong>The</strong> his<strong>to</strong>ry <strong>of</strong> nuclear proliferation has<br />

been that just because a country obtains the nuclear card, it does not necessarily follow that the card will be<br />

played. So, instead <strong>of</strong> a short-run view, we believe the Bush Administration fears that if Iraq holds the reins<br />

<strong>of</strong> nuclear power it may later pursue more advanced ICBM-based fusion weapons and expansionary avenues<br />

it otherwise would not have chosen. <strong>The</strong> continuation <strong>of</strong> the rebound in Iraqi oil exports from very low<br />

levels in the 1990s <strong>to</strong> our estimate <strong>of</strong> 3.5 million barrels per day by <strong>2015</strong>, combined with the higher oil<br />

prices we expect, could provide Iraq with a windfall in the coming years. Our best estimate is that from<br />

<strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong>, Iraq may receive approximately $373 billion <strong>of</strong> cumulative oil revenues in real (year<br />

2000) U.S. dollars, versus about $121 billion received in the 1988 <strong>to</strong> 2001 period. Whether those funds<br />

are used <strong>to</strong> enrich the Iraqi people and diversify the economy, or <strong>to</strong> fund Saddam Hussein’s war machine, is<br />

a question we believe the world will have <strong>to</strong> face.<br />

If Iraq becomes a nuclear threat, the risks compound, in our view. Generally speaking, we believe the<br />

risk <strong>of</strong> a nuclear exchange between two equally armed parties is guided and deterred by the principle <strong>of</strong> Mutually<br />

Assured Destruction (MAD). Given that a MAD balance is not the case in the Middle East, the attention<br />

next shifts <strong>to</strong> Israel’s intentions. Since Israel has shown its posture with respect <strong>to</strong> its (suspected and<br />

implied) superior nuclear weapons <strong>to</strong> be defensive in nature on several occasions, we do not believe the<br />

country plans a preemptive nuclear strike. When nuclear forces are uneven, we believe that the risk <strong>of</strong> a preemptive<br />

strike by a country that has recently acquired nuclear weapons is an unpredictable mixture <strong>of</strong> proximity,<br />

psychology and response. In terms <strong>of</strong> proximity, Israel’s location and small land area (222 miles from<br />

Elat <strong>to</strong> Haifa, for example) are legitimate concerns. In terms <strong>of</strong> psychology, and also on the subject <strong>of</strong> Iraq,<br />

that country’s rout in a conventional-only foray in<strong>to</strong> Kuwait in the Gulf War, as well as Iraq’s inability <strong>to</strong><br />

modernize its military in the subsequent decade, probably reduces Iraq’s appetite for conventional invasion.<br />

On the subject <strong>of</strong> response, we also doubt that a new nuclear power such as, hypothetically, Iraq, would see<br />

a great deal <strong>to</strong> gain in a preemptive strike (or even a retalia<strong>to</strong>ry strike <strong>to</strong> a conventional invasion) with crude<br />

fission devices having limited destruction capability when the subsequent retaliation would likely be an


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -69- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

overwhelming thermonuclear (fusion device) response by one or more countries with more sophisticated<br />

weapons. Even if Iraq were <strong>to</strong> become a neo-nuclear state, given the lopsided nuclear capabilities we<br />

see in the foreseeable future, and after successive Arab defeats in wars with Israel in 1948 <strong>to</strong> 1949,<br />

1967, and 1973 (plus the U.S. in the 1991), we doubt potential Arab (or Persian) state combatants are<br />

anxious <strong>to</strong> repeat past mistakes.<br />

Adding fuel, and perhaps an element <strong>of</strong> irrationality, <strong>to</strong> the Middle East soup, is the Palestinian issue.<br />

His<strong>to</strong>ry has shown that the human suffering on both sides <strong>of</strong> the region can be used <strong>to</strong> mold public support<br />

for actions that have largely economic or political roots. <strong>The</strong> failure <strong>of</strong> U.S. peace efforts may lead <strong>to</strong> an uncharacteristically<br />

unified Islamic country position against U.S. and Israeli interests, though the current<br />

Saudi regime does not appear <strong>to</strong> place great trust in Iraq’s Saddam Hussein in any case. As a result, we shift<br />

our focus <strong>to</strong> what we believe <strong>to</strong> be an underrated risk <strong>to</strong> regional stability in the Persian Gulf, which is the<br />

risk <strong>of</strong> internal rebellion if moderate regimes are perceived <strong>to</strong> be ineffective, and unfavorable demographics<br />

plus oil price deflation aggravates the economic situation.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Risk <strong>of</strong> Civil War That Targets Saudi Arabia's Ruling al-Saud Monarchy<br />

We believe that a key internal risk <strong>to</strong> Persian Gulf peace is Saudi Arabian political continuity, though<br />

we remind ourselves that it is all <strong>to</strong>o easy <strong>to</strong> underestimate the resilience and adaptability <strong>of</strong> Saudi Arabia's<br />

ruling al-Saud family, who have been an important part <strong>of</strong> Arabian life for over two centuries, and especially<br />

since the early 20th century. It is easy <strong>to</strong> overestimate Saudi Arabia's potential internal and external<br />

foes, most <strong>of</strong> which are poorly armed or trained in relation <strong>to</strong> the security and military forces <strong>of</strong> the Kingdom<br />

<strong>of</strong> Saudi Arabia. Nevertheless, extremist elements in Saudi Arabia are preying upon social and economic<br />

pressures <strong>to</strong> further their goals, one <strong>of</strong> which is replacing or bending the Saudi monarchy <strong>to</strong>ward the<br />

Sunni version <strong>of</strong> the Shiite government that <strong>to</strong>ppled the Shah <strong>of</strong> Iran in 1979. We believe that the Israeli/<br />

Palestinian question has migrated from a regional problem <strong>to</strong> a more volatile “East versus West” issue, and<br />

strengthened the hand <strong>of</strong> the radical factions in Saudi Arabia. In our view, Saudi Crown Prince Abdullah’s<br />

peace plan overtures are a sign that he is aware <strong>of</strong> the gravity <strong>of</strong> the situation on a personal and regional basis.<br />

Our view is that even if the al-Saud family were <strong>to</strong> be replaced, the realization <strong>of</strong> the radical’s nostalgic<br />

and <strong>to</strong> some degree mythical goal for Muslim unification is by no means certain, since a coup or a disorderly<br />

royal succession could devolve in<strong>to</strong> a fractious Yugoslavia-type quagmire on a much larger scale,<br />

given the large land area, oil resources, and diverse tribal and religious interests <strong>of</strong> Saudi Arabia.<br />

Radical factions in Saudi Arabia have been especially critical <strong>of</strong> the Monarchy’s decision <strong>to</strong> allow the<br />

presence <strong>of</strong> the U.S. military in Saudi Arabia, the home <strong>of</strong> Islam’s holy sites in Mecca and Medina.<br />

Our analysis concludes that some <strong>of</strong> the criticism <strong>of</strong> this continuing U.S. presence on religious pretexts is a<br />

ruse by insurgent parties <strong>to</strong> rally popular support and encourage the exit <strong>of</strong> the one force capable <strong>of</strong> maintaining<br />

the equipment already sold <strong>to</strong> Saudi Arabia, and capable <strong>of</strong> coordinating military stability in the region.<br />

In addition, we believe King Fahd’s implicit understanding with the U.S. after the Gulf War, which<br />

entailed Saudi cooperation in the prevention <strong>of</strong> oil price inflation in exchange for a U.S. defense umbrella,<br />

may be wearing thin. Given the poor state <strong>of</strong> Persian Gulf joint military cooperation and, <strong>to</strong> a degree, readiness,<br />

then unless U.S. forces are unexpectedly ousted by the government in the interim, our view is that a U.<br />

S. military exit from Saudi Arabia may be many years away.<br />

Civil unrest in Saudi Arabia has been an major issue since rapid “westernization” in the 1970s led <strong>to</strong><br />

an extremist uprising at Mecca in 1979, but we believe that unrest has been revived in recent years by


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -70- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

the cumulative economic pressure <strong>of</strong> low oil prices since the early 1980s. Exhibit 55 is our graphic depiction<br />

<strong>of</strong> the pressure brought <strong>to</strong> bear on the Persian Gulf region by low oil prices. <strong>The</strong> chart shows the cumulative<br />

transfer <strong>of</strong> wealth from the Western nations <strong>to</strong> the Persian Gulf from 1970 <strong>to</strong> 1981, followed by<br />

the transfer <strong>of</strong> wealth from the Persian Gulf back <strong>to</strong> the West in the period 1982 <strong>to</strong> 2001. We show the<br />

West-<strong>to</strong>-East transfer by measuring the cumulative dollar value <strong>of</strong> the annual barrels <strong>of</strong> oil exported by the<br />

Persian Gulf nations multiplied by the annual average real (inflation-adjusted) price for that oil above the<br />

1970 base level <strong>of</strong> $6.01 per barrel (in real, year 2000 dollars). <strong>The</strong>n, <strong>to</strong> demonstrate the East-<strong>to</strong>-West<br />

wealth reversal, we show the cumulative value <strong>of</strong> the annual barrels <strong>of</strong> oil exported by the Persian Gulf nations<br />

multiplied by the annual average real price for that oil below the 1981 base level <strong>of</strong> $65.37 per barrel<br />

(also in real, year 2000 dollars). Because <strong>of</strong> the differing importance <strong>of</strong> oil in relation <strong>to</strong> GDP, this zero-sum<br />

game has been more difficult for the Persian Gulf since 1981 than it was for the West in the 1970s when the<br />

tables were turned. It may be mere coincidence, but in 1995 the cumulative inflation-adjusted transfer <strong>of</strong><br />

wealth out <strong>of</strong> the Persian Gulf exceeded $1.8 trillion, finally matching the cumulative inflow <strong>of</strong> $1.8 trillion<br />

from 1970 <strong>to</strong> 1981. In the very next year, Osama bin Laden’s al-Qaeda network unified a variety <strong>of</strong> disaffected<br />

groups, and thereafter commenced a bombing campaign. While the West has achieved considerable<br />

success dismantling and destroying al-Qaeda, we believe it is difficult <strong>to</strong> kill the Hydra without stanching<br />

the blood flow that sustains it. In the case <strong>of</strong> Saudi Arabia, radicals increasingly are exporting their beliefs<br />

<strong>to</strong> other countries, and their recruitment is sustained by the economic difficulties resulting from oil price<br />

deflation, in our view. This terrorist export is, <strong>of</strong> course, unwelcome in the West, and the risk it poses <strong>to</strong><br />

Exhibit 55 – Cumulative Effect <strong>of</strong> Oil <strong>Price</strong> Swings on Wealth Transfer, 1970 <strong>to</strong> 2001E<br />

$2,000B<br />

Cumulative effect <strong>of</strong> oil price swings on wealth transfer in<strong>to</strong> and out <strong>of</strong> Persian Gulf<br />

Cumulative real $ billion (index year = 2000)<br />

$1,000B<br />

$0B<br />

-$1,000B<br />

-$2,000B<br />

-$3,000B<br />

1970<br />

1971<br />

1972<br />

1973<br />

1974<br />

1975<br />

1976<br />

1977<br />

1978<br />

1979<br />

1980<br />

1981<br />

1982<br />

1983<br />

1984<br />

1985<br />

1986<br />

1987<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

Cumulative wealth transfer <strong>to</strong><br />

Persian Gulf nations resulting<br />

from crude oil price increase<br />

over the 1970 real price level <strong>of</strong><br />

$6.01/bbl (priced in year 2000<br />

dollars).<br />

Cumulative wealth transfer away from Persian<br />

Gulf nations due <strong>to</strong> crude oil price decrease<br />

from the 1981 real price level <strong>of</strong> $65.37/bbl<br />

(priced in year 2000 dollars).<br />

2001E<br />

-$4,000B<br />

Source: Legg Mason format and concept, Persian Gulf states included in this analysis are Saudi Arabia, Iran, Iraq, U.A.E., Kuwait and<br />

Qatar. Data from the Energy Information Administration, United Nations Energy Statistics Database, OPEC Annual Statistical Bulletin,<br />

U.S. Bureau <strong>of</strong> Labor Statistics


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -71- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Saudi Arabia’s standing in the<br />

international community raises<br />

the diplomatic ante, and destabilizes<br />

the oil price outlook, in<br />

our view.<br />

To better understand Saudi<br />

political succession risk,<br />

which could have implications<br />

for oil prices, we provide<br />

a box his<strong>to</strong>ry <strong>of</strong> Saudi<br />

Arabia and its monarchy.<br />

King Fahd is the eldest brother<br />

in a group <strong>of</strong> seven males who<br />

have held key positions in the<br />

Kingdom, known as the Sudairi<br />

Seven, all sons <strong>of</strong> Ibn<br />

Saud, but who also share a<br />

common mother (Hassa bint<br />

Ahmad al-Sudairi). Ibn Saud<br />

had 22 wives, many for political<br />

alliance purposes, and<br />

found a way around the Muslim<br />

limitation <strong>of</strong> four wives<br />

reportedly by utilizing divorce.<br />

Aside from Fahd, another<br />

member <strong>of</strong> the Sudairi Seven<br />

whom we discuss in this report<br />

is Prince Sultan (b. 1928), the<br />

Minister <strong>of</strong> Defense and Aviation<br />

and Second Deputy Prime<br />

Minister. Sultan’s son, Bandar<br />

(b. 1949), is also widely recognized<br />

in America as the longtime<br />

Saudi Ambassador <strong>to</strong> the<br />

United States. Crown Prince<br />

Abdullah, Fahd’s half-brother,<br />

is Saudi Arabia’s de fac<strong>to</strong><br />

ruler since Fahd was incapacitated<br />

by stroke in the late<br />

1990s. Prince Abdullah has no<br />

brothers with whom <strong>to</strong> form a<br />

familial power base, and has<br />

led the more pluralistic and<br />

Bedouin (but highly skilled)<br />

A Brief His<strong>to</strong>ry <strong>of</strong> Saudi Arabia and the al-Saud Royal Family<br />

Saudi Arabia leapt from a nomadic and agrarian society <strong>to</strong> an urban, oilbased<br />

one in the space <strong>of</strong> a few decades, and we do not believe it has the his<strong>to</strong>rical<br />

gravitas <strong>of</strong> other states in the region that are now majority Muslim, such as<br />

the Ot<strong>to</strong>mans (Turkey), the Sumerian then Babylonians (Iraq) or the Persians<br />

(Iran). What Saudi Arabia does have is sudden wealth via the region’s most vast<br />

oil reserves, and that quantum leap in<strong>to</strong> modernity goes a long way <strong>to</strong>ward explaining<br />

its internal struggles. Before oil was an issue, the ances<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>of</strong> the al-<br />

Saud family first gained prominence in the year 1744 when a local leader<br />

named Muhammad Ibn Saud (b. 1710, d. 1765) struck an alliance with Islamic<br />

religious leader Muhammad Ibn Abd al Wahhab, namesake <strong>of</strong> the purist Wahhabi<br />

form <strong>of</strong> Islam, and the two began a volatile but successful alliance that continues<br />

<strong>to</strong>day. Muhammad Ibn Saud's son, Abdul Aziz, conquered most <strong>of</strong> the Arabian<br />

Peninsula by 1806, but was captured and executed by the Ot<strong>to</strong>mans in the early<br />

19th century, and what is now Saudi Arabia changed hands several times over the<br />

next century. <strong>The</strong> foundations <strong>of</strong> the modern Saudi Arabia began when King Abdul<br />

Aziz (b. 1879, d.1953, now known as Ibn Saud), the great-great grandson <strong>of</strong><br />

Muhammad Ibn Saud, re<strong>to</strong>ok Riyadh in 1902. Ibn Saud wore down the Ot<strong>to</strong>mans,<br />

who left in 1912, raising Ibn Saud’s stature and laying the groundwork for his<br />

conquest and unification <strong>of</strong> the peninsula from 1920 <strong>to</strong> 1932 with the help <strong>of</strong><br />

Wahhabi soldiers, known as Ikhwan (brethren). In 1929, Ibn Saud had <strong>to</strong> put<br />

down the rebellious and warlike Ikhwan at the Battle <strong>of</strong> Sibilla, a poignant example<br />

<strong>of</strong> the internal struggle between the al-Saud and Wahhabi. <strong>The</strong> modern economic<br />

base in Saudi Arabia began in 1933, when Ibn Saud signed a royalty<br />

oil concession with America's Standard Oil Company. Ibn Saud died in 1953,<br />

and was succeeded by his eldest son Saud, who ruled for 11 years, engaging in<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>ligate spending and defending Saudi Arabia from the “Pan-Arab” ambitions<br />

<strong>of</strong> Egypt’s Gamal Adbel Nasser (b. 1918, d. 1970). Saud eventually ceded power<br />

<strong>to</strong> his half-brother Faisal, who was Crown Prince and Prime Minister. Faisal continued<br />

the internal and external struggle against Nasser, <strong>to</strong> include a defense<br />

build-up after 1966, but perhaps Faisal’s legacy, in our view, is his recognition <strong>of</strong><br />

the intrinsic value <strong>of</strong> the country's vast oil reserves, which led <strong>to</strong> the Oil Embargo<br />

<strong>of</strong> 1974. Faisal was assassinated in 1975 by a deranged nephew who acted alone,<br />

and Faisal’s half-brother and successor, King Khalid, presided over five-year<br />

plans that modernized the country in a period <strong>of</strong> great wealth. As with Saud,<br />

Khalid’s rule featured a strong role by his Crown Prince Fahd (b. 1923). Saud<br />

and Khalid faced their own insurgency, similar <strong>to</strong> the Battle <strong>of</strong> Sibilla, when in<br />

1979 they had <strong>to</strong> put down an extremist uprising and occupation in Mecca. When<br />

Khalid died in 1982, he was succeeded by Fahd, who has ruled in some <strong>of</strong> Saudi<br />

Arabia’s most challenging years, including the oil price deflation <strong>of</strong> the 1980s,<br />

the Gulf War, and the doubling <strong>of</strong> Saudi Arabia’s population <strong>to</strong> over 20 million<br />

during his reign. Fahd suffered a stroke in 1995, and since 1997 Crown<br />

Prince and half-brother Abdullah (b. 1924), who is the First Deputy Prime<br />

Minister, has assumed the day-<strong>to</strong>-day responsibilities <strong>of</strong> the crown. In early<br />

<strong>2002</strong>, Abdullah reproposed a land (pre-1967 borders, a Palestinian State) for<br />

peace (full diplomatic recognition <strong>of</strong> Israel) plan with Israel.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -72- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Saudi National Guard since 1963. Prince Abdullah is generally regarded as having a more fundamentalist<br />

approach <strong>to</strong> Islam than Fahd, and is reputed <strong>to</strong> be a strong-willed reformer and a pragmatist.<br />

Royal succession could cause political turmoil in Saudi Arabia. Though Prince Abdullah is reportedly<br />

healthy, at age 78, royal succession is still an open question vis-à-vis other members <strong>of</strong> the Sudairi Seven,<br />

their descendants, or other members <strong>of</strong> the royal family. We note that there is a strong relationship between<br />

Abdullah and Saudi Minister <strong>of</strong> Foreign Affairs Saud al-Faisal, the latter being the son <strong>of</strong> former Saudi<br />

King Faisal, and it is possible that Saud al-Faisal could emerge as the next Saudi Crown prince upon King<br />

Fahd’s passing, in our view. <strong>The</strong> lack <strong>of</strong> clarity with regard <strong>to</strong> succession is not a major deviation from the<br />

political his<strong>to</strong>ry <strong>of</strong> Saudi Arabia. Although Saudi Arabia has established a number <strong>of</strong> consultative or democratic<br />

institutions, <strong>to</strong> include the Majlis al Shuria (Consultative Council) that was revived by King Fahd after<br />

the Gulf War, our view is that for the success <strong>of</strong> the al-Saud monarchy, the next Saudi King must<br />

be a reformer and have more national prosperity via higher oil prices.<br />

In our view, the power structure that has evolved in Saudi Arabia is a triumvirate, and its continued<br />

stability is <strong>of</strong> global interest <strong>to</strong> avoid major war and commodity and consumer inflation. In one corner <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Saudi triumvirate, there is the secular political authority <strong>of</strong> the al-Saud monarchy. <strong>The</strong> Saud family derives<br />

inspiration and occasional force from the Islamic religious authorities, who occupy the opposite corner,<br />

some <strong>of</strong> whom are the descendants <strong>of</strong> Abdul Wahhab, and are known as the al-Sheiks. Both parties derive<br />

earthly sustenance from the region’s economic interests - mainly related <strong>to</strong> oil in the modern era – which<br />

occupies the third corner. We believe that oil price deflation since the early 1980s has destabilized the economic<br />

interests <strong>of</strong> the region, since the his<strong>to</strong>ry <strong>of</strong> the Saudi monarchy has been <strong>to</strong> use financial largesse <strong>to</strong><br />

“buy <strong>of</strong>f” discontent. We believe that this economic pressure has created a situation in which some <strong>of</strong> the<br />

long-simmering religious authorities have used the economic malaise <strong>to</strong> blame the political authorities for<br />

economic failure and its consequences, potentially in a bid for power and increased religious governance.<br />

<strong>The</strong> rapid urbanization and collapse <strong>of</strong> per capita GNP in Saudi Arabia, shown in Exhibit 56, has left<br />

the country with a rising cadre <strong>of</strong> disaffected young men, in our view. <strong>The</strong> situation is aggravated by a<br />

birth rate that is among the highest in the world, and a surge from 2000 <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> <strong>of</strong> potentially disenfranchised<br />

young Saudis relative <strong>to</strong> older, more established, and presumably less fiery Saudis, depicted in Exhibit<br />

57. Unless the oil-based economy <strong>of</strong> Saudi Arabia receives a boost, and parlays that wealth in<strong>to</strong> a successful<br />

diversification effort, we believe this youth explosion will collide with a dearth <strong>of</strong> private industry<br />

job opportunities, pushing the existing unemployment rate <strong>of</strong> approximately 25% even higher. In fact, youth<br />

explosion is a pan-Gulf problem. Among the Gulf states, ex-Iran and Iraq, non-citizens make up 37% <strong>of</strong> the<br />

population <strong>of</strong> 32.4 million, and residents under age 15 make up 40% <strong>of</strong> the population. In Saudi Arabia in<br />

particular, where the economy has failed <strong>to</strong> diversify beyond oil, in our view, this raises the prospect that<br />

more people will fall under the spell <strong>of</strong> the radical elements.<br />

With approximately 5,000 Saudi princes, the odds <strong>of</strong> at least several hundred “black sheep” are quite<br />

high, in our view. Those “bad apples” fuel resentment and may give the approximately 100 ruling princes a<br />

bad name, so we believe that current discussions regarding a culling <strong>of</strong> the royal roster may gain momentum,<br />

especially since high birth rates make royal expansion an increasingly serious problem.<br />

As a result, Saudi capital flight and corruption are serious issues, the result <strong>of</strong> some members <strong>of</strong> the<br />

royal family and high-level technocrats protecting their self-interest in a period <strong>of</strong> economic pressure. <strong>The</strong>re


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -73- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

is approximately $700 billion<br />

<strong>of</strong> private Saudi wealth<br />

abroad, as well as $266 billion<br />

from the United Arab<br />

Emirates, $163 billion from<br />

Kuwait, and $65 billion<br />

from the other members <strong>of</strong><br />

the Gulf Cooperation Council.<br />

This wealth is in the<br />

hands <strong>of</strong> an estimated<br />

200,000 individuals, equal<br />

<strong>to</strong> about $6 million per capita<br />

among the holders. It is<br />

noteworthy that an estimated<br />

$400 billion <strong>of</strong> this<br />

capital has been invested in<br />

Western s<strong>to</strong>ck markets, and<br />

has thus benefited from the<br />

very same disinflationdriven<br />

equity bull market <strong>of</strong><br />

the 1982 <strong>to</strong> 2001 period<br />

that was the antithesis <strong>of</strong><br />

the poor economic opportunity<br />

afforded the oil-based<br />

economies. Domestic uses<br />

for the capital are few, as<br />

we believe Saudi Arabia<br />

suffers from inadequate diversification<br />

beyond oil,<br />

and an embryonic work<br />

ethic that relies <strong>to</strong>o heavily<br />

on foreign workers and<br />

meaningless government<br />

jobs. Oil still represents approximately<br />

70% <strong>of</strong> state<br />

revenues and 40% <strong>of</strong> GDP,<br />

according <strong>to</strong> the EIA. Government<br />

positions account<br />

for 40% <strong>of</strong> all jobs, versus<br />

25% in industry (mostly<br />

petrochemicals) and oil. In<br />

time, free markets and high<br />

rate-<strong>of</strong>-return domestic oilrelated<br />

projects could repatriate<br />

much <strong>of</strong> this wealth,<br />

Exhibit 56 – Saudi Arabian GNP Per Capita and Urbanization<br />

Saudi Arabian GNP Per Capita, Constant 1995 U.S.$<br />

$12,000<br />

$11,000<br />

$10,000<br />

$9,000<br />

$8,000<br />

$7,000<br />

$6,000<br />

Exhibit 57 – Saudi Arabia Youth Wave, 1974 <strong>to</strong> 2040E<br />

200%<br />

190%<br />

180%<br />

170%<br />

160%<br />

150%<br />

140%<br />

130%<br />

120%<br />

110%<br />

100%<br />

1970<br />

1971<br />

1972<br />

1973<br />

1974<br />

1975<br />

1976<br />

1977<br />

1978<br />

1979<br />

1980<br />

1981<br />

1982<br />

1983<br />

1984<br />

1985<br />

1986<br />

1987<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

Saudi Arabia GNP per Capita (Constant 1995 U.S.$)<br />

Source: <strong>The</strong> International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook Database 2001<br />

Saudi Arabia: A Measure <strong>of</strong> the Passions <strong>of</strong> a Population?<br />

1980<br />

1990<br />

2000<br />

Ratio <strong>of</strong> Less Stable (age 20-34) <strong>to</strong> More Established (age 35-49)<br />

Source: U.S. Census Bureau, International Data Base, 2000<br />

2010<br />

A<br />

volatile<br />

combination<br />

<strong>The</strong> rise in young Saudis with<br />

few job opportunities relative<br />

<strong>to</strong> older, and presumably more<br />

stable Saudis, provides fodder<br />

for religious extremists in the<br />

<strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> period, in our<br />

view.<br />

2020<br />

2030<br />

90%<br />

85%<br />

80%<br />

75%<br />

70%<br />

65%<br />

60%<br />

55%<br />

50%<br />

Saudi Arabian Urban Population % <strong>of</strong> Total<br />

Saudi Arabia Urban Population as a % <strong>of</strong> <strong>The</strong> Total<br />

2040


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -74- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

if free markets are given time <strong>to</strong> work. In addition <strong>to</strong> improved oil-based prosperity, we believe repatriation<br />

<strong>of</strong> capital in Saudi Arabia will require greater privatization, some form <strong>of</strong> taxation, a reduction <strong>of</strong> corruption<br />

and bribery, improved legal standards and property rights protection, and social reforms such as improved<br />

use <strong>of</strong> female human capital. <strong>The</strong> success without excessive reliance on hydrocarbons <strong>of</strong> Oman,<br />

Bahrain, and Dubai would appear <strong>to</strong> <strong>of</strong>fer examples that Saudi Arabia could follow, albeit selectively, moderately,<br />

and slowly, in our view.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Risk <strong>of</strong> Conventional (Non-Nuclear) War Between States in the Region<br />

Because our interest is the oil resources <strong>of</strong> the Persian Gulf, this section does not address other regional<br />

hot spots. For example, the Israeli-Palestinian imbroglio, or a worsening <strong>of</strong> the contentious Pakistan/<br />

India face-<strong>of</strong>f, could destabilize the region. As inves<strong>to</strong>rs, our focus is on the oil-rich Persian Gulf, particularly<br />

Saudi Arabia, Iraq and Iran, although any conflict could have a contagion effect in the region.<br />

<strong>The</strong> U.S. military presence in the Persian Gulf is invited, and regionwide. In Exhibit 58, we provide a<br />

Middle East map. <strong>The</strong> U.S. Central Command (CENTCOM) and coalition partners maintain a personnel or<br />

forward-deployed material presence in Kuwait and several border states, including the United Arab Emirates,<br />

Bahrain, Oman and Qatar. <strong>The</strong> major CENTCOM facility in Saudi Arabia is Prince Sultan Airbase,<br />

but since aircraft carriers play a large role in force projection, we note that CENTCOM’s naval presence is<br />

Exhibit 58 – Middle East Map<br />

Source: Legg Mason Wood Walker; map outline from www.graphicmaps.com


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -75- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

the Fifth Fleet, headquartered<br />

in Bahrain. If the U.<br />

S. military presence were<br />

<strong>to</strong> be phased out prematurely<br />

in Saudi Arabia, our<br />

view is that it would be<br />

difficult <strong>to</strong> perform a deterrence<br />

role with only forward-deployed<br />

material<br />

and naval facilities.<br />

Exhibit 59 - <strong>The</strong> Persian Gulf Military Balance in 2001<br />

Other Artillery + Fixed<br />

Active Main Armored Multiple Wing<br />

Military Battle Fighting Rocket Combat Armed<br />

Personnel Tanks Vehicles Launchers Aircraft Helicopters<br />

Iraq 429,000 2,700 3,400 2,200 353 120<br />

Saudi Arabia 226,500 1,055 4,285 568 432 33<br />

Saudi military readiness<br />

has been a thorny issue.<br />

<strong>The</strong> all-in life cycle costs<br />

<strong>of</strong> a weapons system are<br />

usually at least twice the<br />

purchase price. <strong>The</strong> pressure<br />

from low oil prices<br />

has slowed Saudi Arabia’s<br />

military purchases, and<br />

spurred a desire <strong>to</strong> better<br />

utilize equipment on hand.<br />

Prior efforts <strong>to</strong> diversify<br />

arms vendors have proved<br />

<strong>to</strong> be an obstacle <strong>to</strong> force<br />

integration and<br />

interoperability, however,<br />

and aggravated an alreadydifficult<br />

readiness situation.<br />

This has contributed<br />

<strong>to</strong> the long-standing U.S.<br />

advisor presence in the<br />

Kingdom, aggravating the<br />

Islamic radical groups, and<br />

creating a problem for<br />

which there is no easy solution.<br />

<strong>The</strong> balance <strong>of</strong> military<br />

power in the Persian<br />

Gulf requires more than<br />

a cursory examination.<br />

In Exhibit 59, we provide<br />

a survey <strong>of</strong> the Persian<br />

Gulf military strength. On<br />

Kuwait 15,300 385 455 68 76 20<br />

Bahrain 11,000 106 411 107 24 26<br />

Oman 43,500 141 219 109 40 -<br />

Qatar 12,330 44 284 44 18 12<br />

UAE 65,000 237 1,138 289 99 49<br />

Yemen 66,300 1,030 1,290 702 89 8<br />

Total Other Gulf (1) 213,430 1,943 3,797 1,319 346 115<br />

Iran 513,000 1,410 1,105 3,224 304 100<br />

(1) Smaller Gulf states bordering or bridging Saudi Arabia. Military readiness is a problem, and there is<br />

generally considered <strong>to</strong> be little military cooperation within the Gulf Cooperation Counsel.<br />

Source: Center for Strategic and International Studies’ Anthony H. Cordesman draft report titled<br />

Saudi Military Forces Enter the 21st Century<br />

Exhibit 60 - Military Quality vs. Quantity in the Persian Gulf, 2001<br />

Total Medium- <strong>to</strong> % Medium- Fixed Medium- <strong>to</strong> % Medium-<br />

Main High- <strong>to</strong> High- Wing High- <strong>to</strong> High-<br />

Battle Quality (1) Quality Combat Quality (2) Quality<br />

Tanks Tanks Tanks Aircraft Aircraft Aircraft<br />

Iraq 2,700 1,000 37% 353 112 32%<br />

Saudi Arabia 1,055 765 73% 432 281 65%<br />

Kuwait 385 368 96% 76 60 79%<br />

Bahrain 106 106 100% 24 12 50%<br />

Oman 141 117 83% 40 28 70%<br />

Qatar 44 - 0% 18 12 67%<br />

UAE 237 192 81% 99 84 85%<br />

Yemen 1,030 310 30% 89 22 25%<br />

Total Other Gulf (3) 1,943 1,093 56% 346 218 63%<br />

Iran 1,410 715 51% 304 175 58%<br />

(1) Medium- <strong>to</strong> high-quality tanks, primarily M-1 and M-60 (U.S.), Tupolev-72 and Tupolev-62 (F.S.U.)<br />

(2) Medium- <strong>to</strong> high-quality aircraft are F-15 C/D/S (U.S.), Mirage F-1 (Fr.), MiG-29/25 and Su-20/22 (F.S.U.),<br />

Tornado IDS/ADV (UK), F-14 (U.S.), F-4E (U.S.)<br />

(3) Smaller Gulf states bordering or bridging Saudi Arabia. Military readiness is a problem, and there is<br />

generally considered <strong>to</strong> be little military cooperation within the Gulf Cooperation Counsel.<br />

Source: Center for Strategic and International Studies’ Anthony H. Cordesman draft report titled<br />

Saudi Military Forces Enter the 21st Century


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -76- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

paper, Iraq appears <strong>to</strong> have a formidable conventional military, <strong>to</strong> include the region’s second-largest number<br />

<strong>of</strong> active military personnel (429,000), and the largest number <strong>of</strong> main battle tanks (2,700). Saudi Arabia<br />

has the most armored fighting vehicles (4,285) and fixed wing combat aircraft (432), and Iran has the<br />

most active military personnel (513,000), the most artillery pieces (3,224) and the only indigenous navy.<br />

But a closer examination <strong>of</strong> quality rather than quantity tells a different s<strong>to</strong>ry. In Exhibit 60, we observe that<br />

73% <strong>of</strong> Saudi Arabia's tanks are medium- <strong>to</strong> high-quality, compared <strong>to</strong> 37% in Iraq and 51% in Iran. In addition,<br />

65% <strong>of</strong> Saudi Arabia's combat aircraft are medium- <strong>to</strong> high-quality, versus 32% for Iraq and 58% for<br />

Iran.<br />

We do not believe that Iraq has ever recovered militarily from the Gulf War defeat. According <strong>to</strong> U.S.<br />

Army Lieutenant General Tom Kelly, during the Gulf War "Iraq went from the fourth-largest army in the<br />

world <strong>to</strong> the second-largest army in Iraq in 100 hours." Little appears <strong>to</strong> have changed for Iraq’s conventional<br />

forces since 1991, in our view. Since 1989, the year before the Iraqi invasion <strong>of</strong> Kuwait, the troop<br />

strength <strong>of</strong> Iraq has declined 52%, and its main battle tank inven<strong>to</strong>ry is down 51%, with most <strong>of</strong> the losses<br />

occurring during the Gulf War itself. In contrast, Saudi Arabia's troop strength is up 179%, and its main battle<br />

tank inven<strong>to</strong>ry is up 92%.<br />

Sparked by fear and vigilance, Saudi Arabia has been one <strong>of</strong> the largest importers <strong>of</strong> military hardware<br />

in the world each year for the last two decades. Saudi Arabia ranked first in the years 1989 <strong>to</strong> 1999 in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> new arm deliveries. Saudi Arabia <strong>to</strong>ok heed when the Shah fell in Iran in 1979, ousted by a Shiite<br />

rebellion, and Saudi Arabia was further alarmed when there was a risk that Iraq would lose the Iran-Iraq<br />

War in the period 1984 <strong>to</strong> 1987. <strong>The</strong> Gulf War <strong>of</strong> 1990 <strong>to</strong> 1991 caused a similar reaction in Saudi Arabia,<br />

which saw a brewing threat <strong>to</strong> its borders. In the period 1995 <strong>to</strong> 2000E, military expenditures <strong>to</strong>taled $109.7<br />

billion for Saudi Arabia, $8.4 billion for Iraq, $28 billion for Iran, and $60.1 billion for the bordering Gulf<br />

states. As a percentage <strong>of</strong> GDP, Saudi military expenditures are now 14.5%, almost three times larger than<br />

Iraq and five times larger than Iran. Arms imports as a percentage <strong>of</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal imports <strong>of</strong> Saudi Arabia are approximately<br />

40%, as compared <strong>to</strong> approximately 12% for the Middle East as a whole. Prince Sultan has<br />

been instrumental in the Saudi military build-up, <strong>of</strong>ten buying what we believe are superior U.S. armaments,<br />

but because <strong>of</strong> U.S. ties <strong>to</strong> Israel and occasional Israeli resistance <strong>to</strong> U.S. sales <strong>to</strong> Saudi Arabia, the<br />

Kingdom has diversified its purchases.<br />

Central <strong>to</strong> the ability <strong>of</strong> Saudi Arabia <strong>to</strong> face a conventional war threat from a neighboring country is<br />

the structure <strong>of</strong> the Saudi military itself, and the level <strong>of</strong> esprit de corps. Saudi Arabia and Iraq have<br />

comparable pools <strong>of</strong> men <strong>of</strong> military age. Iran, with its larger population, has more draft-age men. <strong>The</strong> unsuccessful<br />

experience <strong>of</strong> Saudi Arabia in the Gulf War with respect <strong>to</strong> Pakistani troops contributed <strong>to</strong> a lack<br />

<strong>of</strong> faith among the Saudi military establishment <strong>of</strong> relying upon foreign troops at the combat level, and a<br />

decision was made <strong>to</strong> rely upon a pr<strong>of</strong>essional military in the future. <strong>The</strong> level <strong>of</strong> education and training <strong>of</strong><br />

the Saudi <strong>of</strong>ficer group, many <strong>of</strong> whom are drawn from the royal family, has greatly improved since the pre-<br />

Oil Embargo years, but Saudi <strong>of</strong>ficers performing military training in the U.S. are down approximately 85%<br />

since the early 1990s, and American advisors and civilian contrac<strong>to</strong>rs are key <strong>to</strong> maintaining Saudi Arabia’s<br />

military hardware. Another problem Saudi Arabia has faced in the creation <strong>of</strong> a pr<strong>of</strong>essional military<br />

class is the seniority-based system found in portions <strong>of</strong> the Saudi <strong>of</strong>ficer corps, which is perceived as an<br />

even greater problem than royal nepotism. But as evidence that Saudi <strong>of</strong>ficer positions are considered <strong>to</strong> be<br />

highly prestigious, the Saudi Arabian National Guard (SANG) Academy, which is the more proletarian<br />

branch <strong>of</strong> the service had a 15% acceptance rate last year, which was, coincidentally, approximately the


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -77- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

same acceptance rate as the U.S. Military Academy at West Point. Even the SANG quality <strong>of</strong> troops, many<br />

<strong>of</strong> whom were simple Bedouin just a couple <strong>of</strong> decades ago, has improved. Our view is that Prince Sultan's<br />

build-up <strong>of</strong> Saudi defense forces has shown admirable foresight, given the rising tensions in the region, and<br />

Prince Abdullah’s stewardship <strong>of</strong> the SANG has helped produce an impressive, motivated fighting force.<br />

Still, there is hope among many in the Saudi royal family, and many outside the family, that if Prince Abdullah<br />

becomes King, he will shift the focus from military hardware purchases <strong>to</strong> the less glamorous, but<br />

more critical, readiness and integration issue, and gradually reducing the reliance on outside advisors.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Soviet-era weaponry <strong>of</strong> Saudi Arabia's potential opposition does not enjoy a favorable his<strong>to</strong>ry<br />

versus American military equipment, which lessens the conventional war risk, in our view. As evidence,<br />

we cite Operation Galilee in the spring <strong>of</strong> 1982, in which Israel responded <strong>to</strong> Palestinian attacks launched<br />

from southern Lebanon. In that operation, Israeli Air Force (IAF) pilots flying U.S. F-15 (Eagle) and F-16<br />

(Falcon) aircraft, both <strong>of</strong> which are still in the IAF and U.S. arsenal in updated models, engaged the Syrian<br />

Air Force flying Soviet MiG-21 and MiG-23 aircraft over the Bekaa Valley. <strong>The</strong> IAF downed 90 Syrian<br />

MiGs in aerial combat without a single aircraft lost. Another example occurred in the Gulf War, when the<br />

U.S. VII Corps, under the command <strong>of</strong> Lieutenant General Fred Franks, defeated Iraqi units in February<br />

1991. <strong>The</strong> VII Corps arsenal included equipment such as the U.S.-made Apache helicopter and M1 Abrams<br />

main battle tank, while the Iraqi forces employed Soviet-made Tupolev main battle tanks and other combat<br />

vehicles. In 90 hours <strong>of</strong> movement and combat, VII Corps reportedly destroyed more than a dozen Iraqi divisions,<br />

approximately 1,300 tanks, 1,200 fighting vehicles and armored personnel carriers, 285 artillery<br />

pieces, 100 air defense systems, and captured around 22,000 enemy soldiers. At the same time, VII Corps<br />

had extremely light casualties and equipment losses. Reports from the Gulf War stated that the superior<br />

range <strong>of</strong> the M1 Abrams gun and fire control system, and the superior ability <strong>of</strong> the M1 <strong>to</strong> see through the<br />

smoke and heat generated by burning oil fields, contributed <strong>to</strong> the armored rout. Based on these and other<br />

his<strong>to</strong>rical precedents, we believe inves<strong>to</strong>rs should not overreact <strong>to</strong> face-<strong>of</strong>fs between U.S.-equipped and<br />

trained forces when confronted with older generation Soviet era conventional weapons, although the level<br />

<strong>of</strong> training is, <strong>of</strong> course, a key <strong>to</strong> success. <strong>The</strong> latest generations <strong>of</strong> Russian military hardware are more formidable,<br />

such as the MiG-29 Fulcrum combat aircraft and the Tupolev-90 main battle tank, but that hardware<br />

has not been exported <strong>to</strong> Iraq or Iran, <strong>to</strong> the best <strong>of</strong> our knowledge.<br />

In summary, we do not believe Iraq or Iran poses a major, conventional warfare threat <strong>to</strong> Saudi Arabia,<br />

especially with improved aerial and signal intelligence that can detect troop movements before they become<br />

an invading force. Not <strong>to</strong> be overlooked, on the subject <strong>of</strong> external risk we note that Iran and Syria are<br />

Shiite strongholds, and their governments are indicted terrorist sponsors whose goals are not easily discernable.<br />

Internecine feuds between Shiite and Sunni (the Sunni are the majority in Saudi Arabia) Muslims have<br />

produced bloodshed occasionally, and may do so again, including within Saudia Arabia, in the Shiite-heavy<br />

eastern oil-producing region. On the subject <strong>of</strong> conventional threats <strong>to</strong> the flow <strong>of</strong> oil, we do view the surface<br />

navy <strong>of</strong> Iran and shore-launched anti-ship missiles as a viable threat <strong>to</strong> the Straits <strong>of</strong> Hormuz, through<br />

which 16 million barrels <strong>of</strong> oil pass every day. Given that the other Gulf states have not developed a major<br />

naval counter force <strong>to</strong> Iran, however, we must deduce that the states are confident in the ability <strong>of</strong> the Saudi<br />

and U.S. military <strong>to</strong> neutralize small and moderate threats <strong>to</strong> shipping at the mouth <strong>of</strong> the Persian Gulf.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -78- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Risk <strong>of</strong> Terrorists Obtaining Nuclear Weapons Developed in the Soviet Union<br />

Nuclear complexity inhibits proliferation. <strong>The</strong> difficulty <strong>of</strong> producing weapons grade U-235 or Pu-239<br />

probably places fission and certainly fusion devices beyond the grasp <strong>of</strong> terrorists, at least for the time being.<br />

On the other hand, reac<strong>to</strong>r grade plu<strong>to</strong>nium, other processed waste, as well as the political instability <strong>of</strong><br />

new nuclear powers such as Pakistan, are continuing risks. As for the nuclear arsenal <strong>of</strong> the former Soviet<br />

Union, we believe that the highly centralized command and control system <strong>of</strong> the Soviet military led <strong>to</strong> the<br />

widespread use <strong>of</strong> Permissive Access Links (PALs) such as those used in the U.S. (<strong>The</strong>re is some speculation<br />

the U.S. willingly gave the technology <strong>to</strong> the U.S.S.R.) PALs use heavily encrypted code systems <strong>to</strong><br />

activate a weapon, and are as complex as the weapons are dangerous. We also believe that there have been<br />

numerous public and private U.S. efforts <strong>to</strong> assist Russia in securing its nuclear weapons over the decades.<br />

We highlight the infamous “missing” Soviet “suitcase nukes,” if they ever existed at all, as a case in<br />

point for how inves<strong>to</strong>rs may receive misinformation in the media. <strong>The</strong> nuclear weapons cited were mentioned<br />

by Alexander Lebed (b. 1950), a former deputy commander <strong>of</strong> the Soviet Airborne (paratrooper)<br />

forces and former National Security Advisor (1996) <strong>to</strong> Russian President Boris Yeltsin. In a private meeting<br />

with U.S. congressmen in May 1997, Mr. Lebed cited up <strong>to</strong> 84 missing nuclear weapons <strong>of</strong> a suitcase size.<br />

In August <strong>of</strong> the same year, in a 60 Minutes news program interview, Mr. Lebed upped the number <strong>to</strong> 100<br />

missing nuclear weapons <strong>of</strong> that type. Although similar weapons did exist in the U.S. arsenal (the W54 Special<br />

A<strong>to</strong>mic Demolition Munition, called SADM, and later variants), we have several reasons <strong>to</strong> doubt the<br />

veracity <strong>of</strong> Mr. Lebed’s claim.<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

Mr. Lebed’s claim was based on a preliminary study commissioned by Mr. Lebed when he was President<br />

Yeltsin’s National Security chief in 1996, but he did not stay in <strong>of</strong>fice long enough <strong>to</strong> obtain the<br />

results – he was fired by President Yeltsin for other reasons, some <strong>of</strong> which have been attributed <strong>to</strong> Mr.<br />

Lebed’s political aspirations while President Yeltsin was in ill health.<br />

Mr. Lebed is a self-made combat (rather than political) general from a proletarian background, who<br />

made the transition <strong>to</strong> politician in the melee <strong>of</strong> post-Communist Russia. As a result, he is given <strong>to</strong> bold<br />

political statements that seize the public imagination, in our view.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se weapons were ostensibly produced outside <strong>of</strong> the Soviet military establishment for use by operatives,<br />

but since such small devices would have <strong>to</strong> be Pu-239-based, we doubt the Soviet military would<br />

have lost track <strong>of</strong> that quantity <strong>of</strong> extremely difficult-<strong>to</strong>-produce Pu-239, which requires a complex reac<strong>to</strong>r-based<br />

refinement effort.<br />

<strong>The</strong> alleged weapons have been <strong>to</strong>uted as having large-citywide destructive capability. But the effective<br />

lethal radius (50% casualty rate) <strong>of</strong> a one kilo<strong>to</strong>n “suitcase nuke” fission device de<strong>to</strong>nated at ground<br />

level in an urban setting would be 800 yards, which is nowhere close <strong>to</strong> the six mile lethal radius <strong>of</strong> a<br />

one mega<strong>to</strong>n thermonuclear device <strong>of</strong> the sort found in the arsenals <strong>of</strong> advanced nuclear states.<br />

As we have stated, we believe it is difficult for inves<strong>to</strong>rs <strong>to</strong> separate fact from fiction in the complex and<br />

arcane world <strong>of</strong> political and military analysis. In this section <strong>of</strong> the report, our goal has been <strong>to</strong> shed more<br />

light on the subject so that inves<strong>to</strong>rs may be better informed.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -79- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Non-Economic Contrasts Between East and West That Affect <strong>The</strong> Investment<br />

Outlook<br />

Until this point, we have only discussed economic contrasts between the West and the Middle East,<br />

but there are political and social facets <strong>to</strong> the relationship. Some <strong>of</strong> the radical elements <strong>of</strong> the East and<br />

West believe that there is an inevitable conflict between Islam and Christianity. A few even cite the four<br />

Crusades, which occurred between 1099 A.D. and 1198 A.D., as evidence <strong>of</strong> Christian hostility <strong>to</strong>ward Islam.<br />

In reality, the Crusades, as brutish as they were, were <strong>of</strong>ten bitter defeats for the Christian forces, and<br />

perhaps the Crusades’ only real contribution <strong>to</strong> his<strong>to</strong>ry was the opening <strong>of</strong> mutually beneficial trade routes,<br />

in our opinion. Fast forward a millennium, and we believe that the modern conflict on both sides is a complex<br />

mix <strong>of</strong> greed, envy, jealousy, righteousness and, at its core, the rivalry between secular and religious<br />

interests that has existed since Christ instructed Peter <strong>to</strong> “Render un<strong>to</strong> Caesar that which is Caesar's, and<br />

un<strong>to</strong> God that which is God’s.” In this section we explore the West versus East non-economic fac<strong>to</strong>rs that<br />

we believe will affect investment and commodity prices in the coming years.<br />

Political and Cultural Differences Between East and West<br />

In general, we believe that the Western model is a secular, capitalist republic with a monotheistic religious<br />

conscience. In our opinion, religion <strong>of</strong>ten functions as an effective <strong>of</strong>fset <strong>to</strong> the self-interest <strong>of</strong> individualistic,<br />

nationalistic societies by alternately acting as a brake and a rudder in the “pursuit <strong>of</strong> happiness,”<br />

one component <strong>of</strong> which is improving secular living standards. In the Western capitalist system, markets<br />

consist <strong>of</strong> consumers and producers for whom the psychology alternates over cycles between fear and<br />

greed. We observe that during periods <strong>of</strong> extreme greed, religion functions as a self-correcting mechanism<br />

by emphasizing charity, and in periods <strong>of</strong> extreme fear, religion provides a moral compass that helps markets<br />

(people) emerge from the economic paralysis associated with a loss <strong>of</strong> hope. <strong>The</strong> exact question <strong>of</strong> the<br />

mix between greed, fear and religion is much like observing a pendulum, in our view, because just how far<br />

an arc may travel before it begins a return is key. But an overwhelming confidence in the ability <strong>of</strong> the selfcorrecting,<br />

pendulum mechanisms <strong>to</strong> work, as they <strong>of</strong>ten do, is a trait <strong>of</strong> Western secular systems.<br />

We believe that the prevailing secular view <strong>of</strong> religious governance is that the latter structure leads <strong>to</strong><br />

a decay <strong>of</strong> material living standards and a loss <strong>of</strong> national ambition. This occurs because the systems <strong>of</strong><br />

religious governance <strong>of</strong>ten subordinate the needs <strong>of</strong> the individual <strong>to</strong> the needs <strong>of</strong> the many, removing the<br />

motivation <strong>of</strong> self-interest, and leaving only the self-correcting mechanisms that normally restrain such motivations.<br />

As a result, some secular adherents view this devolution <strong>of</strong> living standards in a theological dicta<strong>to</strong>rship<br />

as a by-product <strong>of</strong> faith by force, which is little changed from the missteps that contributed <strong>to</strong> the<br />

folly <strong>of</strong> the Crusades and the stagnation <strong>of</strong> the Middle Ages. <strong>The</strong> prevailing secular view from afar may be<br />

that the leaders in a theological dicta<strong>to</strong>rship, with the foibles <strong>of</strong> mortals and the vanity <strong>of</strong> scholars, seek <strong>to</strong><br />

insert themselves as the men between Man and God as arbiters <strong>of</strong> the faith beyond that which is clearly circumscribed<br />

by holy texts (even in the least obtuse Bucaille-based or other quasi-scientific interpretations).<br />

<strong>The</strong> prevailing, Western secular view in this regard is not without experience, as Europe had its own period<br />

<strong>of</strong> theological dicta<strong>to</strong>rship, the bulk <strong>of</strong> which occurred during the Middle Ages, roughly the period between<br />

Saint Augustine’s <strong>The</strong> City <strong>of</strong> God (ca. 426 AD) and Dante Alighieri’s <strong>The</strong> Divine Comedy (ca. 1300 AD).<br />

<strong>The</strong> temporary triumph <strong>of</strong> centralized faith over diffused knowledge that marked the Middle Ages segued <strong>to</strong><br />

the accomplishments <strong>of</strong> the Renaissance, as well as the modern era, if human achievement is the standard <strong>of</strong>


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -80- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

measurement. That experience later became a corners<strong>to</strong>ne <strong>of</strong> the separation <strong>of</strong> church and state in the newly<br />

created United States <strong>of</strong> America almost five centuries later.<br />

In contrast, some adherents <strong>to</strong> religious governance, particularly in the East, believe that religion<br />

serves as a framework for a society rather than the foundation for a philosophy. For example, the Koran<br />

was compiled late enough (ca. the 7th century A.D.) in the development <strong>of</strong> modern civilization <strong>to</strong> serve<br />

as a practical guide for living rather than principally as a guide for moral behavior, and forms the basis <strong>of</strong><br />

the political constitution <strong>of</strong> Saudi Arabia, for example. In practice, advocates <strong>of</strong> religious governance find<br />

the religious way <strong>of</strong> life <strong>to</strong> be a fulfilling, powerful, unifying force, capable <strong>of</strong> focusing the disciplined will<br />

<strong>of</strong> the many on a single goal, rather than the individual, factional, or nationalist diversity <strong>of</strong> interests more<br />

typically associated with secular systems. To some <strong>of</strong> those practitioners, this sense <strong>of</strong> community, order<br />

and personal virtue is worth the admission price <strong>of</strong> lost personal freedom and secular wealth, although his<strong>to</strong>ry<br />

has shown that once the theological dicta<strong>to</strong>rship path is chosen, there is little democratic recourse for<br />

peaceful change if the popular sentiment shifts (which is, in our view, increasingly the case in Iran <strong>to</strong>day,<br />

for example).<br />

Areas <strong>of</strong> Instability in the Political and Cultural Relations Between East and West<br />

Some believers in religious governance feel that powerful secular interests are destabilizing their universal<br />

belief system and undermining the internal order in their societies. Since a society that deemphasizes<br />

the primacy <strong>of</strong> the individual and embraces a universal belief system may also be especially<br />

susceptible <strong>to</strong> crowd psychology, the concept <strong>of</strong> “Holy War” may be an extension <strong>of</strong> this crowd behavior.<br />

Although an emphasis on peace, which is another central tenet <strong>of</strong> some religious systems, may serve as a<br />

counterweight <strong>to</strong> the unruly caprice <strong>of</strong> crowd psychology, it is <strong>of</strong>ten not enough, and where conflict results<br />

there is <strong>of</strong>ten reprisal, leading <strong>to</strong> a downward spiral. In addition, there is also a view among some in the<br />

East that the pervasive influence <strong>of</strong> modern technology, such as the Internet and television, creates a corrupting<br />

influence on their societies. Since the propagation <strong>of</strong> electronic information is guided by physics,<br />

not politics, and his<strong>to</strong>ry has shown that it is virtually impossible <strong>to</strong> put the technology information “genie”<br />

back in<strong>to</strong> the bottle, we doubt that situation will reverse itself. In fact, we observe that the West also struggles<br />

with its own “technology genie” in the form <strong>of</strong> nuclear proliferation.<br />

Overarching the conflict and feeding the extremist flames at the periphery is the lack <strong>of</strong> a satisfac<strong>to</strong>ry<br />

resolution <strong>of</strong> the Israeli/Palestinian issue, which we believe is polarizing the conflict among the masses<br />

on both sides and thus expanding the number <strong>of</strong> extremist combatants. In our view, the lack <strong>of</strong> a resolution<br />

<strong>of</strong> this issue strengthens the hand <strong>of</strong> the radical elements <strong>of</strong> East and West. Since the periphery consists <strong>of</strong><br />

economic disenfranchisement and the evils <strong>of</strong> terrorism in the East, and political proselytizing without the<br />

goal <strong>of</strong> bilateral improvement by the West, such actions fan the flames <strong>of</strong> radicalism and resentment, and,<br />

we believe, raise the risk <strong>of</strong> war.<br />

Although we see no parallels in the past century <strong>to</strong> the current situation, veterans <strong>of</strong> the Cold War<br />

shape policy on the world governmental stage. In fact, veterans <strong>of</strong> the Cold War have lingered or<br />

emerged as political leaders in the East and the West. In a few cases, extremists among them already perceive<br />

the conflict as a “civilization war” <strong>of</strong> absolute dominion, similar <strong>to</strong> the Communist versus Capitalist<br />

struggle. We believe that the error <strong>of</strong> this assumption begins with a comparison <strong>of</strong> Middle Eastern versus<br />

Western characteristics in the context <strong>of</strong> the Cold War. In the latter struggle, the viability <strong>of</strong> “pure” commu-


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -81- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

nism was threatened by the presence <strong>of</strong> capitalism in its midst, making a final resolution inevitable since the<br />

u<strong>to</strong>pian end game <strong>of</strong> pure communism required the abolition <strong>of</strong> private ownership <strong>of</strong> the “means <strong>of</strong> production”<br />

before the state could “wither away.” As a practical matter, we believe that the Soviet communist dicta<strong>to</strong>rship<br />

had no intention <strong>of</strong> withering away, but that did not reduce the necessity that government felt <strong>to</strong><br />

expand globally and eliminate the temptation <strong>of</strong> the “Western way” wherever it was encountered. As a result,<br />

arguments in the 1970s and 1980s among some in the West that there could be no moral absolution for<br />

Communism via détente were genuine, and the resulting vic<strong>to</strong>ry <strong>of</strong> capitalism over communism, as the latter<br />

was originally envisioned, was a hallmark <strong>of</strong> the late 20th century. Given that his<strong>to</strong>ry, we fail <strong>to</strong> see the<br />

similarities between the current conflict and the Cold War. We do not expect the West and East <strong>to</strong> converge<br />

on a common set <strong>of</strong> values for quite some time, if ever, but the key conclusion we draw is that<br />

differences between the East and West do not appear <strong>to</strong> require one system <strong>to</strong> replace the other, either,<br />

except, perhaps, in the minds <strong>of</strong> the extremist periphery.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Fork In <strong>The</strong> Road – Inves<strong>to</strong>rs Are Along For the Ride<br />

This is a new century, and instead <strong>of</strong> an antiquated Cold War model, our focus for investment research<br />

on this subject has been on the new realities <strong>of</strong> Iraq, Israel, Saudi Arabia and the Persian<br />

Gulf. We have described the Saudi power structure as a triumvirate, with political, religious and economic<br />

interests. We have drawn a separate line around Saddam Hussein’s Iraqi government, which appears <strong>to</strong> be<br />

guided by secular, terri<strong>to</strong>rial, and updated “Pan-Arab” goals rather than theological ideals. In this report, we<br />

have discussed the <strong>of</strong>ten self-inflicted Middle Eastern lack <strong>of</strong> prosperity in an economic sense, and the need<br />

for improved governance and reduced corruption in a political sense, while fending <strong>of</strong>f the radical elements<br />

seeking greater political power. Ensuring the vic<strong>to</strong>ry <strong>of</strong> the more moderate voices on both sides would appear<br />

<strong>to</strong> be in the best interest <strong>of</strong> inves<strong>to</strong>rs in both the West and the East, in our view, but <strong>to</strong> do so requires<br />

that the radical elements in both regions be removed from a position <strong>of</strong> power by undermining their appeal<br />

via increased global trade and enlargement <strong>of</strong> the global “economic pie.” Since the U.S. dependence on<br />

Persian Gulf oil is back <strong>to</strong> the highest levels <strong>of</strong> the mid-1970s, and <strong>to</strong>tal U.S. oil import dependence is<br />

at the highest level in his<strong>to</strong>ry, while Persian Gulf regimes are at a political and economic crossroads,<br />

the stakes are raised accordingly. As inves<strong>to</strong>rs we believe that it is necessary <strong>to</strong> be keen, disciplined and<br />

impartial observers. Our investment observation is that we believe that the risk <strong>of</strong> Middle East war is gradually<br />

rising, and major wars in U.S. his<strong>to</strong>ry, without exception, have been inflationary.


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -82- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Appendix A – U.S. <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong>s From a Monetary His<strong>to</strong>ry Perspective, 1898 <strong>to</strong> 2001<br />

No two cycles are ever alike, but as Mark Twain said, they do rhyme. In the following paragraphs, we summarize<br />

the conditions that surrounded the inflation cycles <strong>of</strong> the past century, and describe current similarities.<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> 1898 <strong>to</strong> 1920 <strong>The</strong> years 1898 <strong>to</strong> 1914, before World War I, featured 2.2% annual commodity<br />

inflation, 1.2% annual consumer inflation, and a 3.0% annual price return for the U.S. s<strong>to</strong>ck market. <strong>The</strong> wartime period<br />

as we define it, from 1914 <strong>to</strong> 1920, featured inflation <strong>of</strong> 14.6% per year for commodities, 12.2% consumer inflation and<br />

a 0.1% U.S. annualized s<strong>to</strong>ck market return. <strong>The</strong> 1898 <strong>to</strong> 1914 period <strong>of</strong> even mild inflation without a major war was<br />

unprecedented in U.S. his<strong>to</strong>ry, and the reason most widely accepted was that large gold discoveries and improved mining<br />

technology debased the world’s currency reserve by causing world gold inven<strong>to</strong>ries <strong>to</strong> grow at twice the his<strong>to</strong>rical<br />

rate. For example, U.S. monetary gold holdings increased 220% from 1897 <strong>to</strong> 1914. This peacetime increase in gold<br />

supply as the world reserve currency may be similar <strong>to</strong> the strong peacetime (pre-war?) rate <strong>of</strong> increase in U.S.<br />

money supply since the mid-1990s, since the U.S. dollar is the de fac<strong>to</strong> world reserve currency. When World War I<br />

arrived, the combatants began <strong>to</strong> buy supplies from the U.S., which increased the gold s<strong>to</strong>ck <strong>of</strong> the U.S. <strong>The</strong> normal<br />

wartime diversion <strong>of</strong> production fueled inflation, but the fac<strong>to</strong>r that launched a more robust inflation cycle was the decision<br />

by most <strong>of</strong> the warring parties in Europe <strong>to</strong> suspend the gold standard. Just before the outbreak <strong>of</strong> World War I, the<br />

U.S. Congress creating the Federal Reserve System with a mandate <strong>to</strong> “furnish an elastic currency.” But the new Fed<br />

had as its first task fighting a world war, and did not pursue a restrictive monetary policy in its formative years. Also,<br />

direct U.S. involvement in the war caused large budget deficits in 1918 and 1919. If a future Persian Gulf war were <strong>to</strong><br />

occur, we believe that oil prices, which are dollar-denominated, would increase. U.S. dollars would then have <strong>to</strong> be<br />

furnished by the Fed <strong>to</strong> the strained global financial system, despite the inflationary implications, as the lesser <strong>of</strong><br />

two evils, in our view. In addition, the U.S. would likely experience federal budget deficits. After World War I, several<br />

countries repegged currencies <strong>to</strong> gold at the pre-war level, a fateful decision that was later blamed on the gold standard<br />

when, in reality, it was a misapplication <strong>of</strong> the gold standard <strong>to</strong> attempt <strong>to</strong> turn back time and return <strong>to</strong> pre-war<br />

price levels. In addition, the new Fed authorized higher interest rates in late 1919 and early 1920 because it saw declining<br />

free reserves in the U.S. banking system. Since 1920 also featured a bursting commodity speculation bubble<br />

(Exhibit 10, labeled point “A”) as the last hurrah <strong>of</strong> the inflation cycle, the stage was set for a major recession that year,<br />

and a price deflation concurrent with money supply growth that underpinned a new bull market for s<strong>to</strong>cks from 1921 <strong>to</strong><br />

1929. We observe that the commodity speculation bubble <strong>of</strong> 1920 was an asset price phenomenon that would be repeated<br />

several times in subsequent decades, with commodity price bubbles succeeding wars and preceding deflation<br />

and equity bull markets, and equity price bubbles succeeding peace and preceding inflation and secular bear markets<br />

for the equities that were not inflation beneficiaries.<br />

Deflation from 1921 <strong>to</strong> 1932 then led <strong>to</strong>…<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> 1933 <strong>to</strong> 1951 In the midst <strong>of</strong> the Great Depression, between August 1931 and January 1932, a<br />

<strong>to</strong>tal <strong>of</strong> 1,860 U.S. banks with $1.45 billion <strong>of</strong> deposits failed in a liquidity crisis. <strong>The</strong> Fed had terminated a bank credit<br />

inflation in 1928, but tried desperately from 1929 <strong>to</strong> 1931 <strong>to</strong> ward <strong>of</strong>f the emerging crisis by inflating controlled reserves,<br />

although the Fed was simply out-gunned by the liquidity trap, and the aftermath was a financial calamity. Perhaps<br />

the Fed was distracted by the devaluation <strong>of</strong> the (overvalued) U.K. pound sterling in September 1931, which resulted<br />

in a drain <strong>of</strong> U.S. gold reserves <strong>to</strong> overseas, thereby overshadowing the domestic crisis. After some semblance <strong>of</strong><br />

U.S. banking stability was established, a misguided U.S. government published in 1933 a list <strong>of</strong> banks seeking federal<br />

agency assistance from the Reconstruction Financing Corporation, causing an already-skittish public <strong>to</strong> associate the list<br />

with weakness. Another run on deposits and banking panic ensued, worsening the Great Depression. <strong>The</strong> aggressive<br />

response <strong>of</strong> the Greenspan Fed <strong>to</strong> crises such as Long-Term Capital Management and the Asia Crisis grows directly<br />

out <strong>of</strong> a desire not <strong>to</strong> fall behind the power curve, or be caught in a liquidity trap. It should not be lost on inves<strong>to</strong>rs<br />

that the Fed appears <strong>to</strong> place the support <strong>of</strong> war efforts and/or avoidance <strong>of</strong> financial panic ahead <strong>of</strong> price stability<br />

in its mission hierarchy. We believe a number <strong>of</strong> events launched the inflation cycle <strong>of</strong> 1933 <strong>to</strong> 1951. First, President


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -83- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Franklin D. Roosevelt effectively “nationalized” the U.S. monetary gold supply in 1933, ordering that all (monetary)<br />

gold must be turned in<strong>to</strong> the Federal Reserve System in exchange for $35 per troy ounce <strong>of</strong> U.S. currency. <strong>The</strong>reafter,<br />

the U.S. Mint would buy, but not sell domestically, gold at $35 per ounce. Since this price was a sharp devaluation <strong>of</strong><br />

the U.S. dollar’s prior legal weight in gold, Europe had little choice but <strong>to</strong> follow the U.S. devaluation, since a huge<br />

“avalanche” <strong>of</strong> foreign gold began <strong>to</strong> make its way <strong>to</strong> the U.S., greatly increasing banking reserves. Second, the New<br />

Deal programs increased the role <strong>of</strong> the federal government. And third, the U.S. Supreme Count upheld the 1935 National<br />

Labor Relations Act, enabling workers <strong>to</strong> organize and employ strikes for better wages. As a result, 1933 <strong>to</strong> 1937<br />

featured a 53% increase in the U.S. money s<strong>to</strong>ck, <strong>of</strong>fsetting most <strong>of</strong> the one-third decline in money s<strong>to</strong>ck from 1929 <strong>to</strong><br />

1933. By 1937, U.S. real incomes had recovered <strong>to</strong> a level that was 3% above the 1929 peak, since the preliminary effect<br />

<strong>of</strong> inflationary policies is <strong>to</strong> shrug <strong>of</strong>f the stagnation <strong>of</strong> the prior deflation. But the pursuit <strong>of</strong> unilateral self-interest<br />

by the U.S. and other nations made the world a more dangerous place by the late 1930s, replete with trade and foreign<br />

exchange restrictions, competitive devaluation and rising political extremism in Europe. In the modern period, perhaps<br />

the competitive devaluation <strong>of</strong> the European euro and Japanese yen mark a return <strong>to</strong> economic unilateralism. In<br />

the case <strong>of</strong> Europe, politicians seem unwilling <strong>to</strong> make the structural adjustments <strong>to</strong> avoid reliance on devaluation,<br />

and in the case <strong>of</strong> Japan, a weaker yen appears <strong>to</strong> be an act <strong>of</strong> economic desperation. <strong>The</strong> beginning <strong>of</strong> World War II<br />

in Europe in 1939 produced events similar <strong>to</strong> World War I, with an initial inflow <strong>to</strong> the U.S. <strong>of</strong> gold <strong>to</strong> purchase<br />

goods, and such purchases were later funded by U.S. credit <strong>to</strong> our allies. Monetary policy served the war effort, and U.<br />

S. budget deficits averaged about 30% <strong>of</strong> GNP from 1942 <strong>to</strong> 1945 after the U.S. entered the war. For the entire war period<br />

September 1939 <strong>to</strong> August 1948, the U.S. money s<strong>to</strong>ck rose 12.1% per year, and wholesale prices rose 8.7% per<br />

year. <strong>Inflation</strong> was restrained by price controls from early 1942 <strong>to</strong> mid-1946. Those controls were instituted <strong>to</strong> contain<br />

the sort <strong>of</strong> inflation that had occurred in World War I. But as traditional economic theory would suggest, the side effects<br />

<strong>of</strong> price controls included substitution price differentials, barter, and a thriving black market. After 1948, there was a<br />

revival <strong>of</strong> prudent monetary policy, but the outbreak <strong>of</strong> hostilities in Korea in 1950 triggered a renewed round <strong>of</strong> commodity<br />

inflation and hoarding (Exhibit 10, point labeled “B”). As his<strong>to</strong>rical parallels would suggest, this late stage<br />

speculative blow-<strong>of</strong>f heralded the end <strong>of</strong> the preceding inflation mentality (similar <strong>to</strong> 1920) and the start <strong>of</strong> a deflationary<br />

economic and s<strong>to</strong>ck market boom in the 1950s and early 1960s.<br />

Deflation from 1952 <strong>to</strong> 1964 then led <strong>to</strong>…<br />

<strong>The</strong> Commodity <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> 1965 <strong>to</strong> 1981 In 1944, the Allied Powers economic ministers signed the Bret<strong>to</strong>n<br />

Woods Agreement, so named for the ski resort in New Hampshire at which talks were held. In accordance with the<br />

agreement, from 1947 until the system was abandoned in 1971, the U.S. agreed <strong>to</strong> exchange U.S. dollars for gold at $35<br />

per ounce (for foreign treasury signa<strong>to</strong>ries), and member governments agreed <strong>to</strong> peg their currencies <strong>to</strong> the gold-backed<br />

U.S. dollar. Combined with the U.S. manufacturing and service base that emerged from World War II unscathed, the<br />

primacy <strong>of</strong> U.S. economic and political power was sealed. <strong>The</strong> U.S. enjoyed a golden age <strong>of</strong> power in the 1950s that we<br />

do not believe was seen again until the fall <strong>of</strong> Communism ushered in a similar period <strong>of</strong> hegemony in the 1990s. But,<br />

as his<strong>to</strong>ry has shown, reliance on a “leading” central bank <strong>to</strong> put currency bloc altruistic interests ahead <strong>of</strong> nationalist<br />

interests was a fatal flaw. <strong>The</strong> “Guns and Butter” policy <strong>of</strong> pursuing an aggressive social agenda in the 1960s as part <strong>of</strong><br />

President Johnson’s “Great Society,” while simultaneously fighting a prolonged war in Vietnam, led <strong>to</strong> deficits and a<br />

debasing <strong>of</strong> the U.S. dollar. In a hauntingly similar parallel <strong>to</strong> <strong>to</strong>day, we note that the cost <strong>of</strong> the War on Terrorism is<br />

just beginning <strong>to</strong> rise. Also similar <strong>to</strong> the 1960s, the Great Society cost may pale in comparison <strong>to</strong> the medical and<br />

Social Security costs associated with the aging <strong>of</strong> the Baby Boom generation. By year-end 1965, U.S. capacity utilization<br />

was about 90%, and unemployment was only 4.0% versus the 5.5% average from 1960 <strong>to</strong> 1965. This fullemployment<br />

economy collided with fiscal and monetary stimulus <strong>to</strong> undermine the price stability discipline <strong>of</strong> Bret<strong>to</strong>n<br />

Woods. No longer wishing <strong>to</strong> import U.S. inflation, the U.K. and France teamed up <strong>to</strong> challenge the U.S. by demanding<br />

that their dollars be converted in<strong>to</strong> gold in the summer <strong>of</strong> 1971. In response, President Nixon closed the U.S. gold window<br />

on August 15, 1971, ending the Bret<strong>to</strong>n Woods Agreement, and laying the foundations for the 1970s’ inflation. All<br />

that was missing was a catalyst, and we cite two. First, the wave <strong>of</strong> U.S. Baby Boomers born in 1946 began <strong>to</strong> graduate<br />

from high school in 1964 and college in 1968 or 1970, depending on military service. As each year passed, more<br />

“Boomers” required meaningful employment, which created the political imperative <strong>of</strong> a Phillips Curve full-


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -84- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

employment inflation. Second, the oil embargoes made it impossible <strong>to</strong> <strong>of</strong>fset the inflation <strong>of</strong> dollar-denominated oil,<br />

because any reduction in the value <strong>of</strong> the U.S. dollar simply raised the dollar cost <strong>of</strong> oil. Thus, the great inflation <strong>of</strong> the<br />

1970s began, and from 1965 <strong>to</strong> 1980, the average year-over-year growth rate for U.S. M2 was 8.7%, for the U.S. PPI<br />

all commodities index it was 6.9%, and for the CPI inflation rate it was 6.3%. Arguably, had there not been a Mutually<br />

Assured Destruction (MAD) balance between the U.S. and the Soviet Union, this combination <strong>of</strong> events plus such flareups<br />

as the 1973 Arab-Israeli War (with Syria and Egypt backed by the U.S.S.R) may have led <strong>to</strong> a Third World War.<br />

Instead, the economies <strong>of</strong> the West were forced <strong>to</strong> pay the price for pursuing inflationary policies after the mid-1960s,<br />

and for the folly <strong>of</strong> assuming that imported energy would always be abundant and inexpensive. For this reason, and<br />

given the MAD balance that probably forestalled a broad war, we refer <strong>to</strong> the decade <strong>of</strong> the 1970s as a period <strong>of</strong> global<br />

economic warfare. Relating those events <strong>to</strong> <strong>to</strong>day, we observe that the post-Cold War U.S. economic and military hegemony<br />

in the world has produced losers on the receiving end <strong>of</strong> commodity deflation. It further stands <strong>to</strong> reason<br />

that the response <strong>of</strong> some elements in countries overly reliant on oil prices has been <strong>to</strong> engage in asymmetric warfare<br />

(indirect, terrorist, stateless or informally state-sponsored, opportunistic, and focused) against U.S. interests.<br />

<strong>The</strong> late 1970s featured a typical speculative blow-<strong>of</strong>f for commodity prices (Exhibit 10, point labeled “C”) and inflation,<br />

which, as we have seen, heralded the end <strong>of</strong> the inflation regime and the beginning <strong>of</strong> deflation. By 1980, the<br />

Boomers born in 1957, the latter being the peak year <strong>of</strong> births as a percentage <strong>of</strong> the U.S. population (4.31 million live<br />

births in 1957, 2.51% <strong>of</strong> the population) turned approximately age 23 and entered the workforce if they had chosen <strong>to</strong><br />

go <strong>to</strong> college. Those who had not gone <strong>to</strong> college entered the workforce in the late 1970s, no doubt contributing <strong>to</strong> the<br />

heightened inflation <strong>of</strong> that brief period, in our view. At the same time this demographic (and political) weight was being<br />

lifted in 1980, the unreliability <strong>of</strong>—and economic price umbrella afforded by—OPEC oil was encouraging fuel conservation<br />

and non-OPEC oil exploration and production. New Fed Chairman Paul Volcker, perhaps sensing these<br />

changes, instituted a monetary course that replaced the waning political imperatives <strong>of</strong> the 1970s, and set out <strong>to</strong> break<br />

the back <strong>of</strong> inflation. For the third time in a century, around 1980 a commodity bubble was pierced. Following the major<br />

recession <strong>of</strong> 1981 <strong>to</strong> 1982 a 10-year, disinflationary equity bull market began, and this was later supplemented by<br />

the dual U.S. war vic<strong>to</strong>ries <strong>of</strong> the Cold War and the Gulf War around 1990 <strong>to</strong> 1991, furthering the disinflationary peace<br />

dividend, and stringing <strong>to</strong>gether a 20-year, unprecedented, U.S. equity bull market and a largely unbroken deflation<br />

trend that we believe is now ending.<br />

Deflation from 1982 <strong>to</strong> 2001 then led <strong>to</strong>…


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -85- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Appendix B – Caterpillar, Inc. Data Used <strong>to</strong> Build EVA Model, 1970 <strong>to</strong> 2006E<br />

A B C D = E = F G H I = J = K L<br />

B x C A + B - D F - G - H E / I<br />

Consolidated NOPAT Non- Invested NOPAT<br />

Consolidated Tax Rate % Tax Shield on (Net Inc. + Consolidated Interest Capital ROIC CAT Caterpillar<br />

Net Pr<strong>of</strong>it Net Interest (Some are Net Interest + Int. Expense Total Short-term Bearing (Assets - Cash on Aver. Average Shares<br />

After Expense multi-year Expense - Int. Tax Shield Assets Investments Current Liab. & Eq. - NIBCL) Capital Annual Outstg.<br />

Year Tax $000 $000 averages) $000 $000 $000 & Cash $000 $000 $000 $000 <strong>Price</strong> 000s<br />

1970 $143,785 $37,705 47.2% $17,808 $163,682 $1,798,397 $37,471 $302,907 $1,458,019 11.2% $6.19 341,364<br />

1971 $128,290 $32,334 45.6% $14,748 $145,876 $1,808,759 $49,316 $273,876 $1,485,567 9.9% $8.06 341,676<br />

1972 $206,445 $24,751 43.8% $10,842 $220,354 $1,912,278 $81,248 $394,262 $1,436,768 15.1% $9.89 341,864<br />

1973 $246,845 $29,802 38.2% $11,382 $265,265 $2,232,800 $47,100 $413,300 $1,772,400 16.5% $10.73 342,658<br />

1974 $229,200 $62,400 36.8% $22,989 $268,611 $2,934,000 $80,300 $589,300 $2,264,400 13.3% $9.10 343,242<br />

1975 $398,700 $83,800 38.4% $32,200 $450,300 $3,386,600 $121,300 $712,500 $2,552,800 18.7% $11.02 343,410<br />

1976 $383,200 $78,400 41.0% $32,151 $429,449 $3,893,900 $88,100 $761,300 $3,044,500 15.3% $14.43 344,294<br />

1977 $445,000 $99,800 43.0% $42,900 $501,900 $4,345,600 $209,400 $856,000 $3,280,200 15.9% $13.46 344,906<br />

1978 $566,000 $111,900 41.2% $46,131 $631,769 $5,031,100 $244,500 $1,090,000 $3,696,600 18.1% $13.79 345,262<br />

1979 $492,000 $139,100 33.8% $47,037 $584,063 $5,403,300 $147,200 $923,000 $4,333,100 14.5% $13.94 345,624<br />

1980 $565,000 $173,200 30.1% $52,185 $686,015 $6,098,200 $104,000 $1,265,000 $4,729,200 15.1% $13.59 345,834<br />

1981 $579,000 $224,800 28.5% $64,065 $739,735 $7,284,900 $81,000 $2,194,300 $5,009,600 15.2% $15.14 348,714<br />

1982 $(180,000) $334,000 39.0%Avg. $130,197 $23,803 $7,201,000 $81,000 $974,000 $6,146,000 0.4% $10.32 351,996<br />

1983 $(345,000) $306,000 39.0%Avg. $119,282 ($158,282) $6,968,000 $71,000 $1,223,000 $5,674,000 -2.7% $11.00 369,514<br />

1984 $(428,000) $265,000 39.0%Avg. $103,300 ($266,300) $6,223,000 $62,000 $1,462,000 $4,699,000 -5.1% $9.82 383,680<br />

1985 $198,000 $234,000 12.5% $29,250 $402,750 $6,016,000 $282,000 $1,515,000 $4,219,000 9.0% $8.82 391,168<br />

1986 $76,000 $197,000 23.2% $45,768 $227,232 $6,288,000 $124,000 $1,561,000 $4,603,000 5.2% $11.63 394,508<br />

1987 $350,000 $252,000 25.7% $64,784 $537,216 $7,631,000 $155,000 $1,849,000 $5,627,000 10.5% $13.75 398,672<br />

1988 $616,000 $340,000 31.1% $105,796 $850,204 $9,686,000 $74,000 $2,128,000 $7,484,000 13.0% $15.46 405,642<br />

1989 $497,000 $372,000 26.1% $97,043 $771,957 $10,926,000 $148,000 $2,198,000 $8,580,000 9.6% $14.97 405,668<br />

1990 $210,000 $406,000 29.9% $121,333 $494,667 $11,951,000 $110,000 $2,428,000 $9,413,000 5.5% $12.94 404,960<br />

1991 $(404,000) $469,000 27.2%Avg. $127,595 ($62,595) $12,042,000 $104,000 $2,504,000 $9,434,000 -0.7% $11.99 403,640<br />

1992 $(218,000) $497,000 27.2%Avg. $135,213 $143,787 $13,935,000 $119,000 $2,674,000 $11,142,000 1.4% $13.21 403,736<br />

1993 $652,000 $440,000 27.2%Avg. $119,705 $972,295 $14,807,000 $83,000 $3,138,000 $11,586,000 8.6% $18.60 405,200<br />

1994 $955,000 $410,000 27.8% $114,014 $1,250,986 $16,250,000 $419,000 $3,865,000 $11,966,000 10.6% $27.33 406,383<br />

1995 $1,136,000 $484,000 31.0% $150,145 $1,469,855 $16,830,000 $638,000 $3,613,000 $12,579,000 12.0% $29.70 396,858<br />

1996 $1,361,000 $510,000 31.6% $161,066 $1,709,934 $18,728,000 $487,000 $4,086,000 $14,155,000 12.8% $34.57 384,960<br />

1997 $1,665,000 $580,000 33.0% $191,330 $2,053,670 $20,756,000 $292,000 $4,753,000 $15,711,000 13.8% $48.40 381,000<br />

1998 $1,513,000 $753,000 30.6% $230,333 $2,035,667 $25,128,000 $360,000 $4,897,000 $19,871,000 11.4% $49.82 368,130<br />

1999 $946,000 $829,000 32.0% $265,443 $1,509,557 $26,711,000 $548,000 $4,380,000 $21,783,000 7.2% $52.74 359,181<br />

2000 $1,053,000 $980,000 29.3% $286,688 $1,746,312 $28,464,000 $334,000 $4,835,000 $23,295,000 7.7% $37.90 348,898<br />

2001 $805,000 $942,000 31.4% $295,735 $1,451,265 $30,657,000 $400,000 $4,965,000 $25,292,000 6.0% $48.24 347,092<br />

<strong>2002</strong>E $729,691 $799,704 32.7% $261,162 $1,268,232 $33,659,895 $688,783 $5,385,583 $27,585,529 4.8% $54.92 347,737<br />

2003E $1,106,425 $885,857 32.6% $289,141 $1,703,141 $36,763,202 $114,217 $6,249,744 $30,399,241 5.9% $54.92 347,092<br />

2004E $1,311,783 $959,584 33.3% $319,713 $1,951,653 $40,263,170 $203,588 $7,247,371 $32,812,212 6.2% $54.92 347,092<br />

2005E $1,957,980 $1,105,446 33.0% $364,422 $2,699,005 $44,087,292 $142,614 $7,935,713 $36,008,965 7.8% $54.92 347,092<br />

2006E $2,775,888 $1,155,155 32.8% $378,872 $3,552,171 $48,544,089 $109,564 $8,737,936 $39,696,589 9.4% $54.92 347,092<br />

2007E NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

2008E NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

2009E NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

2010E NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

2011E NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

2012E NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

2013E NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

2014E NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

<strong>2015</strong>E NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

Source: Company reports, Moody’s Industrial Manuals, Legg Mason estimates and projections for <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> 2006E


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -86- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Appendix B – Cont’d., Caterpillar, Inc. Data Used <strong>to</strong> Build EVA Model, 1970 <strong>to</strong> 2006E<br />

M N O P Q = R = S = T = U V = W = X<br />

B / P Q x (1-C) [M/(M+P)] J - S M / U (M+P-G)/<br />

x O U<br />

Forward Consol. +[P/(M+P)]<br />

CAT 10-yr. Consolid. Interest After-Tax x R CAT Avg. CAT Avg. CAT Tot.<br />

Mkt. Val. S&P 500 S&P 500 Gross Rate on Cost <strong>of</strong> CAT Total Annual Annual Net Debt/<br />

<strong>of</strong> Eqty. Yrly. Total Total Ret. Debt Average Debt % EVA Sales & <strong>Price</strong>/ EV/ Mkt. Val.<br />

Year 000s Return = Ke $000 Debt % = Kd WACC % Revs. $000 Sales Mult. Sales Mult. Equity %<br />

1970 $2,113,374 3.9% 5.9% $517,642 7.3% 3.8% 5.5% 5.74% $2,127,751 0.99 1.22 23%<br />

1971 $2,754,761 14.3% 8.5% $504,092 6.3% 3.4% 7.7% 2.21% $2,175,169 1.27 1.48 17%<br />

1972 $3,380,060 19.0% 6.5% $358,039 5.7% 3.2% 6.2% 8.89% $2,602,178 1.30 1.41 8%<br />

1973 $3,677,623 -14.7% 6.7% $482,700 7.1% 4.4% 6.5% 10.07% $3,182,358 1.16 1.29 12%<br />

1974 $3,121,951 -26.4% 10.7% $881,200 9.2% 5.8% 9.6% 3.72% $4,082,100 0.76 0.96 26%<br />

1975 $3,785,259 37.2% 14.8% $913,400 9.3% 5.8% 13.1% 5.64% $4,963,700 0.76 0.92 21%<br />

1976 $4,969,249 23.9% 14.3% $1,094,000 7.8% 4.6% 12.6% 2.76% $5,042,300 0.99 1.19 20%<br />

1977 $4,643,656 -7.2% 13.9% $1,110,900 9.1% 5.2% 12.2% 3.70% $5,848,900 0.79 0.95 19%<br />

1978 $4,762,638 6.6% 15.3% $1,164,900 9.8% 5.8% 13.4% 4.69% $7,219,200 0.66 0.79 19%<br />

1979 $4,818,035 18.6% 16.3% $1,415,100 10.8% 7.1% 14.2% 0.31% $7,613,200 0.63 0.80 26%<br />

1980 $4,701,181 32.5% 17.5% $1,378,200 12.4% 8.7% 15.5% (0.39%) $8,603,000 0.55 0.69 27%<br />

1981 $5,280,656 -4.9% 13.9% $1,808,500 14.1% 10.1% 12.9% 2.25% $9,160,000 0.58 0.77 33%<br />

1982 $3,633,625 21.6% 17.6% $2,612,000 15.1% 9.2% 14.1% (13.66%) $6,472,000 0.56 0.95 70%<br />

1983 $4,065,616 22.6% 16.2% $2,247,000 12.6% 7.7% 13.1% (15.82%) $5,429,000 0.75 1.15 54%<br />

1984 $3,767,858 6.3% 14.9% $1,861,000 12.9% 7.9% 12.6% (17.72%) $6,597,000 0.57 0.84 48%<br />

1985 $3,450,224 31.7% 14.4% $1,404,000 14.3% 12.5% 13.8% (4.80%) $6,760,000 0.51 0.68 33%<br />

1986 $4,587,183 18.7% 14.9% $1,582,000 13.2% 10.1% 13.6% (8.49%) $7,380,000 0.62 0.82 32%<br />

1987 $5,480,702 5.2% 15.3% $2,196,000 13.3% 9.9% 13.7% (3.23%) $8,294,000 0.66 0.91 37%<br />

1988 $6,272,662 16.6% 18.0% $3,260,000 12.5% 8.6% 14.8% (1.83%) $10,435,000 0.60 0.91 51%<br />

1989 $6,072,343 31.6% 19.2% $3,994,000 10.3% 7.6% 14.6% (4.97%) $11,126,000 0.55 0.89 63%<br />

1990 $5,240,225 -3.1% 18.2% $4,721,000 9.3% 6.5% 12.7% (7.17%) $11,436,000 0.46 0.86 88%<br />

1991 $4,838,424 30.4% 17.4% $5,247,000 9.4% 6.9% 11.9% (12.60%) $10,182,000 0.48 0.98 106%<br />

1992 $5,333,731 7.6% 12.9% $5,672,000 9.1% 6.6% 9.7% (8.28%) $10,194,000 0.52 1.07 104%<br />

1993 $7,537,353 10.1% 13.1% $5,428,000 7.9% 5.8% 10.0% (1.47%) $11,615,000 0.65 1.11 71%<br />

1994 $11,104,627 1.3% 12.9% $5,903,000 7.2% 5.2% 10.3% 0.36% $14,328,000 0.78 1.16 49%<br />

1995 $11,785,856 37.5% 13.7% $6,400,000 7.9% 5.4% 10.8% 1.21% $16,072,000 0.73 1.09 49%<br />

1996 $13,309,190 22.9% 10.9% $7,459,000 7.4% 5.0% 8.8% 4.01% $16,522,000 0.81 1.23 52%<br />

1997 $18,438,765 33.4% 9.3% $8,568,000 7.2% 4.9% 7.9% 5.84% $18,949,000 0.97 1.41 45%<br />

1998 $18,338,404 28.6% 6.9% $12,452,000 7.2% 5.0% 6.1% 5.33% $21,089,000 0.87 1.44 66%<br />

1999 $18,943,030 21.0% 4.8% $13,802,000 6.3% 4.3% 4.6% 2.68% $19,836,000 0.95 1.62 70%<br />

2000 $13,221,780 -9.1% 3.3% $15,067,000 6.8% 4.8% 4.1% 3.66% $20,378,000 0.65 1.37 111%<br />

2001 $16,744,295 -11.9% 4.7% $16,602,000 5.9% 4.1% 4.4% 1.58% $20,672,000 0.81 1.59 97%<br />

<strong>2002</strong>E $19,097,716 9.2% 6.4% $17,231,595 4.7% 3.2% 4.9% (0.10%) $20,283,690 0.94 1.76 87%<br />

2003E $19,062,293 8.6% 5.9% $18,523,643 5.0% 3.3% 4.6% 1.25% $21,503,665 0.89 1.74 97%<br />

2004E $19,062,293 8.0% 5.3% $19,692,760 5.0% 3.3% 4.3% 1.86% $23,786,587 0.80 1.62 102%<br />

2005E $19,062,293 7.4% 4.8% $21,874,171 5.3% 3.6% 4.1% 3.69% $26,372,535 0.72 1.55 114%<br />

2006E $19,062,293 6.8% 4.4% $23,293,352 5.1% 3.4% 3.9% 5.52% $28,887,074 0.66 1.46 122%<br />

2007E NA 6.3% NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

2008E NA 5.3% NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

2009E NA 4.8% NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

2010E NA 4.3% NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

2011E NA 3.9% NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

2012E NA 3.4% NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

2013E NA 3.0% NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

2014E NA 3.0% NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

<strong>2015</strong>E NA 3.0% NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA NA<br />

Source: Company reports, Moody’s Industrial Manuals, Legg Mason estimates and projections for <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> 2006E


Industrial Portfolio Strategy<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Inflation</strong> <strong>Cycle</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>2002</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>2015</strong> ⎯ April 19, <strong>2002</strong> -87- Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.<br />

Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc. makes a market in the shares <strong>of</strong> Joy Global, Inc.<br />

Additional information is available upon request<br />

<strong>The</strong> information contained herein has been prepared from sources believed <strong>to</strong> be reliable but is not guaranteed by us<br />

and is not a complete summary or statement <strong>of</strong> all available data, nor is it considered an <strong>of</strong>fer <strong>to</strong> buy or sell and securities<br />

referenced herein. Opinions expressed are subject <strong>to</strong> change without notice and do not take in<strong>to</strong> account the particular<br />

investment objectives, financial situation or needs <strong>of</strong> individual inves<strong>to</strong>rs. No investments or services mentioned<br />

are available in the European Economic Area <strong>to</strong> “private cus<strong>to</strong>mers” or <strong>to</strong> anyone in Canada other than a<br />

“Designated Institution.” From time <strong>to</strong> time, Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc. and/or its employees involved in the<br />

preparation or issuance <strong>of</strong> the communication may have positions in the securities or options <strong>of</strong> the recommended issuer.<br />

© Copyright <strong>2002</strong> Legg Mason Wood Walker, Inc.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!