17.05.2015 Views

the common market of the austro-hungarian monarchy

the common market of the austro-hungarian monarchy

the common market of the austro-hungarian monarchy

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

László Katus<br />

THE COMMON MARKET OF<br />

THE AUSTRO-HUNGARIAN<br />

MONARCHY<br />

The Compromise (Act 12 <strong>of</strong> 1867) having determined<br />

<strong>the</strong> joint affairs affecting <strong>the</strong> lands <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hungarian Crown and<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> countries represented in <strong>the</strong> Imperial Council and <strong>the</strong> mechanism<br />

<strong>of</strong> dealing with <strong>the</strong>m, continues thus:<br />

There are o<strong>the</strong>r greatly important public affairs <strong>the</strong> joint<br />

aspects <strong>of</strong> which are not derived from <strong>the</strong> Pragmatica Sanctio but<br />

which partly because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> situation and <strong>the</strong> political perspective<br />

and partly because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> overlap <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> interests <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> two parties<br />

would be more appropriately administered jointly than strictly separately.…The<br />

joint aspects <strong>of</strong> commercial matters also are not<br />

derived from <strong>the</strong> Pragmatica Sanctio because according to it <strong>the</strong><br />

lands <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hungarian Crown, being legally separate countries<br />

from <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r countries <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> prince can make decisions through<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir own responsible government and legislature and can regulate<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir commercial affairs by <strong>the</strong>ir own duty alignments. Because,<br />

however, <strong>the</strong>re are important and numerous mutual connections<br />

between Hungary and His Majesty’s o<strong>the</strong>r lands <strong>the</strong> legislature is<br />

prepared to have customs and commercial unions arranged, from<br />

time to time, between <strong>the</strong> lands <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hungarian Crown and His<br />

Majesty’s o<strong>the</strong>r lands.…The union would be set by joint negotiations<br />

in such a fashion that <strong>the</strong>re would be similar arrangements<br />

between <strong>the</strong> two independent countries.…On this occasion as<br />

well…by agreement <strong>the</strong> rules about <strong>the</strong> nature, uniform ratios, and


22 LÁSZLÓ KATUS<br />

management <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> taxes linked to industrial productions shall be<br />

established so that <strong>the</strong> possibility <strong>of</strong> unilateral decisions <strong>of</strong> a<br />

responsible government or legislature leading to a decrease in <strong>the</strong><br />

revenues <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r party be excluded. The methodology will<br />

also be determined for <strong>the</strong> future so that any reforms to be instituted<br />

about <strong>the</strong>se taxes will be decided by <strong>the</strong> two legislatures by<br />

mutual understanding.<br />

The law also stated, “It is desirable and important for both parties<br />

that <strong>the</strong> monetary system and money rates be identical in <strong>the</strong> countries<br />

belonging to <strong>the</strong> customs union.”<br />

It was on this basis that <strong>the</strong> commercial and customs union was<br />

arranged between <strong>the</strong> two countries and enacted as Act 16 <strong>of</strong> 1867.<br />

Accordingly, “For <strong>the</strong> duration <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> alliance <strong>the</strong> national territory <strong>of</strong><br />

both parties…constitutes a single customs and commercial territory,<br />

which is surrounded by a <strong>common</strong> customs boundary.” The two countries<br />

jointly determined <strong>the</strong> customs duties to be charged and also<br />

entered into commercial agreements with o<strong>the</strong>r countries on <strong>the</strong> basis<br />

<strong>of</strong> mutual understanding. A number <strong>of</strong> economic issues had to be regulated<br />

and administrated by <strong>the</strong> two countries as a joint endeavor.<br />

These included issues <strong>of</strong> importance to both countries, such as railroads,<br />

rivers and maritime navigation, mail and telegraph service, measures<br />

and weights, and copyright.<br />

The income from salt and tobacco and those indirect taxes<br />

which directly affect industrial production, namely taxes on liquor,<br />

beer, and sugar, will be handled during <strong>the</strong> existence <strong>of</strong> this act in<br />

both countries by equal ordinances and administrative regulations…patents<br />

on inventions will be valid in both countries….The<br />

inhabitants <strong>of</strong> one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> national territories who wish to engage in<br />

commerce or industry in <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r territory, or seek employment in<br />

that territory will be treated exactly <strong>the</strong> same way as <strong>the</strong> residents<br />

<strong>of</strong> that territory so far as starting or maintaining a business or <strong>the</strong><br />

taxes to be paid and…will enjoy complete equality before <strong>the</strong> law.<br />

In order to harmonize <strong>the</strong> economic policies to be established in<br />

<strong>the</strong>se matters customs and commercial conferences were held from


THE COMMON MARKET 23<br />

time to time. The customs and commercial agreements were made for<br />

a period <strong>of</strong> ten years but after five years ei<strong>the</strong>r party could initiate negotiations<br />

for <strong>the</strong>ir modification. If <strong>the</strong>se discussions proved unsuccessful<br />

<strong>the</strong> alliance could be canceled.<br />

The treaty stated that, “Until changed by law, <strong>the</strong> Austrian currency<br />

remain joint asset.” The Compromise did not address <strong>the</strong> central bank<br />

issue and only stated that <strong>the</strong> monetary system was one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> matters <strong>of</strong><br />

“<strong>common</strong> interest.” In <strong>the</strong>ory, Hungary had <strong>the</strong> right to establish its own<br />

central bank. The Hungarian government and legislature did not accept<br />

<strong>the</strong> validity <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1862 Bank Act but for <strong>the</strong> time being accepted <strong>the</strong><br />

existing situation and <strong>the</strong> monopoly position <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Austrian National<br />

Bank. On September 12, 1867, in Vöslau, <strong>the</strong> Austrian and Hungarian<br />

ministers <strong>of</strong> finance signed an agreement according to which <strong>the</strong> Hungarian<br />

minister committed himself that until <strong>the</strong> two countries, by joint<br />

agreement, regulated <strong>the</strong> monetary system <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy, Hungary<br />

would not establish a separate central bank and would accept <strong>the</strong><br />

imposed use <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> banknotes issued by <strong>the</strong> Austrian National Bank.<br />

After <strong>the</strong> Compromise <strong>the</strong> situation <strong>of</strong> Hungary took a significant<br />

improvement in <strong>the</strong> economic community <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> empire. It was no<br />

longer in a dependent position and became a partner with equal rights<br />

and equal rank. The unified customs area <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> centralized empire<br />

became a customs union <strong>of</strong> two economically independent and sovereign<br />

countries, designed for a specified period <strong>of</strong> time, voluntary and<br />

subject to cancellation.<br />

One month after his appointment as prime minister, in November<br />

1875 Kálmán Tisza abrogated <strong>the</strong> commercial and customs alliance in<br />

order to achieve changes favorable for Hungary in three areas. These<br />

were: that excise taxes be paid in <strong>the</strong> country where <strong>the</strong> item was consumed<br />

and not <strong>the</strong> country where it was produced, that <strong>the</strong> import<br />

duties (<strong>the</strong> so called fiscal duties) on items not produced in <strong>the</strong> Monarchy<br />

be raised, and <strong>the</strong> central bank be reorganized according to <strong>the</strong><br />

principles <strong>of</strong> Dualism and parity. The Austrians were primarily seeking<br />

a raise in <strong>the</strong> industrial custom duties. The difficult negotiations<br />

dragged on for more than one year and finally an agreement was<br />

reached in February 1877, which met only some <strong>of</strong> Tisza’s demands.<br />

The Austrian National Bank was reorganized on a Dualist basis as <strong>the</strong><br />

Austro-Hungarian Bank, with two identical principal branches, one in


24 LÁSZLÓ KATUS<br />

Vienna and one in Budapest. Parity was accomplished only partially.<br />

The fiscal duties were raised but in <strong>the</strong> matter <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> excise taxes <strong>the</strong><br />

situation, unfavorable for Hungary, could not be changed (Act 20 <strong>of</strong><br />

1878). In exchange for raising <strong>the</strong> industrial duties <strong>the</strong> Austrians<br />

agreed to raise <strong>the</strong> import duties on agricultural products. In Act 25,<br />

1878, <strong>the</strong> Hungarian legislature accepted <strong>the</strong> status <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Austro-Hungarian<br />

Bank and its monopoly <strong>of</strong> issuing <strong>the</strong> banknotes.<br />

The new agreement contained an important new clause: “A joint<br />

stock company legally established in one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> countries, insurance<br />

companies, commercial or industrial associations (Erwerbs- und<br />

Wirtschaft-Genossenschaften) may extend <strong>the</strong>ir activities to <strong>the</strong> territory<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r country and establish a branch <strong>the</strong>re. In such situation<br />

<strong>the</strong>y shall be deemed to be equivalent to <strong>the</strong> domestic establishments.”<br />

For <strong>the</strong> implementation and <strong>the</strong> rules governing <strong>the</strong> above a separate<br />

agreement was made (Act 22 <strong>of</strong> 1878).<br />

In 1887 <strong>the</strong> commercial and customs union was extended without<br />

any difficulty and so were <strong>the</strong> privileges <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Austro-Hungarian Bank.<br />

In 1897, <strong>the</strong> paralysis <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> legislature in Vienna made this impossible<br />

and <strong>the</strong>refore <strong>the</strong> treaty and <strong>the</strong> banking privileges were extended only<br />

for one year. In 1898 <strong>the</strong> Hungarian Bánffy government and <strong>the</strong> Austrian<br />

Thun government reached an agreement concerning <strong>the</strong> details <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

commercial treaty. This agreement was beneficial for Hungary because<br />

<strong>the</strong> Hungarian point <strong>of</strong> view could prevail in two areas which had been<br />

turned down when requested by <strong>the</strong> Tisza government in 1877–1878.<br />

Austria agreed that <strong>the</strong>re would be parity between <strong>the</strong> two countries<br />

within <strong>the</strong> Austro-Hungarian Bank and also that <strong>the</strong> excise taxes would<br />

be paid in <strong>the</strong> country where <strong>the</strong> goods were used or consumed. The<br />

Austrian government agreed to raise <strong>the</strong> agricultural import duties but<br />

demanded that <strong>the</strong> quota, i.e. <strong>the</strong> Hungarian share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> costs <strong>of</strong> joint<br />

endeavors, be raised. Because <strong>the</strong> Austrian legislature still could not<br />

deal with <strong>the</strong> commercial treaty, <strong>the</strong> two governments agreed that it<br />

would be arbitrarily extended until <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> 1903 <strong>the</strong> expiration date<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> international commercial treaties. They also agreed that if by <strong>the</strong>n<br />

no new agreement could be reached, <strong>the</strong> 1887 agreement would continue<br />

to remain in place.<br />

Kálmán Széll, <strong>the</strong> new prime minister appointed at <strong>the</strong> beginning<br />

<strong>of</strong> 1899 published <strong>the</strong> legal formula, known by his name, according to


THE COMMON MARKET 25<br />

which “because a customs and commercial treaty had not been generated<br />

between <strong>the</strong> lands <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hungarian Crown and <strong>the</strong> kingdoms represented<br />

in <strong>the</strong> Imperial Council, a legal status <strong>of</strong> an independent customs<br />

area came into existence for <strong>the</strong> lands <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hungarian Crown.”<br />

He continued to maintain, however, <strong>the</strong> economic community. The<br />

Széll formula was entered into Act 30 <strong>of</strong> 1899, which extended <strong>the</strong><br />

existing commercial agreement until 1907. The act also prescribed<br />

that before a new international commercial treaties could be established<br />

a new autonomous customs tariff system had to be set up for <strong>the</strong><br />

Monarchy. The privileges <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> bank were extended until <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong><br />

1910, changing <strong>the</strong> charter <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> bank in Hungary’s favor. In 1902<br />

negotiations between <strong>the</strong> two governments about a new commercial<br />

and customs union started again. Under pressure from <strong>the</strong> agricultural<br />

sector, <strong>the</strong> Hungarians demanded a substantial increase in <strong>the</strong> agricultural<br />

customs duties but in exchange for this <strong>the</strong>y were forced to<br />

accept an increase in <strong>the</strong> industrial customs duties. On New Year’s Eve<br />

in 1902 an agreement was reached between <strong>the</strong> two governments<br />

about a new commercial and customs alliance and about <strong>the</strong> basic<br />

principles <strong>of</strong> a new, autonomous customs duty system. This was<br />

known as <strong>the</strong> Széll-Körber Pact. This agreement, based on <strong>the</strong> results<br />

achieved at <strong>the</strong> 1898 negotiations, was recognized even by <strong>the</strong> opposition<br />

coalition that from a Hungarian perspective it was <strong>the</strong> best<br />

arrangement since 1867. The practical implementation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> agreement<br />

had to be postponed for a few years because due to <strong>the</strong> 1903<br />

domestic policy crisis in Hungary, <strong>the</strong> Hungarian legislature could not<br />

address this matter.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> agreement made with <strong>the</strong> ruler in April 1906 <strong>the</strong> opposition<br />

coalition gave up its previous demand for an independent customs area<br />

and agreed to enact into law <strong>the</strong> commercial contracts and <strong>the</strong> new<br />

customs tariff. It agreed that even if <strong>the</strong> agreement with <strong>the</strong> Austrian<br />

government could not be reached it would maintain <strong>the</strong> united customs<br />

area until <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> 1917, when <strong>the</strong> international commercial<br />

treaties would expire. The new agreement was reached after many<br />

months <strong>of</strong> negotiations in October 1907 and was based on <strong>the</strong> Széll-<br />

Körber Pact. A new feature in <strong>the</strong> agreement was <strong>the</strong> change that <strong>the</strong><br />

two countries henceforth would not be in alliance but would have a<br />

contract with each o<strong>the</strong>r (Act 12 <strong>of</strong> 1908).


26 LÁSZLÓ KATUS<br />

In <strong>the</strong> actual practice <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economic community <strong>the</strong>re were<br />

numerous problems and difficulties. The foreign trade interests <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

two geographically, economically, and developmentally different countries<br />

were difficult to harmonize when <strong>the</strong> customs tariffs had to be<br />

determined or during commercial negotiations with foreign countries.<br />

There were also frequent disagreements when <strong>the</strong> domestic economicpolitical<br />

issues had to be brought into harmony.<br />

In 1878, after <strong>the</strong> most serious economic crisis <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Dualist era,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Commerce Committee <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hungarian National Assembly<br />

believed that, “<strong>the</strong> customs unity did not hamper <strong>the</strong> economic advances<br />

<strong>of</strong> our country, but, in fact, was a major factor in its favor.” 1<br />

The supporters <strong>of</strong> a <strong>common</strong> customs area pointed out <strong>the</strong> advantages<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> wide imperial <strong>market</strong> for <strong>the</strong> development <strong>of</strong> a modern<br />

economy and for <strong>the</strong> implementation <strong>of</strong> modern technical advances.<br />

The great advantage <strong>of</strong> a larger area <strong>of</strong> business activities is<br />

that <strong>the</strong>y make <strong>the</strong> development <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> particular areas and countries<br />

possible in <strong>the</strong> direction where it is <strong>the</strong> most practical and<br />

where it can take best advantage <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> natural conditions thus making<br />

it possible for <strong>the</strong> individual areas to develop <strong>the</strong>ir nature-given<br />

advantages to <strong>the</strong> fullest and most pr<strong>of</strong>itable extent.…The <strong>common</strong><br />

and united customs area <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Austro-Hungarian Monarchy was,<br />

without a doubt, beneficial for <strong>the</strong> economic well being <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> two<br />

different but interdependent parts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy. 2<br />

This argument was endorsed by historic growth. The <strong>common</strong> customs<br />

area where, in principle, <strong>the</strong>re was an unfettered competition and<br />

1 “A képviselŒház vám és kereskedelemügyi bizottságának jelentése a vám- és kereskedelemi<br />

szövettségrŒl szóló törvényjavaslatról” [Report <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Custom and Commerce Committee<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> House <strong>of</strong> Representatives on <strong>the</strong> bill on <strong>the</strong> customs and commerce union], in Az 1875.<br />

évi augusztus hó 28-ra hirdetett országgyŠlés képviselŒházának irományai [Papers <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

House <strong>of</strong> Representatives <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> National Assembly Convened on August 28, 1875] (Budapest,<br />

1878), vol. 21, p. 342.<br />

2 “Miniszteri elŒterjesztés a vám- s kereskedelmi szövetségrŒl szóló törvényjavaslathoz”<br />

[Ministerial proposal on <strong>the</strong> bill on <strong>the</strong> customs and commercial union], in Az 1875-ik évi<br />

augusztus hó 28-ára kihirdetett országgyŠlés fŒrendi házának irományai [Papers <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> August<br />

28, 1875, Upper House Session <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> National Assembly] (Budapest: 1878), vol. 8, pp. 167<br />

and 171.


THE COMMON MARKET 27<br />

free trade, gave both countries <strong>the</strong> opportunity to develop those branches<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir economy in which <strong>the</strong>y were in an advantageous position<br />

and specialized on <strong>the</strong> production <strong>of</strong> those products for which <strong>the</strong>y<br />

were particularly well suited. In <strong>the</strong> trade between <strong>the</strong> two parts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

Monarchy <strong>the</strong> comparative advantages, granted by <strong>the</strong> natural, historical,<br />

and structural differences, could become manifest.<br />

The creators <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Compromise considered <strong>the</strong> most important<br />

activity <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> subsequent decades to be to make up in all areas for <strong>the</strong><br />

deficiencies <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> past centuries and to move up to <strong>the</strong> level <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

leading European countries or, at least, to <strong>the</strong> level <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> western parts<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy. “We have accepted <strong>the</strong> principle <strong>of</strong> free trade and its<br />

consequence <strong>of</strong> free competition and believed that <strong>the</strong> nation would not<br />

acquiesce in <strong>the</strong> areas where it was left behind and would do everything<br />

to catch up with its neighbors,” stated István Gorove, minister <strong>of</strong> agriculture,<br />

industry, and commerce. 3<br />

Let us examine more closely <strong>the</strong> economic areas in which Hungary<br />

lagged behind Austria and let us attempt to answer <strong>the</strong> question how<br />

much progress and catching-up had been achieved during <strong>the</strong> fifty<br />

years <strong>of</strong> Dualism. In what follows Hungary means <strong>the</strong> lands <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

Hungarian Crown, including Croatia, <strong>the</strong> pre-Compromise Transylvania,<br />

and <strong>the</strong> Military Frontier. The Hungarian data should not be compared<br />

to <strong>the</strong> Austrian because <strong>the</strong> Austrian averages do not reflect <strong>the</strong><br />

significant developmental differences between <strong>the</strong> Hereditary<br />

Provinces and <strong>the</strong> eastern and sou<strong>the</strong>rn border areas, namely Galicia,<br />

Bukovina, and Dalmatia. The last joined <strong>the</strong> Habsburg empire only at<br />

<strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> eighteenth century. Therefore, in our analyses wherever<br />

<strong>the</strong> data permit it, we will divide <strong>the</strong> Austrian averages into <strong>the</strong> Hereditary<br />

Provinces, i.e. <strong>the</strong> fourteen countries and provinces to <strong>the</strong> west <strong>of</strong><br />

Hungary and <strong>the</strong> three provinces to <strong>the</strong> east and south. Hungary’s economic<br />

developmental status was in <strong>the</strong> middle between <strong>the</strong> Hereditary<br />

Provinces and <strong>the</strong> three border territories.<br />

3 Az 1865. évi deczember 10-ikére kihirdetett országgyŠlés képviselŒházának naplója [Journal<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> House <strong>of</strong> Representatives <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> National Assembly Convened on December 10,<br />

1865] (Pest: Emich G. Nyomda, 1868), vol. 6, p. 172.


28 LÁSZLÓ KATUS<br />

It is clear that in agriculture Hungary was on <strong>the</strong> same level as <strong>the</strong><br />

Hereditary Provinces and in some aspects was even ahead <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m.<br />

According to a contemporary study dividing <strong>the</strong> total revenues from<br />

agriculture and forestry would provide each resident in both Austria and<br />

Hungary with approximately 77 forints. The area <strong>of</strong> mining shows a difference.<br />

In all <strong>of</strong> Austria each inhabitant would receive 1.65 forint, in<br />

<strong>the</strong> Hereditary Provinces <strong>the</strong>y would receive 2.29 forints and in Hungary<br />

only 0.92 forint. 4<br />

The differences between agriculture and industry were shown<br />

clearly in <strong>the</strong> 1863 imperial steam engine statistics. According to <strong>the</strong>se<br />

<strong>the</strong>re were 203 steam engines actively engaged in Hungarian agriculture<br />

(except for two steam plows all worked as threshing machines)<br />

with a total energy output <strong>of</strong> 1,661 horsepowers, while in Austria <strong>the</strong>re<br />

were only 18 machines with an energy output <strong>of</strong> 147 horsepowers. In<br />

Fehér County alone more engines were used than in all <strong>of</strong> Austria. In<br />

agricultural mechanization Hungary was thus well ahead <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> areas<br />

west <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Leitha River. In industry <strong>the</strong> situation was precisely <strong>the</strong><br />

opposite. In Austria 2,759 steam engines were engaged in mining and<br />

industry with an energy output <strong>of</strong> 45,948 horsepowers. In <strong>the</strong> lands <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> Hungarian Crown <strong>the</strong> totals were 506 machines with 8,588 horsepowers.<br />

5<br />

4 J. Fillunger, Vergleichende Statistik über die Real- und Productionswerte der Landwirtschaft,<br />

der Montanindustrie, des Verkehrs- und Communications-Anstalten, dann<br />

Erörterung des Staatshaushaltes in österreichischen Kaiserstaate (Vienna: Selbstverl., 1868),<br />

tables 16, 34, and 40.<br />

5 Statitisches Jahrbuch der Österreichischen Monarchie für das Jahr 1863 (Vienna, 1864),<br />

pp. 173–178, 197–200, and 205–234.


THE COMMON MARKET 29<br />

TABLE 1. Steam Engines in Industry and Mining in 1863<br />

Per<br />

Index<br />

100,000 inhabitants (Austria=100)<br />

Machine Horsepower Machine Horsepower<br />

Austria 13.65 227.27 100 100<br />

Hereditary Provinces 19.05 315.25 140 139<br />

Galicia, Bukovina, Dalm. 1.9 36.14 14 16<br />

Hungary 3.29 55.9 24 25<br />

The 1862 tax statistics give us a detailed description <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> relative<br />

level <strong>of</strong> development <strong>of</strong> industry and <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> various branches <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> service<br />

sector in <strong>the</strong> individual countries, territories and regions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

Monarchy. These statistics included all non-agricultural revenues and<br />

extended to all independent business men, from <strong>the</strong> artisans, door-todoor<br />

salesmen and postmasters to <strong>the</strong> major industrialists and merchants,<br />

banks, and railway companies. The statistics contain <strong>the</strong> taxes<br />

paid by nearly one million tax payers divided into 43 groups and 1,300<br />

occupations. The first volume presents <strong>the</strong> industrial areas and <strong>the</strong> second<br />

volume includes all non-agricultural activities under <strong>the</strong> title <strong>of</strong><br />

Commerzialgewerbe and extends to commerce, credit, transportation,<br />

healthcare, independent intellectual occupations, and <strong>the</strong> various service<br />

functions. 6 The number <strong>of</strong> taxpayers per 1,000 <strong>of</strong> population gives<br />

a good indication <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> incidence <strong>of</strong> non-agriculturalist taxpayers. The<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> taxes paid per 1,000 members <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> population indicates <strong>the</strong><br />

relative level <strong>of</strong> development <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> non-agrarian sectors because <strong>the</strong><br />

taxes assessed were proportional to <strong>the</strong> income. In Austria <strong>the</strong>re were<br />

36.23 such taxpayers per 1,000 members <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> population while in <strong>the</strong><br />

lands <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hungarian Crown <strong>the</strong> number was less than half at 17.05.<br />

The difference <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> taxes paid was much greater. In Austria<br />

it was 690 forints and in Hungary only 182 forints. The difference<br />

between <strong>the</strong> two categories indicates that <strong>the</strong> Hungarian taxpayers had<br />

6 Die steuerpflichtigen Gewerbe des österreichischen Kaiserstaates im Jahre 1862, vol. 1,<br />

Industrial-Gewerbe, vol. 2, Commerzial-Gewerbe (Vienna, 1865–1866) [Mit<strong>the</strong>ilungen aus<br />

dem Gebiete der Statistik 12, nos. 1 and 4].


30 LÁSZLÓ KATUS<br />

substantially lower incomes than <strong>the</strong>ir neighbors beyond <strong>the</strong> Leitha<br />

River. It can also be seen from <strong>the</strong>se data that industry in Hungary was<br />

relatively more developed than were commerce and <strong>the</strong> service sectors.<br />

TABLE 2. Taxes Paid in Non-Agricultural Occupations in 1862<br />

Handicraft Industry Commerce Total<br />

Manufacturing credit, transp. non-agriculture<br />

industry all o<strong>the</strong>r serv. activity<br />

Per 1,000 Per 1,000 Per 1,000<br />

Taxpayers Tax Taxp. Tax Taxp. Tax.<br />

Austria 18.60 246 17.62 444 36.23 690<br />

Hered. Prov. 24.51 337 20.61 574 45.12 911<br />

Galicia, etc. 5.19 40 10.84 148 16.03 187<br />

Hungary 10.14 71 7.71 111 17.85 182<br />

Indexes (Austria = 100)<br />

Austria 100 100 100 100 100 100<br />

Hered. Prov. 132 137 117 129 125 132<br />

Galicia, etc. 28 16 62 33 44 27<br />

Hungary 54 29 44 25 49 26<br />

We get a similar picture about <strong>the</strong> relative underdevelopment <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

Hungarian non-agrarian sectors from <strong>the</strong> 1869–1870 census employment<br />

data.<br />

TABLE 3. 1869–1870 Census Data on Employment in <strong>the</strong> Industrial Sector<br />

Ratio <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> employees as a percent <strong>of</strong> all wage earners<br />

Austria Hered. Prov. Galicia, etc Hungary<br />

Industry, mining 20.13 25.57 6.22 9.55<br />

Commerce, etc. 3.36 3.59 2.79 1.83


THE COMMON MARKET 31<br />

Employees in <strong>the</strong> given sector per 1,000/ population<br />

Industry, mining 117.6 156.0 34.9 45.2<br />

Commerce, etc. 19.7 21.5 15.7 8.7<br />

Indexes (Austria = 100)<br />

Industry, mining 100 133 27 38<br />

Commerce, etc. 100 109 80 44<br />

The best indicator <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economic development <strong>of</strong> a region or <strong>of</strong><br />

a country is <strong>the</strong> per capita national income or gross domestic product<br />

(GDP). In recent years two estimates have been developed to reconstruct<br />

<strong>the</strong> GDP for <strong>the</strong> dualistic period <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Austro-Hungarian<br />

Monarchy. One was prepared by <strong>the</strong> eminent American historian,<br />

David Good, an expert on <strong>the</strong> economics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy and <strong>the</strong><br />

o<strong>the</strong>r one was prepared by Max-Stephan Schulze. David Good calculated<br />

<strong>the</strong> GDP <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> countries, territories, and regions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy<br />

per capita between 1870 and 1910. 7 The results <strong>of</strong> his calculations<br />

<strong>of</strong> interest to us are contained in table 4. Because Good did his calculations<br />

in today’s dollars <strong>the</strong> table shows dollar values <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> individual<br />

countries and territories as indices <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Austrian averages. It can<br />

be seen that in 1870 <strong>the</strong> per capita GDP in <strong>the</strong> lands <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hungarian<br />

Crown represented 59 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Austrian values while <strong>the</strong> figure<br />

for <strong>the</strong> eastern and sou<strong>the</strong>rn territories was 52 percent.<br />

7 David F Good, “Revised estimates <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> GDP per capita in Central and Eastern Europe,<br />

1870–1910: Technical Notes and tables,” Center for Austrian Studies Working Papers Series<br />

(1998); and David Good and Tongshu Ma, “The Economic Growth <strong>of</strong> Central and Eastern<br />

Europe in Comparative Perspective, 1870–1989,” pt. 2, European Review <strong>of</strong> Economic History<br />

3, (1999): 103–137.


32 LÁSZLÓ KATUS<br />

TABLE 4. Per Capita GDP Indices According to David Good’s Calculations<br />

(Austria = 100)<br />

1870 1910 Average annual<br />

growth (%)<br />

Austria 100 100 1.48<br />

Hereditary Provinces 118 123 1.56<br />

Galicia, Bukovina, Dalmatia 52 52 1.56<br />

Hungary 62 78 2.05<br />

Croatia 41 52 1.84<br />

Lands <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hungarian Crown 59 75 2.00<br />

Monarchy 85 90 1.63<br />

More recently Max-Stephan Schulze calculated <strong>the</strong> GDP <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> two<br />

countries <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy at <strong>the</strong> 1913 prices. He divided <strong>the</strong> GDP<br />

according to principal economic areas 8 (table 5).<br />

The most important indicators in both calculations show <strong>the</strong> degree<br />

<strong>of</strong> Hungary’s economic backwardness when compared, at <strong>the</strong> time <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> Compromise, with <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy. The per capita<br />

GDP was roughly two thirds <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Austrian one but in <strong>the</strong> industrial<br />

areas it was barely one quarter. The indices also show what we could<br />

deduce from o<strong>the</strong>r contemporary sources, namely that <strong>the</strong> principal sector<br />

<strong>of</strong> Hungarian economy, agriculture, was much less backward than<br />

<strong>the</strong> industrial sectors. The per capita agricultural income in Hungary<br />

was 21 percent higher than <strong>the</strong> one in Austria and Hungarian agriculture<br />

was substantially better mechanized. It is true, however, that average<br />

productivity per unit <strong>of</strong> land was higher in Austria and that <strong>the</strong> productivity<br />

<strong>of</strong> agricultural labor was also higher <strong>the</strong>re.<br />

8 Max-Stephan Schulze, “Patterns <strong>of</strong> Growth and Stagnation in <strong>the</strong> Late Nineteenth Century<br />

Habsburg Economy,” European Review <strong>of</strong> Economic History 4, (2000): 311–340; and<br />

Schulze, “Origins <strong>of</strong> Catch-up Failure: Comparative Productivity Growth in <strong>the</strong> Habsburg<br />

Empire, 1870–1910,” London School <strong>of</strong> Economics Working Papers, no. 100/07 (2007). In<br />

this publication Schulze corrected both <strong>the</strong> Austrian and Hungarian GDP data from <strong>the</strong> earlier<br />

article. Our table shows <strong>the</strong> corrected figures.


THE COMMON MARKET 33<br />

TABLE 5. Austria’s and Hungary’s GDP According to Schulze<br />

Per capita GDP based Hungary as a %<br />

on 1913 prices in crowns <strong>of</strong> Austria<br />

1870 1910 1870 1910<br />

Austria Hungary Austria Hungary<br />

Agriculture 117 141 145 245 120.6 169.5<br />

Industry, Mining 128 31 238 104 24.2 43.7<br />

Commerce, Credit<br />

Transportation 41 12 105 42 29.8 40.4<br />

Services 150 104 146 99 69.4 67.0<br />

GDP 436 288 635 490 66.1 77.1<br />

Distribution <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> GDP<br />

1870 1910<br />

Austria Hungary Austria Hungary<br />

% % % %<br />

Agriculture 26.8 48.8 22.8 49.9<br />

Industry, Mining 29.5 10.8 37.4 21.2<br />

Commerce, etc. 9.3 4.2 16.5 8.7<br />

Services 34.4 36.2 23.3 20.2<br />

GDP 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0<br />

Average Annual Growth Rate %<br />

Total GDP<br />

Per Capita GDP<br />

Austria Hungary Austria Hungary<br />

% % % %<br />

Agriculture 1.39 2.15 0.54 1.39<br />

Industry, Mining 2.40 3.82 1.54 3.05<br />

Commerce, etc. 3.27 3.95 2.40 3.18<br />

Services 0.81 0.62 -0.04 -0.12<br />

GDP 1.80 2.09 0.94 1.34


34 LÁSZLÓ KATUS<br />

Was Hungary able to overtake its neighbors or at least decrease its<br />

differences by <strong>the</strong> outbreak <strong>of</strong> World War I? The answer to this question<br />

can be provided by <strong>the</strong> measures <strong>of</strong> economic growth, namely <strong>the</strong> rate<br />

<strong>of</strong> annual growth in <strong>the</strong> GDP or, ra<strong>the</strong>r, by its per capita rate, calculated<br />

on <strong>the</strong> basis <strong>of</strong> steady prices. The growth <strong>of</strong> Austrian annual national<br />

income was first calculated by Anton Kausel according to <strong>the</strong> requirements<br />

<strong>of</strong> modern economic science. 9 He concluded that between 1870<br />

and 1913 <strong>the</strong> total GDP increased annually by an average <strong>of</strong> 2.21 percent<br />

while <strong>the</strong> per capita GDP increased by 1.32 percent. According to<br />

Iván Berend and György Ránki <strong>the</strong> corresponding changes in Hungary<br />

between 1867 and 1913 were 3.2 percent and 2.5 percent. They calculated<br />

on <strong>the</strong> basis <strong>of</strong> 1900 prices and did not include <strong>the</strong> so-called nonproductive<br />

services and thus <strong>the</strong>ir calculations cannot be compared<br />

directly with <strong>the</strong> Austrian ones. 10 The present author endeavored in <strong>the</strong><br />

1970s to calculate <strong>the</strong> gross and net national product using <strong>the</strong> 1913<br />

prices and including <strong>the</strong> non-productive services, administration,<br />

police, education, healthcare, rental income, etc. to make <strong>the</strong> calculations<br />

comparable with those <strong>of</strong> Austria and o<strong>the</strong>r foreign countries. His<br />

results were 2.5 percent for <strong>the</strong> total GDP and 1.8 percent for <strong>the</strong> per<br />

capita GDP. He later corrected his calculations and had to raise both figures<br />

by 0.2 percent. 11 We have seen in table 4 that Good calculated a<br />

generally similar rate <strong>of</strong> growth for Hungary’s economy (2.00 percent)<br />

9 Anton Kausel, “Österreichs Volkseinkommen 1830 bis 1913, Versuch einer Rückrechnung<br />

des realen Brutto-Inlandsproduktes for die österreichische für Reichshälfte und das Gebiet der<br />

Republik Österreich,” in Geschichte und Ergebnisse der zentralen amtlichen Statistik in Österreich<br />

1829–1979, ed. Österreichischen statistischen Zentralamt (Vienna: Das Amt, 1979), pp.<br />

689–720. Krausel’s calculations are accepted by Angus Maddison, see Maddison, The World<br />

Economy (Paris: Development Center <strong>of</strong> OECD, 2006), p. 404.<br />

10 Iván T. Berend and György Ránki, “Nemzeti jövedelem és tŒkefelhalmozás Magyarországon<br />

1867–1914” [National income and capital accumulation 1867–1914], Történelmi Szemle<br />

9, no. 2 (1966): 187–203.<br />

11 László Katus, “Economic Growth in Hungary during <strong>the</strong> Age <strong>of</strong> Dualism (1867–1913). A<br />

Quantitative Analysis,” in Social-Economic Researches on <strong>the</strong> History <strong>of</strong> East-Central Europe,<br />

ed. Iván T. Berend and o<strong>the</strong>rs (Budapest: Akadémiai Kiadó, 1970); László Katus, “Magyarország<br />

gazdasági fejlŒdése, 1890–1914” [The economic development <strong>of</strong> Hungary<br />

1890–1914], in Magyarország története [The History <strong>of</strong> Hungary], vol. 7, 1890–1919, ed. Péter<br />

Hanák (Budapest: Akadémiai Kiadó, 1978), vol. 1, pp. 394–401; László Katus, “Hazánk és<br />

régiónk a dualizmus korában” [Our country and region in <strong>the</strong> era <strong>of</strong> Dualism], in Tolna megye a<br />

dualizmus korában [Tolna County in <strong>the</strong> Era <strong>of</strong> Dualism), ed. Gyula Dobos (Szekszárd: Tolna<br />

M. Önkormányzat Lvt., 2003), pp. 146–147.


THE COMMON MARKET 35<br />

but he saw Austria’s growth rate to be greater (1.48 percent) than shown<br />

by Kausel.<br />

Max-Stephan Schulze completely recalculated <strong>the</strong> GDP for both<br />

Austria and Hungary between 1870 and 1913 and reached a significantly<br />

lower figure for both countries. For Austria <strong>the</strong> growth rate <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> per<br />

capita GDP came out 0.94 percent and for Hungary 1.39 percent. From<br />

our perspective it is important that according to his calculations Hungarian<br />

economy grew at a considerable faster rate than <strong>the</strong> Austrian one even<br />

though <strong>the</strong> differences in <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> growth between <strong>the</strong> two countries<br />

remained generally <strong>the</strong> same as in <strong>the</strong> earlier calculations (annually<br />

0.4–0.5 percent).<br />

Viewed from half a century away, this difference in <strong>the</strong> annual<br />

growth rate between <strong>the</strong> two countries seems to have resulted in a marked<br />

closing <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> gap for Hungarian economy. According to Schulze’s calculations<br />

<strong>the</strong> difference between <strong>the</strong> per capita GDP in Hungary in 1870<br />

was only 66 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Austrian one but by 1910 it had grown to 77<br />

percent. According to Good’s calculation <strong>the</strong> advance was even more<br />

rapid and rose in forty years from 59 percent to 75 percent. In his final<br />

conclusions Schulze states that <strong>the</strong> failure <strong>of</strong> catching up, which appears<br />

in <strong>the</strong> title <strong>of</strong> his work, was due to Austria’s slowness in development<br />

which made it fall fur<strong>the</strong>r and fur<strong>the</strong>r behind Germany and <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r west<br />

European countries. He considered Hungary’s advance to be a success<br />

story, at least within <strong>the</strong> Monarchy. He believed that during <strong>the</strong> half century<br />

prior to World War I, Hungary occupied a middle position among <strong>the</strong><br />

European nations so far as economic developments were concerned.<br />

Among fifteen European nations Hungary occupied <strong>the</strong> seventh position<br />

so far as growth was concerned. Only Switzerland, Germany, Denmark,<br />

Sweden, Finland, and France did better than Hungary.<br />

So far as international comparisons are concerned <strong>the</strong> data in <strong>the</strong><br />

most recent edition <strong>of</strong> Angus Maddison’s Historical Statistics differ from<br />

those <strong>of</strong> Schulze. Maddison found that Hungary was not in <strong>the</strong> middle<br />

group <strong>of</strong> European countries in <strong>the</strong> area <strong>of</strong> European economic growth<br />

but among <strong>the</strong> leaders. The per capita GDP grew more rapidly only in<br />

three countries, Germany, Denmark, and Switzerland. The combined<br />

average <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> per capita GDP in <strong>the</strong> twelve western European countries<br />

was higher than Hungary’s by 91 percent in 1870 but by 1910 <strong>the</strong> difference<br />

had decreased to 76 percent. This shows that <strong>the</strong> Hungarian econo-


36 LÁSZLÓ KATUS<br />

my was moving closer, albeit slowly, not only to <strong>the</strong> Austrian one but to<br />

all European countries. The indicators also show that in 1913 Hungary was<br />

much closer to <strong>the</strong> west European averages than it is today. If we set <strong>the</strong><br />

Hungarian per capita GDP at 100, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> combined GDP <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> twelve<br />

European countries in 1913 was 176 and in <strong>the</strong> year 2000 it was 277. 12<br />

FIG. 1. Per Capita GDP in 1913 and in 2000 (Hungary = 100)<br />

USA<br />

Japan<br />

Greece<br />

Portugal<br />

Spain<br />

Western Europe<br />

Finnland<br />

Norway<br />

Sweden<br />

Denmark<br />

Holland<br />

Belgium<br />

United Kingdom<br />

France<br />

Switzerland<br />

Germany<br />

Italy<br />

Austria<br />

Hungary<br />

1913<br />

2000<br />

0 100 200 300 400<br />

12 Angus Maddison, The World economy: Historical statistics (Paris: Development Center <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> OECD, 2006), pp. 438–445, 478, and 558. The GDP <strong>of</strong> every country is calculated in 1990<br />

international Geary-Khamis dollars.


THE COMMON MARKET 37<br />

Schulze did some calculations on fixed capital assets and labor productivity<br />

in both halves <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy. The capital assets grew in<br />

Hungary between 1870 and 1910 at an average annual rate <strong>of</strong> 4.01 percent<br />

and in Austria at a rate <strong>of</strong> 2.55 percent. The productivity <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

work force grew annually by 1.29 percent in Austria and by 1.65 percent<br />

in Hungary. The principal reason why productivity grew so rapidly<br />

in Hungary was that <strong>the</strong> work force was well supplied with capital<br />

assets and that <strong>the</strong> capital-output ratio (capital coefficient) was also<br />

growing at a rapid rate. Schulze emphasized that Hungary had made up<br />

its initial substantial backwardness in this area by 1913 and reached<br />

80–90 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Austrian level relative to <strong>the</strong> physical capital per<br />

unit output. 13 Thus in this area Hungary was also successful in moving<br />

closer to Austria because, with <strong>the</strong> exception <strong>of</strong> mining, productivity<br />

grew at a faster rate in every section <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> national economy in Hungary<br />

than in <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy.<br />

TABLE 6. Labor Productivity According to <strong>the</strong> Calculation <strong>of</strong> Schulze<br />

Agricult. Mining Industry Commerce Services Total<br />

Credit<br />

<strong>of</strong> above<br />

Transport.<br />

Value added per worker in constant 1913 prices in cronws<br />

1870<br />

Austria 349 823 1,207 1,438 1,413 702<br />

Hungary 338 648 822 784 934 455<br />

1910<br />

Austria 544 2,122 1,855 1,899 2,039 1,171<br />

Hungary 662 1,525 1,514 1,438 1,373 877<br />

Hungary as a % <strong>of</strong> Austria<br />

1870 97 79 69 55 66 65<br />

1910 122 72 82 76 67 75<br />

Average annual growth 1870–1910 in %<br />

Austria 1.12 2.40 1.08 0.70 0.94 1.29<br />

Hungary 1.69 2.16 1.49 1.53 0.97 1.65<br />

13 Max-Stephan Schulze, “An Estimate <strong>of</strong> Imperial Austria’s Gross Domestic Fixed Capital<br />

Stock, 1870–1913: Methods, Sources, and Results,” in London School <strong>of</strong> Economics Working<br />

Papers, no. 92/05 (2005). He accepts our calculations for Hungary. See Katus, “Economic<br />

Growth,” pp. 109–111.


38 LÁSZLÓ KATUS<br />

The above shows that between 1867 and 1914 <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

growth and <strong>of</strong> structural change was significantly greater in Hungary<br />

than in <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy. This comment is valid for <strong>the</strong><br />

entire national product, for all principal branches <strong>of</strong> economy, for <strong>the</strong><br />

work force, for productivity, and for capital assets, i.e. for all <strong>the</strong> most<br />

important indicators <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> status and dynamism <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> national economy.<br />

The contemporaries were aware <strong>of</strong> this accelerating trend <strong>of</strong> catching<br />

up with <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r, better developed half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy. This<br />

became manifest by <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> relative ability <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> two countries<br />

to bear <strong>the</strong> economic and financial burdens, <strong>the</strong> so-called quota, i.e<br />

Hungary’s contribution to <strong>the</strong> expenditure <strong>of</strong> joint affairs, was raised<br />

between 1867 and 1907 from 30 percent to 36.4 percent.<br />

In spite <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> more rapid growth <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hungarian economy <strong>the</strong>re<br />

were still obvious differences prior to World War I in <strong>the</strong> levels <strong>of</strong> development<br />

between <strong>the</strong> Hereditary Provinces, Hungary, and <strong>the</strong> eastern and<br />

peripheral regions <strong>of</strong> Galicia, Bukovina, Dalmatia, and Croatia. It is<br />

<strong>the</strong>refore a legitimate question whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> integration <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> various<br />

regions, having different conditions, structures and development, in <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>common</strong> customs area, had progressed and moved toward a larger, complete<br />

economic unit. The question is very much justified because it is generally<br />

accepted that political evolution clearly led toward disintegration<br />

and in our case eventually led to <strong>the</strong> dissolution <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy. Analysis<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economic history gives a simple answer: by <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> nineteenth<br />

century in <strong>the</strong> area <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> customs union <strong>the</strong> interregional exchange<br />

<strong>of</strong> merchandise, capital, and working force had increased significantly<br />

and <strong>the</strong>re was a parallel trend toward equalizing <strong>the</strong> regional differences<br />

in prices, salaries, and interest rates. All this shows <strong>the</strong> advances <strong>of</strong> mercantile<br />

integration. 14 David Good calculated <strong>the</strong> per capita GDP in twenty-two<br />

territories and regions for 1870 and for 1910. The reduction in <strong>the</strong><br />

coefficient <strong>of</strong> variation from 0.41 to 0.35, shows <strong>the</strong> gradual leveling <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> territorial differences during <strong>the</strong>se forty years.<br />

14 David E. Good, Economic Rise <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Habsburg Empire, 1750–1914 (Berkeley: University<br />

<strong>of</strong> California Press, 1984), pp. 96–124. He summarizes his facts about economic integration<br />

as follows, ”The quantitative evidence supports those who stress <strong>the</strong> more positive achievements<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Habsburg economic union. Judged in economic terms <strong>the</strong> Empire experiences<br />

substantial <strong>market</strong> integration in <strong>the</strong> decades before World War I” (p. 124).


THE COMMON MARKET 39<br />

The indicators <strong>of</strong> growth for each individual section, shown above,<br />

draw our attention to a perspective which, in our view is very important<br />

in assessing <strong>the</strong> effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>common</strong> <strong>market</strong> on Hungarian economy.<br />

The commercial and customs union brought both advantages and disadvantages<br />

to both countries. The reason why <strong>the</strong> union was first made<br />

and <strong>the</strong>n repeatedly renewed was that both countries believed that <strong>the</strong><br />

advantages to <strong>the</strong>ir economy outweighed <strong>the</strong> disadvantages. Both parties<br />

were willing to make sacrifices in order to preserve <strong>the</strong> advantages.<br />

Hungary gave primacy to its agriculture and food processing industry,<br />

including milling, while Austria considered industry, primarily <strong>the</strong><br />

manufacture <strong>of</strong> consumption goods as its most important activity. In<br />

order to control <strong>the</strong> <strong>market</strong>s in <strong>the</strong> entire Monarchy Hungary was willing,<br />

figuratively speaking, to sacrifice industry and Austria was willing<br />

to sacrifice its agriculture on <strong>the</strong> altar <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>common</strong> <strong>market</strong>. Surprisingly,<br />

<strong>the</strong> data show, that <strong>the</strong> “victims” behaved in a contrary fashion to<br />

each o<strong>the</strong>r and that Hungarian industry could take advantage <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

opportunities <strong>of</strong>fered by <strong>the</strong> <strong>common</strong> <strong>market</strong>. Austria’s agriculture,<br />

accepted its fate, it grew slowly and increasingly lagged behind <strong>the</strong> Hungarian<br />

agriculture. In contrast, Hungarian industry grew at a much more<br />

rapid rate than <strong>the</strong> Austrian and made a good start toward equalizing <strong>the</strong><br />

differences. The service sector <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hungarian economy acted in a<br />

similar fashion and commerce, credit, and transportation all made<br />

appreciable progress. There was insufficient time to reach complete<br />

parity. Prior to World War I <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> per capita industrial production<br />

in Hungary was 44 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Austrian one, according to Schulze,<br />

and 55 percent according to our calculations. 15 Because <strong>the</strong> backwardness<br />

was a long range centennial process, <strong>the</strong> catching up also would<br />

have needed a longer and peaceful period <strong>of</strong> time.<br />

John Komlos calculated <strong>the</strong> temporal arrangement <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> indexes<br />

<strong>of</strong> industrial production between 1850 and 1913 in both countries <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

Monarchy. 16 His calculations also show that <strong>the</strong> Hungarian industry<br />

grew faster than <strong>the</strong> Austrian one (fig. 2).<br />

15 We accepted Waizner’s figures for Austria’s national income. Ernst Waizner, “Das Volkseinkommen<br />

Alt-Österreichs und seine Verteilung auf die Nachfolgestaaten,” Metron 7, no. 4<br />

(1928): 97–182.<br />

16 John Komlos, The Habsburg Monarchy as a Customs Union. Economic Development in Austria-Hungary<br />

in <strong>the</strong> Nineteenth Century (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1983), pp. 281–<br />

318.


40 LÁSZLÓ KATUS<br />

900<br />

FIG. 2. The Indexes <strong>of</strong> Industrial Production in Austria and Hungary<br />

According to John Komlos (Index: 1850 = 100)<br />

800<br />

700<br />

600<br />

500<br />

400<br />

300<br />

200<br />

100<br />

1850 1855 1860 1865 1870 1875 1880 1885 1890 1895 1900 1905 1910<br />

Austria<br />

Hungary<br />

The rapid growth <strong>of</strong> Hungarian industry suggests that relinquishing<br />

industrial protective customs duties could be compensated for, vis-à-vis<br />

<strong>the</strong> industrially more advanced Hereditary Provinces, with o<strong>the</strong>r economic<br />

policy activities, primarily state support <strong>of</strong> industry and <strong>the</strong> development<br />

<strong>of</strong> a system <strong>of</strong> public contracts. The Hungarian economic politicians<br />

also tried to make sure that Hungarian industry participated in <strong>the</strong><br />

orders <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> joint army and navy according to <strong>the</strong> quota. By <strong>the</strong> beginning<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> twentieth century this was largely accomplished.<br />

A few years ago a monograph was published which showed on <strong>the</strong><br />

basis <strong>of</strong> rich Viennese and Hungarian archival data how this economic<br />

policy functioned on a day-by-day basis, how <strong>the</strong> frequently divergent<br />

interests could be brought into harmony, and how negotiations with <strong>the</strong><br />

leaders <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> navy and at sessions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Council for Joint Affairs, a continuous<br />

increase in both <strong>the</strong> ratio and in <strong>the</strong> total <strong>of</strong> orders from Hungarian<br />

industries could be achieved. 17 Distribution, according to <strong>the</strong> quota,<br />

17 Mihály Krámli, A császári és királyi haditengerészet és Magyarország: Magyarország<br />

szerepe a közös haditengerészet fejlesztésében [The Imperial and Royal Navy and Hungary:<br />

Hungary’s Role in <strong>the</strong> Expansion <strong>of</strong> a Common Navy] (Pécs: Pro Pannonia Alapítvány, 2004).


THE COMMON MARKET 41<br />

was not a simple process. Some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> required articles could not be produced<br />

in Hungary and o<strong>the</strong>rs were unavailable at <strong>the</strong> price or quality<br />

required. There were, however, areas <strong>of</strong> military industry where <strong>the</strong><br />

domestic industry was equipped with <strong>the</strong> necessary facilities. In order to<br />

make up for <strong>the</strong>se problems a complex system <strong>of</strong> compensations had to<br />

be worked out. Orders to Hungarian industry were frequently channeled<br />

back through Austrian industries from which raw materials, partially finished<br />

items, and components were obtained. The reverse, however, was<br />

also true. The Austrian industries receiving orders from <strong>the</strong> navy had to<br />

go to Hungary to obtain certain materials and partially finished products.<br />

The industrialization <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hungarian economy is also shown by<br />

<strong>the</strong> changes in <strong>the</strong> structure <strong>of</strong> foreign trade. At <strong>the</strong> time <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Compromise<br />

36.5 percent <strong>of</strong> Hungary’s exports were industrial in nature and<br />

this ratio grew only to 39 percent by <strong>the</strong> middle <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1880s, but rose<br />

to 47.6 percent by <strong>the</strong> years before World War I. We can see a similar<br />

change in Hungary’s exports <strong>of</strong> finished industrial goods to Austria.<br />

The rate <strong>of</strong> growth in exports to Austria was greater between 1882 and<br />

1913 <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> imports, even in <strong>the</strong> area <strong>of</strong> textiles. Austria’s share <strong>of</strong><br />

Hungary’s industrial exports was 64 percent in <strong>the</strong> 1880s and 71 percent<br />

around 1910.<br />

Free <strong>market</strong> competition in <strong>the</strong> territory <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> customs union with<br />

<strong>the</strong> more advanced Austrian and Czech industry had advantages and disadvantages.<br />

It could retard and distort but it could also stimulate and<br />

advance Hungarian industrialization. It is partly due to this that <strong>the</strong> evolving<br />

Hungarian industry was structurally one-sided and distorted and light<br />

industry, particularly <strong>the</strong> textile industry was surprisingly weak and<br />

underdeveloped by international standards. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, it was <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>common</strong> customs area that assured for Hungary <strong>the</strong> availability <strong>of</strong> production<br />

factors that would have been missing o<strong>the</strong>rwise. It provided <strong>the</strong><br />

new factories <strong>the</strong> essential network <strong>of</strong> cooperating industries and <strong>the</strong> service<br />

and support components. According to <strong>the</strong> studies performed at <strong>the</strong><br />

end <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> nineteenth century, a significant part <strong>of</strong> Hungary’s industrial<br />

machinery came from Austria. The competition in <strong>the</strong> free <strong>market</strong> stimulated<br />

technical advances and <strong>the</strong> introduction <strong>of</strong> new products and new<br />

procedures. The large <strong>market</strong>s in <strong>the</strong> Monarchy created an opportunity<br />

for <strong>the</strong> economically sound application <strong>of</strong> modern technology needed for<br />

<strong>the</strong> realization <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> economies <strong>of</strong> scale.


42 LÁSZLÓ KATUS<br />

After <strong>the</strong> end <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1880s <strong>the</strong> hi<strong>the</strong>rto neglected branches <strong>of</strong> industry<br />

started a rapid growth and <strong>the</strong> structure <strong>of</strong> industry became more<br />

complete and more balanced. The increasingly rapid developments at <strong>the</strong><br />

turn <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> century continuously created new gaps in <strong>the</strong> industrial structure<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy and filling <strong>the</strong>se created a good opportunity for<br />

Hungarian industry because in <strong>the</strong> new industrial areas and with <strong>the</strong> new<br />

products <strong>the</strong> earlier industrialized regions’ advantages were less important<br />

and those trying to catch up had a chance to enter <strong>the</strong> race with generally<br />

equal opportunities. A classic example is furnished by <strong>the</strong> Hungarian<br />

electro-technical industry which for two decades stood at <strong>the</strong><br />

leading edge in world-wide developments thanks to <strong>the</strong> inventions and<br />

improvements <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> engineers <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Ganz works. By <strong>the</strong> turn <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

century <strong>the</strong> Austrian chambers <strong>of</strong> industry were complaining that <strong>the</strong><br />

rapidly developing Hungarian industry was a successful competitor with<br />

<strong>the</strong> Austrians in such traditional Austrian-Czech industries as <strong>the</strong> paper<br />

and textile industries, not just at home but in Austria as well.<br />

By <strong>the</strong> turn <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> century appropriate structures appeared in <strong>the</strong> <strong>common</strong><br />

customs area for a higher form <strong>of</strong> economic integration, usually at <strong>the</strong><br />

level <strong>of</strong> individual plants but occasionally on an industry-wide basis as<br />

well. Joint companies were established and <strong>the</strong>re was a gradual development<br />

<strong>of</strong> cooperation between <strong>the</strong> companies <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> two countries in a variety<br />

<strong>of</strong> forms and to various degrees. We find most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> joint companies<br />

in industry. At <strong>the</strong> turn <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> century Austrian and Czech industrial companies<br />

established dozens <strong>of</strong> subsidiary establishments in Hungary primarily<br />

to take advantage <strong>of</strong> government subsidies and <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> benefits <strong>of</strong> a<br />

cheaper labor force and to be closer to <strong>the</strong> consumer <strong>market</strong>s. The subsidiaries<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Austrian companies shortly became independent joint stock<br />

companies but maintained close contacts with <strong>the</strong> parent organization. At<br />

<strong>the</strong> beginning <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> century we know <strong>of</strong> about a hundred such industrial<br />

companies which were some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> largest and strongest companies <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

Monarchy. There were such joint companies in almost all areas <strong>of</strong> industry<br />

with most <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>m being in <strong>the</strong> iron, steel, and textile industries.<br />

Within <strong>the</strong> joint companies a large variety <strong>of</strong> production and business<br />

cooperation developed. These included specialization <strong>of</strong> production,<br />

<strong>the</strong> distribution <strong>of</strong> manufacturing pr<strong>of</strong>iles between <strong>the</strong> various factories.<br />

Mutual provision <strong>of</strong> parts and partially finished products,<br />

exchange <strong>of</strong> expert information, patents, manufacturing procedures,


THE COMMON MARKET 43<br />

and <strong>the</strong> equalization <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its. The historian Sándor Ausch noted, “So<br />

far as <strong>the</strong> exchange <strong>of</strong> component parts typical <strong>of</strong> modern industrial<br />

developments and international commerce, and <strong>the</strong> high percentage <strong>of</strong><br />

exported products are concerned, <strong>the</strong> 1906 Hungarian machine industry<br />

presents a favorable image even in comparison with today’s highly<br />

developed industrial nations. The industrial liaisons between <strong>the</strong> countries<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> imperial <strong>market</strong>s and <strong>the</strong> subsidiary companies created a fertile<br />

soil for specialization, cooperation, and technical collaboration.” 18<br />

The basis for <strong>the</strong> <strong>common</strong> <strong>market</strong> was created by <strong>the</strong> division <strong>of</strong><br />

labor between a country producing agrarian products, food, and raw<br />

materials and a country that was more industrialized. This division<br />

between agriculture and industry remained until <strong>the</strong> end, but from <strong>the</strong><br />

1860s on <strong>the</strong>re was a gradual transition toward a higher and more modern<br />

division <strong>of</strong> labor between <strong>the</strong> two increasingly industrialized countries<br />

with national economies <strong>of</strong> different structure and level <strong>of</strong> development.<br />

This was clearly visible in <strong>the</strong> changes <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> structure <strong>of</strong> commercial<br />

exchange. As stated by <strong>the</strong> American specialist <strong>of</strong> Hungarian economic<br />

history in <strong>the</strong> era <strong>of</strong> Dualism, Scott M. Eddie, “When compared to<br />

<strong>the</strong> 1850s, <strong>the</strong> regional evolution <strong>of</strong> specialization, essential for <strong>the</strong> uniform<br />

production for <strong>the</strong> <strong>common</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy, had made significant<br />

strides by 1882. Hungary was no longer <strong>the</strong> larder <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Empire<br />

but also <strong>the</strong> major exporter <strong>of</strong> certain finished products which were<br />

largely based on <strong>the</strong> raw materials produced within <strong>the</strong> country itself.” 19<br />

The economic relationship with Austria and <strong>the</strong> <strong>common</strong> <strong>market</strong><br />

had a major role in <strong>the</strong> evolution <strong>of</strong> Hungarian economy in <strong>the</strong> era <strong>of</strong><br />

Dualism in three distinct ways.<br />

First, it was due to <strong>the</strong> <strong>common</strong> <strong>market</strong> that <strong>the</strong> leading sector <strong>of</strong><br />

Hungarian economy, agriculture, could preserve its dynamism during<br />

<strong>the</strong> European crisis in <strong>market</strong>ing grain. In <strong>the</strong> competition with American,<br />

Russian, and Romanian wheat and flour and because <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

increasing seclusion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> central and western European countries,<br />

18 Sándor Ausch, “Önálló gazdasági fejlŒdés vagy tŒkés függés” [Independent economic<br />

progress or capital dependence], Történelmi Szemle 11, no. 3 (1968): 319.<br />

19 Scott M. Eddie, “Mit bizonyítanak az 1882–1913-as export statisztikai adatok: Magyarország<br />

valóban csak a Monarchia “éléskamrája volt?” [What is proven by <strong>the</strong> 1882–1913 export<br />

statistics data: Was Hungary really just <strong>the</strong> “larder” <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy?], Történelmi Szemle 25,<br />

no. 3 (1982): 423.


44 LÁSZLÓ KATUS<br />

Hungarian wheat and flour lost its foreign <strong>market</strong>s. The <strong>common</strong> <strong>market</strong>,<br />

however, continued to accept Hungarian agricultural and food<br />

products in increasing volume. The <strong>common</strong> <strong>market</strong> also played an<br />

important role in <strong>the</strong> modernization <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hungarian economy by providing<br />

<strong>the</strong> import <strong>of</strong> capital, and skilled labor.<br />

We have <strong>of</strong>ficial data for trade between Austria and Hungary prior<br />

to 1850 and after 1882. These show that Austria’s share in Hungarian<br />

foreign trade was about 80 percent in <strong>the</strong> 1840s. The situation did not<br />

change significantly between 1882 and 1913. The participation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>common</strong> customs area in Hungarian exports was between 71 and 77<br />

percent and between 73 and 86 percent so far as imports were concerned.<br />

The former showed a steadily increasing trend while <strong>the</strong> latter<br />

kept gradually decreasing. It is beyond doubt that <strong>the</strong>se figures contain<br />

some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> business beyond <strong>the</strong> <strong>common</strong> customs area, achieved with<br />

Austria’s help, but even knowing this we may assume that at least two<br />

thirds <strong>of</strong> Hungarian foreign trade was limited to <strong>the</strong> <strong>common</strong> customs<br />

area. In <strong>the</strong>ir foreign connections <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy was<br />

not nearly as dependent on Hungary as Hungary was on it. Hungary’s<br />

participation in Austria’s foreign trade was only 35 to 40 percent.<br />

The dynamics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>common</strong> customs area is shown by <strong>the</strong> fact<br />

that, calculating at <strong>the</strong> same price from 1882 to 1913, <strong>the</strong> Hungarian<br />

exports to Austria grew annually by 2.85 percent and <strong>the</strong> imports grew<br />

by 3.37 percent. As mentioned above, Austria became <strong>the</strong> most important<br />

export <strong>market</strong> for Hungarian economy. The rate <strong>of</strong> exports between<br />

1882 and 1913 increased more rapidly toward Austria than toward <strong>the</strong><br />

areas beyond <strong>the</strong> <strong>common</strong> customs area. This was true not only for agricultural<br />

products but for industrial products as well.<br />

During <strong>the</strong> 1840s 90 percent <strong>of</strong> Hungary’s exports to Austria consisted<br />

<strong>of</strong> agricultural products and only 10 percent <strong>of</strong> industrial ones. By<br />

<strong>the</strong> 1880s <strong>the</strong> agricultural exports were reduced to 64 percent and <strong>the</strong><br />

industrial exports rose to 35 percent. This structural change in Hungary’s<br />

exports to Austria continued and in 1909–1913 <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> agricultural<br />

raw material exported dropped to 55 percent and <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong><br />

industrial products rose to 44 percent. Within <strong>the</strong> latter <strong>the</strong>re was still a<br />

25 percent component <strong>of</strong> food processing products. This shows that <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>common</strong> <strong>market</strong> stimulated <strong>the</strong> development <strong>of</strong> not only <strong>the</strong> agricultural<br />

sector but <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> industrial one as well.


THE COMMON MARKET 45<br />

The changes in imports were smaller but even <strong>the</strong>se show <strong>the</strong><br />

increasing industrialization <strong>of</strong> Hungarian economy. Hungary’s imports<br />

from Austria continued to be almost 90 percent industrial but it is very<br />

noticeable that <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> finished consumable goods had decreased,<br />

from 73 percent to 64 percent. There was an increase in <strong>the</strong> import <strong>of</strong><br />

investment items and <strong>of</strong> partially finished goods destined for completion<br />

in Hungary. The former increased from 13 percent to 19 percent<br />

and <strong>the</strong> latter from 5 percent to 7 percent.<br />

By comparing Hungary’s trade in <strong>the</strong> <strong>common</strong> customs area with<br />

Hungary’s trade towards <strong>the</strong> areas beyond <strong>the</strong> <strong>common</strong> <strong>market</strong> we can<br />

make an important observation, namely that <strong>the</strong> <strong>common</strong> <strong>market</strong> had a<br />

more beneficial effect on Hungarian economy. Our volume <strong>of</strong> imports<br />

increased more rapidly than that <strong>of</strong> our exports. This was due to <strong>the</strong><br />

export and import price index which led to <strong>the</strong> development <strong>of</strong> favorable<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> trade. According to Eddie’s calculations, between 1882/86 and<br />

1909/1913, Hungary’s export price index to <strong>the</strong> <strong>common</strong> <strong>market</strong><br />

increased annually by 0.17 percent while its import price index decreased<br />

by 1.02 percent, meaning that <strong>the</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> foreign trade improved by 26<br />

percent. This also meant that for <strong>the</strong> same amount exported Hungary<br />

could import 26 percent more, prior to World War I than in <strong>the</strong> first half<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 1880s. In trade beyond <strong>the</strong> customs area <strong>the</strong> situation was precisely<br />

<strong>the</strong> opposite. The price index <strong>of</strong> Hungary’s exports decreased twice as<br />

much as <strong>of</strong> imports, (annually 0.97 and 0.47 percent), and thus Hungary’s<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> trade decreased by 13 percent. 20 This development in <strong>the</strong> terms<br />

<strong>of</strong> foreign trade was due to <strong>the</strong> specific economic division <strong>of</strong> labor in <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>common</strong> customs area, customs tariffs, and to <strong>the</strong> evolution <strong>of</strong> a pricing<br />

structure different from <strong>the</strong> one for <strong>the</strong> world <strong>market</strong>s. The beneficial<br />

effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>common</strong> <strong>market</strong> and <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy’s customs policies<br />

can be seen when we compare <strong>the</strong> foreign trade calculated at Monarchy<br />

prices with those calculated at world <strong>market</strong> prices (figs. 3 and 4).<br />

20 Scott M. Eddie, “The Terms and Patterns <strong>of</strong> Hungarian Foreign Trade, 1882–1913,” Journal<br />

<strong>of</strong> Economic History 37, no. 2 (June, 1977): 333–335; and Eddie, “Mit bizonyítanak,” pp.<br />

416–425.


46 LÁSZLÓ KATUS<br />

140<br />

FIG. 3. The Evolution <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Terms <strong>of</strong> Hungarian Foreign Trade,<br />

1882–1913, at Monarchy Prices (1882 = 100)<br />

130<br />

120<br />

110<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

1882 1887 1892 1897 1902 1907 1912<br />

With Austria<br />

Linear trend<br />

Linear trend<br />

Countries beyond<br />

<strong>the</strong> customs area<br />

FIG. 4. The Evolution <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Terms <strong>of</strong> Hungarian Foreign Trade,<br />

1882–1913, at World Market Prices (1882 = 100)<br />

110<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

1882 1887 1892 1897 1902 1907 1912<br />

With Austria<br />

Linear trend<br />

Linear trend<br />

Countries beyond <strong>the</strong><br />

customs area


THE COMMON MARKET 47<br />

The <strong>common</strong> <strong>market</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy stimulated <strong>the</strong> development<br />

and modernization <strong>of</strong> Hungarian economy by <strong>the</strong> free and rapidly<br />

increasing volume <strong>of</strong> merchandise, but also by supplying factors <strong>of</strong> production<br />

which were ei<strong>the</strong>r missing from <strong>the</strong> backward Hungarian economy<br />

or were in short supply. The importation <strong>of</strong> capital, high level <strong>of</strong><br />

technology, and highly skilled workers had a major strategic effect during<br />

<strong>the</strong> time when <strong>the</strong> Hungarian capitalist economy was established<br />

during <strong>the</strong> 1830s to <strong>the</strong> 1880s. The imported factors <strong>of</strong> production,<br />

which had such an important role in <strong>the</strong> initiation and maintenance <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> Hungarian economic development, came to a large extent from <strong>the</strong><br />

western lands <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy. 21<br />

In <strong>the</strong> 1870s every fifth worker in a Budapest factory was born in<br />

Austria. By 1900 <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> workers from Austria had declined to<br />

9 percent, but among engineers, technical administrators, managers,<br />

and foremen <strong>the</strong> incidence <strong>of</strong> Austrians was still 16 percent. In 1901, 8<br />

percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> industrial plant owners and directors were Austrians. In<br />

<strong>the</strong> textile industry <strong>the</strong> ratio was 17 percent, in <strong>the</strong> paper industry 14<br />

percent, and in <strong>the</strong> chemical industry 11 percent.<br />

During <strong>the</strong> era <strong>of</strong> Dualism 7 to 8 billion crowns <strong>of</strong> foreign capital<br />

were invested in <strong>the</strong> Hungarian economy. Almost half <strong>of</strong> this originated<br />

in <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Monarchy. Frigyes Fellner estimated that <strong>the</strong><br />

face value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> securities issued in Hungary and held in Austria<br />

amounted to 3 billion crowns in 1905 and 3.2 billion in 1913. In table<br />

7 we have tried to show <strong>the</strong> contemporary data and estimates <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

placement <strong>of</strong> securities issued in Hungary. 22<br />

21 Komlos writes: “The close tie to <strong>the</strong> Austrian capital <strong>market</strong>, a tie that was contingent on <strong>the</strong><br />

economic and political union, was <strong>the</strong>refore a crucial factor in <strong>the</strong> development <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hungarian<br />

economy.” See Komlos, The Habsburg Monarchy as a Customs Union, p. 206. According to<br />

Good, “In <strong>the</strong> Habsburg context Austrian capital flows to Hungary were instrumental in <strong>the</strong><br />

emergence <strong>of</strong> modern economic growth in Hungary in <strong>the</strong> late nineteenth Century.” See Good,<br />

Economic Rise, p. 173; Schulze notes, “The outflow <strong>of</strong> Austrian capital to Hungary after <strong>the</strong><br />

1873 Vienna stock <strong>market</strong> crash was crucial in prolonging economic stagnation in Austria, whilst<br />

fueling <strong>the</strong> first widespread wave <strong>of</strong> industrialization in Hungary. The reversal <strong>of</strong> this capital outflow<br />

in <strong>the</strong> early 1890s was associated with an increase in Austrian economic growth and a<br />

decrease in Hungary’s rate <strong>of</strong> expansion.” Schulze, “Patterns <strong>of</strong> Growth,” p. 311.<br />

22 Tabellen zur Währung-Statistik [2. Ausgabe, 2. Theil.] (Vienna, 1900–1904); Franz Bartsch,<br />

Statistische Daten über die Zahlungsbilanz Österreich-Ungarns vor Ausbruch des Krieges.<br />

Mitteilungen des K.K. Finanzministeriums (Vienna, 1917), vol. 12; Frigyes Fellner, A nemzetközi<br />

fizetési mérleg és alakulása Magyarországon [The Development <strong>of</strong> International Balance


48 LÁSZLÓ KATUS<br />

TABLE 7. The Placement <strong>of</strong> Securities Issued in Hungary (Billion Crowns)<br />

In Hungary In Austria Abroad Total<br />

In 1892<br />

Government loans 1.3 2.4 0.7 4.4<br />

O<strong>the</strong>r securities* 0.7 0.6 0.2 1.5<br />

Toge<strong>the</strong>r 2.0 3.0 0.9 5.9<br />

In 1912<br />

Government loans 2.1 1.4 2.4 5.8<br />

O<strong>the</strong>r securities* 5.5 1.7 1.5 8.7<br />

Toge<strong>the</strong>r 7.6 3.1 3.9 14.5<br />

In percent<br />

In 1892<br />

Government loans 29.5 54.5 15.0 100.0<br />

O<strong>the</strong>r securities* 46.7 40.0 13.3 100.0<br />

Toge<strong>the</strong>r 33.9 50.8 15.3 100.0<br />

In 1912<br />

Government loans 36.2 24.1 39.7 100.0<br />

O<strong>the</strong>r securities* 63.2 19.5 17.2 100.0<br />

Toge<strong>the</strong>r 52.4 21.4 26.2 100.0<br />

* Mortgage debentures, municipal bonds, shares and bonds <strong>of</strong> banks, industrial and<br />

transportation companies.<br />

<strong>of</strong> Payment in Hungary] (Budapest: Politzer Zsigmond és fia, 1908); Frigyes Fellner, Ausztria<br />

és Magyarország nemzeti jövedelme [The National Revenues <strong>of</strong> Austria and Hungary] (Budapest:<br />

MTA, 1916). Because <strong>the</strong>se calculations contain numerous estimates, we must agree with<br />

György Kövér, who states, “So far as <strong>the</strong> Austrian participation in nineteenth century national<br />

capital imports is concerned, we believe that a more restrained view is indicated and we should<br />

also be more restrained in discussing <strong>the</strong> accumulations <strong>of</strong> capital in <strong>the</strong> era prior to World War<br />

I. See György Kövér, “A dualizmus-kori tŒkeimport számítások historiográfiai és módszertani<br />

kérdései” [Historiographic and methodological questions about <strong>the</strong> calculations <strong>of</strong> capital<br />

imports in <strong>the</strong> era <strong>of</strong> Dualism], in A felhalmozás íve. Társadalom és gazdaságtörténeti tanulmányok<br />

[The Curve <strong>of</strong> Accumulation. Essays in Social and Economic History] (Budapest: Új<br />

Mandátum, 2002), p. 269.


The Hungarian government loans during <strong>the</strong> twenty-five years after<br />

<strong>the</strong> Compromise were largely financed by Austria or Austrian banks<br />

played a key role in <strong>the</strong> placement <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> loans. At <strong>the</strong> beginning <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

1890s more than 60 percent <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hungarian government bonds had<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir interest and amortization paid in Austria. By <strong>the</strong> turn <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> century<br />

Austria’s role in providing capital for Hungary had decreased significantly.<br />

Its place was taken by domestic accumulations <strong>of</strong> capital and by<br />

capital obtained from beyond <strong>the</strong> customs area, mostly from Germany<br />

and France. At <strong>the</strong> same time a major shift <strong>of</strong> Austrian capital investments<br />

from <strong>the</strong> government to <strong>the</strong> private sector can be seen. The one billion<br />

crowns withdrawn from government loans were invested in <strong>the</strong> securities<br />

<strong>of</strong> private companies, primarily mortgage debentures and industrial<br />

shares (table 7).<br />

In 1914 <strong>the</strong> shares <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Hungarian industrial companies were<br />

worth one billion. Of <strong>the</strong>se 210 million (18.5 percent) were placed in<br />

Austria and only 87 million (7.6 percent) were placed beyond <strong>the</strong> customs<br />

area. The participation <strong>of</strong> Austria was particularly strong in <strong>the</strong><br />

iron industry (40 percent), <strong>the</strong> textile, lea<strong>the</strong>r and clothing industry (23<br />

percent), in <strong>the</strong> machine industry (20 percent), and in <strong>the</strong> chemical<br />

industry (19 percent). According to <strong>the</strong> 1910 industrial statistics 205 <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> 2,480 Hungarian industrial companies were completely or partially<br />

in Austrian hands. 23 THE COMMON MARKET 49<br />

23 Magyar statisztikai évkönyv 1914 [Hungarian Statistical Yearbook, 1914] (Budapest: Magyar<br />

Királyi KSH, 1916), pp. 123–124.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!