11.07.2015 Views

Taste for variety: Model of Grossman and Helpman.

Taste for variety: Model of Grossman and Helpman.

Taste for variety: Model of Grossman and Helpman.

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Variety expansionIntroduction◮ In the end <strong>of</strong> 1980-s economists mainly agreed upon theunsatisfactory results <strong>of</strong> neoclassical growth theory;◮ According to empirical findings,less than 50 percent <strong>of</strong> growthmight be attributed to the growing capital - labour ratio;◮ Hence, the half <strong>of</strong> growth rate is due to Solow residual;◮ Thus the models endogenizing technology as a source <strong>of</strong>growth emerged;◮ The first generation <strong>of</strong> such models were <strong>of</strong> taste-<strong>for</strong>-<strong>variety</strong>type;◮ The main idea <strong>of</strong> these was to find some source <strong>of</strong> growth,other that capital productivity (K/L ratio);◮ The model <strong>of</strong> <strong>Grossman</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Helpman</strong> achieved nice <strong>for</strong>maldescription <strong>of</strong> these ideas in 1990.


Variety expansionThe <strong>Model</strong>Overall structure◮ There are two countries in the world economy;◮ Each country is engaged in three types <strong>of</strong> productiveactivities:◮ Final output, being consumption good, Y ;◮ The continuum <strong>of</strong> varieties <strong>of</strong> differentiated middle products(intermediaries);◮ Research <strong>and</strong> development (R&D).◮ There is a single primary factor <strong>of</strong> production;◮ This factor is fixed, constant, specific to the country i:L i = const.◮ Capital consists <strong>of</strong> all the intermediaries, as in Romer’s model.


Variety expansionThe <strong>Model</strong>Final goods producers◮ The final good is produced in a perfectly competitive way;◮ Hence the prices are set through the marginal pricing rule,P = MC;◮ Each such producer solves the problem <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it maximization:( ( ∫ nΠ i (Y i ) = p Yi BA i L 1−β∫ n− w i L Yi −0Y i0p xi (ω)x i (ω)dω →) β/α )x i (ω) α dω −max . (2)L Yi ,x i (ω)


Variety expansionThe <strong>Model</strong>Middle product dem<strong>and</strong> IIFrom Eq. 4 we derive dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> the middle products ω = k,ω = l:( ∫x i (k) = p xi (k) − 11−α ×(βp nYi BA i L 1−βx i (l) = p xi (l) − 11−α ×(βp Yi BA i L 1−βY iY i0( ∫ n0) β/α−1 ) 1x i (ω) α 1−αdω; (5)) β/α−1 ) 1x i (ω) α 1−αdωDenoting the term in brackets as X one may rewrite dem<strong>and</strong> asx i (k) =(6)( pxi (l)) 11−αx i (l). (7)p xi (k)


Variety expansionThe <strong>Model</strong>Middle product dem<strong>and</strong> IIINow insert this last equation into the expression <strong>for</strong> the output:X =(( n∫ ) β/α )βp Yi BA i L 1−β1Y ix i (ω) α 1−αdω0( n∫ ) 1x i (ω) α 1−αdω0(8)This using Eq. 7 will give the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> each intermediateproduct as function <strong>of</strong> total output, X <strong>and</strong> prices:x i (k) = X ×n∫0p xi (k) − 11−αp xi (ω) 1− 11−α dω(9)


Variety expansionThe <strong>Model</strong>Final output price◮ Using Eqs. 3, 4 we obtain the price <strong>of</strong> the output as afunction <strong>of</strong> factor prices <strong>and</strong> productivity:p Yi =( wi) 1−β ( ∫ nA i0p X (ω) 1−ɛ dω) β/(1−ɛ);(10)ɛ = 11 − α > 1.◮ Middle products are freely traded between both countries <strong>and</strong>have the same price in both countries,p xi = p xj = p X . (11)


Variety expansionThe <strong>Model</strong>Middle products producers◮ Middle products producers engage in oligopolistic competitionin every country;◮ Every producer sets the price <strong>of</strong> his/her product as tomaximize pr<strong>of</strong>its:π i (ω) = (p X (ω) − w i a LXi ) ×p X (ω) −ɛβ ∑ n∫p X (ω) 1−ɛ dω i0p Yi Y i . (12)where a LXi is the unit labour requirement in country i <strong>for</strong>production <strong>of</strong> intermediaries.◮ The pr<strong>of</strong>it is per unit pr<strong>of</strong>it (in brackets) times the dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong>the middle product.


Variety expansionThe <strong>Model</strong>Prices <strong>for</strong> middle products◮ The price is set according to the fixed mark-up rule:αp X (ω) = w i a LXi ; (13)◮ From this it is straight<strong>for</strong>ward that all the varieties fromcountry i has the same price, p Xi ;◮ With equal prices <strong>for</strong> all the nation-specific varieties, theequation <strong>for</strong> final good’s price, Eq. 10, is condensed intop Yi =( wiA i) 1−β (∑◮ And <strong>variety</strong> price in country i isjn j p 1−ɛX j) β/(1−ɛ)(14)p Xi = 1 α w ia LXi . (15)


Variety expansionThe <strong>Model</strong>Output <strong>of</strong> intermediaries◮ With prices given by two last equations, the aggregate output<strong>of</strong> middle products is:X i =∑jn ip −ɛX in j p 1−ɛ β ∑X j jp Yj Y j (16)◮ Being the function <strong>of</strong>:◮ Number <strong>of</strong> producers in the country, n i ;◮ Price <strong>of</strong> the <strong>variety</strong> (identical across varieties), p Xi ;◮ Total output <strong>of</strong> final product in both countries.


Variety expansionThe <strong>Model</strong>Comments◮ So far the model follows that <strong>of</strong> Romer (1990) very closely;◮ The role <strong>of</strong> fixed human capital is delegated to labour with nosignificant differences;◮ There is no difference in levels <strong>of</strong> production <strong>of</strong> differentvarieties;◮ This is the direct consequence <strong>of</strong> homogeneity <strong>of</strong> knowledge;◮ In economic terms, the dem<strong>and</strong> system <strong>for</strong> intermediariesyields similar dem<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> prices;◮ There is no difference in productivities gain <strong>of</strong> varieties beingused in final good production;◮ This implies similar prices, which imply similar levels <strong>of</strong>producing these varieties.


Variety expansionThe <strong>Model</strong>Research sector◮ Resources devoted to research generate blueprints;◮ These blueprints exp<strong>and</strong> the measure <strong>of</strong> differentiatedproducts;◮ Research is made by private, pr<strong>of</strong>it maximizing entrepreneurs;◮ Their pr<strong>of</strong>it is th fraction <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its <strong>of</strong> oligopolies producingthe newly invented middle product:◮ They receive indefinite patent protection;◮ Blueprints are not tradable, thus all varieties have to beproduced in the country <strong>of</strong> origin;◮ There is the free entry <strong>of</strong> new entrepreneurs into the R&Dsector in any country.


Variety expansionThe <strong>Model</strong>Expected pr<strong>of</strong>its from R&D◮ The free entry requires, that the number <strong>of</strong> oligopolisticproducers is defined from the expected zero pr<strong>of</strong>it condition;◮ Pr<strong>of</strong>its <strong>of</strong> inventors are equal to costs <strong>of</strong> research then;◮ Zero pr<strong>of</strong>it condition implies then:∫ ∞te −(R(τ)−R(t)) π i (τ)dτ = c ni (t), ∀t. (17)◮ Expected discounted stream <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its from producing themiddle product is equal to costs <strong>of</strong> inventing this product atany given time t.


Variety expansionThe <strong>Model</strong>No-arbitrage conditionDifferentiating Eq. 17 w. r. t. to time we obtain the so-calledno-arbitrage condition:π i (t) + c ˙ ni (t)c ni (t)= ˙ R(t). (18)instantaneous return on shares <strong>of</strong> <strong>variety</strong> producing firms must bethe same as the instantaneous interest rate.


Variety expansionThe <strong>Model</strong>Knowledge growth◮ The R&D activities in each country has two effects:◮ The increase i the measure <strong>of</strong> varieties, ni which may bepatented;◮ And the growth <strong>of</strong> productivity Ai , which decreases theamount <strong>of</strong> labour needed <strong>for</strong> the invention <strong>of</strong> new products.◮ This second effect is immediately widespread across the world<strong>and</strong> is non-excludable;◮ It is the by-product <strong>of</strong> new products inventions;◮ This last depends on the achieved productivity <strong>of</strong> labour (dueto the second effect):˙ n i (t) = L ni K(t)/a Lni ; (19)where K is the current stock <strong>of</strong> knowledge <strong>and</strong> a Lni is theproductivity parameter.


Variety expansionThe <strong>Model</strong>Knowledge growth II◮ Knowledge is growing proportional to the achieved knowledge;◮ There are no diminishing returns;◮ By choosing the units <strong>for</strong> K such as the proportionality factoris 1, we have:K(t) ˙ = ∑ L ni K(t)/a Lni . (20)isince knowledge is not country-specific.◮ The acquisition <strong>of</strong> knowledge is costless <strong>and</strong> free;◮ Hence the costs <strong>of</strong> product development are:c ni = w i a Lni /n. (21)


Variety expansionThe <strong>Model</strong>Households◮ Households consume only the final product, Y ;◮ They have identical, homothetic preferences worldwide:◮ Final products from two countries are imperfect substitutes <strong>for</strong>them;◮ They maximize life-time time-separable utility subject tointertemporal budget constraint:U t =∫ ∞te −ρ(τ−t) log u(y 1 (τ), y 2 (τ))dτ, (22)where y i (τ) is the consumption <strong>of</strong> final good from country iat the time τ.


Variety expansionThe <strong>Model</strong>Intertemporal optimization <strong>of</strong> consumption◮ Assuming linearly homogeneous instantaneous utility function,the solution has two stages;◮ First, one maximizes instantaneous utility at time τ <strong>for</strong> somefixed E(τ);◮ This generates the indirect utility function, v(p Y1 (τ), p Y2 (τ));◮ At the second stage one has to choose optimal time pattern<strong>of</strong> expenditures to maximize this indirect utility;◮ This generates the condition <strong>for</strong> expenditures plan.


Variety expansionThe <strong>Model</strong>Derivation <strong>of</strong> optimal conditionThe intertemporal indirect utility has the <strong>for</strong>m∫ ∞V t = e −ρ(τ−t) {log v(p Y1 (τ), p Y2 (τ)) + log E(τ)}dτ. (23)t<strong>and</strong> have to be maximized subject to the constraint on resources:∫ ∞∫ ∞e −(R(τ)−R(t)) E(τ)dτ ≤ e −(R(τ)−R(t)) w(τ)Ldτ + Z(t). (24)ttwhere Z(t) is the value <strong>of</strong> consumer’s asset holdings at time t.


Variety expansionThe <strong>Model</strong>Optimal expenditures◮ The maximization <strong>of</strong> intertemporal consumption path leads tothe condition on expenditures:E(t) ˙E(t) = R(t) ˙ − ρ; (25)◮ Which means, that expenditures should grow at the same rateas the interest rate on assets holdings minus discount rate;◮ Consumers may invest their holdings into firms’ shares with Rrate <strong>of</strong> return or into riskless bonds with ρ rate <strong>of</strong> return;◮ The condition on optimal expenditures is the no arbitragecondition, meaning, that composition <strong>of</strong> portfolios should notmatter.


Variety expansionEquilibriumEquilibrium definitionIn this model equilibrium is defined by the set <strong>of</strong> equations:◮ Prices <strong>for</strong> goods (both final <strong>and</strong> middle ones) are defined;◮ Asset returns are related by no arbitrage condition;◮ Market clearing <strong>for</strong> final goods;◮ Market clearing <strong>for</strong> factors markets.Two first points are derived within the model already:( wi) 1−β (∑ ) β/(1−ɛ);p Yi =n j p 1−ɛAX jijp Xi = 1 α w ia LXi ;π i (t) + c ˙ ni (t)c ni (t)E(t) ˙E(t) == ˙ R(t);˙ R(t) − ρ. (26)


Variety expansionEquilibriumProducts markets clearing◮ At every point in time markets <strong>for</strong> final goods in bothcountries should be in equilibrium;◮ Static equilibrium implies, that:in both countriesp Yi Y i = s i (p Y1 , p Y2 )E; (27)◮ The function s i (•) is the function (fraction <strong>of</strong> expenditures)derived from intertemporal optimization <strong>of</strong> consumption;◮ It is homogeneous <strong>of</strong> degree zero;◮ Clearing condition means that consumption <strong>of</strong> final goods isequal to the share <strong>of</strong> world spending allocated to final productby consumers.


Variety expansionEquilibriumDem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> labour◮ Labour market clearing condition equates labour supply <strong>and</strong>dem<strong>and</strong> in each country;◮ Dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> labour by final goods producers is:L D Y ii= (1 − β)p Yi Y i /w i ; (28)◮ The dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> labour by middle goods producers is:L D X ii= a LXi X i ; (29)◮ Dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> labour by product developers is:L Dn ii= (a Lni /n) n˙i . (30)


Variety expansionEquilibriumLabour market clearingThe labour market clearing requires that total dem<strong>and</strong> given by thesum <strong>of</strong> Eqs. 28,29,30 above equal to total labour supply:(1 − β)p Yi Y i /w i + a LXi X i + (a Lni /n) n˙i = L i (31)where L i is constant <strong>and</strong> fixed.


Variety expansionEquilibriumSteady state conditions◮ The necessary conditions <strong>for</strong> convergence <strong>of</strong> the model to thesteady state growth path (or BGP) are:p X1 = n(a LX1 /a Ln1 );p X2 = n(a LX2 /a Ln2 ). (32)◮ These are conditions on prices <strong>of</strong> middle products (all <strong>of</strong> them)as function <strong>of</strong> relative labour productivities in both countries;◮ These conditions imply that relative prices <strong>of</strong> middle productsare constant along the convergent path;◮ This implies that relative wages <strong>and</strong> relative final goods pricesare also constant;◮ Then expenditure shares s i are also fixed.


Variety expansionEquilibriumBalanced growth rates◮ Denote by g the growth rate <strong>of</strong> the number <strong>of</strong> productsworldwide:g(t) =n(t)/n(t) ˙ = K(t)/K(t); ˙(33)since knowledge grows in the 1-to-1 proportion to the number<strong>of</strong> products;◮ Then prices <strong>of</strong> middle products (<strong>and</strong> all other prices) alsogrow at this rate:p X1 ˙ /p X1 = p X2 ˙ /p X2 = w˙1 /w 1 = g. (34)


Variety expansionEquilibriumComparative advantageDenotee = E/n; σ i = n i /n, b i = (a Lni /a LXi ) α , (35)◮ The first is expenditure-to-<strong>variety</strong>;◮ The second denotes the fraction <strong>of</strong> worldwide varieties beingproduced in country i;◮ The last denotes the comparative advantage <strong>of</strong> thecountry in conducting R&D;◮ With b 1 > b 2 country 1 has a comparative advantage ininventions.


Variety expansionEquilibriumGrowth rateWith these notions the growth rate <strong>of</strong> the world economy may bedescribed asg = ∑ in˙i /n = H − β e σ − 1 − β se, (36)αwhere:H = ∑ L i /a Lni - total effective labour <strong>for</strong>ce;is = ∑ s i /b i - product shares; σ = ∑ σ i b i - weighted average <strong>of</strong>iicomparative advantages.


Variety expansionEquilibriumCommentsThe equation <strong>for</strong> overall growth rate 36 implies that:◮ The intersectoral structure <strong>of</strong> allocation is summarized in σ;◮ It is in inverse proportion to the growth rates;◮ It grows only if the number <strong>of</strong> differentiated products in acountry with comparative disadvantage exceeds that in theother country;◮ Spending per middle product worldwide decrease growth rates;◮ The two variables which govern the world economy, are e <strong>and</strong>σ as some overall charactersitics <strong>of</strong> allocation <strong>of</strong> expenditures<strong>and</strong> production.


Variety expansionEquilibriumExpenditures growth rateThe evolution <strong>of</strong> the world economy may be described by the pair<strong>of</strong> equations:◮ The first relates rate <strong>of</strong> growth <strong>of</strong> expenditures per middleproduct to the growth rate:ėeβe= Ė/E − g =ασ + 1 − β se − H − ρ; (37)α◮ This rate is greater, the greater is spending per product;◮ It is smaller, the greater is the share <strong>of</strong> products beingproduced in the county with comparative disadvantage;


Variety expansionEquilibriumDistribution <strong>of</strong> varieties dynamics◮ The second describes the evolution <strong>of</strong> production <strong>of</strong> middleproducts across countries;◮ Rates <strong>of</strong> change <strong>of</strong> product shares are:σ˙i /σ = n˙i /n i − ṅ/n; (38)◮ At the same time, the sum <strong>of</strong> changes is zero;◮ Hence, one may characterize the rate <strong>of</strong> product shareschange by a single equation:˙σ = ∑ iσ˙i b i = h − 1 − β (α e − σ H − 1 − β )α se , (39)h = ∑ iL i /a Lni b i .


Variety expansionEquilibriumDynamics◮ The whole system is governed by equations on e <strong>and</strong> σ;◮ This is a 2-dimensional autonomous system;◮ The curve ė = 0 has a positive slope in e − σ space;◮ However, ˙σ = 0 curve has a different <strong>for</strong>m depending onparameters;◮ There are two distinct cases <strong>of</strong> dynamics;◮ They are defined by the conditions:hH < 1 s ; h H > 1 s . (40)


Variety expansionEquilibriumGeneral remarks◮ In these different cases authors define long term determinants<strong>of</strong> the growth rates;◮ New intermediate products permit greater furtherspecialization in production in two countries;◮ The one with more efficient (comparatively) R&D producesmore intermediaries while the other produces final products;◮ The specialization leads to welfare gains in both countries;◮ The improvements in R&D being made in the backwardcountry will not speed the overall growth;◮ Thus complete concentration <strong>of</strong> R&D activities in the leadingcountry is efficient.


Variety expansionEquilibriumLiterature◮ <strong>Grossman</strong> G. <strong>and</strong> <strong>Helpman</strong> E. (1990) Comparative Advantage<strong>and</strong> Long-run Growth. The American Economic Review, Vol.80, No. 4, pp. 796-815;◮ Romer P. (1990) Endogenous Technological Change. Journal<strong>of</strong> Political Economy, Vol. 98, No. 5, Part 2, pp. S71-S102;◮ Ethier W. (1982) National <strong>and</strong> International Returns to Scalein the Modern Theory <strong>of</strong> Trade. The American EconomicReview, Vol. 72, No. 3, pp. 389-405.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!