12.07.2015 Views

danish research unit for industrial dynamics druid working paper no ...

danish research unit for industrial dynamics druid working paper no ...

danish research unit for industrial dynamics druid working paper no ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

DANISH RESEARCH UNIT FOR INDUSTRIAL DYNAMICSDRUID WORKING PAPER NO. 97-8Towards a Characterisation of AssetsAnd K<strong>no</strong>wledge Created in Tech<strong>no</strong>logicalAgreements: Some evidence from theAutomobile-robotics sector.ByNathalie Lazaric and Luigi MarengoSeptember 1997


TOWARDS A CHARACTERISATION OF ASSETS AND KNOWLEDGECREATEDIN TECHNOLOGICAL AGREEMENTS:Some evidence from the automobile-robotics sector 1 .Nathalie LAZARIC (University of Compiègne, France)And Luigi MARENGO (University of Trento, Italy)AbstractThis <strong>paper</strong> tries to bring new insights on the <strong>dynamics</strong> of inter-firm by focusing oncognitive and organisational dimensions. We consider the k<strong>no</strong>wledge bases created insidethe agreement and the characteristics of such k<strong>no</strong>wledge bases (such as tacitness, level ofgenerality, degree of centralisation...). The nature of assets <strong>for</strong> supporting this creation isalso essential <strong>for</strong> the redeployability of k<strong>no</strong>wledge created. We began by a brief review ofsome problems encountered by transactions cost eco<strong>no</strong>mics and present some case studiesof agreements between firms in the automobile and robotics sector. After having presenteda taxo<strong>no</strong>my of k<strong>no</strong>wledge and assets involved in such agreements, we bring some newdiscussion on the exploration/exploitation's dilemma. We argue finally that our taxo<strong>no</strong>mymay be fruitful <strong>for</strong> a better understanding of the dynamic of firm boudaries by trying to godeeper into the "black box" of agreements.KeywordsInter-firm relations, automobile industry, tech<strong>no</strong>logical agreementsJEL ClassificationD23, O32, L62ISBN (87-7873-027-9)1 A first version of this text was presented at EAEPE conference in Antwerp in Belgium ( 7- 9 November).Many thanks <strong>for</strong> useful comments from J. Niosi, B. Loasby, P. Saviotti and A. Narduzzo among others.


5ContentsPreface............................................................................................................................... 71. Introduction.................................................................................................................. 92. Dynamics of agreements and production of k<strong>no</strong>wledge: some open questions ........ 113. Presentation of the case studies.................................................................................. 174. Production of specific assets and their transfer......................................................... 235. Towards a taxo<strong>no</strong>my of k<strong>no</strong>wledge created in tech<strong>no</strong>logicalagreements ...................................................................................................................... 315.1 Characteristics of k<strong>no</strong>wledge produced ................................................................... 315.2 Transfer of k<strong>no</strong>wledge and dynamic of learning....................................................... 366. Conclusions ................................................................................................................. 41References ....................................................................................................................... 43


7PrefaceWe are happy to integrate international scholars in the DRUID network and to publish theircontributions in the DRUID <strong>working</strong> <strong>paper</strong> series. This is especially so when <strong>paper</strong>sanalyze phe<strong>no</strong>mena that are at the core of <strong>research</strong> programme of DRUID.A common concern <strong>for</strong> the programme as a whole is the relationship between k<strong>no</strong>wledgecreation and eco<strong>no</strong>mic development. Learning is regarded as a process that is fundamental<strong>for</strong> the per<strong>for</strong>mance of firms, networks and national systems of in<strong>no</strong>vation. To betterunderstand what is learnt, how and by whom is fundamental <strong>for</strong> making progress in thisrespect. This <strong>paper</strong> by Natalie Lazaric and Luigi Marengo makes an important contributionin this respect. The focus is on learning in connection with tech<strong>no</strong>logy agreements betweenfirms from respectively the automobile sector and the robotics sector.Distinctions are made between different kinds of k<strong>no</strong>wledge in terms of degree ofcodification, generality and centrality and it is shown that these factors have an impact onhow and to what degree learning takes place. The <strong>paper</strong> also demonstrates the limits oftransaction cost analysis when it comes to explain tech<strong>no</strong>logical agreements.We hope to be able to bring more contributions of this kind where the analysis of learningand k<strong>no</strong>wledge is concrete and empirically based. A key to make eco<strong>no</strong>mics more relevantis to develop a better understanding of the eco<strong>no</strong>mics of k<strong>no</strong>wledge-creation and of thelearning eco<strong>no</strong>my.Bengt-Åke Lundvall


91. IntroductionThe purpose of this <strong>paper</strong> is to attempt an analysis of the cognitive and organisational<strong>dynamics</strong> of inter-firm tech<strong>no</strong>logical agreements. One of the neglected dimensions intransactions cost eco<strong>no</strong>mics is the transfer of k<strong>no</strong>wledge and mutual learning in situations<strong>no</strong>t necessarily characterised by a high degree of opportunism. This conflictual/politicaldimension is <strong>no</strong>t ig<strong>no</strong>red, but we deliberately choose to focus our attention on the cognitiveaspects of the agreements. Incentive and conflict reducing mechanisms can<strong>no</strong>t on their ownexplain the existence and <strong>dynamics</strong> of such agreements and, especially, the creation ofcompetencies in the long run (Chandler, 1992, Dosi, Teece and Winter, 1992).Transactions Cost Eco<strong>no</strong>mics focuses on the production of specific assets withoutconsidering their underlying k<strong>no</strong>wledge bases. According to us, the nature andcharacteristics of such k<strong>no</strong>wledge bases (such as the level of tacitness, level of generality,degree of centralisation, etc.) drive the learning <strong>dynamics</strong> as well as the nature andcharacteristics of tech<strong>no</strong>logical, relational and organisational assets. The nature of assetsand of the k<strong>no</strong>wledge supporting them is essential <strong>for</strong> their potential redeployability.Indeed, tech<strong>no</strong>logical k<strong>no</strong>wledge characterised by a high degree of specificity may beconfined to an agreement and hardly be redeployable, thus reducing the combinativecapacities of the firm. Such k<strong>no</strong>wledge can thus push the firm into a competency trap,jeopardising its capacity to solve general problems.After a brief review of some problems encountered by transactions cost eco<strong>no</strong>mics inaccounting <strong>for</strong> the origin and <strong>dynamics</strong> of tech<strong>no</strong>logical agreements, we will present somecase studies of agreements between firms in the automobile and robotic sectors. This willlead us to present a taxo<strong>no</strong>my of the assets and k<strong>no</strong>wledge bases involved in suchagreements and to discuss the links between them. Finally we draw some conclusions.


112. Dynamics of agreements and production of k<strong>no</strong>wledge: some openquestionsThe aim of our contribution is to try to offer an alternative perspective from transactionscost eco<strong>no</strong>mics (TCE) by focusing on the way problem solving and competence gaps, push<strong>for</strong> the association of dissimilar activities. This point is important <strong>for</strong> explaining thestability and evolution of the T <strong>for</strong>m - "temporary <strong>for</strong>ms" according to Williamson'stermi<strong>no</strong>logy (Williamson, 1995). According to us, the TCE perspective misses twoimportant points <strong>for</strong> the correct understanding of inter-firms relations. As underlined byBrousseau (1996) and Lazaric and Wolff (1996), transactions cost theory falls short ofaccounting <strong>for</strong> institutional <strong>dynamics</strong>, as its perspective is a comparatively static one.Organisational <strong>for</strong>ms are <strong>no</strong>t really examined in their evolution and historical developmentbut compared under the hypothesis that static efficiency properties are sufficient to explaintheir selection.According to us this theoretical background, though indeed very relevant, is <strong>no</strong>t sufficient<strong>for</strong> the analysis of path-dependent processes of organisational adaptation. The very idea ofselecting the most efficient organisational <strong>for</strong>m is rather ambiguous, <strong>for</strong> on the one handboundedly rational agents can hardly be capable of selecting the most efficientorganisational <strong>for</strong>m, and, on the other hand, the capabilities of the market mechanisms <strong>for</strong>per<strong>for</strong>ming such selection has been widely questioned (cf., <strong>for</strong> instance, Winter (1986)).TCE assumes that agents can select ex-ante the best governance structure minimisingtransaction costs (Brousseau, 1996), whereas selection occurs with multiple and nestedselection criteria (e.g. organisational coherence, problem-solving, social interaction,tech<strong>no</strong>logical learning,.... cf. Dosi, 1995).Secondly, learning is described by TCE through the concept of “remediableness” (if agentsselect an inefficient organisational <strong>for</strong>m, they have the possibility of changing it). In ourview, this concept is <strong>no</strong>t sufficient to explain the context of learning embedded i<strong>no</strong>rganisational arrangements (competency trap, organisational inertia, cf. Levinthal, 1992).We argue that learning can<strong>no</strong>t be described only by the minimisation of transactions costsand has to be understood within a perspective of k<strong>no</strong>wledge building, with the possibility of


12individual and collective failures and the difficulty of choosing ex-ante optimal structuresof governance. As recognised by Langlois and Robertson:“.... the point is that one can<strong>no</strong>t have a complete theory of the boundaries of the firmwithout considering the process of learning in firms and markets. The reigning transactioncosttheories of vertical integration provide illuminating snapshots of possible institutionalresponses to a momentary situation. But they do <strong>no</strong>t place those responses in the context ofpassage of time. Most theories of the boundaries of the firm are static in an important sense.They take the circumstances of production as given and investigate comparatively theproperties of market-contract arrangements, internal organisation, and sometimes othermodes of organisation. What happens, however when the tech<strong>no</strong>logies of production-andperhaps other environmental factors- are changing rapidly?” (Langlois and Robertson, p.30).In TCE, organisational <strong>for</strong>ms originate from the inability of market mechanisms to channeland process in<strong>for</strong>mation effectively. In the evolutionary/cognitive perspective, by contrastorganisations are first of all loci of the creation, reproduction and modification ofk<strong>no</strong>wledge, and strong emphasis is put on the fact that the latter can<strong>no</strong>t be reduced to merein<strong>for</strong>mation processing (cf. Winter, 1982, Dosi and Marengo, 1994).Thirdly, opportunism may be important in agreements, but it may be <strong>no</strong>t the only valuemonitoring alliances. Two arguments can be stressed here. At the organisational level,transaction costs due to opportunism will decrease as learning takes place: with repeatedinteractions, hold-ups and moral hazard problems will be attenuated through the creation of<strong>no</strong>rms of cooperation and reciprocity as well as routines (Langlois and Robertson, ibid). Atthe individual level, we argue that opportunism may co-exist with other conflicting valueslike trust (Noorderhaven, 1996). Indeed there is ample recognition that the human mind is<strong>no</strong>t so mo<strong>no</strong>lithic and has to face judgement biases, cognitive dissonance and conflictingvalues (Tversky and Kahneman, 1978; Lazaric, 1996; Payne et al., 1992).Our major point in this <strong>paper</strong> is that tech<strong>no</strong>logical agreements should be mainly examinedas loci of learning and that such a learning dimension can<strong>no</strong>t be fully captured by analyticaltools which are confined to the mere consideration of transactions costs. A tech<strong>no</strong>logicalagreement has as its main purpose the generation of a new body of k<strong>no</strong>wledge out of the


13encounter and interaction of two or more previously existing bodies of organisationalk<strong>no</strong>wledge. Thus the nature and the <strong>dynamics</strong> of the agreement can<strong>no</strong>t be fully grasped interms of flow and processing of in<strong>for</strong>mation among the partners and the costs and incentiveproblems stemming from such activities. Some recent approaches on collectivecompetences (Hodgson, 1996), k<strong>no</strong>wledge bases (Beije, 1996), decision rules <strong>for</strong>cooperation (Nooteboom, 1996) and on the paradox of learning (Bureth, Wolff and Zanfei,1996), illustrate this cognitive dimension that we would like to explore further.Moreover, learning can<strong>no</strong>t be reduced to mere in<strong>for</strong>mation acquisition, but it impliesinterpretation, that is the generation of mental models, cognitive frames, categories whichare <strong>no</strong>t contained in and can<strong>no</strong>t be derived from in<strong>for</strong>mation (cf. Dosi and Marengo (1994),Marengo (1996), Dosi, Marengo and Fagiolo (1996)). In social organisations and, a<strong>for</strong>tiori, in tech<strong>no</strong>logical agreements, k<strong>no</strong>wledge and learning processes are typicallydistributed 2 and a successful agreement is the one which sets the appropriate interactionmechanisms <strong>for</strong> generating new collective k<strong>no</strong>wledge.At least two orders of problems are involved in designing such mechanisms: a first issueconcerns the communication and sharing of k<strong>no</strong>wledge, a second one concerns the degreeof commonality/diversity of the k<strong>no</strong>wledge bases and the learning processes involved. Onthe first issue, in addition to the already widely analysed strategic problems of in<strong>for</strong>mationdisclosure, pre-strategic obstacles to communication and sharing of k<strong>no</strong>wledge arise fromits tacit component. Tacitness prevents k<strong>no</strong>wledge from being fully communicated as it is<strong>no</strong>t entirely transparent even to those who possess it. Nelson and Winter (1982) havebroadly discussed the implication of tacit k<strong>no</strong>wledge <strong>for</strong> eco<strong>no</strong>mic organisation, but it isworth stressing that, as argued by Polanyi (1969), tacitness is much more widespread thanusually considered in the evolutionary eco<strong>no</strong>mics and eco<strong>no</strong>mics of technical changetradition. While Polanyi refers mainly to the tacit components in skilful (mainly physical)activities, where of course <strong>no</strong> codified set of instructions could ever contain all thek<strong>no</strong>wledge required, tacitness appears more generally in every act of interpretation andmeaning attribution, as it depends on categories, mental models, cognitive frames which2 K<strong>no</strong>wledge is said to be distributed when a group of agents k<strong>no</strong>w something that <strong>no</strong>ne of the members ofsuch a set (fully) k<strong>no</strong>ws. Of course such collective k<strong>no</strong>wledge is generated by the social interactionmechanisms which connect together. Distributed k<strong>no</strong>wledge must be distinguished from other <strong>for</strong>ms ofsocial distribution of k<strong>no</strong>wledge such as common k<strong>no</strong>wledge, when every member of the group k<strong>no</strong>wssomething, he k<strong>no</strong>ws that all the others k<strong>no</strong>w it, he k<strong>no</strong>ws that all the others k<strong>no</strong>w that he k<strong>no</strong>ws it, and soon ad infinitum.


14can only with difficulty be reduced to codified and communicable in<strong>for</strong>mation. Thus, thereexists a cognitive dimension in the problem of k<strong>no</strong>wledge disclosure and communication,which can act quite independently of the strategic use of k<strong>no</strong>wledge 3 . In particular, afundamental issue in managing effective k<strong>no</strong>wledge transfer in agreements is the provisio<strong>no</strong>f shared k<strong>no</strong>wledge, languages, codes which provide the parties with the necessarycapacity <strong>for</strong> effective communication and k<strong>no</strong>wledge absorption. Among these,organisational routines play an especially central role, as they carry the memory of pastinteraction (cf. Cohen et al. (1995)). It is our claim that the <strong>dynamics</strong> of agreements can<strong>no</strong>tbe fully analysed without referring to the characteristics and <strong>dynamics</strong> of the routinesdeveloped within the agreement itself.A second issue concerns the trade-off between commonality and diversity of k<strong>no</strong>wledgebetween the agents involved. First, consider the two (or more) organisations which <strong>for</strong>m theagreement and in particular those parts of the organisations which are actually involved init. If the k<strong>no</strong>wledge bases of the parties are homoge<strong>no</strong>us (that is the two originatingorganisations have analogous competencies) the agreement will probably face fewcoordination problems (at least as far as its cognitive aspect is concerned) but will beunlikely to provide opport<strong>unit</strong>ies <strong>for</strong> mutual learning of the parties involved, as each party’sk<strong>no</strong>wledge is already similar to the other’s. On the other hand, if the k<strong>no</strong>wledge bases arehighly diverse, opport<strong>unit</strong>ies <strong>for</strong> mutual learning are high, but communication andcoordination between parties are likely to be more problematic.Similar trade-offs between commonality and heterogeneity of k<strong>no</strong>wledge arise with respectto the relationship between the parts of each organisation, which are actually participatingin the learning process and the rest of the organisation itself. If, possibly because of highlearning produced by the agreement, this part of the organisation moves its k<strong>no</strong>wledge basisfurther away from the rest of the organisation, the chances <strong>for</strong> the latter to be able to exploitsuch new k<strong>no</strong>wledge are lowered. In other terms, cognitive coordination must be ensuredbetween the agreement and the originating organisations in order to allow the integration ofthe new k<strong>no</strong>wledge with that already existing.3 Indeed there are different meanings of tacitness. "Tacit à la Rosenberg" which refers to technical skillsdifficult to acquire without a long experience and practice. "Tacit à la Dasgupta/David" which refers onthe incentives to disclose k<strong>no</strong>wledge allowing rewards agents have <strong>for</strong> this disclosure process. "Tacit à laDosi" refers finally on unaware, automatic and unconscious skills like mental models and heuristics usedby agents <strong>for</strong> solving problems ans skills used during the repetition of a specific task. For a longer


15It is worth pointing out that such cognitive coordination can be achieved through differentorganisational set-ups, ranging from highly centralised creation of codes, routines andpractices which create and maintain a widely shared k<strong>no</strong>wledge basis, to highlydecentralised systems of k<strong>no</strong>wledge sharing and communication which instead generatesystems of local codes, routines and practices (cf., <strong>for</strong> some comparative analyses ofdifferent organisational set-ups, Crémer, 1992, Marengo, 1996).Related to the trade-off between tacitness and codification, the trade-off betweencommonality and diversity and the trade-off between centralisation and decentralisation, isa<strong>no</strong>ther fundamental “cognitive” trade-off which we believe constitutes a key dimension <strong>for</strong>the analysis of organisational <strong>for</strong>ms: it is the trade off between generality and specificity.Generality of k<strong>no</strong>wledge involves the possibility of applying it to a broad range of domains(Arora and Gambardella, 1994). Thus general k<strong>no</strong>wledge is more likely to be redeployed,articulated in widely shared categories, and thus also more likely to be commonly sharedand homogeneously distributed, and also more likely to be centralised. Fleck, in hisdescription of the implementation of engineering systems, makes a similar distinctionbetween generic and local k<strong>no</strong>wledge: "The local practical k<strong>no</strong>wledge is highly contingentto the particular firm concerned. It deals with the specific 'k<strong>no</strong>wledge base' built up overmany years of experience in carrying out the firm's business. Moreover, this localcomponent is usually distributed among the many operatives involved in day-to-dayactivities. In many cases, this k<strong>no</strong>wledge is tacitly embodied in skills and practices whichhave been gradually <strong>for</strong>med over a period and are <strong>no</strong>t available in any other centralised or<strong>for</strong>malised <strong>for</strong>m" (Fleck, 1994, pp. 641-642).discussion on those aspects, see Balconi (1997). Here in our discussion, we are refering more particularlyon tacit k<strong>no</strong>wledge "à la Rosenberg" or "tacit k<strong>no</strong>wledge à la Dosi".


173. Presentation of the case studiesThis <strong>research</strong> is primarily based on observations made during a study of the robotic sectorbetween 1992 and 1994, in which 8 agreements were followed in their historicaldevelopment. The aim of this investigation is to show how firms try to generate and absorbk<strong>no</strong>wledge through tech<strong>no</strong>logical agreements. We focus our attention on 8 agreementsbetween users and producers and try to see how cooperation evolves between the twopartners, how organisational co-ordination emerges and how specific assets are created.The agreements involve European firms of different nationalities: two agreements involveonly French partners, two only German partners and one only Italian partners; theremaining three involve partners of different nationalities. Data were collected byinterviews which were carried out during a period of two years, allowing <strong>for</strong> the study ofthe different interactions which intervened be<strong>for</strong>e the establishment of the <strong>for</strong>mal or thein<strong>for</strong>mal alliance. A two-year observation period was also important <strong>for</strong> updatingin<strong>for</strong>mation in the case of organisational change between the two firms (this wasparticularly important in the case of Renault -Renault Automation).These kind of agreement between automobile and robotic firms usually have the feature ofbeing motived by the goal of k<strong>no</strong>wledge generation (contrary to what usually happens inagreements which mainly serve the purpose of increasing production efficiency or reducingfinancial risks) and by tech<strong>no</strong>logical complementarities. In our view thesecomplementarities between partners provide stronger incentives to exchange and share abroader range of in<strong>for</strong>mation and k<strong>no</strong>wledge than is the case where partners simplycooperate to reduce production costs or share financial resources.All the tech<strong>no</strong>logical agreements considered here are characterised by high degree of quasiindependenceof the joint venture from the parent firms. This feature allows us to analysethe agreements in relative isolation, whereas stronger and more frequent links between theparent firms and the joint venture have an influence on the process of k<strong>no</strong>wledgegeneration. A general pre-condition <strong>for</strong> assuming quasi-independence of the joint venture isthat the parent firms be themselves independent entities: when in fact partners already havestrong links it seems hardly possible that what they give rise to can be properly defined as


18an agreement. For this reason, we study firms which do <strong>no</strong>t have reciprocal financial links.Two cases however appear as partial exceptions. First, the case of Renault and RenaultAutomation has been kept because the latter firm increased its independence during the 80'sand became auto<strong>no</strong>mous at the beginning of the 90's. The case of Comau and Fiat was alsokept even if Comau still has a financial link with Fiat, because of the great independence ofComau in terms of tech<strong>no</strong>logical creation.A<strong>no</strong>ther criterion <strong>for</strong> selection of alliances was the desire to analyse agreements whoseoperations had terminated. In this way it was possible to give an overall evaluation of theagreement. This criterion allowed <strong>for</strong> qualitative evaluation of the impact of the agreementon organisational conditions, the nature of the k<strong>no</strong>wledge produced, the <strong>dynamics</strong> oflearning, the nature of assets and their possible redeployability in others agreements. As thenumber of producers in the robotic sector is very small, we were also able to take intoconsideration all agreements or interactions which had taken place be<strong>for</strong>e the alliance.The automobile sector was chosen because car manufacturers have a long-standingcommitment to producing their own equipment, and have thus developed internalcompetencies in the design of robots. Citroën, BMW, Fiat and Renault have played a veryactive role in developing robotic k<strong>no</strong>w-how by beginning to design their own robots in theirplants be<strong>for</strong>e externalising this activity. Most of the users have there<strong>for</strong>e a specificexperience and may be considered in some cases as "lead users" 4 .This specific context helps to have a "history" of <strong>industrial</strong> relations between the firms andto illuminate some particular transfer of k<strong>no</strong>wledge realised in the agreements between thetwo firms. In this context it seems to us interesting to see how learning might be sustainedby these initial conditions and how learning can evolve in a <strong>no</strong>n deterministic wayaccording the nature of assets engaged in cooperation.The content of the agreements may concern the development of various projects. Someagreements concern the development and the implementation of software either <strong>for</strong>monitoring the robot or <strong>for</strong> improving the process by implementing an "off line" systemwhich provides data be<strong>for</strong>e the launching of the car. Some agreements include rathersophisticated opto-electronic developments concerning the robots <strong>for</strong> assembly lines.4 For a longer discussion on this point and some recent illustrations on the role of users in this dynamic, seeKong Rae Lee (1996), Hippel and Tyre (1995), Balconi (1996) and Fleck (1994).


19These projects are very uncertain in their development and in their commercialisationbecause each plant has its own configuration and its own constraints affecting theautomation of the assembly line and which introduce different kinds of complexity.Software <strong>for</strong> welding robots poses fewer problems because the users have a considerableexperience with this tech<strong>no</strong>logy whereas software <strong>for</strong> the assembly is <strong>no</strong>t very well tested.In short, all the agreements related to the development of rather uncertain tech<strong>no</strong>logies, ofwhich the partners had little experience. Only one agreement is rather different: the Renault-Renault Automation case concerns the development of a hydroelectric system in thepowering of the welding robot.Concerning organisational <strong>for</strong>ms, agreements are established in joint venture with theprinciple of an even sharing of the expenses. In<strong>for</strong>mal agreements are rather frequentbecause the mutual trust developed in previous interactions acted as a substitute <strong>for</strong> <strong>for</strong>malcontracting. In their implementation, <strong>for</strong>mal or in<strong>for</strong>mal agreements are <strong>no</strong>t very differentas regard tech<strong>no</strong>logical features. One agreement is dissimilar in its nature: the case of OEMagreements concerning BMW and Kuka <strong>for</strong> the commercialisation of a specific system firsttried out in the user plant. A complete presentation of the agreements is to be found in thefollowing table.


20Table 1: Presentation of the case studiesPartnersRenault French automobilefirmRenault AutomationFrench robot producerPSA Automobile producerRenault AutomationFrench robot producerRenault French AutomobilefirmABB Internationalrobot producerBMW German automobilefirmKuka German robotproducerMercedes Germanautomobile firmKuka German robotproducerFiat Italian automobile firmComau Italian robotproducerMercedes, GermanAutomobile firmComau Italian robotproducerCitroën, French automobilefirmComau Italian robotproducerYear of theagreementType of theagreement1985 in<strong>for</strong>malagreement1990 joint venture1991 joint venture1985 OEM1989 in<strong>for</strong>malagreement1984 in<strong>for</strong>malagreement1991 joint venture1989 in<strong>for</strong>malagreementField of the agreementDevelopment of a specific hydroelectricsystemLaser yag designing in weldingsystemDevelopment of an "off line"softwareDevelopment and commercialisatio<strong>no</strong>f a monitoringsystemDevelopment and of an optoelectronicsystemDevelopment of an electronicwelding systemDevelopment of an electronicwelding systemDevelopment of an "off line"monitoring system based onartificial intelligenceIn order to explain the content of tech<strong>no</strong>logical agreements in terms of the k<strong>no</strong>wledgeproduced, we need to see how tech<strong>no</strong>logical creation may be supported by intangibleinvestments allowing <strong>for</strong> the coordination of distant corporate cultures. Indeed establishing


21these intangible conditions are often a first step be<strong>for</strong>e making material commitments.Learning in these conditions is a very cautious process supported by relational investmentsand organisational rules which help to combine k<strong>no</strong>w-how in a coherent and shared way(Lazaric and Wolff, 1996; Lazaric, 1994; Bureth et al., 1996). Let us examine the differentkinds of assets produced in these agreements and their characteristics.


234. Production of specific assets and their transferIn order to occur, learning needs some specific commitments both in tangible andintangible assets <strong>for</strong> sustaining cooperation (Lazaric and Wolff, 1996; Gulati et al., 1994).These resources play two roles: on the one hand they coordinate diversity of k<strong>no</strong>wledgecoming from the association of two different corporate cultures and on the other hand theypreserve cooperation by creating irreversibility’s. If the partners do <strong>no</strong>t commit someresources, cooperation has little chance of succeeding. Firms engaging in cooperation haveto make a bet on the future rents from the alliance and must commit some resources withouthaving any degree of certainty about the returns on this kind of cooperation. In fact thisprocess is <strong>no</strong>t an automatic one and needs time <strong>for</strong> creating a climate of trust and <strong>for</strong>finding some organisational rules able to coordinate the diversity without bringing intoquestion the identities of the two firms involved (Bureth et al., 1996).Specific tech<strong>no</strong>logical assets can be embodied in some specific equipment but can alsoinclude some collective competencies, as we usually find in the design phase. They can berelational through the creation of many ties during the project or be<strong>for</strong>e its implementation.These assets are very important <strong>for</strong> mobilising new combinations of k<strong>no</strong>wledge whichcan<strong>no</strong>t be created if conflicts between firms exist. In this way, these relational assets aresustained by personal trust coming from close interactions between individuals <strong>working</strong>together. Finally as we shall show later, relational assets are the first step <strong>for</strong> improvingcoordination by helping the creation of some appropriate organisational mechanisms suchas rules or routines 5 . From a<strong>no</strong>ther side specific assets either tech<strong>no</strong>logical, relational ororganisational produce some strong externalities and increase returns to the ongoinglearning (Levinthal and March, 1981; March, 1991).These externalities promote exchange of in<strong>for</strong>mation and k<strong>no</strong>wledge that create a degree oflock-in which discourages the cooperation with others partners. That is the reason why welook very carefully at the nature of assets produced because some part of them may belocked in and difficult to transfer while some others may be re-deployed in different5 We would like to stress that building competencies in agreements can<strong>no</strong>t overlook the role of humancapital which play an active part in the trans<strong>for</strong>mation and adaptation of the tech<strong>no</strong>logy. These relationaland organizational resources are important <strong>for</strong> increasing the problem-solving capacity of each firm andmay be considered as assets (Winter, 1987).


24agreements giving stronger externalities to initial investments. The indivisible assets or thepartly re-deployable ones play an important role in enabling firms to benefit fromcooperation and avoid excessive specialisation occurring when they are unable to exploitwith other partners benefits from previous collaboration (Lazaric and Wolff, 1996; Burethand alii, 1996). Let us discuss more precisely the different types of assets be<strong>for</strong>e seeingtheir potential redeployability.* Tech<strong>no</strong>logical assetsTech<strong>no</strong>logical assets first are usually engaged in the cooperation after some period ofmutual observation (one or two years depending of the previous interactions be<strong>for</strong>e theagreement). For example all the firms have produced tech<strong>no</strong>logical assets which theredeployability is linked. In the case of ABB and Renault, by contrast, firms have <strong>no</strong>tsucceeded in committing shared resources <strong>for</strong> the creation of some joint artefact. Theselater two firms were cooperating <strong>for</strong> the first time together and discovering the way theywere <strong>working</strong>, and at the same time the difficulty of attuning their rather distant practices.ABB was used to implementing general principles which were easy to transfer from oneuser to a<strong>no</strong>ther one <strong>for</strong> the reproduction the automation process with few specifications.This firm as an international producer in this field, was <strong>no</strong>t used to making a lot ofconcessions <strong>for</strong> its user. From the other side Renault was cooperating with other <strong>for</strong>eignrobot producers and was rather demanding about the specificity of technical solutions. Ifthis firm was interested in a different way of implementing robots, it did <strong>no</strong>t question itsown corporate culture. So the cooperation between the two firms failed to build anytech<strong>no</strong>logical assets because in the climate of mutual observation it was difficult to puttogether current element of k<strong>no</strong>w-how and to combine them. At this stage cooperationremains merely a matter of eye contact without a credible commitment <strong>for</strong> sustaining it.Two others case studies show high degree of <strong>no</strong>n redeployability (examples of cases ofRenault and Renault Automation and of Renault Automation with PSA). These cooperationare very different in nature. The first is <strong>no</strong>n redeployable because the tech<strong>no</strong>logical assetsare exploiting a rather traditional trajectory based on hydraulic principles specific toRenault and difficult to transfer to a<strong>no</strong>ther user (all users were at this time engaged inelectric trajectory as well as in the motorization and in monitoring principles) (Lazaric,1992). PSA and Renault Automation on the other hand were engaged in a very risky project


25concerning a laser Yag <strong>for</strong> exploring a new way of cutting metals be<strong>for</strong>e placing thewheels. This project including a system of censoring that was so specific to user needs thatit was difficult to transfer it in a<strong>no</strong>ther plant.* Relational assetsTech<strong>no</strong>logical assets are supported by relational conditions because firms need to k<strong>no</strong>weach other be<strong>for</strong>e engaging in specific investments. Communication between the differentcorporate cultures is essential otherwise alliances may be limited to an association ofdiverse k<strong>no</strong>wledge without any absorption and trans<strong>for</strong>mation of it. These relational assetsprovide a mutual understanding and facilitate absorptive capacity: "Just as priorinvolvement in a given tech<strong>no</strong>logical domain facilitates the understanding andinterpretation of subsequent in<strong>for</strong>mation within that domain, prior in<strong>for</strong>mation sharing witha given individual enhances the interpretation of subsequent in<strong>for</strong>mation exchange. Theparticular "dialect" of different actors will be more effectively decoded" (Levinthal, 1996,p. 9). Shared language will be an important step <strong>for</strong> making current practices explicit and<strong>for</strong> trying to share elements of tacit k<strong>no</strong>wledge embedded in them.The transmission of collective k<strong>no</strong>wledge through narration gives a better idea of the waythe firms work and solve in situ problems. In this construction of shared languages, there isan ef<strong>for</strong>t of translation <strong>for</strong> expliciting practices and trying to incorporate some of them in amore <strong>for</strong>mal way. This narration is very important because some k<strong>no</strong>wledge may beobservable but difficult to articulate and to codify (Winter, 1987; Senker, 1995). Closelinks in a small comm<strong>unit</strong>y help to observe and to teach some of it (Brown and Duguit,1990)In our case studies a shared language has been created in almost all the agreements andsustained by prior interactions. In some cases the language is common because historicaland organisational reasons have created a sort of commonality between the different firms(in the case of Renault and Renault Automation and in that of Fiat and Comau). Sometimesshared language is present despite an apparent cultural distance between the two firms(Citröen and Comau; Mercedes and Comau). In this later case, prior interactions played animportant role in implementing a shared professional language between partners. In thecase of Renault and ABB, the cultural distance between the two firms brought some


26confrontation in the current practice without creating a shared language which unifiedthem.Communication and shared language are supported by a useful lubricant: trust emerging byclose contacts between individuals who are cooperating together. In this context we make adistinction between "personal trust" emerging from prior k<strong>no</strong>wledge between individualsand "organisational trust" concerning shared beliefs between two organisational entities(Dodgson, 1993). Personal trust concerns subjective beliefs: "the decision of an agent toplace trust in a<strong>no</strong>ther depends on her believing that he will act in a way that makes herbetter or worse off. In general when we say that agents trust one a<strong>no</strong>ther we are referring tothis background of belief among them" (Lazaric and Lorenz, 1995, p.2). These beliefs are<strong>no</strong>t given but take place at the same time that learning occurs: they are inductivelyconstructed at each step of the cooperation and opened to trans<strong>for</strong>mation if some agentproduces some contradictatory or ambiguous signals. Trust in cooperation may begin bysome personal links but this intangible asset will be less fragile if it is <strong>no</strong>t limited tobilateral ties and interpersonal relations and if this belief can be extended to the members o<strong>for</strong>ganisations. 6This belief is more bilateral in the relation of PSA and Renault Automation and in the caseof Citröen and Comau and does <strong>no</strong>t exist in the cooperation between Renault and ABB. It isinteresting to observe here that rapid success in tech<strong>no</strong>logical projects may have asignificant impact on this belief and may be a substitute of years of familiarity (<strong>for</strong>example, in the case of Mercedes and Comau initial success rapidly triggered thisdynamic). More generally organisational trust is most of the time based on competencies, iethe capacity one partner has <strong>for</strong> solving a problem, even if the situation is characterised bystrong uncertainty 7 . 'Competence trust' between organisations refers to the beliefs thattrading partners are capable of living up to their commitments. This <strong>no</strong>tion is distinct fromthe belief that partners are intending to uphold their promise: 'competence trust' refers to6 According Livet and Reynaud's definition, organizational trust depends on the members of a groupinvolved in some collective endeavour holding 'reasonable' belief that each is implicitly committed to it(Livet et Reynaud, 1997).7 For a similar point of view on competence trust in the japanese machine tool between users andspecialized suppliers, see Lee, 1996,p.494.


27the capacity to undertake certain tasks whereas 'intentions trust' refers more on the partner'shonesty to keep its promises (Sako, 1997) 8 .With regard to our previous discussion most of our case studies show strong ties betweenfirms and organisational trust. This result has to be analysed carefully because of the natureof the links be<strong>for</strong>e agreement takes place. Most of the time the agreement is just the<strong>for</strong>malisation of previous work over many years. Mercedes and Kuka <strong>for</strong> example wereinteracting from the end of the 70's. It is <strong>no</strong>t surprising in these conditions thatorganisational trust exists! Fiat-Comau and Renault -Renault Automation are in the sameposition whereas Mercedes-Comau have cooperated <strong>for</strong> only <strong>for</strong> five years but have alwayssucceeded in implementing very in<strong>no</strong>vative and risky projects. Organisational trust is inthis latter case more based on competence and a very good understanding facilitating thetransfer of solutions experienced in other agreements and their hybridisation according tonew constraints, than intentions or familiarity.*Organisational assetsRules are collective k<strong>no</strong>wledge that eco<strong>no</strong>mise individual k<strong>no</strong>wledge (ie they substitutecomplexity of individual k<strong>no</strong>wledge <strong>for</strong> the simplicity of collective k<strong>no</strong>wledge (Favereau,1989, 1995). More precisely, a rule is a prescription one may con<strong>for</strong>m to and whichindicates what behaviour is allowed or prohibited in a particular context (Shima<strong>no</strong>ff, 1980).In the case of cooperation, rules bring some mechanisms which may facilitate coordinationbetween two distant corporate culture. Rules may be considered as patterns of actionsexperienced in a local context be<strong>for</strong>e being repeated. They may be trans<strong>for</strong>med andreproduced through time if they tend to bring some robust responses to organisationalcoordination. We make a distinction between local rules which are specific domains and areproduced in some particular context which is difficult to reproduce, and "meta rules", <strong>no</strong>ndomain-specific because there is ample scope to interpret them and a capacity to reproducethem in a<strong>no</strong>ther context because they are general e<strong>no</strong>ugh in their principles to bring somemethodological k<strong>no</strong>wledge possible to transfer or to adapt in a<strong>no</strong>ther agreement. "Metarules" are defined as redeployable assets.8 If these <strong>no</strong>tions are conceptually distinct, they are often related in practice because the belief that yourpartner is able to undertake certain tasks is also related to its intentions to undertake them <strong>no</strong>t in a<strong>no</strong>pportunistic manner.


28The first "meta rule" that we observed can be called the rule of "step by step". Most of ourcase studies show that firms started by making small commitments to each other and thenprogressively increased their commitments depending on the quality of their exchange.Learning follows in this case an incremental process. Firm generally begin theircooperation on some rather mi<strong>no</strong>r tech<strong>no</strong>logical problems. Cooperation in Germanybetween Kuka and Mercedes and Kuka and BMW <strong>for</strong> example began with Fraunhoferinstitutions on small tech<strong>no</strong>logical projects partly supported by the institute. If partnerssucceed in their collaboration including a third partner they may begin other moresignificant collaborations. For example the robot producer has been involved intech<strong>no</strong>logical developments <strong>for</strong> a new car model in BMW and Mercedes with moreimportant financial commitments. This process of engaging more investments incooperation took as long as three to four years and has been strongly supported byrelational ties. At the same time that engagements were increasing, meta rules onappropriability were constructed to facilite transfer of k<strong>no</strong>wledge outside agreements.This other meta rule was guiding tech<strong>no</strong>logical appropriability by fixing some generalprescriptions about transfer. In this way, it stabilises tech<strong>no</strong>logical development allowingclarifications in the transferability of technical solutions and providing a compromisebetween collective interests (ie the rapid dissemination of in<strong>no</strong>vative solutions) and theindividual interests of the user (ie to preserve the exclusivity of his solution). The cases ofBMW-Kuka and Mercedes-Kuka are very illustrative of this kind of dynamic. For examplein the case of the creation of specific off-line software <strong>for</strong> monitoring the robot, thetechnical solution and its methodology are transferred, but the data of this specific softwareremains confidential. The general principle is to maximise the dissemination of in<strong>no</strong>vativesolutions after maintaining exclusivity <strong>for</strong> a short time (around 24 months) helping firms toconvert k<strong>no</strong>wledge in further cooperation and to benefit from prior experience. Quote herethat users and producers' interests are contradidactory because a user has a strong incentiveto preserve the confidentiality of technical solutions as long as possible to benefitin<strong>no</strong>vation's rent whereas the supplier has an interest in transmitting as soon as possible thiscollective k<strong>no</strong>wledge in order to exploit this in<strong>no</strong>vation with different users. Firms have tofind appropriate compromises <strong>for</strong> separating private from public k<strong>no</strong>wledge and have tocreate temporary rights <strong>for</strong> each participant (data in software programmation may remainconfidential and may be re-used in others agreements in excluding some specificin<strong>for</strong>mation from user like the site configuration). If firms have <strong>no</strong>t e<strong>no</strong>ugh experience and


29general k<strong>no</strong>wledge about those aspects, they are <strong>no</strong>t able to find a suitable compromisebetween private and collective interests 9 .Comau <strong>for</strong> example has also a great capacity to combine k<strong>no</strong>wledge and to convert it indifferent cooperations by fixing meta rules producing methodological k<strong>no</strong>wledge which iseasy to transfer in to different contexts. ABB from the other side set down by someorganisational rules rather similar from one cooperation to a<strong>no</strong>ther but does try e<strong>no</strong>ugh toadapt rules with different contexts. ABB gives some general principles about the creation ofan "off line" software but this firm is <strong>no</strong>t flexible e<strong>no</strong>ugh to operate any hybridisation withuser conditions. This impedes some new combinations of k<strong>no</strong>wledge and does <strong>no</strong>t en<strong>for</strong>ceabsorptive capacity <strong>for</strong> the user.Some others local rules deal more with problems of uncertainty. In order to face difficultiesin tech<strong>no</strong>logical creation and unexpected constraints, the rule is to continue to invest <strong>for</strong> theproject at least one year even if the initial results seem <strong>no</strong>t to be very promising. Thisspecific rule has been very useful in the case of the Mercedes Comau agreement becausefirms encounter local problems with the Sindelfingen plant. Equipment required differentunpredictable adaptations. Comau incited its partner to reinvest <strong>for</strong> one more year and findfinally new ways to design equipment according specific indications during the two lastsmonths. This solution proved to be very in<strong>no</strong>vative and a useful means of exploringk<strong>no</strong>wledge coming from different agreements. This local rule which seems to be trivial isimportant because tech<strong>no</strong>logical projects often encounter problems of delay and ofadaptation to local conditions. If partners are <strong>no</strong>t able to deal with this uncertainty bychanging the terms of initial contracts engaged at the beginning of the joint venture theyhave be disappointed by the cooperation. In fact partners have to adapt their owncompetence and their requests during the project <strong>for</strong> supporting this collective work.Without compromises from both sides cooperation is likely to disappoint partners. Thecomplete presentation of assets produced is to be found in the following table.9 For a more global description of private, public and collective k<strong>no</strong>wledge in science, see Cassier andForay, 1996.


30Table 2: Assets created in agreementsTech<strong>no</strong>logical and relational assetsOrganisational assetsRenault and • Tech<strong>no</strong>logical assets <strong>no</strong>n redeployable • Local rulesR A • Common language • Organisational trustPSA and R A • Indivisible tech<strong>no</strong>logical assets • Local rules• Shared language• Personal trustRenault and . No tech<strong>no</strong>logical assets • Meta rulesABB • High cultural distance between firms • No trustBMW and Kuka • Tech<strong>no</strong>logical assets partly redeployable • Local and meta rules• Shared language• Organisational trustMercedes and • Tech<strong>no</strong>logical assets partly redeployable • Local and meta rulesKuka • Shared language • Organisational trustFIAT and • Tech<strong>no</strong>logical assets partly redeployable • Local rulesComau • Common language • Organisational trustMercedes and • Tech<strong>no</strong>logical assets redeployable • Local and meta rulesComau • Shared language • Organisational trustCitroën and • Tech<strong>no</strong>logical assets redeployable • Local and meta rulesComau • Shared language • Personal trust


315. Towards a taxo<strong>no</strong>my of k<strong>no</strong>wledge created in tech<strong>no</strong>logical agreementsOur next step, in this section, is to see more explicitly the link between assets andk<strong>no</strong>wledge produced in agreements <strong>for</strong> going inside the "black box" of the generation ofspecific capabilities with regard to organisational contexts. We try to stretch a taxo<strong>no</strong>my ofk<strong>no</strong>wledge created and to give some elements of interpretation concerning the dynamic oflearning. This taxo<strong>no</strong>my tries to bring some light to bear on the nature of k<strong>no</strong>wledgeaccording the level of codification, the level of diversity, the level of generality and thelevel of centralisation 10 . We look very carefully at the link between the level ofgeneralisation and other kinds of k<strong>no</strong>wledge (according the level of codification <strong>for</strong>example) and try to see if any kind of k<strong>no</strong>wledge has an impact on the exploitation andexploration trade-off supporting the learning process.5.1 Characteristics of k<strong>no</strong>wledge produced* Level of codificationK<strong>no</strong>wledge generated inside the agreement is most of the time both tacit and codified 11 .This k<strong>no</strong>wledge has initially been taught through direct experimentation. After a period ofteaching, some codification has been done. This process is <strong>no</strong>t trivial because roboticproduction is complex and requires different bodies of interrelated k<strong>no</strong>wledge. This level ofcomplexity calls <strong>for</strong> specific procedures in order to codify k<strong>no</strong>wledge without excluding itstacit dimension. In practice we observe that engineers have to have worked together at leastone year in order to explain their own practice and their idiosyncratic needs. After thisperiod of k<strong>no</strong>w-how exchange, some groups try to memorise the shared k<strong>no</strong>wledge through10 The taxo<strong>no</strong>my relies upon a qualitative evaluation of k<strong>no</strong>wledge produced. Empirical facts have beencollected during interviews and update when the organizational entity has been trans<strong>for</strong>med.In<strong>for</strong>mations are used here more to bring some light on the historical perspective of competencies'building than to bring some accurate measures of k<strong>no</strong>wledge created.11 As recognized Senker, in the robotic sector, tacit k<strong>no</strong>wledge coexist most of the time with codificationprocedure because of the distributed k<strong>no</strong>wledge incorporated in each firm. " Limits to codificationexposed by attemps to produce general solutions to automation as shown by the history of <strong>industrial</strong>robots. The original vision <strong>for</strong> this tech<strong>no</strong>logy was the production of a universal replacement <strong>for</strong> humanlabour. In the event, families of different special-purpose robots have emerged, adapted to the needs ofspecific users and specific applications. Moreover, the successful implementation of robots depends on'detailed and specific k<strong>no</strong>wledge about the particular situation in which it is proposed to introduce arobot, and about the tech<strong>no</strong>logy itself" (Fleck, 1983, p. 67); beside being widely distributed throughoutan organisation, much of this k<strong>no</strong>wledge is tacit and uncodified "(Senker, 1993, p.221).


32a procedure of "reporting". This consists in writing all the steps involved in tasks and theobjectives <strong>for</strong> the next step. In the case of Mercedes and Comau, firms began by solving theproblem of plant configuration. Secondly, an internal report in the agreement was discussed<strong>for</strong> planning the next stage which consists in the creation of a specific software able to takein consideration all these parameters. This rule of reporting also helps to summarise and toarticulate previous tasks and to see their evolution. An important consequence was that thisprocedure helps to simplify the current work and to generalise the local k<strong>no</strong>wledge. If thisprocedure of memorisation was perceived at the beginning <strong>for</strong> engineers as a constraintwhich impedes the organisational coordination to go quicker, after some period (betwee<strong>no</strong>ne and two years) they understand its utility and were <strong>no</strong>t any more reluctant to apply andto improve it.In most of our cases studies tacit k<strong>no</strong>wledge coexisted with more codified <strong>for</strong>ms(memorised in internal reports or data). Nevertheless some agreements show an importantdegree of tacit k<strong>no</strong>wledge. BMW /Kuka and Renault /Renault-Automation cases show somedifficulty in the trans<strong>for</strong>mation of local k<strong>no</strong>wledge in to general. Some reasons explain thisprocess. Firstly, codification is as long as it is costly and requires particular attention.Secondly, when firms are cooperating over a long period they think that there is <strong>no</strong>necessity to articulate prior tasks. This strategy may be risky in the case of high tur<strong>no</strong>ver aswe saw in the Kuka firm. After a conflictual period the robotic firm has renewed thecontracts of a large number of employees. Some of them were dedicated to the project withBMW and have had great difficulty understanding current procedures and prior work.Codification does <strong>no</strong>t mean an easier access from outside the patnership to tech<strong>no</strong>logical ororganisational capabilities. Codification does <strong>no</strong>t necessarily decrease the complexity of theproduct and does <strong>no</strong>t necessarily facilitate the absortive capacity by others users because ofthe need to adapt tech<strong>no</strong>logy according plant's specificity. Robotic tech<strong>no</strong>logy has to copewith many utilisation’s in different contexts, producing situated k<strong>no</strong>wledge that is <strong>no</strong>t easyto transfer. That the reason why this process does <strong>no</strong>t allow a free access <strong>for</strong> thistech<strong>no</strong>logy. As Balconi recognised, the problem of <strong>no</strong>n easy transferability goes beyondcodification because of the need of trans<strong>for</strong>ming tech<strong>no</strong>logy according user's needs and ofproviding practical demonstration on site to transmit k<strong>no</strong>w-how and by explaining k<strong>no</strong>w -why (Balconi, 1996).


33Three types of problem are related to the dynamic of codification. Firstly, the incentive tocodify tacit k<strong>no</strong>wledge and to articulate in general categories (Nelson and Winter, 1982).Secondly, the costs and the benefits of this articulation on new media generate atrans<strong>for</strong>mation of traditional k<strong>no</strong>w-how and k<strong>no</strong>w-why (Lundvall and Johnson, 1994).Thirdly, the cost of this codification which will be related to the nature of the environment.In an environment characterised by high uncertainty about tech<strong>no</strong>logical trajectories,incentives to codification are rather low. In a stable environment however benefits are moretangible (Cowan and Foray, 1996). In the robotic sector, characterised by an intermediateuncertainty about tech<strong>no</strong>logical development, firms find some benefit from codification butalso some paradoxes due to the sophistication of robotic use 12 .* Level of diversityIn most of our case studies shared k<strong>no</strong>wledge was very important <strong>for</strong> the starting up of theagreement. In the case of very diverse k<strong>no</strong>wledge like ABB and Renault, firms havedifficulty creating assets and do <strong>no</strong>t trust e<strong>no</strong>ugh to exchange tacit k<strong>no</strong>wledge. In thisexample, firms explore some new ideas but do <strong>no</strong>t have e<strong>no</strong>ugh incentive to exploit themoutside this locus of experimentation. Here shortness in the relationship is an importantfactor because the confrontation of the different corporate cultures has <strong>no</strong>t been overcomeby familiarity and personal links inside the agreement. Shared k<strong>no</strong>wledge is most of thetimes connected with a shared or common language between firms which decreases somecultural distance between the two entities. As trust takes time to be constructed, the absenceof prior ties between firms play a negative role in the creation of specific k<strong>no</strong>wledge.In the case of Renault and ABB, firms in their agreement were confronted with differentvisions <strong>for</strong> solving problems (technical or organisational ones) and were <strong>no</strong>t able to find asuitable compromise in order to absorb new background k<strong>no</strong>wledge. On the other hand, thegap between two different capabilities was too distant with empirical and tacit k<strong>no</strong>wledgeused by Renault and codified k<strong>no</strong>wledge used by ABB allowing the international firm tooffer technical solutions with any user. The gap between the firms did <strong>no</strong>t allow the12 Benefits from opto-electonics in some applications like the fitting out in last operations of assembly line,have been hardly questionned because the productivity obtained by using opto-electronic systems likesensors is lost with a decrease of flexibility in the case of a breakdown. In these applications, humanlabor with its tacit k<strong>no</strong>wledge is fareaway more flexible ! Nevertheless in traditional operations likehandling or manipulations, uncertainty is weaker and advantages to codification higher.


34combination of different types of k<strong>no</strong>w-how or progress in the exploration of sophisticated"off-line” monitoring system.* Level of generalityIn terms of level of generality, firms encounter difficulties in finding an appropriate balancebetween local and general k<strong>no</strong>wledge. Local k<strong>no</strong>wledge is most of the time associated withlocal rules and <strong>no</strong>n redeployable assets (as in the cases of Renault and Renault Automation,PSA and Renault Automation, BMW and Kuka, Mercedes and Kuka). Firms createk<strong>no</strong>wledge but find it hard to accomplish some generalisation <strong>for</strong> exploiting it in othersagreements. Their investments remain local and have lower returns that in a case ofpossible transfer. The most illustrative feature of this local k<strong>no</strong>wledge is one producedinside the Renault and Renault Automation case. K<strong>no</strong>w-how was created according theidiosyncratic needs of the user in the trajectory of hydraulic servo-mechanism <strong>for</strong> welding.Renault-Automation has in fact little possibility of exploiting this technical k<strong>no</strong>wledge withother users and to diffuse its local competence in this field. Indeed all users during the 80'sadopted electrical servo-mechanisms in powering and have slowly deserted hydraulic orpneumatic servo-mechanisms in the connecting of components with electric systems. Thisextreme case shows how crucial is the trade-off between general and local k<strong>no</strong>wledge inavoiding competency trap.General k<strong>no</strong>wledge is as well based on technical principles as organisational ones. Wemean that the way k<strong>no</strong>wledge is produced and organised according to the degree ofspecificity or generality plays an important role in transferring k<strong>no</strong>wledge more than theonly process of codification. In some cases, codification may be interconnected with thelevel of generality but this process is <strong>no</strong>t automatic. Moreover, codified k<strong>no</strong>wledge may beincluded in local k<strong>no</strong>wledge because even if you produce codified k<strong>no</strong>w-how, you do <strong>no</strong>thave the guarantee to extract e<strong>no</strong>ugh methodological k<strong>no</strong>wledge to exploit it in a<strong>no</strong>theragreement.Local and general k<strong>no</strong>wledge was generated by Comau during its agreements with <strong>for</strong>eignpartners. This firm has in fact a great ability to extract methodological k<strong>no</strong>wledge and to reexploitit with new partners <strong>for</strong> the production of new combinations of k<strong>no</strong>w-how. Forexample, a long-satnding task between Comau and Fiat created "Robogate", a celebrated


35welding system integrating robot and engineering processes into the same conception. Thissolution, allowing a good synchronisation of product and process, is a major in<strong>no</strong>vation,based on a specific methodology <strong>for</strong> welding. The cooperation between the two firms wasintensive between 1976 and 1982 and less regular after this period. Fiat was however <strong>no</strong>twilling to invest in new tech<strong>no</strong>logical cooperation and wanted to exploit a technicalsolution to improve the process, Comau began to explore new technical opport<strong>unit</strong>ies with<strong>for</strong>eign users. Agreements with Citroën and Mercedes were illustrative of this new way of<strong>working</strong>. This exploration was crucial <strong>for</strong> Comau which had an important k<strong>no</strong>w-how in themachine tool business and needed to trans<strong>for</strong>m it by integrating new kinds of k<strong>no</strong>wledge inelectronic trajectory. The cooperation between Comau and Mercedes in 1991 <strong>for</strong> a weldingsystem, which took as its dominant design the "Robogate", gives a better idea of thisdynamic. In the case of the "Robogate", user and producer were adapting the weldingsystem to the plant configuration, but the particular configuration of the Sindelfingenchanged the routinized way of <strong>working</strong>. These new constraints trans<strong>for</strong>med the weldingsystem bringing new in<strong>no</strong>vative solutions in the way the robot approached the car. Insteadof exploiting the same methodology, Comau managed in recombining existing technicalsolutions and organisational procedures <strong>for</strong> improving and renewing previous in<strong>no</strong>vations.This cooperation which created the "Rotogate" benefited from important learningexternalities with other users. Comau had in 1986 began to work with BMW <strong>for</strong> improvingthe "Robogate" on the E 30 model. Comau and BMW concluded an in<strong>for</strong>mal agreementtwo years later <strong>for</strong> improving this system during the E 34 launching. This very ambitiousproject failed because of time delays and excessive material investments <strong>for</strong> the two firms.The failure was relative and gave Comau experience useful in its cooperation withMercedes three years later. Comau was able to create a specific solution, to use this localk<strong>no</strong>wledge and it had the capacity to extract abstract k<strong>no</strong>wledge from practice.As we can see, most of the time local and general k<strong>no</strong>wledge is complementary. Asillustrated by Fleck in his concept of "learning by trying", successful implementation of atech<strong>no</strong>logy is "a matter of finding a synthesis of local and generic k<strong>no</strong>wledge adequate <strong>for</strong>meeting particular requirements" (Fleck, 1994, p. 647).* Level of centralisation


36K<strong>no</strong>wledge produced in agreements is in most cases decentralised. This seems ratherobvious because alliances are sub <strong>unit</strong>s, quasi-independent of their owners. This quasiauto<strong>no</strong>my is important <strong>for</strong> creating an entity able to solve problems without beingconstantly monitored by a hierarchical structure. The level of effective decentralisation hasto be carefully examined. Kline and Rosenberg have underlined this point by showing theadvantages of Japanese firms <strong>for</strong> in<strong>no</strong>vating in quasi-horizontal organisation (Kline andRosenberg, 1986). The aim of this horizontal organisation is to cluster links betweendifferent departments and to speed feed-backs inside each step of the in<strong>no</strong>vative process.Small structures or decentralised <strong>unit</strong>s may be more able to create local k<strong>no</strong>wledge and mayprovide strong incentives <strong>for</strong> supporting in<strong>no</strong>vative projects (Nonaka, 1994).Our case studies show an important degree of decentralised k<strong>no</strong>wledge. Two agreementscontradict however this principle. Renault and Renault Automation is illustrative of a weaklevel of decentralised k<strong>no</strong>wledge which has to be explained with the story of the firms.Renault Automation became independent at the beginning of the 90's, but has strong linkswith its user because the robotic activity was initially created in its department be<strong>for</strong>e beinga distinct entity. In this historical context, Renault has always monitored its robotic supplierand considered it as a part of its own activities. Although the firms became auto<strong>no</strong>mousfrom a juridical point of view at the beginning of the 90's, historical conditions have createdsome path dependence in tech<strong>no</strong>logical creation. In the case of Comau and Fiat, where linksare considerable, <strong>industrial</strong> relations are different. Fiat began its robotic activity byincorporating a firm coming from the machine tool sector. Comau has a different corporateculture and was used to <strong>working</strong> with different <strong>industrial</strong> partners. The creation of internalcompetencies in the field of robotics was made through constant and regular work with Fiatand through different interactions with others partners (Italian or international). AlthoughComau still has some financial links with Fiat, the robotic <strong>unit</strong> is more independent in itstech<strong>no</strong>logical creation than its French partner because <strong>no</strong>t monitored by a single user. Thisexplains why Comau was able to combine different backgrounds of k<strong>no</strong>wledge and to bevery in<strong>no</strong>vative during the 90's.5.2 Transfer of k<strong>no</strong>wledge and dynamic of learningConsidering <strong>no</strong>w the dynamic of learning, we have to take in consideration different kindsof k<strong>no</strong>wledge generation. In the first case, firms in cooperation have both learned and


37increased their internal level of competence (cases of Mercedes and Kuka, PSA and RenaultAutomation, Fiat and Comau, Mercedes and Comau, Citröen and Comau). PSA has <strong>for</strong>example tried to help Renault Automation to absorb some competence in electric trajectoryby <strong>working</strong> with its producer in designing electrical robots and in sophisticated optoelectronicsprojects. PSA has also experimented the first electrical robot produced byRenault Automation in 1985 and has generated an important feed-back <strong>for</strong> improving thedominant design. From the other side, PSA has benefited from considerable in<strong>for</strong>mation onthe automative process (simplification on the line <strong>for</strong> bringing less complexity). Thelearning dynamic has explored new paths inside the electrical and opto-electronic trajectoryand at the same time has exploited new ideas <strong>for</strong> improving the technical solutions createdand <strong>for</strong> implementing them in a more realistic way (the laser Yag solution <strong>for</strong> assemblyrequired some important simplifications in order to be robust e<strong>no</strong>ugh on the line).Agreements with Comau (in the cases of Fiat, Mercedes and Citroën) show a similardynamic of the mutual benefits of cooperation with an in<strong>no</strong>vative dynamic characterised byboth exploitation and exploration. Comau begun its in<strong>no</strong>vative project with Fiat and hascreated the Robogate, a major in<strong>no</strong>vation in the robotic sector. This creation is in fact anautomative product integrating robots and various pieces of equipment on the line. Withoutimportant requirements coming from its user and a high level of learning by doing, Comauwould have <strong>no</strong>t been able to create such a successful piece of equipment in <strong>for</strong>eign markets.This project, patented at the beginning of the 80's, was trans<strong>for</strong>med <strong>for</strong> new plantconfiguration at the beginning of the 90's. Automobile firms needed more flexibleequipment and redeployable processes. Rationalisation in this sector required flexible linesadapted to small batches which could be easily trans<strong>for</strong>med according to user needs. Thisequipment also needed to be reconverted in others plants. The"Robogate" was <strong>no</strong>t flexiblee<strong>no</strong>ugh. That the reason why Mercedes and Comau created a new line benefiting from bothcompetencies (the competencies of Mercedes in flexible automative pocess and thecompetence of Comau in designing equipment including robots). This process called"Rotogate", patented in 1991, has been recreated with other users according theiridiosyncratic needs. Comau has developed an internal competence allowing the firm totrans<strong>for</strong>m and to combine its specific equipment with different backgrounds of k<strong>no</strong>wledge(the case of Citroën and Comau illustrates this combinative capacity). Comau proposes ageneral methodology flexible e<strong>no</strong>ugh <strong>for</strong> being adapted to user needs. This helps it to


38explore new ways of solving problems and to exploit prior k<strong>no</strong>wledge coming fromdifferent agreements by generalising and transferring local k<strong>no</strong>w-how.Other case studies show a different way of learning through the unilateral transfer ofk<strong>no</strong>wledge. BMW and Kuka Renault and Renault Automation illustrate the case of leadusers which have begun to produce robots by themselves and tried to transfer thiscompetence to their own producer. BMW, <strong>for</strong> example, started to build robots in anexperimental way in the middle of the70's. This automobile firm developed somein<strong>no</strong>vative solutions (<strong>no</strong>tably the portical robot <strong>for</strong> welding) and decided to exploit thistech<strong>no</strong>logy and to improve it with Kuka by giving to this firm a property right to exploitsome technical solutions (licence of exploitation). Kuka thus absorbed considerable k<strong>no</strong>whowin this sector and was able to develop in<strong>no</strong>vative solutions on her own some yearslater. This firm was able to trans<strong>for</strong>m this local k<strong>no</strong>wledge and to explore different ways ofsolving problems in the 80's and has developed important in<strong>no</strong>vative solution in theelectrical trajectory allowing it to compete with international firms like Comau and ABB.Its explorative capacity was also rein<strong>for</strong>ced by major collaborations with Fraunhoferinstitutes (IPA and IPK) helping it gradually to absorb new skills in opto-electronicstech<strong>no</strong>logies.Contrary to the case of Kuka and BMW, Renault and Renault Automation did <strong>no</strong>t succeedin extracting local k<strong>no</strong>wledge and transferring it in others agreements. This lowcombinative capacity may be explained by some historical events. This firm was constantlymonitored by its user who had previously created the robotics department and wasmonitoring this activity according its specific needs. This impedes the producer fromexploring different backgrounds of k<strong>no</strong>wledge and trans<strong>for</strong>ming its competence accordingto international competition. To summarise briefly, the transfer of k<strong>no</strong>wledge coming fromits specific user "locked" Renault Automation into the hydraulic trajectory and graduallyevicted it from international markets.In the middle of the 80's, Renault Automation tried to absorb different backgrounds ofk<strong>no</strong>wledge by cooperating with other users (<strong>no</strong>tably PSA), but encountered manydifficulties to go beyond its existing competence’s and has <strong>no</strong>t e<strong>no</strong>ugh k<strong>no</strong>w-how in theelectronic trajectory to compete with <strong>for</strong>eign producers. The exploitation of the hydraulicstechnical solution progressively decreased its capacity to solve various problems and


39prevented it from benefiting from the diversity of k<strong>no</strong>wledge of others users. That thereason why the firm was <strong>no</strong>t able to propose in<strong>no</strong>vative solutions at the end of the 80's andhas <strong>no</strong>t really succeeded to in regaining its lead in this field.The presentation of the cognitive characteristics created in agreements are to be found inthe following table.


40Table 3: Dynamic of learning and cognitive characteristics of agreementsCharacteristics of k<strong>no</strong>wledge producedCharacteristicsCharacteristics ofof transferlearningLevel ofLevel ofLevel ofLevel ofLevel of absorptiveLevel ofdiversitygeneralisatiocentralisatiocodificationcapacityexploitation ornnexplorationRenaultSharedLocalLinksTacitTransfer ofExploitation andandRenaultAutomationK<strong>no</strong>wledgek<strong>no</strong>wledgefrequentbetwee<strong>no</strong>wner firmsk<strong>no</strong>wledgemoreimportantk<strong>no</strong>wledge fromRenault to RenaultAutomationcompetencytrap in hydraulicstechnicalsolutionPSA andSharedLocalDecentra-Tacit andTransfer ofExploitation withRenaultAutomationanddiversek<strong>no</strong>wledgelisedk<strong>no</strong>wledgesomecodifiedk<strong>no</strong>wledge <strong>for</strong> 2firms in a rathersomeexplorationk<strong>no</strong>w-k<strong>no</strong>wledgesymmetric wayledgeRenaultDiverseGeneralDecentra-CodifiedNo transferExplorationand ABBK<strong>no</strong>w-k<strong>no</strong>wledgelisedk<strong>no</strong>wledgeledgek<strong>no</strong>wledgeBMW andSharedLocalDecentra-More tacitTransfer ofExploitationKukaK<strong>no</strong>w-k<strong>no</strong>wledgelisedthan codifiedk<strong>no</strong>wledge fromledgek<strong>no</strong>wledgeBMW to KukaMercedes andSharedLocalDecentra-Tacit andTransfer ofExploitation andKukaK<strong>no</strong>w-k<strong>no</strong>wledgelisedcodifiedk<strong>no</strong>wledge <strong>for</strong> the 2explorationledgek<strong>no</strong>wledgefirmsFIAT andSharedLocal andLinksTacit andTransfer ofExploitation andComauK<strong>no</strong>w-generalfrequentcodifiedk<strong>no</strong>wledge <strong>for</strong> the 2explorationledgek<strong>no</strong>wledgebetweenfirmsowner firmsMercedes andSharedLocal andDecentra-Tacit andTransfer ofHigh explorationComauK<strong>no</strong>w-generallisedcodifiedk<strong>no</strong>wledge <strong>for</strong> the 2andledgek<strong>no</strong>wledgek<strong>no</strong>wledgefirmsexploitationCitroën andSharedLocal andDecentra-Tacit andTransfer ofExploitation andComauK<strong>no</strong>w-generallisedcodifiedk<strong>no</strong>wledge <strong>for</strong> the 2explorationledgek<strong>no</strong>wledgek<strong>no</strong>wledgefirms


416. ConclusionsThis <strong>paper</strong> was intended as a first attempt to shed new light on the nature and <strong>dynamics</strong> ofinter-firm tech<strong>no</strong>logical agreements by focusing on the learning aspects. As the mainpurpose of such agreements is to create new competencies, we have argued that the natureand characteristics of the k<strong>no</strong>wledge bases which originate such learning process play anessential role in defining the directions and the outcome of learning. In particular, the casestudies examined in this <strong>paper</strong> show a link between the degree of generality of thek<strong>no</strong>wledge produced in the agreement and the capacity of exploring new learning paths.This explorative capacity also appears linked to the ability to generate meta-rules.In many agreements characterised by an explorative capacity (Mercedes and Kuka, Fiat andComau, Mercedes and Comau, Citroën and Comau), the assets produced are totally orpartly redeployable and supported by meta rules (except in the case of Fiat and Comauwhere path dependency in the relationship impeded the creation of more general rules).Most of the time k<strong>no</strong>wledge is general (in the case of Mercedes and Kuka neverthelessk<strong>no</strong>wledge is codified but also local) but also supported by local k<strong>no</strong>wledge in order tohave the possibility of understanding the users' needs. The explorative capacity may bereduced to pure exploration without transfer of k<strong>no</strong>wledge and shared assets if firms are <strong>no</strong>table to reduce the distance between their corporate culture and to combine some k<strong>no</strong>wledgetogether (see the case of ABB and Renault where general and meta rules have beeninsufficient <strong>for</strong> the dynamic of learning). The level of centralisation however does <strong>no</strong>t havea clear role either on exploration or on exploitation, even if most of the case studies arecharacterised by decentralised k<strong>no</strong>wledge. This level is most of the time more related to thehistorical specificity of each user in this sector.In the case of exploitation with low exploration (as in the cases of Renault and RenaultAutomation, PSA and Renault Automation, BMW and Kuka), we can see that k<strong>no</strong>wledge ismore often tacit than codified and local, assets are difficult to redeploy, whereas rules aremore generally local than general.We argue finally that our taxo<strong>no</strong>my of k<strong>no</strong>wledge and assets produced may be fruitful <strong>for</strong> abetter understanding of the dynamic of firms' boundaries by trying to go deeper into the"black box" of agreements. A debate, that according to us, goes beyond a purely cognitive


42perspective (with only the codification issue) and beyond the TCE vision which overestimatesthe political aspects such as opportunism, excluding the possibility of discoveringthe creation of competencies in the long run.


43ReferencesArora A. and Gambardella A. (1994) : “The changing tech<strong>no</strong>logy of tech<strong>no</strong>logicalchange : general and abstract k<strong>no</strong>wledge and the division of in<strong>no</strong>vative labour”, ResearchPolicy 23.Balconi M. (1996) : "Tech<strong>no</strong>logical capabilities, learning and codification of k<strong>no</strong>wledge",Working Paper, International Conference of Mexico September.Beije P. (1996) : "Transaction Costs and tech<strong>no</strong>logical learning", in J. Groenewegen (eds)Bureth A., Zanfei A. and Wolff S. (1995): “The two faces of learning by cooperating :The evolution and stability of inter-firm agreements in the European electronics industry”,Worshop “The eco<strong>no</strong>mics of scientific and tech<strong>no</strong>logical <strong>research</strong> in Europe”, Urbi<strong>no</strong>, Italie24-25 février. Forthcoming in Journal of Eco<strong>no</strong>mic Behavior and Organization, 1996.Brousseau E.(1996) : "Néo-institutionnalisme et évolutionnisme : quelles convergences",Working <strong>paper</strong> in Colloque Evolutionnisme, Sorbonne Paris 19-20 Sept.Brown J. S. et Duguit P. (1991) : "Organizational learning and comm<strong>unit</strong>ies-of -practice :towards a unified view of <strong>working</strong>", learning and in<strong>no</strong>vation, in Organization Science, Vol2, n° 1, Février.Cassier M. and Foray D. (1996) : "Building public and collective k<strong>no</strong>wledge in science",Working Paper, University of Dauphine, Paris.Chandler A. (1992) : "Organizational Capabilities and The Eco<strong>no</strong>mic History of theIndustrial Enterprise", Journal of Eco<strong>no</strong>mic Perspectives, Vol. 6, Number 3.Cohen M.D, Burkhart R., Dosi G., Egidi M., Marengo L., Warglien M. et Winter S.(1995) : "Routines and other recurring action patterns of organizations: contempory <strong>research</strong>issues", Working <strong>paper</strong>, Santa Fe institute, à paraitre dans Industrial and Corporate Change,1996.


44Cowan R. and Foray D. (1996) : "The eco<strong>no</strong>mics of codification and the diffusion ofk<strong>no</strong>wledge", Mimeo.Dosi G., Teece D. et Winter S. (1992) : “Toward a Theory of Corporate Coherence :preliminary Remarks”, dans Dosi G. et alii (eds), Tech<strong>no</strong>logy and enterprise in a historicalperspective, Ox<strong>for</strong>d University Press, Ox<strong>for</strong>d.Dosi G. and F. Malerba (1996) : Organization and Strategy in the Evolution of theEnterprise, London, MacMillan.Dosi G. and L. Marengo (1994) : “Toward a Theory of Organizational Competencies”, inR.W. England (ed.), Evolutionary Concepts in Contemporary Eco<strong>no</strong>mics, Ann Arbor,Michigan University Press, pp. 157-178.Dosi G., L. Marengo and G. Fagiolo (1996) : "Learning in Evolutionary Environments",Laxenburg, Austria, IIASA <strong>working</strong> <strong>paper</strong>.Favereau O. (1995) : "Apprentissage collectif et coordination par les règles : application àla théorie des salaires", dans Lazaric N. et Monnier JM (eds), Eco<strong>no</strong>mica.Fleck J. ( 1994) : "Learning by trying : the implementation of configurational tech<strong>no</strong>logy",Research Policy, 23.Foss N.J. (1993) : "Theories of the firm : contractual and competence perspectives", Journalof evolutionary Eco<strong>no</strong>mics, 3.Groenewegen J. (eds) (1996) : Transaction cost ecomics and beyond, Kluwer AcademicPublishers.Hodgson G.(1996) : "Corporate culture and the nature of the firm" in Groenewegen J. edsKline S. J.& Rosenberg N. (1986) : "An overview of in<strong>no</strong>vation", in The positive SumStrategy, R. Landau, N. Rosenberg, Academy of Engineering Press, pp 275-305.


45Kong Rae Lee (1996) : "The role of user in the in<strong>no</strong>vation of machine tools : the japanesecase", Research Policy, 25.Langlois R. and Robertson P. (1994): Firms markets and eco<strong>no</strong>mic change, RoutledgeLondon and New York.Lazaric N. (1996 a): "Apprentissage collectif et frontières de la firme", Miméo Février,soumis à la Revue d'Eco<strong>no</strong>mie Politique.Lazaric N. (1996 b) : "Organizational Learning and Combinative Capacity duringtech<strong>no</strong>logical agreements : some Empirical Evidence in the Robotic Sector", RevueInternationale de Systémique, Vol. 10, n° 3.Lazaric N.and Wolff S. (1996): "Dynamique organisationnelle des accords inter-firmes : lecas des tech<strong>no</strong>logies de l'in<strong>for</strong>mation", Mimeo.Lazaric N.and Lorenz E. (1997): "Trust and learning during inter-firms agreements",<strong>for</strong>thcoming in Eco<strong>no</strong>mics of Trust and Learning, Lazaric N. et Lorenz E. eds, Ed. Elgar,London.Livet P. and Reynaud B. (1997): "Organizational trust, learning and implicitcommitments", <strong>for</strong>thcoming in The eco<strong>no</strong>mics of trust and learning, Lazaric N. and LorenzE. eds, Edward Elgar London.Marengo L. (1996): “Structure, competences and learning in an adaptive model of thefirm”, in G. Dosi and F. Malerba (1996),Nelson R. et Winter S. (1982): An evolutionary theory of eco<strong>no</strong>mic change, HarvardUniversity Press.Nonaka I. (1994): "A dynamic theory of Organizational K<strong>no</strong>wledge Creation",Organization Science, vol. 5, n°1,


46Nooderhaven N. G. (1996) : "Opportunism and trust in transaction cost eco<strong>no</strong>mics", inGroenewegen J. eds.Nooteboom B.(1996) : "Towards a learning based model of transactions", in GroenewegenJ. eds.Polanyi, K. (1969): K<strong>no</strong>wledge and Being, Routledge.Sako M. (1997): "The in<strong>for</strong>mational requirements of trust in supplier relations : evidencefrom Japan Europ and the United States", <strong>for</strong>thcoming in The eco<strong>no</strong>mics of trust andlearning , Lazaric and Lorenz eds, Edward Elgar London.Senker J. (1993): "The contribution of tacit k<strong>no</strong>ledge to in<strong>no</strong>vation", AI - Society , 7.Senker J. (1995): "Tacit k<strong>no</strong>wledge and models of in<strong>no</strong>vation", Industrial and CorporateChange, Volume 4 (2).Tversky D. and Kahneman D. (1982): "On the study of stastistical intuitions", in"Judgement under uncertainty: heuristics and biases", Kahneman D. Slovic P. et Tversky A.eds., Cambridge University Press.Von Hippel E. and Tyre MJ. (1995): "How lerning by doing is done: problemidentification in <strong>no</strong>vel process equipment", Research Policy, 24.Williamson O. (1985): The eco<strong>no</strong>mic institutions of capitalism, Free Press, New York.Williamson O. (1995): "Hierarchies, power, authority and in eco<strong>no</strong>my: an eco<strong>no</strong>micperspective", Industrial and Corporate Change, Volume 4 ( 1).Winter S.G. (1986): "Comments on Arrow and on Lucas", Journal of Business, vol. 59,pp. 5427-34.


47Winter S.G. (1987): "K<strong>no</strong>wledge and competence as strategic assets", in Teece D.J. thecompetitive challenge: strategies <strong>for</strong> <strong>industrial</strong> in<strong>no</strong>vation and renewal, BallingerCambridge.Winter S.G. (1988) : "On Coase, competence and the corporation", Journal of Law andEco<strong>no</strong>mic Organization, 4.


49Danish Research Unit <strong>for</strong> Industrial DynamicsThe Research ProgrammeThe DRUID-<strong>research</strong> programme is organised in 3 different <strong>research</strong> themes:- The firm as a learning organisation- Competence building and inter-firm <strong>dynamics</strong>- The learning eco<strong>no</strong>my and the competitiveness of systems of in<strong>no</strong>vationIn each of the three areas there is one strategic theoretical and one central empirical andpolicy oriented orientation.Theme A: The firm as a learning organisationThe theoretical perspective confronts and combines the ressource-based view (Penrose,1959) with recent approaches where the focus is on learning and the dynamic capabilities ofthe firm (Dosi, Teece and Winter, 1992). The aim of this theoretical work is to develop ananalytical understanding of the firm as a learning organisation.The empirical and policy issues relate to the nexus tech<strong>no</strong>logy, productivity, organisationalchange and human ressources. More insight in the dynamic interplay between these factorsat the level of the firm is crucial to understand international differences in per<strong>for</strong>mance at themacro level in terms of eco<strong>no</strong>mic growth and employment.Theme B: Competence building and inter-firm <strong>dynamics</strong>The theoretical perspective relates to the <strong>dynamics</strong> of the inter-firm division of labour andthe <strong>for</strong>mation of network relationships between firms. An attempt will be made to developevolutionary models with Schumpeterian in<strong>no</strong>vations as the motor driving a Marshallianevolution of the division of labour.The empirical and policy issues relate the <strong>for</strong>mation of k<strong>no</strong>wledge-intensive regional andsectoral networks of firms to competitiveness and structural change. Data on the structure ofproduction will be combined with indicators of k<strong>no</strong>wledge and learning. IO-matrixes whichinclude flows of k<strong>no</strong>wledge and new tech<strong>no</strong>logies will be developed and supplemented bydata from case-studies and questionnaires.


50Theme C: The learning eco<strong>no</strong>my and the competitiveness of systems of in<strong>no</strong>vation.The third theme aims at a stronger conceptual and theoretical base <strong>for</strong> new concepts such as'systems of in<strong>no</strong>vation' and 'the learning eco<strong>no</strong>my' and to link these concepts to theecological dimension. The focus is on the interaction between institutional and technicalchange in a specified geographical space. An attempt will be made to synthesise theories ofeco<strong>no</strong>mic development emphasising the role of science based-sectors with those emphasisinglearning-by-producing and the growing k<strong>no</strong>wledge-intensity of all eco<strong>no</strong>mic activities.The main empirical and policy issues are related to changes in the local dimensions ofin<strong>no</strong>vation and learning. What remains of the relative auto<strong>no</strong>my of national systems ofin<strong>no</strong>vation? Is there a tendency towards convergence or divergence in the specialisation intrade, production, in<strong>no</strong>vation and in the k<strong>no</strong>wledge base itself when we compare regions andnations?The Ph.D.-programmeThere are at present more than 10 Ph.D.-students <strong>working</strong> in close connection to theDRUID <strong>research</strong> programme. DRUID organises regularly specific Ph.D-activities such asworkshops, seminars and courses, often in a co-operation with other Danish or internationalinstitutes. Also important is the role of DRUID as an environment which stimulates thePh.D.-students to become creative and effective. This involves several elements:- access to the international network in the <strong>for</strong>m of visiting fellows and visits at the sisterinstitutions- participation in <strong>research</strong> projects- access to supervision of theses- access to databasesEach year DRUID welcomes a limited number of <strong>for</strong>eign Ph.D.-students who wants to workon subjects and project close to the core of the DRUID-<strong>research</strong> programme.External projectsDRUID-members are involved in projects with external support. One major project whichcovers several of the elements of the <strong>research</strong> programme is DISKO; a comparative analysisof the Danish In<strong>no</strong>vation System; and there are several projects involving international cooperationwithin EU's 4th Framework Programme. DRUID is open to host other projects asfar as they fall within its <strong>research</strong> profile. Special attention is given to the communication of<strong>research</strong> results from such projects to a wide set of social actors and policy makers.


51DRUID Working Papers96-1 Lundvall, Bengt-Åke: The Social Dimension of the Learning Eco<strong>no</strong>my.(ISBN 87-7873-000-7)96-2 Foss, Nicolai J.: Firms, Incomplete Contracts and Organizational Learning.(ISBN 87-7873-001-5)96-3 Dalum, Bent and Villumsen, Gert:Are OECD Export Specialisation PatternsSticky?’ Relations to the Convergence-Divergence Debate. (ISBN 87-7873-002-3)96-4 Foss, Nicolai J: Austrian and Post-Marshallian Eco<strong>no</strong>mics: The Bridging Work ofGeorge Richardson. (ISBN 87-7873-003-1)96-5 Andersen, Esben S., Jensen, Anne K., Madsen, Lars and Jørgensen, Martin:The Nelson and Winter Models Revisited: Prototypes <strong>for</strong> Computer-BasedReconstruction of Schumpeterian Competition. (ISBN 87-7873-005-8)96-6 Maskell, Peter: Learning in the village eco<strong>no</strong>my of Denmark. The role ofinstitutions and policy in sustaining competitiveness. (ISBN 87-7873-006-6)96-7 Foss, Nicolai J. & Christensen, Jens Frøslev: A Process Approach to CorporateCoherence. (ISBN 87-7873-007-4)96-8 Foss, Nicolai J.: Capabilities and the Theory of the Firm. (ISBN 87-7873-008-2)96-9 Foss, Kirsten: A transaction cost perspective on the influence of standards onproduct development: Examples from the fruit and vegetable market. (ISBN 87-7873-009-0)96-10 Richardson, George B.: Competition, In<strong>no</strong>vation and Increasing Returns. (ISBN87-7873-010-4)96-11 Maskell, Peter: Localised low-tech learning in the furniture industry.(ISBN 87-7873-011-2)96-12 Laursen, Keld: The Impact of Tech<strong>no</strong>logical Opport<strong>unit</strong>y on the Dynamics ofTrade Per<strong>for</strong>mance. (ISBN 87-7873-012-0)96-13 Andersen, Esben S.: The Evolution of an Industrial Sector with a Varying Degreeof Roundaboutness of Production. (ISBN 87-7873-013-9)


5296-14 Dalum, Bent, Laursen, Keld & Villumsen, Gert: The Long Term Development ofOECD Export Specialisation Patterns: De-specialisation and “Stickiness”. (ISBN 87-7873-014-7)96-15 Foss, Nicolai J.: Thorstein B. Veblen: Precursor of the Competence-BasedApproach to the Firm. (ISBN 87-7873-015-5)96-16 Gjerding, Allan Næs: Organisational in<strong>no</strong>vation in the Danish private businesssector. (ISBN 87-7873-016-3)96-17 Lund, Reinhard & Gjerding, Allan Næs: The flexible company In<strong>no</strong>vation, workorganisation and human ressource management. (ISBN 87-7873-017-1)97-1 Foss, Nicolai J.: The Resource-Based Perspective: An Assessment and Diag<strong>no</strong>sis ofProblems. (ISBN 87-7873-019-8)97-2 Langlois, Richard N. & Foss, Nicolai J.: Capabilities and Governance: the Rebirthof Production in the Theory of Eco<strong>no</strong>mic Organization. (ISBN 87-7873-020-1)97-3 Ernst, Dieter: Partners <strong>for</strong> the China Circle? The Asian Production Networks ofJapanese Electronics Firms. (ISBN 87-7873-022-8)97-4 Richardson, George B.: Eco<strong>no</strong>mic Analysis, Public Policy and the SoftwareIndustry. (ISBN 87-7873-023-6)97-5 Borrus, Michael & Zysman, John: You Don’t Have to Be A Giant: How TheChanging Terms of Competition in Global Markets are Creating New PossibilitiesFor Danish Companies. (ISBN 87-7873-024-4)97-6 Teubal, Morris.: Restructuring and Embeddeness of Business Enterprises-Towardsan In<strong>no</strong>vation System Perspective on Diffusion Policy. (ISBN 87-7873-025-2)97-7 Ernst, Dieter & Guerrieri, Paolo: International Production Networks andChanging Trade Patterns in East Asia: The case of the Electronics Industry. (ISBN87-7873-026-0)97-8 Lazaric, Nathalie & Marengo, Luigi: Towards a Charaterisation of Assets andK<strong>no</strong>wledge Created in Tech<strong>no</strong>logical Agreements: Some evidence from teautomobile-robotics sector. (ISBN 87-7873-027-9)


53In<strong>for</strong>mation <strong>for</strong> subscribers.Subscription price <strong>for</strong> 1997 is 600 DKR (about 20 <strong>paper</strong>s). The rate <strong>for</strong> single issues is 40DKR. It is possible to make a commitment to an exchange of <strong>paper</strong>s from relateddepartments or <strong>research</strong> teams. All correspondence concerning the DRUID Working Papersshould be send to.Pernille WittrupFibigerstræde 4DK-9220 Aalborg OETel. 45 96 35 82 65Fax. 45 98 15 60 13E-mail: <strong>druid</strong>-wp@business.auc.dk

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!