12.07.2015 Views

The Futility of Unification and Harmonization in International ...

The Futility of Unification and Harmonization in International ...

The Futility of Unification and Harmonization in International ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

UNIVERSITY OF VIRGINIA SCHOOL OF LAWLegal Studies Work<strong>in</strong>g Papers Series<strong>The</strong> <strong>Futility</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Unification</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Harmonization</strong><strong>in</strong> <strong>International</strong> Commercial LawPaul B. StephanWork<strong>in</strong>g Paper No. 99-10June 1999This paper can be downloaded without charge from theSocial Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=1692091


2<strong>The</strong> <strong>Futility</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>Unification</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Harmonization</strong> <strong>in</strong><strong>International</strong> Commercial LawPaul B. Stephan *<strong>The</strong> title <strong>of</strong> this symposium h<strong>in</strong>ts at a certa<strong>in</strong> complacency about a venerable project. For morethan a century, specialists <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>and</strong> comparative law have gathered <strong>in</strong> various venues topromote convergence <strong>in</strong> those national laws that affect <strong>in</strong>ternational commercial transactions. <strong>The</strong>yhave pursued, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> large part achieved, the promulgation <strong>of</strong> conventions <strong>and</strong> other legal <strong>in</strong>strumentsthat states <strong>in</strong> turn have adopted to govern this commerce. Today, for example, <strong>in</strong>ternational sales <strong>of</strong>goods, bank credits <strong>and</strong> payments, <strong>and</strong> contracts <strong>of</strong> carriage largely rest on these laws, as does agrow<strong>in</strong>g body <strong>of</strong> procedural rules regulat<strong>in</strong>g the disputes that arise when these transactions turn sour.Apparently <strong>in</strong>ternational traders need unification <strong>and</strong> harmonization <strong>of</strong> the law <strong>and</strong> have embracedthe efforts <strong>of</strong> lawyers to meet these dem<strong>and</strong>s.I wish to sound a skeptical note. Much <strong>of</strong> the effort directed at unify<strong>in</strong>g these laws isunnecessary, <strong>and</strong> some produces rules that h<strong>in</strong>der rather than promote <strong>in</strong>ternational bus<strong>in</strong>ess. <strong>The</strong>sedeficiencies are due, I will argue, to <strong>in</strong>herent limitations <strong>in</strong> the process that generates <strong>in</strong>ternationalagreements for national implementation. <strong>The</strong> specialist community, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> particular scholars, haveexacerbated the problem by a mistaken focus on what the project should produce. We ought to spendless time draft<strong>in</strong>g rules to govern the substantive rights <strong>and</strong> duties <strong>of</strong> persons engaged <strong>in</strong> a transaction,<strong>and</strong> more on devis<strong>in</strong>g ways to encourage states to facilitate contractual choices made by parties <strong>in</strong>the course <strong>of</strong> transactions <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> encourag<strong>in</strong>g states to reveal how they propose to deal with privatedisputes aris<strong>in</strong>g out <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational commerce.I beg<strong>in</strong> by ask<strong>in</strong>g what benefits may unification <strong>and</strong> harmonization achieve. I dist<strong>in</strong>guish threegoals—reduction <strong>of</strong> legal risk associated with <strong>in</strong>ternational commerce, law reform, <strong>and</strong> enhancement<strong>of</strong> the role <strong>of</strong> legal advisers to <strong>in</strong>ternational bus<strong>in</strong>ess people. Next I exam<strong>in</strong>e the process thatgenerates <strong>in</strong>ternational conventions <strong>and</strong> model laws. <strong>The</strong> political economy <strong>of</strong> this process resultstoo <strong>of</strong>ten either <strong>in</strong> rules written for the benefit <strong>of</strong> particular <strong>in</strong>dustries <strong>and</strong> other <strong>in</strong>terest groups, or<strong>in</strong> the suppression <strong>of</strong> conflict that <strong>in</strong> turn <strong>in</strong>creases legal risk. F<strong>in</strong>ally I speculate about otherstrategies for <strong>in</strong>ternational lawmak<strong>in</strong>g that might ameliorate some <strong>of</strong> the problems that lie embedded<strong>in</strong> the k<strong>in</strong>ds <strong>of</strong> legal <strong>in</strong>struments that we currently produce.I. THE BENEFITS OF UNIFICATION AND HARMONIZATION<strong>The</strong> impulse to reduce diversity among the legal systems govern<strong>in</strong>g commerce has manifesteditself for as long as people have traded across political boundaries. One <strong>of</strong> the glories <strong>of</strong> the RomanEmpire <strong>and</strong> Byzantium was the coherence <strong>of</strong> Roman law, which unified the rules <strong>of</strong> commerce for*Percy Brown, Jr. Pr<strong>of</strong>essor <strong>and</strong> Barron F. Black Research Pr<strong>of</strong>essor, University <strong>of</strong> Virg<strong>in</strong>ia School <strong>of</strong> Law. I amgrateful for comments <strong>and</strong> criticism from Curtis A. Bradley, Helmut Koziol, Robert E. Scott, Michael J. Wh<strong>in</strong>cop <strong>and</strong>participants <strong>in</strong> the 1998 Sokol Colloquium, <strong>and</strong> for research assistance provided by X<strong>in</strong>h Luu <strong>and</strong> Joe Wynne. Responsibilityfor misjudgments, mistakes, <strong>and</strong> other lapses rema<strong>in</strong>s solely m<strong>in</strong>e.


large portions <strong>of</strong> the commercial world. <strong>The</strong> revival <strong>of</strong> Roman law <strong>in</strong> Western <strong>and</strong> Central Europedur<strong>in</strong>g the eleventh <strong>and</strong> twelfth centuries had much to do with the desire <strong>of</strong> the various market cities1to acquire a s<strong>in</strong>gle template for shap<strong>in</strong>g the rules govern<strong>in</strong>g trade. More recently <strong>and</strong> closer to home,the Supreme Court <strong>of</strong> the United States through Justice Story launched the body <strong>of</strong> federal common2law as a means <strong>of</strong> provid<strong>in</strong>g common rules for <strong>in</strong>terstate commerce. <strong>The</strong> various Uniform Laws, <strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong> particular the Uniform Commercial Code, cont<strong>in</strong>ue this project. Similarly, groups now seek todevelop a common private law for the members <strong>of</strong> the European Union.<strong>The</strong>se examples <strong>in</strong>volve the imposition <strong>of</strong> a unified body <strong>of</strong> rules by an <strong>in</strong>stitution with at leastsome sovereign powers, or the creation <strong>of</strong> coherent rules <strong>in</strong> the absence <strong>of</strong> any nation state. Whatwe have seen dur<strong>in</strong>g the last century is a systematic effort to enlist sovereign nations <strong>in</strong> the unification<strong>of</strong> the law <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational commerce. <strong>The</strong> effort’s successes <strong>in</strong>clude, cit<strong>in</strong>g only the most prom<strong>in</strong>ent3examples, the Vienna Convention on the <strong>International</strong> Sale <strong>of</strong> Goods (CISG), the BrusselsConvention for the <strong>Unification</strong> <strong>of</strong> Certa<strong>in</strong> Rules <strong>of</strong> Law Relat<strong>in</strong>g to Bills <strong>of</strong> Lad<strong>in</strong>g (the Hague4Rules), the Warsaw Convention on the <strong>Unification</strong> <strong>of</strong> Certa<strong>in</strong> Rules Relat<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>International</strong>5Transportation by Air (Warsaw Convention), the New York Convention on the Recognition <strong>and</strong>6Enforcement <strong>of</strong> Foreign Arbitral Awards, the Hague Convention on the Service Abroad <strong>of</strong> Judicial7<strong>and</strong> Extrajudicial Documents <strong>in</strong> Civil or Commercial Matters, the Hague Convention on the Tak<strong>in</strong>g8Evidence Abroad <strong>in</strong> Civil or Commercial Matters, <strong>and</strong> the <strong>International</strong> Chamber <strong>of</strong> Commerce’s9<strong>International</strong> Rules for the Interpretation <strong>of</strong> Trade Terms (Incoterms) <strong>and</strong> Uniform Customs <strong>and</strong>10Practice for Documentary Credits (UCP). Many more projects rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> various stages <strong>of</strong>gestation.What motivates us to produce these laws? Many explanations exist, only some <strong>of</strong> which reflectwell on the process. To underst<strong>and</strong> how unification <strong>and</strong> harmonization proceeds <strong>in</strong> the contemporary31See generally Harold J. Berman, <strong>The</strong> Law <strong>of</strong> <strong>International</strong> Commercial Transactions (Lex Mercatoria), 2 EMORYJ. INT’L DISPUTE RESOL. 235 (1988).2Swift v. Tyson, 16 Pet. (41 U.S.) 1 (1842).3Convention on Contracts for the <strong>International</strong> Sale <strong>of</strong> Goods, Apr. 10, 1980, U.N. DOC. A/Conf/97/18, repr<strong>in</strong>ted <strong>in</strong>52 FED. REG. 6264 (1987) [here<strong>in</strong>after CISG].4Convention for the <strong>Unification</strong> <strong>of</strong> Certa<strong>in</strong> Rules <strong>of</strong> Law Relat<strong>in</strong>g to Bills <strong>of</strong> Lad<strong>in</strong>g, August 25, 1924, 51 Stat. 233(1934) [here<strong>in</strong>after Hague Rules] implemented by Carriage <strong>of</strong> Goods at Sea Act, __ Stat. ____, 46 U.S.C. App. §§ 1300-15(19__).5Convention for the <strong>Unification</strong> <strong>of</strong> Certa<strong>in</strong> Rules Relat<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>International</strong> Transportation by Air, Oct. 12, 1929, 49Stat. 3000, T.S. No. 876 (1934) [here<strong>in</strong>after Warsaw Convention].6Convention on the Recognition <strong>and</strong> Enforcement <strong>of</strong> Foreign Arbitral Awards, 21 U.S.T. 2517, T.I.A.S. No. 6997(1970).7Convention on the Service Abroad <strong>of</strong> Judicial <strong>and</strong> Extrajudicial Documents <strong>in</strong> Civil or Commercial Matters, 20 U.S.T.261, T.I.A.S. No. 6638 (1969).8Convention on the Tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> Evidence Abroad <strong>in</strong> Civil or Commercial Matters, 23 U.S.T. 2555, T.I.A.S. No. 7444(1974).9<strong>International</strong> Chamber <strong>of</strong> Commerce, PUBLICATION NO. 460, INCOTERMS—INTERNATIONAL RULES FOR THEINTERPRETATION OF TRADE TERMS (1990).10<strong>International</strong> Chamber <strong>of</strong> Commerce, PUBLICATION NO. 500, UNIFORM CUSTOMS AND PRACTICE FOR DOCUMENTARYCREDITS (1993) [here<strong>in</strong>after UCP].


4world, consider first what a benevolent <strong>and</strong> public-spirited <strong>in</strong>ternational lawmaker might wish toaccomplish.A. Manag<strong>in</strong>g Legal RiskA benevolent lawmaker’s first objective should be predictability <strong>and</strong> stability <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternationalcommercial relations. In a world <strong>of</strong> multiple legal systems <strong>and</strong> uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty about where th<strong>in</strong>gs willgo wrong, the parties must worry about divergent rules apply<strong>in</strong>g to their disputes. A carrier or goodsmay end up <strong>in</strong> one place, the parties may hold assets <strong>in</strong> another, <strong>and</strong> courts <strong>in</strong> any number <strong>of</strong>jurisdictions might both make it easy to sue foreign parties <strong>and</strong> refuse to apply another jurisdiction’ssubstantive law. Know<strong>in</strong>g that this divergence exists, parties may act opportunistically, such as byclaim<strong>in</strong>g a default <strong>and</strong> fil<strong>in</strong>g suit <strong>in</strong> a jurisdiction know for its eccentric rules <strong>and</strong> practices. Expect<strong>in</strong>gthis, parties <strong>in</strong> turn will <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> ways to protect themselves from this opportunism, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g at themarg<strong>in</strong> turn<strong>in</strong>g away from otherwise pr<strong>of</strong>itable transactions. I will use the term legal risk to capturethe concept <strong>of</strong> unpredictable rules apply<strong>in</strong>g to a bus<strong>in</strong>ess relationship.Reduction <strong>of</strong> legal risk <strong>in</strong> turn <strong>in</strong>creases the value <strong>of</strong> transactions. To underst<strong>and</strong> this po<strong>in</strong>t, th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>creased certa<strong>in</strong>ty as a form <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation, for which bus<strong>in</strong>esses will<strong>in</strong>gly would pay someth<strong>in</strong>g.M<strong>in</strong>imiz<strong>in</strong>g the possibilities for opportunism also allows parties to cut back on their precautions,further add<strong>in</strong>g value to potential deals. A legal system that allows people to form clear legalcommitments with predictable consequences makes it easier for people to rely on each other <strong>and</strong>thereby extends the realm <strong>of</strong> productive cooperative behavior.<strong>The</strong>se benefits seem clear enough. Indeed, a substantial body <strong>of</strong> contracts law scholarship focuses11on the particular capacity <strong>of</strong> law to assist people <strong>in</strong> deal<strong>in</strong>g with the future. What may not seem soobvious is that reduction <strong>in</strong> legal risk does not come without costs. <strong>The</strong>re is, <strong>in</strong> other words, anoptimal level <strong>of</strong> legal risk that is greater than zero.This counter<strong>in</strong>tuitive po<strong>in</strong>t becomes clearer if one considers what the reduction <strong>of</strong> legal riskentails. Greater clarity <strong>in</strong> legal rules means provid<strong>in</strong>g more precise <strong>in</strong>structions cover<strong>in</strong>g a greaternumber <strong>of</strong> eventualities. As these rules become more exact <strong>and</strong> all-encompass<strong>in</strong>g, the odds <strong>in</strong>creasethat they will lead to outcomes that parties to a transaction would like to avoid. Even if the rulespermit alternative results, as much <strong>of</strong> contract <strong>and</strong> property law does, the parties still must addressall those <strong>in</strong>stances where they would prefer alternatives. Forc<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess people to tailor their owntransactional relationships at some po<strong>in</strong>t becomes counterproductive. We commonly assume that <strong>in</strong>commerce people <strong>of</strong>ten prefer <strong>of</strong>f-the-rack legal regimes, but these regimes work only if they do notcramp the relationships they govern with excessively detailed requirements. In commercial law wecont<strong>in</strong>ually must make trade<strong>of</strong>fs between flexibility <strong>and</strong> certa<strong>in</strong>ty, <strong>and</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess people with<strong>in</strong>reasonable limits seem to want the former. 1211See Lon Fuller & Perdue, <strong>The</strong> Reliance Interest <strong>in</strong> Contract Damages (pt. 1), 46 YALE L.J. 52 (1936); Charles J.Goetz & Robert E. Scott, Enforc<strong>in</strong>g Promises: An Exam<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> the Basis <strong>of</strong> Contract, 89 YALE L.J. 1261 (1980).12See Charles J. Goetz & Robert E. Scott, <strong>The</strong> Limits <strong>of</strong> Exp<strong>and</strong>ed Choice: An Analysis <strong>of</strong> the Interactions BetweenExpress <strong>and</strong> Implied Contract Terms, 73 CALIF. L. REV. 261 (1985). See also Clayton P. Gillette, Harmony <strong>and</strong> Stasis <strong>in</strong>


Imag<strong>in</strong>e, for example, a legal regime that held that late deliveries voided a contract <strong>of</strong> sale, nomatter what delayed the goods. This rule optimizes certa<strong>in</strong>ty by mak<strong>in</strong>g the legal relations <strong>of</strong> theparties turn on an objectively knowable event, namely the moment <strong>of</strong> delivery. But many partieswould prefer a more lenient if ambiguous rule that dist<strong>in</strong>guished between serious delays <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>in</strong>imus tard<strong>in</strong>ess, with further ref<strong>in</strong>ements perhaps depend<strong>in</strong>g on the nature <strong>of</strong> the goods, the market<strong>in</strong> which the goods might be resold, <strong>and</strong> the preferred method <strong>of</strong> shipment. A legal regime that forcedparties <strong>in</strong>dividually to negotiate each <strong>of</strong> these conditions would burden persons wish<strong>in</strong>g to engage <strong>in</strong>repetitive st<strong>and</strong>ardized transactions, but saddl<strong>in</strong>g them with a rule <strong>of</strong> absolute liability for delay mightforce just such negotiations.A related explanation for the costl<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>of</strong> legal risk reduction relies on general observations aboutrisk preferences. Substantial evidence <strong>in</strong>dicates that <strong>in</strong> general the taste for risk, like that for spicyfood, varies considerably among people, <strong>and</strong> that many persons (<strong>of</strong>ten those who becomeentrepreneurs) prefer a certa<strong>in</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> risk. <strong>The</strong>re is no reason to believe that attitudes towardlegal risk differ. Some traders will prefer undertak<strong>in</strong>g a deal not know<strong>in</strong>g for sure what the legalconsequences <strong>of</strong> a lapse might be to hav<strong>in</strong>g to confront <strong>in</strong>evitable legal consequences <strong>of</strong> failure.We thus must consider unification <strong>and</strong> harmonization as desirable to the extent it achieves adesirable reduction <strong>of</strong> legal risk, but not if it imposes such a highly developed <strong>and</strong> specific set <strong>of</strong> rulesthat a considerable number <strong>of</strong> transactions require substantial <strong>in</strong>dividualized negotiations.B. Improv<strong>in</strong>g the LawA second objective <strong>of</strong> unification <strong>and</strong> harmonization might be the substitution <strong>of</strong> better rules forthose extant <strong>in</strong> the legal systems <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual states. By “better rules,” I mean rules that improve onthe status quo with respect to some normative social goal, such as redistributive justice or enhanc<strong>in</strong>geconomic welfare. Here the goals <strong>of</strong> harmonization <strong>and</strong> law reform blend. But disconcert<strong>in</strong>gquestions immediately arise. What dist<strong>in</strong>guishes an <strong>in</strong>ternational pursuit <strong>of</strong> good law from a domesticone? When might <strong>in</strong>ternational law reform succeed where domestic efforts have failed?Several possibilities exist. First, draw<strong>in</strong>g from an <strong>in</strong>ternational pool <strong>of</strong> legal talent might <strong>in</strong>creasethe quantity <strong>and</strong> quality <strong>of</strong> expertise available to address a problem, <strong>and</strong> better expertise might leadto better rules. Second, systematic study <strong>of</strong> the experience <strong>of</strong> different legal systems might providelaw reformers with more <strong>and</strong> better data for draw<strong>in</strong>g conclusions about which rules work best. <strong>The</strong>searguments have special appeal to academic specialists, who comb<strong>in</strong>e dis<strong>in</strong>terest with expertise <strong>and</strong>tend to believe that their talents, properly applied, may improve the law.But it does not seem obvious why <strong>in</strong>ternational projects to unify <strong>and</strong> harmonize commercial lawshould enjoy any special advantage due to the quality <strong>of</strong> expertise <strong>and</strong> data available to <strong>in</strong>form thereformers. A purely domestic law reform project also can draw on a wide range <strong>of</strong> legal talent <strong>and</strong>employ comparative analysis to determ<strong>in</strong>e optimal rules. One need th<strong>in</strong>k only <strong>of</strong> the many efforts <strong>in</strong>5Trade Usages for <strong>International</strong> Sales, __ VA. J. INT’L L. ___ (1999).


6the former socialist countries to adopt new laws <strong>in</strong> support <strong>of</strong> a market economy. <strong>The</strong> array <strong>of</strong>mult<strong>in</strong>ational academic talent <strong>and</strong> detailed comparative studies <strong>of</strong> legal systems that these projectsengage would be the envy <strong>of</strong> most <strong>in</strong>ternational harmonization efforts.Conversely, efforts simultaneously to reform the legal systems <strong>of</strong> many countries tends to requireparticipants who have some multil<strong>in</strong>gual, if not multicultural, talents. Persons work<strong>in</strong>g on the projectmust speak to <strong>and</strong> underst<strong>and</strong> each other, someth<strong>in</strong>g that proceeds more effectively if they c<strong>and</strong>ispense with <strong>in</strong>terpreters. This requirement cuts down on the pool <strong>of</strong> talent available for suchprojects.A different argument for law reform through unification rests on the dist<strong>in</strong>ctive issues presentedby <strong>in</strong>ternational commerce <strong>in</strong> a world <strong>of</strong> national legal systems. Cooperative rulemak<strong>in</strong>g byrepresentatives <strong>of</strong> many states may solve collective action problems that deter <strong>in</strong>dividual states fromenact<strong>in</strong>g optimal rules. An example I discuss later <strong>in</strong> this paper <strong>in</strong>volves the treatment <strong>of</strong> foreignclaimants <strong>in</strong> a bankruptcy proceed<strong>in</strong>g. An ideal system would specify clear <strong>and</strong> precise choice-<strong>of</strong>-lawrules to allocate the authority to resolve legal claims to the jurisdiction with the greatest <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong>each transaction <strong>and</strong> otherwise would discourage discrim<strong>in</strong>ation aga<strong>in</strong>st foreign claimants thatdim<strong>in</strong>ishes the overall efficiency <strong>of</strong> a bankruptcy system. But absent coord<strong>in</strong>ation among states, eachnation has an <strong>in</strong>centive to adopt rules that, on the marg<strong>in</strong>, favor nationals over foreigners <strong>in</strong> thedisbursement <strong>of</strong> the bankrupt’s estate. <strong>The</strong>y can do so not only by transparently devalu<strong>in</strong>g foreignclaims, but also by apply<strong>in</strong>g local law to unravel contracts or property claims formed <strong>in</strong> a differentlegal environment. An <strong>in</strong>ternational regime might <strong>in</strong>crease overall welfare by giv<strong>in</strong>g every state astake <strong>in</strong> a system that elim<strong>in</strong>ates such discrim<strong>in</strong>ation.A f<strong>in</strong>al opportunity for law reform through <strong>in</strong>ternational harmonization concerns a narrow butsignificant category <strong>of</strong> cases. It rests on perceptions <strong>of</strong> political style <strong>in</strong> a world where national pridestill carries considerable weight. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the last decade many countries that largely had elim<strong>in</strong>atedformal market relations from their economies have decided, with vary<strong>in</strong>g degrees <strong>of</strong> enthusiasm, toembrace private commerce. Most approach the task with little or no suitable domestic law, <strong>and</strong> mightdo better simply to appropriate a well elaborated foreign body <strong>of</strong> commercial rules, such as that <strong>of</strong>New York or Engl<strong>and</strong>. But however pragmatic such a move might be, few <strong>of</strong> these newly marketorientedcountries feel secure enough <strong>in</strong> their national identities to permit a naked embrace <strong>of</strong> foreign13legal systems. Instead, they wish to preserve the form <strong>of</strong> sovereign equality even as they struggleto meet needs creates by dist<strong>in</strong>ctive gaps <strong>in</strong> their law. For these states, an <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>strumentcan provide the right solution. It may permit the country <strong>in</strong> need <strong>of</strong> a legal tradition to embraceforeign commercial law while seem<strong>in</strong>g to preserve its sovereign dignity <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>dependence.C. Develop<strong>in</strong>g Intermediaries13This <strong>in</strong>security by no means is limited to former socialist countries. Consider, for example, the mixture <strong>of</strong> amusement<strong>and</strong> dismay with which Justice Scalia, himself a former pr<strong>of</strong>essor <strong>of</strong> comparative law, greeted the possibility that Article 17<strong>of</strong> the Warsaw Convention required signatory states to <strong>in</strong>corporate French law concern<strong>in</strong>g the def<strong>in</strong>ition <strong>of</strong> legally cognizableharm <strong>in</strong>to their domestic legal systems. Zicherman v. Korean Air L<strong>in</strong>es, 516 U.S. 217, 222-23 (1996).


A third objective <strong>of</strong> unification <strong>and</strong> harmonization might be to give legal advisers <strong>in</strong> all parts <strong>of</strong>the commercial world a broader common fund <strong>of</strong> specialized knowledge. Whether the unified rulesproduce desirable results or not, lawyers will wish to master them <strong>and</strong> to work with other lawyersaround the world <strong>in</strong> implement<strong>in</strong>g them. Increas<strong>in</strong>g the ability <strong>of</strong> advisers to underst<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> tocommunicate with each other enhances the value <strong>of</strong> the services they render <strong>in</strong>dependently <strong>of</strong> anyimprovement <strong>in</strong> the legal rules. Given the cultural, l<strong>in</strong>guistic, <strong>and</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>essional differences thatotherwise divide lawyers located <strong>in</strong> different countries, the potential for bridg<strong>in</strong>g gaps among thosework<strong>in</strong>g on commercial transactions with<strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>ternational legal community is great.Improv<strong>in</strong>g the position <strong>of</strong> lawyers <strong>of</strong> course generates rents for the pr<strong>of</strong>ession, but it also canproduce benefits for society as a whole. Specialized lawyers (or the firms to which they belong) tendto work on particular transactions more <strong>of</strong>ten than any one client does. <strong>The</strong>y thus have the <strong>in</strong>centivecommon to all repeat players to develop a reputation for reliability <strong>and</strong> predictability. To protect this<strong>in</strong>vestment, specialized lawyers may work to reduce legal risk even where the rules themselves mayseem to enhance it. In particular, they may become expert <strong>in</strong> produc<strong>in</strong>g predictable outcomes throughsettlement even where the results courts might generate rema<strong>in</strong> highly variable. In the United States,for example, some lawyers who sue <strong>and</strong> represent <strong>in</strong>surance companies <strong>in</strong> personal <strong>in</strong>jury cases havea reputation for reach<strong>in</strong>g settlements <strong>in</strong> spite <strong>of</strong> the notorious unpredictability <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stability <strong>of</strong> U.S.tort law. More generally, an important scholarly tradition trac<strong>in</strong>g back to Janet L<strong>and</strong>a’s sem<strong>in</strong>al study<strong>of</strong> ethnic Ch<strong>in</strong>ese middlemen <strong>in</strong> the Malaysian rubber trade emphasizes the benefits that cohesive<strong>in</strong>termediaries can br<strong>in</strong>g to unstable legal environments. 14This argument about the value <strong>of</strong> specialized legal expertise <strong>in</strong>troduces a theme that I develop <strong>in</strong>the rema<strong>in</strong>der <strong>of</strong> this article. Not all the benefits <strong>of</strong> unification <strong>and</strong> harmonization accrue to thegeneral welfare. Indeed, we have a reason to fear that, like all lawmak<strong>in</strong>g projects, efforts atunification may generate advantages for some discrete group at the expense <strong>of</strong> the overall publicgood. <strong>The</strong>re is no reason to believe that the public choice dynamic so much studied <strong>in</strong> other areas<strong>of</strong> the law, where coherent <strong>and</strong> well-organized <strong>in</strong>terest groups obta<strong>in</strong> legislation that serves their ownends, does not work <strong>in</strong> this field as well. We need to discuss the possibility that other, less benignforces may come <strong>in</strong>to play when experts, seek<strong>in</strong>g the reduction <strong>of</strong> legal risk, law reform, <strong>and</strong> thestrengthen<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> the roles <strong>of</strong> specialist legal advisers, set <strong>of</strong>f to develop unified <strong>and</strong> harmonized rules<strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational commerce.7II. THE UNIFICATION AND HARMONIZATION PROCESSIn the previous section I focused on idealized benefits derived from the substantive content <strong>of</strong> aunified <strong>in</strong>ternational commercial law. I now focus on the process that may produce such law. I firstdiscuss an idealized lawmak<strong>in</strong>g process, <strong>and</strong> then review how the most significant <strong>in</strong>struments forunify<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>ternational commercial law have come about.14Janet T. L<strong>and</strong>a, A <strong>The</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> the Ethnically Homogeneous Middleman Group: An Institutional Alternative toContract Law, 10 J. LEG. STUD. 349 (1981); Robert Cooter & Janet T. L<strong>and</strong>a, Personal Versus Impersonal Trade: <strong>The</strong> Size<strong>of</strong> Trad<strong>in</strong>g Groups <strong>and</strong> Contract Law, 4 INT’L REV. L. & ECON. 15 (1984); Robert Cooter, Decentralized Law for a ComplexEconomy: <strong>The</strong> Structural Approach to Adjudicat<strong>in</strong>g the New Law Merchant, 144 U. PA. L. REV. 1643 (1996).


8A. Process IdealsIn a perfect world we would make laws <strong>in</strong> a way that blends complete democratic accountabilitywith full realization <strong>of</strong> skilled technical expertise. We care about accountability because the personsaffected by laws should have some k<strong>in</strong>d <strong>of</strong> voice <strong>in</strong> how the rules laid down affect their lives. It iscerta<strong>in</strong>ly just, <strong>and</strong> perhaps even conducive to the enactment <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>strumentally good laws, for theactors who must comply with the legislative m<strong>and</strong>ate to have some way <strong>of</strong> reward<strong>in</strong>g those who enactsuccessful laws <strong>and</strong> punish<strong>in</strong>g those whose laws prove hurtful. At the same time we care abouttechnical expertise, both prospectively <strong>and</strong> retrospectively. Prospectively, specialists help lawmakersto anticipate the consequences <strong>of</strong> laws <strong>and</strong> to identify the choices that the lawmak<strong>in</strong>g project mustconfront. Retrospectively, specialists help us to <strong>in</strong>terpret the impact <strong>of</strong> legislation <strong>in</strong> a complex world<strong>and</strong> to specify the criteria for success <strong>and</strong> harm.When it comes to lawmak<strong>in</strong>g that aims at widespread unification <strong>of</strong> diverse bodies <strong>of</strong> national law,we must accept some adjustments <strong>of</strong> these ideals. In the absence <strong>of</strong> any <strong>in</strong>ternational publiclegislature, we cannot expect the lawmakers to face the same k<strong>in</strong>d <strong>of</strong> electoral accountability thatnational parliamentarians ord<strong>in</strong>arily confront. No mechanism exists for voters to pass judgment onthe <strong>in</strong>ternational lawmakers. At best they can vote for the domestic governments that <strong>in</strong> turn choose15the drafters <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational agreements. Nor is exit, the conventional alternative to voice fordiscipl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g decisionmakers, an attractive option. Widespread rejection by national governmentsdefeats the purpose <strong>of</strong> legal unification.If the unification process necessarily must sacrifice someth<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the way <strong>of</strong> accountability, it maycompensate by exploit<strong>in</strong>g technical expertise more fully than national lawmakers normally do.Unencumbered by petty political obstacles, experts engaged <strong>in</strong> the draft<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> unified laws may havethe freedom to develop sophisticated <strong>and</strong> well-balanced drafts that anticipate <strong>and</strong> resolve a wide range<strong>of</strong> potential problems. We should expect them to produce legislation that achieves both elegance <strong>and</strong>a certa<strong>in</strong> scientific soundness.B. <strong>The</strong> Lawmak<strong>in</strong>g BodiesWhat k<strong>in</strong>ds <strong>of</strong> organizations promote unification <strong>in</strong> the real, as opposed to an idealized, world?A survey <strong>of</strong> the field suggests that <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>stitutions served ma<strong>in</strong>ly by technical expertsdom<strong>in</strong>ate the process. None <strong>of</strong> these organizations directly enacts legislation, <strong>and</strong> hence politicalaccountability rema<strong>in</strong>s largely absent. Rather, these bodies draft laws for national governments toadopt, either as treaties or domestic legislation.At present a variety <strong>of</strong> groups engage <strong>in</strong> various k<strong>in</strong>ds <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational unification projects.Typical is the UN Commission on <strong>International</strong> Trade Law (UNCITRAL). This organizationembodies thirty-six <strong>of</strong>ficial delegations represent<strong>in</strong>g national governments chosen on a rotat<strong>in</strong>g basis15For a more extensive discussion <strong>of</strong> these problems, see Paul B. Stephan, Accountability <strong>and</strong> <strong>International</strong>Lawmak<strong>in</strong>g: Rules, Rents <strong>and</strong> Legitimacy, 17 NORTHWESTERN J. INT’L L. & BUS. 681 (1996-97).


y the UN General Assembly. It possesses a permanent secretariat that adm<strong>in</strong>isters its work <strong>and</strong>provides publicity. It operates largely through work<strong>in</strong>g groups consist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> experts. UNCITRALselects the members <strong>of</strong> the work<strong>in</strong>g group on the basis <strong>of</strong> its particular assignment. <strong>The</strong> secretariatenjoys substantial background <strong>in</strong>fluence over the composition <strong>of</strong> the group as well as selection <strong>of</strong>projects. <strong>The</strong> work<strong>in</strong>g groups develop a draft, which a conference <strong>of</strong> delegates from the variousmember states must approve. It is not unusual for the draft to go through several revisions <strong>in</strong> light<strong>of</strong> conference review, <strong>and</strong> for the entire process to consume many years.UNCITRAL holds annual conferences to review <strong>and</strong> approve what the work<strong>in</strong>g groups havedone. <strong>The</strong> delegates to the conferences, like the members <strong>of</strong> the work<strong>in</strong>g groups, typically arespecialists <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational law, <strong>of</strong>ten drawn from the academy, rather than politicians or civil servants.<strong>The</strong> end <strong>of</strong> the Cold war has seen some <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> UNCITRAL’s activity. S<strong>in</strong>ce 1991 it hasapproved two conventions <strong>and</strong> four model laws, as compared to one convention <strong>and</strong> one model lawbetween 1981 <strong>and</strong> 1991 <strong>and</strong> a total <strong>of</strong> seven conventions <strong>and</strong> five model laws dur<strong>in</strong>g the entire thirtyyears <strong>of</strong> its existence. 16<strong>The</strong> <strong>International</strong> Institute for the <strong>Unification</strong> <strong>of</strong> Private Law (UNIDROIT) <strong>and</strong> the HagueConference on Private <strong>International</strong> Law (Hague Conference) operate <strong>in</strong> much the same way as doesUNCITRAL. UNIDROIT first appeared as an organ <strong>of</strong> the League <strong>of</strong> Nations, obta<strong>in</strong>ed formalstatus as an <strong>in</strong>dependent <strong>in</strong>ternational organization <strong>in</strong> 1940, <strong>and</strong> then revived follow<strong>in</strong>g World WarII. Its membership consists <strong>of</strong> 58 nations whose governments send representatives to periodicconferences to review <strong>and</strong> approve the work <strong>of</strong> task forces. To date it has produced eight<strong>in</strong>ternational conventions, two <strong>of</strong> which became largely obsolete upon the adoption <strong>of</strong> the Conventionon Contracts for the <strong>International</strong> Sale <strong>of</strong> Goods (CISG). It also has done background work for anumber <strong>of</strong> other unification projects, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the CISG.<strong>The</strong> Hague Conference, which began work <strong>in</strong> 1893 but did not take on a permanent <strong>in</strong>stitutionalcharacter until 1955, has 45 members, most <strong>of</strong> whom also belong to UNIDROIT. Like UNCITRAL<strong>and</strong> UNIDROIT, it carries out its work primarily through task forces (called special commissions)that present their results to delegates from the member states that meet <strong>in</strong> quadrennial diplomaticconferences. S<strong>in</strong>ce World War II it has promulgated 33 Conventions, some <strong>of</strong> which have achievedwidespread adoption.At the regional level, the European Union <strong>and</strong> the Organization <strong>of</strong> American States also employspecialists <strong>in</strong> work<strong>in</strong>g groups to draft multilateral conventions <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>ternational commercial law<strong>and</strong> otherwise to encourage unification <strong>and</strong> harmonization <strong>of</strong> commercial law. Both have developed,<strong>in</strong>ter alia, laws affect<strong>in</strong>g carriage <strong>of</strong> goods by rail <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>termodal transport <strong>and</strong> transnational privatelitigation. <strong>The</strong> European Union has launched a more ambitious project to harmonize the civil law <strong>of</strong>all fifteen <strong>of</strong> its members.916This data reflects <strong>in</strong>formation posted on the UNCITRAL homepage <strong>and</strong> is current as <strong>of</strong> May 25, 1998. Seehttp://www.un.or.at/uncitral/status.


10In each <strong>of</strong> these cases, the technocratic model <strong>of</strong> lawmak<strong>in</strong>g prevails. <strong>The</strong> persons who representnational members at the conferences that approve task force proposals are selected more for theirreputation as specialists than because <strong>of</strong> political, bureaucratic, or <strong>in</strong>dustrial ties. Work<strong>in</strong>g groupshave stable membership but a limited terms <strong>of</strong> reference, <strong>and</strong> not many people participate <strong>in</strong> morethan one. Turnover is higher <strong>in</strong> the delegations sent to the periodic conferences that review what thework<strong>in</strong>g groups have produced.<strong>The</strong> <strong>International</strong> Chamber <strong>of</strong> Commerce (ICC) differs significantly <strong>in</strong> its structural form from thepublic bodies mentioned above. It draws its membership from the private sector, <strong>and</strong> chooses itsexperts more on <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong>terest than academic prestige. It does not have to answer to nationalgovernments either <strong>in</strong> the choice <strong>of</strong> specialists assigned to draft<strong>in</strong>g projects or <strong>in</strong> the approval <strong>of</strong> legal<strong>in</strong>struments. Rather, it forms commissions l<strong>in</strong>ked largely to <strong>in</strong>dustrial sectors (bank<strong>in</strong>g, telecommunications,<strong>and</strong> the like) which, among other th<strong>in</strong>gs, promulgate st<strong>and</strong>ardized contractual termsfor particular transactions. Unlike the other groups, the ICC also conducts an arbitration service thatallows it to supervise the <strong>in</strong>terpretation <strong>of</strong> its <strong>in</strong>struments. But the ICC also collaborates with theother <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>stitutions <strong>in</strong> all areas <strong>of</strong> mutual <strong>in</strong>terest. It ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong>formal ties with thework<strong>in</strong>g groups <strong>and</strong> secretariats <strong>and</strong> normally sends observers to the various conferences that takeup proposed legislation. It also coord<strong>in</strong>ates its activities with <strong>in</strong>dustry-specific bodies <strong>of</strong> legal experts,such as the Legal Committee <strong>of</strong> the <strong>International</strong> Civil Aviation Organization or the Comité Maritime<strong>International</strong>.Much dist<strong>in</strong>guishes these organizations, which have their own histories, cultures <strong>and</strong> agendas, butwhat <strong>in</strong>terest me are the common elements <strong>of</strong> their lawmak<strong>in</strong>g process. At their heart is an <strong>in</strong>terplaybetween an ad hoc task force consist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> academics <strong>and</strong> practitioners with great substantivecomm<strong>and</strong> <strong>of</strong> the subject under consideration, <strong>and</strong> a broader body <strong>of</strong> lawyers, typically well-seasoned<strong>and</strong> dist<strong>in</strong>guished, whose approval is necessary before the group will embrace a task force proposalas its own. Membership <strong>in</strong> the task forces tends to be stable but not overlapp<strong>in</strong>g, while the broadergroup has a less stable membership but a broader range <strong>of</strong> lawmak<strong>in</strong>g authority. <strong>The</strong> members <strong>of</strong>both bodies, the task forces <strong>and</strong> the broader group, br<strong>in</strong>g their own preferences <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>terests but donot belong to parties or coalitions that can impose discipl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>and</strong> develop collective programs. Even<strong>in</strong> those organizations where the members <strong>in</strong> the larger body have some sort <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficial status asrepresentatives <strong>of</strong> their nations, such as UNCITRAL, UNIDROIT <strong>and</strong> the Hague Conference, rarelydo national governments impose substantial political constra<strong>in</strong>ts on their emissary. Rather, thetechnical nature <strong>of</strong> the subject matter ensures the relative obscurity <strong>of</strong> the process.What these bodies seem to represent, <strong>in</strong> other words, is a fairly complete realization <strong>of</strong> thetechnocratic ideal <strong>of</strong> lawmak<strong>in</strong>g. Each nation’s lead<strong>in</strong>g specialists convene to draft an <strong>in</strong>strument thatought to embody the best rules that they can devise for <strong>in</strong>ternational commerce. National politiciansparticipate only <strong>in</strong>directly, mostly by reta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the f<strong>in</strong>al say over accept<strong>in</strong>g the completed <strong>in</strong>strument.<strong>The</strong> technical experts have a relatively free h<strong>and</strong> to discover the common ground that can transcenddifferences <strong>in</strong> culture, history, levels <strong>of</strong> economic development, <strong>and</strong> social structure. While ideological<strong>and</strong> conceptual barriers may rema<strong>in</strong>, the process should be free <strong>of</strong> less elevated distractions.


<strong>The</strong> converse also is true: we cannot blame political <strong>in</strong>terference for any shortcom<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> the<strong>in</strong>struments produced by these groups. Rather, their flaws must <strong>in</strong>dicate some <strong>in</strong>adequacies <strong>in</strong> thetechnocratic ideal. Of course, even the f<strong>in</strong>est experts make mistakes, but the issue is not whethermeasures meant to unify <strong>in</strong>ternational commercial law fall short <strong>of</strong> perfection. What we mustdeterm<strong>in</strong>e is whether the k<strong>in</strong>d <strong>of</strong> technocratic lawmak<strong>in</strong>g that these organizations promote hasstructural characteristics that lead to systematic problems with their products.C. A Positive Model <strong>of</strong> Private LegislaturesSeveral <strong>in</strong>tellectual traditions have advanced critiques <strong>of</strong> scientific-technical expertise generally<strong>and</strong> the use <strong>of</strong> technical ideals <strong>in</strong> lawmak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> particular. Some claim that what passes for technicalexpertise <strong>of</strong>ten represents only the current preferences <strong>of</strong> dom<strong>in</strong>ant elites <strong>and</strong> that technical skills17serve mostly to mask the naked <strong>and</strong> irrational power that lies beh<strong>in</strong>d most legislation. Sucharguments are fasc<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g but cut far too deeply for my present purposes. I do not consider my taskto extend to debat<strong>in</strong>g the merits <strong>of</strong> post-<strong>in</strong>dustrial capitalism or the place <strong>of</strong> legal theory <strong>in</strong> the postmodernfirmament. Rather, I wish to concentrate on one particular analysis <strong>of</strong> expert-grouplawmak<strong>in</strong>g that recently has appeared <strong>in</strong> the legal literature.Scholars associated with the law-<strong>and</strong>-economics movement have studied the political economy<strong>of</strong> technical experts engaged <strong>in</strong> lawmak<strong>in</strong>g. <strong>The</strong>ir work suggests that these groups, no less than moreconventional legislatures, confront the <strong>in</strong>fluence <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest groups <strong>and</strong> face systematic pressure todraft laws that fail to improve on the status quo <strong>and</strong> may produce overall welfare losses.Technocratic lawmak<strong>in</strong>g, they argue, still has its own politics <strong>and</strong> is not necessarily improved by itsfreedom from broader political constra<strong>in</strong>ts.18This work studies what Robert Scott <strong>and</strong> Alan Schwartz call private legislatures. It focuses ontwo U.S. <strong>in</strong>stitutions, the American Law Institute (ALI) <strong>and</strong> the National Conference <strong>of</strong>Commissioners <strong>of</strong> Uniform State Laws (NCCUSL). Both bodies exist outside <strong>of</strong> normal politicalorgans, choose their own membership, <strong>and</strong> carry out their legislative draft<strong>in</strong>g through a process thatbeg<strong>in</strong>s with a specially selected work<strong>in</strong>g group <strong>and</strong> concludes with consideration by the wholemembership <strong>of</strong> the work<strong>in</strong>g group’s drafts. <strong>The</strong>ir pr<strong>of</strong>essed goal is both to unify <strong>and</strong> to improve thesubstantive law <strong>of</strong> the several States by produc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>struments that legislatures then will adoptwithout modification.Scott <strong>and</strong> Schwartz argue that these private legislatures have four significant characteristics thatshape the k<strong>in</strong>ds <strong>of</strong> the legislation they produce: (1) the costs <strong>of</strong> logroll<strong>in</strong>g are high; (2) members <strong>of</strong>both the task forces <strong>and</strong> broader legislative body acts as <strong>in</strong>dividuals <strong>and</strong> have no political power that1117See generally Mark Kelman, A GUIDE TO CRITICAL LEGAL STUDIES (1987); Thomas S. Kuhn, THE STRUCTURE OFSCIENTIFIC REVOLUTIONS (2d ed. 1970); Robert Mangabeira Unger, THE CRITICAL LEGAL STUDIES MOVEMENT (1986);Herbert Marcuse, ONE-DIMENSIONAL MAN—STUDIES IN THE IDEOLOGY OF ADVANCED INDUSTRIAL SOCIETY (1964).18Robert E. Scott, <strong>The</strong> Politics <strong>of</strong> Article 9, 80 VA. L. REV. 1783 (1994); Alan Schwartz & Robert E. Scott, <strong>The</strong>Political Economy <strong>of</strong> Private Legislatures, 143 U. PA. L. REV. 595. For my previous discussion <strong>of</strong> these claims <strong>and</strong> theirapplication to <strong>in</strong>ternational commercial law, see Paul B. Stephan, note 15 supra, at 688-90, 700-02.


12they can wield <strong>in</strong> the lawmak<strong>in</strong>g process; (3) <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetries exist between task forces <strong>and</strong>the broader legislative body; <strong>and</strong> (4) members <strong>of</strong> the task forces tend to have a stronger preferencefor mov<strong>in</strong>g away from the status quo than does the median member <strong>of</strong> the larger body. Each deservessome elaboration:Absence <strong>of</strong> logroll<strong>in</strong>g: Those persons who are selected for particular task forces <strong>in</strong> most caseswork exclusively on that draft<strong>in</strong>g project. If they do other work, it comes at different times. As aresult, they do not have the capacity to make deals across projects.Absence <strong>of</strong> political agency: Membership <strong>in</strong> the groups <strong>and</strong> their organs depends on the<strong>in</strong>dividual’s technical expertise, not his or her associations with political actors work<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> thebackground. <strong>The</strong> members do not form coalitions or submit to any other k<strong>in</strong>d <strong>of</strong> substantial politicaldiscipl<strong>in</strong>e. <strong>The</strong>y do not formally represent organized <strong>in</strong>terests, although they may have some aff<strong>in</strong>ityor pr<strong>of</strong>essional ties with particular groups.Information asymmetries: <strong>The</strong> wider body meets episodically <strong>and</strong> normally does not have manysubjects on its agenda. <strong>The</strong> members <strong>of</strong> the task forces, by virtue <strong>of</strong> their focused effort <strong>and</strong> researchas well as the <strong>in</strong>itial selection process, know more about the background <strong>and</strong> anticipated effect <strong>of</strong> theproposed legislation than do the persons serv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the broader body.Preferences to alter status quo: Prom<strong>in</strong>ent pr<strong>of</strong>essionals normally do not agree to spend a greatamount <strong>of</strong> time on what is typically an undercompensated consultative project unless they have eithera strong ideological commitment to some issue implicated by the project or expect to enjoy thebenefits <strong>of</strong> an enhanced reputation as a result <strong>of</strong> the project’s successful completion. Ideologicalcommitment to preserv<strong>in</strong>g the status quo is possible but unusual, especially with<strong>in</strong> the legal academiccommunity. Similarly, few projects are seen as successful <strong>and</strong> reputation-enhanc<strong>in</strong>g if they concludewith a rejection <strong>of</strong> any change. <strong>The</strong> members <strong>of</strong> the broader groups that must approve the products<strong>of</strong> task forces, by contrast, do not have the same personal <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> the legislative projects <strong>and</strong>may have to answer to groups who prefer a known present to an uncerta<strong>in</strong> future.Hav<strong>in</strong>g postulated these characteristics, Schwartz <strong>and</strong> Scott make a prediction about the relative<strong>in</strong>fluence <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest groups on the deliberations <strong>of</strong> private legislatures. <strong>The</strong>y contend that, ceterisparibus, representatives <strong>of</strong> such groups will have greater credibility with the members <strong>of</strong> the largerbody that will approve a completed project than will the experts who form the task force thatproduces a proposal. <strong>The</strong>y base this claim on three generalizations about the behavior <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>terestgroups, experts, <strong>and</strong> the members <strong>of</strong> the broader body: (1) unlike the members <strong>of</strong> the task force, an<strong>in</strong>terest group must bear additional costs to develop alternatives to a task force proposal; (2) <strong>in</strong>terestgroups have an ongo<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> the various projects undertaken by these organizations <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> thatsense are repeat players <strong>in</strong> the game <strong>of</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g proposals, while the experts employed <strong>in</strong> taskforces tend to concentrate more exclusively on the s<strong>in</strong>gle activity <strong>in</strong> which they have a h<strong>and</strong>, whichmeans that <strong>in</strong>terest groups will bear greater future costs if they are caught out <strong>in</strong> exaggeration ormisrepresentation; <strong>and</strong> (3) experts work<strong>in</strong>g on task forces tend to have, <strong>and</strong> are known by others tohave, a greater preference for <strong>in</strong>novation than either <strong>in</strong>terest group representatives or the members<strong>of</strong> the approv<strong>in</strong>g bodies.


Several consequences flow from the assumption that members <strong>of</strong> the approv<strong>in</strong>g bodies, <strong>in</strong> the face<strong>of</strong> their relative ignorance about what the projects will do, will have greater respect for the<strong>in</strong>formation provided by <strong>in</strong>terest groups than that <strong>of</strong>fered by their nom<strong>in</strong>al subord<strong>in</strong>ates, the members<strong>of</strong> the task force. Interest groups should be most effective <strong>in</strong> derail<strong>in</strong>g proposed rules that theirmembers would f<strong>in</strong>d harmful. Where a s<strong>in</strong>gle <strong>in</strong>terest group br<strong>in</strong>gs pressure to bear on a project <strong>and</strong>no other group participates, the group also has an advantage <strong>in</strong> shap<strong>in</strong>g the project to benefit itsmembers. In the more common scenario where well organized groups have conflict<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terests, thepressure <strong>in</strong>side the lawmak<strong>in</strong>g body to produce someth<strong>in</strong>g will lead to the adoption <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>strumentsthat have the form <strong>of</strong> a legislative enactment but that conta<strong>in</strong> few or no rules that will impose clearcosts on any organized group. In practice such <strong>in</strong>struments must employ rules that postpone hardchoices by leav<strong>in</strong>g it to the discretion <strong>of</strong> future decisionmakers to make them.Summariz<strong>in</strong>g the argument, the new work on the political economy <strong>of</strong> private lawmak<strong>in</strong>g bybodies <strong>of</strong> technical experts predicts that: (1) many rules will vest considerable discretion <strong>in</strong> decisionmakers,such as judges, rather than specify<strong>in</strong>g outcomes that must flow from described circumstances;(2) those rules that are precise <strong>and</strong> constra<strong>in</strong> decisionmakers will largely reflect the preferences <strong>of</strong>particular <strong>in</strong>terest groups, such as banks, broadcasters, common carriers, etc.; <strong>and</strong> (3) the rules takenas a whole will not constitute a clear <strong>and</strong> def<strong>in</strong>ite departure from the status quo, because <strong>in</strong>terestgroups will enjoy considerable success <strong>in</strong> block<strong>in</strong>g any rules that entrench on their particularpreferences.<strong>The</strong> various organizations active <strong>in</strong> the development <strong>of</strong> unified <strong>in</strong>ternational commercial law seemremarkably similar to the ALI <strong>and</strong> NCCUSL. <strong>The</strong>ir reliance on work<strong>in</strong>g groups formed on a perprojectbasis, as opposed to a permanent legislature <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> address<strong>in</strong>g a broad legislative agenda,discourages logroll<strong>in</strong>g. Even though several <strong>of</strong> the organizations (UNCITRAL, the HagueConference, UNIDROIT, the EU <strong>and</strong> the OAS) consist <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficial delegations chosen by nationalgovernments, as a practical matter political agency plays no role <strong>in</strong> their work. <strong>The</strong> technical nature<strong>of</strong> the task <strong>and</strong> the importance <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>essional reputation, as opposed to political connections, <strong>in</strong> theselection process means that the members act <strong>in</strong> accordance with their own views <strong>of</strong> what laws arebest, not pursuant to <strong>in</strong>structions from a political body. <strong>The</strong> members <strong>of</strong> the work<strong>in</strong>g group typicallypossess far more <strong>in</strong>formation about the implications <strong>of</strong> their proposals than do the persons who attendthe conference that adopt particular <strong>in</strong>struments. And the work<strong>in</strong>g group members, by the nature <strong>of</strong>their <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> these projects, tend to have stronger preference for alter<strong>in</strong>g the status quo th<strong>and</strong>o the conference delegates.<strong>The</strong> similarity is not complete. <strong>The</strong> ALI <strong>and</strong> NCCUSL have more stable memberships than theconferences or other broad bodies affiliated with the <strong>in</strong>stitutions that produce <strong>in</strong>ternationalcommercial laws. Typically a member <strong>of</strong> the ALI <strong>and</strong> the NCCUSL serves without term, while thedelegations to the various <strong>in</strong>ternational bodies tend to turn over more frequently. But this dist<strong>in</strong>ctionshould accentuate, rather than dim<strong>in</strong>ish, the <strong>in</strong>formation asymmetries between the work<strong>in</strong>g groups<strong>and</strong> the conferences <strong>and</strong> thus enhance the tendency <strong>of</strong> the conference delegates to look to outsiders,especially those associated with <strong>in</strong>terest groups, for help.13


14Does the similarities among these technocratic lawmak<strong>in</strong>g processes extend to the content <strong>of</strong> lawsthey produce? If so, we can predict that the <strong>in</strong>struments <strong>in</strong>tended to promote unification will displayseveral characteristics. <strong>The</strong>y <strong>of</strong>ten will <strong>in</strong>crease legal risk beyond optimal levels. <strong>The</strong> <strong>in</strong>crease willcome from substitut<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>ternational st<strong>and</strong>ard that leaves considerable discretion to nationaldecisionmakers, especially judicial bodies, for preexist<strong>in</strong>g national rules that may be more developed<strong>and</strong> conf<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g. Those <strong>in</strong>stances where the <strong>in</strong>struments provide greater certa<strong>in</strong>ty than does priornational law <strong>of</strong>ten will represent victories for narrow economic <strong>in</strong>terests rather than the generalwelfare. <strong>The</strong> triumphs <strong>of</strong> these <strong>in</strong>terests should occur <strong>in</strong> cases where a s<strong>in</strong>gle concentrated groupwith a coherent preference faces no opposition from other such groups <strong>and</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ds it possible tooutmaneuver the reformist members <strong>of</strong> a task force when it lobbies the body that approves an<strong>in</strong>strument. More generally, we should not expect unification efforts to achieve a clear <strong>and</strong> def<strong>in</strong>itebreak with the prior laws even when the status quo seems <strong>in</strong>adequate <strong>in</strong> light <strong>of</strong> broadly acceptednormative criteria.How accurate are these predictions? In the next section I review several important <strong>in</strong>strumentsthat have emerged from the <strong>in</strong>ternational unification process. My survey, while neithercomprehensive nor systematic, does suggest that technocratic lawmak<strong>in</strong>g does no better <strong>in</strong> that<strong>in</strong>ternational arena than when it proceeds through the ALI or the NCCUSL. I raise enough questionsabout the overall value <strong>of</strong> past efforts to justify an attempt to develop alternative approaches tounification <strong>and</strong> harmonization.D. Open-ended Discretion <strong>and</strong> Bright L<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong> <strong>Unification</strong> InstrumentsI exam<strong>in</strong>e six <strong>in</strong>struments. <strong>The</strong> selection rests not on any presumed criteria <strong>of</strong> typicality, as Irema<strong>in</strong> unsure as to what constitutes a “representative” unification law. Rather, I concentrate onprom<strong>in</strong>ence <strong>and</strong> significance. Different unification organizations produced these laws, so they do notreflect only one group’s predilections. Four <strong>of</strong> the first five <strong>in</strong>struments—the Hague Rules, theWarsaw Convention, the CISG, <strong>and</strong> the UCP—today govern a wide array <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational commercialtransactions. <strong>The</strong> Hamburg Rules purport to replace the Hague Rules <strong>and</strong> thus deserves considerationalongside the preexist<strong>in</strong>g law. <strong>The</strong> sixth, UNCITRAL’s Model Law on Cross-BorderInsolvencies (UNCITRAL Insolvency Law), was adopted <strong>in</strong> 1997 <strong>and</strong> has not yet come <strong>in</strong>to force,directly or <strong>in</strong>directly, anywhere. But it represents one important group’s effort to wrestle with agrow<strong>in</strong>g problem present<strong>in</strong>g clear collective action difficulties. How the model law confronts thesechallenges suggests someth<strong>in</strong>g generally about the ability <strong>of</strong> unification <strong>in</strong>struments to produce ga<strong>in</strong>sfrom <strong>in</strong>ternational cooperation.1. Sea Transport—<strong>The</strong> Hague <strong>and</strong> Hamburg RulesConsider first the unification <strong>of</strong> the legal rules relat<strong>in</strong>g to one <strong>of</strong> the most ancient technologies <strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>ternational commerce, namely carriage <strong>of</strong> goods by ship. <strong>The</strong> lion’s share <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational sale <strong>of</strong>goods <strong>in</strong>volves sea transport. Technological <strong>in</strong>novations such as conta<strong>in</strong>erization, advancedtelecommunications, satellite-assisted navigation, <strong>and</strong> electronic storage <strong>and</strong> dissem<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> shipp<strong>in</strong>gdocuments <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation have affected the efficiency, cost structure <strong>and</strong> reliability <strong>of</strong> this <strong>in</strong>dustry,but the fundamental legal issues have not changed much s<strong>in</strong>ce the time <strong>of</strong> the Phoenicians.


Once shippers <strong>and</strong> carriers get past the price issue, they look to commercial law to def<strong>in</strong>e theservice provided. Shippers entrust their goods to carriers <strong>and</strong> want a timely delivery <strong>of</strong> undamagedgoods. Carriers live with the vagaries <strong>of</strong> the sea <strong>and</strong> do not want to assume liability for its <strong>in</strong>juries.More specifically, carriers seek precision <strong>in</strong> the def<strong>in</strong>ition <strong>of</strong> their responsibilities to shippers, <strong>and</strong> wishto avoid open-ended liability rules such as responsibility for consequential damages <strong>and</strong> exposure tolosses associated with goods <strong>of</strong> undeclared value. Shippers want to ensure that carriers have everyreason to take all reasonable precautions for the safe delivery <strong>of</strong> their cargo <strong>in</strong> a timely fashion. Moregenerally, repeat players (almost all carriers <strong>and</strong> most shippers) want a stable legal environment.It seems reasonable to assume that at any given time, some countries might have stronger carrier<strong>in</strong>dustries than do others, <strong>and</strong> that the balance struck <strong>in</strong> commercial law between shippers <strong>and</strong> carriersmight vary among countries. Extreme cases where countries have almost no domestic carriers <strong>and</strong>a heavy dependence on shipp<strong>in</strong>g might produce rules that redistribute wealth from carriers, <strong>and</strong> thereverse might be true <strong>in</strong> countries with an especially strong carrier <strong>in</strong>dustry. Thus one might expectsignificant variation among national legal regimes, with the applicability <strong>of</strong> any particular set <strong>of</strong> rulesturn<strong>in</strong>g on unpredictable factors such as the location <strong>of</strong> ship or cargo at the time <strong>of</strong> dispute. Aga<strong>in</strong>stsuch a background, a unification project might expect to realize substantial benefits simply byreduc<strong>in</strong>g legal risk.Dur<strong>in</strong>g the early years <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dustrial revolution general pr<strong>in</strong>ciples <strong>of</strong> contract law, albeit ref<strong>in</strong>edby specialization <strong>and</strong> the development <strong>of</strong> a dist<strong>in</strong>ct admiralty jurisprudence, governed the legal rights<strong>and</strong> obligations <strong>of</strong> sea carriers <strong>and</strong> their customers. Rely<strong>in</strong>g on contract law, <strong>in</strong>ternational carrierstended to <strong>of</strong>fer st<strong>and</strong>ard terms to most shippers, usually exculpat<strong>in</strong>g themselves from a wide range<strong>of</strong> legal liabilities. By the end <strong>of</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eteenth century, however, the <strong>in</strong>dustry faced the likelihood<strong>of</strong> legislative <strong>in</strong>tervention. <strong>The</strong> emergence <strong>of</strong> powerful cartels <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dustry, called conferences orr<strong>in</strong>gs, <strong>in</strong>vited some sort <strong>of</strong> response. <strong>The</strong> United K<strong>in</strong>gdom launched an <strong>of</strong>ficial <strong>in</strong>quiry <strong>in</strong>to the<strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong> 1906, <strong>and</strong> a congressional <strong>in</strong>vestigation followed <strong>in</strong> the United States a few years later. 19To be sure, at the turn <strong>of</strong> the century the carrier <strong>in</strong>dustry would not have seen changes <strong>in</strong>commercial law as the greatest threat it faced. Price controls, discrim<strong>in</strong>atory taxation <strong>and</strong> portcharges probably seemed to present more serious problems. But, as the experience <strong>of</strong> the railroad<strong>in</strong>dustry illustrated, commercial law also could have a redistributive impact on carriers. Damagerules, for example, might expose them to substantial liability for consequential <strong>in</strong>juries caused by20failures or delays <strong>of</strong> delivery. <strong>The</strong> United States had enacted the Harter Act <strong>in</strong> 1893 with thepurpose <strong>of</strong> impos<strong>in</strong>g m<strong>and</strong>atory liability obligations on <strong>in</strong>ternational sea carriers. Other statesthreatened to follow with their own approaches to the maritime contract <strong>of</strong> carriage. It seemed likelythat, at a m<strong>in</strong>imum, the legislative process would create a legal environment that varied substantially1519See Timothy J. May, <strong>The</strong> Status <strong>of</strong> Federal Maritime Commission Shipp<strong>in</strong>g Regulation under Pr<strong>in</strong>ciples <strong>of</strong><strong>International</strong> Law, 54 GEO. L.J. 794, 795-99 (1966). <strong>The</strong> U.S. <strong>in</strong>vestigation led ultimately to the enactment <strong>of</strong> the Shipp<strong>in</strong>gAct <strong>of</strong> 1916, which established the United States Shipp<strong>in</strong>g Board, the ancestor <strong>of</strong> today’s Federal Maritime Commission, toregulate common carriers <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>terstate commerce. 39 Stat. 728, as amended <strong>and</strong> codified at 46U.S.C. §§ 801-42 (19__).20See generally Richard Danzig, Hadley v. Baxendale: A Study <strong>in</strong> the Industrialization <strong>of</strong> the Law, 4 J. LEG. STUD.249 (1975).


16among jurisdictions, with carriers fac<strong>in</strong>g relatively favorable or unfavorable rules depend<strong>in</strong>g on wherethey found themselves <strong>in</strong> court.In 1897, lawyers associated with both carriers <strong>and</strong> bulk shippers formed an <strong>in</strong>ternationalorganization, the Comité Maritime <strong>International</strong> (CMI), to lobby for an <strong>in</strong>ternational conventiongovern<strong>in</strong>g carriage contracts. <strong>The</strong> Belgian government, recogniz<strong>in</strong>g the importance <strong>of</strong> these issuesto its great ports, <strong>in</strong> effect became the CMI’s partner <strong>in</strong> this effort. In 1905 the Belgians convenedthe first <strong>of</strong> several diplomatic conferences <strong>in</strong>tended to adopt conventions deal<strong>in</strong>g with the maritimetrade. In 1922 the CMI took over a draft that had emerged out <strong>of</strong> the Maritime Law Committee <strong>of</strong>the <strong>International</strong> Law Association. This document, after the CMI had revised it, became the basisfor the Hague Rules, which a diplomatic conference approved <strong>in</strong> 1924. Almost all the major seapowers today recognize these Rules, either <strong>in</strong> their prist<strong>in</strong>e form or as amended <strong>in</strong> 1968. <strong>The</strong> UnitedStates implemented the 1924 convention through enactment <strong>of</strong> the Carriage <strong>of</strong> Goods at Sea Act <strong>of</strong>1936. 21Several aspects <strong>of</strong> this process are noteworthy. First, the parties pursu<strong>in</strong>g unification bypassedboth the Hague Conference <strong>and</strong> UNIDROIT, then an organ <strong>of</strong> the League <strong>of</strong> Nations. <strong>The</strong>yapparently worried that work<strong>in</strong>g through preexist<strong>in</strong>g bodies tied directly or <strong>in</strong>directly to the Leaguewould deter nonmembers, especially the United States, from participat<strong>in</strong>g. As a major maritimenation <strong>and</strong> the world’s foremost <strong>in</strong>dustrial power, the United States had to take part for the HagueRules to have any significance, but its repudiation <strong>of</strong> the League meant that any new <strong>in</strong>ternationalengagement had to be approached with great delicacy.Second, one should note the role <strong>of</strong> the CMI as the expert group responsible for draft<strong>in</strong>g theConvention. Neither the CMI nor the the various diplomatic conferences it served took on thecharacter <strong>of</strong> a public legislature. <strong>The</strong>ir narrowly def<strong>in</strong>ed competence—unification <strong>of</strong> private law rulesrelat<strong>in</strong>g to commercial sea carriage—made opportunities for logroll<strong>in</strong>g rare if not nonexistent, <strong>and</strong>the technical nature <strong>of</strong> the project plus strong <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong>fluence precluded any political agency fromaffect<strong>in</strong>g their preferences except <strong>in</strong> the most general sense. <strong>The</strong> CMI members undoubtedlypossessed better <strong>in</strong>formation about the implications <strong>of</strong> their proposals than did most <strong>of</strong> the <strong>of</strong>ficialgovernmental representatives who reviewed their work.Turn<strong>in</strong>g to the substance <strong>of</strong> the Hague Rules, one encounters many clear-cut rules give courts <strong>and</strong>other decisionmakers little room to maneuver. <strong>The</strong>se tend to reveal the f<strong>in</strong>gerpr<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>of</strong> the carrier<strong>in</strong>dustry. Perhaps the most significant is Article IV(5), which relieves the carrier from liability fordamages to goods <strong>in</strong> excess <strong>of</strong> $ 500 per package, absent a declaration by the shipper <strong>of</strong> higher21Carriage <strong>of</strong> Goods at Sea Act, 46 U.S.C. App. §§ 1300-15.


22value. <strong>The</strong> cap applies except when <strong>in</strong>jury stems from the carrier’s know<strong>in</strong>g or recklessmisconduct. 23This limitation is not absolute, as passengers <strong>and</strong> shippers rema<strong>in</strong> free to negotiate for greaterliability. But the drafters probably appreciated that a right to dicker over liability would have littlepractical effect. <strong>The</strong>y easily could have expected that specialist <strong>in</strong>surance firms normally wouldprovide this protection at a lower cost than could carriers. <strong>The</strong> cartelized nature <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dustry madeit likely that the shipper would bear the cost <strong>of</strong> additional coverage whether obta<strong>in</strong>ed from the carrieror a third party. At a m<strong>in</strong>imum, the transaction costs associated with negotiat<strong>in</strong>g anyth<strong>in</strong>g differentfrom the st<strong>and</strong>ard liability term would deter shippers from seek<strong>in</strong>g a departure except <strong>in</strong> cases wherethe benefit derived from carrier (as opposed to third party) liability exceeded by some substantialamount the difference <strong>in</strong> cost between procur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>surance <strong>and</strong> shar<strong>in</strong>g the burden with the carrier.Other provisions also reflect the carriers’ <strong>in</strong>terests. Article IV(2)(a) provides them with ancomplete defense for all liability caused by faults <strong>in</strong> navigation, even when the ship’s capta<strong>in</strong> serves24as the carrier’s employee. Article IV(2) lists other conditions, such as war, weather, <strong>and</strong> laborunrest, that would free carriers from liability <strong>and</strong> forbids the imposition <strong>of</strong> liability without fault. 25F<strong>in</strong>ally, Article III(6) gives the recipients <strong>of</strong> cargo only a limited time to compla<strong>in</strong> about damage afterthey take possession. Failure to compla<strong>in</strong> immediately, <strong>in</strong> the case <strong>of</strong> apparent damage, or with<strong>in</strong>three days, <strong>in</strong> all other cases, results <strong>in</strong> a legal presumption that the goods arrived <strong>in</strong> good condition.26Shippers then have a year to sue. As with Article IV(5), carriers rema<strong>in</strong> free to contract for greaterobligations than those imposed by the Hague Rules, but may not contract away those duties imposedby the Rules. 27One could challenge my characterization <strong>of</strong> these provisions as pro-carrier. None may favorcarriers as much as a legal regime that allows carriers an unrestricted right to contract out <strong>of</strong> mostif not all liability. But by the end <strong>of</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eteenth century, freedom <strong>of</strong> contract with respect to seacarriage was wan<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> some form <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry regulation seemed <strong>in</strong>evitable. <strong>The</strong> limits on liabilityfound <strong>in</strong> the Hague Rules seem at least as hospitable, <strong>and</strong> probably better, than those that carriersmight have confronted had the <strong>in</strong>ternational process not cut short national legislative developments.Further evidence that the Hague Rules favor sea carriers comes from subsequent efforts byshippers to overturn the regime. At the <strong>in</strong>itial suggestion <strong>of</strong> Chile, a country that relies heavily on1722Hague Rules Art. IV(5).<strong>The</strong> Protocol to Amend the 1924 Convention for the <strong>Unification</strong> <strong>of</strong> Certa<strong>in</strong> Rules <strong>of</strong> LawRelat<strong>in</strong>g to Bills <strong>of</strong> Lad<strong>in</strong>g, Feb. 23, 1968 [here<strong>in</strong>after cited as Visby Rules], <strong>in</strong>creased the monetary value <strong>of</strong> Article IV(5)’slimit. Many important jurisdictions, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, Canada, South Africa, France <strong>and</strong> Belgium, apply theVisby Rules, but the United States still adheres to the unamended Hague Rules.23Hague Rules Art. IV(5).24Hague Rules Art. IV(2)(a). Carrier do have an obligation to exercise care <strong>in</strong> prepar<strong>in</strong>g the vessel for seaworth<strong>in</strong>ess<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> select<strong>in</strong>g their agents <strong>and</strong> servants, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the master. Id. Art. III(1).25Id. Art. IV(2).26Id. Art III(6). <strong>The</strong> Visby rules permits owners <strong>of</strong> damaged cargo to br<strong>in</strong>g actions for <strong>in</strong>demnity after the one-yearperiod has expired. Visby Rules Art. III(6bis).27Hague Rules Arts. III(8), V.


18exports but which does not have a substantial maritime <strong>in</strong>dustry, UNCITRAL <strong>in</strong> 1969 began todevelop a new <strong>in</strong>strument to replace the exist<strong>in</strong>g regime. A work<strong>in</strong>g group approved a draft that,28follow<strong>in</strong>g their adoption by a diplomatic conference <strong>in</strong> 1978, became the Hamburg Rules. In 1992enough countries had jo<strong>in</strong>ed this <strong>in</strong>strument for it to go <strong>in</strong>to effect, but as a practical matter it haslittle significance. Participation rema<strong>in</strong>s limited to twenty-five countries dist<strong>in</strong>guished by their lack<strong>of</strong> shipp<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>and</strong>, for the most part, weak economies. <strong>The</strong> only members <strong>of</strong> the OECD tohave adopted the Hamburg Rules are l<strong>and</strong>-locked Austria, Czech Republic <strong>and</strong> Hungary.<strong>The</strong> Hamburg Rules change or supplement several Hague Rules affect<strong>in</strong>g carrier liability. Carrierslose their immunity for <strong>in</strong>juries caused by nautical fault, as well as the other Hague Rules ArticleIV(2) exemptions from liability, <strong>and</strong> must compensate shippers for losses attributable to delay <strong>in</strong>delivery, over <strong>and</strong> above damage to the cargo. <strong>The</strong> Hamburg Rules normally presume the carrier’sfault, with the burden <strong>of</strong> pro<strong>of</strong> on the carrier to show it did everyth<strong>in</strong>g possible to prevent <strong>in</strong>jury. 29<strong>The</strong> carrier becomes liable for any <strong>in</strong>juries occurr<strong>in</strong>g while the goods rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> the carrier’s charge,30whether on board the vessel or not. <strong>The</strong> cap on liability for damage to cargo has <strong>in</strong>creased, with31recoveries for delay count<strong>in</strong>g aga<strong>in</strong>st that cap. If the carrier subcontracts the carriage to anothercarrier for any part <strong>of</strong> the voyage, it will rema<strong>in</strong> liable to the shipper for any result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>juries unlessits carriage contract specifies the subcontractor <strong>and</strong> guarantees the shipper a right to relief aga<strong>in</strong>st that32 33carrier. <strong>The</strong> shipper receives a longer statute <strong>of</strong> limitations for br<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>g its claims. F<strong>in</strong>ally, theHamburg Rules, where they have taken effect, apply to a wider range <strong>of</strong> transactions than do theHague Rules. 34I do not mean to suggest that the Hamburg Rules represent an optimal allocation <strong>of</strong> risk betweencarriers <strong>and</strong> shippers, or that the Hague Rules necessarily have disserved <strong>in</strong>ternational commerce.<strong>The</strong> po<strong>in</strong>t, rather, it that both <strong>in</strong>struments conta<strong>in</strong> precise rules that purport to alter the preexist<strong>in</strong>glegal order, <strong>and</strong> that <strong>in</strong> both cases these rules seem to serve one particular <strong>in</strong>terest group. Differentprocesses represent<strong>in</strong>g different forces produced these two <strong>in</strong>struments, mak<strong>in</strong>g their apparent<strong>in</strong>consistency more underst<strong>and</strong>able. Carriers seemed to have won most <strong>of</strong> arguments about whatshould go <strong>in</strong>to the Hague Rules, while shippers largely prevailed dur<strong>in</strong>g the UNCITRAL process thatproduced the Hamburg Rules. In both cases, special <strong>in</strong>terests got largely what they wanted.What we have, then, are examples <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational agreements that unify the private law <strong>of</strong>carriage by sea <strong>in</strong> a way that benefits a discrete <strong>and</strong> coherent <strong>in</strong>dustry. In each case one <strong>in</strong>dustry ledthe effort to create an <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>strument, <strong>and</strong> its experts played a central role <strong>in</strong> the draft<strong>in</strong>g28Convention on the Carriage <strong>of</strong> Goods by Sea, Mar. 31, 1978, A/Conf.89/13, U.N.T.S., U.N. Doc. 1978 [here<strong>in</strong>afterHamburg Rules].29Id. Art. 5. An exception exists for fire, on which case the shipper must prove the carrier’s negligence contributed toits <strong>in</strong>juries.30Id. Art. 4.31Id. Art. 6.32Id. Art. 10.33Id. Art. 20.34Id. Art. 2.


process. As predicted, the <strong>in</strong>strument takes the form <strong>of</strong> clear <strong>and</strong> precise rules that constra<strong>in</strong> futuredecisionmakers, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> substance the constra<strong>in</strong>ts favor the <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong>dustry.What, then, should we make <strong>of</strong> the current legal regime for carriage <strong>of</strong> goods by sea? Adoption<strong>of</strong> the Hague Rules no doubt reduced legal risks, one <strong>of</strong> the pr<strong>in</strong>cipal objectives <strong>of</strong> unificationprojects, but at what cost? It seems unlikely that the Hague Rules substituted “good” law for badrules, <strong>and</strong> from the perspective <strong>of</strong> passengers <strong>and</strong> shippers the reverse may have been true. Nor isit likely that they helped to build up a cadre <strong>of</strong> specialist <strong>in</strong>termediaries whose expertise <strong>in</strong> sea carriagelaw allowed them to act more broadly as brokers for the transportation <strong>in</strong>dustry. To the contrary,the Convention if anyth<strong>in</strong>g seemed to strengthen the position <strong>of</strong> lawyers tied to the carriers relativeto everyone else.This assessment may seem too harsh. To identify the Hague Rules as special <strong>in</strong>terest legislationis not necessarily to condemn it. Impos<strong>in</strong>g the costs <strong>of</strong> accidents on passengers <strong>and</strong> shippers, ratherthan concentrat<strong>in</strong>g them on the carriers, may have helped <strong>in</strong> the development <strong>of</strong> new technologies.<strong>The</strong> net ga<strong>in</strong>s that passengers <strong>and</strong> carriers have derived from improvements <strong>in</strong> air service may haveoutweighed the burdens that the Hague Rules imposed on them. Perhaps no better way existed todeal with the problem.But another story also suggests itself. Where government regulation limits entry <strong>in</strong>to an <strong>in</strong>dustry,price competition among its members, <strong>and</strong> the prices charged consumers, the <strong>in</strong>dustry may turn tom<strong>and</strong>atory rules <strong>of</strong> contract as the only convenient means for extract<strong>in</strong>g monopoly rents. By the timethe Hague Rules appeared, such regulation existed at least <strong>in</strong> the United States <strong>and</strong> the UnitedK<strong>in</strong>gdom, two <strong>of</strong> the lead<strong>in</strong>g maritime nations <strong>of</strong> the day. <strong>The</strong> carriers surely anticipated that with<strong>in</strong>their government-ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>ed cartel, they could gouge consumers through shoddy service, but not byrais<strong>in</strong>g prices. <strong>The</strong> Hague Rules may have served to implement this strategy.<strong>The</strong> broader po<strong>in</strong>t is not that the technocratic process necessarily produced bad legislation.Rather, it seems that the use <strong>of</strong> technical experts at the center <strong>of</strong> an <strong>in</strong>ternational process resulted <strong>in</strong>a k<strong>in</strong>d <strong>of</strong> legislation that we might expect from the most venal <strong>of</strong> domestic political bodies. <strong>The</strong> bestwe can say is that the <strong>in</strong>ternational technocrats did not produce a law that is provably worse thanwhat any other lawmaker might have enacted. This claim, however, falls far short <strong>of</strong> a r<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>gendorsement <strong>of</strong> the process.2. Air Transport—<strong>The</strong> Warsaw ConventionOnce the commercial possibilities <strong>of</strong> air transport became clear, carriers had to confront theconsequences <strong>of</strong> breakdowns <strong>in</strong> service. Airplane accidents, when they occur, tend to result <strong>in</strong>greater damage to passengers <strong>and</strong> cargo than when ships, tra<strong>in</strong>s, or trucks encounter trouble. In theearly years <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dustry, the legal consequences <strong>of</strong> these accidents rema<strong>in</strong>ed unclear. Was a carrierliable for all <strong>in</strong>juries caused by its activity because it engaged <strong>in</strong> an ultrahazardous activity? Didpassengers <strong>and</strong> shippers proceed at their own risk when they contracted with an air carrier, given theobvious dangers? What would be the appropriate st<strong>and</strong>ard <strong>of</strong> care applicable to air carriers, if any?19


20Neither U.S. law nor that <strong>of</strong> the other major <strong>in</strong>dustrial countries <strong>of</strong>fered clear answers to thesequestions back <strong>in</strong> the 1920s, when the <strong>in</strong>dustry first emerged.<strong>The</strong>se problems were exacerbated by the uneven spread <strong>of</strong> aviation technology around the world.<strong>The</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry reasonably could anticipate that for some period <strong>of</strong> time firms based <strong>in</strong> only a h<strong>and</strong>ful<strong>of</strong> countries would carry out most commercial air transport, but that their services would extend toa large portion <strong>of</strong> the globe. As a result, for a substantial number <strong>of</strong> potential dest<strong>in</strong>ations thereexisted the risk <strong>of</strong> a pro-shipper bias that, <strong>in</strong> ways not easy to anticipate, might result <strong>in</strong> anti-carrierlaws.With the recent experience <strong>of</strong> the maritime shipp<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry before them, air carriers also couldanticipate significant government <strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>in</strong> their prices <strong>and</strong> other terms <strong>of</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess. In manycountries, <strong>and</strong> particularly <strong>in</strong> the United States, government contracts to carry mail provided thepr<strong>in</strong>cipal source <strong>of</strong> revenues for the nascent airl<strong>in</strong>es. Along with these contracts came governmentcontrol over entry <strong>in</strong>to the <strong>in</strong>dustry, revenues, <strong>and</strong> other aspects <strong>of</strong> do<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess. Full-blown35regulation did not come until later, but the shape <strong>of</strong> the future seemed apparent.As early as 1922, various groups represent<strong>in</strong>g the air carrier <strong>in</strong>dustry, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the Air TransportCommittee <strong>of</strong> the <strong>International</strong> Chamber <strong>of</strong> Commerce, began lobby<strong>in</strong>g for an <strong>in</strong>ternational effort toconfront these issues. <strong>The</strong> French government convened a diplomatic conference <strong>in</strong> 1925, with 44states represented <strong>and</strong> another three, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the United States, present through <strong>of</strong>ficial observers.That conference created an <strong>International</strong> Technical Committee <strong>of</strong> Aerial Legal Experts, which <strong>in</strong> 1926began work on the text that, follow<strong>in</strong>g its 1929 approval at another diplomatic conference, becamethe Warsaw Convention. <strong>The</strong> United States acceded to the Convention <strong>in</strong> 1934, the same year thatit created the regulatory structure for the <strong>in</strong>dustry that largely survives to this day. 36<strong>The</strong> parallels between this process <strong>and</strong> that which produced the Hague Rules seem remarkable.A private <strong>in</strong>dustry formed a group <strong>of</strong> technical experts <strong>and</strong> found a convenient host government tosponsor an <strong>in</strong>ternational conference. <strong>The</strong> expert group outlasted the conference <strong>and</strong> became thepr<strong>in</strong>cipal forum for <strong>in</strong>ternational discussions <strong>of</strong> legal aspects <strong>of</strong> air carriage, much as the CMI hascarried out that role for sea transport. <strong>The</strong> participants <strong>in</strong> the 1925 conference created a special<strong>in</strong>stitution for the unification <strong>of</strong> commercial air law, the <strong>International</strong> Technical Committee. This<strong>in</strong>dustry-dom<strong>in</strong>ated group, which cont<strong>in</strong>ued to work until its absorption by the <strong>International</strong> CivilAviation Organization <strong>in</strong> 1946, operated as a st<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g work<strong>in</strong>g group unattached to any permanent<strong>in</strong>stitution. It <strong>in</strong>stead served at the call <strong>of</strong> any <strong>in</strong>ternational conference that might be convened toaddress subjects with<strong>in</strong> its competence.As with the CMI <strong>and</strong> the Hague Conference, the <strong>International</strong> Technical Committee <strong>and</strong> the ParisConference did not take on the character <strong>of</strong> a public legislature. <strong>The</strong>y also had few opportunities forlogroll<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> rema<strong>in</strong>ed largely free <strong>of</strong> political agency, <strong>and</strong> enjoyed an <strong>in</strong>formation advantage relative35See ANDREAS F. LOWENFELD, AVIATION LAW 1-2 (1972); PAUL S. DEMPSEY & WILLIAM E. THOMS, LAW ANDECONOMIC REGULATION IN TRANSPORTATION 26-27 (1986)36Id.


to the bodies to which they reported. That the Committee rema<strong>in</strong>ed active long after the adoption<strong>of</strong> the Warsaw Convention, <strong>and</strong> throughout a period <strong>of</strong> unprecedented <strong>in</strong>ternational economic <strong>and</strong>political disruption, says someth<strong>in</strong>g about the strength <strong>of</strong> its members’ commitment to further changes<strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>ternational legal environment. That the countries <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational aviation adoptedno other unification <strong>in</strong>struments after 1929 also <strong>in</strong>dicates that the Committee’s preference for newlaw was greater than that <strong>of</strong> the broader aviation community.<strong>The</strong> Warsaw Convention conta<strong>in</strong>s a number <strong>of</strong> clear-cut rules that give courts <strong>and</strong> otherdecisionmakers little room to maneuver. Particularly strik<strong>in</strong>g are its strict monetary limits on thecarrier’s liability for <strong>in</strong>jury to passengers <strong>and</strong> cargo. Article 22(1) <strong>of</strong> the Convention sets a cap <strong>of</strong>125,000 French francs, valued <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> gold pursuant to the formula found <strong>in</strong> Article 22(4), for37<strong>in</strong>juries to a passenger, <strong>and</strong> 250 francs a kilogram for cargo. <strong>The</strong>se limits do not apply <strong>in</strong> cases38where the carrier’s “willful misconduct” causes <strong>in</strong>jury. Carriers may not propose lower limits but39may negotiate higher ones. As with the Hague Rule’s similar provisions, these Articles at am<strong>in</strong>imum allowed carriers to unbundle <strong>in</strong>surance from shipp<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>and</strong> probably enabled them toprocure additional <strong>in</strong>come from their customers. We similarly <strong>in</strong> no position to prove that thisoutcome necessarily departed from efficiency, because it allowed carriers to concentrate on their corebus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>and</strong> to let others deal with the challenge <strong>of</strong> predict<strong>in</strong>g accident rates dur<strong>in</strong>g their <strong>in</strong>dustry’s40developmental period. But, <strong>in</strong> the presence <strong>of</strong> governmental regulation, we also can regard Article22 as consistent with the <strong>in</strong>direct extraction <strong>of</strong> monopoly rents by an <strong>in</strong>dustry that enjoyed unusualprotection from competition.Other Convention provisions seem both clear <strong>and</strong> pro-carrier. For example, Article 26(2) giveshippers <strong>of</strong> h<strong>and</strong> luggage three days, <strong>and</strong> other shippers seven days, to compla<strong>in</strong> about damage to41goods after tak<strong>in</strong>g possession <strong>of</strong> them from the carrier. Failure to notify the carrier with<strong>in</strong> thosetime periods results <strong>in</strong> a forfeiture <strong>of</strong> all rights to compensation.<strong>The</strong> provisions def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the scope <strong>of</strong> the Convention also <strong>in</strong>dicate a commitment to precision.All flights that, “accord<strong>in</strong>g to the contract made between the parties” (i.e., the face <strong>of</strong> the ticket)2137Warsaw Convention Art. 22. <strong>The</strong> 1955 Hague Protocol to the Convention doubled the limit for personal <strong>in</strong>juries.Protocol to Amend the Convention for the <strong>Unification</strong> <strong>of</strong> Certa<strong>in</strong> Rules Relat<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>International</strong> Carriage by Air, September28, 1955, Art. XI. <strong>The</strong> 1966 Montreal Agreement, which applies only to flights that have connect<strong>in</strong>g po<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong> the UnitedStates, further raised the personal <strong>in</strong>jury limit to $ 75,000. U.S. courts, perhaps <strong>in</strong> recognition <strong>of</strong> the pro-carrier premisesunderly<strong>in</strong>g these provisions, have enforced these limits rigorously. See, e.g., Trans World Airl<strong>in</strong>es, Inc. v. Frankl<strong>in</strong> M<strong>in</strong>t Corp.,466 U.S. 243 (1984) (U.S. court will convert Article 22 limits <strong>in</strong>to dollars us<strong>in</strong>g the gold value <strong>of</strong> dollars at the time <strong>of</strong> theConvention’s adoption).38Warsaw Convention Art. 25.39Id. Art. 23.40<strong>The</strong> recent efforts <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational air carriers to relax these limits <strong>in</strong>dicates that the freedom to unbundle <strong>in</strong>surancefrom carriage serves means less to a mature <strong>in</strong>dustry with stable <strong>and</strong> predictable accident rates. F<strong>in</strong>nair now publicizes thefact that it will accept unlimited liability for personal <strong>in</strong>juries. Perhaps to thwart competition over this service <strong>and</strong> to make iteasier for airl<strong>in</strong>es to pass on the cost <strong>of</strong> coverage to their passengers, the Legal Committee <strong>of</strong> the ICAO <strong>in</strong> 1997 recommendeda major overhaul <strong>of</strong> Article 22’s personal liability cap. Under its proposal, no absolute limit would exist for carrier liability,although states could award only $150,000 per person without a determ<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> fault.41Warsaw Convention Art. 26(2).


22beg<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> one party to the convention <strong>and</strong> has its dest<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>in</strong> another, regardless <strong>of</strong> stopp<strong>in</strong>g po<strong>in</strong>ts,come under the Convention. All flights that have a beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> dest<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>in</strong> a s<strong>in</strong>gle party’sterritory <strong>and</strong> that have “an agreed stopp<strong>in</strong>g place” <strong>in</strong> some other country, whether a party to theConvention or not, also come with<strong>in</strong> its provisions. <strong>The</strong> Convention does not apply to any other42flights. <strong>The</strong> Convention’s limits on liability for personal <strong>in</strong>juries applies to any harm suffered whileembark<strong>in</strong>g or disembark<strong>in</strong>g from such flights or while on board, even if the plane never takes <strong>of</strong>f. 43None <strong>of</strong> the terms on which application <strong>of</strong> these provisions depends leaves much room for<strong>in</strong>terpretation.One might object that the Warsaw Convention represents a particularly unfair example <strong>of</strong>unification legislation because it <strong>in</strong>volved a completely novel technology, <strong>and</strong> thus an untestedenvironment for the application <strong>of</strong> preexist<strong>in</strong>g legal pr<strong>in</strong>ciples. <strong>The</strong>re was no status quo to defendor reform, because no one had a clear idea <strong>of</strong> what rules applied to this new <strong>in</strong>dustry. Under thesecircumstances, <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong>siders had a clear <strong>in</strong>formational advantage that they could exploit dur<strong>in</strong>gthe lawmak<strong>in</strong>g process. But once a legal system matures along with the <strong>in</strong>dustry it governs, perhapspossibilities for reform will emerge.But this argument fails, both as a historically complete account <strong>and</strong> as an effort to <strong>in</strong>terpret thecontext <strong>of</strong> the late twentieth century. Maritime shipp<strong>in</strong>g did not <strong>in</strong>volve radically new technologies,yet the <strong>in</strong>ternational regime for that <strong>in</strong>dustry became the template for the Warsaw Convention. And<strong>in</strong> broader terms, law has played a game <strong>of</strong> catch up with new <strong>and</strong> economically significanttechnologies s<strong>in</strong>ce the onset <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dustrial revolution at the end <strong>of</strong> the eighteenth century. <strong>The</strong>challenge <strong>of</strong> adopt<strong>in</strong>g old rules <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitutions to new bus<strong>in</strong>ess patterns seems even greater today.Computerization <strong>and</strong> improved telecommunications means that a wide range <strong>of</strong> traditionalcommercial law systems must adapt to a new world <strong>of</strong> paperless transactions <strong>and</strong> more sophisticated<strong>in</strong>formation process<strong>in</strong>g. Thus we cannot exempt the Convention without provid<strong>in</strong>g a ready excusefor the <strong>in</strong>adequacies <strong>of</strong> almost all unification efforts.3. <strong>International</strong> Sales Law—CISGIn a world economy dom<strong>in</strong>ated by trade <strong>in</strong> primary <strong>and</strong> manufactured products, the contract forthe sale <strong>of</strong> goods serves as a fundamental unit <strong>of</strong> legal status. It facilitates exchange, permits shifts<strong>in</strong> risks tied to future events, <strong>and</strong> specifies the collateral obligations that follow from a change <strong>in</strong>ownership <strong>of</strong> goods. Transparency <strong>and</strong> uniformity <strong>of</strong> the rules govern<strong>in</strong>g these contracts haveobvious appeal. Parties can control legal risk by mak<strong>in</strong>g their legal rights <strong>and</strong> obligations <strong>in</strong>dependent<strong>of</strong> their bus<strong>in</strong>ess locations or the places where their goods wend their way <strong>in</strong> the course <strong>of</strong> exchange.In addition, the law <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational sales contracts might promote other social goals, such aseconomic development or redistribution <strong>of</strong> wealth to victims <strong>of</strong> past first-world exploitation. F<strong>in</strong>ally,unification <strong>of</strong> the law <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational sales can strengthen bonds among lawyers <strong>in</strong> different countrieswho specialize <strong>in</strong> import <strong>and</strong> export transactions.4243Id. Art. 1(2).Id. Arts. 17, 22.


Other, less benign ends also might prompt unification <strong>in</strong> this area. Nations that mostly consumeprimary products <strong>and</strong> sell f<strong>in</strong>ished goods (<strong>in</strong> other words, the first world) might want to confrontdevelop<strong>in</strong>g countries with a set <strong>of</strong> rules that discourages redistribution or <strong>in</strong>dependence from theglobal economy. Specialists <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational trade might want to maximize the value <strong>of</strong> their servicesby promot<strong>in</strong>g a legal regime that requires their participation for the consummation <strong>of</strong> the mostord<strong>in</strong>ary transaction. Experts <strong>in</strong> contract law might regard the <strong>in</strong>ternational lawmak<strong>in</strong>g process asan end <strong>in</strong> itself, lead<strong>in</strong>g to travel, research opportunities, <strong>and</strong> the stature that comes with a personall<strong>in</strong>k to an <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>strument.For whatever reasons, the effort to produce a unified set <strong>of</strong> rules for <strong>in</strong>ternational contracts began<strong>in</strong> the 1920s, not long after the start <strong>of</strong> the process that led to the Warsaw Convention <strong>and</strong> HagueRules. UNIDROIT began work on a draft treaty <strong>in</strong> 1930 but, distracted by the Great Depression <strong>and</strong>World War II, achieved noth<strong>in</strong>g until the 1960s. A diplomatic conference convened <strong>in</strong> 1964 toconsider UNIDROIT’s efforts adopted a convention on the formation <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational sales contracts<strong>and</strong> another on the content <strong>of</strong> such contracts, but the newly decolonized <strong>and</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g statesroundly declared these <strong>in</strong>struments unacceptable. Seek<strong>in</strong>g to keep the process alive, the promoters<strong>of</strong> unification shifted its venue to UNCITRAL. This proved a wise choice. 44<strong>The</strong> Convention on the <strong>International</strong> Sale <strong>of</strong> Goods (CISG) became the most widely adopted <strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>fluential <strong>of</strong> UNCITRAL projects. Follow<strong>in</strong>g another decade <strong>of</strong> deliberation, a Work<strong>in</strong>g Grouppublished a draft <strong>in</strong> 1978, <strong>and</strong> UNCITRAL convened a conference to adopt a f<strong>in</strong>al version <strong>in</strong> 1980.It went <strong>in</strong>to force for the first eleven signatories, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the United States, <strong>in</strong> 1988. As <strong>of</strong> May1998, fifty-six countries, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g most major trad<strong>in</strong>g nations other than Japan or the UnitedK<strong>in</strong>gdom, had adopted the CISG.<strong>The</strong> CISG epitomizes a unification agreement for which legal academics played the dom<strong>in</strong>ant role<strong>in</strong> shap<strong>in</strong>g the agenda <strong>and</strong> content <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>strument. At the 1980 conference, a law pr<strong>of</strong>essorpresided. Many <strong>of</strong> the most important delegations, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>of</strong> the United States, had academicsat their head or as members. No particular <strong>in</strong>dustry or <strong>in</strong>terest group had an obviously dist<strong>in</strong>ct stake<strong>in</strong> the outcome <strong>of</strong> the negotiations. Most bus<strong>in</strong>ess both buy <strong>and</strong> sell goods, mak<strong>in</strong>g them largely<strong>in</strong>different among rules that favor buyers or sellers. And the Convention does not s<strong>in</strong>gle out nicheactivities where a particular group would care about the applicable rules.<strong>The</strong> CISG conta<strong>in</strong>s few if any provisions that would annoy any particular <strong>in</strong>terest group. Its rulesdo not transparently promote exploitation <strong>of</strong> primary product exporters, although <strong>in</strong> the most generalsense the CISG does bolster <strong>and</strong> susta<strong>in</strong> a capitalist trad<strong>in</strong>g system based on (perhaps false)assumptions about arms-length exchange. Nor does it encourage redistribution or restitution for past2344See generally John O. Honnold, <strong>The</strong> United Nations Commission on <strong>International</strong> Trade Law: Mission <strong>and</strong> Methods,27 AM. J. COMP. L. 201 (1979); John A. Spanogle, <strong>The</strong> Arrival <strong>of</strong> <strong>International</strong> Private Law, 25 GEO. WASH. J. INT’L L. &ECON. 477 (1991). <strong>The</strong> two <strong>in</strong>struments generated by the UNIDROIT process, the Convention Relat<strong>in</strong>g to a Uniform Law onthe <strong>International</strong> Sale <strong>of</strong> Goods, 834 U.N.T.S. 107 (1972), <strong>and</strong> the Convention Relat<strong>in</strong>g to a Uniform Law on the Formation<strong>of</strong> Contracts for the <strong>International</strong> Sale <strong>of</strong> Goods, 834 U.N.T.S. 169 (1972), did go <strong>in</strong>to effect but only with respect to a h<strong>and</strong>ful<strong>of</strong> states.


24imperialist abuses. None <strong>of</strong> its rules, for example, expressly addresses the question <strong>of</strong> whether thelaw should modify contracts <strong>in</strong> light <strong>of</strong> any <strong>in</strong>equalities between the parties.What the CISG conta<strong>in</strong>s are a great many rules <strong>of</strong> a sort that allow virtually unbounded discretionto the decisionmaker who must apply them. <strong>The</strong> very extent <strong>of</strong> the convention, as well as the rulesapplicable to contracts with<strong>in</strong> its coverage, rema<strong>in</strong>s sufficiently unclear to allow decisionmakers tomake almost any choice they wish. Moreover, even when the language <strong>of</strong> the CISG follows that <strong>of</strong>preexist<strong>in</strong>g rules, such as those <strong>of</strong> Article 2 <strong>of</strong> the UCC, it effectively displaces the clarify<strong>in</strong>g glossesthat national courts have given to domestic law.Consider, for example, a U.S. corporation that buys textiles from a Russian manufacturer. If theU.S. purchaser has a representative <strong>of</strong>fice <strong>in</strong> Russia that places orders, does the CISG apply? Article1(1)(a) states that the Convention governs contracts “between parties whose places <strong>of</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess are45<strong>in</strong> different states,” each <strong>of</strong> which has jo<strong>in</strong>ed the Convention. Russia <strong>and</strong> the United States eachbelong, but do the parties have places <strong>of</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong> separate countries? Article 10(a) states that ifa party has more than one place <strong>of</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess, that “which has the closest relationship to the contract46<strong>and</strong> its performance” is the one that counts. Does this mean that, because the U.S. company usesa Russian representative <strong>of</strong>fice, both parties have a Russian place <strong>of</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess, <strong>in</strong> which case theConvention does not apply? Nowhere <strong>in</strong> the CISG do we f<strong>in</strong>d a def<strong>in</strong>ition <strong>of</strong> a place <strong>of</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess,except <strong>in</strong> the negative sense that, accord<strong>in</strong>g to Article 1(3), “the civil or commercial character <strong>of</strong> theparties . . . is [not] to be taken <strong>in</strong>to consideration <strong>in</strong> determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the application <strong>of</strong> this Convention.” 47Suppose a U.S. company sells a Russian firm the equipment for manufactur<strong>in</strong>g compact disks,<strong>and</strong> the sales contract conta<strong>in</strong>s an obligation to tra<strong>in</strong> the Russian personnel, customize the equipmentto meet the customer’s requirements, <strong>and</strong> a three-year commitment both to repair the equipment <strong>and</strong>to modify it <strong>in</strong> light <strong>of</strong> technological changes. Would this be a contract for the sale <strong>of</strong> goods or forservices? Article 3(2) states that the Convention “does not apply to contracts <strong>in</strong> which the48preponderant part” <strong>of</strong> the seller’s obligation consists <strong>of</strong> services. How do we determ<strong>in</strong>e what ispreponderant? Do we consider, for example, potential costs <strong>of</strong> future services, or the period overwhich they must be rendered?Suppose <strong>in</strong>stead a U.S. company contracts with a Russian firm to purchase photocopiersassembled <strong>in</strong> Russia. <strong>The</strong> purchaser contracts with another Russian firm for the toner cartridges,which it then supplies to the Russian photocopier assembler. Article 3(1) states that the Conventiondoes not apply if the purchaser supplies “a substantial part” <strong>of</strong> the materials necessary for produc<strong>in</strong>g49the purchased good. Does the purchaser supply the cartridges when it buys them from one Russian45CISG Art. 1(1)(a).46Id. Art. 10(a).47Id. Art. 1(3). See also Arthur Rosett, Critical Reflections on the United Nations Convention on Contracts for the<strong>International</strong> Sale <strong>of</strong> Goods, 45 OHIO ST. L.J. 265, 274-81 (1984).48CISG Art. 3(2).49Id. Art. 3(2).


firm <strong>and</strong> then sells them to the producer for <strong>in</strong>stallation <strong>in</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>ished product, <strong>and</strong>, if so, are thecartridges a substantial part <strong>of</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>ished product?A further source <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>determ<strong>in</strong>ancy <strong>in</strong>volves the dist<strong>in</strong>ction made <strong>in</strong> Article 4(a) between, on theone h<strong>and</strong>, issues <strong>of</strong> contract formation <strong>and</strong> rights <strong>and</strong> obligations aris<strong>in</strong>g from a contract <strong>and</strong>, on theother h<strong>and</strong>, questions <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g the validity <strong>of</strong> contractual provisions. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to Article 4(a), the50CISG has no bear<strong>in</strong>g on validity issues, which local law must resolve. But what dist<strong>in</strong>guishes theeffectiveness <strong>of</strong> a contractual provision from its validity? If national law, for example, requires salesprices to be states <strong>in</strong> local currency <strong>and</strong> a contract covered by the Convention refers only to U.S.dollars, does local law <strong>in</strong>validate the agreement or may we consider this an acceptable formulaic priceprovision under the Convention?A f<strong>in</strong>al issue <strong>of</strong> coverage <strong>in</strong>volves the right <strong>of</strong> parties under Article 6 to exclude the application51<strong>of</strong> the Convention altogether or on a provision-by-provision basis. <strong>The</strong> CISG nowhere <strong>in</strong>dicateswhat process the parties must undertake to achieve such an exclusion. Does adoption <strong>of</strong> a manifestly<strong>in</strong>consistent provision do the trick, or must the contract refer to the CISG to disavow it? What aboutthe case where one party supplies a form (say a purchase order) say<strong>in</strong>g the CISG does not apply, <strong>and</strong>the other party’s form (say an <strong>in</strong>voice) does not address the issue?None <strong>of</strong> these problems about the uncerta<strong>in</strong> scope <strong>of</strong> the CISG would matter so much if partiescould freely opt <strong>in</strong>to the Convention. But the CISG does not purport to obligate its signatory statesto permit parties to non<strong>in</strong>ternational transactions to choose to apply CISG rules. What we have<strong>in</strong>stead is a world where parties who wish to come under the CISG face considerable uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty asto whether they do <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> any event have no power to guarantee that the Convention will apply, <strong>and</strong>where parties who wish to avoid the CISG have no guidance as to what they must do to get out fromunder it.Also consider how the CISG deals with problems <strong>of</strong> determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g what commitments an otherwisevalid contract conta<strong>in</strong>s. Suppose a seller <strong>and</strong> buyer send purchase orders <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>voices that purportto specify the terms <strong>of</strong> the agreement, that these forms differ significantly <strong>in</strong> their content, <strong>and</strong> thatthe seller ships, <strong>and</strong> the buyer takes possession <strong>of</strong> the goods without either advert<strong>in</strong>g to the conflictbetween their forms. Article 19 <strong>of</strong> the CISG follows almost verbatim Article 2-206 <strong>of</strong> the UCC,52which <strong>of</strong>fers one much-criticized solution to this dilemma. <strong>The</strong> UCC, however, deals both withcases where the discrepancy between the conflict<strong>in</strong>g forms is significant <strong>and</strong> where it is not, <strong>and</strong>provides rules <strong>in</strong> both situations to determ<strong>in</strong>e which terms apply. Article 19, by contrast, is silent asto what happens if the <strong>of</strong>feree (such as a seller dispatch<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>voice <strong>in</strong> response to an earlierpurchase order) proposes materially different terms.2550Id. Art. 4(a).51Id. Art. 6.52Compare id. Art. 19 with UNIFORM COMMERCIAL CODE § 2-207. See generally Douglas G. Baird & RobertWeisberg, Rules, St<strong>and</strong>ards, <strong>and</strong> the Battle <strong>of</strong> the Forms: A Reassessment <strong>of</strong> § 2-207, 68 VA. L. REV. 1217 (1982).


26Another problem that the UCC resolves but that the CISG does not <strong>in</strong>volves open quantity <strong>and</strong>price terms. Article 14(2) states that an <strong>of</strong>fer must “make provision for determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the quantity <strong>and</strong>the price,” but does not <strong>in</strong>dicate whether leav<strong>in</strong>g quantity open for the buyer (“requirements”) or53seller (“output”) or price to be agreed at a later date is a permitted practice. Article 55, which statesthat the parties who fail to state a price will pay the generally prevail<strong>in</strong>g price at the time <strong>of</strong>performance, does not help <strong>in</strong> cases where the parties want to leave the matter for futurenegotiations. 54F<strong>in</strong>ally, consider a fairly straightforward problem, namely the time <strong>of</strong> delivery <strong>in</strong> cases where theparties do not advert to the issue. Both the UCC <strong>and</strong> the CISG state that <strong>in</strong> the absence <strong>of</strong> an expressagreement, a course <strong>of</strong> deal<strong>in</strong>g between the parties, or a customary <strong>in</strong>dustry practice, the seller must55deliver the goods with<strong>in</strong> a “reasonable” time. One might argue that where the CISG duplicates thelanguage <strong>of</strong> national law, it neither adds nor subtracts from legal stability <strong>and</strong> risk management. Butif national law conta<strong>in</strong>s a body <strong>of</strong> practice <strong>and</strong> authority that ref<strong>in</strong>es the mean<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> “reasonable” <strong>and</strong>gives the term some precision, decisionmakers must wrestle with the choice between us<strong>in</strong>g local lawto <strong>in</strong>terpret the CISG <strong>and</strong> follow<strong>in</strong>g CISG Article 7(1) admonition’s to promote “uniformity” amongnational <strong>in</strong>terpretations. 56In all these examples, the CISG enhances, or at least does not restrict, the autonomy <strong>of</strong> thosepersons who must apply the Convention <strong>in</strong> subsequent disputes over <strong>in</strong>ternational sales contracts.<strong>The</strong> decisionmaker <strong>of</strong>ten can choose to apply the CISG or not, given the ambiguities <strong>in</strong> theConvention’s coverage. Where it does choose to follow the Convention, the decisionmaker mayselect among a wide range <strong>of</strong> possible solutions to particular problems. This autonomy comes at thecost <strong>of</strong> predictability <strong>and</strong> hence <strong>in</strong>creases the legal risk associated with a contract.Suppose, for example, that before adoption <strong>of</strong> the CISG the law <strong>of</strong> country A clearly permittedrequirements contracts, <strong>and</strong> the law <strong>of</strong> country B clearly regarded them as unenforceable. Legal riskwould exist to the extent that either country might ga<strong>in</strong> jurisdiction over a dispute. But once thatissue were confronted, perhaps with a (possibly valid) choice-<strong>of</strong>-law or -forum clause, a course <strong>of</strong>conduct that avoided any contact with either country A or country B, or by fatalistically accept<strong>in</strong>gthe possibility that the contract might fail, the parties would have covered all bases. Now supposeboth countries entered <strong>in</strong>to the Convention. <strong>The</strong> parties would have to worry whether a court wouldapply the Convention to their agreement, if so whether a court would enforce their requirementscontract under the Convention, <strong>and</strong> if not whether the local law <strong>of</strong> country A or B would apply.Add<strong>in</strong>g the CISG <strong>in</strong>creases legal risk.This augmented legal risk might be desirable, <strong>of</strong> course, if it enhanced party flexibility or gavegreater sway for variances <strong>in</strong> risk preferences among potential parties. But this does not seem likely.53CISG Art. 14(2).54Id. Art. 55. See also Arthur Rosett, note 47 supra, at 288-89.55Compare CISG Art. 33(c) with UNIFORM COMMERCIAL CODE § 2-.56See CISG Art. 7(1). For a more general critique <strong>of</strong> the CISG’s <strong>in</strong>terpretative rules, see Arthur Rosett, note 47 supra,at 286-88. For a defense <strong>of</strong> these rules, see Michael P. Van Alst<strong>in</strong>e, Dynamic Treaty Interpretation, 146 U. PA. L. REV. 687(1998).


<strong>The</strong> k<strong>in</strong>ds <strong>of</strong> questions that the CISG leaves open or reopens seem unrelated to the k<strong>in</strong>ds <strong>of</strong> issuesthat parties might want to leave unsettled. <strong>The</strong> most one can argue is that the existence <strong>of</strong> CISGmight help <strong>in</strong> cases <strong>of</strong> fierce national hostility where parties would refuse to contract altogether unlessthey could avoid submitt<strong>in</strong>g to the other’s laws. In such cases, the Convention might a way out,albeit at the cost <strong>of</strong> considerable legal <strong>in</strong>determ<strong>in</strong>ancy.If the CISG has an overall effect <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g legal risk <strong>and</strong> does not seem to advance any othersubstantive social goal, what must rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> the way <strong>of</strong> potential benefits <strong>in</strong>volves the creation <strong>of</strong> aclass <strong>of</strong> CISG specialists who will promote <strong>in</strong>ternational sales through their mediation <strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>in</strong> these transactions. S<strong>in</strong>ce the Convention has been <strong>in</strong> force only for ten years, it maybe premature to ask whether it has produced such a cadre, <strong>and</strong> if so whether their existence promotes<strong>in</strong>ternational sales <strong>in</strong> spite <strong>of</strong> legal <strong>in</strong>determ<strong>in</strong>ancy. But some skepticism seems <strong>in</strong> order.Before the adoption <strong>of</strong> the CISG, we had specialists <strong>in</strong> comparative law <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternationalcommercial arbitration, both <strong>of</strong> which may add value to transactions. <strong>The</strong> CISG may dim<strong>in</strong>ish, butdoes not destroy either area <strong>of</strong> expertise. Whatever the reasons prompt<strong>in</strong>g the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, thecountry with the oldest <strong>and</strong> richest body <strong>of</strong> case law govern<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>ternational sales transactions (<strong>and</strong>a specialist court <strong>in</strong> London set up to apply it) <strong>and</strong> Japan, with perhaps the most dist<strong>in</strong>ct (<strong>and</strong> leasttransparent) body <strong>of</strong> applicable law, to hold out from the CISG system, the cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>completeness<strong>of</strong> the system will mean that the need to master commercial arbitration <strong>and</strong> comparative law willrema<strong>in</strong> with us for some time. Why we also need CISG specialists then becomes unclear.How, then, should we assess the CISG? We have good reason to suspect that the good th<strong>in</strong>gsit does, especially <strong>in</strong> provid<strong>in</strong>g a way around nationalist preferences <strong>in</strong> contract law, do not expla<strong>in</strong>why so many states have adopted it. <strong>The</strong> costs from <strong>in</strong>creased legal risk seem more than sufficientto <strong>of</strong>fset the desirable aspects <strong>of</strong> the Convention. One then must speculate what other, less generalbenefits flow from its adoption. Given that the CISG seems to produce no particular return todiscrete groups, other than to legal specialists <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> its development, we must suspect that theConvention may exist primarily because those <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> its production, especially <strong>in</strong> the Work<strong>in</strong>gGroup, preferred an agreement that <strong>of</strong>fended no one to no <strong>in</strong>strument at all.This claim, if true, does not impeach the motives <strong>of</strong> those who worked on the CISG or suggestthat unification projects <strong>of</strong> the type it represents necessarily harm the world economy. Rather, onecomes away with the sense that the Convention <strong>in</strong>flicts no great <strong>in</strong>juries, but also seems a somewhathollow accomplishment. Perhaps the process that produced it may serve as a model for serious <strong>and</strong>susta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong>ternational cooperation <strong>in</strong> other, more difficult areas, <strong>and</strong> perhaps those who took partcame away with <strong>in</strong>tellectual <strong>in</strong>sights that they then could employ to the benefit <strong>of</strong> local contract law.But it seems hard to shake <strong>of</strong>f a sense that the game hardly seems worth the c<strong>and</strong>le, at least if onewishes substantially to improve the legal environment for <strong>in</strong>ternational transactions. <strong>The</strong>re must bea better way <strong>of</strong> do<strong>in</strong>g this.27


284. <strong>International</strong> Bank Credits—UCPIn any <strong>in</strong>ternational sale where carriage <strong>of</strong> the goods will take some time, the buyer <strong>and</strong> seller facea dilemma with respect to payment. <strong>The</strong> buyer can pay <strong>in</strong> advance <strong>and</strong> risk never gett<strong>in</strong>g the goods;the seller can wait until the buyer receives the goods to obta<strong>in</strong> payment <strong>and</strong> risk never see<strong>in</strong>g themoney. Either party accept<strong>in</strong>g such a risk will seek a price adjustment, thereby detract<strong>in</strong>g from thevalue <strong>of</strong> the exchange. Parties that contract with each other on an ongo<strong>in</strong>g basis do not have as greata problem, but many <strong>in</strong>ternational sales <strong>in</strong>volves parties who deal with each others as strangers.An <strong>in</strong>stitution that ameliorates the dilemma is the letter <strong>of</strong> credit, which commits a third-partyissuer to make payment to the beneficiary (the seller) aga<strong>in</strong>st the account <strong>of</strong> the bank’s customer (thebuyer) upon the receipt <strong>of</strong> documents <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g that the seller has performed its obligations. <strong>The</strong>solution is not perfect. <strong>The</strong> documents (normally a bill <strong>of</strong> lad<strong>in</strong>g provided by the carrier) do notguarantee that the seller has fully performed. Nonetheless, the credit device goes a long way towardbridg<strong>in</strong>g the gap between the buyer’ <strong>and</strong> seller’s needs. While precise figures rema<strong>in</strong> unatta<strong>in</strong>able,observers have estimated that letters <strong>of</strong> credit figure <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational sales transactions worth $ __billion annually.Banks wish to m<strong>in</strong>imize the extent <strong>of</strong> their obligations under a credit <strong>and</strong> their liability formistakes made while perform<strong>in</strong>g such obligations as they have. Clear rules that set precise boundarieson their duties <strong>and</strong> liability suit their <strong>in</strong>terests. <strong>The</strong> customer <strong>and</strong> the beneficiary would prefer thatthe bank show some flexibility <strong>and</strong> that it assume responsibility for <strong>in</strong>juries caused by its negligence.As compared to banks, they probably prefer somewhat more open-ended contractual terms. <strong>The</strong>ythen could fall back on judicial outrage <strong>in</strong> cases where banks mish<strong>and</strong>le the transaction <strong>in</strong> a way thatcauses them serious <strong>in</strong>jury.National letter-<strong>of</strong>-credit law has tended to wobble a bit on these issues <strong>in</strong> spite <strong>of</strong> the considerablesay banks have had <strong>in</strong> draft<strong>in</strong>g the legislation on which credits rest. Some jurisdictions <strong>in</strong> the UnitedStates seem to have moved toward a regime that holds a bank liable for consequential <strong>in</strong>juries tocustomers <strong>in</strong> cases where they negligently perform their tasks, but this trend has not yet clearlymanifested itself <strong>in</strong> letter-<strong>of</strong>-credit law. At the <strong>in</strong>ternational level, not all countries have a substantialf<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>dustry, <strong>and</strong> those that do not may either lack rules clarify<strong>in</strong>g the parties’ rights <strong>and</strong> dutiesunder a credit or discrim<strong>in</strong>ate aga<strong>in</strong>st issuers.S<strong>in</strong>ce 1930, the <strong>International</strong> Chamber <strong>of</strong> Commerce has responded to these potential problems<strong>in</strong> domestic letter-<strong>of</strong>-credit law by issu<strong>in</strong>g the Uniform Customs <strong>and</strong> Practice for DocumentaryCredits. This publication provides a detailed description <strong>of</strong> the rights <strong>and</strong> duties <strong>of</strong> the issu<strong>in</strong>g bank,which credits may <strong>in</strong>corporate by reference. Because banks typically draft the credit documents, most<strong>in</strong>ternational letters stipulate that the UCP applies. National courts <strong>in</strong> turn tend to respect thesecontractual terms. New York, an <strong>in</strong>ternational f<strong>in</strong>ancial center where banks have particular <strong>in</strong>fluence,has gone so far as to authorize by statute the wholesale substitution <strong>of</strong> the UCP for the statutory rulesnormally applicable to letters <strong>of</strong> credit. 5757See N.Y. U.C.C. § 5-102(4).


<strong>The</strong> ICC committees responsible for draft<strong>in</strong>g the UCP have represented only one group <strong>in</strong>volved<strong>in</strong> letter-<strong>of</strong>-credit transactions, namely the banks. Until the latest revision, completed <strong>in</strong> 1993, thecommittee never had <strong>in</strong>corporated lawyers from outside the <strong>in</strong>dustry. Even <strong>in</strong> the latest iteration, the58additional participants <strong>in</strong>cluded only academics, not representatives <strong>of</strong> other <strong>in</strong>terest groups. Notsurpris<strong>in</strong>gly, the UCP seem largely to conta<strong>in</strong> precise rules that benefit banks. <strong>The</strong>y do not <strong>in</strong>vitejudicial <strong>in</strong>novation to compensate customers or beneficiaries <strong>in</strong>jured by careless or overly formalisticconduct on the part <strong>of</strong> banks.<strong>The</strong> provisions that favor banks fall <strong>in</strong>to two categories. <strong>The</strong> first provide sweep<strong>in</strong>g immunityfrom liabilities that national legal systems otherwise might impose. For example, Article 14(c) givesthe bank sole discretion as to whether to approach the customer to obta<strong>in</strong> a waiver <strong>of</strong> discrepancies59<strong>in</strong> documents presented on behalf <strong>of</strong> the beneficiary. Article 15 relieves banks <strong>of</strong> liability for the“form, sufficiency, accuracy, genu<strong>in</strong>eness, falsification or legal effect” <strong>of</strong> the documents acceptedaga<strong>in</strong>st payment, <strong>and</strong> for the bad faith, acts or omissions <strong>of</strong> “the consignors, the carriers, the60forwarders, the consignees or the <strong>in</strong>surers <strong>of</strong> the goods, or any other person whomsoever.” Article16 relieves the banks <strong>of</strong> responsibility for delays or mistransmission <strong>of</strong> any message, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g61telecommunications, <strong>and</strong> permits banks to transmit documents without translat<strong>in</strong>g them. AndArticle 17 absolves banks <strong>of</strong> responsibility for any untoward consequences aris<strong>in</strong>g from their use <strong>of</strong>other banks “for the purpose <strong>of</strong> giv<strong>in</strong>g effect to the <strong>in</strong>structions <strong>of</strong> the [customer].” 62Some <strong>of</strong> these waivers leave some issues for future decisionmakers to resolve. Does theexemption from liability apply to <strong>in</strong>tentional or know<strong>in</strong>g misconduct, or does the reasonable care63st<strong>and</strong>ard <strong>of</strong> Article 13(a) govern a bank’s conduct? In particular, does a bank that accepts adocument after receiv<strong>in</strong>g extr<strong>in</strong>sic <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g its fraudulent nature violate its duty underArticle 13(a), or may it rely on the same provision’s statement reliev<strong>in</strong>g it <strong>of</strong> any obligation to64exam<strong>in</strong>e anyth<strong>in</strong>g other than the documents stipulated <strong>in</strong> the credit? Under what circumstances isthe use <strong>of</strong> another bank “for the purpose <strong>of</strong> giv<strong>in</strong>g effect” to the customer’s <strong>in</strong>structions?But the drift is clear enough. Banks have the right to make payment aga<strong>in</strong>st documents or not,<strong>and</strong> bear little if any liability for the harmful consequences <strong>of</strong> mistaken acceptance or rejection. Tothe extent possible, the UCP tries to do away with bank liability for wrongful payment ornonpayment. What <strong>in</strong>determ<strong>in</strong>ancy rema<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong>volves only the extent <strong>of</strong> this ambition, not its directionor fundamental achievement.2958Ross P. Buckley, <strong>The</strong> 1993 Revision <strong>of</strong> the Uniform Customs <strong>and</strong> Practice for Documentary Credits, 28 GEO. WASH.J. INT’L L. & ECON. 265, 267 (1995).59UCP Art. 14(c).60Id. Art. 15.61Id. Art. 16.62Id. Art. 17.63See id. Art. 13(a): “Banks must exam<strong>in</strong>e all documents stipulated <strong>in</strong> the Credit with reasonable care . . . .”64See id.: “Documents not stipulated <strong>in</strong> the Credit will not be exam<strong>in</strong>ed by banks.” Can “documents” be read toembrace all extr<strong>in</strong>sic <strong>in</strong>formation?


30<strong>The</strong> second category <strong>of</strong> pro-bank provisions conta<strong>in</strong>s rules that set precise boundaries on what65the banks must do. <strong>The</strong> bank pays only aga<strong>in</strong>st the delivery <strong>of</strong> documents, <strong>and</strong> the customer may66not specify a nondocumentary condition. Presentation <strong>of</strong> the documents will trigger the bank’sobligation to pay only if made to that bank or its nom<strong>in</strong>ee, even if the issu<strong>in</strong>g bank acts as a67confirm<strong>in</strong>g bank for another issuer. Time limits for exam<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> the documents are fixed, rather68than left to an open-ended reasonableness st<strong>and</strong>ard. Each <strong>of</strong> these rules dim<strong>in</strong>ishes uncerta<strong>in</strong>tyabout the bank’s responsibility <strong>and</strong> provides clear guidance to bank employees.Identify<strong>in</strong>g pro-bank rules with<strong>in</strong> the UCP <strong>and</strong> not<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>fluence <strong>of</strong> banks over their draft<strong>in</strong>gdoes not establish that the UCP have the purpose or effect <strong>of</strong> ga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g economic rents for the banks.It may be that the UCP achieve an ideal allocation <strong>of</strong> risk <strong>and</strong> responsibility, <strong>and</strong> that burden<strong>in</strong>g bankswith additional obligations would dissipate the benefits <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry st<strong>and</strong>ardization by assign<strong>in</strong>gobligations to the party that generally cannot perform them most efficiently. But a basis forreasonable suspicion exists. Banks presumably engage <strong>in</strong> credit transactions more <strong>of</strong>ten than mostcustomers or beneficiaries, <strong>and</strong> this greater experience might enable them better to detect <strong>in</strong>dicators<strong>of</strong> faulty transactions. Impos<strong>in</strong>g a higher duty on banks to <strong>in</strong>quire <strong>in</strong>to the validity <strong>of</strong> documents,coupled with substantial liability for failure to honor this duty, might encourage banks to undertakea function that they might perform efficiently. At a m<strong>in</strong>imum, leav<strong>in</strong>g greater <strong>in</strong>determ<strong>in</strong>ancy <strong>in</strong> thelaw might give courts greater flexibility to respond to egregious cases <strong>of</strong> bank misbehavior.Of course, if banks really could produce welfare ga<strong>in</strong>s by polic<strong>in</strong>g credit documents morethoroughly, why don’t they do so <strong>and</strong> capture some <strong>of</strong> those ga<strong>in</strong>s as pr<strong>of</strong>it? Two arguments, eachsuggestive but not overwhelm<strong>in</strong>g persuasive, might expla<strong>in</strong> their lack <strong>of</strong> ambition. First, bankstraditionally have enjoyed a certa<strong>in</strong> amount <strong>of</strong> protection from competition, <strong>and</strong> bank executivesmight exploit this position to prefer more leisure <strong>and</strong> less risk. Second, the benefits derived fromst<strong>and</strong>ardization <strong>of</strong> contractual terms might be so great as to make departures costly even <strong>in</strong> thosecases where a modification might produce some welfare ga<strong>in</strong>s. It is at least plausible that leisureseek<strong>in</strong>gbank <strong>of</strong>ficials might have enough clout <strong>in</strong> the formulation <strong>of</strong> the UCP to impose theirpreferences on the group, <strong>and</strong> that the cost <strong>of</strong> depart<strong>in</strong>g from the UCP rema<strong>in</strong>s too great to justifypursuit <strong>of</strong> the benefits that defect<strong>in</strong>g banks might realize.All this is speculative. What seems clear enough is that the <strong>in</strong>ternational st<strong>and</strong>ard for bank-issueddocumentary credits seems to favor banks, that banks had the dom<strong>in</strong>ant role <strong>in</strong> draft<strong>in</strong>g the st<strong>and</strong>ard,<strong>and</strong> that the clear ga<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> legal certa<strong>in</strong>ty achieved by the st<strong>and</strong>ard come with unwanted baggage <strong>of</strong>potentially redistributive outcomes. As with the Warsaw Convention <strong>and</strong> the Hague Rules, we mustworry about the costs <strong>of</strong> legal risk reductions <strong>and</strong> the seem<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>evitability <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest group <strong>in</strong>fluenceover clear <strong>and</strong> specific <strong>in</strong>ternational rules.5. UNCITRAL Model Law on Cross-Border Insolvency65Here I draw on my prior analysis <strong>of</strong> the UCP. See Paul B. Stephan, note 15 supra, at 715-16.66Id. Art. 13(c).67Id. Art. 9(b).68To be precise, article 13(b) gives the issu<strong>in</strong>g bank “a reasonable time, not to exceed seven bank<strong>in</strong>g days follow<strong>in</strong>gthe receipt <strong>of</strong> the documents,” to reject nonconform<strong>in</strong>g documents.


31In the last six years UNCITRAL has adopted four model laws deal<strong>in</strong>g various aspects <strong>of</strong><strong>in</strong>ternational commercial relations. UNCITRAL does not <strong>in</strong>tend for these <strong>in</strong>struments to enterverbatim <strong>in</strong>to the law <strong>of</strong> adopt<strong>in</strong>g countries, as its conventions do. Rather, they serve as a list <strong>of</strong>69recommendations for domestic legislation, more <strong>of</strong> a wish list than a m<strong>and</strong>ate. This burst <strong>of</strong> activity,all occurr<strong>in</strong>g s<strong>in</strong>ce the end <strong>of</strong> the Cold War, deserves more general treatment. I will concentrate,however, on the most recent UNCITRAL proposal, the Model Law on Cross-Border Insolvency.<strong>The</strong> last decade has witnessed a number <strong>of</strong> spectacular <strong>in</strong>ternational bankruptcies, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g that<strong>of</strong> the Bank <strong>of</strong> Commerce <strong>and</strong> Credit <strong>International</strong>, the Maxwell publish<strong>in</strong>g empire, <strong>and</strong> the Reichmanfamily real estate bus<strong>in</strong>ess. Much dist<strong>in</strong>guishes these <strong>and</strong> other, less publicized <strong>in</strong>ternational bus<strong>in</strong>essfailures, but they do share several common elements. Each bus<strong>in</strong>ess had assets <strong>and</strong> creditors <strong>in</strong>multiple jurisdictions, <strong>and</strong> the proportions between assets <strong>and</strong> credits varied significantly amongjurisdictions. Some countries controlled significant assets, aga<strong>in</strong>st which its citizens possessedrelatively few claims, while other states had many creditors but few assets. In no case did a s<strong>in</strong>glecourt obta<strong>in</strong> control over the global resources <strong>of</strong> the debtor. While these cases have not all reachedtheir conclusion, it appears typical for one state to release assets to other jurisdictions only afterlook<strong>in</strong>g after the <strong>in</strong>terests <strong>of</strong> its resident creditors. As a result, creditors’ recoveries have variedsubstantially among jurisdictions.Over the last twenty years we have become used to look<strong>in</strong>g at bankruptcy rules primarily as exante barga<strong>in</strong>s that, the law assumes, debtors <strong>and</strong> creditors would want to negotiate <strong>in</strong> advance <strong>of</strong> anyf<strong>in</strong>ancial distress to maximize the value <strong>of</strong> their <strong>in</strong>vestments. Seen from this perspective, it seemsimplausible that an <strong>in</strong>ternational firm <strong>and</strong> its creditors would want a state-by-state, as opposed toglobal, determ<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> creditors’ rights. Allow<strong>in</strong>g the debtor to impair or enhance any creditor’srights simply by mov<strong>in</strong>g assets across borders creates <strong>in</strong>security. When deal<strong>in</strong>g with <strong>in</strong>ternationalbus<strong>in</strong>esses, creditors should respond to this problem by dem<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g either credible covenants or ahigher rate <strong>of</strong> return as compensation for absorb<strong>in</strong>g this risk. Debtors <strong>in</strong> turn should regret eitherhav<strong>in</strong>g to reduce their freedom <strong>of</strong> action, which might result <strong>in</strong> missed bus<strong>in</strong>ess opportunities, orpay<strong>in</strong>g more for capital.Ideally firms <strong>and</strong> their creditors might negotiate their way out <strong>of</strong> this dilemma by committ<strong>in</strong>gthemselves to a global bankruptcy regime, under which creditors could convene to claim aga<strong>in</strong>st thedebtor’s worldwide assets. But <strong>in</strong> a world <strong>of</strong> national bankruptcy systems, no one state has a reasonto defer to any other. We have, <strong>in</strong> other words, a classic collective action problem. Were states ableto commit themselves to some mechanism for coord<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g their approaches to <strong>in</strong>ternationalbankruptcy, we should expect substantial welfare ga<strong>in</strong>s. 7069Ct. United Nations Commission on <strong>International</strong> Trade Law, Guide to Enactment <strong>of</strong> the UNCITRAL Model Law onCross-Border Insolvency, A/CN.9/442, 12 (1997).70See Paul B. Stephan, Don Wallace Jr., & Julie A. Ro<strong>in</strong>, INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS—LAW ANDPOLICY 369-83 (2d Ed. 1996). For a recent paper develop<strong>in</strong>g this po<strong>in</strong>t at greater length, see Lucian Arye Bebchuck & AndrewT. Guzman, An Economic Analysis <strong>of</strong> Transnational Bankruptcies (Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper July 1998).


32Does the UNCITRAL Model Law realize this potential by creat<strong>in</strong>g a credible mechanism forenforc<strong>in</strong>g bankruptcy regimes on a global basis? One comes away from the legislation more with asense <strong>of</strong> missed opportunities <strong>and</strong> frustration. <strong>The</strong> statute largely exp<strong>and</strong>s the range <strong>of</strong> action <strong>of</strong>bankruptcy courts without impos<strong>in</strong>g substantial obligations that those bodies must honor. <strong>The</strong> resultis a regime that, if implemented, would decrease the predictability <strong>of</strong> outcomes <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternationalbankruptcies without achiev<strong>in</strong>g any clear improvements <strong>in</strong> the legal regime.At the heart <strong>of</strong> the Model Law is a procedure that, <strong>in</strong> theory, allows one jurisdiction to takecontrol over a debtor’s global assets <strong>and</strong> obligations. <strong>The</strong> Model Law attaches legal significance tothe place where an <strong>in</strong>solvent bus<strong>in</strong>ess has “the center <strong>of</strong> its ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>terests” (a term taken from the EU71Convention on Insolvency Proceed<strong>in</strong>gs) or an “establishment.” In either case, the Law requires astate to “recognize” an <strong>in</strong>solvency proceed<strong>in</strong>g under way <strong>in</strong> either place absent the applicability <strong>of</strong> a72narrow public policy exception. Upon recogniz<strong>in</strong>g such a proceed<strong>in</strong>g, a court normally must stayall local claims aga<strong>in</strong>st the debtor’s assets <strong>and</strong> suspend the debtor’s right to dispose <strong>of</strong> its property. 73But at this po<strong>in</strong>t the m<strong>and</strong>atory obligations <strong>of</strong> the local proceed<strong>in</strong>g end, <strong>and</strong> discretion takes over.<strong>The</strong> local court may transfer assets to the foreign jurisdiction or give effect to determ<strong>in</strong>ations made74by that tribunal, but it does not have to do either. In particular, the local court reta<strong>in</strong>s full discretionto determ<strong>in</strong>e the priority <strong>of</strong> local claims aga<strong>in</strong>st local assets, <strong>and</strong>, where national law permits, todiscrim<strong>in</strong>ate aga<strong>in</strong>st foreign claimants. 75Were a substantial number <strong>of</strong> states to enact the Model Law, creditors would face greateruncerta<strong>in</strong>ty about their rights <strong>in</strong> a bankruptcy proceed<strong>in</strong>g than they currently do. Under the statusquo, creditors underst<strong>and</strong> that their eventual pay<strong>of</strong>f turns to a large extent on where assets happento end up when a debtor becomes <strong>in</strong>solvent. Through covenants, they can protect themselves tosome extent aga<strong>in</strong>st cross-border transfers that might impair their claims. But under the Model Law,location <strong>of</strong> the assets no longer has the same clear significance. Local courts might still favor localclaimants, but they also rema<strong>in</strong> free to defer to foreign tribunals. No precise st<strong>and</strong>ards govern whichchoice they must make. Rather than solv<strong>in</strong>g the coord<strong>in</strong>ation problem that exists under current law,the Model Law makes it worse.If the Model Law regime has the potential to <strong>in</strong>crease, rather than lower, the cost <strong>of</strong> capital t<strong>of</strong>irms operat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>ternationally, why has UNCITRAL advanced this legislation? <strong>The</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficialcommentary notes that bankruptcy practitioners, both <strong>in</strong> the private bar <strong>and</strong> the judiciary, had animportant role <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g the Law, both dur<strong>in</strong>g the draft<strong>in</strong>g process <strong>and</strong> through an <strong>in</strong>ternational76meet<strong>in</strong>g held to review the Work<strong>in</strong>g Group’s draft. <strong>The</strong> expansion <strong>of</strong> discretionary authority <strong>of</strong>bankruptcy tribunals doubtlessly appealed to this group. Judges would have more power, therebyenhanc<strong>in</strong>g the prestige <strong>and</strong> satisfaction <strong>of</strong> their work. Lawyers who specialized <strong>in</strong> the field couldcharge more for their skills as a result <strong>of</strong> the more challeng<strong>in</strong>g legal environment.717273747576UNCITRAL Model Law on Cross-Border Insolvency, A/52/17/Annex 1, Arts. 2(b), 2(c).Id. Arts. 6, 17.Id. Art. 20.Id. Arts. 19, 21.Id. Art. 13(2).United Nations Commission on <strong>International</strong> Trade Law, note 69 supra, at 4-7.


I do not mean to suggest anyth<strong>in</strong>g so s<strong>in</strong>ister as naked self-aggr<strong>and</strong>izement by an <strong>in</strong>terest group.Rather, we underst<strong>and</strong>ably should expect skilled pr<strong>of</strong>essionals to value their talents <strong>and</strong> to believe <strong>in</strong>good faith that the world would be a better place if society relied on them even more. <strong>The</strong> ModelLaw seems to reflect this conviction, unchecked by the concerns <strong>of</strong> those who might have to pick upthe tab for their work.Of course, enhanc<strong>in</strong>g the position <strong>of</strong> bankruptcy pr<strong>of</strong>essionals might push this group <strong>in</strong>to theposition <strong>of</strong> an <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>termediary. As they <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> their reputations through repeated deal<strong>in</strong>gswith one another, the bankruptcy lawyers might develop unstated but clearly understood norms fordivid<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>ternational bankrupt’s estate that could function as effectively as a transparent <strong>and</strong>precise set <strong>of</strong> legislatively m<strong>and</strong>ated rules. <strong>The</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>essionals might have persuaded the drafters togive them greater discretion not to <strong>in</strong>crease their <strong>in</strong>comes, but rather because a middleman groupmight provide a better solution to the coord<strong>in</strong>ation problems <strong>in</strong>herent <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational bankruptcy thanwould an explicitly global system <strong>of</strong> adm<strong>in</strong>ister<strong>in</strong>g bankrupt estates.<strong>The</strong> problem is that noth<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the model law rewards bankruptcy pr<strong>of</strong>essionals specifically forfacilitat<strong>in</strong>g successful global settlements. <strong>The</strong> broad discretionary powers enjoyed by nationaltribunals might work either to promote <strong>in</strong>ternational cooperation or to tear away at local assets forthe benefit <strong>of</strong> local creditors. Most successful middleman systems, by contrast, reward the<strong>in</strong>termediary for promot<strong>in</strong>g welfare-enhanc<strong>in</strong>g outcomes. <strong>The</strong> Model Law does not do this.33III. ALTERNATIVES TO THE UNIFICATION PROJECT: CONTRACT AND COMPETITION<strong>The</strong> project <strong>of</strong> unify<strong>in</strong>g substantive <strong>in</strong>ternational commercial law necessarily depends on atechnocratic legal process. I have raised at least a reasonable suspicion that this process has its ownpolitical economy with predictable <strong>and</strong> unattractive implications for what it produces. <strong>International</strong>unification <strong>in</strong>struments display a strong tendency either to compromise legal certa<strong>in</strong>ty or to advancethe agendas <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest groups. In either case they <strong>of</strong>fer no obvious welfare ga<strong>in</strong>s as compared torules produced through the national legislative process. In particular, we have no reason to expectthese <strong>in</strong>struments to achieve substantial improvements <strong>in</strong> the law, if we may disregard what the<strong>in</strong>terest groups get out <strong>of</strong> their adoption. Nor can we detect evidence that these <strong>in</strong>struments bolstercadres <strong>of</strong> middlemen whose <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> reputation, group coherence <strong>and</strong> discipl<strong>in</strong>e will substitutefor clear <strong>and</strong> desirable legal rules. And what reduction <strong>of</strong> legal risk the <strong>in</strong>struments achieve comesmostly, if not entirely, through conced<strong>in</strong>g the field to specific <strong>in</strong>terest groups, whether carriers,bankers, or other cohesive m<strong>in</strong>orities.In addition, my critique <strong>of</strong> technocratic lawmak<strong>in</strong>g necessarily implies that we cannot correctthese tendencies by redirect<strong>in</strong>g the focus <strong>of</strong> the unification project. If the draft<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> substantive lawsresults <strong>in</strong> either compromised <strong>and</strong> largely empty content or clear-cut victories for special <strong>in</strong>terests,we should not expect <strong>in</strong>ternational efforts aimed at reform<strong>in</strong>g adjectival law—e.g., a harmonizedsystem <strong>of</strong> choice <strong>of</strong> law—to do any better. <strong>The</strong> problems we have observed reflect the nature <strong>of</strong> theprocess itself, not its agenda. No matter what the task <strong>of</strong> technocratic reformers, we must expect<strong>in</strong>terest groups to have the capacity either to thwart rules that they f<strong>in</strong>d threaten<strong>in</strong>g or to capture theprocess for their own purposes.


34If technocratic law reform does not work especially well, does it follow that we should not tryto improve <strong>in</strong>ternational commercial law? I th<strong>in</strong>k not. Developments <strong>in</strong> U.S. law (<strong>and</strong> perhaps <strong>in</strong>other jurisdictions about which I know less) po<strong>in</strong>t toward another path, one that largely bypasses<strong>in</strong>ternational bodies, the pr<strong>of</strong>essariat <strong>and</strong> legislatures. Increas<strong>in</strong>gly, U.S. law has allowed nationallegal systems to compete among themselves as to the terms they will <strong>of</strong>fer commercial actors, <strong>and</strong>bus<strong>in</strong>ess people to choose among the competitors. Those concerned with improv<strong>in</strong>g the law t<strong>of</strong>acilitate <strong>in</strong>ternational commercial transactions should applaud this tendency <strong>and</strong> seek ways to extendit. 77 Imag<strong>in</strong>e a world where persons engaged <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational commerce had virtually unlimited powerto choose by agreement which law would apply to disputes aris<strong>in</strong>g out <strong>of</strong> their relationship, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>gclaims based on tort as well as contract <strong>and</strong> property law. Individual nations would rema<strong>in</strong> free todevelop their substantive law, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the adoption <strong>of</strong> rules that advance the redistributive goals <strong>of</strong>particular groups, but would have limited authority to prevent persons subject to their jurisdictionfrom contract<strong>in</strong>g out <strong>of</strong> such rules. States thus could compete for legal bus<strong>in</strong>ess on the basis <strong>of</strong> theattractiveness <strong>of</strong> their rules <strong>and</strong> dispute resolution procedures, rather than coerce their subjects t<strong>of</strong>ollow any one system <strong>of</strong> commercial law.Four Supreme Court cases decided <strong>in</strong> the last few decades, echoed <strong>and</strong> extended by a number <strong>of</strong>lower court decisions, have taken the United States toward such a system. <strong>The</strong> first, <strong>The</strong> Bremen v.78Zapata Off-Shore Co., enforced a provision <strong>in</strong> a tow<strong>in</strong>g contract between a German carrier <strong>and</strong> aU.S. towee that required all disputes to be heard before an English court. <strong>The</strong> contract conta<strong>in</strong>ed aclause exculpat<strong>in</strong>g the carrier for damages to the towed object, which English courts would enforce<strong>and</strong> U.S. courts would not. <strong>The</strong> Court refused to hold that the forum clause violated U.S. publicpolicy even thought it amounted to a choice <strong>of</strong> materially different liability law. A decade later79Mitsubishi Motors v. Soler Chrysler-Plymouth held that a clause requir<strong>in</strong>g a U.S. car dealer toarbitrate <strong>in</strong> Japan all its disputes with a Japanese manufacturer applied to antitrust claims brought80under federal law, <strong>and</strong> as such was enforceable. In Carnival Cruise L<strong>in</strong>es, Inc. v. Shute, the Courtenforced a choice-<strong>of</strong>-forum clause found <strong>in</strong> a small-type form contract appended to a cruise ticket.It rejected the passenger’s argument that the absence <strong>of</strong> any opportunity to barga<strong>in</strong> over thisprovision rendered the clause unenforceable. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>in</strong> Vimar Seguos y Reaseguros, S.A. v. M/V Sky81Reefer, the Court ruled that an agreement to arbitrate <strong>in</strong> Japan a carrier’s liability for damage tocargo did not violate Article III(8) <strong>of</strong> the Hague Rules by dilut<strong>in</strong>g the carrier’s m<strong>and</strong>atory obligations77Several <strong>of</strong> the papers <strong>in</strong> this symposium, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> particular that <strong>of</strong> Andrew Guzman, seem to po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> this direction.See Andrew T. Guzman, Develop<strong>in</strong>g Capital Markets <strong>in</strong> a Global Economy—Choice <strong>of</strong> Law <strong>and</strong> Arbitration <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>gCountry F<strong>in</strong>ancial Markets, __ VA. J. INT’L L. ___ (1999). See also Arthur Rosett, <strong>Unification</strong>, <strong>Harmonization</strong>, Restatement,Codification, <strong>and</strong> Reform <strong>in</strong> <strong>International</strong> Commercial Law, 40 AM. J. COMP. L. 683 (1992). For similar approaches takenby Commonwealth scholars, who confront a somewhat more <strong>in</strong>tractable judiciary, see Michael J. Wh<strong>in</strong>cop & Mary E. Keyes,Statutes’ Doma<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> Private <strong>International</strong> Law: An Economic <strong>The</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> the Limits <strong>of</strong> M<strong>and</strong>atory Rules, 20 SYDNEY L. REV.435 (1998); Putt<strong>in</strong>g the ‘Private’ Back <strong>in</strong>to Private <strong>International</strong> Law: Default Rules <strong>and</strong> the Proper Law <strong>of</strong> the Contract,21 MELBOURNE U.L. REV. 515 (1997).78407 U.S. 1 (1972).79473 U.S. 614 (1985).80499 U.S. 595 (1991).81515 U.S.528 (1995).


to the shipper. Each case <strong>in</strong>volved an <strong>in</strong>ternational commercial transaction, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> each the Courtupheld contractual forum clauses that had either a direct or <strong>in</strong>direct effect on the underly<strong>in</strong>gsubstantive law.Of course, none <strong>of</strong> the Supreme Court cases held that parties had an unqualified right to contract82out <strong>of</strong> m<strong>and</strong>atory statutory rules. <strong>The</strong> Bremen noted that the British law, although different fromthat <strong>of</strong> the United States, did not violate U.S. public policy. Mitsubishi Motors emphasized thedifference between enforc<strong>in</strong>g an agreement to arbitrate <strong>and</strong> enforc<strong>in</strong>g an arbitral award, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>dicated<strong>in</strong> dicta that an arbiter’s failure adequately to address the antitrust claims would render its award anullity <strong>in</strong> the United States. Carnival Cruise L<strong>in</strong>es held that the law <strong>of</strong> Florida, the forum chosen <strong>in</strong>the form contract, did not oppress passengers. Vimar left open the possibility that the Japanesearbitral award would not be enforced if the arbiter applied substantive law that differed substantiallyfrom the requirements <strong>of</strong> the Carriage <strong>of</strong> Goods at Sea Act. In every case the Court <strong>in</strong>voked its rightto reta<strong>in</strong> control over the substantive law that would result from enforc<strong>in</strong>g the contractual choice <strong>of</strong>forum. But the Court also <strong>in</strong>dicated that the foreign law need not serve as a perfect substitute forU.S. rules, <strong>and</strong> it upheld the pr<strong>in</strong>ciple <strong>of</strong> freedom <strong>of</strong> contract even when a transaction <strong>in</strong>volved aconsumer <strong>and</strong> a small-pr<strong>in</strong>t st<strong>and</strong>ard form. <strong>The</strong> tendency to prefer contractual choices over regulatorynorms exists, even if it has not blossomed <strong>in</strong>to an unequivocal commitment.What we have seen is a fundamental shift <strong>in</strong> the terms <strong>of</strong> debate over homemade law <strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>ternational commercial relations. Before <strong>The</strong> Bremen, the relevant question is whether persons<strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational commerce had any right to choose which legal system would govern theirrelations. After Vimar, the issue has become what limits rema<strong>in</strong> on the exercise <strong>of</strong> this right. A world<strong>of</strong> possibilities has opened, even though its boundaries rema<strong>in</strong> undeterm<strong>in</strong>ed.Analogical strategies <strong>in</strong> related areas <strong>of</strong> commercial law exist. As many observers have noted,U.S. corporate law allows states to compete over the terms under which corporations will be allowedto govern themselves. This competition exists only because <strong>in</strong> the United States, unlike Europe, aconsensus accepts that the law <strong>of</strong> the state <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>corporation, a voluntary contractual choice, willgovern most issues aris<strong>in</strong>g out <strong>of</strong> a firm’s <strong>in</strong>ternal decisionmak<strong>in</strong>g. Academics have argued fordecades whether this competition is virtuous or malign, but the best recent evidence supports theproposition that corporate managers decide where to <strong>in</strong>corporate largely on the basis <strong>of</strong> whichjurisdiction’s laws are most likely to maximize the firm’s value. 83Could a similar approach <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational commercial law produce a virtuous race to the top? Icannot <strong>of</strong>fer a def<strong>in</strong>itive response. Too much depends on debatable assumptions about the politicaleconomy <strong>of</strong> the many branches <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational commerce. We simply do not know enough about3582Lower courts have enforced contracts for the sale <strong>of</strong> securities that have the effect <strong>of</strong> replac<strong>in</strong>g U.S. securitiesrdthregulation with the comparable laws <strong>of</strong> the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom. See, e.g., Richards v. Lloyd’s <strong>of</strong> London, 135 F.3 1289 (9 Cir.rd th rd th1998); Haynsworth v. <strong>The</strong> Corporation, 121 F.3 956 (5 Cir. 1997); Allen v. Lloyd’s <strong>of</strong> London, 94 F.3 923 (4 Cir. 1996);rd th rd thShell v. R.W. Sturge, Ltd., 55 F.3 1227 (6 Cir. 1995); Bonny v. Society <strong>of</strong> Lloyd’s, 3 F.3 156 (7 Cir. 1993), cert. denied,ndnd510 U.S. 111 (1994); Roby v. Corporation <strong>of</strong> Lloyd’s, 996 F.2 1353 (2 Cir.), cert. denied, 510 U.S. 945 (1993); Riley v.ndK<strong>in</strong>gsley Underwrit<strong>in</strong>g Agencies, Ltd., 969 F.2 953 (10th Cir.), cert. denied, 506 U.S. 1021 (1992).83For a review <strong>of</strong> the literature, see Roberta Romano, FOUNDATIONS OF CORPORATE LAW 87-99 (1993).


36how particular legal rules operate <strong>in</strong> different bus<strong>in</strong>ess environments to make any claims withconfidence. I do contend, however, that the experiment seems worth pursu<strong>in</strong>g a bit further. <strong>The</strong>arguments for do<strong>in</strong>g so fall <strong>in</strong>to several categories.Legal Certa<strong>in</strong>ty <strong>and</strong> the Volume <strong>of</strong> Law. I began this paper by posit<strong>in</strong>g that commercial actors,given the opportunity to do so at a reasonable cost, will pursue legal risk reduction up to some level<strong>of</strong> acceptable risk. All other th<strong>in</strong>gs be<strong>in</strong>g equal, one <strong>of</strong> the best strategies for reduc<strong>in</strong>g legal risk isto work with<strong>in</strong> a fully developed legal system with a long history <strong>of</strong> fairly consistent <strong>and</strong> elaboratedispute resolution rest<strong>in</strong>g on reasonably stable pr<strong>in</strong>ciples <strong>of</strong> jurisprudence. In commercial law, thismeans specify<strong>in</strong>g a particular national system, such as English law, New York law, or the Swiss CivilCode. 84I do not mean to argue that more law necessarily is better law, or that one can expect fundamentalcoherence <strong>and</strong> consistency <strong>in</strong> any legal system. Rather, I believe that the tendency <strong>of</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>esscontractors to gravitate toward particular jurisdictions, when given the freedom to do so—Delaware<strong>in</strong> the case <strong>of</strong> corporate charters, New York or Engl<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> the case <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>and</strong>commercial transactions—to some extent reflects a reasonable belief <strong>in</strong>, <strong>and</strong> preference for, therelative density <strong>and</strong> stability <strong>of</strong> their legal systems. It is possible to characterize national legal systemsas more or less developed, <strong>and</strong> at least some bus<strong>in</strong>esses seem to prefer developed systems to those<strong>of</strong> their home base.Density <strong>and</strong> stability <strong>in</strong> law cannot be manufactured overnight. Publish<strong>in</strong>g rules <strong>in</strong> a statute is notenough. <strong>The</strong> persons to whom the rules will apply need to know how they work <strong>in</strong> practice, howdecisionmakers fill <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>evitable gaps <strong>and</strong> react to particular fact patterns. <strong>The</strong>y can acquire this<strong>in</strong>formation only by observ<strong>in</strong>g the system over time on the basis <strong>of</strong> many iterations <strong>of</strong> the disputeresolution process. National legal systems all have to vary<strong>in</strong>g degrees histories <strong>and</strong> traditions that canbe cultivated <strong>and</strong> enhanced. Any new <strong>in</strong>ternationally unified system, whether <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g a fewjurisdictions or many, must <strong>in</strong>volve a break with the past, <strong>and</strong> thus sacrifices density <strong>and</strong> stability.Thus national systems seem the best venues for the pursuit <strong>of</strong> legal risk reduction.Laboratory Effects. <strong>The</strong> prior argument rested on the pr<strong>of</strong>oundly conservative assumption that,all th<strong>in</strong>gs be<strong>in</strong>g equal, bus<strong>in</strong>ess people fear change <strong>and</strong> prefer predictable legal rules. It seems equallyplausible, however, that some commercial actors would want an opportunity to <strong>in</strong>novate <strong>in</strong> their legalrelationships. <strong>The</strong> question then becomes whether it is easier to adopt <strong>in</strong>novative rules throughestablish<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>ternational consensus, or <strong>in</strong>stead by permitt<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dividual nations to enact such rules<strong>and</strong> then enabl<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess actors to select them to govern their relations.<strong>The</strong> case for national rather than <strong>in</strong>ternational experimentation seems unassailable. <strong>The</strong> variety<strong>of</strong> nation states means that many experiments may proceed at once, while any <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>novationrequires the exclusion <strong>of</strong> all other alternatives. It also seems likely that enlist<strong>in</strong>g a s<strong>in</strong>gle country <strong>in</strong>the implementation <strong>of</strong> a novel legal rule would be much easier than establish<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>ternational84For fuller discussion <strong>of</strong> the problem <strong>of</strong> novelty <strong>in</strong> commercial law terms, see Steven Walt, Novelty <strong>and</strong> the Risks <strong>of</strong>Uniform Sales Law, __ VA. J. INT’ L. __ (1999).


consensus. Conf<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g an experiment to one jurisdiction reduces the costs if the idea turns out tocause unanticipated harm, although concededly it also reduces the value <strong>of</strong> the experiment by limit<strong>in</strong>gthe generality <strong>of</strong> its results.Avoidance <strong>of</strong> Rentseek<strong>in</strong>g. An essential element <strong>of</strong> the critique <strong>of</strong> technocratic lawmak<strong>in</strong>g at the<strong>in</strong>ternational level rests on the premise that <strong>in</strong>terest groups can <strong>in</strong>fluence the process both to defeatrules that they f<strong>in</strong>d threaten<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> to foist on the lawmakers rules that distribute wealth <strong>in</strong> theirfavor. <strong>The</strong>se concerns about <strong>in</strong>ternational lawmak<strong>in</strong>g seem plausible precisely because a substantialbody <strong>of</strong> evidence suggest that such rentseek<strong>in</strong>g takes place with some frequency at the national level.We anticipate <strong>in</strong>ternational special-<strong>in</strong>terest outcomes because we know that national lawmak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong>tenveers <strong>in</strong> this direction.But if some states enact laws that benefit <strong>in</strong>terest groups to the cost <strong>of</strong> those who must deal withthem, we might consider ways <strong>of</strong> facilitat<strong>in</strong>g exit from such traps. Here freedom <strong>of</strong> contract might<strong>of</strong>fer a way out. A bus<strong>in</strong>ess would not have to abide by special-<strong>in</strong>terest legislation simply becauseit happened to operate <strong>in</strong> a jurisdiction where some group had prevailed on the legislature. Instead,it could <strong>in</strong>sist on us<strong>in</strong>g another, more neutral set <strong>of</strong> rules as a condition <strong>of</strong> its contracts.This argument suffers from at least one serious <strong>in</strong>consistency. If <strong>in</strong>terest groups have enoughpower to shape national legislation towards their ends, why would the submit to contracts that snatchaway these ga<strong>in</strong>s? Or even worse, why wouldn’t powerful groups abuse their contractual freedomto foist these special-<strong>in</strong>terest laws on parties located <strong>in</strong> other jurisdictions?<strong>The</strong> plausibility <strong>of</strong> these concerns turns on two issues. First, local <strong>in</strong>fluence over a legislature mayor may not translate <strong>in</strong>to superior barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g power. We already have detected areas where differentgroups with adverse <strong>in</strong>terests have relatively greater <strong>in</strong>fluence <strong>in</strong> different countries, e.g., shippers <strong>in</strong>Austria <strong>and</strong> Chile, mar<strong>in</strong>e carriers <strong>in</strong> Belgium <strong>and</strong> the United States. This pattern suggests theexistence <strong>of</strong> at least some <strong>in</strong>stances where parties may contract out <strong>of</strong>, rather than <strong>in</strong>to, one-sidednational legal regimes. How frequently such opportunities will arise, <strong>and</strong> how <strong>of</strong>ten dom<strong>in</strong>ant firms<strong>in</strong>stead will use their contractual power to impose their own legal preferences becomes a matter forempirical research.Second, one must confront the <strong>in</strong>evitable question <strong>of</strong> why persons with superior barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g powerwould employ this advantage to obta<strong>in</strong> friendly legal rules <strong>in</strong>stead <strong>of</strong> better price terms. Absent<strong>in</strong>formation asymmetries between the parties (as might be the case if one party engaged <strong>in</strong> many<strong>in</strong>ternational transactions <strong>and</strong> the other <strong>in</strong> few), we should expect barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g power to translate first<strong>of</strong> all <strong>in</strong>to a better money return on the deal. Aga<strong>in</strong> the question reduces to an empirical issue: how<strong>of</strong>ten do <strong>in</strong>ternational commercial transactions <strong>in</strong>volve one party with great barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g power <strong>and</strong>experience <strong>and</strong> another with little power <strong>and</strong> experience?Taken together, these reservations suggest grounds on which local law might base limitations onthe power to contract <strong>in</strong>to different legal systems. We might want to preserve, for example, somepublic policy exception to enforc<strong>in</strong>g contractual choices <strong>of</strong> forum or law, even though the existence37


38<strong>of</strong> such arguments <strong>in</strong>troduces an element <strong>of</strong> legal risk. But they do not provide a rationale for anabsolute prohibition on free choices <strong>of</strong> law.More to the po<strong>in</strong>t, these reservations <strong>in</strong>directly support my critique <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational lawmak<strong>in</strong>g.If certa<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest groups have enough <strong>in</strong>fluence not only to capture national law but to force theirbus<strong>in</strong>ess partners to submit to the law they have shaped, surely they can dom<strong>in</strong>ate any <strong>in</strong>ternationalprocess. And we should regard an <strong>in</strong>ternational st<strong>and</strong>ard that serves the redistributive ends <strong>of</strong> an<strong>in</strong>terest group as the worst possible outcome, because it makes evasion <strong>of</strong> rentseek<strong>in</strong>g even moredifficult.Exp<strong>and</strong>ed Choice. One <strong>of</strong> the bedrock assumptions <strong>of</strong> contract law has been that, all other th<strong>in</strong>gsbe<strong>in</strong>g equal, giv<strong>in</strong>g parties as many legal possibilities as possible <strong>in</strong>creases the likelihood that peoplewill construct relationships that best suit their needs. This tenet coexists with the belief that, with<strong>in</strong>reason, people also benefit from committ<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> advance to restrictions on their freedom <strong>of</strong> action.A core conviction that unites these two propositions is that bus<strong>in</strong>ess people, if not burdened by anydisability or victimized by fraud, largely can make effective choices about the scope, strength <strong>and</strong>content <strong>of</strong> the legal obligations they need to assume to pursue their objectives. And allow<strong>in</strong>g themto make these choices <strong>in</strong> turn provides society as a whole with more <strong>and</strong> better <strong>in</strong>formation abouttheir preferences <strong>and</strong> how to implement them.Few would argue today that limitless expansion <strong>of</strong> contractual choices necessarily benefitscontractors. Some desirable solutions to collective action problems result <strong>in</strong> coercive rules, <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>any event people <strong>in</strong> the real world operate under a wide range <strong>of</strong> disabilities <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation deficits.We also recognize a large number <strong>of</strong> contractual choices that generate negative externalities, suchas commitments to form cartels or to pollute the environment. Only unreconstructed libertarianswould reject the need to restrict freedom to contract <strong>in</strong> these <strong>in</strong>stances.But none <strong>of</strong> these reasons for limit<strong>in</strong>g contractual choices undercuts the fundamental po<strong>in</strong>t. <strong>The</strong>arguments <strong>in</strong> favor <strong>of</strong> exp<strong>and</strong>ed freedom <strong>of</strong> contract seem sufficiently appeal<strong>in</strong>g, at least <strong>in</strong> thecommercial world, to justify a presumption <strong>in</strong> its favor, with the burden <strong>of</strong> justification rest<strong>in</strong>g onthose who would restra<strong>in</strong> it. Allow<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess people to elect <strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> out <strong>of</strong> national commercial lawsystems follows from this general proposition. <strong>The</strong> issue then becomes what specific objections mightone raise to these particular choices.<strong>The</strong> most obvious category <strong>of</strong> arguments aga<strong>in</strong>st exp<strong>and</strong>ed choice rests on fears about races tothe bottom. Jurisdiction might compete for bus<strong>in</strong>esses not by <strong>of</strong>fer<strong>in</strong>g them legal rules that generallyadd value, but rather by tolerat<strong>in</strong>g arrangements that generate negative externalities. A country mightallow itself to become a haven for cartels, con artists, or polluters, <strong>in</strong> part by allow<strong>in</strong>g firms engaged<strong>in</strong> these practices to contract out <strong>of</strong> liability for the harms they produce. States might be especiallyprone to compete <strong>in</strong> this fashion if others outside <strong>of</strong> their jurisdiction were to bear the brunt <strong>of</strong> theharms. If we augment this story with fears about powerful firms impos<strong>in</strong>g contracts <strong>of</strong> adhesion onhelpless consumers, the problem becomes even greater. Predators will force those with whom theycontract to accept national legal regimes that conta<strong>in</strong> malignant rules.


We should take these stories seriously, but also underst<strong>and</strong> what they do <strong>and</strong> do not <strong>in</strong>dicateabout unification <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational commercial law. A race to the bottom requires the existence <strong>of</strong><strong>in</strong>terest groups sufficiently <strong>in</strong>fluential to bend national laws toward their own ends. Unless groupscan reward states who enact attractive laws, no country has any particular reason to enter <strong>in</strong>to thecompetition. Yet our review <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>ternational lawmak<strong>in</strong>g process suggests that at least some<strong>in</strong>terest groups have succeeded <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>fluenc<strong>in</strong>g the content <strong>of</strong> unification <strong>in</strong>struments. <strong>The</strong>re is noparticular reason to believe that groups capable <strong>of</strong> triumph<strong>in</strong>g at the national level necessarily wouldfare worse <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>ternational arena.In sum, arguments aga<strong>in</strong>st exp<strong>and</strong>ed contractual choice do not po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> the direction <strong>of</strong>constra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>esses by impos<strong>in</strong>g a s<strong>in</strong>gle <strong>in</strong>ternational regime. Rather, if we worry about <strong>in</strong>terestgroups captur<strong>in</strong>g national law for their own purposes, we ought to recognize the power <strong>of</strong> otherstates to forbid persons subject to their jurisdiction from contract<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to those laws. To guardaga<strong>in</strong>st bad laws, <strong>in</strong> other words, we still should want a system with pluralism at the national level,albeit with less than complete freedom on the part <strong>of</strong> private parties to pick <strong>and</strong> choose amongnational laws.39IV. CONCLUSION<strong>The</strong> unification project <strong>of</strong> the past century has served as a useful means for promot<strong>in</strong>g comparativeresearch <strong>and</strong> scholarship <strong>and</strong> deepened our underst<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>gs <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>stitutions <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternationalcommerce. Whether the project has also produced laws that improve on what existed before rema<strong>in</strong>sless clear. Confusion <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>tellectual merits <strong>of</strong> the exercise <strong>and</strong> its practical implications may havedistracted us from confront<strong>in</strong>g this question.In formulat<strong>in</strong>g a critique <strong>of</strong> the unification project, I have had several goals. First, I have triedto show how arguments drawn from the field <strong>of</strong> political economy can illum<strong>in</strong>ate important issues <strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>ternational law. Second, I have tried to shift the focus <strong>of</strong> private <strong>in</strong>ternational law scholarship fromsubstantive law to the lawmak<strong>in</strong>g process. Third, I have tried to ruffle the complacency <strong>of</strong> thescholarly community, which too <strong>of</strong>ten confuses the beautiful with the good <strong>and</strong> its own best <strong>in</strong>tentionswith society’s best <strong>in</strong>terests.In us<strong>in</strong>g arguments drawn from political economy to address <strong>in</strong>ternational law questions, I do notclaim to have broken any new ground either <strong>in</strong> the development <strong>of</strong> legal theory or <strong>in</strong> the analysis <strong>of</strong><strong>in</strong>ternational law. Others have done the basic work <strong>in</strong> propos<strong>in</strong>g a model for private legislatures.And while <strong>in</strong>ternational law scholarship rema<strong>in</strong>s beh<strong>in</strong>d other fields <strong>in</strong> its will<strong>in</strong>gness to <strong>in</strong>corporatethe methodologies <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>sights <strong>of</strong> the law-<strong>and</strong>-economics movement, <strong>in</strong> the last five years it hasbegun to catch up. What I have sought to do here is susta<strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> support that tendency <strong>in</strong> the onlyway I know how, which is to demonstrate how the application <strong>of</strong> theory to concrete problems makesboth the theory <strong>and</strong> the problems more <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g.My emphasis on the lawmak<strong>in</strong>g process <strong>in</strong> turn reflects a desire to move <strong>in</strong>ternational law towarda range <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>quiry that has taken center stage <strong>in</strong> other discipl<strong>in</strong>es, especially U.S. constitutional law.Who decides <strong>and</strong> what gets decided are related but separate issues. Our colleagues <strong>in</strong> these fields


40have proven that one can learn a lot by isolat<strong>in</strong>g the lawmak<strong>in</strong>g process <strong>and</strong> then look<strong>in</strong>g at its effecton what gets produced. Those <strong>of</strong> us who work on <strong>in</strong>ternational law problems need to follow theirlead.F<strong>in</strong>ally, my desire to disrupt our complacency about the unification project should not be mistakenfor an effort to trash the serious <strong>and</strong> important work <strong>of</strong> those engaged <strong>in</strong> that process. <strong>The</strong> projectdeserves a critique precisely because it lies at the center <strong>of</strong> a susta<strong>in</strong>ed practical effort to improve<strong>in</strong>ternational law. It is the nobility <strong>of</strong> the project’s aspirations that makes a critical analysis bothchalleng<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> worthwhile. My critique, if it succeeds, should not end that effort. At best, it willmove the agenda.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!