13.07.2015 Views

ZICw2w

ZICw2w

ZICw2w

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

86 • The Containing and Sustaining Ecosystem: The WholeA resource is nonrival betweengenerations if the use by onegeneration does not leave lessof the resource for futuregenerations.most concentrated ores, it becomes cheaper to start mining the lowestentropywaste. For example, slag heaps near old silver mines have beenmined again with newer methods. But the slag heaps resulting from thesecond mining will be harder to mine.Another type of waste results from entropy in the form of mechanicalor chemical erosion of the material in question. Pennies eventually wearout through use—an atom rubbed off here, another there. Other metalsrust away. Hence, gross subterranean stocks are never depleted (First Lawof Thermodynamics). They simply become stocks of higher and higherentropy, akin to bound energy, and are no longer of use to humans (SecondLaw of Thermodynamics).We have some control over the creation of waste in the form of discardedgoods, but virtually none over the effects of entropy. The entropiclimit to extraction in this case occurs when the extraction process consumesmore material than it can provide. As we stated earlier, some peopleassert that this never happens, while others assert it will happen soonenough to make a steady-state economy a pipe dream; we take the middleroad.As more minerals are brought to the surface and put to use, entropyacts on a larger stock. As more subterranean stocks are extracted, the remainderbecomes more difficult to find and extract. Therefore, even beforein-ground stocks are exhausted, the rate of dissipation of abovegroundstocks must become greater than the net extraction of new material, andaboveground stocks begin to decline. However, even after reaching theentropic limit to extraction, we are still likely to have a large stock of materialin the economy that can be reused and recycled. Over time, ofcourse, it must gradually erode away, atom by atom. In Figure 5.2, the distancebetween the lines depicting cumulative extraction and abovegroundstocks measures cumulative dissipation, and eventually the entire abovegroundstock must succumb to entropy. This process is probably slowenough that we could achieve a steady state through material recycling fora very, very long time. However, as is the case with oil, the threat to us isprobably more from the impacts of the waste itself than from the exhaustionof mineral resources. We’ll put this discussion off until we get to thesection on waste absorption capacity in Chapter 6.What points can we draw from our discussion? First, mineral resourcesare rival goods at a given point in time. If I am using a hunk of steel in mycar, it is not available for you to use. But through recycling, most of theseresources could be made available for someone else to use in the future.Thus, we can think of mineral resources as rival goods within a generation butas partially nonrival between generations, depending on how much iswasted and how much recycled. Fossil fuels are rival both within and betweengenerations. Second, stocks of low-entropy mineral ores are finite

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!