23.10.2018 Views

Predatory Lending

Predatory Lending

Predatory Lending

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

On the other hand, Jonathan Rothwell notes that studying the "increase in the income<br />

share of the top 1 percent" in countries in the OECD between 1980 and 2014 finds "no<br />

correlation across countries" between the change in inequality and change in labor's<br />

share of GDP. Both inequality and labor's share of GDP have risen in the UK, while in<br />

the Netherlands labor's share has fallen and inequality is unchanged.<br />

Information Technology<br />

The growth in importance of information technology has been credited with increasing<br />

income inequality. Technology has been called "the main driver of the recent increases<br />

in inequality" by Erik Brynjolfsson, of MIT. In arguing against this explanation, Jonathan<br />

Rothwell notes that if technological advancement is measured by high rates of<br />

invention, there is a negative correlation between it and inequality. Countries with high<br />

invention rates — "as measured by patent applications filed under the Patent<br />

Cooperation Treaty" — exhibit lower inequality than those with less. In one country, the<br />

United States, "salaries of engineers and software developers rarely reach" above<br />

$390,000/year (the lower limit for the top 1% earners).<br />

Globalization<br />

Change in real income between 1988 and 2008<br />

at various income percentiles of global income<br />

distribution.<br />

Trade liberalization may shift<br />

economic inequality from a global to<br />

a domestic scale. When rich<br />

countries trade with poor countries,<br />

the low-skilled workers in the rich<br />

countries may see reduced wages<br />

as a result of the competition, while low-skilled workers in the poor countries may see<br />

increased wages. Trade economist Paul Krugman estimates that trade liberalisation has<br />

had a measurable effect on the rising inequality in the United States. He attributes this<br />

trend to increased trade with poor countries and the fragmentation of the means of<br />

production, resulting in low skilled jobs becoming more tradeable. However, he<br />

concedes that the effect of trade on inequality in America is minor when compared to<br />

other causes, such as technological innovation, a view shared by other experts.<br />

Empirical economists Max Roser and Jesus Crespo-Cuaresma find support in the data<br />

that international trade is increasing income inequality. They empirically confirm the<br />

predictions of the Stolper–Samuelson theorem regarding the effects of international<br />

trade on the distribution of incomes. Lawrence Katz estimates that trade has only<br />

accounted for 5-15% of rising income inequality. Robert Lawrence argues that<br />

technological innovation and automation has meant that low-skilled jobs have been<br />

replaced by machine labor in wealthier nations, and that wealthier countries no longer<br />

have significant numbers of low-skilled manufacturing workers that could be affected by<br />

competition from poor countries.<br />

Page 47 of 181

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!