24.07.2013 Views

Vertical or horizontal separation? - Alive2green

Vertical or horizontal separation? - Alive2green

Vertical or horizontal separation? - Alive2green

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Vertical</strong> <strong>or</strong> h<strong>or</strong>izontal<br />

<strong>separation</strong>?<br />

Rail regulation issues<br />

21 September 2011


Introduction<br />

• A number of policy initiatives are currently on the table f<strong>or</strong> the South<br />

African freight rail sect<strong>or</strong>:<br />

– Economic regulat<strong>or</strong><br />

– Introduction of private participation<br />

– Possible <strong>separation</strong> of track from operations<br />

• The choice of structural model f<strong>or</strong> rail has massive implications f<strong>or</strong> the<br />

complexity of economic regulation, and would merit m<strong>or</strong>e discussion<br />

• <strong>Vertical</strong> <strong>separation</strong> of the track from freight operations is not the only<br />

possible solution: h<strong>or</strong>izontal <strong>separation</strong> of freight into a number of<br />

competing, vertically integrated operat<strong>or</strong>s should also be considered<br />

• Ideally all feasible alternatives should be considered bef<strong>or</strong>e decisions<br />

are made<br />

2


Contents<br />

Outline of presentation<br />

• Implications of vertical versus h<strong>or</strong>izontal <strong>separation</strong> in rail<br />

• Implications of structural choices f<strong>or</strong> economic regulation task<br />

• Current policy debate<br />

• Conclusions<br />

3


<strong>Vertical</strong> and h<strong>or</strong>izontal <strong>separation</strong>


Competition in netw<strong>or</strong>ks<br />

• Not all markets are created equal<br />

– Competition w<strong>or</strong>ks best when a market can supp<strong>or</strong>t many independent<br />

firms, who can only affect each other by competing f<strong>or</strong> customers<br />

– In netw<strong>or</strong>k economies, firms benefit from large netw<strong>or</strong>k size – the m<strong>or</strong>e<br />

they cooperate, the better<br />

– Conversely, if a very large firm in a netw<strong>or</strong>k economy refuses to cooperate<br />

with others, it can drive everyone else out of business (especially if it is<br />

either not possible to replicate the netw<strong>or</strong>k, <strong>or</strong> would be prohibitively<br />

expensive)<br />

• Key problem of netw<strong>or</strong>k economies: how do you ensure that enough<br />

cooperation takes place between firms to supp<strong>or</strong>t market<br />

development, but without stifling competition?<br />

5


Rail as a netw<strong>or</strong>k economy<br />

What characteristics make rail a netw<strong>or</strong>k economy?<br />

• The cost of building a rail netw<strong>or</strong>k is very high in prop<strong>or</strong>tion to the<br />

operating costs per trip<br />

– the m<strong>or</strong>e volume that netw<strong>or</strong>k does, the easier it is to cover the costs of<br />

the initial investment in the track<br />

• The usefulness of the rail netw<strong>or</strong>k to freight customer increases as<br />

interconnectedness increases<br />

– the m<strong>or</strong>e destinations offered, the m<strong>or</strong>e likely customers are to use rail,<br />

and the easier it is to get the volumes necessary to operate profitably<br />

• Everybody who uses a piece of track affects everybody else<br />

– have to co<strong>or</strong>dinate speeds, maintenance, signalling, etc <strong>or</strong> the system<br />

grinds to a halt<br />

• Given these characteristics, running rail as a monopoly makes<br />

intuitive sense<br />

– but the cost is the loss of price and quality competition<br />

6


Why <strong>separation</strong>?<br />

• <strong>Vertical</strong> and h<strong>or</strong>izontal <strong>separation</strong> models both attempt to introduce<br />

competition in rail<br />

– These models arguably decrease the operating efficiency of rail<br />

– Pay-off is the increase in price and quality competition<br />

– But: not certain that this pay-off will materialise if the regulat<strong>or</strong> can’t cope<br />

with the complex regulat<strong>or</strong>y task posed by either f<strong>or</strong>m of <strong>separation</strong><br />

• <strong>Vertical</strong> <strong>separation</strong>: rail track should be housed in a separate<br />

agency. It is a natural monopoly and should be run as a public utility,<br />

possibly on a not-f<strong>or</strong>-profit basis. The job of the track owner is to allow<br />

operat<strong>or</strong>s to compete freely among themselves<br />

• H<strong>or</strong>izontal <strong>separation</strong>: each operat<strong>or</strong> owns its own track and rolling<br />

stock, but is restricted to a given geographical area, and competes<br />

with other integrated operat<strong>or</strong>s<br />

• Which produces the best result?<br />

7


<strong>Vertical</strong> <strong>separation</strong><br />

• The goal of vertical <strong>separation</strong> is to level the playing field between<br />

competing rail operat<strong>or</strong>s<br />

– All operat<strong>or</strong>s face the same cost structure in using the netw<strong>or</strong>k<br />

– Customers can ideally then choose between different operat<strong>or</strong>s f<strong>or</strong> the<br />

same service, on the same track – enables competition<br />

– Because all netw<strong>or</strong>k facilities are shared, no single operat<strong>or</strong> has the ability<br />

to deny a competit<strong>or</strong> access<br />

• This model has been used f<strong>or</strong> freight rail in a number of countries,<br />

including the United Kingdom and the European Union<br />

8


Substantial practical costs<br />

<strong>Vertical</strong> <strong>separation</strong> & efficiency<br />

• Some studies have suggested that the reduction in technical<br />

efficiency associated with vertical <strong>separation</strong> can be in the region of<br />

20-40% (Ivaldi & McCullough 2004, 16)<br />

• Technical efficiency issues have a number of sources:<br />

– Money spent on maintaining rolling stock helps to reduce damage to the<br />

track and vice versa: separating ownership means both parties have an<br />

incentive to under-invest in maintenance<br />

– Scheduling and co<strong>or</strong>dination affects efficiency – m<strong>or</strong>e difficult to<br />

accomplish with multiple operat<strong>or</strong>s<br />

– May create sequential monopolies anyway – single operat<strong>or</strong>s on certain<br />

c<strong>or</strong>rid<strong>or</strong>s<br />

• Determining appropriate access fees and allocating scarce access to<br />

track are also complex tasks f<strong>or</strong> the track owner<br />

• Potential f<strong>or</strong> damaging favouritism<br />

9


H<strong>or</strong>izontal <strong>separation</strong><br />

• Under h<strong>or</strong>izontal <strong>separation</strong>, each area is covered by only one<br />

operat<strong>or</strong> – establishes regional monopoly providers, with integrated<br />

above track/below track activities<br />

• However, some competitive constraints remain:<br />

– Competition f<strong>or</strong> concessions can be used to constrain pricing behaviour<br />

over the term of the concession<br />

– Competition to service key geographical destinations may be possible,<br />

depending on geography<br />

• The interchange points between different vertically integrated<br />

operat<strong>or</strong>s become the focus of regulat<strong>or</strong>y attention<br />

• Countries using some f<strong>or</strong>m of h<strong>or</strong>izontal <strong>separation</strong> in freight rail<br />

include the United States, Canada and Mexico<br />

10


Geography is probably key<br />

H<strong>or</strong>izontal <strong>separation</strong> & efficiency<br />

• H<strong>or</strong>izontally separated operat<strong>or</strong>s are appropriately incentivised to<br />

invest in optimal maintenance levels – efficiency improving<br />

• Counter-balanced if the freight geography lends itself to bottlenecks<br />

and natural monopolies<br />

• Mexican example:<br />

– Mexico City is a key freight destination<br />

– It is landlocked and served by several rail freight c<strong>or</strong>rid<strong>or</strong>s linked to<br />

different p<strong>or</strong>ts<br />

– Only area of shared track infrastructure is directly around Mexico City –<br />

limits regulat<strong>or</strong>y burden<br />

– H<strong>or</strong>izontal <strong>separation</strong> is able to generate substantial competition f<strong>or</strong> freight<br />

• Geographical similarities to Johannesburg?<br />

11


H<strong>or</strong>izontal competit<strong>or</strong>s?<br />

12


Market structure and regulation


When to regulate?<br />

• Economic regulation is difficult to do, and even m<strong>or</strong>e difficult to do<br />

well<br />

– Requires intrusion into private business affairs that may be legally<br />

contested: needs excellent legal framew<strong>or</strong>k and skill set to implement<br />

– Requires en<strong>or</strong>mous amounts of data and highly skilled interpretation of that<br />

data to set prices and prevent anti-competitive behaviour<br />

– Needs to be done continuously<br />

• Logical implication: you only regulate when you absolutely have to<br />

– Market failure which resists structural solutions<br />

– Potential pay-off from regulation sufficient to compensate f<strong>or</strong> costs of<br />

regulation<br />

– Intermodal competition insufficient to restrain prices<br />

• Regulation should resolve market logjams and enable competition as<br />

much as possible<br />

14


<strong>Vertical</strong> vs h<strong>or</strong>izontal <strong>separation</strong><br />

Choice should be influenced by the<strong>or</strong>y and facts on the ground<br />

• Economic regulation is critical f<strong>or</strong> the success of both vertical and<br />

h<strong>or</strong>izontal <strong>separation</strong><br />

• Size of the regulat<strong>or</strong>y task depends on the characteristics of the<br />

netw<strong>or</strong>k concerned<br />

– Do geographical conditions enable competition between vertically<br />

integrated operat<strong>or</strong>s?<br />

– Is there sufficient scale on existing c<strong>or</strong>rid<strong>or</strong>s to ensure the viability of<br />

competing vertically separated operat<strong>or</strong>s?<br />

– Is there a hist<strong>or</strong>ical relationship between the track and a given operat<strong>or</strong>,<br />

which would lead to favouritism issues under vertical <strong>separation</strong>?<br />

– Would h<strong>or</strong>izontally separated operat<strong>or</strong>s need substantial access to other<br />

netw<strong>or</strong>ks to effectively compete? (which would require an additional access<br />

pricing regime – compuls<strong>or</strong>y trackage rights)<br />

15


Devil is in the details<br />

Policy intentions can be derailed by implementation choices<br />

• The establishment of an economic regulat<strong>or</strong> is not a cure-all – scope<br />

of regulat<strong>or</strong> to improve sect<strong>or</strong> outcomes strongly affected by policy<br />

choices<br />

• F<strong>or</strong> example:<br />

– Does the chosen market structure complicate <strong>or</strong> simplify the regulat<strong>or</strong>y<br />

task?<br />

– Does the regulat<strong>or</strong> have sufficient control of the incumbent to offset its<br />

competitive advantage over new entrants?<br />

– Has the regulat<strong>or</strong> been given sufficient independence?<br />

• The choice of vertical <strong>or</strong> h<strong>or</strong>izontal <strong>separation</strong>, <strong>or</strong> some mixture of the<br />

two, plays a maj<strong>or</strong> role in determining regulat<strong>or</strong>y viability – and thus<br />

the net impact of regulation on market outcomes<br />

16


The South African policy debate


Way f<strong>or</strong>ward not clear<br />

• Limited transparency in the rail policy debate to date:<br />

– National Freight Logistics Strategy 2005 called f<strong>or</strong> limited introduction of<br />

private competition at operat<strong>or</strong> level, with the track infrastructure retained<br />

by the state – implied vertical <strong>separation</strong><br />

– Also commissioning of branch lines – mixed h<strong>or</strong>izontal and vertical<br />

<strong>separation</strong>?<br />

– Concessionaires beginning to complain about lack of access to main lines:<br />

does this imply that a vertical <strong>separation</strong>/track access model is not really on<br />

the cards?<br />

• Transnet has now also declared its opposition to splitting out track<br />

assets and vertical <strong>separation</strong> in general<br />

• Not aware of any publically available w<strong>or</strong>k that has been done on the<br />

trade-off between h<strong>or</strong>izontal and vertical <strong>separation</strong> in South Africa<br />

18


Conclusions


Good policy needs good research<br />

• Something needs to be done to improve rail freight perf<strong>or</strong>mance<br />

• Exactly what that is, is an empirical question, that needs to be<br />

resolved by careful analysis<br />

• Based on what has been released to the public by policymakers in<br />

rail, there is no evidence that this has yet been done<br />

– Some preference seems to be shown f<strong>or</strong> vertical <strong>separation</strong><br />

– Interpretation of vertical <strong>separation</strong> may also have h<strong>or</strong>izontal elements, that<br />

tend to further disadvantage new entrants<br />

– Limited discussion of h<strong>or</strong>izontal <strong>separation</strong> – not clear if it has been<br />

considered and rejected, <strong>or</strong> not evaluated at all<br />

• Would be extremely encouraging to see m<strong>or</strong>e consideration of this<br />

issue going f<strong>or</strong>ward – evidence-based policy making techniques<br />

would be of use, particularly regulat<strong>or</strong>y impact assessment models<br />

20


Tel +27 (0)12 362 0024<br />

Fax +27 (0)12 362 0210<br />

Email contact@dnaeconomics.com<br />

www.dnaeconomics.com<br />

4th Flo<strong>or</strong>, South Office Tower, Hatfield Plaza,<br />

1122 Burnett Street, Hatfield, Pret<strong>or</strong>ia, 0083<br />

PO Box 95838, Waterkloof, 0145<br />

DNA Economics is the registered business and trading name of Development Netw<strong>or</strong>k Africa (Pty) Ltd<br />

Company Registration: 2001/023453/07│Direct<strong>or</strong>s: Elias Masilela │Matthew Stern

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!