10.08.2013 Views

Full Version - Issue 7 | November 2011 - LTA Academy

Full Version - Issue 7 | November 2011 - LTA Academy

Full Version - Issue 7 | November 2011 - LTA Academy

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

costs, public transport, especially in local<br />

urban contexts, can be considered a natural<br />

monopoly with significant economies of scale.<br />

This means that one large operator can supply<br />

public transport services at lower costs than<br />

two or more smaller operators.<br />

Due to the high fixed costs relative<br />

to operating costs, public transport,<br />

especially in local urban contexts, can<br />

be considered a natural monopoly<br />

with significant economies of scale.<br />

This means that one large operator<br />

can supply public transport services<br />

at lower costs than two or more<br />

smaller operators.<br />

While there are potential benefits, there are<br />

also risks associated with privatisation. Basic<br />

economic theory warns of the dangers of<br />

monopoly, public or private. Driven by the profit<br />

motive, private monopolies could exploit their<br />

market power to charge much higher prices<br />

than would have been possible with market<br />

competition. They may also reduce costs by<br />

lowering service levels, such as reducing service<br />

frequencies and equipment maintenance<br />

levels. An effective regulatory framework with<br />

price control must be in place to ensure that<br />

monopoly exploitation does not occur.<br />

Different Approaches to Public<br />

Transport Provision<br />

Government Operators<br />

Some would argue that, since private<br />

monopolies are likely to abuse their market<br />

power, it would be preferable to nationalise<br />

public transport. Nationalisation can be<br />

defined in several ways, for example, it could<br />

mean the government taking over transport<br />

planning, ownership of infrastructure, or<br />

service provision. In this article, nationalisation<br />

is defined specifically as government provision<br />

of public transport services.<br />

Proponents believe that government-run public<br />

transport operators which are not profit-driven<br />

would be less likely to abuse their market power,<br />

and would place greater priority on public<br />

service objectives, such as affordable fares and<br />

service enhancement. The government would<br />

also have more direct control over fares, supply<br />

of services, and service quality.<br />

However the lack of a profit motive provides<br />

little incentive for government operators to<br />

be efficient. While it is possible to set clear<br />

performance objectives for public enterprises,<br />

the experience in several countries has shown<br />

that government operators have generally<br />

failed to operate efficiently and their unit costs<br />

have increased steadily over the years. They<br />

would also face greater political pressure to<br />

provide unprofitable services.<br />

A benchmarking study done in 2008 compared<br />

Sydney’s government-run rail operator CityRail<br />

with Melbourne’s private rail operator Connex<br />

(LEK 2008). Both operators were comparable in<br />

scale but there was a disparity in cost efficiency.<br />

Using data from 2006/7, the study found that<br />

Connex’s costs were lower than CityRail’s.<br />

Connex’s annual rolling stock costs were 40%<br />

JOURNEYS | <strong>November</strong> <strong>2011</strong><br />

Different Approaches to Public Transport Provision<br />

Some would argue that, since private<br />

monopolies are likely to abuse their<br />

market power, it would be preferable<br />

to nationalise public transport.<br />

33

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!