13.08.2013 Views

IPO Auctions: English, Dutch, ... French, and Internet

IPO Auctions: English, Dutch, ... French, and Internet

IPO Auctions: English, Dutch, ... French, and Internet

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

18 BIAIS AND FAUGERON-CROUZET<br />

investors do not have enough funds to buy the whole <strong>IPO</strong>. This is more realistic,<br />

given the relatively small size of <strong>IPO</strong> issues, compared to the large bidding power<br />

of institutional investors. Second, we consider N informed investors, with different<br />

<strong>and</strong> imperfect signals, rather than a single, perfectly informed investor.<br />

In the case of fixed price offers, the only choice of the seller is to set the price, p.<br />

Since the uninformed agents cannot absorb the whole issue, <strong>and</strong> since the seller<br />

must sell the S shares, he must ensure that the informed agents are willing to bid<br />

for the shares, even when they have observed bad signals. Hence, the price must<br />

be set to satisfy the individual rationality constraint of the informed agent with a<br />

bad signal.<br />

We assume that informed investors can costlessly bid for up to S shares. If they<br />

want to bid for a larger amount, up to ¯Q > S, they incur cost c. As only S shares<br />

are for sale, such very large bids are expected not to be fully executed. They can<br />

be optimal, however, to the extent that they enable the investor to obtain a larger<br />

share of underpriced <strong>and</strong> overbid issues. The cost c can be thought of as the cost<br />

of immobilizing funds during the period of the <strong>IPO</strong> (Keloharju (1993) notes that<br />

in Finl<strong>and</strong> this period can be quite long).<br />

Consider the c<strong>and</strong>idate equilibrium where investors with good signals bid for<br />

a large amount ( ¯Q), while investors with a bad signal bid for a lower amount (S)<br />

<strong>and</strong> retail investors also participate to the <strong>IPO</strong>. In this context, the execution rate<br />

when there are n good signals is<br />

S<br />

τn =<br />

S(1 − k + N − n) + n ¯Q .<br />

Setting the expected gain of the informed with a bad signal bidding for S shares<br />

to 0<br />

E(Sτ(v − p) | b) = 0,<br />

pins down the <strong>IPO</strong> price. Correspondingly, we obtain the following proposition:<br />

PROPOSITION 2. If K1 ≤ c ≤ K2 (where K1 <strong>and</strong> K2 are constants defined in<br />

the proof ), then in the fixed price offer the highest possible <strong>IPO</strong> price is<br />

where,<br />

N−1<br />

p = λlv(l),<br />

λl =<br />

l=0<br />

πlτl<br />

N−1 l=0 πlτl<br />

,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the informed agent with a good signal bids for ¯Q, while the informed agent<br />

with a bad signal bids for S, <strong>and</strong> the uninformed agent bids for S(1 − k).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!