19.10.2014 Views

Download Publication - Rio+20

Download Publication - Rio+20

Download Publication - Rio+20

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

ISSN 1809-8185<br />

POLÍTICA<br />

AMBIENTAL<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

green economy<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities


2<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Conservação Internacional is a private non-profit organization,<br />

founded in 1987, with the objective of promoting human well-being by<br />

strengthening society’s role in the responsible and sustainable care<br />

of nature – our global biodiversity – supported by a solid foundation in<br />

science, partnerships and field experiences.<br />

President: José Alexandre Felizola Diniz-Filho<br />

Executive Director: Fábio Scarano<br />

Director of Environment Policy: Paulo Gustavo Prado<br />

Director of Communications: Isabela de Lima Santos<br />

Conservação Internacional<br />

Av. Getúlio Vargas, 1300, 7º andar<br />

30112-021 Belo Horizonte MG<br />

tel.: 55 31 3261-3889<br />

e-mail: info@conservacao.org<br />

www.conservacao.org<br />

Política Ambiental is an electronic journal issued by Conservation<br />

International that publishes scientific and technical articles about the<br />

main topics of current environmental policy.<br />

Política Ambiental<br />

Green economy: challenges and opportunities<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Editorial coordination: Camila L. Gramkow<br />

Paulo Gustavo Prado<br />

Coordination of edition: Gabriela Michelotti<br />

Translation: Cecília Barsk Romero<br />

(Pages 24 to 35, 96 to 107, 120 to 126 - Elza Suely Anderson)<br />

(Pages 86 to 95, 108 to 119 - Janaína Mendes)<br />

Cover photographs: Larger photograph: © CI/Haroldo Castro Smaller<br />

photographs (top down): © CI/Luciano Candisani,<br />

© CI/Luciano Candisani, © CI/M. de Paula, Wild Wonders of<br />

Europe/Laszlo Novak, iStockphoto, Cortesia UNICA,<br />

© CI/John Martin, © CI/Sterling Zumbrunn,<br />

© CI/Enrico Bernard and © CI/Christine Dragisic<br />

Design and graphic editing: Grupo de Design Gráfico Ltda.<br />

Catalog card prepared by Librarian Nina C. Mendonça CRB6/1288<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

P769<br />

Política Ambiental / Conservação Internacional - n. 8, jun. 2011 – Belo<br />

Horizonte: Conservação Internacional, 2011.<br />

n. 1 (maio 2006)<br />

ISSN 1809-8185<br />

1. Política ambiental – Periódicos. I. Conservação Internacional Brasil.


3<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

content<br />

Acronyms ............................................................................................................. 4<br />

Preface ................................................................................................................. 6<br />

Executive Summary ............................................................................................ 9<br />

Delineations of a green economy<br />

Helena Pavese ..................................................................................................... 16<br />

The necessarily systemic character of the transition to a green economy<br />

Alexandre D’Avignon and Luiz Antônio Cruz Caruso ............................................ 24<br />

Green economy and/or sustainable development?<br />

Donald Sawyer ..................................................................................................... 36<br />

International perspectives of the transition to a low-carbon green economy<br />

Eduardo Viola ....................................................................................................... 43<br />

Green economy in Latin America: the origins of debate in ECLAC work<br />

Márcia Tavares ..................................................................................................... 57<br />

The role of inclusive growth for a green economy in developing countries<br />

Clóvis Zapata ....................................................................................................... 69<br />

Brazil and the green economy: a panorama<br />

Francisco Gaetani, Ernani Kuhn and Renato Rosenberg ..................................... 76<br />

Growth potential of the green economy in Brazil<br />

Carlos Eduardo F. Young ..................................................................................... 86<br />

Brazil and the green economy: foundations and strategy for transition<br />

Cláudio Frischtak ................................................................................................. 96<br />

Innovation and technology for a green economy: key issues<br />

Maria Cecília J. Lustosa ...................................................................................... 108<br />

Agriculture for a green economy<br />

Ademar R. Romeiro ............................................................................................. 120<br />

Green economy and a new cycle of rural development<br />

Arilson Favareto ................................................................................................... 127<br />

Deforestation of the Brazilian Amazon rainforest: causes and solutions<br />

Bastiaan P. Reydon .............................................................................................. 138<br />

The transition to a green economy in Brazilian law:<br />

perspective and challenges<br />

Carlos Teodoro Irigaray ........................................................................................ 151<br />

Market mechanisms for a green economy<br />

Peter H. May ........................................................................................................ 165<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Valuation and pricing of environmental resources for a green economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta ...................................................................................... 174<br />

The role of financial institutions in the transition to a green economy<br />

Mário Sérgio Vasconcelos .................................................................................... 186<br />

Measurement in policies for transition to a green economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta and Carolina Dubeux .................................................... 192


4<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

acronyms<br />

BASIC – Brazil, South Africa, India and China<br />

BNDES – National Bank of Economic and Social Development<br />

BRIC – Brazil, Russia, India and China<br />

CNI – National Industrial Confederation<br />

CU – Conservation Unit<br />

ECLAC – Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean<br />

EMBRAPA – Brazilian Agricultural Research Company<br />

GDP – Gross Domestic Product<br />

GE – Green Economy<br />

GMO – Genetically Modified Organism<br />

FAO – United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization<br />

FEBRABAN – Brazilian Federation of Banks<br />

GHG – Greenhouse Gases<br />

HIV/AIDS – Human immunodeficiency virus/acquired immunodeficiency<br />

syndrome<br />

IBAMA – Brazilian Institute of Environment and Renewable Natural<br />

Resource<br />

IBSA – India, Brazil, South Africa<br />

IBGE – Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics<br />

ICMBio – The Chico Mendes Institute for Biodiversity Conservation<br />

Imazon – Amazon Institute of People and the Environment<br />

INCRA – National Institute of Colonization and Agrarian Reform<br />

INPE – National Institute for Space Research<br />

IPCC – Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change<br />

IPC-IG - International Policy Center for Inclusive Growth<br />

IPEA – Institute of Applied Economic Research<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

MCT – Ministry of Science and Technology<br />

MDA – Ministry of Agrarian Development<br />

Mercosul – Southern common market


5<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Siglário<br />

MMA – Ministry of the Environment<br />

MME – Ministry of Mines and Energy<br />

NGO – Non-Governmental Organization<br />

OECD – Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development<br />

OTCA – Amazon Cooperation Treaty Organization<br />

R&D – Research and Development<br />

PES – Payment for Environmental Services<br />

REDD – Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and Forest Degradation<br />

REDD+ – Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and Forest Degradation,<br />

including conservation, sustainable forest management, afforestation and<br />

re-forestation.<br />

Rio 92 – United Nations Conference on Environment and Development<br />

Rio+10 – World Summit on Sustainable Development that took place in 2002<br />

in Johannesburg<br />

<strong>Rio+20</strong> – United Nations Conference on Sustainable Development that will<br />

be held in 2012 in Rio de Janeiro<br />

TEEB – The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity<br />

UN – United Nations<br />

UNASUR – Union of South American Nations<br />

UNIDO – United Nations Industrial Development Organization<br />

UNDP – United Nations Development Programme<br />

UNEP – United Nations Environment Programme<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011


6<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Preface<br />

Environmental issues have become increasingly incorporated in the<br />

scientific agendas of the most diverse fields of knowledge and in local, national,<br />

regional and global political agendas. Its growing relevance originates from the<br />

widespread understanding that environmental sustainability is indispensable<br />

to the long term development of societies. On one hand, from an alarmist<br />

perspective, neglecting this issue would probably result in perverse effects on<br />

human beings and development, as pointed out currently by many studies 1 .<br />

From a strategic perspective, possibilities and opportunities have been identified<br />

deriving from its effective incorporation, once it could contribute to achieving<br />

more sustainable development processes in various dimensions (economic,<br />

social and environmental) 2 .<br />

The challenge of moving towards a more egalitarian and sustainable society<br />

is, more than ever, on the agenda. It is in this context that the green economy<br />

concept has emerged. Defined by the UNEP as that which “results in improved<br />

human well-being and social equality, while significantly reducing environmental<br />

risks and ecological scarcity” 3 , green economy will be one of the key topics 4<br />

of <strong>Rio+20</strong>, the United Nations Conference on Sustainable Development that<br />

will take place in 2012 in Rio de Janeiro.<br />

The challenge is not simple and discussions are only beginning. Despite<br />

having a formal conceptualization, precise delineations are still to be determined.<br />

After all, what is a green economy? Which economies are closer to reaching it?<br />

How to measure the degree of “greening” of an economy? What does it mean,<br />

concretely, to achieve transition to a green economy? What is the role of the<br />

state in this transition? How to finance the transition? Which sectors will be<br />

most affected? Which will be most benefitted? How would the transition affect<br />

the daily lives of citizens? What are the risks of not transforming to a green<br />

economy? And in the case of Brazil, what has the country done and what is<br />

left to do to advance towards a green economy? How is the country doing,<br />

compared to the others? What are the main obstacles and challenges? How to<br />

address them? What would a transition mean for society, productive sectors,<br />

for government, for consumers? How can developed and developing countries<br />

cooperate in this transition? How can international promotion and cooperation<br />

organizations align themselves with these objectives? How can United Nations<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

1. In global terms, see Stern (2007) and IPCC (2007). For an analysis of the Brazilian case, see<br />

World Bank (2010), Marcovitch (coord.) (2010) and NAE (2005).<br />

2. TEEB (2011) and UNEP (2011).<br />

3. UNEP (2011).<br />

4. The two key topics to guide the Conference are: (i) green economy in the context of<br />

sustainable development and poverty eradication; and (ii) institutional framework for<br />

sustainable development.


7<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Preface<br />

priority international initiatives, such as the Climate Change and the Biodiversity<br />

Conventions, encourage and implement common agendas aimed at achieving<br />

these objectives?<br />

Green economy raises many questions that do not have simple and straight<br />

answers. We know, however, that the transition requires substantial efforts<br />

and engagement from all segments of society, especially government and the<br />

private sector. It demands that governments level the playing field for greener<br />

products by removing perverse incentives, revising policies and incentives,<br />

strengthening market infrastructure, introducing new market mechanisms,<br />

redirecting public investment and “greening” public procurement. The private<br />

sector, on the other hand, will need to respond to these policy reforms through<br />

increased financing and investments, as well as by creating innovation skills<br />

and capabilities to make the best of green economy opportunities.<br />

The timing to discuss an alternative paradigm, where the generation of<br />

wealth does not increase social disparities or produce environmental risks,<br />

nor ecological scarcities, could not be more opportune. The 2008 crisis, from<br />

which the global economy is still trying to recover, could be an opportunity to<br />

think about and formulate the economic model that we wish to follow.<br />

The transition to a green economy could benefit Brazil in various ways. The<br />

green economy demands greater social equity, something that is especially<br />

necessary in Brazil, which is among the ten countries with the worst income<br />

distribution on the planet 5 . The transition could, thus, serve as a platform for<br />

poverty eradication. Furthermore, Brazil has greatly favorable natural conditions:<br />

the richest biodiversity on the planet, ample water resources, large continental<br />

and coastal areas, ocean resources yet to be discovered; that is, a natural that<br />

albeit threatened is still abundant. In a green economy, natural capital becomes<br />

an asset that generates dividends and produces a competitive edge. Thus, the<br />

pre-requisites are in place that enable Brazil to be more than a beneficiary, but<br />

rather capable of leading the green economy transition, and assuming a role<br />

as global agent for change.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Change can already be seen in various parts of the world 6 . The transition to<br />

a green economy is both a global and a national movement, where cooperation<br />

and coordination are paramount. The reversal of the processes of natural capital<br />

loss and increased social inequality require the efforts of all nations. These<br />

efforts tend to convert themselves into competitive advantages, a situation that<br />

already has become reality in some economies and sectors today. Developing<br />

countries, as keepers of a large portion of the planet’s natural capital, could<br />

exercise a more strategic role. Developed countries, despite already having<br />

consumed a large share of their natural capital, are developing significant<br />

5. UNDP (2010).<br />

6. TEEB (2011).


8<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Preface<br />

advances in so-called green technologies, which tend to be a differential.<br />

Political, technical, scientific-technological, financial and economic cooperation<br />

between the two, in the more than necessary race towards a green economy,<br />

could generate mutual benefits.<br />

This special edition presents ideas for advancing in the direction of a green<br />

economy. It brings reflections from some of the main Brazilian specialists – and<br />

‘Brazilianists’ – on the subject, in a search to respond to the key questions raised<br />

by the green economy in general and in a country such as Brazil. Eighteen<br />

articles gather the contributions of experts from diverse affiliations and origins.<br />

Elements that may form the basis for the green economy discussion in Brazil<br />

are hereby released.<br />

Enjoy the reading!<br />

References<br />

World Bank (2010). Estudo de baixo carbono para o Brasil. Available at: .<br />

IPCC (2007). IPCC fourth assessment report: climate change 2007. Available at: .<br />

Marcovitch, Jacques (coord.) (2010). Economia da mudança do clima no Brasil: custos<br />

e oportunidades. São Paulo: IBEP Gráfica.<br />

NAE - Núcleo de Assuntos Estratégicos da Presidência da República (2005). Cadernos<br />

NAE, série mudança do clima, n. 3, February. Brasília: Núcleo de Assuntos<br />

Estratégicos da Presidência da República, Secretaria de Comunicação de Governo<br />

e Gestão Estratégica.<br />

Stern, Nicholas (2007). The Economics of Climate Change: the Stern review. Cambridge:<br />

Cambridge University Press.<br />

TEEB (2011). The economics of ecosystems and biodiversity: mainstreaming the<br />

economics of nature: a synthesis of the approach, conclusions and recommendations<br />

of TEEB. Available at: .<br />

UNDP (2010). Actuar sobre el futuro: romper la transmisión intergeneracional de la<br />

desigualdad. Informe regional sobre desarrollo humano para América Latina y el<br />

Caribe 2010. New York: UNDP.<br />

UNEP (2011). Towards a Green Economy: Pathways to Sustainable Development and<br />

Poverty Eradication - A Synthesis for Policy Makers. Available at: .<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011


9<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Executive Summary<br />

The first article, written by Helena Pavese, puts forth the concept of green<br />

economy and main results of the report “Towards a green economy: pathways to<br />

sustainable development and poverty eradication”, launched in February 2011.<br />

Starting from the finding of elevated levels of ecosystem services degradation<br />

and, therefore, of natural capital, the author presents the Green Economy<br />

Initiative, launched with the intention of identifying the social and economic<br />

risks and costs generated by current standards of excessive natural resource<br />

use, as well as the opportunities for a transition to more sustainable practices.<br />

From this Initiative, the Report on green economy emerged, whose main results<br />

Pavese succinctly outlines. It is concluded that green economy is possible and<br />

desirable, as it is capable of aligning income and employment generation with<br />

poverty eradication and natural capital conservation.<br />

Alexandre D’Avignon and Luiz Antônio Cruz Caruso analyze the UNEP report<br />

from a critical perspective. They affirm that the Report represents a qualitative<br />

leap in the sense of introducing values that go beyond maximizing utility.<br />

They reveal the necessity of thinking about the green economy transition in a<br />

systemic way, where human activities are merely a subsystem of civil society,<br />

which in turn is a subsystem of the universe (or the biosphere and its set of<br />

living and inanimate matter). They argue that other theoretical lines, in addition<br />

to the neo-classical theory, can provide important insights about the issues<br />

in question. Ecologic economics would offer a more systemic approach and<br />

schumpeterian and neo-schumpeterian theories could assist in rethinking the<br />

economy from the perspective of technology as a vector of transformation of<br />

human societies. These approaches give consideration to alternative solutions<br />

that are flexible and of a local character, and conducive to an effective transition<br />

to a green economy.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Donald Sawyer analyzes the relationship between green economy and<br />

sustainable development concepts. Sawyer draws attention to the risk of<br />

green economy acquiring an exclusively economic (or economistic) shape,<br />

where market instruments and pricing of natural resources would prevail to<br />

the detriment of measures of a different nature. Thus, Sawyer asserts that<br />

other dimensions are relevant to the green economy, such as social, ethical,<br />

cultural, political and judicial, etc. The author claims that the green economy<br />

should necessarily be public in a greater sense, implemented through policies<br />

that guarantee rights to all and maintain ecosystem functions interlinked, so that<br />

this concept becomes concrete, instrumental and popular, in complementarity<br />

to and connection with the sustainable development concept, that is more<br />

abstract, diplomatic and governmental.


10<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Executive Summary<br />

Eduardo Viola presents a panorama of current international circumstances in<br />

terms of transition to a green economy with a focus on low-carbon characteristics.<br />

Based on recent GHG emissions data of large and medium powers, Viola<br />

presents the main policies and measures that these groups of countries have<br />

practiced, and indicates future prospects based on the current juncture. The<br />

large powers, the United States, China and the European Union, are countries<br />

that: provide elevated contributions to global emissions, possess essential<br />

technological and human capital for decarbonizing the economy and have veto<br />

power over international agreements. The medium powers, such as India and<br />

Brazil, have limited influence on the aspects considered. A similar exercise<br />

is carried out for South America in particular, where the triple negative effect<br />

of deforestation in the region (loss of natural heritage, informality and public<br />

demoralization) and the favorable position of the region, whose economies are<br />

not extensively based on fossil fuels, with some exceptions, are highlighted.<br />

The author also surveys the main techno-economic vectors of a low-carbon<br />

transition, and concludes with a reflection on future prospects.<br />

Márcia Tavares surveys the main contributions of ECLAC to the green<br />

economy field due to its role in drafting documents and leading research and<br />

through its function as political mediator for the Latin American and Caribbean<br />

countries in international discussions. The author describes, in chronological<br />

order, the documents produced and their political and historical contexts.<br />

Tavares argues that these documents enable us to evaluate the complexity<br />

of environmental problems in the region and their direct links with economic<br />

and social structures and processes, an indispensable step to advance in<br />

solving the environmental, economic and social problems of the region. It is<br />

concluded that in order for Latin America to effectively transition to a green<br />

economy, there must be coordination between actors and institutions in different<br />

spheres, removal of barriers to change and strong and permanent institutions<br />

that prioritize sustainability.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Clóvis Zapata highlights the role of inclusive growth in the transition to a<br />

green economy in developing countries. The author starts from the observation<br />

that there are similarities between the UNEP green economy concept and the<br />

concept of inclusive growth. Zapata defends a holistic approach in which the<br />

transition to a green economy should be thought out and planned according to<br />

its various dimensions (environmental, social, economic, political, etc), which<br />

have different windows of opportunity that should be taken into appropriate<br />

consideration. The author argues that policies of a social nature and policies<br />

of an environmental nature have not been sufficiently coordinated, when in<br />

fact, they should act in complementarity. Zapata asserts that promotion of<br />

structured policies is necessary, as exemplified by the analysis of the Brazilian<br />

Biodiesel Program. The author also highlights the importance of South-South<br />

debate, and concludes with a reflection on the importance of inclusive growth


11<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Executive Summary<br />

and the contributions of international organizations and the private sector to<br />

the transition to a green economy in developing countries.<br />

Francisco Gaetani, Ernani Kuhn and Renato Rosenberg provide an overview<br />

of the situation in Brazil with regards to green economy. They argue that Brazil<br />

is an environmental energy power, due to the abundant availability of natural<br />

resources and policies and measures aimed at environmental conservation.<br />

From an international perspective, the authors claim that the country has one<br />

of the highest GHG emissions in the world, but that Brazil is changing this<br />

situation by assuming voluntary emissions reduction targets. They outline the<br />

main actions that Brazil has been implementing in the direction of a green<br />

economy in sectors such as forestry, solid waste treatment, water resources,<br />

among others. The main challenges of the transition are also presented. The<br />

authors conclude that Brazil starts from a privileged position in the transition to<br />

a green economy from various aspects, but that most of the current actions can<br />

be considered as the beginning of the institutional structuring and creation of<br />

economic mechanisms that compose the agenda of a country that is increasingly<br />

focused on the development of markets related to a green economy.<br />

Carlos Eduardo F. Young carries out analytical exercises that aim to study the<br />

impact of a “greening” of Brazilian economy, that is, the transition to a growth<br />

model driven by sectors with low environmental impacts, on the economic and<br />

social performance of the country. Based on the finding that, over the past ten<br />

years, there has been a re-specialization in primary products of Latin American<br />

and Brazilian export bundles, Young shows evidence that there has also been<br />

a specialization in pollution, since the sectors with the most pollution potential<br />

have grown above average. From the results of an input-output matrix model,<br />

the author arrives at the conclusion that the greening of the Brazilian economy<br />

could bring better results in employment and income generation than the current<br />

model specialized in exporting natural resources through predatory extraction<br />

or industrial goods with high levels of pollution in production processes. The<br />

author concludes that, based on the results obtained, the dichotomy between<br />

economic growth and environmental conservation is false.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Cláudio Frischtak analyzes the foundations and strategies of the transition to<br />

a green economy in Brazil. The author starts with the proposal that this transition<br />

requires an inversion of the dominating logic that well-being and intensive (and<br />

unsustainable) use of natural resources are inseparable; and adopt the idea<br />

that higher growth becomes (necessarily) dependent on and is accompanied<br />

by increased conservation or sustainable resource use. Frischtak develops an<br />

analytical structure composed of supply (market or structured) and demand<br />

(induced or spontaneous), that results in a 2x2 matrix. From that analytical<br />

structure, the transition towards a green economy is analyzed with a focus on<br />

certain topics (ecosystem conservation, transportation, sanitation, energy and<br />

product life-cycles). The author also proposes transition strategies based on the


12<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Executive Summary<br />

establishment of a working group, a reference framework, a set of norms and the<br />

restoration of natural capital. It is concluded that a new paradigm is emerging<br />

and that, with support from adequate government policies, Brazil is fully capable<br />

of being one of the first countries to enter into a green economy.<br />

Maria Cecília J. Lustosa analyzes the importance of environmental<br />

innovations as means of changing the current technological model, intensive<br />

in raw materials and energy from fossil fuels, in a more ecologically correct<br />

direction. Lustosa presents the historical emergence of environmental issues<br />

and their relations to economic production. Then, the author highlights the<br />

importance of the innovative process in technological change and paradigm shift,<br />

and presents the circumstances under which such changes could occur and in<br />

which directions, with a focus on EST (Environmentally Sound Technologies).<br />

Internal and external constraints of the capabilities of businesses to become<br />

innovative are also presented. Lustosa further conducts analysis of innovation<br />

linked to environmental issues in Brazilian businesses, and identifies its main<br />

characteristics. Ultimately, the author concludes that environmental innovations<br />

are necessary to enter into a green economy and that building business capacity<br />

is fundamental, and when appropriate, associated with incentives promoted<br />

by the State. In the case of Brazil, low innovation investment in the productive<br />

sector is certainly a factor that further inhibits the search for environmental<br />

innovation.<br />

Ademar R. Romeiro investigates the topic of agriculture in a green economy.<br />

The work offers a description of what agriculture should be in a green economy.<br />

Romeiro begins with the definition of what is understood as green economy from<br />

the perspective of a given long-term sustainability concept, and moves on to<br />

presenting the conditions for making agriculture compatible with this definition of<br />

a green economy. The author seeks to show that an agriculture that is sufficiently<br />

productive to attend to current agricultural production needs is scientifically<br />

and technologically possible, but is chiefly based on management by farmers<br />

of the very forces of nature in order to obtain ecosystem services. The main<br />

agricultural policy recommendation that results from the analysis is to amplify<br />

agro-ecological research efforts by the large public research institutions.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Arilson Favareto brings the new cycle of rural development topic to the<br />

discussion, by analyzing how it aligns with the green economy. The new cycle<br />

of rural development, happening at different intensities around the world and<br />

whose distinguishing feature is the transition from an agrarian and agricultural<br />

paradigm to a paradigm organized around the environmental rooting of<br />

rural development, is in line with the transition to a green economy. Modern<br />

agriculture, intensive in natural resource use, generates a lot of income but<br />

little employment. Favareto presents the main characteristics of new rurality<br />

and analyzes the situation in Brazil, identifying that here, as in the rest of the<br />

world, agriculture has a declining tendency in relation to other activities and


13<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Executive Summary<br />

that rural regions are no longer experiencing a general exodus, but rather a<br />

heterogeneity of its demographic profile, with elevated levels of schooling and<br />

greater social differentiation. The author concludes with ideas for an agenda<br />

that aligns this new cycle with the transition to a green economy.<br />

Bastiaan P. Reydon conducts an analysis of the causes of and solutions to<br />

deforestation in the Brazilian Amazon. Reydon begins by presenting data on<br />

deforestation in the Amazon, and highlights the main causes attributed to this<br />

deforestation. The author argues that deforestation results from the continued<br />

tradition of expanding the Brazilian agricultural frontier, which generally takes<br />

the following steps: occupation of virgin land (private or public), extraction of<br />

hardwood, installation of livestock farming and, ultimately, development of<br />

modern farming and cattle raising. Reydon proposes that land speculation is<br />

the principal engine of deforestation in the Amazon rainforest, and presents<br />

empirical data that deforestation is associated with land valuation. The author<br />

conducts an analysis of the Amazon land tenure situation in its various<br />

categories, pointing to the inability of the Brazilian state to govern over the<br />

lands in the region. The reasons for which the land issue is not appropriately<br />

dealt with in the country are evaluated through a recapturing of the historical<br />

evolution of the associated Brazilian institutional framework. Reydon concludes<br />

that adequate, participative and effective governance is a necessary, but<br />

insufficient, condition to contain deforestation in the region.<br />

Carlos Teodoro Irigaray analyzes the prospects and challenges of Brazilian<br />

law in the transition to a green economy. Irigaray starts by contextualizing<br />

green economy in the realms of sustainable development. The author argues<br />

that, from a legal perspective, the transition to a green economy requires<br />

measures that involve the structuring of a system that can effectively guide<br />

public policy, combining the use of economic instruments and command and<br />

control mechanisms, that, necessarily, should be informed by some ethical<br />

principles such as environmental justice and intra and intergenerational<br />

equity. In the context of Brazil, Irigaray identifies three main challenges to<br />

the transition: poverty, deforestation, and agriculture. The author asserts that<br />

Brazil already has a solid regulatory framework, and highlights the recognition<br />

of the fundamental right to an ecologically balanced environment associated<br />

with government and collectivity duty of defending and preserving this right.<br />

Nevertheless, some adjustments are necessary, such as institutionalizing<br />

REDD. Furthermore, the legislative advances are weakly reflected in practice.<br />

In this sense, contradictions between the policies of the Brazilian government<br />

are especially relevant.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Peter H. May brings up the issue of market mechanisms for a green economy.<br />

May claims that, from the perspective of ecological economics, instruments<br />

of natural resource management are based on two variables: the relative<br />

non-substitutability of the resource in question and its resilience (capacity to


14<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Executive Summary<br />

recover from stress or degradation). The author asserts, without ignoring the<br />

difficulty of precise their understanding, that these two variables reveal, without<br />

resorting to devices of market valuation, the biophysical constraints of human<br />

intervention. It is argued that command and control mechanisms can drive the<br />

direct regulation of resources, by establishing ceilings for levels of appropriate<br />

use (that could be null). Once caps are established, the market can act in a<br />

way to achieve efficient allocation (trade). The author specifically analyzes<br />

PES and REDD instruments. It is concluded that market mechanisms should<br />

assume an important role in the transition to a green economy, in a way that<br />

this role is mediated by regulation that defines the criteria of access and control<br />

of natural resources, reflected by biophysical limits backed by science and<br />

ample previous consultations with populations whose sustenance depends<br />

on those resources.<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta presents the topic of valuation and pricing of<br />

environmental resources in a green economy. It is argued that, due to the lack<br />

of secure property and usage rights of natural resources, externalities are not<br />

totally captured by the price system, which consequently becomes imperfect and<br />

causes inefficient allocations of these resources. Seroa da Motta reveals the<br />

components of the Economic Value of Environmental Resources (EVER): the<br />

use value (direct use, indirect use, and option) and the non-use (or existence)<br />

value. Categories of environmental services are also presented (provision,<br />

regulation, support and cultural), and related to the EVER components. The<br />

author reveals the environmental economic evaluation methods, which can be<br />

grouped into production function methods and demand function methods, and<br />

presents the complexity that such exercises involve. Seroa da Motta analyses<br />

the possibilities of internalizing environmental externalities by charging or<br />

creating markets. The author concludes with an evaluation of the limits to the<br />

potential of valuation and economic pricing of the environment.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Mário Sérgio Vasconcelos analyzes the role of financial institutions in the<br />

transition to a green economy in Brazil. The author argues that starting in<br />

the 1990’s, a series of voluntary commitments and self-regulation has been<br />

implemented by the sector. He asserts that Brazil exhibits a distinguished<br />

performance among emerging countries. The author surveys the main<br />

pacts and commitments assumed by domestic banks. The Green Protocol<br />

is emphasized as an effort to adopt socio-environmental policies that are<br />

precursory, multiplicative, demonstrative or exemplary of banking practices<br />

and that are in line with the objective of promoting sustainable development.<br />

Vasconcelos presents some measures that Brazilian banks have taken to<br />

promote sustainability in the country. The author argues that these activities<br />

result from the fact that environmental risks have generated an actual and<br />

growing impact on the four large risks faced by banking institutions. The main


15<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Executive Summary<br />

challenges of the sector are also identified. It is concluded that banks no longer<br />

play the passive role of monitoring, but rather an active role of identifying<br />

entrepreneurs, technologies and new business models.<br />

Ultimately, Ronaldo Seroa da Motta and Carolina Dubeux conduct an analysis<br />

of the measurements of policies for the transition towards a green economy.<br />

The authors argue that it is possible to understand sustainability as that which<br />

allows us to maintain the capital stock, which defines the future fluxes of goods<br />

of services, at least constant. They defend that the capacities of ecosystems to<br />

generate services have limits, which, once surpassed, cause a collapse. The<br />

definition of these limits (that is, the critical level of natural capital) determines<br />

the sustainability trajectory of an economy. The green economy is that which<br />

produces a continuous increase in the stock of natural capital. The authors<br />

analyze the creation of institutional capacity to integrate environmental policies<br />

with economic policies and a system of environmental indicators that would be<br />

capable of measuring and monitoring the benefits of natural capital investments.<br />

They propose, in this sense, a systematization of environmental indicators, the<br />

amplification of economic instruments and the removal of perverse incentives.<br />

It is concluded that environmental regulation should not be seen as a problem<br />

and that, beyond a solution, it could represent a source of economic and social<br />

benefits for Brazil.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011


16<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Delineations of a green<br />

economy<br />

Helena Boniatti Pavese 1<br />

In t r o d u c t io n<br />

Over the past 50 years, human beings have been altering ecosystems at an<br />

increasingly accelerated and intensive pace than in any other period of human<br />

history, especially due to the increasing demand for natural resources, such as<br />

food, water, timber, fibers and fuels 2 .<br />

Despite the significant contribution to economic growth and to promoting<br />

social well-being, the excessive extraction of these resources led to irreversible<br />

losses of global biodiversity and services provided by ecosystems, many of<br />

which are considered essential to human survival.<br />

Wh a t a r e e n v ir o n m e n t a l s e r v i c e s?<br />

According to the Millennium Ecosystem Assessment Report (MEA) 3 ,<br />

environmental (or ecosystem) services are defined as “the benefits people<br />

obtain from ecosystems”.<br />

They can be divided into four categories:<br />

(i) provisioning services, such as food, water and timber, etc.;<br />

(ii) regulating services, such as those that affect climate, flooding,<br />

diseases, water quality, among others<br />

(iii) cultural services, related to recreational, esthetic and spiritual; and<br />

(iv) supporting services, which include soil formation, photosynthesis and<br />

nutrient recycling.<br />

Also according to the report, close to 60% of these services have been<br />

degraded or used unsustainably, including fresh water, purification of air and<br />

water, and local and regional climate regulation 4 . These alterations increase<br />

the probability of accelerated, abrupt and irreversible changes with significant<br />

consequences for human well-being, and threaten the survival of many<br />

communities, especially in developing countries, where in some cases close<br />

to 90% of GDP is linked to nature or natural resources 5 .<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

1. Environmental Policy Manager at Conservation International Brazil and former Regional<br />

Coordinator for Latin America and the Caribbean at the World Conservation Monitoring<br />

Center of the United Nations Environment Programme (WCMC/UNEP).<br />

2. Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (2005).<br />

3. Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (2005), p. V.<br />

4. Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (2005), p.1.<br />

5. UNEP (2011a).


17<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Delineations of a<br />

green economy<br />

Helena Pavese<br />

Despite the proven intrinsic relationship between human well-being and<br />

natural resources, unsustainable economic activities still prevail. Currently,<br />

around 1-2% of the global GDP are destined to substituting practices that, in<br />

many cases, lead to the degradation of natural resources, such as fishing and<br />

agriculture 6 .<br />

These investments are motivated by the rapid accumulation of physical,<br />

financial and human capital, disregarding natural capital, and thus generating<br />

a vicious cycle through which negative impacts exerted on natural resources<br />

consequently lead to negative impacts on human well-being and the escalation<br />

of poverty.<br />

This article aims to point out the main advances in the delineations of a<br />

green economy. Beyond this introduction, the article consists of three sections.<br />

The first elaborates on the Green Economy Initiative, and the output Report on<br />

green economy, launched in February 2011. The second presents some main<br />

results raised in this Report. Ultimately, are the final remarks.<br />

Th e Gr e e n Ec o n o m y Initiative<br />

Seeking to raise evidence about the social and economic risks and costs<br />

generated by current standards of excessive resource use as well as highlight<br />

opportunities for a transition to more sustainable practices, the United Nations<br />

Environment Programme (UNEP) launched the Green Economy Initiative (GEI)<br />

in 2008. The main objective of this initiative is to support the development of a<br />

global plan for the transition to a green economy that is dominated by investment<br />

and consumption of goods and services that promote the environment.<br />

Wh a t is a g r e e n e c o n o m y?<br />

Green economy is understood as “one that results in the improvement<br />

of human well-being and social equity, while significantly reducing<br />

environmental risks and ecological scarcities”. 7<br />

A green economy is based on three main strategies: (1) the reduction<br />

of carbon emissions, (2) enhanced energy and resource efficiency and<br />

(3) the prevention of loss of biodiversity and ecosystem services.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

To become viable, these strategies must be catalyzed and supported<br />

by targeted public and private investments as well as by political reforms<br />

and regulatory changes. Also, natural capital should be maintained,<br />

enhanced and, when necessary, rebuilt, especially for poor people whose<br />

livelihoods and security depend on nature.<br />

6. UNEP (2011a). p.1.<br />

7. How is a Green Economy Defined? (n.d.) Retrieved from: .


18<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Delineations of a<br />

green economy<br />

Helena Pavese<br />

The GEI flagship is the development of the Report about green economy,<br />

launched in February 2011, “Towards a green economy: pathways to sustainable<br />

development and poverty eradication”. The document contains an analysis<br />

of macroeconomic aspects and issues linked to sustainability and poverty<br />

reduction related to investments in a range of sectors from renewable energy<br />

to sustainable agriculture. It is expected that such analysis will support the<br />

formulation of policies that can catalyze an increase in investments in these<br />

green sectors. In addition to analyzing this content, GEI provides consulting<br />

services to countries and regions and produces research products as well<br />

as promotes the establishment of partnerships with a wide range of actors,<br />

including academia, non-governmental organizations, the private sector, among<br />

others, for the effective promotion and implementation of green economy<br />

strategies.<br />

“To w a r d s a g r e e n e c o n o m y: p a t h w a y s to<br />

s u s t a in a b l e d e v e l o p m e n t a n d p o v e r t y e r a d ic a t io n”<br />

Produced by the UNEP in partnership with global economists and specialists,<br />

the report “Towards a green economy: pathways to sustainable development<br />

and poverty eradication” seeks to defend the proposal that making economies<br />

green does not necessarily imply a reduction in economic growth and<br />

employment levels. On the contrary, such a transition would allow growth to<br />

be strengthened through the generation of descent jobs 8 and would consist<br />

of a vital strategy to eliminate poverty. It is hoped that the evidence raised by<br />

this study will encourage decision makers to develop favorable conditions for<br />

increased green economy investments, based on three main strategies:<br />

1. Stimulate a change in investments, both public and private, seeking to<br />

encourage critical sectors in the transition to a green economy;<br />

2. Demonstrate how a green economy can reduce persistent poverty through<br />

a wide range of important sectors, including agriculture, forestry, fishery, water<br />

and energy; and<br />

3. Provide guidelines on policies that permit this change; through the<br />

elimination of perverse subsidies, identification of market failures, establishment<br />

of regulatory frameworks or stimulus for sustainable investments.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The report seeks to demystify the idea that there is an inevitable trade-off<br />

between social development, economic growth and environmental sustainability<br />

and dispel misconceptions that green economy is a luxury whose costs only<br />

developed countries can bear. The principal message highlighted by the Report<br />

is that:<br />

8. Employment that provide an adequate salary, social welfare and respect of workers’ rights<br />

that allow workers to express their opinions about decisions that affect their lives. Source: OIT<br />

(2009).


19<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Delineations of a<br />

green economy<br />

Helena Pavese<br />

“An investment equivalent to 2% of the global GDP in ten key sectors<br />

can combat poverty and generate greener and more efficient growth”.<br />

According to the Report, such an investment could be the initial kick-off for<br />

the transition to a green economy with efficient resource use and low carbon.<br />

The authors claim that this amount corresponds to only 1.3 trillion dollars per<br />

year and would drive global economic growth to levels that are probably higher<br />

than those of current economic models 9 .<br />

Agriculture, construction, fishery, forestry, energy supply, industry, tourism,<br />

transport, waste and water management are the 10 sectors evaluated in the<br />

study and identified as fundamental for making the global economy more<br />

green.<br />

For these sectors to transition to a greener economy, in general terms, the<br />

study puts forth the following allocation of resources 10 :<br />

• Agriculture: US$ 108 billion, includes small farms<br />

• Buildings: US$ 134 billion, applied to energy efficiency programs<br />

• Energy (supply): Above US$ 360 billion<br />

• Fisheries: US$ 110 billion, includes reducing the capacity of global fleets<br />

• Forestry: US$ 15 billion to combat climate change<br />

• Industry: US$ 75 billion<br />

• Tourism: US$ 135 billion<br />

• Transport: US$ 190 billion<br />

• Waste management: US$ 110 billion, includes recycling<br />

• Water: a similar amount, includes basic sanitation<br />

The report also presents results and recommendations for specific sectors,<br />

highlighting sectoral opportunities generated by the transition to a green<br />

economy, including poverty reduction, job creation, strengthened social equity<br />

and the maintenance and restoration of natural capital. Among these, the<br />

following stand out:<br />

Agriculture<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Reducing deforestation and increasing reforestation generate benefits<br />

for agriculture and rural communities, through the use of economic<br />

mechanisms and existing markets, such as, certifications for wood, payments for<br />

ecosystem services and potential benefits from REDD+ mechanisms, strategies<br />

that can currently be found in national and international discussion forums .<br />

9. UNEP (2011b), p.4.<br />

10. UNEP (2011a).


20<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Delineations of a<br />

green economy<br />

Helena Pavese<br />

Greener agriculture ensures food supply for a growing global population<br />

without harming the resource base of this sector. This can be done through<br />

the transition from industrial and subsistence agricultural practices to more<br />

sustainable models, with more efficient use of water, extensive use of organic<br />

or natural soil nutrients and integrated pest control 12 .<br />

The transition to a green economy also requires strengthened<br />

institutions and the development of infrastructure in rural areas of<br />

developing countries. This aspect includes the removal of ecologically<br />

perverse subsidies and the promotion of regulatory reform that incorporates<br />

the cost of degradation into food and commodity prices 13 .<br />

Greening agriculture in developing countries, concentrating on small<br />

properties, can reduce poverty while permitting investment in natural<br />

capital on which the poorest depend. The adoption of sustainable practices<br />

(such as agroforestry, integrated management of nutrients and pests) is one of<br />

the most efficient ways to increase the availability of food and facilitate access<br />

to emerging international markets for green products. Adopting such practices<br />

can move agriculture from the position as major greenhouse gas emitter to a<br />

neutral position, and also contribute to reducing deforestation and water use<br />

by 55% and 35%, respectively 14 .<br />

Water<br />

The growing scarcity of water can be mitigated through fomentation<br />

policies and investments aimed at improving the provision and efficiency<br />

of water use 15 .<br />

Investments in the provision of drinking water and sanitation services<br />

for the poor represent a great opportunity to accelerate the transition to<br />

a green economy in many developing countries. Annual investments of<br />

0.15% of the global GDP would enable global water use to be maintained at<br />

sustainable levels as well as the achievement of the Millennium Development<br />

Goals related to water by 2015 16 .<br />

The supply of jobs in the water sector would suffer temporary<br />

adjustments due to the necessity of recovering water resources.<br />

Improvements in efficiency and reductions in consumption would reduce<br />

total water consumption by 20% and employment opportunities by 25% by<br />

2050 compared to current rates. However, such forecasts do not capture new<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

11. UNEP (2011b), p.6.<br />

12. UNEP (2011b). p.7.<br />

13. UNEP (2011b). p.7.<br />

14. UNEP (2011b). p.9.<br />

15. UNEP (2011b). p.8.<br />

16. UNEP (2011b). p.10.


21<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Delineations of a<br />

green economy<br />

Helena Pavese<br />

job opportunities generated by infrastructure developments aimed at water<br />

efficiency 17 .<br />

Energy sector<br />

Renewable energy presents great economic opportunities. “Greening”<br />

the energy sector requires a substitution of investments in carbon intensive<br />

energy sources to investments in clean energy, as well as improvements in<br />

energy efficiency. Many of these investments would be rewarded in the future,<br />

considering the growth in the market for renewable technologies and the<br />

growing concern over the social costs generated by technologies based on<br />

fossil fuels 18 .<br />

Government policies play an essential role in strengthening incentives<br />

for investments in renewable energy, including time-bound incentives, feedin<br />

tariffs (payments for renewable energy that users produce), direct subsidies<br />

and tax credits 19 .<br />

A minimum allocation of 1% of the global GDP to increase energy<br />

efficiency and expand the use of renewable energy would create additional<br />

jobs and produce more competitive energy 20 .<br />

An annual investment of around 1.25% of the global GDP in energy<br />

efficiency and renewable energy could reduce global primary energy<br />

demands by 9% by 2020 and 40% by 2050 21 .<br />

Tourism<br />

The development of tourism, when well designed, can strengthen local<br />

economies and reduce poverty 22 .<br />

Fisheries<br />

Investments in the fisheries management, including the creation of<br />

protected marine areas, and deactivation and reduction in fleet capacity<br />

can recuperate the fishery resources of the planet. Such recuperation entails<br />

an increase in catches from the current 80 million tons to 90 million as well as<br />

the creation of a significant number of jobs in the sector by 2050 23 .<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

17. UNEP (2011b). p.13.<br />

18. UNEP (2011b), p.14.<br />

19. UNEP (2011b), p.15.<br />

20. UNEP (2011b), p.12.<br />

21. UNEP (2011a).<br />

22. UNEP (2011b), p.11.<br />

23. UNEP (2011a).


22<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The benefits from a transition of the fishing industry exceed 3 to 5 times<br />

the investment necessary for this transition 24 .<br />

The job supply in the fishery sector would suffer temporary adjustments<br />

due to the necessity of recovering fish stocks. “Greening” the fisheries<br />

sector would result in job losses in the short and medium terms, but the long<br />

term supply would go back up due to the recuperation of fish stocks 25 .<br />

Delineations of a<br />

green economy<br />

Helena Pavese<br />

Waste management<br />

With a 108 billion dollar annual investment in “greening” the waste sector,<br />

the global recycling of waste could triple by 2050. This would imply a reduction<br />

of more than 85% of the amounts currently deposited in landfills 26 .<br />

Such investments may result in full recycling of electronic wastes, as<br />

compared to current levels of 15% 27 .<br />

A 10% increase in the life-spans of all products produced would lead<br />

to a similar reduction in the volume of extracted resources.<br />

The job supply in the waste management sector would grow as a result<br />

of the increased waste generated by population and income growth, but<br />

the challenges related to the generation of descent employment in this<br />

sector are considerable. Currently, recycling generates around 12 million<br />

jobs in only three countries (Brazil, China and the United States) 28 . In green<br />

investment scenarios, projected growth of the job supply in the waste sector<br />

would be 10% compared to current trends.<br />

Transport<br />

Annual investments of 0.34% of the global GDP up to 2050 could reduce<br />

the use of petroleum by 80%, compared to current patterns, and elevate<br />

employment rates by 6% 29 .<br />

The environmental and social costs generated by the transport sector<br />

are currently at around 10% of the GDP of a country or region.<br />

A “greening” of the transport sector requires the creation of policies to<br />

foster the utilization of public and non-motorized transport, fuel efficiency<br />

and the development of less polluting vehicles.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

24. UNEP (2011b), p.11.<br />

25. UNEP (2011b), p.13.<br />

26. UNEP (2011a).<br />

27. UNEP (2011a), p.1.<br />

28. UNEP/ILO/IOE/ITUC (2008).<br />

29. UNEP (2011b), p.23.


23<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Delineations of a<br />

green economy<br />

Helena Pavese<br />

Gr e e n e c o n o m y: p o s s i b l e a n d d e s ir a b l e<br />

The final message transmitted by the report is that a green economy is both<br />

desirable and possible. This concept possesses the potential to promote the<br />

much desired sustainable development and poverty eradication, rapidly and<br />

effectively. A green economy favors growth with the generation of income and<br />

jobs.<br />

However, such a transformation is subject to two great changes: in the way<br />

our economy is structured and in the recognition that the environment forms the<br />

basis of our physical goods, which should be managed as sources of growth,<br />

prosperity and well-being 30 .<br />

Green investments have great potential to strengthen sectors and technologies<br />

that could be the main promoters of economic and social development in the<br />

future, including technologies for renewable energy, energy efficient construction<br />

and low-carbon transport systems 31 .<br />

Thus, in addition to technologies, complimentary investments in human capital<br />

would also be necessary, which includes generating and sharing strategies,<br />

mechanisms and policies that promote a transition to a green economy 32 .<br />

Therefore, the transition to a green economy triggers, according to the<br />

Report, a series of desirable results in the long term, whether in economic,<br />

social or environmental terms. The Report offers clear directives of what can<br />

be done in each of the ten sectors analyzed to bring about such a transition.<br />

The document supports the proposition that a transition to a green economy<br />

would bring benefits in the long term that would compensate for possible short<br />

term losses.<br />

References<br />

Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (2005). Ecosystems and Human Well-Being:<br />

Synthesis. Washington, DC: Island Press, p.1.<br />

OIT (2009). Programa Empregos Verdes. Brasília: OIT.<br />

UNEP (2011a). Rumo a uma economia verde: caminhos para o desenvolvimento<br />

sustentável e a erradicação da pobreza, Press Release United Nations Environment<br />

Programme. Retrieved from: .<br />

UNEP (2011b). Towards a Green Economy: pathways to sustainable development and<br />

poverty eradication. United Nations Environment Programme, p.4.<br />

UNEP/ILO/IOE/ITUC (2008). Green jobs: towards decent work in a sustainable, lowcarbon<br />

world. Nairobi: UNEP.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

30. UNEP (2011b), p. 37.<br />

31. UNEP (2011b), p. 37.<br />

32. UNEP (2011b), p. 37.


24<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The necessarily systemic<br />

character of the transition<br />

to a green economy<br />

Alexandre d´Avignon 1<br />

Luiz Antônio Cruz Caruso 2<br />

The green economy as defined in the United Nations Environment<br />

Programme’s (UNEP) publication, “Towards a green economy: pathways to<br />

sustainable development and poverty eradication”, brings a series of challenges.<br />

This economy seeks human well-being and social equity, while reducing<br />

environmental risks and resource scarcity, and is characterized by low carbon<br />

intensity. Certainly this was not the first expression that captures the aspirations<br />

of those who seek structural changes in the capitalist economy, focused on<br />

values other than the maximization of profits, in a perfectly competitive market<br />

tending to equilibrium. The breakthrough of this approach is essentially in its<br />

overcoming the anthropocentric view of nature and the planet, in which these<br />

must serve humankind and attend its needs. As René Passet (1991) pointed,<br />

the order and the cycles of nature must be respected so as not to exhaust its<br />

potentialities and energy sources.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The biosphere and the interactions of its subsystems (atmosphere,<br />

lithosphere, hydrosphere and biota) determine the conditions under which<br />

human activities can take place, whether social or economic. Ultimately, it is<br />

the biosphere that will determine the limits and possibilities of mutual influence<br />

between living beings and the planet. Humans are part of this whole, and an<br />

important part because of their ability to intervene in the environment, but there<br />

is not a hierarchy in which humans are at the top. The relationship between<br />

human societies and the biosphere cannot be reduced to economic or even<br />

social dimensions. Human activities such as are analyzed in economics through<br />

the relations of production, exchange, consumption, etc. represent only a first<br />

sphere of human practices in an ordainment with specific rules established,<br />

included in a broader social sphere, civil society, the state, ideologies etc. Yet<br />

the latter is circumscribed, in turn, by an even broader universe consisting of<br />

inanimate and living matter, which surrounds and extends beyond. It is within<br />

these three spheres – modes of production, formation of society and the<br />

1. Professor of the Program for Public Policies, Strategies and Development of the Economics<br />

Institute of Federal University of Rio de Janeiro (PPED/IE/UFRJ) and researcher at the<br />

Program for Energy Planning (COPPE/UFRJ).<br />

2. Doctoral student at the Program for Public Policies, Estrategies and Development of the<br />

Economics Institute of Federal University of Rio de Janeiro (PPED/IE/UFRJ).


25<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The necessarily<br />

systemic character<br />

of the transition to a<br />

green economy<br />

Alexandre d'Avignon<br />

Luiz Caruso<br />

biosphere – that human activities are inserted. The reproduction and functioning<br />

of each sphere are regulated by the other two. Due to the relationship between<br />

these three spheres of inclusion, it can be affirmed that the elements of the<br />

economic sphere belong to the biosphere and obey its laws, but that all elements<br />

of the biosphere do not belong necessarily pertain to the economic sphere of<br />

economy and are not subject to its rules. As James Lovelock (2001) states, the<br />

earth became what it is through its habitation by living beings and these have<br />

been the means but not the purpose for the planet’s development.<br />

It is interesting to observe, however, that at UNEP’s homepage on the internet,<br />

where the above publication can be accessed, is a statement in small print:<br />

“environment for development.” Is this not a contradiction of the perception<br />

of the program regarding the proposed definition of green economy in the<br />

publication?<br />

Painting neoclassical economics green is not the solution. We need a<br />

structural change in the “household management” (oikos = house + nomia =<br />

management, study or laws, according to Houaiss, 2001), referring to the planet<br />

as the home of all living beings and, as such, needing to be preserved and<br />

respected. Making the conventional economy green, from UNEP’s perspective,<br />

is to prioritize growth of income and employment. The latter are to be stimulated<br />

by public and private investments that reduce carbon emissions and pollution<br />

and promote the efficient use of energy and natural resources, preventing the<br />

loss of ecosystem services and biodiversity. These investments will be catalyzed<br />

and supported by public policy reforms and regulatory changes. The proposed<br />

route of development should maintain, enhance and, where necessary, restore<br />

natural capital, since it is a critical economic asset that generates public benefits,<br />

especially for poor people whose livelihoods and security depend essentially<br />

on nature.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Encouraging public and private entities to assume primary responsibility,<br />

in which the action of external private or public agents is proposed as the<br />

solution, is precisely the approach criticized by Elinor Ostrom (2008). According<br />

to her, this option comes from a metaphorical and specific view contained in<br />

the “Tragedy of the Commons”, described by Garrett Hardin in 1968, and the<br />

Prisoner’s Dilemma model proposed by the same author, as well as the “Logic<br />

of Collective Action” developed by Mancur Olson with the idea of free riding in<br />

joint activities in a community for the public good. Ostrom questions currently<br />

fashionable approaches involving intervention by coercive or regulatory state<br />

action or by the definition of ownership through privatization. Empirically, such<br />

approaches are associated with a huge list of failures. In Ostrom’s view, solutions<br />

should always be defined on a case-by-case basis through agreement among<br />

stakeholders, for managing what she calls the use of common resources, i.e.,<br />

public goods. The author describes a number of real alternative solutions to<br />

external intervention.


26<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The necessarily<br />

systemic character<br />

of the transition to a<br />

green economy<br />

Alexandre d'Avignon<br />

Luiz Caruso<br />

In the UNEP publication, biodiversity, as an example of a public good,<br />

would not be valued properly in neoclassical economics. Nor can neoclassical<br />

economics properly value environmental services, which contribute to human<br />

welfare and family livelihoods and could provide a source of new skilled<br />

jobs. Estimating the economic value of ecosystem services is essential for<br />

the identification of natural capital. This is one of the dimensions that would<br />

support the transition to a green economy, stimulating a change in conventional<br />

economic indicators and leading them to account for the loss of natural capital<br />

as negative and not positive components of national accounts. Is the correct<br />

valuation of these services associated with favorable conditions sufficient<br />

conditions for this transition?<br />

How can one assign new parameters to a green economy, if the essential<br />

discussion of equity and local participation is kept on the sidelines? The<br />

voracious consumption of energy and natural resources characteristic of<br />

industrialized countries shows that this is not a development model that<br />

respects the biosphere, its principles and pace of regeneration. The legacy left<br />

by development based on fossil fuels has brought to the forefront global issues<br />

such as climate change and ozone layer destruction, revealing economic options<br />

that were imposed, causing the abandonment of innovations that could have<br />

been stimulated by national innovation systems, which would involve R&D,<br />

legal framework of incentives and patent system. An important example would<br />

be the intensive use of biomass through the BTL (Biomass to Liquid) or BTG<br />

(Biomass to Gas) at a growth rate appropriate to the regenerative capacity of<br />

natural resources. Energy from solar and photovoltaic sources, wind power,<br />

hydrogen, more efficient batteries were not adequately exploited due to current<br />

technological route, causing the abandonment in the past of other options.<br />

It is worth recalling that Rudolf Diesel patented his engine to work with<br />

vegetable oils, in this case of peanuts, and even before his presentation at<br />

the Paris World Fair in 1898, there were manufactures of vehicles with electric<br />

motors. The latter have proliferated in public transport with trams, which were<br />

later replaced by internal combustion vehicles in several cities. If there had not<br />

been an imposition by specific economic sectors, these technologies could<br />

have persisted and received a share of investments from national innovation<br />

systems. In this case, the options nowadays in terms of development of<br />

technologies considered as alternatives would have been much more promising,<br />

comprehensive and widespread.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

This short historical account raises other issues related to the green economy.<br />

Could the problems generated by the economy practiced today be overcome by<br />

adopting the recommendations proposed by UNEP, during the next 20 years,<br />

as indicated by the scenario options displayed in “Towards a Green Economy:<br />

Pathways to Sustainable Development and Eradication Poverty”? Shouldn’t


27<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The necessarily<br />

systemic character<br />

of the transition to a<br />

green economy<br />

Alexandre d'Avignon<br />

Luiz Caruso<br />

the economic model proposed have been adopted years ago due to the global<br />

issues we face today such as global warming? Isn’t it now too late?<br />

In addition to the balanced access to natural and energy resources by the<br />

planet’s population, there is a need for the development of technologies based<br />

on regional vocations and not the imposition of a technological pathway derived<br />

from economies of scale and short-term profits. The technologies relating to<br />

the burning of liquid or solid fossil fuels in thermodynamic cycles generally<br />

capable of using no more than 30% of energy supplied, rather than more<br />

elegant alternatives, such as the manufacture of polymers, is an example of<br />

the imposition of a single pathway, dominated by large global organizations.<br />

Cogeneration of power and fixed systems integrated to generate electricity<br />

and heat, for example, are much more efficient and would provide yields up to<br />

50% in automobile engines.<br />

Temporal equity is another important element to be taken into account, since<br />

it brings us to the origin of the concept of sustainable development contained<br />

in “Our Common Future”, a publication resulting from the 1987 Brundtland<br />

Report. This book provides as one definition of the concept: “Development that<br />

seeks to meet the needs of the present generation without compromising the<br />

ability of future generations to meet their own needs.” This means enabling<br />

people, now and in the future, to achieve a satisfactory level of social and<br />

economic development and human and cultural accomplishment, making, at<br />

the same time, reasonable use of land resources with preservation of species<br />

and habitats. The latter element does not appear explicitly in the green economy<br />

concept proposed by UNEP, but it does appear when it proposes to prevent<br />

loss or depletion of environmental services and biodiversity.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The United Nations´ Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC),<br />

while incorporating concepts such as the precautionary principle and of<br />

common but differentiated responsibilities, also promotes another concept<br />

related to an international economy favorable and conducive to sustainable<br />

growth and development, particularly in developing countries. This perception<br />

of international cooperation is essential for a structural transformation in the<br />

economy. The creation of national innovation systems that are integrated<br />

with international systems, promote environmentally sound technologies<br />

aimed at conserving biodiversity and ecosystem services and reversing the<br />

planet´s degradation and is patents free, is increasingly imperative. Market<br />

mechanisms or governmental regulations lack the necessary vitality to drive<br />

the radical transformations required to implement a planet-level management<br />

that harmonizes the interaction between human activities and the biotic and<br />

a-biotic environments. These mechanisms do not provide adequate information<br />

or, as in the case of market-defined prices, or do not have enough information,<br />

especially in the case of governments. Moreover, these mechanisms do not<br />

seem feasible to keep pace with the urgent needs of reversing degradation,


28<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The necessarily<br />

systemic character<br />

of the transition to a<br />

green economy<br />

Alexandre d'Avignon<br />

Luiz Caruso<br />

eliminating poverty and providing quality of life for the biosphere´s inhabitants.<br />

A national system of information with the specific objective of creating agreed<br />

alternatives, associating the interested stakeholders, could develop research<br />

and technologies with a sustainable and environmentally harmonious bias.<br />

Schumpeterian and neoschumpeterian approaches provide some important<br />

elements for rethinking the economy. They focus on technology as a vector<br />

for transformation of human societies and emphasize the concept of creative<br />

destruction, aligned with the idea of using crises as levers for transformation.<br />

They do not view an economy as tending toward equilibrium, but as an everchanging<br />

system that is redesigned whenever new options or other technological<br />

paradigms emerge. In the case of evolutionary economics, the replacement<br />

of old technologies with new ones could provoke disruptions to conventional<br />

paradigms. From an environmental perspective, the main impulse leading to<br />

disruptions would be increasingly clean technological options, which would<br />

replace those that have become environmentally and climatically “obsolete.”<br />

This approach certainly would not bring extraordinary profits to entrepreneurs<br />

because they would still lack scale and competitiveness, but it would take into<br />

account the negative externalities caused by conventional, environmentally<br />

obsolete technologies. It would require temporary incentive mechanisms for<br />

the new technological to gain scale and autonomy. Such incentives would be<br />

extracted from the negative impacts, or in other words, the negative externalities<br />

of conventional technologies. For example, the value of hospitalizations caused<br />

by the use of private transport in large cities would no longer be paid by the<br />

government, if such transport were substituted by collective options without<br />

emissions.<br />

In the reflections contained in the UNEP publication, the transition to a green<br />

economy involves two types of myths. The first refers to a lack of simultaneous<br />

co-existence between economic growth and environmental sustainability. The<br />

second concerns an interpretation that the transition is a way for rich countries<br />

to perpetuate poverty in developing countries. To question the validity of these<br />

myths, the paper’s authors used the projection model T-21 (Threshold 21)<br />

and simulated the behavior of some variables, generating scenarios for a<br />

green economy. In addition, they compared these results with the results of a<br />

business-as-usual trend and concluded that there are numerous advantages<br />

to investing in natural capital. The use of scenarios to explore future trends<br />

based on current conditions is a useful tool, but it is quite fragile over a 20-year<br />

timeframe, as in the present case.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

According to the authors, the T21 model was designed to support a<br />

comprehensive and integrated planning process for countries. It consists of<br />

three pillars: economic, social and governmental. It is important to emphasize<br />

that the economic pillar includes the agriculture, industry and service sectors,<br />

which are characterized by Cobb-Douglas production functions with inputs of


29<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The necessarily<br />

systemic character<br />

of the transition to a<br />

green economy<br />

Alexandre d'Avignon<br />

Luiz Caruso<br />

labor, capital and technology (Mahmoud and El Sebaei, 2005). In this general<br />

equilibrium model variations were introduced in the dynamics of some sectors<br />

to see the impact on future GDP, employment, the intensity of resources used,<br />

emissions and environmental impacts. Eight major sectors were chosen as<br />

those capable of setting trends for transition to an economy characterized by<br />

poverty alleviation, investment in the maintenance and restoration of natural<br />

capital, job creation and improved social equity, incentives for renewable energy<br />

and energy efficiency, and urban mobility and sustainability.<br />

The first sector analyzed was forestry. The transition in this sector would<br />

require: reduced deforestation and expansion of reforestation; certification of<br />

forest products; payment for environmental services; and REDD+, assuming<br />

legal changes and modifications in local governance. Certainly, this would be a<br />

promising path, but it is important to remember that there has been no regulation<br />

of REDD+ and that the conventional activities such as production of livestock<br />

and export led monocultures are large-scale vectors that are basically contrary<br />

to this approach. Other related measures would be necessary to encourage the<br />

practice of semi- or full-confinement of livestock to reduce pressure on forests, to<br />

encourage using animal waste and plant residues for energy generation, etc.<br />

The second sector, agriculture, would require changes in family farming<br />

and agribusiness in the direction of: practices for managing soil fertility; more<br />

sustainable and efficient use of water, seed diversification; management<br />

of animal and plant health; appropriate level of mechanization; integrated<br />

management of pesticides; and integrated management of nutrients. The<br />

reduction or elimination of subsidies that distort the real cost of agricultural inputs<br />

is also required. It is interesting to emphasize that the integrated activities, such<br />

as agro-silvo-pastoral systems, are non-conventional solutions that, similar to<br />

bio-digesters for producing biogas and bio-fertilizer, deserve proper attention.<br />

Remember that integrated systems can meet most of a rural activity´s needs<br />

for energy and raw materials, both in a family and in a business operation. The<br />

wastes and residues, when properly used in rural activities, become sources<br />

of energy and fertilizer.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The third sector is related to the scarcity of water and requires improvements<br />

in managing its supply and efficient use. In developing countries, such<br />

improvements frequently need to focus on reservoirs and sanitation, associated<br />

with changes in institutional arrangements. In this case, the main focus would<br />

be the care of water bodies currently threatened by pollution caused by poor<br />

sanitation. This would certainly be the main vector for reducing waterborne<br />

diseases and creating the necessary conditions to improve the quality of life<br />

for the poor in most developing countries.<br />

In the fourth sector, fishing, the sustainable management of fisheries<br />

is paramount. Steps toward sustainable management of fisheries include<br />

strengthening management and financing the reduction of excess fishing


30<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The necessarily<br />

systemic character<br />

of the transition to a<br />

green economy<br />

Alexandre d'Avignon<br />

Luiz Caruso<br />

capacity worldwide. Such steps clearly involve external intervention, which<br />

might hinder innovative solutions related to sea culture and other practices<br />

aimed at restocking the oceans, rivers and lakes.<br />

The fifth sector, ecotourism, improvements would lead to local economic<br />

development and poverty reduction. The greening of the sector would increase<br />

local community participation, especially the poor, in the tourism value chain,<br />

thereby reducing poverty. Tourism activities often have no commitment to local<br />

activities and, instead, frequently degrade areas where local communities carry<br />

out those activities. It will be necessary to provoke a fairly sharp transformation<br />

in the culture of this sector to ensure that tourism becomes a vector for poverty<br />

alleviation.<br />

With respect to renewable energy and energy efficiency, the sixth sector,<br />

the growing supply from renewable sources reduces the risks of increasing the<br />

volatile prices characteristic of fossil fuels, and also helps to mitigate emissions<br />

of greenhouse gas emissions. There would be considerable potential for growth<br />

in this sector, through investments in renewable energy, including second<br />

generation bio-fuels. In this case, greening would require that investments<br />

migrate from carbon-intensive technologies to clean energy and energy<br />

efficiency improvements. Investments in renewable energy and energy policies<br />

could improve the living standards and health of populations.<br />

Until the outbreak of economic crisis, investments in alternative sources<br />

of renewable energies and energy efficiency (excluding nuclear sources and<br />

large hydropower projects) were steadily growing. In 2004, they totaled US$ 46<br />

billion and had multiplied almost five times by 2008, reaching US$ 173 billion,<br />

or nearly 10% of global investments in energy infrastructure according to the<br />

UNEP publication. Just in power generation, renewable and energy efficiency<br />

achieved 42 GW of the capacity installed in 2008, nearly a quarter of the total<br />

(190 GW) installed that year. The growth of investments, which range from<br />

private and public R&D to programs in private companies and government<br />

agencies, were closely associated with distributed generation, in which the<br />

small decentralized units are prioritized over centralized production.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

According to the IPCC, to stabilize CO 2 e concentrations at a level of 450 ppm<br />

by 2030 will require a reduction of 60% in CO 2 e emissions in relation to 1990.<br />

This challenge means that, within a few decades, a complete restructuring of the<br />

planet´s energy infrastructure will be required. Although not precisely estimated,<br />

according to the Stern Report these changes would absorb approximately 1% of<br />

global GDP. If we take into account the overall GDP of 2007 of US$ 54 trillion,<br />

this would mean required investments of US$ 540 billion per year. Another<br />

estimation in 2008 by the International Energy Agency indicates a need for<br />

annual investments of US$ 550 billion in alternative renewable energy sources<br />

through 2030 to stabilize concentrations at 450 ppm CO 2 e. In the case of New


31<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The necessarily<br />

systemic character<br />

of the transition to a<br />

green economy<br />

Alexandre d'Avignon<br />

Luiz Caruso<br />

Energy Finance’s Global Futures, the estimated average annual investment<br />

is US$ 515 billion.<br />

Certainly these figures are much higher today than those observed in the<br />

years before the crisis, and it would take at least three years of growth at 50%<br />

per year to reach the required levels just in the energy sector, taking into account<br />

the level of 2009 investments (US$ 162 billion). Forms of distributed power<br />

generation associated with other economic activities would be critical for this<br />

transition. For distributed generation, this means easing taxation to encourage<br />

decentralization and stimulate self-generation.<br />

In transport, the seventh sector, improving the energy efficiency of the different<br />

modes of transport is a fundamental requirement in the evolution from private<br />

to public transport and to non-motorized transport. Urban mobility is closely<br />

linked to spatial occupation across the landscape by people. In developing<br />

countries, the high urban growth and concentration observed in recent decades<br />

undermines the sustainability of cities, which wind up “dominating” areas far<br />

beyond their borders. Planning of urban land occupation and incentives to<br />

reverse the flow of migrants seem crucial to halt the continued growth of vehicles<br />

and the continued deterioration of public health in these centers. The use of<br />

high quality, electric public transport and other alternatives is fundamental for<br />

transition to take place.<br />

Finally, in the manufacturing industry, the central strategy would be to extend<br />

the life of the manufactured products by increased emphasis on redesign,<br />

remanufacture and recycling, which constitute the core of closed-circuit<br />

production. This eighth sector would be of vital importance. But how to slow the<br />

pace of production growth for a population that continues to grow? Respecting<br />

nature’s cycles and generating waste at a pace that can be absorbed by those<br />

cycles seems the best path. It is necessary, however, to make use of more<br />

sophisticated tools such as life cycle analysis to increase the efficiency in the<br />

use of natural resources and, sharply decreasing the amount of raw materials<br />

in consumer goods and durables and, as a result, the amount of energy used in<br />

manufacturing processes. The European Union has already adopted a 4-factor<br />

reduction, i.e. a quarter of the amount of raw materials for new products. Some<br />

countries already show a 10-factor reduction. Changing the current preferences<br />

from unused to recycled commodities generates substantial conflicts in some<br />

sectors. Likewise, changing the established pace of growth in the production of<br />

iron ore, soybeans and meat is a Herculean task. Dematerializing contemporary<br />

society still seems a distant dream.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Using changes in the variables proposed by the publication and applying them<br />

to the T21 model, result in the scenarios that point to a green economy growing<br />

faster than the business-as-usual while also maintaining and restoring natural<br />

capital and promoting poverty reduction (UNEP, 2011). This application bears<br />

resemblance to the World 3-91 program, established to formulate “The Limits to


32<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The necessarily<br />

systemic character<br />

of the transition to a<br />

green economy<br />

Alexandre d'Avignon<br />

Luiz Caruso<br />

Growth”, first published in 1972, later reissued as “Beyond the Limits” in 1992<br />

and finally republished in 2004 under the title “Limits Growth: 30-Year Update”,<br />

which showed that there was still hope because we had not yet exceeded the<br />

limits of no return. The limits model, based on the systems dynamics of Jay<br />

Forrester, operated in a highly aggregated fashion without taking into account<br />

political changes, war or widespread shortages.<br />

The second myth discussed in the UNEP publication – that the transition<br />

would be a way for rich countries to perpetuate poverty in developing countries<br />

– has thornier issues to address. According to Kemp and Soete (1992), we<br />

are already in a transition from a fossil fuel-based economy to a low-carbon<br />

economy. In this phase, greener economic activities would primarily use end<br />

of pipe technologies and some cleaner technologies. Moving toward a lowcarbon<br />

economy requires investments in the generation and diffusion of cleaner<br />

technologies. The diffusion of a range of cleaner technologies is subject to<br />

changes in the institutional framework that supports economic activities. A<br />

reorientation of policies related to education, and science and technology, and<br />

the integration of environmental policies with those of other sectors, would also<br />

be necessary.<br />

In the long term, many green economic activities will derive from the<br />

convergence of technologies such as nanotechnology, biotechnology and<br />

information and communication technologies. The UNEP publication calls<br />

attention to the fact that the transition from the current economy to a green<br />

economy requires a well-planned regulatory framework that creates incentives<br />

to drive green economic activities, as well as to remove barriers to green<br />

investments. However, the transition depends not only on institutional but<br />

also technological innovations. Some of these innovations are complex,<br />

multidisciplinary, and require complementarities between companies and<br />

research institutes. Miles and Leite (2010), on citing Roco (2007), identify<br />

four generations in the process of developing nanotechnologies: passive<br />

nanostructures; active nanostructures; systems of three dimensional nanosystems;<br />

and nano-systems comprised of heterogeneous molecules. Only in the<br />

first generation do we find some evidence of efforts in research and generation<br />

of innovations in developing countries.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

According to Fonseca, Bianchi and Stallivieri (2010), the core of modern<br />

biotechnology is built around the basic knowledge of genetic engineering, i.e.,<br />

molecular biology, genomics and proteomics. In 2009, however, of the total<br />

projects in genomics, 91% were concentrated in the United States, Britain,<br />

Japan, France and Germany. If this indicates a trend toward domination of new<br />

technologies by developed countries, it is appropriate to add a further reflection<br />

regarding socio-technical transition. According to Geels and Schot (2007),<br />

the socio-technical regime is an extended version of the technological regime<br />

of Nelson and Winter (1982), which refers to shared cognitive routines in an


33<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The necessarily<br />

systemic character<br />

of the transition to a<br />

green economy<br />

Alexandre d'Avignon<br />

Luiz Caruso<br />

engineering community that explain development patterns along technological<br />

trajectories. Sociologists of technology expanded this explanation, arguing that<br />

scientists, political decision makers, users and special interest groups also<br />

contribute to the standardization of technological development.<br />

If there is a technological regime dominated by developed countries that<br />

strongly condition the technological development of developing countries,<br />

windows of opportunity could be built that would be particularly conducive to<br />

the development of cleaner technologies in nanotechnology and biotechnology.<br />

Certainly there is no guarantee that this will be done, since the ownership of<br />

the technology and the pathways for its development adds value to the product<br />

of developed countries.<br />

Concerning professional training and qualifications, the UNEP publication<br />

emphasizes the need to retrain the workforce as part of the restructuring process<br />

needed to transition to a green economy. This emphasis is particularly important<br />

for the change in the energy matrix that is taking place in developed countries.<br />

The publication also highlights that the withdrawal of investments in fishery<br />

assets will generate a need to retrain the workers in this sector. Furthermore,<br />

it is worth noting that, according to the OECD (2011), qualified people play a<br />

crucial role in innovation through the new knowledge that they generate, how<br />

they adopt and adapt existing ideas, and their ability to learn new skills and<br />

adapt to a changing environment. The OECD also highlights the importance of<br />

becoming familiar with the different types of skills that contribute to innovation<br />

and better ways to build them, so as to design policies that contribute to the<br />

sustainable development of such skills.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

In this sense, the OECD also points out that the qualifications for innovation<br />

could be any skill, proficiency, competency or attribute that contributes to the<br />

implementation of new products, processes, marketing methods or methods<br />

to organize the workplace. When it comes to establishing some type of<br />

measurement, the focus is on the group known as human resources in science<br />

and technology (HRST). The HRST are the people involved or who have<br />

adequate training to be involved in the production, development, dissemination<br />

and application of systematic scientific and technological knowledge. Within<br />

the HRST, researchers are an important group, because the effectiveness of<br />

spending on R&D critically depends on the efficient allocation of workers directly<br />

involved in its implementation. The number of these workers is therefore an<br />

important indicator of a nation´s scientific and technological capacity. In 2006<br />

there were about four million researchers working in R&D in OECD countries,<br />

i.e., a ratio of 7.4 researchers per 10,000 employees (OECD, 2011).<br />

Although there is not an equivalent indicator for developing countries, and<br />

since their rates of completing higher education are lower, we can infer that these<br />

countries show a significant difference in their ability to generate innovations in<br />

relation to developed countries. Thus, if developing countries do not have clear


34<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The necessarily<br />

systemic character<br />

of the transition to a<br />

green economy<br />

Alexandre d'Avignon<br />

Luiz Caruso<br />

policies, and in the absence of international regulations that promote technology<br />

transfer from developed countries to developing countries, the second myth<br />

could become a reality.<br />

The UNEP document raises another delicate point in discussing this concept<br />

and associating it with the sectors that generate the greatest emissions of<br />

anthropogenic greenhouse gases in developing countries, such as agriculture<br />

and forests, related to land use. Developed countries as a group are still those<br />

that emit more and the sectors responsible for most emissions in these countries<br />

– such as conventional power generation using coal, transport and buildings<br />

– were practically out of the discussion, with the exception of transport and<br />

renewable energy. It is necessary to provide greater details on the emissions<br />

of developed countries and suggest solutions to decarbonize their economies,<br />

as well as mechanisms to contribute effectively to “greening” the economies<br />

of developing economies.<br />

In sum, the UNEP document seems to present an overly optimistic vision<br />

about the transition to a green economy. An effective transition would occur<br />

if there were a change in the prevailing view about the solutions contained in<br />

the UNEP report, such as those associated with the need for governmental<br />

regulations or the definition of property rights through privatization as proposed<br />

by neoliberals.<br />

Local solutions seem to provide a clue and may become an important driver of<br />

innovations in the workplace, in association with interest groups. The search for<br />

flexible solutions, in which there is greater participation of affected communities,<br />

seems to be a decisive factor for a desired transition. The questioning of<br />

developed countries´ voracity for energy and natural resources, to the detriment<br />

of developing countries, appears to be another essential element. Equity in the<br />

use of these resources would build the solidarity required for a transition to an<br />

economy that is more harmonious with the environment, while seeking other<br />

theoretical lines, beyond the neoclassical, that provide a conceptual foundation<br />

for alternatives to the degrading pathway which we are currently following.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

References<br />

Debier, J. C., Deléage, J. P. and Hermery, D. (2002). Uma história da energia. Brasília:<br />

Edunb.<br />

Fonseca, M. G. D., Bianchi, C. and Stallivieri, F. (2010). Biotecnologia no Brasil: uma<br />

avaliação do seu potencial empresarial e industrial. Brasília: SENAI.<br />

Geels, F. W. and Schot, J. (2007). Typology of sociotechnical transition pathways.<br />

Research Policy, Amsterdam, 36, 399-417.<br />

Houaiss, A. (2001). Dicionário Houaiss da Língua Portuguesa. Rio de Janeiro: Ed.<br />

Objetiva.<br />

Kemp, R. and Soete, L. (1992). The greening of technological progress: an evolutionary<br />

perspective. Futures, 24(5), 437-457.


35<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The necessarily<br />

systemic character<br />

of the transition to a<br />

green economy<br />

Alexandre d'Avignon<br />

Luiz Caruso<br />

Lovelock, J. (2001). Gaia – um modelo para dinâmica planetária e celular. In W. I.<br />

Thompson (org.), Gaia, uma teoria do conhecimento. 3ª ed. São Paulo: Gaia.<br />

Mahmoud, A. S. and El Sebaei, N. M. (Ed.) (2005). Proceedings of the Workshop T21<br />

Model as a tool for studying the future of development in developing countries. Cairo:<br />

Center for Future Studies.<br />

Meadows, D. and Randers, J. (2007). Limites do crescimento, a atualização de 30 anos.<br />

Rio de Janeiro: Qualitymark.<br />

Miles, I. and Leite, E. (2010). Nanotecnologia: oportunidades para a indústria e novas<br />

qualificações profissionais. Brasília: SENAI.<br />

Nelson, R. R. and Winter, S. G. (1982). An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change.<br />

Belknap Press, Cambridge, Mass. and London.<br />

Nobre, M. and Amazonas, M. C. (2002). Desenvolvimento sustentável: a<br />

institucionalização de um conceito. Brasília: IBAMA.<br />

OECD (2011). Skills for innovation and research. Paris: OECD.<br />

ONU (1994). CQNUMC.<br />

Ostrom, E. (2008) Governing de commons, the evolution of institutions for collective<br />

action, 22nd printing. Cambridge: University Press.<br />

Passet, R. (1979). L´économique et le vivant. Paris: Payot.<br />

UNEP (2011). Towards a Green Economy: Pathways to Sustainable Development and<br />

Poverty Eradication - A Synthesis for Policy Makers. Retrieved from: .<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011


36<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy and/or<br />

sustainable development?<br />

Donald Sawyer 1<br />

Green Economy, in addition to international governance and poverty<br />

eradication, will be a central theme of the <strong>Rio+20</strong> conference in 2012 (UN,<br />

2011). This term, which first emerged in the context of the Earth Summit in 1992<br />

(Adams, 1997), was recently elaborated upon in a United Nations Environment<br />

Programme report published in six languages (UNEP, 2011). In short order,<br />

an apparent global consensus was reached (Belinky, 2011). Green Economy<br />

seems to be an alternative to Sustainable Development, which had been<br />

acclaimed in Rio de Janeiro in 1992.<br />

Green Economy is directly related to climate change: low carbon, energy<br />

efficiency, renewable energy etc. (Gouvello, 2010; ESMAP, 2010). In order<br />

to compensate for the strong emphasis on climate since 2007, biodiversity<br />

and ecosystems were reincorporated in the international discourse through<br />

an initiative called The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity (TEEB),<br />

organized by UNEP and funded by the European Commission and European<br />

governments 2 (Sukhdev, 2010, 2011). However, the environmental impacts of<br />

industrial pollution and urban waste (the “brown agenda”) as well as oceans,<br />

surface and ground water (the “blue agenda”) are not receiving the attention<br />

they deserve. Flows of atmospheric water (“aerial rivers”), which could be the<br />

focus of a “white agenda”, remain invisible in the policy arena (Salati, 2009;<br />

Arraut et al., 2011).<br />

The treatment given to Green Economy will make big differences for public<br />

policies, the role of the State (the governance that we have now) and production<br />

and consumption patterns. It will generate a wide variety of repercussions<br />

throughout Brazil and the world. The expected positive effects may not<br />

materialize and various unexpected negative effects could lead to unpleasant<br />

surprises if there is not adequate analysis of all the relevant factors at play.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

1. Professor at the Center for Sustainable Development of the University of Brasília (CDS/<br />

UnB) and Associate Researcher at the Institute for Society, Population and Nature (ISPN).<br />

The research was carried out with support from the European Union, through the projects<br />

on “Eco-social Links among Brazilian Forests: Sustainable Livelihoods in Productive<br />

Landscapes” (FLORELOS) and “Environmental Governance in Latin America and the<br />

Caribbean” (ENGOV), among other sources, but does not necessarily represent the<br />

viewpoints of these institutions or sources, being the exclusive responsibility of the author.<br />

2. Germany, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden and the United Kingdom.


37<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy and/or<br />

sustainable development?<br />

Donald Sawyer<br />

Caution is required in use of the term Green Economy, apparently instead of<br />

Sustainable Development, a term sometimes considered worn out and misused<br />

(FASE, 2011). Great care must be taken to avoid outcomes that are insignificant<br />

or even perverse, especially by diverting attention to issues and territories that<br />

are of secondary importance, without maintaining diverse ecosystems functions<br />

or attending to present and future human needs.<br />

Despite the similarities, Green Economy runs great risks of being transformed<br />

into something very different from Sustainable Development. Although it is<br />

vague, the term Sustainable Development (Brundtland, 1987) and its explicit<br />

meaning (meeting present needs without compromising the ability of future<br />

generations to meet their own needs) were approved by all the countries in<br />

the world in 1992. It must be remembered that any consensual diplomatic<br />

language, especially as a result of global agreements, is necessarily vague.<br />

Green Economy, in addition to lacking strong political support, may be worse<br />

than Sustainable Development in terms of its implicit meaning and its possible<br />

uses and abuses.<br />

Since it requires meeting the needs of present and future generations, i.e<br />

establishing both intra- and intergenerational equity, Sustainable Development<br />

is necessarily systemic in space and time and among sectors. Green Economy,<br />

on the other hand, may not go beyond superficial inclusion of a few new sectors<br />

or additional layers. Green activities or projects currently in fashion might not go<br />

far beyond photovoltaic panels, wind turbines, remote national parks, recycling<br />

schemes, organic farms and jungle lodges, without changing what really<br />

counts: unsustainable production and consumption patterns. Green Economy<br />

can easily be turned into cosmetic greenwashing, not to mention doing little or<br />

nothing to reduce poverty.<br />

Green Economy, based on monetary valuation and economic instruments,<br />

tends to reduce everything to monetary values, foreseeing payments made<br />

by polluters and received by environmental service providers (World Bank,<br />

2010). This does not necessarily imply “market environmentalism” (FASE,<br />

2011), but it is not true that everything in life is or should be commodities. We<br />

cannot avoid cost-benefit calculations and the reality of the financial world, but<br />

not everything in society, the population and nature can be reduced to goods<br />

or services. There are no markets for human beings, cultures, rights, health,<br />

flora, fauna or ecological functions.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Worse yet is the probability that there will never be enough money in Brazil<br />

or the world to pay for all the existing environmental services. For example, if<br />

the Legal Reserves and Permanent Preservation Areas defined in the Brazilian<br />

Forest Code have a total area of 100 million hectares and the owners receive<br />

only $200 per hectare per year to not deforest these areas, a conservative<br />

estimate, the annual total cost would be $20 billion. The Brazilian Family Grant


38<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy and/or<br />

sustainable development?<br />

Donald Sawyer<br />

(Bolsa Família) program costs $10 billion per year. Would government ever<br />

spend more on payments for environmental services than on family grants?<br />

The World Bank estimates that Brazil would need $21 billion per year to reduce<br />

carbon emissions (Agência Brasil, 2010; World Bank, 2010). Others estimate<br />

$13 billion (EFE, 2010). Meanwhile, the government is trying hard to cut $30<br />

billion from its budget.<br />

Payment for Environmental Services (PES) has great appeal, but raises<br />

various questions (Amazonas, 2010; Pirard et al., 2010). One of the risks of<br />

paying producers for their services provided is that it suggests that anyone else<br />

not receiving these payments is not obliged to behave correctly. Another risk<br />

is the implication that anyone who receives PES has the right to destroy the<br />

environment if and when payments are no longer received. Moreover, there<br />

is the problem of “free-riders”. In this case, rural producers who do not protect<br />

nature benefit for free from the services provided by producers that sacrifice<br />

production for the benefit of nature.<br />

There are also fundamental ethical questions. Is it correct to pay someone<br />

not to harm others? Should the costs of negative externalities not be assumed<br />

by producers, rather than being passed on to taxpayers or consumers? On<br />

the other hand, do positive externalities require remuneration? In the event of<br />

compensation, as could happen with international payments, is there not a sort<br />

of “indulgence”, i.e. paying a fee to continue living in sin (polluting)?<br />

As for international transfers of new and additional financial resources<br />

from developed to developing countries, it is certainly possible to make such<br />

demands, but it would be unwise to expect much actual payment, especially<br />

in the case of relatively developed countries like Brazil, which aspires to play a<br />

role of global leadership. It is clear that donors are now giving priority to small<br />

islands and Africa.<br />

It is important to perceive the economic interests underlying the new<br />

proposals. On the one hand, changing the noun from “development,” with<br />

its multiple dimensions (at least social and environmental, if not others) to<br />

“economy” limits the scope to only one of the dimensions. This tends to empower<br />

economists and their “economic instruments” as opposed to state regulation,<br />

which is denigrated as “command and control”. Nature becomes “natural<br />

capital”. This approach seems to be based on professional class interests. On<br />

the other hand, many governments, entrepreneurs and NGOs seek to jump on<br />

the bandwagon or gravy train of opportunities for green business and managing<br />

the new funds.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

International or global governance, in turn, tends to empower UNEP or<br />

another agency to receive generous funding and become a specialized<br />

international super-agency, with potential international police powers. However,<br />

such an agency would be subject to the interests of the donors.


39<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy and/or<br />

sustainable development?<br />

Donald Sawyer<br />

At the same time, international or global governance contradicts sovereignty,<br />

a fundamental and practically sacred principle. Although problematic in<br />

practical terms, sovereignty should only be questioned in extreme cases of<br />

grave violations, not in diffuse, routine affairs. It would be more coherent and<br />

defensible if international interventions were approved by the United Nations,<br />

not by a specialized agency.<br />

The appeal of the adjective “green” seems to have been taken over from<br />

political movements, including green parties and environmental movements<br />

such as Greenpeace, which share few or none of the principles on which<br />

the Green Economy is based. At a first glimpse, “green” would have more in<br />

common with the environment than sustainability, but in reality it narrows the<br />

scope in various ways. Sustainability is not just green, but includes a whole<br />

range of colors, if not lying somewhere over the rainbow.<br />

The Green Economy discourse is well developed in terms of natural<br />

capital, poverty reduction, low carbon, energy efficiency, innovation and global<br />

governance, all of which are interesting features. However, it should be noted<br />

that all these concepts or terminologies can also be ingenious ways to replace<br />

or relegate sovereignty, equity, nature, ecological functions, sustainable use,<br />

fundamental human and citizenship rights and reduction of emissions (which<br />

can include use and sequestration of carbon), among other important values.<br />

In practice, topical “green” changes can constitute alternatives that avoid<br />

systemic change. Green Economy runs the risk of being limited to tokenism<br />

that actually maintains the status quo in environment, society and the economy.<br />

It could perpetuate the almost exclusive focus on the Amazon rainforest to the<br />

detriment of other biomes and urban areas where the majority of the population<br />

lives. Ultimately, it lets governments get off the hook instead of doing what they<br />

should or have committed to doing.<br />

Thus, there are various possible perverse and unexpected effects of the<br />

Green Economy approach that should be taken into account. Existing proposals<br />

seem to ignore rebound and backfire effects resulting from increased efficiency.<br />

Did the Industrial Revolution not increase efficiency and unleash consumption?<br />

A few green jobs, albeit entirely positive when seen in isolation, can eliminate<br />

many conventional jobs through the substitution of labor by modern technology<br />

(capital).<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

More than promoting innovation and patents, a discourse used to justify<br />

investments in scientific research (MCT, 2010a, 2010b), countries like Brazil<br />

need application of technologies that are already known. They are in greater<br />

need of competence than innovation. Brazil does not have enough engineers,<br />

qualified construction workers, truck and tractor drivers, trained electricians<br />

and teachers at all levels. Bridges and roads collapse or become blocked,<br />

electric power is subject to frequent blackouts and the quality of education is


40<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy and/or<br />

sustainable development?<br />

Donald Sawyer<br />

far from sufficient. Improving this situation does not require new technologies<br />

transferred from developed countries.<br />

In the final analysis, the Green Economy may favor the rich and central<br />

countries. It seems to be a strategy to promote sale of technology from the<br />

North to countries of the South. Although it does not confuse “sustained growth”<br />

with Sustainable Development, which is a common error, growth in GDP<br />

continues to be the top priority, as long as it is uncritically classified as green<br />

(Latouche, 2005). Green Economy leaves out vulnerability and adaption to<br />

climate change (Lahsen, 2010) and justifies incentives or subsidies for various<br />

green lobbies.<br />

In sum, in order to contribute significantly to Sustainable Development rather<br />

than avoiding it, Green Economy cannot be limited to isolated, business-oriented<br />

initiatives supported by policies with such a narrow focus. Private enterprise<br />

needs to be involved, but policies and programs would have to be public in<br />

terms of guaranteeing fundamental rights and maintaining interdependent<br />

ecosystem functions. Green Economy would have to be a social-ecosystemic<br />

strategy adopted by the State and covering all sectors and territories.<br />

Some of the participants in the process are aware of these issues. The<br />

Chinese diplomat responsible for coordinating the organization of <strong>Rio+20</strong>,<br />

Secretary-General Sha Zukang, insists that we are dealing with Green Economy<br />

in the context of Sustainable Development and poverty reduction. To him, who<br />

has strong political support, the conference is not about an isolated Green<br />

Economy, but one that exists within a broader economic and social context.<br />

Various other visions of the future are possible (Bursztyn, 2008; Sachs, 2010;<br />

Machado, 2010; Sanwal, 2011; Abramovay, 2009; Lesbaupin, 2010; Prins,<br />

2010; Martins, 2010). Recently, new anti-capitalist proposals have emerged<br />

in Latin America, such as the rights of nature and Pacha Mama, against the<br />

mercantilization of nature (Bacarji, 2010; UNDP, 2010). Dialogue would be<br />

desirable and, from a United Nations perspective, necessary.<br />

Most important of all would be to see what could be done here and<br />

now, without ambitious treaties, global governance agencies, new financial<br />

resources and transfer of new technologies (Sawyer, 2011). There is room<br />

for action on various levels: national, bilateral, regional and among emerging<br />

countries. Otherwise, good intentions could generate innocuous or negative<br />

results.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

In the short run, Sustainable Development could be operationalized in<br />

terms of already existing fundamental rights, such as human rights, which are<br />

universal, or citizenship rights, which are national (ESCR-Net et al., 2010; IISD,<br />

2010; Lusiani, 2010; Santilli, 2005; Sousa, 2010; Varella, Leuzinger, 2008).<br />

Rights refer to ethical values (Grasso, 2010) and imply duties. One’s own<br />

rights end where the rights of others begin. The rights of future generations to


41<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy and/or<br />

sustainable development?<br />

Donald Sawyer<br />

meet their needs depend on the duties of present generations and limit their<br />

freedom. This realist approach, within existing legal frameworks and institutions,<br />

is possible.<br />

In conclusion, both Green Economy and Sustainable Development can and<br />

should be promoted. Green Economy can be more concrete, instrumental<br />

and popular, and Sustainable Development more abstract, diplomatic and<br />

governmental. The economic approach labeled as green can generate<br />

awareness among decision-makers, appeal to business interests and placate<br />

proponents of development, especially in developing countries. However, the<br />

advances of 1992, which constitute an historical landmark for humanity, should<br />

not be lost from sight, nor should the Earth Charter and the progress achieved<br />

over the past 20 years. What really matters are the needs of the planet and<br />

present and future generations, all of which depend on functioning ecosystems,<br />

with or without additional financial resources, transfer of technologies and new<br />

forms of global governance.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

References<br />

Abramovay, R. (2009, December 10). Muito mais que o clima, discute-se o capitalismo.<br />

Valor Econômico, p. D10.<br />

Adams, W. M. (1997). Green development: environment and sustainability in the Third<br />

World. London: Routledge.<br />

Agência Brasil (2010, November 11). “Banco Mundial diz que Brasil precisa de R$34,2<br />

bi por ano para reduzir emissões de carbono”.<br />

Amazonas, M. C. (2010). Pagamento por serviços ambientais: dilemas conceituais e<br />

normativos. Brasília: Instituto Sociedade, População e Natureza (ISPN).<br />

Arraut, J., Nobre, C., Barbosa, H. M. J., Obregon, G. and Marengo, J. (2011). Southward<br />

moisture flow from Amazonia, seasonal aerial rivers and subtropical rainfall in South<br />

America. São José dos Campos: INPE. No prelo.<br />

Bacarji, C. D. (2010). Direitos da Mãe Terra: projeto de declaração gera polêmica.<br />

Envolverde, 22 apr.<br />

Belinky, A. (2011). Rumo à Rio 2012: considerações sobre a 1ª reunião intersessional<br />

preparatória. São Paulo: Instituto Vitae Civilis.<br />

Brundtland, G. H. et al. (1987). Nosso futuro comum. Comissão Mundial sobre Meio<br />

Ambiente e Desenvolvimento. New York: UN.<br />

Bursztyn, M. (2008). Think locally, act globally: new challenges to environmental<br />

governance. Cambridge: Sustainability Science Program, Kennedy School of<br />

Government, Harvard University.<br />

EFE (2010, November 11). Brasil precisa de US$ 20 bilhões por ano para reduzir<br />

emissões de gases. Folha de São Paulo, Ambiente.<br />

ESCR-Net - International Network for Economic, Social and Cultural Rights and Center<br />

of Concern et al. (2010). Guidelines for a human rights approach to economic policy<br />

in agriculture. New York: Kuala Lumpur.<br />

ESMAP - Energy Sector Management Assistance Program (2010). Low carbon<br />

development for Brazil. Washington: World Bank, Low Carbon Growth Country<br />

Studies Program, Mitigating Climate Change through Development.<br />

FASE (2011). <strong>Rio+20</strong>: resistir ao ambientalismo de mercado e fortalecer os direitos e<br />

a justiça ambiental. Rio de Janeiro: Federação de Órgãos para Assistência Social e<br />

Educacional. Retrieved from: < http://www.fase.org.br/v2/pagina.php?id=3484><br />

Gouvello, C. et al. (2010). Brazil low-carbon: country case study. Brasília: World<br />

Bank.<br />

Grasso, M. (2010). An ethical approach to climate adaptation finance. Global<br />

Environmental Change, 20(1), 74-81.


42<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy and/or<br />

sustainable development?<br />

Donald Sawer<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

IISD (2010). Summary of the Fifth Rights and Resources Initiative (RRI) Dialogue on<br />

Forests, Governance and Climate Change, 22 June 2010.<br />

Lahsen, M. (2010). Impacts, adaptation and vulnerability to global environmental change:<br />

challenges and pathways for an action-oriented research agenda for middle-income<br />

and low-income countries. Current Opinion in Environmental Sustainability, n.2,<br />

364-74.<br />

Latouche, S. (2005). Vers la décroissance ou écodémocratie. Le Monde Diplomatique,<br />

52(620).<br />

Lesbaupin, I. (2010). Por uma nova concepção de desenvolvimento. Le Monde<br />

Diplomatique Brasil, nov., p.32.<br />

Lusiani, N. (2010). Human rights can fix our broken agricultural system, advocates<br />

argue. Retrieved from: .<br />

Machado, T. C. (2010). Ignacy Sachs: a <strong>Rio+20</strong> deveria superar a Rio-92. Retrieved<br />

from: .<br />

Martins, A. (2010). Fórum Social Mundial: adeus à autoreferência? IPS/Envolverde,<br />

28 jan.<br />

MCT (2010a). Consolidação das recomendações da 4ª Conferência Nacional de Ciência,<br />

Tecnologia e Inovação para o Desenvolvimento Sustentável. Brasília: Ministério da<br />

Ciência e Tecnologia.<br />

MCT (2010b). Livro azul: 4ª Conferência Nacional de Ciência, Tecnologia e Inovação<br />

para o Desenvolvimento Sustentável. Brasília: Ministério da Ciência e Tecnologia.<br />

MMA (2010). Plano de ação para produção e consumo sustentáveis: PPCS. Brasília:<br />

Ministério do Meio Ambiente.<br />

Pirard, R., Billé, R. and Sembrès, T. (2010). Questioning the theory of payments for<br />

ecosystem services (PES) in light of emerging experience and plausible developments.<br />

Analyses, n.4, 10 jun.<br />

Prins, G. et al. (2010). The Hartwell paper: a new direction for climate policy after the<br />

crash of 2009. Oxford: Institute for Science, Innovation and Society.<br />

Sachs, I. (2010). In search of three-win solutions: the challenges of the 2012 Conference<br />

on Environment and Sustainable Development. Paper prepared for the 2nd<br />

International Conference on Climate, Sustainability and Development in Semi-arid<br />

Regions (ICID 2010). Fortaleza, Ceará, August 16-20.<br />

Salati, E. (coord.) (2009). Economia das mudanças climáticas no Brasil: estimativas<br />

da oferta de recursos hídricos no Brasil em cenários futuros de clima (2015-2100).<br />

Revisado. Rio de Janeiro: Fundação Brasileira para o Desenvolvimento Sustentável<br />

(FBDS).<br />

Santilli, J. (2005). Socioambientalismo e novos direitos: proteção jurídica à diversidade<br />

biológica e cultural. São Paulo; Peirópolis; Brasília: Instituto Internacional de<br />

Educação do Brasil (IEB).<br />

Sanwal, M. (2011). Vision for the <strong>Rio+20</strong> Summit. MEA Bulletin, n.111, p.1.2, 11 mar.<br />

Sawyer, D. (2011). A global climate treaty? Ein globaler Klimavertrag? Un traité mondial<br />

sur le climat? EuroChoices, 10(1), p.45.<br />

Sukhdev, P. (2010). The economics of ecosystems and biodiversity: ecological and<br />

economic foundations. Retrieved from: .<br />

Sukhdev, P (2011). The economics of ecosystems and biodiversity in national and<br />

international policy making. Retrieved from: .<br />

Sousa Júnior, J. G. (2010). O direito e a cidadania. Darcy, n.5. nov./dec.<br />

UN (2011). Synthesis report on best practices and lessons learned on the objective<br />

and themes of the conference. New York: United Nations. Retrieved from: .<br />

UNDP (2010). World People’s Conference on Climate Change and the Rights of Mother<br />

Earth, Cochabamba, Bolivia, 19-22 April 2010: summary and analysis. New York:<br />

United Nations Development Programme.<br />

UNEP (2011). Towards a Green Economy: pathways to Sustainable Development<br />

and poverty eradication; a synthesis for policy makers. Nairobi: United Nations<br />

Environment Programme.<br />

Varella, M. D. and Leuzinger, M. D. (2008). O meio ambiente na Constituição de 1988:<br />

sobrevoo por alguns temas vinte anos depois. Revista de Informação Legislativa,<br />

v.45, no.179, jul./sep., p.397-402.<br />

World Bank (2010). Economics of adaptation to climate change: synthesis report.<br />

Washington: World Bank. 136p.


43<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

International perspectives<br />

of the transition to a<br />

low-carbon green economy 1<br />

Eduardo Viola 2<br />

In it ia l c o n s id e r a t io n s<br />

A fundamental dimension of an international green economy is the low<br />

carbon intensity, which will be the focus of this article. A solid transition to a<br />

green economy assumes the continuous reduction of carbon emissions in<br />

developed countries, an accelerated decrease in the emissions growth curve<br />

starting before 2020 and the establishment of a stabilizing year for emerging<br />

mid-income countries, in addition to an accelerated decrease in the carbon<br />

intensity of GDP globally. In the case of rich countries, there should be an<br />

accelerated decrease in per capita emissions, and in the case of mid-income<br />

countries, an accelerated reduction in the carbon intensity of GDP and a light<br />

and continued fall in per capita emissions. Poor countries would still be allowed<br />

space to increase their per capita emissions.<br />

Emissions of GHG grew by 3% during the first decade of the 21st century,<br />

according to information from the Netherlands Environmental Assessment<br />

Agency 3 . Including figures from diverse sources on deforestation in Brazil and<br />

Indonesia, the main emitters in 2009 were: China, responsible for 24% of the<br />

global total (and a 5% annual growth over the last decade), the US with 19% of<br />

total emissions (and 0.8% annual growth), the European Union (27 countries)<br />

with 15% of the total (growing at 0.3% annually), India with 7% of the total<br />

(growing at 6% per year), Russia with 5% of the total (and annual growth of<br />

5%), Brazil with 4% of the total (4% annual growth until 2004, which drastically<br />

reduced between 2005 and 2009), Indonesia with 4% (growing by 4% per year),<br />

Japan with 3.5% (0.4% annual growth), Mexico with 2.5% of the total (growing<br />

at 2% annually), Canada with 2% of the total (growing at 1.5% per year), South<br />

Africa with 1.5% per year (growing at 2% per year), South Korea with 1.5% of<br />

the total (growing by 0.7% annually) and Saudi Arabia with 1.5% of the total<br />

(growing at 6% per year).<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

1. Article written to be published by Conservation International in a volume about green<br />

economy.<br />

2. Full Professor at the Institute of International Relations, University of Brasília, Coordinator of<br />

the Climate Change and International Relations Research Network and Senior Researcher at<br />

the Brazilian Council for Scientific and Technological Development.<br />

3. The most important institute producing data on greenhouse gas emissions in the world.


44<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

International<br />

perspectives of the<br />

transition to a<br />

low-carbon green<br />

economy<br />

Eduardo Viola<br />

These 13 countries (considering the European Union as one unit) are<br />

responsible for over 80% of global emissions and constitute the two crucial<br />

groups of great and medium powers. The great powers share three highly<br />

relevant characteristics: the first and essential, each one is responsible for<br />

a high proportion of global carbon emissions (at least 15%) and of global<br />

GDP; secondly, they possess important technological and human capital for<br />

decarbonizing the economy; and thirdly, they have veto power over any global<br />

international agreement that is effective. The medium powers are of limited<br />

relevance in terms of their participation in emissions and the global economy and<br />

none of them alone has veto capabilities over a global international agreement.<br />

There are three great powers – the US, China and the European Union –<br />

that stand for 54% of global GDP and 58% of global carbon emissions. The<br />

European Union is isolated in the defense of an effective global architecture for<br />

a rapid transition to a low-carbon economy. The US and China resist a global<br />

agreement on a transition to low-carbon. There are ten medium powers: India,<br />

Russia, Brazil, Indonesia, Japan, Mexico, Canada, South Africa, South Korea<br />

and Saudi Arabia.<br />

The severity of the 2008 economic crisis opened a limited window of<br />

opportunity for a partial transformation of values in developed and emerging<br />

countries in the direction of a diminished importance attributed to immediatism,<br />

which favors the perception of the gravity of the climate issue. Since the<br />

economic crisis is systemic, the recuperation process currently on course does<br />

not imply the return to a situation similar to that existing prior to September 2008.<br />

As opposed to what the majority of international economists and analysts had<br />

imagined in mid-2008, a substantial part of the economic stimulus packages<br />

initiated in November 2008 in various key countries propelled the transition to<br />

a low-carbon economy: 65% of the increased spending in South Korea, 35%<br />

in China, 20% in the United Kingdom, 20% in Germany and 15% in the United<br />

States (Stern, 2009). Brazil, India, South Africa, Indonesia and Russia had very<br />

poor progress in this case.<br />

This article is organized in four parts. In the first, the current situation and<br />

main policies of the great and medium powers in the transition to a low carbon<br />

green economy will be analyzed. In the second part, the specific situation of<br />

South America in this transition will be summarized. In the third part, the main<br />

techno-economic vectors in the transition to a low carbon green economy will<br />

be described. Finally, the fourth part contains a reflection on future perspectives<br />

of the transition on a global level.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011


45<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

International<br />

perspectives of the<br />

transition to a<br />

low-carbon green<br />

economy<br />

Eduardo Viola<br />

Th e Gr e a t p o w e r s a n d t h e m e d iu m p o w e r s in t h e<br />

t r a n s it io n t o a l o w c a r b o n e c o n o m y<br />

The US continues to be the most important country in the international climate<br />

negotiations, due to its status as second largest emitter and for continuing to<br />

have the greatest potential for technological innovation of global impact in the<br />

direction of low carbon (Giddens, 2009). The US emits 5.8 billion tons of carbon<br />

dioxide equivalent per year, corresponding to 19% of total global emissions,<br />

19 tons per capita and 0.4 tons of carbon for each US$ 1,000 of GDP. It is one<br />

of the countries with the highest per capita emissions in the world. In global<br />

terms, the US economy operates with a relatively high energy efficiency and<br />

low carbon intensity, though presents one of the greatest intensities among<br />

developed countries – exceeded only by Canada and Australia – due to the<br />

combination of an energy matrix based on carbon and oil with high utilization<br />

of air and personal car transport. Emissions in the US grow at 0.8% per year<br />

in this century.<br />

There is a marked difference between the first six months of the Obama<br />

government and the previous period. At the beginning, there were signs that<br />

the new administration would focus on the economic and climate crises as<br />

interconnected processes that should be solved simultaneously, and thus giving<br />

a decisive push to decarbonize the economy. The emergency economic program<br />

for short term recuperation of the economy was compatible with the medium<br />

and long term goals of the Obama platform: expansion of renewable energies,<br />

upgrade of national electrical grid, promotion of public transport (especially high<br />

speed trains) in metropolitan regions and incentives for all economic sectors<br />

that created new green jobs in general. The emergency program differed from<br />

a classic program of government spending expansion and was compatible with<br />

the strategic objective of increasing energy security (Friedman, 2009).<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The Waxman bill of energy and climate – that imposed a system of<br />

ceilings and quotas for carbon emissions – was approved by the House of<br />

Representatives in June 2009 and then paralyzed in the Senate during the<br />

second term due to priorities given by the Obama administration to healthcare<br />

reform, only to be officially abandoned by the democrats in July 2010. At the<br />

beginning of 2011, the picture was very different from the first months of the<br />

Obama government, with the failure of his first initiatives. Various factors explain<br />

this failure: extreme bipartisan polarization in Congress with the subsequent<br />

legislative paralysis and governance crises; high unemployment rates eroding<br />

Obama's popularity; Democrat Party defeat in the 2010 legislative elections;<br />

Republican Party offensive against the IPCC due to some errors in the 2007<br />

report and dubious proceedings of consensus building; a wave of extreme<br />

cold on the American east coast during the 2010 winter, that was used by<br />

the Republican Party as a “demonstration” of the exaggerations in evaluating<br />

the dangers of global warming; aggressive offensive of petroleum, carbon,


46<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

International<br />

perspectives of the<br />

transition to a<br />

low-carbon green<br />

economy<br />

Eduardo Viola<br />

cement, steel and electricity lobbies against approval of the climate bill, as it<br />

supposedly would imply competitive losses for North American industry; limits<br />

to the promotion of green investments due to severe fiscal deficits and growing<br />

government debt; and various surveys showing strong growth in the proportion<br />

of the North American population that believes the risks of global warming are<br />

being exaggerated (Viola, 2010).<br />

Important resistance is expressed in Congress with respect to emissions<br />

reduction. The majority of these derives from the non-existence of reduction<br />

commitments by large emerging countries, especially China. There is also a<br />

more structural resistance, championed by strong economic sectors associated<br />

with the fossil energy matrix: states that produce coal, oil, steel; and electric<br />

energy businesses based on the production of coal fired power. On the other<br />

hand, almost all the big businesses from the lower carbon intensity sectors have<br />

favorable positions for significantly reducing emissions. In the communication<br />

and information sectors, there are Google, Apple, Microsoft, Oracle and CNN; in<br />

biotechnology, renewable energies and nuclear there is General Electric; among<br />

the large retail chains is Wall Mart; producers of inputs for “green” building are<br />

also among those that support emissions reductions, among others.<br />

The United States has an important margin for reducing emissions through: a<br />

technological change from coal fired power to clean coal (cleaner technologies)<br />

and the use of carbon capture and storage; the expansion of wind, solar, biofuel<br />

and nuclear power; decreased size and increased efficiency standards for<br />

automobiles; modernization of the electrical grid and the establishment of new<br />

green standards for construction (buildings and houses designed or renovated<br />

to reduce emissions)<br />

The European Union, composed of 27 countries, emits 4.5 billion tons of<br />

carbon equivalent, corresponding to 15% of the world total, 10 tons per capita<br />

and 0.3 tons of carbon for each US$ 1,000 of GDP. The European Union is<br />

very heterogeneous, both in terms of per capita emissions – from 22 tons in<br />

Luxemburg to 4 tons in France and Portugal – and in carbon intensity, which<br />

is low in the Nordic countries, Germany, the United Kingdom and France;<br />

average in Spain, Belgium and Italy; and high in Poland, Czech Republic,<br />

Romania, Bulgaria and the Baltic countries. European Union emissions grew<br />

by 0.5% per year, as a result of the almost stable emissions of Germany, the<br />

United Kingdom and Sweden and the accelerated growth in emissions of Spain,<br />

Portugal, Greece and the Eastern European countries (even though the latter<br />

ones are below their 1990 base year).<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The main political leaders of the European Union have over recent years<br />

been in favor of an incisive action to mitigate global warming, in particular<br />

the governments and public opinions in the United Kingdom, Germany,<br />

Sweden, France and Denmark, joined by – although with less emphasis – the<br />

Netherlands, Belgium and Finland. However, the 2008-9 economic crises and


47<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

International<br />

perspectives of the<br />

transition to a<br />

low-carbon green<br />

economy<br />

Eduardo Viola<br />

the subsequent eurozone instability greatly eroded the European capacity to<br />

lead the transition to a green economy.<br />

China emits 6.5 billion tons of carbon equivalent per year, which corresponds<br />

to 24% of global emissions, 6 tons per capita and 1.5 tons of carbon for each<br />

US$ 1,000 of GDP. This is a very carbon intensive economy due to its energy<br />

matrix being based substantially on coal and petroleum, and notably, its low<br />

energy efficiency. Even though the carbon intensity of the Chinese GDP has<br />

been falling by 5% per year over the past decade, the country still maintains a<br />

carbon intensity that is nine times greater than Japan’s and four times greater<br />

than the US. Contrary to common sense, the per capita emissions in China are<br />

average as opposed to low. The cost of reducing emissions in China is high<br />

in the case of a continuation of the current industrialization model, but would<br />

be viable in the case of a reoriented model based more on the internal market<br />

and productivity growth, instead of the model based on export expansion. In<br />

the year 2007, global emissions of GHG grew by 3.3% in relation to 2006 and<br />

50% of this increase took place in China, since 2/3 of the growth in China was<br />

based on burning coal. Even more important than reducing the consumption<br />

of oil in the world is the reduction of coal burning and, consequently, a drastic<br />

change in how the Chinese carbon (and also the Indian) is consumed is decisive.<br />

Technologies of carbon capture and sequestration, of clean carbon and nuclear<br />

power are very important for China.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The position of the Chinese government – in national energy and climate<br />

policies, as well as in international negotiations – was negligent up to 2006,<br />

when there were changes based on the evaluation of China's vulnerability to<br />

climate change. The government strongly encouraged growth in wind and solar<br />

energy and announced an objective to reduce the growth rate of emissions.<br />

This objective was reflected by the National Climate Change Plan and the<br />

anti-crises economic stimulus package approved in November 2008, with a<br />

proportion of 35% of public spending aimed at transitioning to a low-carbon<br />

economy. There is a cleavage in China between globalist and nationalist forces,<br />

and the power of the prior is growing continuously and exhibits an intention<br />

to change the Chinese position in the sense of global responsibility. However,<br />

the Chinese position in international negotiations has remained delayed in<br />

comparison with its new energy policy. China continues refusing to assume<br />

commitments related to establishing an emissions peak and a stabilizing year<br />

prior to 2020, as demanded by the international scientific community and by<br />

the EU, the US and Japan – this being one of the factors that increases the<br />

firepower of conservatives in the American Congress. In the technological area,<br />

what stands out is the great technological advances, efficiency and productivity<br />

of Taiwanese businesses in the field of solar photovoltaics and the formation<br />

of joint ventures for massive investment in an extensive program in China<br />

called “low carbon cities”. As of 2009, it is possible to say that two Chinas exist


48<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

in terms of carbon: on one hand, a traditional and highly predominant China<br />

that is a production machine and exporter of carbon emissions; and on the<br />

other hand, a new, low-carbon and of the minority China that is growing at an<br />

extraordinary pace due to the country's high capacity to save and invest, and<br />

that creates a new low carbon business community with interests that contradict<br />

traditional China.<br />

Next, the medium powers will be analyzed.<br />

International<br />

perspectives of the<br />

transition to a<br />

low-carbon green<br />

economy<br />

Eduardo Viola<br />

India emits 2.2 billion tons of carbon equivalent per year, corresponding to<br />

6% of total global emissions, 1.7 tons of carbon per capita and 1.4 tons for<br />

each US$ 1,000 of GDP. However, per capita emissions rate is low and carbon<br />

intensity is high due to low energy efficiency and the heavy weight of coal and<br />

oil in the energy matrix. However, the country has developed photovoltaic<br />

solar and wind power at much higher proportions than Brazil, although less<br />

than China. India has partially developed ethanol production due to being the<br />

largest producer of sugar in the world, although the majority of this production<br />

is destined for food purposes. Emissions grow at 6% per year in India, which is<br />

expected to substitute China as the country that emits most GHG in the world<br />

during the 2010 decade. The Indian government position has been historically<br />

negligent, like the Chinese, and has not changed until this day.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Some comparisons should be made between India and China, since the<br />

behaviors of their societies are crucial for the present and the future, due to<br />

the dramatic growth of their contributions to global warming. India is much<br />

more vulnerable to climate change than China, considering that a fundamental<br />

part of its population depends on water originating in the Himalayas, under<br />

sovereignty of China, a country with growing temptations to divert the rivers<br />

for consumption of its immense population, and furthermore, whose glaciers<br />

are receding because of global warming. In addition, an important part of<br />

India's population is living in lowlands subject to monsoons and devastating<br />

clashes between the terrestrial and oceanic atmospheric circulation. India has<br />

a democratic regime – even though of low quality due to cast inheritance – with<br />

the presence of an important environmental movement that has contested,<br />

though ambivalently, the official position to this day. The Indian population on<br />

average has a less materialist lifestyle than the Chinese due to religious factors<br />

and thus being more sensitive to the state of the planet. The Indian government<br />

is very fragmented and inefficient, which makes it much more difficult for a<br />

change in the direction of lower carbon intensity to occur there than in China.<br />

India, with 1.7 tons of carbon per capita, cannot be pushed internationally to<br />

the same degree of China (6 tons per capita) and Brazil (10 tons per capita)<br />

and therefore has significant room for carbon to occupy to the detriment of<br />

developed and mid-income countries.<br />

Russia emits 2 billion tons of carbon equivalent per year, corresponding to<br />

5% of global emissions, 14 tons per inhabitant and 1.3 tons of carbon for each


49<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

International<br />

perspectives of the<br />

transition to a<br />

low-carbon green<br />

economy<br />

Eduardo Viola<br />

US$ 1,000 of GDP. Russia has an economy with high per capita emissions<br />

and high carbon intensity, constituting a unique profile among large economies<br />

in the world. Russian society has enriched significantly over the past decade,<br />

but through low energy efficiency and an energy matrix that is strongly based<br />

on fossil fuels, given that the country is a large exporter of oil and gas. Russia<br />

occupies an extremely unique position in the global arena. As an economy<br />

whose main heritage is the superabundance of fossil fuels, it can be seen as<br />

potential looser in the transition to a low carbon economy. However, an important<br />

part of the elite and opinion-makers perceive – at least until the extremely<br />

warm summer of 2010 – that global warming could favor Russia because of<br />

an extraordinary increase in arable land.<br />

Japan emits an annual 1.6 billion tons of carbon equivalent, corresponding<br />

to 3.5% of the global total, 12 tons per inhabitant and 0.15 tons of carbon for<br />

each US$ 1.000 of GDP. Japan is, along with European Union countries such<br />

as France, Sweden and Denmark, among the economies with lesser carbonintensity<br />

in the world, due to very high energy efficiency and a heavy weight of<br />

nuclear energy in electricity generation. Public opinion and an important part of<br />

the business community (Honda and Toyota being symbolic) are in favor of a<br />

rapid transition to a low-carbon economy, but Japan's leadership position in the<br />

international arena is below its potential due to its low-profile foreign policy and,<br />

more recently, to the negative effects of the Fukushima nuclear accident.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Indonesia increased its emissions during the first decade of the century, due<br />

to significant deforestation of peat forests with large carbon stocks. Canada has<br />

made the least progress among developed countries. The large increase in oil<br />

production in the Alberta province and the fact that natural resource extraction<br />

is regulated at a provincial as opposed to federal level, are the main factors<br />

that explain the Canadian delay. Mexico adopted a national climate change<br />

plan in 2007 under the Presidency of Calderon, and assumed an international<br />

vanguard position, but the new rhetoric does not correspond closely with the<br />

behaviors of economic actors. In 2008, South Africa announced goals related<br />

to emissions stabilization and peak, and thus taking the lead among emerging<br />

countries belonging to G77. Over recent years, South Korea has maintained a<br />

profile that puts it at the forefront of the transition to a low-carbon economy. Saudi<br />

Arabia has maintained a very conservative historical position in international<br />

negotiations and has exercised a decisive role in regulating the oil price thanks<br />

to its superior capacity to extract and refine, which allows it to rapidly increase<br />

production in response to demand or supply shocks. This is of fundamental<br />

importance, because the international oil price level is essential to extensive<br />

investment growth in clean energy. It could be argued that Saudi Arabia will<br />

always act in defense of its strict national interest, by avoiding an excessive<br />

increase in the oil price for a prolonged period, which would greatly accelerate<br />

investments in renewable energy.


50<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

International<br />

perspectives of the<br />

transition to a<br />

low-carbon green<br />

economy<br />

Eduardo Viola<br />

In summary, from a May 2011 perspective, the formation of a victorious<br />

decarbonization alliance in the world depends on, firstly, positive changes in the<br />

United States, and secondly, an acceleration in the new Chinese energy policy<br />

initiated in 2008. Changes in the US would positively affect China, relatively<br />

fast. Once these changes in the US and China are achieved, a coalition of<br />

the US, the EU, Japan, China, Brazil, South Korea, Mexico and South Africa<br />

can put pressure on Russia, India, Saudi Arabia and Indonesia to accelerate<br />

decarbonizing measures in their respective economies. The extensive<br />

negotiations of this process would take place in multiple arenas – bilateral US-<br />

China, China-EU and US-EU, trilateral (US, China, EU) and plurilateral (G20,<br />

where South Korea and Brazil could play an active and crucial reformist role<br />

against conservative medium-powers) – and finally, these negotiations would<br />

be legitimized in a multilateral UN level.<br />

So u t h Am e r ic a in t h e t r a n s it io n t o a l o w<br />

c a r b o n e c o n o m y<br />

South America emits approximately 3 billion tons of carbon dioxide equivalent<br />

annually. Emissions of carbon dioxide (industry, energy, transport, deforestation<br />

and changes in land use); methane (livestock farming, waste, hydroelectric<br />

reservoirs) and nitrous oxide (agricultural fertilizers) summed together for the<br />

region totaled approximately 7% of the global carbon emissions in 2009. A<br />

unique aspect in South America is that carbon dioxide emissions derived from<br />

deforestation and land use change were proportionally very high up to 2005. The<br />

deforestation rate over the past five years has grown a lot in Bolivia, Ecuador<br />

and Paraguay; increased moderately in Peru and Colombia; remained stable in<br />

Venezuela and fell slightly in Argentina and dramatically in Brazil. Deforestation<br />

rates (as a proportion of total forest cover) oscillated from 1% per year in Bolivia<br />

to 0.1% per year in Argentina and has remained at 0.2% per year in Brazil<br />

over recent years. Uruguay is the only country with a positive balance, with an<br />

increasing forest cover due to reforestation and forestation.<br />

Venezuela and Argentina each account for approximately 1% of global<br />

emissions. Per capita emissions in Venezuela are 7 tons and in Argentina, 5<br />

tons. Venezuela emits 1.3 tons of carbon per US$ 1,000 of GDP and Argentina<br />

emits 1 ton. Colombia, Peru and Chile are each responsible for approximately<br />

0.5% of global emissions.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Deforestation in South America has a triple negative effect on societies.<br />

Firstly, deforestation implies a great destruction of natural resources and a<br />

very inefficient conversion of forests. Secondly, it causes the proportion of the<br />

informal economy to be high throughout the economy, with great systemic<br />

inefficiencies due to the fact that the economy associated with deforestation<br />

is, in general, small-scale and illegal or semi-legal. Thirdly, deforestation<br />

undermines government authority and the rule of law, and thus generates an


51<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

International<br />

perspectives of the<br />

transition to a<br />

low-carbon green<br />

economy<br />

Eduardo Viola<br />

environment favorable to a growth in other illicit activities such as: corruption,<br />

smuggling, drug trafficking, prostitution, trafficking of arms and wild animals<br />

and even murder.<br />

Although South America is highly vulnerable to climate change, as a whole<br />

the region finds itself in a favorable position for transitioning to a low carbon<br />

economy. The situation is very different in large emerging countries in other<br />

regions of the world – China, India, Russia, South Africa, Mexico –, that produce<br />

the majority of their electricity from fossil fuels. South American electricity is the<br />

most hydro-intensive in the world: 85% of the total in the case of Brazil, 37%<br />

in Argentina, 67% in Venezuela, 75% in Colombia, 53% in Chile, 80% in Peru,<br />

62% in Ecuador, 64% in Bolivia, 99% in Uruguay and 100% in Paraguay. Even<br />

Venezuela, which has a more carbon intensive economy – due to transport<br />

inefficiencies and oil low prices – has a large hydro weight in its electricity<br />

generation.<br />

Brazil emitted approximately 1.8 billion tons of carbon equivalent in 2009,<br />

corresponding to around 4% of global emissions, 10 tons per capita and 0.9<br />

tons of carbon for each US$ 1,000 of GDP. Emissions in Brazil over the years<br />

2005-2010 suffered a large reduction compared to the 2001-2004 period, due<br />

to a dramatic fall in the Amazon deforestation rate from an annual average<br />

of 20,000 km 2 to an annual average of 11.000 km2 between 2005 and 2010,<br />

arriving at a low figure in 2010 (6,200 km 2 ).<br />

Similar to Brazil, most of the countries in South America (Colombia,<br />

Ecuador, Peru, Bolivia and Paraguay) could significantly decrease their carbon<br />

emissions by reducing deforestation. Argentina and Uruguay have a lot to gain<br />

in terms of energy conservation and as such, could grow economically with<br />

stabilized emissions. The price structure of energy in Argentina is irrational<br />

both from an economic point of view and from a carbon emissions perspective.<br />

Chile, the richest country in South America, has a lot of margin to increase<br />

energy efficiency and vehicle emissions standards. Chile already has greater<br />

energy efficiency and above average economic productivity that allows a<br />

more rapid incorporation of new climate technologies that are emerging in<br />

developed countries. Venezuela also has a good margin for lowering carbonintensity<br />

through three vectors: eliminating direct and indirect subsidies for<br />

oil consumption, which make the vehicle fleet of this country one of the most<br />

irrational in the world; increasing electric energy conservation where there is<br />

a lot of room for gain; and reducing deforestation.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Up to now, regional integration structures in South America – Mercosur,<br />

Andean Community, Union of South America and Organization of the Treaty for<br />

Amazonian Cooperation – have not been dedicated to the issue of transitioning<br />

to a low-carbon economy. The Amazonia Treaty, institutionalized in 2004,<br />

existed on a solely formal level until 2009, especially due to the low interest<br />

of the Brazilian government. This is yet another paradox of Brazil's South


52<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

International<br />

perspectives of the<br />

transition to a<br />

low-carbon green<br />

economy<br />

Eduardo Viola<br />

American policy, since the productivity of financial and institutional resources<br />

allocated in this cooperative structure could be very high, by combining the<br />

combat of illicit transnational activities and illegal deforestation and promoting<br />

the rule of law. As of 2010, the governments of Brazil, Colombia and Ecuador<br />

started giving more importance to the Treaty, which tends to strengthen the<br />

organization. Brazil should assume the cost of leadership through policies<br />

and Brazilian financial resources in several dimensions: promotion of public<br />

safety in frontier zones and combat of illicit transnational activities; promotion<br />

of transportation infrastructure of all types, but especially waterway, railway<br />

and air transportation; promotion of integrated energy development, especially<br />

in the hydroelectric sector, in which Brazil and the region have a competitive<br />

advantage on a global scale; and promotion of a regional network of biodiversity/<br />

biotechnology laboratories with contributions from American, European and<br />

Japanese capital. A decisive task of international cooperation in the Amazon<br />

is the establishment of an Amazon Panel of Climate Change and Biodiversity<br />

molded after the IPCC. This institutionalism is fundamental to develop regional<br />

governance in the Amazon.<br />

Gl o b a l t e c h n o-e c o n o m ic v e c t o r s f o r t h e<br />

t r a n s it io n t o a l o w-c a r b o n g r e e n e c o n o m y<br />

For the solid and rapid transition to an international low-carbon economy, a<br />

large international agreement would be necessary (on a much greater scale<br />

than the Kyoto Protocol) that should be supported by a series of behavioral<br />

changes, as well as simultaneous and complementary technological and<br />

economic developments. The literature over the past few years calls for a series<br />

of vectors for this transition. The below list of vectors has been synthesized<br />

by the author:<br />

1. Accelerate the growth pace of energy efficiency (this growth takes place<br />

normally in the history of capitalism, but the pace needs to be increased) for<br />

residential and industrial use, in transport and urban planning. Increase recycling<br />

at all levels of the supply chain and in consumption;<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

2. Increase the proportion of non-fossil renewable energies (wind, solar,<br />

biofuels and hydroelectric) in the global energy matrix. Hydroelectric energy has<br />

been completely competitive during the past century and the competitiveness<br />

of wind, solar and biofuel power developed extraordinarily in the past decade<br />

due to advances in large and medium powers, only missing, in a majority of the<br />

countries, appropriate regulatory frameworks that create incentives for more<br />

vigorous growth. Recent experiences with biofuels show that only ethanol from<br />

sugarcane is very effective in terms of reducing emissions; ethanol from corn<br />

and beetroot and all biodiesel exhibit important limitations up to now. Second<br />

generation ethanol – from cellulose – appears as a fundamental alternative


53<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

International<br />

perspectives of the<br />

transition to a<br />

low-carbon green<br />

economy<br />

Eduardo Viola<br />

(the issue in this case concerns the speed at which this technology will be<br />

available on a large scale);<br />

3. Increase the proportion of nuclear power in the global energy matrix, taking<br />

advantage of significant improvements in reactor technologies from an operation<br />

security perspective, despite the remaining problem of final disposal of nuclear<br />

waste and the life-spans of old and unsafe reactors; in addition to this, there are<br />

prospects for developing fourth generation nuclear reactors. The expansion of<br />

nuclear energy is fundamental to accelerate decarbonization in various powers,<br />

such as the US, China, India, Russia, Indonesia and Mexico;<br />

4. Develop regulatory frameworks that promote the use of hybrid cars<br />

(gasoline-electric and gasoline-ethanol) that have already reached full maturity<br />

in terms of competing with conventional cars. Increase the use of public transport<br />

and diminish car use. Utilize smaller and lighter cars;<br />

5. Drastically reduce deforestation (currently responsible for 14% of global<br />

emissions), reforest cleared areas and plant in areas that never had forests,<br />

but that today are appropriate for homogeneous rapid-growing forests;<br />

6. Increase the use of livestock farming techniques that are suited to the<br />

carbon cycle, such as no till farming, precision irrigation and animal feed that<br />

generates less methane. Reduce consumption of beef in high and medium<br />

income countries, and thus enabling an increased consumption of this product<br />

among global emerging middle class without imposing excessive pressures<br />

on methane emissions;<br />

7. Efficient use of water in domestic, agricultural and industrial consumption<br />

and expanded basic sanitation across the planet. Appropriate disposal of waste<br />

and sewer and a dramatic increase in methane power plants;<br />

8. Promote rapid stabilization of the global population, between 2020<br />

and 2025, and retirement schemes that correspond with life expectancies<br />

(approximately 68 years for men and women in high and medium income<br />

countries) and health systems that promote healthy life-styles, longevity with<br />

quality of life and that minimize gigantic expenditures to prolong life with abysmal<br />

quality in the final year, as is currently the case;<br />

9. Accelerate the development of carbon capture and sequestration<br />

technologies, separating the carbon dioxide both in coal and petroleum and<br />

injecting it back into the already mined and empty coal fields that are highly<br />

stable from a geologic perspective;<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

10. Reduce the proportion of face meetings (especially those that involve<br />

air travel) and increase meetings via teleconferencing. Slow down the growth<br />

of air transport. Develop airplanes with lighter materials, more aerodynamic<br />

design and greater energy efficiency;


54<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

International<br />

perspectives of the<br />

transition to a<br />

low-carbon green<br />

economy<br />

Eduardo Viola<br />

11. Accelerate the development of the hydrogen cell, which will certainly be<br />

the energy of the future. It will probably not play a significant role before 2050<br />

but its development would give a clear signal that the transition to a low-carbon<br />

economy is profound and irreversible;<br />

12. Establish international accords that promote integrated inter-institutional<br />

research to develop new advanced technologies to decarbonize the energy<br />

matrix. Some of these are already at the initial stage, such as the utilization<br />

of ocean and wave power; high altitude wind turbines; and solar nano cells.<br />

Create a global cultural and institutional environment favorable to synergies<br />

between new energy technologies and the revolutions in information technology,<br />

communication and nanotechnology. Promote the development of climate<br />

geoengineering research with the objective of having a plan B alternative in<br />

the event of an exponential acceleration of global warming.<br />

13. The transition to a low-carbon green economy assumes a profound<br />

transformation of dominant values in international society (hyper materialism,<br />

consumerism, immediatism, and disregard for long-term thinking) and, therefore,<br />

transformation at all levels of formal education and media activities (classically<br />

referred to as environmental education, but that nowadays should be called<br />

education for a sustainable low-carbon society) will always play an important<br />

role, to generate awareness among populations of these value changes and<br />

the extraordinary gains in quality of life and happiness to be derived from them<br />

– much more important than some short term losses in irrational consumption,<br />

which would be a consequence of the transition to a decarbonized society,<br />

feared by large segments of populations in the world.<br />

Fu t u r e p r o s p e c t s<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The year 2009 significantly changed the international political economy of<br />

climate change. The legacy of Kyoto, that left the US and other large emerging<br />

countries outside the carbon constraint, has disintegrated (Ladislaw, 2010;<br />

Barret, 2010). The Copenhagen agreement is extremely weak from a judicial<br />

standpoint, but almost universal from a carbon emissions constraint perspective.<br />

It is practically impossible to advance in the sense of a new comprehensive and<br />

legally binding treaty, until the US approves climate legislation that demands<br />

quantified emissions reductions. Given current political dynamics, this is unlikely<br />

to happen, even in best case scenario, before 2013-14: assuming the reelection<br />

of president Obama in November 2012, a democrat victory in both chambers<br />

of Congress and a decision by Obama to prioritize climate legislation at the<br />

beginning of his second term. Another factor that influences the prospects for<br />

this very important global agreement is the tension between the US and the<br />

EU on the one hand and China on the other, due to China´s resistance to the<br />

revaluation of the Yuan. The issue of reevaluation of the Yuan could generate<br />

an anti-Chinese coalition among the countries that are invaded by Chinese


55<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

International<br />

perspectives of the<br />

transition to a<br />

low-carbon green<br />

economy<br />

Eduardo Viola<br />

merchandise due to its increased export capacity. Countries that are threatened<br />

by the Chinese export machine include the majority of G20 members. Brazil, as<br />

a significant exporter of commodities to China, is in an intermediary position:<br />

its mining and food production sectors are favored by the Chinese dynamics,<br />

and the manufacturing sector is threatened.<br />

The economic and security dimensions of the international system have<br />

a decisive impact on the climate dimension and it is necessary to take them<br />

into priority consideration in any realistic analysis of the future of climate<br />

negotiations. Tensions between countries with international trade surpluses and<br />

deficits, especially in relation to China, can limit or even stop the G20 advances<br />

in global economic governance that took place in 2009. The international system<br />

could be reversing the dynamics of cooperative depolarization that occurred in<br />

2008 and 2009. In the case of the predominance of a dynamics of moderate<br />

increases of conflicts in the international system over the coming years, this<br />

would be sufficient to block advances in a new international climate treaty, even if<br />

a comprehensive climatic legislation were to be approved in the US in 2013.<br />

In this context, the global transition to a low-carbon economy will be very slow<br />

and one of its principal international instruments will be the establishment of<br />

trade barriers for carbon-intensive products. In the case of Russia and India, a<br />

majority of the sectors are threatened. In the case of China, the scenario would<br />

be more complex considering that, due to the great advances in wind and solar<br />

power, the proportion of products with low-carbon intensity (currently very low)<br />

would increase rapidly on the agenda of Chinese exports.<br />

In the case that a tendency towards cooperation and continued depolarization<br />

of the international system prevails over the coming years and Obama becomes<br />

reelected in 2012, it is probable that the American position will change from<br />

being a great conservative power to a great reformist power in regard to a global<br />

agreement to constrain carbon. Also probable is that an alliance between the<br />

European Union, Japan, Canada, South Korea, Brazil, Mexico, South Africa<br />

and the United States is able to persuade China, Russia and India to establish<br />

emission peaks and different stabilizing years – prior to 2020 for China and<br />

Russia and between 2025 and 2030 for India, considering that the per capita<br />

emissions in Russia are almost double that of the Chinese and five times greater<br />

than that of India; and Chinese emissions are three times greater than Indian<br />

emissions (Viola and Machado Filho, 2010).<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

In an international system where forces of convergence predominate, China’s<br />

globalization and decarbonization forces are favored.. From the perspective<br />

of low-carbon technology, there are some small countries that will have<br />

global impact due to their technological advances: Israel, Taiwan, Singapore,<br />

Switzerland and Norway. The principal variable to increase cooperation and<br />

produce a decarbonizing agreement in the international system is more flexible<br />

intellectual property rights in the area of low-carbon technologies. The scenario


56<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

International<br />

perspectives of the<br />

transition to a<br />

low-carbon green<br />

economy<br />

Eduardo Viola<br />

is not simple, since some emerging countries are already at the forefront of<br />

low-carbon technology in some areas. For example, China would need a more<br />

flexible system in the areas of nuclear energy and second generation ethanol,<br />

but not in wind and solar in which several mid and low income countries<br />

would need Chinese-Taiwanese technology transfers. Brazil would need a<br />

relaxation of intellectual property laws in the areas of wind and photovoltaic<br />

solar energy, but would be at the forefront and should transfer technology in<br />

the areas of hydroelectricity and first generation ethanol to medium and low<br />

income countries.<br />

A new and great question is how long Brazil will maintain the discrepancy<br />

between a climate policy with emissions reduction targets and an international<br />

negotiations position that follows China and India, which have more conservative<br />

climate policies. Due to the relative power interests of various economic sectors<br />

in Brazil and the dynamics of public opinion, it is probable that this inconsistency<br />

will not be maintained for long and that the Brazilian negotiating position would<br />

converge with that of the European Union, Japan and South Korea.<br />

References<br />

Barret, S. (2010). Contrasting future path for an evolving climate regime. Global<br />

Policy, 1.<br />

Friedman, T. (2009). Hot, flat and crowded. Why we need a green revolution and how<br />

it can renew America. New York: Farrar, Strauss and Giroux.<br />

Giddens, A. (2009). The politics of climate change. London: Polity Press.<br />

La Viña, A. (2010). Ways forward after Copenhagen: reflections on the climate change<br />

negotiations process by the REDD-plus facilitator. Manila: Foundation for International<br />

Environmental Law and Development.<br />

Ladislaw, S. (2010). A post-Copenhagen pathway. Washington: Center for Strategic<br />

and International Studies.<br />

Stern, N. (2009). The global deal. Climate change and the creation of a new era of<br />

progress and prosperity. New York: Public Affairs.<br />

Viola, E. (2010). A política climática global e o Brasil, 2005-2010. Tempo do Mundo,<br />

vol. 1, n. 2. Brasília: IPEA.<br />

Viola, E. and Machado Filho, H. (2010). Os BICs (Brasil, Índia e China) e as negociações<br />

de mudança climática. Rio de Janeiro: Centro de Estudos de Integração e<br />

Desenvolvimento, Breves 35.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011


57<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy in Latin<br />

America: the origins of<br />

debate in ECLAC work<br />

Márcia Tavares 1<br />

The exact meaning of the term green economy is still being discussed, and<br />

other articles in this volume certainly will contribute to this debate. It is likely<br />

that the term will acquire different meanings in different countries and contexts.<br />

In the context of the preparatory process for the United Nations Conference<br />

on Sustainable Development (<strong>Rio+20</strong>), resolution 64/236 of the General<br />

Assembly specifies that the term to be used is “green economy in the context<br />

of sustainable development and the eradication of poverty” (italics added).<br />

This qualification reflects four decades of dialogue between governments of<br />

developed and developing countries about the environment, economics and<br />

development, through the sequence of global conferences on the subject: the<br />

1972 United Nations Conference on the Human Environment in Stockholm, the<br />

1992 United Nations Conference on Environment and Development in Rio de<br />

Janeiro and the 2002 World Summit on Sustainable Development, and now the<br />

preparatory process for <strong>Rio+20</strong>. All these landmark conferences were marked<br />

by resistance to the imposition of the manner in which these relations should<br />

be handled by each country, how priorities should be defined in national policy<br />

and the relative importance attributed to different challenges of development<br />

and the protection of the environment. This tension, along with different<br />

views on the role of international cooperation and the importance of historic<br />

responsibilities, is visible in the definition of sustainable development by the<br />

Brundtland Commission, in various of the principles of the Rio Declaration on<br />

Environment and Development, in the difficulties in reaching an agreement on<br />

climate change and currently in the debates between governments on green<br />

economy.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Since the beginning of the 1970's, ECLAC has undertaken two functions<br />

in regard to the relations between economics and environment – and as of<br />

the end of the 1980's, “sustainable development”. Firstly, ECLAC supports<br />

governments of the Latin American and Caribbean region in intergovernmental<br />

processes. This role was reinforced by Agenda 21 in 1992, the Johannesburg<br />

Plan of Implementation in 2002 and the reformulation of the modus operandi of<br />

1. Márcia Tavares is Economic Affairs Officer of the Sustainable Development and Human<br />

Settlements Division of the Economic Commission for Latin American and the Caribbean<br />

(ECLAC). Opinions expressed in this article are the responsibility of the author and do not<br />

necessarily coincide with those of ECLAC.


58<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy in Latin<br />

America: the origins of<br />

debate in ECLAC work<br />

Márcia Tavares<br />

the Commission on Sustainable Development (CSD) in 2003. Today, ECLAC<br />

is the United Nations agency responsible for the regional preparatory process<br />

for <strong>Rio+20</strong> in Latin America and the Caribbean. Secondly, since its foundation<br />

in 1948, ECLAC has been a think tank on Latin American (and as from 1984,<br />

Caribbean) economies and their insertion in the international context. 2 In<br />

exercising these two functions, a number of ECLAC´s institutional publications<br />

and works by authors associated to the institution have addressed the relations<br />

between environment and economics either directly or indirectly when dealing<br />

with other aspects of development in the region.<br />

This article extracts some of the main ideas from works undertaken within<br />

ECLAC from the beginning of the 1970's to the beginning of the 1990's, at key<br />

moments in the debate about relations between economics and environment or<br />

about sustainable development. Some of the issues dealt with, the approaches<br />

adopted, or even the language of these documents may now be outdated, but<br />

the central arguments continue important to inform the debate about green<br />

economy and the shape that this concept will take in Latin America. They<br />

can be helpful in assessing the complexity of environmental problems in the<br />

region and their direct link to economic and social structures and processes.<br />

The references below do not do justice to the wealth of the original texts, but<br />

will hopefully raise interest in them as historical references.<br />

1. In p r e p a r a t io n f o r t h e St o c k h o l m<br />

Co n f e r e n c e: “Hu m a n En v ir o n m e n t a n d Ec o n o m ic<br />

De v e l o p m e n t in La t in Am e r ic a”, 1971<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

One of ECLACs first incursions in the environmental issue area was the<br />

work related to the organization, in 1971, of a preparatory meeting for the<br />

Stockholm Conference (1972). For this meeting, ECLAC published a study in<br />

collaboration with the Latin American Institute of Economic and Social Planning<br />

(ILPES) and the regional office of the Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO)<br />

(ECLAC, 1971). The document identified low development and deficient income<br />

distribution as the main sources of the “poor environmental conditions” of the<br />

region. Industrialization, though necessary for development, had generated<br />

new problems. Thus, it was argued, there coexisted in Latin America, to a<br />

greater degree than in other regions, environmental problems associated<br />

with underdevelopment and those associated with technological progress.<br />

The document addressed the issue through the perspective of relations of<br />

dependency, the region’s peripheral nature and structural heterogeneity,<br />

elements that had dominated ECLAC thinking during the previous decade<br />

(Bielschowsky, 1998).<br />

3. “Founex Report on Development and the Environment”, presented by a group of specialists<br />

summuned by the Secretary General of the United Nations Conference on the Human<br />

Environment, 4 to 12 June, Founex, Switzerland.<br />

2. For an overview of ECLAC thought up to the 1990’s, see Bielschowsky (1998) and (2009).


59<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy in Latin<br />

America: the origins of<br />

debate in ECLAC work<br />

Márcia Tavares<br />

Influenced by the Founex report written some months before 3 , the dominant<br />

argument in this 1971 document was that development is a condition for<br />

ensuring “desirable environmental conditions”. Implicitly, the document reacted<br />

to theses that saw growth as detrimental to environmental quality, including<br />

that of the limits to growth. On the other hand, it addressed the dilemma of<br />

resource allocation between environmental and development objectives. This<br />

dilemma applied both to public resource allocation and to private sector business<br />

decisions. One example of the latter was the difficulty companies in the region<br />

found to develop and adopt more modern and less polluting technology, due<br />

to insufficient technological capacity and the need to maintain competitiveness<br />

(low costs and prices) in the international market.<br />

The 1971 document discussed the main environmental problems in urban<br />

and rural areas; the difficulties in ensuring a sufficient expansion of urban public<br />

services to meet the needs of a growing urban population; and the problems of<br />

industrial pollution. It also showed the relation between the agricultural production<br />

structure and the generation of large numbers of un- or underemployed, which<br />

were forced to occupy marginal lands with little capacity to generate surplus<br />

production or to integrate the increasing marginalized urban population. The<br />

text goes on to discuss other problems that still today dominate regional and<br />

international agendas, such as the challenges of securing energy for growing<br />

populations and economies; the effects of mining on the environment and the<br />

health of workers; the inefficient use of water; and the difficulty of developing<br />

domestic technology compatible with the local context and its environmental<br />

challenges. As would later be consolidated in both the 1992 instruments and<br />

in the Seventh Millennium Development Goal (environmental sustainability),<br />

the document supports the need to integrate environmental issues in public<br />

policymaking. The life-cycle logic in production and consumption is mentioned<br />

and used to show how natural materials such as cotton would be considered<br />

more competitive than synthetic materials if the costs of adequate disposal<br />

were considered. This was still a relevant subject on the agenda of the CSD<br />

in 2011.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The conclusions lead to the debate about the means of implementation of<br />

international environmental and sustainable development commitments, an<br />

issue that is still significant in the preparations for <strong>Rio+20</strong>, including the debates<br />

on green economy. These include the issue of trade restrictions; the capacity<br />

of industry to adapt to a new paradigm; the need for technology transfer and<br />

financial assistance; and the inseparability between economic development,<br />

social development and the environment, which came to be the basis of the<br />

concept of sustainable development.


60<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy in Latin<br />

America: the origins of<br />

debate in ECLAC work<br />

Márcia Tavares<br />

2. “De v e l o p m e n t s t y l e s a n d t h e e n v ir o n m e n t”,<br />

1980<br />

During most of the 1970's, the work of ECLAC was centered on what would<br />

become known as “styles of development. 4 This line of work originated in the<br />

perception that although the region had obtained good results in terms of growth<br />

and industrialization, this had taken place with the exclusion of large sectors<br />

of society, aggravating unemployment, underdevelopment and poverty, and<br />

accumulating political tension. The aim of this approach was to understand and<br />

respond to the development styles of countries in the region, seen in the context<br />

of the internationally prevalent styles. It was understood that an “ascending”,<br />

transnational, development was imposed over the “dominant” development<br />

styles of each country. This confrontation of styles, together with existing social<br />

forces, contributed to the structural heterogeneity 5 that characterizes peripheral<br />

countries within the capitalist system, another key concept of ECLAC thought<br />

in the 70's (Bielschowsky, 1998; Sunkel, 1980).<br />

Mainstream work about development styles did not explicitly consider<br />

the environmental dimension. Responding to this deficiency, between 1978<br />

and 1980, ECLAC and the United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP)<br />

developed a project entitled Development Styles and the Environment. This<br />

formed the basis for work by ECLAC in the environmental issue area over<br />

the 20 years that followed (Gligo, 2006). The results of the initial project were<br />

joined into two volumes published in 1980 6 and summarized in an introductory<br />

article by Osvaldo Sunkel (1980). This article relates environmental problems<br />

in the region to the Latin American development process between the colonial<br />

period and the end of the 1970's, and particularly to the emergence of the<br />

“transnational” style after the post-war era.<br />

According to Sunkel (1980), the development styles of the countries that are<br />

developed today (including consumption choices, infrastructure, technological<br />

pathways) have been generated over time based on a world vision where<br />

natural resources were seen as unlimited. Colonial powers saw in the then<br />

apparently infinite resources of the colonies, a source for that which lacked or<br />

became scarce inside national boundaries. The United States´s ample territory<br />

generated the same perception. The depletion of the best natural resources<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

4. There have been various definitions of “development styles” over time. Sunkel (1980) quotes<br />

complementary definitions to those by Aníbal Pinto and Jorge Graciarena (free translation): “the<br />

manner in which human resources and materials are organized and assigned within a certain<br />

system with the purpose of resolving the questions of what, for whom and how to produce<br />

goods and services” and the “concrete and dynamic modality adopted by a system in a defined<br />

area and at a determined historical moment”.<br />

5. The term structural heterogeneity refers to “the intra and inter sectoral asymmetries in terms of<br />

productivity” (Pinto, 1970). These asymmetries are the hard core from which other inequalities<br />

are transmitted to all of society ECLAC (2010).<br />

6. Sunkel, Osvaldo and Gligo, Nicolo (compilers) (1980), “Estilos de Desarrollo y Medio<br />

Ambiente en la América Latina”, Fondo de Cultura Económica, México. The two volumes of<br />

this compilation contain 37 articles about development styles and the environment in general,<br />

and the development of the agriculture, livestock and forestry industries, urbanization and<br />

marginalization, energy and industrialization, and policies, strategies and planning sector. A<br />

special edition of the CEPAL Review (No. 12, December 1980) gathered some of these articles.


61<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy in Latin<br />

America: the origins of<br />

debate in ECLAC work<br />

Márcia Tavares<br />

(high grade, best location for extraction) and the degradation of renewable<br />

ones was not seen as a problem for these countries as technological progress<br />

and expansion to new territories always made new resources available. Upon<br />

gaining independence, ex-colonies reproduced development models based on<br />

a perception of unlimited natural resources, not necessarily compatible with<br />

their factor endowments and structural conditions, and without managing to<br />

generate autonomous processes of technological progress.<br />

Up to the 1940's, environmental problems in Latin America were, according<br />

to the study, mainly related to agricultural practices associated with a structure<br />

that combined large, under-utilized estates with overexploited smallholdings. In<br />

parallel, the expansion of the agricultural frontier generated its own problems,<br />

as did the exploitation of natural resources, a basic sector of the economies in<br />

the region. Revenue generated from mineral extraction was not being reinvested<br />

in local development. On the contrary, revenues were for the most part sent<br />

abroad. Additionally, as early as the 1940's, environmental problems existed<br />

in relation to the marginalization of segments of society both in rural and urban<br />

areas, despite industrial pollution being dispersed and of limited significance.<br />

By the end of the Second World War, the hegemony of the United States had<br />

extended the North American development style – referred to as “transnational” -<br />

to the rest of the world. The ascendance of this style in Latin America generated<br />

new environmental problems. The transnational style was characterized by,<br />

among others, the dominant role of transnational companies; the generation of<br />

irreversible transformations in national economies and societies that reduced<br />

the policy space of governments in the pursuit of autonomous development<br />

processes; the homogenization of production, marketing and consumption<br />

patterns; the internationalization of industrial production; and the intensification<br />

of natural resource exploitation and growing dependence on oil. The expansion<br />

of the use of the automobile influenced the dynamics of urban expansion and<br />

generated a growing demand for land in residential areas and for transportation<br />

infrastructure.<br />

Against the background of this ascending style, in the post war period policies<br />

of a breadth seldom seen since then were adopted in many countries to promote<br />

the development of basic industries such as the petroleum and automobile<br />

industries, as well as the infrastructure necessary to support these new sectors.<br />

The financial surplus derived from the exploitation of natural resources – that<br />

remained predominant in economic structures – was sent abroad or used to<br />

finance imports of consumer goods.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

One of the main characteristics of development in the region as understood<br />

through the lens of the ascendance of the transnational style was high-energy<br />

intensity and dependence on petroleum, the relevance of which much exceeds<br />

the problems of atmospheric pollution. The contribution of Raul Prebisch to the<br />

ECLAC/UNEP project collection (Prebisch, 1980) shows among other things, how


62<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy in Latin<br />

America: the origins of<br />

debate in ECLAC work<br />

Márcia Tavares<br />

the era of cheap petroleum influenced the direction of technological research.<br />

Investments allowed for the increase of productivity but not improvements in<br />

energy efficiency. The expanded use of petroleum as a raw material led to the<br />

substitution of natural fibers and wood by synthetic materials, to the detriment<br />

of employment. In agriculture, mechanization generated unemployment and<br />

migration to cities, which contributed to a massive and precarious urbanization<br />

process. The use of fertilizers and pesticides from petrochemical origins<br />

contributed to soil contamination.<br />

Also inherent to the ascendance of the transnational style was the geographical<br />

concentration of the industrial, political and bureaucratic administrative centers.<br />

This partly explains the repeated failure of regional decentralization policies<br />

between 1960 and 1980. Similarly, the dynamics of massive and precarious<br />

migration always undermined policies aimed at addressing the housing deficit<br />

or extending basic services to the poorest. While the most privileged groups<br />

retreated to suburban neighborhoods, occupying land previously employed in<br />

agriculture and requiring investments in the development of infrastructure for<br />

the new areas, within the cities the poorest groups occupied increasing areas<br />

of marginal land.<br />

The oil crisis at the beginning of the 1970's led to a crisis of the transnational<br />

style. However, by then its models of consumption, production, infrastructure<br />

and urban development, as well as social structures, had already been firmly<br />

established and still prevail to a great extent today. There were, by then, few<br />

alternatives for substantial changes in development paths. The oil crisis at the<br />

beginning of the 1970's, for instance, did not cause economies to shift to other<br />

sources of fuels despite significant initiatives such as Pró-Álcool (Pro-Ethanol)<br />

in Brazil. Rather, it generated even more pressure on export sectors to be able<br />

to finance petroleum imports.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

For an alternative development style compatible with the satisfaction of<br />

the basic needs of the majority of the population and the preservation of the<br />

natural resource base and the environment, the following recommendations<br />

emerged from the research on styles of development and the environment: less<br />

dependence on fossil fuels and a greater use of renewable and less polluting<br />

energy sources; development of more labor intense technologies that are<br />

adjusted to the local natural resource base; recycling and reuse of waste; natural<br />

resource management with ecologically based knowledge and technology;<br />

institution of decentralized administrative and political processes grounded in<br />

local communities; and deterrence of the continued expansion of large cities<br />

and excessive consumption. In addition, no development effort should leave<br />

out consideration of the environmental dimension. It was recommended that<br />

development planning and science and technology policies have as central<br />

concerns the knowledge and assessment of natural resources and ecosystems,<br />

the need for permanent monitoring, the development of alternative technologies


63<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy in Latin<br />

America: the origins of<br />

debate in ECLAC work<br />

Márcia Tavares<br />

and diversification of production based on ecologically adequate techniques.<br />

Lastly, the document recommended, the establishment of mechanisms that<br />

enable the participation of society in decision-making, which later became<br />

consolidated as Principle 10 in the Rio Declaration.<br />

The following citation draws attention to similarities with certain definitions<br />

of the concept of green economy, or green growth as adopted by the OECD 7 .<br />

In the words of Sunkel (1980) (free translation):<br />

“Policies aimed at conserving, improving and expanding natural resources<br />

and their productivity, and those that seek to conserve, improve and expand<br />

the artificial environment and its productivity, are a part of development<br />

policies, as they make development sustainable in the long term. But<br />

they can also make positive contributions to solve problems characteristic<br />

of the current development style (…) Conservation projects for soil and<br />

forests, reforestation, dredging and conservation of irrigation channels,<br />

maintenance and construction of roads that penetrate rural areas and the<br />

self-construction of housing and community equipment in urban zones,<br />

if adequately designed, can contribute to alleviate problems such as<br />

unemployment and underemployment, at the same time as they promote<br />

social organization at the base of society, increasing productivity and<br />

improving living conditions.”<br />

3. Th e d e b t c r is is a n d t h e Br u n d t l a n d<br />

Co m m is s io n: r e f l e c t io n s b e t w e e n 1985 a n d 1990<br />

The World Commission on Environment and Development, also known as<br />

the Brundtland Commission, was created in 1983. In 1987, the Commission<br />

published its report, which defines sustainable development as development<br />

that meets the needs of the present without compromising the ability of future<br />

generations to meet their own needs.<br />

During this period and the years that followed, Latin America´s international<br />

economic relations – and thereby the focus of ECLAC – were dominated by<br />

“financial asphyxia due to indebtedness” (Bielschowsky, 1998). Two articles by<br />

Osvaldo Sunkel – one before and one after the Brundtland report – refer to the<br />

relation between the debt crisis and sustainable development. They make a<br />

call for the global debate on the environment and sustainable development not<br />

to disconsider the great challenges of the economic context in Latin American<br />

countries and of the way in which they were inserted in the international<br />

economic system. Sunkel suggested that the debt crisis was an opportunity to<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

1. “A way to pursue economic growth and development, while preventing environmental<br />

degradation, viodiversity loss and unsustainable natural resource use”. This refers to<br />

strategies that emerged in response to the global crisis and that sought sources of growth<br />

that could contribute simultaneously to economic efficiency, environmental integrity and social<br />

equality (OECD, 2010).


64<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy in Latin<br />

America: the origins of<br />

debate in ECLAC work<br />

Márcia Tavares<br />

improve the relation between economy and environment, which is reminiscent<br />

of the concepts of green economy within the context of the United Nations,<br />

and green growth within the context of the OECD, later emerged largely as a<br />

reaction to the global crisis that reached its summit in 2008.<br />

The 1985 article describes the effects of the crisis on the environment and<br />

environmental institutions, an aspect that had allegedly not been adequately<br />

addressed by the Brundtland Commission up to that point (Sunkel, 1985).<br />

Environmental institutions were still weak and their role still the object of much<br />

uncertainty when they were hit by the crisis. The budget constraints stemming<br />

from the crisis and an economic and financial outlook that focused on the short<br />

term further weakened the environmental institutions that had emerged since<br />

the Stockholm Conference. Furthermore, the pressure to raise hard currency to<br />

cover debt servicing and the political consequences of adjustments increased<br />

poverty levels and contributed to aggravate problems of over-exploitation of<br />

land and natural resources, as well as migration from rural areas to cities and<br />

the consequent increase in urban poverty. Within cities, informal housing and<br />

activities expanded. Running counter to sustainable development, the pressure<br />

to raise hard currency led to the favoring of activities with visible short-term<br />

results, to the detriment of long-term investments (such as those related to<br />

environmental protection).<br />

Similarly, in a compilation of Latin American perspectives on the Brundtland<br />

report, Sunkel (1990) again demonstrates how the debt crisis, the deterioration<br />

in the terms of trade and the conditions of international financing introduced<br />

– or helped to perpetuate – despite what was promoted internationally, the<br />

precedence of the short term. It shows how the crisis reduced the capacity of<br />

the State to invest and attend to the basic necessities of the population (health,<br />

education). Investments that resulted in high exports were favored, which in<br />

turn generated resources that were channeled to pay off debts. Resources<br />

allocated to environmental protection, whose results were not tangible or only<br />

materialized in the long term, became scarce.<br />

However, just like the oil crisis at the beginning of the 70's, the debt crisis<br />

was also presented as an opportunity to change the style of economic growth<br />

and to make development compatible with the environment. Again similar to the<br />

first documents on green economy during the reactivation efforts of the global<br />

economy in 2008, Sunkel proposed, in 1985, a vision of the new crisis as an<br />

opportunity to change paths (free translation):<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

“It is possible to face the issue of environmental resources, the resources<br />

given by nature and the constructed ones, as a way to establish a link<br />

between short term economic policies and the need for medium and long term<br />

development policies. In other words, what I am suggesting is that we face<br />

the crisis as an opportunity. An opportunity to mobilize resources in a way that<br />

enables change in the style of growth, taking into consideration the need to


65<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy in Latin<br />

America: the origins of<br />

debate in ECLAC work<br />

satisfy the essential necessities of the population and introduce a sustainable,<br />

or “conscious”, development process.”<br />

The article argues for an expansive, but selective, policy rather than<br />

recessive adjustment; relates macroeconomic policies to the environment; and<br />

includes specific policies for social issues, for small and medium businesses<br />

and for industrial development. It also promotes the attachment of value to<br />

environmental and natural resources in order to ensure that present and future<br />

needs are met, This would influence the way in which the productive sectors,<br />

instrumental in shaping development patterns, view the environment. The<br />

1990's took a different direction.<br />

Márcia Tavares<br />

4. Pr o d u c t iv e t r a n s f o r m a t io n, e q u a l it y a n d t h e<br />

e n v ir o n m e n t, 1991<br />

The issue of productive transformation was a central them in ECLAC work<br />

over most of the 1990's. Building on the theoretical base developed since<br />

the end of the 1940's, in 1990 ECLAC proposed the concept of “productive<br />

transformation with equality” as a regional priority over the coming decade<br />

(ECLAC, 1990, 2008; Bielschowsky, 1998). A productive transformation<br />

was proposed that would be sustained by the deliberate and systematic<br />

incorporation of technical progress and increased productivity as factors<br />

necessary for authentic international competitiveness 8 . The systemic character<br />

of competitiveness was emphasized, as well as links between businesses,<br />

the education system, technological, energy and transport infrastructures,<br />

relations between employers and employees, the public and private institutional<br />

apparatus and the financial system. It was argued that a suitable and stable<br />

macroeconomic environment and a policy to correct prices, though necessary,<br />

would not be sufficient to trigger productive transformation. Macroeconomic<br />

management should be combined with sectoral policies, which could induce<br />

productive transformation. It was necessary to secure links between different<br />

sectors (exploitation of raw materials, industry, services) in order to generate<br />

a progressive homogenization of levels of productivity. Equality, democracy<br />

and environmental sustainability were seen as key factors in a productive<br />

transformation process.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

ECLAC´s document to support regional preparations for the Rio Summit<br />

in 1992, “Sustainable development: productive transformation, equity and<br />

environment” (ECLAC, 1991), was written in this context. The document<br />

deals with various issues related to sustainable development in the region,<br />

among them that of the relationship between productive transformation and<br />

sustainability, based on the results of a study specifically dedicated to the topic<br />

8. Concept construed in opposition to that of spurious competitiveness, based on the<br />

degradation of natural resources and low valuation of human resources.


66<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy in Latin<br />

America: the origins of<br />

debate in ECLAC work<br />

Márcia Tavares<br />

(ECLAC/UNIDO, 1991).<br />

The latter demonstrates that the traditional focus on productive development<br />

on the one hand, and ecology on the other, emphasized different and<br />

apparently irreconcilable objectives: growth and international competitiveness<br />

as opposed to equity and environmental sustainability. The link that could<br />

make these objectives converge would be the incorporation and diffusion of<br />

technical progress (ECLAC/UNIDO, 1991). The dependence of Latin American<br />

economies on natural resource extraction was seen as a concern; not only<br />

because of the related environmental problems, but also because the way<br />

in which these industries were organized was not conducive to overcoming<br />

sectoral “encapsulation”, that is, the lack of productive links between different<br />

sectors (primary, secondary, tertiary). The Latin American experience differed<br />

from that of some OECD countries whose economies were also based on<br />

natural resources, but whose industrial development had taken place mainly<br />

as a result of the transformation of these resources, in a context that enabled<br />

a wide range of technological innovation.<br />

Overcoming sectoral “encapsulation” required strong and coordinated<br />

policies; however, these were not sufficiently put into practice throughout the<br />

1990's. A 2008 assessment demonstrated that, despite a greater diversification<br />

of exports and economic benefits due to price increases in raw materials, the<br />

region had not managed to reduce dependence on traditional exports, nor<br />

incorporate more knowledge and aggregate value to activities and supply<br />

chains. The increase in manufactured exports had not been translated into<br />

an increase in activities of higher aggregate value, technology diffusion or<br />

generating technological capabilities. Innovation efforts continue being rare,<br />

especially if compared to Asian competitors (ECLAC, 2008).<br />

In the green economy debates, the development of new “green” sectors is<br />

mentioned as a way to stimulate economies, as a new technological paradigm. It<br />

is important to consider, when defining the instruments to be adopted nationally<br />

and internationally, that the challenge of productive transformation has persisted<br />

in the region for decades. Managing to use the green economy as a motor of<br />

economic expansion requires efforts of great magnitude in terms of policies<br />

related to education, innovation and productive development, which cannot<br />

be managed nor implemented solely by governmental agencies related to the<br />

environment.<br />

5. Po in t s f o r r e f l e c t i o n<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Among the questions that this compilation of documents raises for the green<br />

economy debate, the following are highlighted due to their importance and<br />

link to the second theme of <strong>Rio+20</strong>, the institutional framework for sustainable<br />

development.


67<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy in Latin<br />

America: the origins of<br />

debate in ECLAC work<br />

Márcia Tavares<br />

As a group, the documents mentioned are a reminder that the relation<br />

between environmental, social and economic problems in Latin America is<br />

profound and complex. The reflection on how to change these relations and<br />

solve the great environmental problems in the region, that disproportionately<br />

affect the poorest, must consider these roots. In this sense, green economy<br />

strategies will tend to be insufficient if managed and implemented separately<br />

by entities – governments, civil society, businesses and their representative<br />

entities – that deal with the environment as a specialized area.<br />

Secondly, seen with the benefit of hindsight, the documents show the<br />

importance of identifying and removing barriers to change. Already in 1971,<br />

solutions were suggested that continue to be debated internationally, but that are<br />

only marginally implemented, such as the adoption of a life-cycle approach to<br />

production. 9 Two ideas found at the origins of the international projection of the<br />

green economy concept – that of transforming crisis into opportunity to redirect<br />

development towards greater sustainability and that of making environmental<br />

protection a source of economic opportunities – had already emerged in 1980<br />

(Sunkel, 1980), if not before. Why did these ideas – of which ECLAC was only<br />

a small exponent – not have significant practical consequences? It is known<br />

that there are, among others, technological, entrepreneurial, legal, institutional<br />

and information barriers, including the difficulties of valuation of natural capital.<br />

There is an inertia derived from investments made under a paradigm that did not<br />

attribute value to the environment: investments in technology, energy sources,<br />

monitoring systems, industrial plants, business models, methods for calculating<br />

the cost-benefit of projects, public institution mandates, etc. To ensure that<br />

the green economy – under whichever precise concept comes to be adopted<br />

internationally and by each country – goes beyond a set of well-intended<br />

declarations, it will be necessary to overcome these barriers in a coordinated<br />

manner among institutions and actors in different spheres.<br />

On the other hand, as shown through the experience in the 1980's, if there<br />

are not strong and permanent institutions that can ensure that between two<br />

options the sustainable one is favored, the progress is nullified in times of crisis<br />

when choices have to be made between objectives.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Finally, the green economy has been mentioned as an opportunity for a<br />

new technological and innovation cycle. This could mean, for Latin American<br />

countries, the entrance into new markets and a new opportunity to participate in<br />

sectors with higher value added, that diffuse technology, in some cases linked to<br />

the natural resource sectors that are so important in the economies of the region.<br />

When considering this argument, it is important to keep in mind the experiences<br />

in the region with productive transformation – mentioned previously in relation<br />

9. In addition to debates on green economy, see the reports from the 18th and 19th sessions<br />

of the Commission on Sustainable Development, particularly with regards to the topic of<br />

consumption and sustainable production.


68<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

to the documents from the beginning of the 1990's – and the lessons learned:<br />

to take advantage of opportunities such as this active policies are needed, with<br />

clear strategic objectives. This includes an articulated combination of policies<br />

addressing education, and industry, science and technology, among others. A<br />

necessary condition is a clear choice, by a relevant and articulated group of<br />

public institutions, to prioritize a sustainable development path.<br />

Green economy in Latin<br />

America: the origins of<br />

debate in ECLAC work<br />

Márcia Tavares<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

References<br />

Bielschowsky, R. (1998). Cincuenta años del pensamiento de La CEPAL: una reseña.<br />

In CEPAL, Cincuenta Años de Pensamiento en la CEPAL: Texto Seleccionados.<br />

Mexico: ECLAC/Fondo de Cultura Económica.<br />

Bielschowsky, R. (2009). Sesenta años de la CEPAL: estructuralismo y neoestructuralismo.<br />

In Revista de la CEPAL, n. 97. April, 173-194.<br />

ECLAC (1971). El medio ambiente humano y el desarrollo económico en América<br />

Latina. Seminário Regional Latinoamericano sobre los Problemas del Medio Ambiente<br />

Humano y Desarrollo, ST/ECLA/Conf.40/L.2, August 25, Santiago de Chile.<br />

ECLAC (1990). Transformación productiva com equidad: la tarea prioritaria del desarrollo<br />

em América Latina y el Caribe em los años noventa (LC/G.1601-P). Santiago de<br />

Chile: United Nations <strong>Publication</strong>.<br />

ECLAC (1991). El desarrollo sustentable: transformación productiva, equidad y médio<br />

ambiente (LC./G.1648(CONF.80/2)/Rev.1.). Santiago de Chile: United Nations<br />

<strong>Publication</strong>.<br />

ECLAC (2008). La transformación productiva 20 años después: viejos problemas,<br />

nuevas oportunidades (LC/G.2367(SES.32/3). United Nations <strong>Publication</strong>.<br />

ECLAC (2010). La hora de la igualdad: brechas por cerrar, caminos por abrir (LC/<br />

G.2432(SES.33/3). Santiago de Chile: United Nations <strong>Publication</strong>.<br />

ECLAC/UNIDO (1991). Tecnología, Competitividad y Sustentabilidad (LC.L/608).<br />

Santiago de Chile: United Nations <strong>Publication</strong>.<br />

Gligo, N. (2006). Estilos de desarrollo y medio ambiente en América Latina, un cuarto<br />

de siglo después. Serie Medio Ambiente y Desarrollo, n. 126, May. ECLAC.<br />

OECD (2010). Interim report of the green growth strategy: implementing our commitment<br />

for a sustainable future. Paris: OECD.<br />

Pinto, A. (1970[2000]). Natureza e Implicações da Heterogeneidade Estrutural da<br />

América Latina. In Bielschowsky, R. (org.), Cinquenta anos de pensamento da CEPAL.<br />

Rio de Janeir; São Paulo: ed. Record, ECLAC, Cofecon, vol.2.<br />

Prebisch, R. (1980). Biósfera y desarrollo. In Sunkel, O. and Gligo, N. (comp.), Estilos<br />

de Desarrollo y Medio Ambiente en la América Latina. Mexico: Fondo de Cultura<br />

Económica.<br />

Sunkel, O. (1980). Introducción: la interacción entre los estilos de desarrollo y el<br />

medio ambiente en la América Latina. In Sunkel, O. and Gligo, N. (comp.), Estilos<br />

de desarrollo y medio ambiente en la América Latina. Mexico: Fondo de Cultura<br />

Económica.<br />

Sunkel, O. (1985). Dívida, desenvolvimento e meio-ambiente. Espaços & Debates –<br />

Revista de Estudos Regionais e Urbanos, ano V, no. 16.<br />

Sunkel, O. (1990). El difícil contexto internacional para un desarrollo sustentable. In<br />

Maihold, Günther and Victor L. Urquidi (comp.), Dialogo con nuestro futuro comun:<br />

perspectivas latinoamericanas del Informe Brundtland. Mexico: Fundación Friedrich<br />

Ebert- Editorial Nueva Sociedad.


69<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The role of inclusive growth<br />

for a green economy in<br />

developing countries<br />

Clóvis Zapata 1<br />

In t r o d u c t io n<br />

The proposition that anthropogenic emissions of greenhouse gases have<br />

dangerously modified global climate is already consensually accepted. One<br />

may ask, however, what the economic impacts are of necessary measures to<br />

achieve reductions in emissions levels and environmental degradation capable<br />

of minimizing such effects. Environmental economists agree that public policies<br />

based on economic incentive instruments can alleviate the effects caused by<br />

climate change at an acceptable cost.<br />

According to the 2011 UNEP report “Towards a green economy: pathways<br />

to sustainable development and eradication of poverty”, in a green economy<br />

income and employment growth is fostered by public and private investment<br />

that reduces carbon emissions and pollution, improves efficiency in the use<br />

of energy and natural resources, and avoids the loss of biodiversity and<br />

ecosystem services. These investments should be supported by directed public<br />

expenditure, policy reform and regulatory changes. This development path<br />

should maintain, improve and, where necessary, rebuild natural capital as a<br />

critical economic asset and source of public benefits, especially for poor people<br />

whose survival and security depend strongly on nature. The essential notion<br />

advocated by the green economy concept is that public policy coupled with<br />

changes in key sectors can conduce national economies to admissible levels of<br />

environmental degradation, without drastic changes in consumption patterns.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Despite the theoretical possibility, the practical challenge is tremendous<br />

for developing economies, since public policy makers must already associate<br />

economic growth with other areas, such as increased consumption patterns to<br />

the poorest segments of society. In this sense, Gunningham et al. (2003) point<br />

to the importance of combining economic, social, environmental and political<br />

dimensions in the design of both economic incentive instruments and commandand-control<br />

measures for environmental policy , which is a fundamental issue<br />

for developing economies willing to enter the green economy.<br />

1. Senior researcher at the International Policy Centre for Inclusive Growth of the United<br />

Nations Development Programme (IPC-IG/UNDP) and professor of Finance at the University<br />

of Brasília.


70<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The role of inclusive<br />

growth for a<br />

green economy in<br />

developing countries<br />

Clóvis Zapata<br />

Th e g r e e n e c o n o m y<br />

The green economy can be defined as a paradigm shift that proposes a<br />

reduction of current environmental risks and ecological limitations, coupled<br />

with an increased human well-being and social equity (UNEP, 2011). Thus, the<br />

concept can be easily connected to the notion of inclusive growth, which proposes<br />

improved quality of life for all those that live in an economy. In this sense, both<br />

are of fundamental importance for policy makers in developing countries.<br />

In order for an economy to move from the current model to the desirable green,<br />

investments in strategic areas of natural capital that minimize environmental<br />

risks are fundamental. Despite the issue having been presented extensively in<br />

the academic literature, governments have only recently started to take more<br />

proactive measures to translate the rather vague green economy concept into<br />

practical actions.<br />

It is worth emphasizing the role played by international organizations, such as<br />

the United Nations, which provide a forum for permanent debate, disseminating<br />

successful cases of developed and developing countries and presenting<br />

innovative policy proposals. The Green Initiative, for instance, was launched<br />

in 2009 by the UNEP, as part of the nine UN-Wide Joint Crisis Initiatives that<br />

involve all 21 UN agencies, including the Bretton Woods institutions.<br />

Contributions are also made in the area of public policy proposals. The most<br />

prominent example has been the UNEP report that broadly defends that annual<br />

investments equivalent to 2% of the global GDP (close to US$ 1.3 trillion) until<br />

2050 would fuel the development and transition of 11 key sectors to a green<br />

economy (UNEP, 2011). These are: 1- agriculture, 2- buildings, 3- renewable<br />

energy, 4- forestry, 5- manufacturing industry, 6- fishery resources, 7- tourism,<br />

8- transport, 9- water resources, 10- solid waste management and 11- cities.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

According to the defended thesis, investments coupled with political reforms<br />

should foster change in the selected industrial sectors, which would improve<br />

the industries competitive position in the long term. As a consequences,<br />

sustainability transformation could be driven by eco-efficient solutions, which<br />

propose more efficient utilization of scarce natural resources and present<br />

innumerable social benefits, such as employment in 'green jobs'. From a<br />

social perspective, this process can conduct emerging countries to a situation<br />

where a growing green economy unfolds into the desired inclusive growth.<br />

The development of these key sectors can reduce poverty and minimize<br />

income discrepancies. To achieve this, the policy menu is diverse, including<br />

direct generation of green jobs, increased access to environmental products<br />

and services in needy communities, design of conditional cash transfers,<br />

direct subsidies to certain industrial sectors and restructure of national public<br />

spending policies.


71<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The role of inclusive<br />

growth for a<br />

green economy in<br />

developing countries<br />

Clóvis Zapata<br />

Many developing countries have already incorporated sustainable<br />

development concepts, at least in certain sectors, that link various key policy<br />

areas such as pro-poor and pro-employment economic growth. In this sense,<br />

a fundamental aspect for developing countries is that the inclusion of a<br />

green economy can connect dimensions that were previously perceived as<br />

antagonistic.<br />

According to Gunningham et al., (2003), environmental, social, economic and<br />

political dimensions should be taken into account when designing public policies<br />

capable of modifying environmental progress in industrial sectors. An analysis of<br />

the 'license to operate' model indicates the relevance of the interaction between<br />

dimensions as the starting point for influencing the environmental progress of<br />

industry. . As such, these diverse dimensions should be taken into account by<br />

countries that are interested in developing certain sectors of the economy.<br />

This holistic understanding goes beyond the interpretations offered by<br />

authors of corporate strategy such as Porter and Van der Lind (1995) and Hart<br />

(1997), who were pioneers in the idea that the private sector can benefit from<br />

environmental regulation in competitive terms. Such concepts were thereafter<br />

modified by Reinhardt (2000) and Orsato (2009), that indicate conditions where<br />

gains could be realized. Despite the great relevance of such literature, few<br />

industrial sectors have actually awoken to the new areas of green economy,<br />

especially in developing countries. Many of the efforts have been solely<br />

focused on the green discourse and green packaging of old unsustainable<br />

practices. Thus, the role that governments and international organizations play<br />

in promoting the agenda for developing a green economy is essential, since the<br />

combination of fiscal incentives and regulations can accelerate the process of<br />

change through technological innovation and the creation of green markets. If<br />

left to the exclusive will of the private sector, as has been the case, economies<br />

turn out to be incapable of actually entering into a green economy.<br />

It is important to note that social, economic, political and environmental<br />

dimensions follow different mecanisms that should be carefully understood<br />

for developing countries. Despite the existence of potential synergies and<br />

strong interactions between these dimensions, it cannot be assumed that the<br />

dynamics and responses of each one can be identical. Each country faces<br />

the challenge of finding solutions that drive economic growth in a way that is<br />

environmentally sustainable, socially inclusive and politically feasible, within<br />

their unique contexts.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Th e c o m p l e m e n t a r it y b e t w e e n s o c ia l a n d<br />

e n v ir o n m e n t a l d im e n s io n s<br />

In terms of public policy, the economic and social dimensions have been on<br />

the centre of policy making in developing countries. Although the development


72<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The role of inclusive<br />

growth for a<br />

green economy in<br />

developing countries<br />

Clóvis Zapata<br />

of social policies should be coupled with the development of the green economy,<br />

the evolution seen in the field of social program design was not accompanied<br />

by environmental concerns. In the social field, Brazil and other developing<br />

countries recently adopted a series of innovative social protection strategies<br />

to improve the lifestyles of the poorest. Brazil, for example, implemented the<br />

Family Grant program (Bolsa Familia), and Mexico the Oportunidades. Such<br />

programs have generated significant benefits in combating poverty, raising the<br />

living standards of the population in certain areas and guaranteeing benefits<br />

in the fields of education and health.<br />

However, the interaction between social and environmental policies still<br />

requires more robust debate. One of the options presented by some countries is<br />

the payment for environmental services, which utilizes conditional cash transfer<br />

instruments to rural landowners that preserve part of their land, as was done<br />

in Costa Rica. Such programs have generated positive effects, but still have<br />

not been widely adopted in other countries. In Brazil, for example, despite the<br />

success of the Family Grant program and the efforts by the Brazilian Ministry<br />

of the Environment, the country has not been capable of introducing a payment<br />

for environmental services program in an effective large scale manner.<br />

It is noteworthy that the generation of green jobs through the sectors<br />

highlighted by UNEP (2011) is essentially different, as it is based on the belief<br />

that the market is capable of generating such positions, with support provided<br />

by the public sector. Conditional cash transfer programs are designed to tackle<br />

a different issue, since they are better equipped to eliminate distortions relative<br />

to extreme poverty and to families in great need for financial resources. Green<br />

jobs focus on substituting unsustainable processes with cleaner more advanced<br />

alternatives.<br />

The 'license to operate' framework presented by Gunningham et al. (2003)<br />

notes that the interaction between social, environmental, economic and political<br />

licenses is intricate and should be analysed case by case. In a very simplified<br />

way, conditional cash transfer programs can be seen as inducers of a non-trivial<br />

response. Such programs serve to solve poverty issues, but still have not been<br />

able to fully incorporate exit strategies nor the environmental dimension..<br />

However, policies of productive inclusion can be designed to attend to<br />

environmental needs and promote key sectors in the green economy.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

In d u s t r ia l d e v e l o p m e n t a n d p r o d u c t iv e in c l u s io n:<br />

t h e c a s e o f t h e Br a z il ia n Bi o d i e s e l Pr o g r a m<br />

Beyond social strategies, the development of a green economy requires<br />

structured growth policies, which generate jobs and include marginal<br />

populations in supply chains with high aggregate values. Social strategies can<br />

serve as complements to deal with specific social aspects, but as sources of


73<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The role of inclusive<br />

growth for a<br />

green economy in<br />

developing countries<br />

Clóvis Zapata<br />

development and 'green' innovation. As such, the combination of expansionist<br />

macroeconomic policies capable of generating employment and income,<br />

coupled with national structures that encourage industrial development, is<br />

fundamental. In this section, these issues will be briefly contextualized with<br />

the use of the Brazilian Biodiesel Program case.<br />

Biodiesel is an area of great debate in the development of renewable energy<br />

for transport. Brazil is internationally recognized as one of the leaders in the<br />

research and development of biofuels for the automotive industry. In this context,<br />

the Brazilian Biodiesel Program brings important elements to the debate, as<br />

it relates both to the areas of sustainable transport and renewable energy, as<br />

well as presents a political structure to address the social dimension.<br />

The Brazilian Biodiesel Program has been developed to structure the<br />

productive supply chain and incorporate small family farmers in the production of<br />

raw materials for the production of biodiesel. The program was designed so that<br />

small farmers could contribute with a series of vegetable sources such as soy,<br />

castor bean, sunflower, palm and cotton. Despite the extensive background the<br />

country possess in this area, the inclusion of small family farmers in the biofuel<br />

supply chain was an innovative policy effort that turned out to be disappointing,<br />

due to innumerable problems related to the program design and implementation<br />

(Zapata et al., 2010).<br />

In 2010, the government, perceiving the need to redirect the program to<br />

increase the participation of small farmers, remodeled the program structure and<br />

placed Petrobras Biofuels as principal stakeholderr. After this change, positive<br />

anecdotal evidence has have emerged. . It is expected that consolidated data<br />

will be available this year.<br />

The Brazilian Biodiesel Program has shown that the policies that t seek<br />

to reduce poverty through the productive inclusion of small family farmers is<br />

complex, but feasible. Lessons can be taken and applied in other countries that<br />

wish to follow similar paths. Despite the effort of combining the environmental<br />

and social dimensions, Brazil takes timid steps in the development of<br />

technologies and radical innovation strategies, such as hydrogen and electric<br />

or hybrid vehicles. The transport strategy is based on incremental modifications<br />

of internal combustion engines with marginal environmental effect (Zapata and<br />

Nieuwenhuis, 2010).<br />

Th e So u t h-So u t h d e b a t e<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Beyond the central importance of social and environmental dimensions for<br />

the development of a green economy in developing countries, the political<br />

dimension is also crucial. Interest groups can influence governments and society<br />

to take measures that generate profound changes in determined areas of the<br />

economy and can strengthen the elements necessary for the development of


74<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The role of inclusive<br />

growth for a<br />

green economy in<br />

developing countries<br />

Clóvis Zapata<br />

the green economy. As such, f international organizations can play a central role<br />

that presents feasible opportunities to shape the political dimension in accord<br />

with the interests of wider society and not just specific interest groups. The<br />

United Nations system, for example, has achieved highly significant results in<br />

the political sphere through the promotion of international discussion forums.<br />

Experiences with rural and urban inclusive production that drive development<br />

in sectors specific to the development of a green economy should be better<br />

studied and shared between countries with similar characteristics. In the field<br />

of productive inclusion policies or conditional cash transfers, the sharing of<br />

experiences among southern countries is fundamental. In this context, it is<br />

important to emphasize the efforts made in the IBSA (India, Brazil and South<br />

Africa) and BRIC (Brazil, Russia, India and China) countries through IPC-IG,<br />

which has acted as catalyst in the debate and experience sharing in specific<br />

forums for these two groups.<br />

Co n c l u s io n<br />

The green economy is an ample concept that should be better translated into<br />

measures that modify the current structure of national economies. The current<br />

debate is lead by UNEP is based on the premise that incremental modifications<br />

in selected industrial sectors would be sufficient to conduct humanity towards<br />

sustainability. However, the demands from developing countries are pressing,<br />

as aside from the critical environmental dimension, the social dimension is also<br />

in desperate need. In this sense, the concept of inclusive growth should be<br />

fundamentally incorporated in the green economy discussion.<br />

In general terms, the discourse of international organizations and many<br />

countries is substantially optimistic, and based on the dissemination of<br />

successful cases in certain areas. However, it is important to note that the<br />

international replicability of such experiences is very limited, since each strategic<br />

sector exists within specific local and national conditions, with particular social,<br />

environmental, economic and political dimensions.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The efforts made by the United Nations and other international organizations<br />

are essential, but still incipient in the area of green economy. The private<br />

sector should play a leading role in this context. However, It should be noted<br />

that the consensus among environmental economists disappears regarding<br />

the time necessary to achieve such transformations. A process of profound<br />

change in production and consumption, based on radical innovation, is not on<br />

the agenda, because much more substantial investments would be required.<br />

Thus, we should ask if the current debate on the green economy encompasses<br />

the sense of urgency necessary to solve the environmental problem within the<br />

required time-frame.


75<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The role of inclusive<br />

growth for a<br />

green economy in<br />

developing countries<br />

Clóvis Zapata<br />

References<br />

Gunningham, N., Kagan, R. and Thornton, D. (2003). Shades of green: business, regulation,<br />

and environment. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press.<br />

Hart, S. (1997). Beyond greening: strategies for a sustainable world. Harvard Business<br />

Review, 75(1), 66–76.<br />

Orsato, R. (2009). Sustainability strategies. New York: Palgrave MacMillan and INSEAD<br />

Business Press.<br />

Porter, M. and Van der Linde, C. (1995). Towards a new conception of the environmentcompetitiveness<br />

relationship. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(4), 97-118.<br />

Reinhardt, F. (2000). Down to earth, applying business principles to environmental<br />

management. Cambridge: Harvard Business School Press.<br />

UNEP (2011). Towards a green economy: pathways to sustainable development and<br />

poverty eradication. Retrieved from: .<br />

Zapata, C. and Nieuwenhuis, P. (2010). Exploring innovation in the automotive industry:<br />

new technologies for cleaner cars. Journal of Cleaner Production, 18(1), 14-20.<br />

Zapata, C., Vazquez-Brust, D. and Plaza-Úbeda, J. (2010). Productive inclusion of<br />

smallholder farmers in Brazil’s biodiesel value chain: programme design, institutional<br />

incentives and stakeholder constraints. International Policy Centre for Inclusive<br />

Growth Working paper 73.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011


76<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: a panorama<br />

Francisco Gaetani 1<br />

Ernani Kuhn 2<br />

Renato Rosenberg 3<br />

1. In t r o d u c t io n<br />

Upon seeking to understand the situation in Brazil as relates to the green<br />

economy (GE) and its perspectives, some crucial questions arise. What are<br />

the main advances already achieved in relation to GE? How is Brazil doing<br />

in comparison to other countries? What are the main challenges that need to<br />

be addressed? These questions are ample, current and narrowly related to<br />

discussions about the impacts of climate change and new formulations in the<br />

sphere of economic theory.<br />

According to the document “Green Economy: synthesis for policy makers”,<br />

elaborated by the UNEP in 2011, green economy can be defined as that<br />

which results in improvements to human well-being and social equity, while<br />

significantly reducing environmental risks and ecological scarcities. In other<br />

words, GE can be thought of along the lines of low carbon, efficient resource<br />

use and social inclusion.<br />

Productive restructuring efforts towards a greener economy are part of<br />

government programs both in developed and emerging countries. Development<br />

of new markets guided by cleaner energy sources, sustainable arrangements<br />

of economic activities and socio-economic inclusion, dominated the debate in<br />

the second half of the 20th century, though the 2008 financial crisis and the<br />

democratic revival in the Arab world have re-introduced the regressive scenario<br />

of predatory growth on the agenda.<br />

2. Br a z il a s p o t e n t ia l e n v ir o n m e n t a l e n e r g y<br />

s u p e r p o w e r<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

To analyze the GE potential of Brazil, it is fundamental to also understand<br />

the distinguished role of the country in relation to its privileged environmental<br />

conditions of natural resources abundance. The national territory encompasses<br />

the second largest forest area on the planet, which occupies around 4.8 million<br />

square kilometers; representing 56% of national territory and 10% of global<br />

1. Deputy Minister of the Brazilian Ministry of the Environment.<br />

2. Program Director at the Brazilian Ministry of the Environment.<br />

3. Technical Advisor to the Brazilian Ministry of the Environment.


77<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: a panorama<br />

Francisco Gaetani<br />

Ernani Kuhn<br />

Renato Rosenberg<br />

forests (Governo Federal, 2008). Beyond these great dimensions, the forests<br />

are also rather diversified, ranging from the Amazon rainforest, the Araucarias<br />

Forests (Brazilian pine forests), the seasonal forests, the tropical Atlantic<br />

Forests, the Caatinga (Brazilian dry forests), the Campinaranas (Brazilian heath<br />

forests), to the Cerrado (Brazilian savannahs), making this the most bio-diverse<br />

country on the planet – the other two with similar characteristics are Indonesia<br />

and the Democratic Republic of the Congo.<br />

In terms of water resources, Brazil also exhibits indicators of global relevance:<br />

the country has approximately 12% of the surface water available on the planet<br />

according to the Brazilian National Water Agency, to which the Amazon region<br />

contributes almost 75% (MMA, 2010). In addition to the genetic wealth derived<br />

from the country’s biodiversity, an enviable natural resource endowment has<br />

also been recorded – in the volume of deposits and heterogeneity of resources<br />

– comparable only to Russia, the United States, Canada and Australia.<br />

Brazil has been developing a series of institutional, economic and<br />

technological instruments aimed at preserving and utilizing these resources in<br />

a more rational and sustainable way. This is a recent effort, though it has been<br />

gathering force over the past 25 years. The challenge today is to benefit from the<br />

accumulated efforts in favor of environmental preservation and socio-economic<br />

development, by taking advantage of the global window of opportunity that is<br />

opening through and for Brazil.<br />

One example of a distinguished initiative is the Brazilian experience with<br />

using combustible alcohol, more commonly known as ethanol fuel. Research<br />

to utilize ethanol derived from sugarcane in automotive engines began in the<br />

1920’s (Magalhães and Schartzman, 1981). By the 1930’s, Decree n. 19.717 (20<br />

February 1931) made the addition of ethanol to gasoline mandatory. The first oil<br />

crisis in 1973 brought an energy shortage to the country. Through the National<br />

Ethanol Program (Pró-Álcool), Brazil was mobilized to produce ethanol to be<br />

mixed with gasoline as a first step, and subsequently to be utilized directly as<br />

fuel on a large scale, which put Brazil in a unique position in relation to the rest<br />

of the world. In recent years, cars called flex (bio-fueled) have already reached<br />

a relevant share of the vehicle fleet sold in the country, and thus significantly<br />

changing the fuel consumption profile, by consolidating the possibility of using<br />

ethanol as a substitute to gasoline and by affecting the demand characteristics<br />

in this market by suddenly offering consumers a choice.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Such initiatives did not have environmental protection as an objective. Today,<br />

however, they are of significant importance in the Brazilian strategy to achieve<br />

a transition to a green economy. In the case of ethanol, this fuel emits much<br />

lower levels of greenhouse gases than its main competitor, gasoline.<br />

According to the Brazilian Ministry of Mines and Energy, between 1970 and<br />

2007 the consumption 854 million barrels of petroleum was avoided due to the


78<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: a panorama<br />

Francisco Gaetani<br />

Ernani Kuhn<br />

Renato Rosenberg<br />

utilization of ethanol, and thereby withholding the emission of 800 million tons of<br />

CO 2 into the atmosphere (MME, 2008). Aggregated to this is the public health<br />

benefit due to reduced emissions of atmospheric pollutants. The increased<br />

agricultural and industrial productivity in the ethanol sector, a result of intensive<br />

research and development, to a certain extent contributed to reduce pressure<br />

on forests being converted into agricultural land. Despite increased productivity,<br />

the recent higher levels of demand made the adoption of mitigative measures<br />

a necessity in order to preserve areas with important environmental capital.<br />

In addition to technological progress, there were a series of measures of an<br />

institutional character that enabled Brazil to capitalize on its enormous potential<br />

to generate environmental benefits. Among these, the Forest Code (1965) and<br />

the National Environmental Policy (1981) stand out historically. More recently,<br />

a presidential decree was issued to approve the Agroecological Zoning of<br />

sugarcane, which prohibited plantations in environmentally sensitive areas,<br />

such as forest remnants, sand dunes, mangroves and strategic biomes and<br />

hydrographic basins, more specifically in the Amazon, the Pantanal and the<br />

Alto Paraguai basin. Also established were standards to encourage mechanical<br />

harvesting as a way to curb the burning of straw from sugarcane.<br />

These are some examples of GE in Brazil: develop economic, technological<br />

and institutional instruments to benefit efficiently from the excellent natural<br />

conditions of the country and ensure that the benefits gained through these<br />

activities are inclusively incorporated into Brazilian society.<br />

3. Br a z il o n t h e in t e r n a t io n a l s c e n e<br />

However, in spite of favorable natural and geographic conditions, Brazil is a<br />

large emitter of CO 2 . In 2005, total global emissions of GHG reached 44.130<br />

billion metric tons of carbon equivalent (MtCO2eq) and increased at an annual<br />

rate of 1.24% between 1990 and 2005 (ECLAC, 2010). In this context, Latin<br />

America and the Caribbean contributed to 12% of total global emissions,<br />

with an amount of 5.390 MtCO 2 eq, and exhibited a growth rate similar to the<br />

global average of 1.19% between 1990 and 2005. It can also be noted that<br />

the emissions per country in the region are very heterogeneous, with a strong<br />

relative concentration in some countries. Furthermore, there are differentiated<br />

behaviors based on emission sources, with growth in energy sources and<br />

the relative dominance of emissions resulting from changes in land use<br />

(deforestation) (ECLAC, 2010).<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

During the period 1990-2005, Brazil exhibited a percentage growth in<br />

emissions below the average for the region. Nevertheless, Brazil is the largest<br />

GHG emitter in the region, corresponding to more than 50% of emissions<br />

during the mentioned period (ECLAC, 2010). Considering total equivalent CO 2<br />

emissions during the same period, excluding emissions from land use (Barbier,


79<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: a panorama<br />

Francisco Gaetani<br />

Ernani Kuhn<br />

Renato Rosenberg<br />

2009), the country is in 7th place globally (2.6%), behind China (18.6%), the<br />

United States (18%), the European Union (13%), Russia (5.1%), India (4.8%)<br />

and Japan (3.5%). It is worth pointing out that in Brazil, the greatest part of GHG<br />

emissions stems from change in land use that, if included in this calculation,<br />

would certainly elevate the country to one of the greatest global emitters.<br />

The main sources of emissions at a global level are concentrated in the<br />

energy sector (65%), followed by the agricultural sector (14%) and emissions<br />

caused by changes in land use (12%). Emission sources in Latin America<br />

and the Caribbean have a unique structure in that emissions originating from<br />

changes in land use represent almost half of the regional total, while the energy<br />

sector makes up 28% and agriculture 20% (ECLAC, 2010). This demonstrates<br />

that mitigation strategies in Latin America should consider both emissions<br />

related to energy consumption and, primarily, the levels of deforestation and<br />

land degradation.<br />

When considering per capita emissions of GHG in 1990 and 2005, Brazil<br />

occupied 4th place among the greatest regional emitters, behind only Bolivia,<br />

Venezuela and Trinidad and Tobago. Considering CO2 emissions from energy<br />

consumption and the production of cement (2005), Brazil is below the levels of<br />

the countries in Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC, 2010).<br />

When speaking about climate change in Brazil, as a large emitter of GHG,<br />

the country has already adopted a pro-active stance by assuming voluntary<br />

goals within the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change and<br />

the Kyoto Protocol. The country committed to, through its National Policy on<br />

Climate Change (Governo Federal, 2008), reduce between 36.1% and 38.9%<br />

of its projected emissions for the year 2020. In concrete terms, this means<br />

reducing close to 6% of its emissions relative to the base year 2005, by the<br />

year 2020, which is equivalent to around 132 million tons of carbon equivalent.<br />

This attitude should have a positive impact, if not fundamental, on future Kyoto<br />

Protocol negotiations.<br />

4. Pr in c ip a l Ac t io n s 4<br />

4.1 Forests<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

With regards to the National Policy on Climate Change, important advances<br />

were recorded for the year 2010, most noteworthy being the National Fund on<br />

Climate Change regulation, in which it was established that part of the funds<br />

would be derived from the petroleum supply chain. Among the objectives of<br />

fund are combating desertification, education and training projects, with the<br />

development and diffusion of technologies, support for sustainable supply<br />

chains and payment for environmental services.<br />

4. The source of the mentioned actions is Presidência da República do Brasil (2011).


80<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: a panorama<br />

Francisco Gaetani<br />

Ernani Kuhn<br />

Renato Rosenberg<br />

Another sensitive point is preventing and controlling deforestation and<br />

burning. In the important Amazon biome, between 1st August 2009 and 31<br />

July 2010, an area of 6,451 km² was deforested according to Brazilian National<br />

Institute for Space Research. The rate represents a 13.6% reduction compared<br />

to the previous period and close to 75% in relation to data from 2003.<br />

The so-called Action Plan for Prevention and Control of Deforestation in<br />

the Amazon centralized its efforts in 43 municipalities responsible for the<br />

highest deforestation rates. Close to 90% succeeded in reducing this process.<br />

Furthermore, in order to accelerate the process of environmental regularization<br />

of rural properties in the Amazon, 94 municipalities initiated Rural Environmental<br />

Registration activities. Just in the states of Mato Grosso and Para, this<br />

registration has already been implemented on more than 40,000 properties.<br />

Command and control mechanisms, especially enforcement instruments,<br />

have also been utilized in the region. Over the analyzed period, the Brazilian<br />

Institute of Environment and Renewable Natural Resource with help from the<br />

National Public Security Force, the Federal Police and the Federal Highway<br />

Police, issued close to 5,400 fines for a total value of R$ 1.8 billion. Close to 86<br />

thousand m³ of timber were seized and 170 thousand hectares embargoed.<br />

In the Cerrado biome, measures are also planned to reduce deforestation<br />

rates, burning, and forest fires through the Action Plan for Prevention and<br />

Controlling Deforestation and Burning in the Cerrado. Highlights include the<br />

systematic monitoring system of the Cerrado forest cover, the training of 4.5<br />

thousand firefighters, the drafting of the Ecologic and Economic ‘Macro-zoning’<br />

for Cerrado regions, the creation of 2.5 million hectares of protected areas (or<br />

conservation units, the term used in Brazil), the inclusion of more than seven<br />

socio-biodiversity products in the Minimum Price Guarantee Policy, the provision<br />

of credit lines for recovery of degraded pastures and increase of planted forests<br />

in already open areas.<br />

The Plan to Prevent and Control Deforestation in the Caatinga Biome,<br />

which is in elaboration phase by the Federal Government, will be concluded in<br />

2011. With the increased monitoring of national territories that stems from the<br />

Monitoring Deforestation of Brazilian Biomes via Satellite Project, more recent<br />

data will be provided for Caatinga, Pantanal and Atlantic forest biomes. The<br />

challenges are great, but changes are taking place.<br />

4.2 Macro-zoning<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Ecological-economic macro-zoning in the Legal Amazon, which comprises<br />

the territories of nine Brazilian states, was institutionalized by decree in<br />

December 2010. The same year, physical, biotic and socio-economic diagnoses<br />

were published for the hydrographic basin of the Sao Francisco River. Currently,<br />

close to 50% of the territory has already received some directive on land use


81<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: a panorama<br />

Francisco Gaetani<br />

Ernani Kuhn<br />

Renato Rosenberg<br />

and occupation, at the scale of 1:250.000. More than 2/3 of the national area is<br />

covered by this zoning. Such zoning is important to make agricultural production<br />

compatible with environmental issues, aiming to avoid disordered expansion<br />

and the resulting environmental damage.<br />

Macro-zoning is a fundamental instrument for implementing an environmental<br />

policy that necessarily is linked to territories. The migration of portions of the<br />

Brazilian economy towards a green economy has various dimensions with<br />

implications for regional development that should be anticipated through the<br />

incorporation of these concerns in the sustainability dimension beyond microentrepreneurial<br />

viewpoints. The macro-regions that have guided environmental<br />

policy – the six biomes: the Amazon, Caatinga, Cerrado, Atlantic Forest,<br />

Pantanal and Pampa – require analyzes that overlap them with other vectors<br />

of economic and social development, such as the Accelerated Growth Program<br />

and its infrastructure investments, local productive arrangements, settlements<br />

and others, in order to permit the planning of environmental, economic and<br />

social responses to each specific context.<br />

4.3 Solid waste treatment<br />

Another thematic area acting as important catalyst in the development of a<br />

green economy in Brazil is the treatment of urban solid waste. The National<br />

Solid Waste Policy was endorsed on 2 August 2010 and its regulation enacted<br />

on 23 December the same year. With the 2011 drafting of the National Solid<br />

Waste Plan, the implementation of the National Waste Management Information<br />

System and the realization of Sectorial Accords, which should consider the<br />

reverse logistics implementation mechanisms of main products and the<br />

packaging of each activity, there is a context of great expectations and a lot of<br />

activity for the government and the diverse actors involved.<br />

The development of these markets and the change in operational levels<br />

indicate a new scale in the greening process of the economy, with implications<br />

for business areas that are traditionally influenced by local and state<br />

governments. Basic sanitation, solid waste and reverse logistics are important<br />

pillars of the (new) green economy. These are markets whose growth rates will<br />

be substantially greater than the average for the economy.<br />

4.4 Water resources<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The year 2010 was characterized by a strengthened National Water<br />

Resources Policy and National Water Resources Management System.<br />

Relevant events took place, such as the 1st National Water Conference and<br />

the first revision of the National Water Resources Plan. Other actions stand<br />

out, such as the development of a matrix of technical coefficients for water


82<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: a panorama<br />

Francisco Gaetani<br />

Ernani Kuhn<br />

Renato Rosenberg<br />

consumption in production processes and a general equilibrium model; the<br />

strategic planning of National Water Resources Management System and the<br />

development of strategies for strengthening the National Water Resources<br />

Council; and the development of the National Water Resource Plan Information<br />

System, that will be integrated with the National System of Water Resources<br />

Information.<br />

Other initiatives deserve to be mentioned. The Hydrographic Basin<br />

Revitalization Program seeks to contribute to minimizing environmental<br />

degradation and recuperating the natural state of water resources. The<br />

Program is decentralized and carried out through partnerships with states and<br />

municipalities. In 2010, actions in the Sao Francisco river basin were prioritized,<br />

which included the implementation of a water supply system in riverain<br />

communities in 106 municipalities, sewage system works in 194 municipalities<br />

and solid waste treatment system projects in 13 inter-municipal consortiums.<br />

Charging for water use has been implemented in Brazil since 2001. For<br />

rivers controlled by the Union, charges have already been established for the<br />

Paraíba do Sul river basin (southeast region of Brazil) since 2003, the rivers<br />

basins of Piracicaba, Capivari and Jundiaí (southeast region of Brazil) since<br />

2006 and the Sao Francisco river basin since 2010. The raised resources fully<br />

return to the water agencies or delegated entities.<br />

4.5 Forest management<br />

In the field of public forest management, the forest concession, among others,<br />

has started to be adopted as a way to protect public property and structure<br />

a sustainable economy with a forest basis. The Brazilian Forest Service has<br />

already provided more than a million hectares for forest management, an activity<br />

that can generate jobs and move the economy in places that need sustainable<br />

development. This is the beginning of a process to capitalize on a business<br />

area with great potential.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Forest management is simultaneously perceived as an alternative action<br />

to economic exploitation, environmental preservation and socio-productive<br />

inclusion. The dissemination of good practices in this sphere is conditioned<br />

on factors such as a) the development of forest research that indicates viable<br />

and economically feasible alternatives to exploitation; b) business modeling<br />

so that the Brazilian Forest Service, the Brazilian Institute of Environment and<br />

Renewable Natural Resource and the Chico Mendes Institute for Biodiversity<br />

Conservation work in harmony to construct partnerships with the private sector;<br />

and c) demonstrating the economic viability of this type of venture, however,<br />

not at the expense of environmental protection and social concerns.


83<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: a panorama<br />

Francisco Gaetani<br />

Ernani Kuhn<br />

Renato Rosenberg<br />

4.6 Conservation unit management<br />

The Chico Mendes Institute for Biodiversity Conservation is responsible for<br />

administering conservation units (CUs) in Brazil, which occupy 8.5% of national<br />

territories. There are 12 unit categories – national parks, ecological stations,<br />

biological reserves, wildlife refuges, natural monuments, integral protection<br />

CUs, areas of relevant ecological interest, areas of environmental preservation,<br />

areas of national forests, extractive reserves, areas of sustainable development<br />

and sustainable use CUs – of which 32% already have management plans and<br />

27% have draft plans in process.<br />

In the context of disseminating practices associated with GE, there is current<br />

discussion about the menu of institutional arrangements likely of being adopted<br />

in these CUs in order to identify business models capable of reconciling the<br />

premise of preservation, as well as the development of other activities such<br />

as research (basic and applied), tourism, sustainable forest management,<br />

extractivism, sustainable economic exploitation and others. Preservation largely<br />

depends on society perceiving that it is conscious, planned and careful use of the<br />

country’s natural patrimony that guarantees its conservation and expansion.<br />

5. Ch a l l e n g e s<br />

The challenges that Brazil faces in the environmental area are proportional<br />

to their potentials. They involve rethinking the country’s economic development<br />

strategies, taking into account growing imperatives of a socio-environmental<br />

nature. Developing a strong and structured green economy with an increased<br />

generation of green jobs is fundamental. This is a national issue that transcends<br />

the jurisdiction of the Brazilian Ministry of the Environment and for which society<br />

and various levels of government are responsible.<br />

There are pressing issues, such as the reconciliation of the need to improve<br />

the combat against deforestation with the strong pressure of agricultural<br />

and cattle raising expansion. Even the management of the national energy<br />

matrix brings important dilemmas, such as those associated with changing<br />

the equilibrium between renewable and non-renewable sources, an issue<br />

that cannot be addressed without an analysis of the costs and competitive<br />

advantages associated with each alternative.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The coordination of environmental policies in the area of federal government<br />

administration and the cooperative federalism pact related to the process of<br />

implementation of these policies are permanent challenges. The Ministry of<br />

the Environment interacts with almost all the other ministries in the federal<br />

public administration and bilateral agendas are being formed with each one.<br />

In the area of inter-governmental relations, it is worth registering that Brazilian<br />

environmental issues are national, not federal. But the capital needed for<br />

coordination is, without a doubt, a very scarce resource in any government.


84<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: a panorama<br />

Francisco Gaetani<br />

Ernani Kuhn<br />

Renato Rosenberg<br />

Dialogues with the business sector, social movements and NGOs can be<br />

found in the DNA of the environmental agenda and it is not surprising that all<br />

are moving rapidly in the direction of a greener society and economy. The<br />

history of the Ministry of the Environment is the result, to a large extent, of<br />

these dialogues. The challenge is to deepen them so that they become more<br />

and more qualified and produce developments in the sphere of environmental<br />

public policies, especially the inclusive sort.<br />

Finally, it is necessary to mention that today Brazil is known internationally<br />

as a global environmental power that dialogues with rich, developing, emerging<br />

and poor countries in relation to the global environmental agenda. In the area<br />

of large global conferences, in the sphere of international technical cooperation<br />

and South-South platforms (Ibas, Basic, Bric, Unasul, etc), a leadership position<br />

is increasingly being expected from Brazil. But leadership requires example:<br />

therein lies the importance of the whole nation engaging itself in addressing<br />

these simultaneous challenges in an extensive and coordinated way.<br />

6. Co n c l u s io n<br />

From various geopolitical aspects, Brazil starts from a privileged situation in<br />

the direction of a green economy. The natural characteristics and their past use<br />

are already driving one of the cleanest energy matrices in the world. Recent<br />

initiatives, herein focused on the scope of government activities, mainly compose<br />

the beginning of a consolidated development effort in different areas.<br />

In most cases, institutional structuring is only beginning, as well as the<br />

creation of economic mechanisms that compose the agenda of a country<br />

that is increasingly focused on evolving markets related to a green economy.<br />

Some initiatives are already presenting good progress, such as the reduction<br />

of deforestation in the Amazon biome, though that does not mean to say that<br />

there is not a long road ahead, in particular for this one, but also for other<br />

biomes. The best protection should be combined with proper biodiversity use<br />

integrated with the process of national development.<br />

GE is included in the context of a national development project that is<br />

sustainable and inclusive and does not accept, from the point of view of<br />

government policy proposals, artificial trade-offs that do not serve in the<br />

national interest, such as growth versus sustainability or social inclusion versus<br />

environmental preservation.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The Brazilian Ministry of the Environment, integrated with the federal<br />

government administration, has become a strategic actor in the economic<br />

agenda of the country, because the government understands that there is no<br />

development that does not seek sustainability and biodiversity.


85<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: a panorama<br />

Francisco Gaetani<br />

Ernani Kuhn<br />

Renato Rosenberg<br />

References<br />

Barbier, E. B. (2009). Rethinking the economic recovery: a global green new deal.<br />

Report prepared for the Economics and Trade Branch of the Division of Technology,<br />

Industry and Economics of UNEP. University of Wyoming: Department of Economics<br />

and Finance.<br />

Decreto Federal n. 19.717, 20 February 1931.<br />

ECLAC (2010). La Economía del Cambio Climático en América Latina y el Caribe.<br />

Síntesis 2010. Santiago de Chile: United Nations <strong>Publication</strong>.<br />

Governo Federal (2008). Plano Nacional sobre Mudança Global do Clima – PNMC –<br />

Brasil. Comitê Interministerial sobre Mudança do Clima.<br />

Magalhães Castro, M. H and Schwartzman, S. (1981). Tecnologia para a Indústria: a<br />

história do Instituto Nacional de Tecnologia. Retrieved from: <br />

en el 19 de setiembre de 2007.<br />

MMA (2010). Tabela de Indicadores do MMA. Retrieved from: en el 08 de abril de 2011.<br />

MME (2008). Biocombustíveis: instrumento para inclusão social e fator de desenvolvimento<br />

econômico com respeito ao meio ambiente. Retrieved from: <br />

en el 08 de abril de 2011.<br />

Presidência da República do Brasil (2011). Mensagem ao Congresso Nacional 2011:<br />

1ª Sessão Legislativa Ordinária da 54ª legislatura. Brasília.<br />

UNEP (2011). Towards a green economy. Pathways to sustainable development and poverty<br />

eradication. A synthesis for policy makers. St-Martin-Belleveu, France: UNEP.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011


86<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Growth potential of the<br />

green economy in Brazil 1<br />

Carlos Eduardo Frickmann Young 2<br />

1. Gr e e n e c o n o m y a s a n e w p a t t e r n o f<br />

d e v e l o p m e n t<br />

The concept of green economy suggests that the dynamism of the economy<br />

must be set by the expansion of sectors with low environmental impact<br />

by promoting actions such as clean technology, renewable energy, green<br />

transportation, waste management, green buildings, sustainable agriculture,<br />

forest management and payment for environmental services. The reason for<br />

that is that this process of reconfiguration of economic activity provides better<br />

return on investments in natural, human and economic capital, while reducing<br />

the pressure on the environment and contributing to greater social equity 3 .<br />

Therefore, the green economy offers the opportunity to reconcile the traditional<br />

goals of economic policy, especially growth of income and employment with<br />

the social and environmental objectives of sustainable development: a strategy<br />

to enter into a development process based on the endogenous capacity of<br />

generation and incorporation of technical progress while social issues (including<br />

environmental protection) receive the same importance as economic goals.<br />

The aim of this paper is to show that the “greening” of the Brazilian economy<br />

through the expansion of economic activities with low environmental impact,<br />

can bring better results to the generation of employment and income than<br />

the current model of specialization of exports of natural resources exploited<br />

predatorily or industrial goods with a high degree of pollution in their production<br />

processes. That is to say that the adoption of an alternative model, based on<br />

the expansion of “clean” sectors, can bring more social and economic benefits<br />

than the current path of specialization in “dirty” activities.<br />

To demonstrate this, the results of an input-output matrix model will be<br />

presented so as to compare alternative options of economic growth (“green”<br />

or “brown”) in terms of capacity to generate employment and income (Young,<br />

2010). The growth scenarios based on spurious depletion or degradation of<br />

natural resources bring worse results than the scenarios where the production<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

1. This article is the result of the research project “Transición de América Latina y el Caribe<br />

hacia un modelo de crecimiento verde e inclusivo”, with the support of UNEP and ECLAC. I<br />

would like to thank Mr. Leonardo Barcellos de Bakker and Mr.André Falkenbach Santoro for<br />

their comments and help in the elaboration of this text.<br />

2. Profesor of the Institute of Economics of the Federal University of Rio de Janeiro (IE/UFRJ).<br />

Email: young@ie.ufrj.br<br />

3. UNEP (2011).


87<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

dynamism is concentrated in sectors that are less harmful to the environment:<br />

the creation of employment and wages are higher in scenarios where the<br />

dependence on natural resources and degradation are reduced, proving that the<br />

dichotomy between environmental conservation and improvement of economic<br />

conditions is false.<br />

Growth potential of the<br />

green economy in Brazil<br />

Carlos Eduardo Young<br />

2. Th e r e s p e c ia l iz a t io n o f La t in Am e r ic a o n<br />

n a t u r a l r e s o u r c e e x p o r t s<br />

The increasing dependence on exports based on natural resources or<br />

pollution-intensive goods is a structural problem in Latin American countries,<br />

whose exports are increasingly concentrated in natural resources or industrial<br />

goods characterized by a relatively high degree of pollution in their production<br />

processes (Young, 1988; Lustosa and Young, 2001, 2002, Malavasi et al., 2005).<br />

This trend has been accentuated in recent years, both in terms of the relative<br />

share of natural resources in the exports basket and specialization in pollutionintensive<br />

industrial goods. The results obtained by Young (2010), using the<br />

international trade database TradeCan and coefficients of potential emission of<br />

industrial pollutants (ILITHA) of the Industrial Pollution Projection System - IPPS<br />

(Hettige et al., 1994) show that there is a clear trend of increasing dependence<br />

of the export basket on primary goods, which has rapidly accelerated in the<br />

2000s. Figures 1 and 2 present the results for Brazil.<br />

Figure 1<br />

Participation of primary products in exports (%), Brazil and Latin America<br />

Primary/total – Brazil<br />

Primary/total – Latin America<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Source: Young (2010), based on data from TradeCan.


88<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Figure 2<br />

Average intensity of potential pollution of industrial exports<br />

(ILITHA/IPPS), Brazil and Latin America<br />

Growth potential of the<br />

green economy in Brazil<br />

ILITHA/Industrials – Brazil<br />

Carlos Eduardo Young<br />

ILITHA/Industrials – Latin America<br />

Source: Young (2010), based on data from IPPS and TradeCan (Hettige et al., 1994)<br />

These results are associated with the hypothesis of deindustrialization,<br />

showing that the liberalization process initiated in the 1990s, along with the<br />

boom in commodity prices in the 2000s, resulted in structural change in the<br />

region, returning to a position where the dynamism of foreign markets is based<br />

on direct sales of natural resources or of goods whose production is intensive<br />

in pollutant emissions. Combining both results, in the 2000s exports from<br />

Brazil and Latin America have become increasingly dependent on the spurious<br />

competitiveness based on depletion of the natural resource base, instead of a<br />

virtuous cycle in which the commercial gain would be obtained from technical<br />

progress and innovation.<br />

This issue is particularly problematic, because consumers in developed<br />

countries are increasingly aware of environmental footprints of the products they<br />

buy and the position of Latin America can be seen as fragile if this awareness<br />

is reflected in trade restrictions against products harmful to the environment.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Despite these problems, it is common to find defenders of the current growth<br />

trend supported by natural resources or emissions-intensive products arguing<br />

that environmental losses are a necessary cost of economic development. This<br />

hypothesis, usually called “environmental Kuznets curve”, would justify that, at<br />

certain stages of development, the sacrifice of natural resources is an inevitable<br />

price to improve the material conditions of life. The next section presents a<br />

model to test the validity of this hypothesis in the Brazilian context.


89<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Growth potential of the<br />

green economy in Brazil<br />

Carlos Eduardo Young<br />

3. In d u s t r ia l p o l l u t i o n a n d s o c ia l in c l u s io n:<br />

s c e n a r io s f o r t h e f u t u r e<br />

In the previous session, it was shown that Brazil and the rest of Latin America<br />

increased their structural dependence of primary goods and pollution-intensive<br />

goods in their export basket. Obviously this brings negative consequences for<br />

the environment. Even so, exports have been a major engine of economic growth<br />

and, therefore, some argue that it is necessary to accept some environmental<br />

damage in order to increase the pace of economic activity.<br />

The implicit hypothesis in this argument is that economic activity and<br />

environmental conservation are necessarily in opposition and that, consequently,<br />

policymakers have to decide between (i) increase employment and income<br />

levels, or (ii) weaken economic growth in pursuit of environmental preservation.<br />

The purpose of this session is to show that an alternative path of economic<br />

growth is possible, exemplifying how the priority to the green economy,<br />

besides conserving the environment, will bring beneficial effects to the levels<br />

of employment and income.<br />

This session examines the problem, testing whether a growth based on<br />

degradation of natural resources would bring better or worse results than<br />

the economical alternative to concentrate the product in higher value added<br />

activities, which bring less harm to the environment. To illustrate this point,<br />

scenarios have been constructed using the input-output matrix of 2005 (the<br />

most recent) of Brazil, comparing different possibilities of economic growth,<br />

using the generation of jobs and wages as a measure of economic growth.<br />

Among other reasons, employment and wages are good indicators of growth<br />

with social inclusion, since they express better the evolution of welfare than<br />

GDP growth. Furthermore, given the extreme concentration of income in Latin<br />

America, it is more important to avoid growth measures that do not consider<br />

the redistribution of income.<br />

The exercises performed sought to answer the following questions:<br />

• What generates higher growth: the expansion of activities intensive in natural<br />

resources or those based on manufactured goods or services?<br />

• Within the manufacturing sector, which generates higher growth: the<br />

expansion of activities more or less pollution-intensive?<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The advantage of using the input-output matrix is that it allows the perception<br />

of the entire production chain. In order to make the scenarios comparable, all<br />

of them must all be based on similar expansions of final demand, by means of<br />

an exogenous increase in exports.<br />

There are a number of limitations on the use of an input-output matrix.<br />

Technical coefficients and relative prices are assumed to be constant, as if the<br />

economy remained static during the period under analysis. In addition, there are


90<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Growth potential of the<br />

green economy in Brazil<br />

Carlos Eduardo Young<br />

no observed coefficients of emissions, only potential estimates based on older<br />

models such as the Industrial Pollution Projection System (IPPS), elaborated<br />

by the World Bank and on which this analysis is based.<br />

Despite all the problems reported above, the exercise of input-output based<br />

on a real economy provides important results, since it allows the consideration<br />

of inter-sectoral chains and are a more effective way to simulate an alternative<br />

growth of possibilities than ungrounded assumptions or tests on the consistency<br />

of its results.<br />

a. Methodology<br />

The exercise simulated an expansion of final demand of R$ 40 billion (at<br />

2005 prices), or approximately 12% of exports in 2005 - this figure was chosen<br />

because it was the average annual growth of Brazilian exports between 2000<br />

and 2005. Each scenario has distributed the expansion of that same amount<br />

(R$ 40 billion) in different combinations of final demand in economic sectors.<br />

The first question that arises is which sector generates more growth, as<br />

measured by employment and wage growth. The economy was divided into<br />

three major sectors (primary products, manufactured goods and services) and<br />

the total expansion of final demand (R$ 40 billion) was distributed according<br />

to the following criteria:<br />

• In Scenario 1 the expansion of final demand took place only in primary<br />

activities.<br />

• In Scenario 2 the expansion of final demand occurred only in manufactured<br />

products.<br />

• In Scenario 3 the expansion of final demand was distributed among the<br />

service, industrial utilities and civil construction sectors.<br />

The second question is whether there are differences between the growth<br />

led by the most “clean” or “dirty” industries in terms of employment and income<br />

generation. To answer this, the Scenario 2 was divided into two sub-scenarios<br />

in which the growth of industrial activity was distinguished by the intensity<br />

of potential pollution in accordance with the IPPS coefficients: the 10 most<br />

polluting industries, according to the IPPS were separated from the rest of the<br />

industry.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

• In Scenario 2.1, it has been assumed that most of the growth of final demand<br />

(R$ 30 billion) was concentrated in the 10 most polluting activities, while growth<br />

of exports from the least polluting activities has been of only R$10 billion.<br />

• In Scenario 2.2, the opposite scenario has been simulated, assuming<br />

that the 10 most polluting activities grew by only R$10 billion, while the least<br />

polluting grew R$30 billion.


91<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Growth potential of the<br />

green economy in Brazil<br />

Carlos Eduardo Young<br />

The 10 most polluting industrial activities under the IPPS are:<br />

• Wood products, excluding furniture<br />

• Paper and pulp<br />

• Oil refineries and coking<br />

• Chemicals<br />

• Resins<br />

• Chemicals and its derivatives - various<br />

• Cement<br />

• Other non-metallic products<br />

• Manufactures of metal<br />

• Non-metallic metallurgy<br />

The total production associated with each of these scenarios has been<br />

obtained by multiplying the Leontief Matrix by expansion of the respective<br />

increases in final demand. Hence, the increase in employment (personnel<br />

employed) has been calculated by multiplying the job/income coefficient (the<br />

coefficient between employment and value of production per activity) by the<br />

coefficient of expansion of product by sector. The equation below summarizes<br />

the procedure:<br />

ΔEi = (E/VP). (I-A) -1 . ΔXi<br />

Where:<br />

ΔEi: Employment expansion in the scenario “i”<br />

E/VP: Employment/value of production<br />

(I-A) -1 : Leontief Matrix for Brazil (2005), calculated by the Brazilian<br />

Institute of Geography and Statistics<br />

ΔXi: Expansion of export in scenario “i”<br />

The increase in wages (including social contributions) has been estimated<br />

in a similar manner by multiplying the salary/income coefficient (the coefficient<br />

between wages, including social security contributions, and value of production<br />

per activity) by the coefficient of expansion of output by sector. The equation<br />

below summarizes the procedure:<br />

ΔWi= (W/VP).(I-A) -1 . ΔXi<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Where:<br />

ΔWi: Expansion of salary under scenario “i”<br />

W/VP: Wages/Value of production


92<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

b. Results<br />

Table 2 presents the aggregated results for each scenario. Interestingly<br />

enough, although the expansion of aggregate exports is the same in all<br />

scenarios (R$ 40 billion), the results vary considerably, both in terms of<br />

employment generation and generation of income.<br />

Growth potential of the<br />

green economy in Brazil<br />

Carlos Eduardo Young<br />

Table 1<br />

Employment and wages created by scenario<br />

Scenario Employment Wage creation<br />

creation<br />

(R$ Bi)<br />

Scenario 1<br />

Expansion in primary activities 2,476,906 11,182<br />

Scenario 2<br />

Expansion in the manufacturing industry<br />

– linear increase in all sectors 1,351,194 13,186<br />

Scenario 2.1 – Expansion in the<br />

manufacturing industry – concentrated<br />

increase in the most polluting sectors 1,050,523 11,747<br />

Scenario 2.2 – Expansion in the<br />

manufacturing industry – concentrated<br />

increase in the least polluting sectors 1,409,478 13,464<br />

Scenario 3 – Expansion in services,<br />

industrial utilities and civil construction 2,008,166 15,220<br />

Source: Author’s calculations based on data from the Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics<br />

(Input-Output Matrix, Brazil 2005).<br />

At a first glance, it seems that, under Scenario 1, the expansion of primary<br />

activities have benefited more employment growth, since it presented the<br />

highest number of jobs creation. However, two factors must be considered.<br />

• The expansion in primary activities generates the lowest wage growth,<br />

indicating that the quality of jobs created by these sectors is of the worst quality<br />

among all scenarios. The results of Scenario 3, characterized by activities<br />

identified with the “dematerialized growth”, shows that the total salary would<br />

have been 36% greater than in Scenario 1, even though employment would<br />

have increased 19% less.<br />

• Dynamic effects: models based on input-output matrices design the patterns<br />

for the future, keeping all the technical parameters constant over time. However,<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

the rapid mechanization in agricultural production and the increasing capital<br />

intensity in the mining sector have had the effect of replacing more work,<br />

reducing the demand for manpower. Therefore, these sectors are responsible<br />

for liquid unemployment, rather than employment. This can be proven by


93<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Growth potential of the<br />

green economy in Brazil<br />

Carlos Eduardo Young<br />

looking at the Brazilian National Accounts: the rapid expansion of primary<br />

activities, increasing its share in GDP from 7.2% to 8.4% in 2000-2006, was<br />

accompanied by a steady reduction in total work force, from 22.4% to 19.8%<br />

during the same period (Table 2).<br />

Table 2<br />

Relative participation (%) of primary activities in GDP and Employment,<br />

Brazil<br />

% Primary activities on total GDP<br />

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006<br />

7.2 7.4 8.2 9.1 8.8 8.2 8.4<br />

% Primary activities on total employment<br />

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006<br />

22.4 21.3 21.1 21.1 21.5 21.0 19.8<br />

Source: Author’s calculations based on data from the Brazilian Institute of Geography and<br />

Statistics (Input-Output Matrix, Brazil 2005).<br />

On the other hand, the expansion in Scenario 3 shows a good performance<br />

of the employment (the second largest volume of jobs created) and the<br />

largest increase in total salary. Note that Scenario 3 is the most identified with<br />

the “greening” of the economy as it expands the civil construction industry<br />

(investment in the “cleaning” of economy require civil construction works, such<br />

as sanitation) and services, the basis of “dematerialization” of growth (also<br />

known as “decoupling”) based on knowledge, culture, technology and tacit<br />

components.<br />

A similar trend is also observed within the manufactory industry. Export<br />

expansion is concentrated in the group of less-polluting industries (Scenario<br />

2.2), which would generate 34% more jobs and pay 15% more than in Scenario<br />

2.1, where the dynamic sectors are the most polluting ones. This is related to the<br />

fact that most of the sectors with high pollution potential, such as intermediate<br />

goods, are very intensive on capital and require relatively few jobs.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The message of the analysis of these results is clear: it is a fallacy to think that<br />

developing countries like Brazil have to decide between economic growth and<br />

environmental quality. The scenarios that showed the most consistent results<br />

for improving economic activity, as measured by job and wage creation, are<br />

precisely those where the dependence on natural resource consumption and<br />

degradation are reduced. So there is no reason to believe that, as predicted<br />

by the “environmental Kuznets curve”, the decline in environmental quality is<br />

necessary to achieve a greater economic activity: scenarios with more pollution<br />

and resource depletion would lead to reduced growth compared with scenarios<br />

of “green growth”.


94<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Growth potential of the<br />

green economy in Brazil<br />

Carlos Eduardo Young<br />

Co n c l u s io n<br />

This study has shown that the “green economy” initiatives consist on an<br />

opportunity to start a new pattern of development based on the endogenous<br />

capacity of generation and incorporation of technical progress, while being<br />

socially inclusive and environmentally responsible. In this sense, there are<br />

many similarities with the original concept of industrialization proposed in the<br />

Center-Periphery System (Prebisch, 1949): long-term development can only<br />

be achieved when the economy becomes more intense in innovation and less<br />

dependent on extensive exploitation of natural resources. This concept was<br />

further deepened by Fajnzylber (1988) through the concept of authentic or<br />

systemic competition.<br />

Nevertheless, the empirical exercises have shown that there is a clear<br />

trend, since the late 1990s, of increasing dependence of exports of primary<br />

commodities and industrial goods that are intensive on pollution during their<br />

production process. This result is of great concern because it shows that Brazil<br />

and other Latin American economies are doing the opposite of what is required<br />

by the principles of sustainable development. Moreover, there is an increasing<br />

risk that the mechanisms of punishment may be established in the ‘dirty’<br />

products in international trade, with obvious damage to the countries whose<br />

exports are associated with degradation or depletion of natural resources.<br />

The main argument for those who defend the status quo is that developing<br />

countries must decide between economic growth and environmental quality. The<br />

implicit assumption behind this view is that economic activity and environmental<br />

conservation are necessarily in opposition and therefore decision makers<br />

have to choose between one or the other, as if preserving natural resources<br />

automatically blocks the growth of income and employment. This argument,<br />

known as “environmental Kuznets curve” is commonly quoted in literature,<br />

although no definite evidence that a pattern of “dirty” growth would bring better<br />

results than the one of ‘’greening” of the economy.<br />

In order to test the differences in terms of job creation and wage standards<br />

in “dirty” and “clean” scenarios input-output techniques have been created to<br />

simulate the consequences of using different patterns of natural resources<br />

use. In each scenario, the same amount of final demand has been considered,<br />

but with different sectoral distribution. Employment and wages have been<br />

considered as a measure of growth because they are better indicators of social<br />

inclusion than GDP.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The results are very consistent, showing that the spurious growth based<br />

on consumption of natural resources or degradation can bring much worse<br />

results than other economic options that focus on producing higher value added<br />

products, which are less harmful to the environment. The scenarios of increased<br />

employment and wage creation are exactly those where the dependence on


95<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Growth potential of the<br />

green economy in Brazil<br />

Carlos Eduardo Young<br />

natural resources consumption and degradation are reduced. More pollution<br />

and depletion of natural resources would lead to unfavorable performances,<br />

instead of more inclusive growth, leading to an opposite result to that expected<br />

from the “environmental Kuznets curve”.<br />

Finally, it should be noted that the results presented in this report have<br />

important limitations related to the methodology and hypothesis used and<br />

the quality of data is far from ideal. The improvement of production data and<br />

generation of environmental indicators is an important need to improve our<br />

understanding of the relationship between trade, competitiveness issues and<br />

the environment. Thus, another policy recommendation is to implement an<br />

effective system of environmental information related to the economic indicators<br />

already available.<br />

References<br />

Fajnzylber, F. (1988). Competitividad internacional: evolución y lecciones. Revista de<br />

la CEPAL, n. 36, December, 7-24.<br />

Hettige, H., Martin, P., Singh, M. and Wheeler, D. (1994). IPPS - The industrial pollution<br />

projection system. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.<br />

Malavasi, L. O., Schuschny, A. R. and Gallopín, G. (2005). Evolución de las emisiones<br />

industriales potenciales en América Latina, 1970-2000. Serie Medio Ambiente y<br />

Desarrollo, 97. Santiago de Chile: ECLAC.<br />

Prebisch, R. (1949). El desarrollo económico de la América Latina y algunos de sus<br />

principales problemas. Santiago de Chile: ECLAC.<br />

Young, C. E. F. (1998). Industrial pollution and export-oriented policies in Brazil. Revista<br />

Brasileira de Economia, v.52, 543–561.<br />

Young, C. E. F. (2010). Transition towards a green and inclusive economic model: a<br />

Latin American perspective. Reserach report prepared for the Transición de América<br />

Latina y el Caribe hacia un modelo de crecimiento verde y inclusivo Project (UNEP/<br />

ECLAC). Rio de Janeiro: IE/UFRJ.<br />

Young, C. E. F. and Lustosa, M. C. J. (2001). Meio ambiente e competitividade na<br />

indústria brasileira. Revista de Economia Contemporânea, v. 5, 231-259.<br />

Young, C. E. F. and Lustosa, M. C. J. (2002). Competitividade e meio ambiente. In<br />

Braga, A. S. and Miranda, L. C. (ed.), Comércio e meio ambiente: uma agenda para<br />

a América Latina e Caribe, 41-60. Brasília: MMA.<br />

UNEP (2011). Towards a green economy: pathways to sustainable development and<br />

poverty eradication – a synthesis for policy makers. Retrieved from: .<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011


96<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: foundations and<br />

strategy for transition<br />

Cláudio R. Frischtak 1<br />

In t r o d u c t io n<br />

The dominant view about environmental conservation continues to be that, in<br />

the process of development, countries ultimately face a choice: more growth or<br />

more conservation. To propose foundations for a new economy it is necessary<br />

to revisit the basic assumptions underlying the predominant economy and how<br />

its results are measured. This is not an easy task, because the fragility of the<br />

dominant paradigm is not part of the concrete experience of most countries.<br />

After all, the industrial revolution was a predator of natural resources, but at the<br />

same time it accelerated growth and generated increasing levels of wellbeing.<br />

So why rethink the economy and abandon the connection - apparently more<br />

necessary the lower the income level - between growth and intensive (and<br />

unsustainable) resource use?<br />

First, because exhausting of the capacity of ecosystems to withstand the<br />

pressure of economic activities could undermine economic growth itself. From<br />

this perspective, economic growth can only be sustained by conserving that<br />

capacity. Second, the need to develop new foundations for a transition to a green<br />

economy will produce new opportunities. Products and services geared toward<br />

this transition will assume an increasing proportion of economic activities.<br />

The exhaustion of the old model and the transition to a green economy<br />

require a reversal of the predominant assumption: increased growth becomes<br />

dependent on and (necessarily) accompanied by greater conservation or<br />

sustainable use of natural resources, so that the new trade-off would be<br />

between growth and the predatory use of natural capital. The objective of this<br />

study is to establish the foundations for a green economy in Brasil as well as<br />

a transition strategy.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

1. President of Inter.B International Business Consulting (Inter.B Consultoria Internacional de<br />

Negócios).


97<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: foundations<br />

and strategy for<br />

transition<br />

Cláudio R. Frischtak<br />

Th e t r a n s it io n t o a g r e e n e c o n o m y in Br a z il<br />

The green economy has no precedent or model. It proposes a transformation<br />

in the mode of production and consumption, redefinition of government planning<br />

and policy, and greater emphasis on innovative effort. To enable public policy<br />

approaches of sectoral support for the transition to green economy, the study<br />

develops the following analytical framework to facilitate the illustrations.<br />

Supply is organized into two categories. "Market" supply is that which<br />

responds autonomously to demand that is either pre-existing or arises in<br />

response to supply; in both cases, production results from the normal course<br />

of business by incumbent firms and by the entry of new firms. "Structured"<br />

supply is that which encounters difficulties in meeting demand, either due to<br />

inadequate returns or due to technological or institutional complexity, and as<br />

a result requires some level of intervention or support, in the form of R&D,<br />

planning, investment, organization of production or pricing. The structuring of<br />

supply may involve direct investments by government, fiscal incentives, financial<br />

subsidies or changes in the regulatory environment, among other actions.<br />

Demand, in turn, can be characterized as “spontaneous” when it emerges<br />

from the basic needs of individuals, being determined primarily by income<br />

level and education, the volume and nature of the information that they have<br />

access to, through the experience (of consumption) and its surroundings (via<br />

demonstration effect). Alternatively, demand can be characterized as "induced",<br />

which requires that it be managed or encouraged through the transfer of<br />

information, including awareness campaigns and public education, to ensure the<br />

creation of markets for goods and services that do not arise spontaneously.<br />

These typologies of supply and demand produce a 2x2 matrix, summarized in<br />

the form of an analytical framework (Figure 1). In a clockwise direction, starting at<br />

the upper left, is Quadrant I, which covers activities that combine a spontaneous<br />

demand and a market supply and that, together, constitute the dominant part<br />

of GDP in a conventional economy and a small share of Green GDP. Quadrant<br />

II is composed of activities that require supply to be "structured" for markets to<br />

form and spontaneous demand (potential) be met. Quadrant III brings together<br />

activities that depend on both structured supply and induced demand to be<br />

economically viable. These activities would presumably take longer and absorb<br />

more resources to function. Finally, Quadrant IV includes activities that can<br />

be viable if demand is stimulated by a greater flow of information (including<br />

information campaigns) to consumers that induce behavioral changes, and by<br />

other measures to change the dominant pattern of consumption.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011


98<br />

Figure 1<br />

Matrix of Green GDP activities and the dynamics of public policies<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Market<br />

supply<br />

structured<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: foundations<br />

and strategy for<br />

transition<br />

Cláudio R. Frischtak<br />

DEMAND<br />

INDUced spontaneous<br />

The matrix also illustrates the dynamics of a typically "green" activity, where<br />

initial size is limited, but, driven by the "hand of the State" in initially structuring<br />

the supply and then inducing demand, expands over time (symbolically, larger<br />

concentric circles), characterizing the transition to a green economy. Increasing<br />

returns to scale, or accumulated experience reflected by learning curves and<br />

the resulting productivity gains, could make some of these activities return back<br />

to Quadrant I (or in its direction), having already reached a size that assures<br />

economic viability.<br />

Below we consider the application of this analytical framework to a set of<br />

activities that would comprise part of a Green GDP - understood as the set of<br />

economic activities that maintain and expand the stock of natural capital – and,<br />

although not exhausting the Green GDP potential, they are possibly the most<br />

emblematic 2 .<br />

Conservation of ecosystems<br />

This category consists of economic activities that contribute to the integrity<br />

of ecosystems and their ability to provide material support and a wide range of<br />

services essential to a decent life for current and future generations.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

2. The area of the circles reflects the relative economic importance of the measured activities as<br />

estimated by their contribution to the country’s GDP.


99<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Figure 2<br />

Conservation of ecosystems<br />

Market<br />

supply<br />

Native Species<br />

Reforestation (6)<br />

structured<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: foundations<br />

and strategy for<br />

transition<br />

Cláudio R. Frischtak<br />

DEMAND<br />

INDUced SPONTaneous<br />

natural<br />

pharmacos (1)<br />

Organic<br />

Products (2)<br />

Natural<br />

Cosmetics (4)<br />

Native Species<br />

Reforestation (3)<br />

Sustainable<br />

Agriculture<br />

Ecological<br />

Tourism (5)<br />

Sustainable<br />

Extractive<br />

Activities<br />

(Food)<br />

REDD / REDD + (7)<br />

Preparation: Inter.B. Sources:<br />

1. “Valuation of the Real and the competiveness of exports,” 7 April 2010, .<br />

2. “Changing habits”,” 27 May 2009, Valor Econômico.<br />

3. “Invasive species cause US$1.4 billion in damages,” 28 April 2010, Valor Econômico.<br />

4. “Jewels of the forest,” 28 April 2010, Valor Econômico.<br />

5. “Economic and socio-cultural value of ecotourism and recreational activities provided by the<br />

Serra de São José Area of Environmental Protection (Minas Gerais state)” PIBIC/CNPq,<br />

.<br />

6. “Harvests from trees,” 12 December 2005, Unicamp, .<br />

7. “Discussion about REDD defines the future of the forest, 24/ August 2009, Valor Online.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Note that the activities in Figure 2 are still relatively small in magnitude, have<br />

limited support and are concentrated in Quadrant I. There still is not a real forestbased<br />

economy, with intelligent extraction at a scale that is not limited to only<br />

biodiversity products (pharmaceuticals, cosmetics), but involving sustainable<br />

extractivism and ecotourism, among others. The great exception is the planting<br />

of eucalyptus on “cleared” land, or land used for low productivity livestock<br />

farming, especially when combined with the restoration of native vegetation.<br />

A recent example 3 suggests that this latter alternative of restoring native<br />

vegetation is economically feasible and, as it gains in scale and experience,<br />

will become an activity consolidated in Quadrant I.<br />

3. For example, Vale Reflorestar, a fund with R$ 605 million to be used for reforestation. Jornal<br />

do Comercio, 6 May 2010.


100<br />

Figure 3<br />

Conservation of ecosystems in the transition to a green economy<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Market<br />

Native Species<br />

Reforestation (6)<br />

supply<br />

structured<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: foundations<br />

and strategy for<br />

transition<br />

Cláudio R. Frischtak<br />

DEMAND<br />

INDuced spontaneous<br />

Natural<br />

Cosmetics (4)<br />

Organic<br />

Products (2)<br />

Ecological<br />

Tourism (5)<br />

Sustainable<br />

Extractive<br />

Activities (Food)<br />

Sustainable<br />

Agriculture<br />

REDD / REDD + (7)<br />

Overall, the expansion of these activities depends not only on government<br />

policies to structure the supply and occasionally induce demand, but on basic<br />

legislation that promotes the protection and sustainable use of ecosystems. In<br />

the area of ecosystem protection, Brazil has a fairly comprehensive legislation,<br />

focusing primarily on the National System of Conservation Units, the Forest<br />

Code, the Water Code and regulations that guide the use of natural resources,<br />

economic activities and interventions in the landscape.<br />

The system of conservation units (Brazilian term for protected areas) needs<br />

to be strengthened by establishing new conservation units in critical areas and,<br />

fundamentally, by consolidating existing conservation units. Systems are needed<br />

for management, monitoring and supervision to ensure the integrity of the<br />

conservation units and inhibit predatory activities inside. Social networks must be<br />

established for protection in and around the units, involving traditional communities<br />

and providing them with decent living conditions, through for example payments<br />

for environmental services and sustainable natural resource extraction.<br />

The Forest Code is another basic text that guides conservation activities,<br />

and for which an ongoing revision by the Brazilian Congress has generated<br />

contentious debate. For many producers in remote frontier areas, obtaining land<br />

registration and environmental licensing (in the context of a plan for restoring<br />

Permanent Preservation Areas and Legal Reserves), regularizing land tenure<br />

and legalizing the use of land for economic purposes, is highly advantageous.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

A powerful but underutilized tool to promote land-use sustainability is rural<br />

credit. The 2010-11 Harvest Plan is a step in that direction through the Low<br />

Carbon Agriculture Program, even though the program does not absorb more<br />

than 5% of the available resources 4 .<br />

4. See Valor, 7 June 2010 p. B12.


101<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: foundations<br />

and strategy for<br />

transition<br />

Cláudio R. Frischtak<br />

There are other instruments to promote these sustainable land-use activities.<br />

Some measures consist of governmental policies that need to be expanded,<br />

such as the inclusion of environmental criteria to municipal value-added tax<br />

revenues (such as the ecological tax on operations related to the circulation<br />

of goods and the provision of inter-state and inter-municipal transport services<br />

and communication). More broadly, companies and individuals should be<br />

encouraged to develop and execute projects on sustainable and intelligent<br />

use of natural resources, with conservation and restoration of ecosystems.<br />

The key is that ecosystem protection is not only a government task, but should<br />

actively involve society.<br />

Transport and sanitation<br />

This section analyzes activities that serve to build sustainable cities<br />

through targeted investments for improvements in accessibility, mobility and<br />

sanitation.<br />

Figure 4<br />

Networks of sustainable cities<br />

Market<br />

supply<br />

STRUctured<br />

Sanitation (5)<br />

Single ticket (3)<br />

DEMAND<br />

INDUced SPONTaneous<br />

Bicycle transport (7)<br />

Electric car (6)<br />

Subway transport (2)<br />

Subway transport (3)<br />

RAPID TRANSIT BUS<br />

Preparation: Inter.B. Sources:<br />

1,2,3,4 “Government blames cars and motorcyles for pollution,” 26 March 2010, Folha de São<br />

Paulo. 2,3 “Chinese and Spaniards enter in dispute for the TAV Project,” 6 August 20/09, 4“Even without a budget, government<br />

wants more waterways,” 12 January 2010, Valor Econômico.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

5Baltar, Emerenciano and Pereira, “Subsidy for providing water sanitation,” <br />

6“Without official support, electric car not viable,” 13 April 2010, Valor Econômico. 7<br />

“Reinventing mobility,” 12 August 2009, Agenda Sustentável, <br />

8“Paes says that single ticket will not be subsidized,” 24 April 2010, O Globo.


102<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: foundations<br />

and strategy for<br />

transition<br />

Cláudio R. Frischtak<br />

Figure 4 reveals that, in general, to exist or gain scale, these activities require<br />

a structured supply, because there is no "pure" market solution for efficient and<br />

low impact mass transit such as rail, subway or trams. These systems facilitate<br />

accessibility within networks of cities and are critical for intra-urban mobility.<br />

Although innovations such as electric cars should be seen as a breakthrough,<br />

cities will only be effectively sustainable if irrigated by efficient systems of mass<br />

transport. In the case of basic sanitation, economic viability (beyond the cost<br />

of investment) often depends on the income level of users.<br />

The weaknesses in the transport and sanitation systems, combined with<br />

a low degree of adaptation of the cities to their natural environment, require<br />

the design of a specific strategy in order to make cities sustainable. One must<br />

consider Brazil’s high degree of urbanization and how this impacts quality of<br />

life and the fact that public sector interventions, involving both in investments<br />

and the regulation of urban activities, seem essential (Figure 5).<br />

Figure 5 suggests the importance of active policies for the sustainability<br />

of transport and sanitation systems, with special emphasis on mass transit.<br />

Metropolitan areas require integrated planning in terms of accessibility and<br />

mobility as well as in the case of sanitation. This should be handled by<br />

a metropolitan planning agency with powers to allocate resources, while<br />

respecting civil society consultation processes. Investments aimed at improving<br />

the quality of life of urban populations are high, and collective interests should<br />

be the dominant criterion in investment decisions with regard to resource<br />

allocation.<br />

Figure 5<br />

Networks of sustainable cities in the transition to a green economy<br />

MARKET<br />

supply<br />

STRUCTURED<br />

sanitation (5)<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

DEMAND<br />

INDUCED SPONTANEOUS<br />

Bicycle transport (7)<br />

Electric car (6)<br />

High speed train<br />

Subway<br />

transport (2)<br />

Metropolitan railway (3)<br />

RAPID TRANSIT BUS


103<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: foundations<br />

and strategy for<br />

transition<br />

Cláudio R. Frischtak<br />

Energy<br />

This category consists of activities directed toward the production and efficient<br />

use of renewable energy. Brazil is relatively unique in that the country already<br />

has a structure relatively adapted to a low-carbon economy due to the significant<br />

share of renewable energies in the country’s energy matrix. Figure 6 suggests,<br />

however, that the new generation of energy solutions - solar, wind, nuclear and<br />

frontier hydropower and biomass projects - have not yet gained scale (as in the<br />

case of bio-fuels) and thus will require more structured forms of support.<br />

The agenda for energy sustainability is dense, as illustrated in Figure 7.<br />

It is necessary to move energy efficiency and innovation to the cutting edge<br />

of the economy, and stimulating the use of new sources at increased scales,<br />

by consolidating the significant advances that have been made domestically<br />

while also cooperating with global efforts for new solutions. Two sets of actions<br />

are essential: first, structured support for R&D, both in the public realms of<br />

universities and research centers, and in private and corporate spheres. Second,<br />

it is necessary to expand programs of energy efficiency, with emphasis on<br />

production processes and products, and on rational and efficient use.<br />

Figure 6<br />

Energy<br />

mARKET<br />

supply<br />

STRUCTURED<br />

Biomass from sugarcane<br />

Wind power (2)<br />

DEMAND<br />

INDUCED SPONTANEOUS<br />

HYDRO power<br />

SOLAR power (3)<br />

White line of Major appliance (4)<br />

Nuclear power<br />

BIOFUELS (1)<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Preparation: Inter.B. Sources:<br />

1. “Government blames cars and motorcycles for pollution,” 26 March 2010, Folha de São<br />

Paulo.<br />

2. “Wind at the price of water,” 10 January 2010, Revista Brasil Energia Ed. 350.<br />

3. “Solar energy in Brazil,” 24 March 2010, Valor Econômico.<br />

4. “Smaller IPI tax for appliances will respect environmental criteria,” 29 October 2009, Valor<br />

Econômico.


104<br />

Figure 7<br />

Energy in the transition to a green economy<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

supply<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: foundations<br />

and strategy for<br />

transition<br />

Cláudio R. Frischtak<br />

DEMAND<br />

INDUCED SPONTANEOUS<br />

MARKET<br />

HYDRO power<br />

Biomass<br />

from<br />

sugarcane<br />

SOLAR power (3)<br />

White line of low consumption (4)<br />

Wind power (2)<br />

STRUCTURED<br />

BIOFUELS (1)<br />

Nuclear power<br />

Wastes<br />

Figure 8 displays activities related to waste generation and treatment:<br />

product disposal, recycling of certain materials and reduction or elimination<br />

of non-biodegradables over reasonable period time. The scope for expanding<br />

market solutions will be determined by a combination of public policies and<br />

increased awareness of society.<br />

Figura 8<br />

Life cycle<br />

MARKET<br />

supply<br />

STRUCTURED<br />

DEMAND<br />

INDUCED SPONTANEOUS<br />

Recycled paper (1)<br />

RECYCLED METALS (2)<br />

Innovative products<br />

(recyclable,<br />

biodegradable) (5)<br />

Green plastic<br />

Sustainable<br />

demolition (4)<br />

Selective WASTE<br />

collection (3)<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Preparation: Inter.B. Sources:<br />

1. “Recycled paper fad opens a new niche for industries” 18 January 2007, Valor Econômico.<br />

2. “Reduced costs moves recycling market,” 29 January 2010, Valor Econômico.<br />

3,5. “Changing habits,” 27 May 2009, Valor Econômico.<br />

4. “Sustainability for the demolition of the Help Discotheque” 12 April 1010, O Globo<br />

6. “’The dissolving pen,” 24 April 2010, O Globo.


105<br />

Figure 9<br />

Product life cycle in the transition to a green economy<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

MERKET<br />

SUPpLY<br />

STRUCTURED<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: foundations<br />

and strategy for<br />

transition<br />

Cláudio R. Frischtak<br />

DEMAND<br />

INDUCED SPONTANEOUS<br />

Reverse<br />

logistics<br />

RECYCLED<br />

METALS (2)<br />

“Innovative products”<br />

(recyclable,<br />

biodegradable) (5)<br />

Green plastic<br />

Sustainable<br />

demolition (4)<br />

Selective WASTE<br />

collection (3)<br />

As shown in Figure 9, a new policy focused on waste management is needed,<br />

based on thoughtful examination of the need (or not) to control or regulate<br />

production and use of goods whose footprints are sensitive, either due to<br />

negative externalities throughout the life cycle, or low degradability following<br />

disposal, and that do not present economically viable recycling. The role of<br />

government policy would be to encourage alternatives based on the redesign<br />

of products, new materials, and to promote recycling and waste reduction 5 .<br />

It is important to emphasize that many of the measures designed to encourage<br />

recycling at the individual level are relatively simple, because they depend on<br />

standards to be followed by the producer / distributor without public spending.<br />

At the same time, many government interventions may be transient, so that<br />

after a period of returns to scale and cost reductions, activities to integrate the<br />

life cycle of products become viable in the market. The combination of greater<br />

scarcity and higher prices of raw materials, and with the returns to scale initially<br />

encouraged by government policies and rugulations, the collection and recycling<br />

of disposable items through operations of reverse logistics would be the result<br />

of company-driven initiatives. Even selective collection, after an initial period,<br />

can become self-sustainable and eventually profitable enough to dispense with<br />

government subsidies.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

In short, improvements of ecosystem protection, urban transport and<br />

sanitation systems, energy and waste management can be integrated into a<br />

green economy with limited and temporary government interventions. The above<br />

5. A very significant advance took place in 2010 with the establishment of the National Policy<br />

for Solid Wastes, which regulates recycling and waste management, and innovates with<br />

reverse logistics, which states that everyone involved in the supply chain of products must<br />

organize to collect used packaging and product waste.


106<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: foundations<br />

and strategy for<br />

transition<br />

Cláudio R. Frischtak<br />

analysis indicates that a substantial part of Green GDP is already prefigured in<br />

Quadrant I. This implies that there are market solutions, but many are incipient<br />

and others do not yet exist. The expansion of many of these activities will depend<br />

on active policies, although such support can only be temporary.<br />

Tr a n s it io n s t r a t e g y<br />

Implementing a green economy transition strategy requires the establishment<br />

of a governmental green economy agenda. This agenda could involve:<br />

First, the constitution of a working group or equivalent involving not only<br />

government, but universities and research institutions, companies and civil<br />

society organizations, with the following objectives:<br />

• Identify, in an objective way, general sustainability criteria that would guide<br />

direct or indirect government support to projects and activities.<br />

• Conversely, define what would constitute predatory uses of natural capital<br />

that should be contained, taxed or discouraged.<br />

• Introduce into the national accounting system sustainability dimensions in<br />

the sense suggested by the Stiglitz report, focusing on variations in the<br />

stocks of natural capital.<br />

• Gradually construct indicators that serve to price the services provided by<br />

major ecosystems, recognizing that this exercise is tentative and subject to<br />

trial and error, and that certain critical services are possibly not measurable<br />

in economic terms.<br />

• Inventory government actions (including those by state-owned companies)<br />

that directly or indirectly affect the conservation of natural capital in Brazil,<br />

ranking them according to their impacts.<br />

Second, and based on the results of the efforts undertaken above, define a<br />

reference framework and a set of norms as a basis for reorienting government<br />

actions. It is worth stressing that Brazil still has a wide range of public policies<br />

and government initiatives that incentivize predatory activities or activities<br />

without merit in the context of a green economy.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

A detailed review should be carried out of government programs, as well as<br />

tax financial and other incentives, both at sector and regional levels, in addition<br />

to investment plans of state-owned enterprises, to exame their economic and<br />

legal viability (from this new perspective), as a step toward eliminating over<br />

the next few years all forms of support to projects and activities that are clearly<br />

incompatible with the green economy, because they:<br />

• Directly exploit natural capital without adequately compensating for their<br />

economic impacts;


107<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Brazil and the green<br />

economy: foundations<br />

and strategy for<br />

transition<br />

Cláudio R. Frischtak<br />

• Contribute to "dirtying" the energy matrix (such as power generation based<br />

on diesel oil, fuel oil or coal);<br />

• Reduce access to and mobility within cities; and<br />

• Ignore new architectural concepts and standards, construction methods<br />

and use of materials designed to conserve energy, maximize recycling and<br />

utilization of rain water, among others.<br />

Third, a positive agenda focused on the protection and restoration of<br />

natural capital in major ecosystems must be promoted. It is imperative that the<br />

country protects its biodiversity. On the specific issue of rain forest protection,<br />

Brazil should strengthen its leadership in monitoring capabilities, preventing<br />

deforestation and seeking alternatives to generate decent employment and<br />

income for forest peoples, traditional communities, as well as settlers attracted<br />

by government programs, among others. In terms of water resources, the<br />

country must intensify its efforts to properly manage watersheds and ensure<br />

multiple, balanced and sustainable water use, for which high quality production<br />

and conservation need to involve riverain communities and farmers, and where<br />

appropriate pricing is essential to encourage rational use.<br />

These are the directives for a green economy transition strategy.<br />

Co n c l u s io n<br />

Years ago the world economy began a transition process supported by the<br />

predatory use of natural capital and the depletion of the ecosystem capacities,<br />

with deleterious effects on sustainability. A new paradigm is emerging, where<br />

growth and conservation are positively correlated and form the basis of a green<br />

economy.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Brazil is a global environmental power due to its ample ecosystem resources,<br />

and renewable energy. With the support of adequate government policies, it<br />

can become one of the countries to most rapidly incorporate a green economy.<br />

This process is based on four key vectors of the Brazilian Green GDP: (i)<br />

the preservation and expansion of natural capital, through efficient forms of<br />

agriculture and a new forest economy based on the intelligent use of biodiversity;<br />

(ii) the transformation of cities through integrated planning at the metropolitan<br />

level, with reference to the need for a transformative vision of accessibility<br />

and urban mobility, and the expansion of sanitation and the establishment of<br />

new standards for architecture and construction; (iii) increased stimulus for the<br />

generation and use of renewable energy, necessarily linked to increased efforts<br />

in energy efficiency; and (iv) the integration of product life cycles in the economic<br />

calculations of producers and consumers, through appropriate regulation of new<br />

legislation, and innovative effort in the design and use of new materials.


108<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Innovation and technology<br />

for a green economy: key<br />

issues<br />

Maria Cecília Junqueira Lustosa 1<br />

In t r o d u c t io n<br />

The discussion on the limits of growth due to the finiteness of environmental<br />

resources has placed the challenge of combining economic growth and<br />

environmental preservation. Within this debate, two approaches can be<br />

identified: the first focuses on technology as the main vector of change, creating<br />

more environmentally friendly production processes and thus stretching the<br />

limits of economic growth. The other approach, contrary to the first, puts the<br />

impossibility of combining environmental preservation and economic growth in<br />

the capitalist system. The need for new markets, imposing a pattern of intensive<br />

use of raw materials and energy, makes the dependence of environmental<br />

resources grow increasingly beyond the limits of the availability of these<br />

resources, even with cleaner technologies.<br />

Regardless of this debate, technological evolution towards more efficient<br />

production processes from the environmental point of view, using fewer<br />

materials and releasing less waste into the environment, is desirable from a<br />

social point of view, since if it does not solve the environmental problem, at least<br />

it seeks to soothe it. In this sense, the development of cleaner technologies is<br />

extremely necessary.<br />

Nevertheless, the study of technological change involves many aspects and<br />

is an evolutionary process that presents nonlinearity, cumulativity and temporal<br />

interdependence (path dependence) characteristics. Moreover, technological<br />

change towards environmental sustainability depends on other non-economic<br />

factors such as development of specific capabilities of enterprises, infrastructure<br />

and institutional changes.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

This article discusses issues related to innovation in the transition to a green<br />

economy from the evolutionary theory of technological change point of view<br />

and is divided into four sections besides this introduction. The first deals with<br />

the emergence of environmental issues as a result of the economic output.<br />

1. Associate professor at the Faculty of Economics, Business Administration and Accounting<br />

of the Federal University of Alagoas (FEAC/UFAL), researcher at the Research Group on<br />

Agribusiness and Innovation (GAIN/UFAL) and the Research Network on Local Productive<br />

and Innovative Systems and Arrangements (RedeSist/UFRJ) and Northeast region director of<br />

the Brazilian Society for Ecological Economics (EcoEco).


109<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The second addresses issues of the relationship between innovation and<br />

environment, focusing on factors that influence the capacity of enterprises<br />

to become innovative. The third presents the results of researches on the<br />

environmental performance of Brazilian companies, especially regarding<br />

environmental investments.<br />

Innovation and<br />

technology for a green<br />

economy: key issues<br />

Maria Cecília Junqueira<br />

Lustosa<br />

1. En v ir o n m e n t a l i s s u e s a n d e c o n o m ic p r o d u c t io n<br />

Since the Industrial Revolution of the late 18th century, the economic and<br />

technological development based on intensive use of raw materials and energy<br />

increased the pace of utilization of natural resources. Given the abundance of<br />

these resources, the issue of sustainability of the economic system (namely<br />

the maintenance of good conditions for its good development, not depleting<br />

needed resources and making them available in good quality for future use)<br />

was not at the center of economists’ concerns for many decades.<br />

More than a century and a half after the onset of the industrialization process<br />

and the emergence of agriculture and livestock farming systems the issue of the<br />

finitude of natural resources, seen as a threat to the growth of modern economies,<br />

has definitively become part of the economists’ research agenda.<br />

Besides the intensive use of natural resources, waste of production processes<br />

released into the environment resulted in the accumulation of pollutants<br />

above its carrying capacity, causing pollution. Pollution goes beyond the local<br />

dimension (degradation of water bodies, soil and air quality) reaching a regional<br />

(acid rain) and global dimension (climate change and ozone layer depletion).<br />

The depletion of natural resources and pollution are environmental problems<br />

resulting from anthropic activities, which also lead to loss of biodiversity,<br />

generating imbalances in ecosystems and making them to lose part of their<br />

social and biological functions. This set of problems is called “environmental<br />

issue”. Its negative effects on the environment are the result of past actions and<br />

decisions, suggesting a temporal interdependence (path dependence), revealing<br />

a process of continuous change and highlighting uncertainties regarding the<br />

knowledge about environmental impacts derived from economic growth.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The hypothesis that the carrying capacity of the planet was reaching its<br />

limits, either by the amount of pollutants released into the environment or<br />

by the depletion of natural resources, dates from the late 1960s. Heated<br />

debates in the political, academic and social spheres have taken place when<br />

the environmental movement’s discourse was incorporated, which pointed to<br />

the incompatibility between environmental preservation and economic growth<br />

based on the intensive use of natural resources and non renewable energy<br />

sources. After more than five decades of debate, it is clear that there it is not<br />

growth that has reached its limit, but the technology and consumer standards<br />

hitherto adopted by industrialized countries.


110<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Innovation and<br />

technology for a green<br />

economy: key issues<br />

Maria Cecília Junqueira<br />

Lustosa<br />

Economic growth based on technological standards that make intesive use of<br />

raw materials and energy, especially from hydrocarbons (the main consumers<br />

of natural resources) can run into the limits of finitude of environmental<br />

resources, either through exhaustion or loss of quality. The change of current<br />

technology standards towards others that are less harmful to the environment<br />

is a necessary condition for economic growth to be continuous. In this sense<br />

economic growth may be possible for all countries, but with cleaner and natural<br />

resources efficient technologies 2 .<br />

It is evident, therefore, that there is a difference between the change of the<br />

current technological standard based on the burning of fossil fuels and the<br />

development of new cleaner technologies within the same standard in order<br />

to minimize the environmental impacts of economic activities.<br />

The change of technological patterns is extremely complex, since it occurs<br />

in the long term, depends on many variables, and even when induced by any<br />

kind of policy, it is not possible to know a priori all the consequences deriving<br />

from it, because not all negative externalities of technology, designed and used<br />

for specific purposes, can be envisaged. When it comes to issues concerning<br />

the environment, externalities affect an additional dimension, as they may have<br />

cumulative and depletion effects, which involve uncertainties. As accumulated<br />

pollution increases (cumulative effect), the adverse effects on ecosystems and<br />

human health can be observed, but no one knows exactly how far they may<br />

be affected.<br />

But technology alone, even when using intensively natural resources and<br />

restoring the waste of productive activities to the environment, would not<br />

generate significant environmental impacts if not for the scale effect - the<br />

environmental limit is reached by the pattern of consumption.<br />

The ever-increasing production requires greater amount of natural resources<br />

and disposes more waste into the environment. This increase is associated<br />

with the consumption pattern imposed by the capitalist mode of production,<br />

intensive in material and energy use that is the standard of central countries,<br />

which, through cultural, economic, technological and financial subordination, is<br />

transferred to the countries of the periphery 3 , following the logic of the capitalist<br />

system of accumulation. For its expansion, new markets and therefore new<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

2. Kemp and Soete (1992) properly note that the term “clean technology”, despite being widely<br />

used, is not the most correct linguistically. Firstly, because no technology is totally clean,<br />

and secondly, because the term clean technology and cleaning technology (technologies<br />

that elliminate pollution in the environment) must be distinguished. The correct term would<br />

be “cleaner technology” or “environment-saving”. There are also control technologies, which<br />

monitor emission levels and degradation of natural resources.<br />

3. The center-periphery scheme is a thesis of Raul Prebisch, in which Latin America was part<br />

of a system of international economic relations that operated as a constellation whose center<br />

was the industrialized countries and the periphery was the passive Latin America. In this<br />

context, Brazil has undergone a process of “modernization”, by the adoption of sophisticated<br />

consumption patterns of developed countries by a small portion of the population, which<br />

concentrated mostly the income from coffee exports (Furtado, 1974). With the deepening<br />

of globalization in recent decades, the consumption pattern of the central countries spread<br />

through all capitalist economies, creating a huge market of material and energy intensive<br />

products, which present great technological obsolescence.


111<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Innovation and<br />

technology for a green<br />

economy: key issues<br />

Maria Cecília Junqueira<br />

Lustosa<br />

consumer needs are required, which in order to be met demand indefinitely<br />

developing production 4 . Thus, the population grows and so does its needs,<br />

increasing the scale of industrial production and agricultural and livestock<br />

farming systems, resulting in increases in the demand for natural resources<br />

and of waste in production processes.<br />

As a consequence there is a trade-off between economic growth and<br />

environmental preservation. On the one hand, economic growth has brought<br />

improvements in the population’s living conditions, generating greater quantity<br />

of goods and services available to meet the needs, though not equitably<br />

distributed. On the other hand, that same growth has brought environmental<br />

problems, which are not restricted to industrial and agricultural activities such as<br />

uncontrolled urbanization, worsening of environmental conditions and causing<br />

damage to human health and to the quality of the environment.<br />

Given the complexity of the issue outlined above, this article addresses a<br />

specific aspect to support this broader discussion: environmental innovation as<br />

a way of changing the current standard technology toward a green economy. As<br />

a consequence, a central question arises: how to induce technological change<br />

in the direction of cleaner technologies in order to achieve environmental<br />

sustainability? That is, in a direction where natural resources serve to present<br />

and future generations and that pollution levels are reduced, even when there<br />

is an increase in production?<br />

2. In n o v a t io n a n d t h e e n v ir o n m e n t<br />

The industrial sector is one that causes more damage to the environment,<br />

either by their production processes or by manufacture of products that pollute<br />

and/or generate disposal problems after use. If on the one hand adopted<br />

technologies have led to environmental degradation, on the other, they enabled<br />

more efficient use of natural resources and input substitution in the production<br />

process. An outstanding example was improved energy use derived from<br />

petroleum and its partial substitution by other energy sources after the first oil<br />

shock in 1973. Therefore, the technological development towards a pattern of<br />

production less aggressive to the environment is seen as a partial solution to<br />

the problem.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Technological change in the direction of cleaner technologies entangles<br />

innovation process. According to Hall (1994), the innovation process<br />

corresponds to all the activities that generate technological change and<br />

dynamic interaction between them, which need not be primary inventions.<br />

When innovating, the company is seeking a solution to a given problem that is<br />

4. The organization of the industrial society since the 19th century is based on “... mechanic<br />

productivist model of positivism: scientific progress = technical progress = economic<br />

development = sociocultural progress” (Labeyrie, 2004, p. 125). In this context, there is no<br />

room for discussing social inequities and ecological imbalances caused by scientific and<br />

technological progress, basis of economic growth.


112<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Innovation and<br />

technology for a green<br />

economy: key issues<br />

Maria Cecília Junqueira<br />

Lustosa<br />

solved within a technological paradigm, i.e., within certain standard solutions<br />

widely accepted based on principles of natural sciences. Thus, once the<br />

technological paradigm is established, innovations become selective in the<br />

ability to solve problems, while hindering other solutions that would be outside<br />

the technological paradigm – characterizing a “blindness” of the prevailing<br />

technological paradigm. Technologies are elected in the selection process<br />

which, according to the predominant features of the selective environment,<br />

chooses certain technologies and not others.<br />

However, when the difficulties of finding solutions increase, inclusive<br />

regarding environmental problems, there is a strong incentive for a shift on<br />

the technological paradigm. However this is not a sufficient condition since<br />

in order to establish a new paradigm it is necessary that advances in basic<br />

knowledge occur, as well as other institutional and market factors. Thus, the<br />

dominant technological paradigm and the selective environment set the pace<br />

and direction of technical progress, which can even generate a paradigm shift,<br />

in a slow and gradual process.<br />

Within the current technological paradigm, a particular technology is selected.<br />

According to B. Arthur (quoted by López, 1996), the technology is not elected<br />

because it is the most efficient, but it becomes more efficient because it has<br />

been elected. That is, technologies become more attractive as they are more<br />

used. Hence, technology has temporal interdependence (path-dependent)<br />

since it is the result of predefined trajectories. This engenders a lock-in effect,<br />

leading companies to get caught in the more widespread technology and to<br />

the prevailing technological paradigm. These events have major effects on the<br />

company’s ability to find solutions to specific problems, that is, on its ability<br />

to innovate, including in the direction of Environmentally Sound Technologies<br />

(ESTs).<br />

The ESTs can be defined as the set of knowledge, techniques, methods,<br />

processes, experiences and equipment that use natural resources sustainably<br />

and that enable the proper disposal of industrial wastes, so as not to degrade<br />

the environment. They are obtained by means of environmental innovations.<br />

Technological changes in the direction of environmental technologies can<br />

occur in the technological trajectory (i.e. a more powerful combustion engine<br />

that generatesless emissions) or in the technological paradigm (a change of<br />

primary energy sources toward generating less environmental impact). With<br />

regard to primary energy generation, it is possible to identify the “hydrocarbon<br />

paradigm” based on oil and natural gas.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Therefore, for environmental improvements to occur, companies must adopt<br />

innovations. However, innovation in the enterprise is not the result of a decision<br />

based on internal factors but of complex interactions between the company and<br />

its customers and suppliers, and a broader context, including the institutional


113<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Innovation and<br />

technology for a green<br />

economy: key issues<br />

Maria Cecília Junqueira<br />

Lustosa<br />

environment, cultural and social infrastructure, macroeconomic aspects: the<br />

innovation system. The focus of the analysis should therefore be go beyond<br />

the company and seek a systemic approach.<br />

These considerations lead to an important aspect for the green economy<br />

(how to direct technological change toward environmental innovations) and<br />

raise the following question: What enables companies to generate and adopt<br />

environmental innovations? There are several factors - economic, social,<br />

institutional and scientific - that influence the capacity of enterprises to become<br />

innovative. In general, it is possible to group them into internal and external<br />

factors to business. Among the internal factors, it is possible to highlight the<br />

company’s specific skills for problem solving, its absorptive capacity and its<br />

access to innovations developed by others.<br />

The company’s specific competencies to solve problems are accumulated<br />

over time. That is, they consist of skills and knowledge that the company has<br />

acquired over time, which determine its ability to absorb and create knowledge.<br />

These skills and specific knowledge depend on investments in research and<br />

development (R&D), individual knowledge of employees, the size and nature of<br />

the enterprise (public, private, transnational etc.), sector of activity and degree<br />

of specialization.<br />

The second internal factor is directly related to the first. The absorptive<br />

capacity, according to Cohen and Levinthal (1990), is defined by the skills<br />

of recognizing the value of new information, assimilate it and apply it for<br />

commercial purposes, being crucial to enable the company to innovate. This<br />

ability to evaluate and use external knowledge is the function of prior knowledge,<br />

that is, when the external knowledge and the company have basic standards and<br />

common languages, it becomes easier to use the information productively.<br />

The access to innovations developed by third parties is not free and, in<br />

general, has high costs. Whether by lack of information from the company that<br />

wants to adopt the environmental innovation, by the innovator’s competitive<br />

strategy of not diffuding their innovation, by patent protection and by trade<br />

secrecy or the costs of maintaing absorptive capacity, innovations are not<br />

available as “products on a supermarket shelf”. This means that there is a<br />

charge for access and it can be high. Thus, for many companies it is difficult<br />

to innovate, whether because of high cost of internal development or of the<br />

acquisition of third party technologies.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Among the external factors are: the current technological paradigm, the<br />

National Innovation System, the macroeconomic context, measures of<br />

regulatory nature and degree of market competition in which the company<br />

operates.<br />

The current technological paradigm, as explained earlier, determines the<br />

company’s ability to innovate, because it sets the standard in which scientific


114<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Innovation and<br />

technology for a green<br />

economy: key issues<br />

Maria Cecília Junqueira<br />

Lustosa<br />

innovations must be circumscribed. In this sense, the shift in the technology<br />

paradigm may make the company become more or less innovative, depending<br />

on their specific expertise.<br />

The National Innovation System (NIS), the second external factor, will<br />

influence the ability of businesses to generate and adopt innovations, since it<br />

is an organizational system that aims to develop science and technology within<br />

the country. It is a complex institutional arrangement involving companies’<br />

laboratories of R&D, research institutes and universities, financial, educational<br />

and law institutions (patents, laws regulating competition). The NIS should be<br />

considered in its three dimensions: institutions; the interaction between them,<br />

forming a network; and the learning ability. Thus, an effective NIS induces<br />

enterprises to be innovative.<br />

The macroeconomic context is a factor that interferes with the process of<br />

innovation in businesses, since it makes explicit the economic context in which<br />

it is inserted. Companies have difficulty in making decisions in conditions of<br />

great uncertainty, generated by a scenario of macroeconomic instability. In<br />

this context, there is some paralysis to innovate. Reversely, macroeconomic<br />

stability creates confidence in economic agents, which will tend to consume<br />

and invest more.<br />

Measures of regulatory nature are crucial to induce environmental<br />

innovations. Some scetors require greater regulations due to the type of<br />

activity they develop. For example, companies whose activities have negative<br />

impacts on the environment are subject to compliance with regulations, which<br />

may induce innovations, depending on the objectives and instruments of<br />

environmental policy.<br />

Finally, the degree of market competition in which the company operates<br />

is one of the factors that most influence their decision to generate and adopt<br />

innovations, including environmental. With market pressure, especially the<br />

most competitive ones, innovation becomes the differentiating factor between<br />

the company and its competitors, creating asymmetries between them and<br />

may be the only way to survive in a market that values the non-aggression to<br />

the environment.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

In the light of the above, new paths and bifurcations of technological<br />

trajectories must be induced so as to incorporate environmental improvements,<br />

even though this is not the primary purpose of developing a particular<br />

technology. That is to say that when incorporating environmental issues in<br />

innovations, environmental improvements and economic gains can be achieved<br />

simultaneously. The adoption of cleaner technologies has not been driven<br />

by environmental protection, but by the search for efficiency in resource use<br />

(Fukusaku, 2000).


115<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Innovation and<br />

technology for a green<br />

economy: key issues<br />

Maria Cecília Junqueira<br />

Lustosa<br />

Despite the advances in the environmental technologies of the industrial<br />

sector (cleanear technologies, increased use of materials less harmful to the<br />

environment, improved processes and systems for the reuse of materials)<br />

environmental problems persist. The condition to achieve gains in the direction<br />

of a production pattern which is more environmentally friendly implies to move<br />

towards a technological paradigm that is not grounded in intensive use of energy<br />

and raw materials, and the consequent adaptation of production processes.<br />

A new technological paradigm requires a long maturation period, with several<br />

changes, including of conceptual order.<br />

The definition of consumption, for example, needs to be revised. Consumption<br />

is a term distinct of use. The first means the destruction of the original material,<br />

or rather the transformation into other elements. That is, when we burn coal,<br />

consumption has taken place, as it was transformed into carbon dioxide and<br />

water. Use means no transformation of the materials, but other elements can<br />

be added to them. This is the case of water and metals, which remain water<br />

and metals even after use. Thus, they can be recycled and reused in other<br />

circumstances. However, this distinction is not made by the majority of economic<br />

activities that generate pollution since they do not recycle materials already<br />

used, thus not transforming the production process’ waste into wealth.<br />

3. In n o v a t io n a n d t h e e n v ir o n m e n t in Br a z il ia n<br />

c o m p a n ie s<br />

Brazilian industrialization has been marked by a relative neglect of<br />

the environmental issue, a result of “... the delay in the establishment of<br />

environmental rulings and specialized agencies in pollution control; growth<br />

strategy associated with import substitution industrialization, focusing on<br />

emission-intensive sectors, and the trend towards the specialization of the<br />

export sector in potentially polluting activities” (Young and Lustosa , 2001).<br />

For many years, the industrial sector did not pay attention to the environmental<br />

costs of their production processes, neither to the related waste, including<br />

pollution. There used to be a belief that producing in an environmentally<br />

sound manner would be more costly and would harm the companies’ financial<br />

performance. However, the search for alternatives that minimize the negative<br />

impacts of productive activity on the environment has been reflected in economic<br />

gains and improved competitiveness of enterprises.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Environmental issues gained ground on businesses’ social concerns since<br />

the 1990s. When companies realized the society’s growing interest and<br />

concern with the environment, they sought to insert themselves in the context<br />

as participating agents of change in response to the expectations of society,<br />

having seen the decline in the State’s financial capacity and the disbelief on<br />

the State as an actor capable of solving relevant social problems.


116<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Innovation and<br />

technology for a green<br />

economy: key issues<br />

Maria Cecília Junqueira<br />

Lustosa<br />

As the preservation of the environment has become a differentiating factor for<br />

companies, as a business opportunity, the possibility to include environmental<br />

concerns arose in their strategies, by means of more environmentally<br />

appropriate practices. Such practices have resulted in the adoption of ESTs,<br />

implementation of environmental management systems, rational use of natural<br />

resources, among others.<br />

Taking the opportunity to improve their image and have society’s<br />

acknowledgement as a key player in the transformation process, companies<br />

are investing in environmental programs of social nature. Even with little tax<br />

incentive, companies engaged in these projects pursuing a positive image,<br />

acting as a powerful marketing tool, differentiating themselves from their<br />

competitors and gaining attention in the media - spontaneously, inclusive. This is<br />

a first indication that the environment can be a way to improve competitiveness.<br />

Despite the social and environmental initiatives implemented by companies with<br />

positive results for the environment and society, environmental problems “at<br />

home” (resulting from negative environmental impacts of their core activities)<br />

were well below the visibility of environmental projects targeted at society. The<br />

exceptions are companies that have suffered some pressure to do so: the<br />

requirement of countries which import Brazilian products and environmental<br />

regulations that force companies to lower the environmental impacts of their<br />

activities.<br />

Cost reduction has also played an important role in minimizing the<br />

environmental impacts of companies. However, the environment was not the<br />

focus - programs for energy conservation, process optimization aiming at<br />

reducing input costs, automated control processes that reduce waste, water<br />

recirculation, among others, presented a positive effect in the direction of a<br />

more rational use of natural resources.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Empirical evidence shows that the innovations that generate positive impacts<br />

both to the environment and to the companies’ economic performance are related<br />

to their size. Whether by employed personnel or by range of net revenues, the<br />

biggest companies are those that consider the environment a motivating factor<br />

for the company to innovate (Lustosa, 2002; Podcameni, 2007). The company<br />

size has a positive influence on the probability of implementation of environment<br />

investment, that is, the larger the company, the greater that probability (Ferraz<br />

and Seroa da Motta, 2001). Micro and small enterprises (MSEs) have worked<br />

less on solutions for environmental issues as indicated by variables of adoption<br />

of environmental management, improved image, increased sales, access to<br />

new markets and investment environment (CNI et al. 2001).<br />

Other studies confirm that the requirements imposed by law are still the main<br />

determinant of environmental investment in enterprises. According to Almeida<br />

et al. (2004), most companies still restricts its environmental responsibility to<br />

comply with environmental legislation and in response to the fines and penalties.


117<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Innovation and<br />

technology for a green<br />

economy: key issues<br />

Maria Cecília Junqueira<br />

Lustosa<br />

However, the increasing demands of the market and competitivity between<br />

companies turn the adoption of environmental management principles into a<br />

necessary condition for the businesses’ survival.<br />

Ferraz and Seroa da Motta (2001), in a study that analyzes the determinants<br />

of environmental investment in the industry in the State of São Paulo, found<br />

some internal and external factors to enterprises, which are significant for<br />

environmental investment. The internal factors indicate that plants with<br />

more workers, older firms and those with foreign capital tend to make more<br />

environmental investments, as well as those with a higher proportion of exports<br />

over sales and those belonging to sectors considered pollutants. In relation<br />

to factors external to companies, only the factors associated with formal<br />

environmental regulation, as the number of warnings given by the environmental<br />

agency, for example, were significant.<br />

Tigre (1994), in a research carried out with producers of equipment and<br />

environmental services, shows that 69% of companies have realized that the<br />

government regulations are extremely influential in the growth of their market<br />

and that 21% considered such regulations influential 5 .<br />

Innovation in the MSEs is related to factors such as the organization and<br />

the need for innovation in the sector in which they operate. Although in most<br />

cases they do not have enough capital, they have other advantages that<br />

favor investment in innovation such as the flexibility of their structures, their<br />

diversified activities and their quick adaptation to market changes. However,<br />

small enterprises have less access to technological information than the larger<br />

ones; besides, the difficulty in obtaining credit makes innovation initiatives<br />

quite risky.<br />

Among other factors that inhibit innovation in MSEs are low managerial<br />

capacity of the people who are ahead of the business and the short-term<br />

planning. Because of their small size, owners and/or administrators cling to<br />

solve daily problems and do not give the due importance to long-term strategies<br />

and to innovation.<br />

With regard specifically to the issue of environmental innovation, its<br />

importance lies in the fact that eco-efficient production is an important instrument<br />

of competitiveness, as it reduces costs and improves product quality, enabling<br />

the opening of new markets..<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

5. To the other answer options, “little influent” or “non influent”, the percentages of 7% and 3%<br />

have been attributed, respectivelly.


118<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Innovation and<br />

technology for a green<br />

economy: key issues<br />

Maria Cecília Junqueira<br />

Lustosa<br />

Co n c l u s io n s<br />

The growth process of modern capitalist economies, which started with<br />

the Industrial Revolution of the 19th century, generated an enormous output<br />

of material goods. Concomitant with this dramatic increase in production<br />

scale, the “environmental issues” arose - depletion of natural resources and<br />

pollution. However, it was in the late 1960s that the degradation of the planet<br />

started gradually to enter into the discussion agenda of the social, political and<br />

academic spheres. The environmental movement began to take a social and<br />

political conotation.<br />

In this debate, innovation and technology become important variables to be<br />

studied, since they are those that determine the set of knowledge, techniques,<br />

methods, processes, equipment and experiences that will transform raw<br />

materials into consumer goods.<br />

Therefore, the technological standard presents a double face: it was and still<br />

is largely one of the factors leading to the aggravation of environmental issues<br />

in proportion to increases in the scale of production. Its other side emerges as<br />

the solution to environmental problems through technological changes in the<br />

direction of environmentally sound technologies - which use natural resources<br />

sustainably and enable the proper disposal of waste in production, so as not<br />

to degrade the environment. These changes occur through environmental<br />

innovations.<br />

Once the companies are the producing agents in the economy, their capacity<br />

to generate and adopt environmental innovations is crucial for the obtainment<br />

of production processes and products less harmful to the environment and,<br />

therefore, environmental improvements - properly managing natural resources<br />

and controlling pollution.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Despite the benefits that environmental innovations can bring, there are<br />

factors in the technological, political and market spheres that limit their<br />

generation and diffusion. In cases where companies show no interest in<br />

practices less harmful to the environment, the State must use legal means<br />

(environmental policy and its regulations), through public environmental<br />

management and encourage companies to change their behavior in relation<br />

to the environmental impacts of their activities. Environmental regulation has<br />

both normative and informative sides: it translates the needs of environmental<br />

protection into specific requirements, signaling to polluters and suppliers of<br />

environmental technologies what is being demanded. The generation and<br />

particularly the diffusion of environmental innovation are crucial to harmonize<br />

environmental preservation with the growth of economic output.


119<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Innovation and<br />

technology for a green<br />

economy: key issues<br />

Maria Cecília Junqueira<br />

Lustosa<br />

References<br />

Almeida, J. R., Mell, C. S. and Cavalcanti, Y. (2004). Gestão ambiental: planejamento,<br />

avaliação, implantação, operação e verificação, 2ª ed. Rio de janeiro: THEX.<br />

CNI, SEBRAE, BNDES (2001). Relatório da Competitividade da Indústria Brasileira.<br />

Brasília: CNI/SEBRAE; Rio de Janeiro: BNDES.<br />

Cohen, W. and Levinthal, D. (1990). Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning<br />

and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35, 128-152.<br />

Ferraz, C. and Seroa da Motta, R. (2001). Regulação, mercado ou pressão social?<br />

Os determinantes do investimento ambiental na indústria. Anais do XIX Encontro<br />

Nacional de Economia, Salvador - BA, ANPEC.<br />

Fukasaku, Y. (2000). Stimuler l’innovation environnementale. In OCDE, Le developpement<br />

durable. Número especial, Paris: OCDE.<br />

Furtado, C. (1974). O mito do desenvolvimento econômico. Rio de Janeiro: Paz e<br />

Terra.<br />

Hall, P. (1994). Innovation, economics and evolution: theoretical perspectives on<br />

changing technology in economic systems. New York: Harvester Wheatsheaf.<br />

Kemp, R. and Soete, L. (1992). The greening of technological progress: an evolutionary<br />

perspective. Futures, 24(5), 437-457.<br />

Labeyre, V. (2004). As conseqüências ecológicas das atividades tecno-industriais. In<br />

Morin, E., A religação dos saberes: o desafio do século XXI, 4a ed. Rio de Janeiro:<br />

Bertrand Brasil.<br />

López, A. (1996). Competitividad, innovacion y desarrollo sustentable: una discusión<br />

conceptual. DT 22, Buenos Aires: CENIT.<br />

Lustosa, M. C. J. (2002). Meio ambiente, inovação e competitividade na indústria<br />

brasileira: a cadeia produtiva do petróleo. Doctorate thesis, Rio de Janeiro: IE/<br />

UFRJ.<br />

Podcameni, M. G. (2007). Meio ambiente, inovação e competitividade: uma análise da<br />

indústria de transformação brasileira com ênfase no setor de combustível. Master’s<br />

degree dissertation. Rio de Janeiro: IE/UFRJ.<br />

Preston, J. T. (1997). Technology innovation and environmental progress. In Chertow,<br />

M. R. and Esty, D. C., Thinking ecologically – the next generation of environmental<br />

policy. London: Yale Univ. Press.<br />

Tigre, P. B. (coord.) (1994). Tecnologia e meio ambiente: oportunidades para a indústria.<br />

Rio de Janeiro: UFRJ.<br />

Young, C. E. F.ande Lustosa, M. C. J. (2001). Meio ambiente e competitividade na<br />

indústria brasileira. Revista de Economia Contemporânea, v. 5, Edição Especial,<br />

231-259. Rio de Janeiro: IE/UFRJ.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011


120<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Agriculture for a green<br />

economy<br />

Ademar Ribeiro Romeiro 1<br />

1. In it ia l c o n s id e r a t io n s<br />

What is a “green economy”? The An understanding of the meaning of a green<br />

economy depends on the underlying concept of ecological sustainability. In the<br />

recent UNEP report on green economy, this conception is that implied by the<br />

sustainable development concept: it is possible to reconcile economic growth<br />

with environmental conservation by increasing ecological efficiency 2 , by using<br />

greater caution in decisions that involve environmental impacts, by raising<br />

consumer awareness in selecting goods and services with lower impacts, etc.<br />

The report clarifies how much can be done to bring about “a greening” of the<br />

economy. 3<br />

However, over a very long term, within a human time scale (thousands of<br />

years 4 ), the concept of ecological sustainability to be considered is one that<br />

clearly establishes that economic growth, as expressed by increased material/<br />

energy production per capita, cannot continue indefinitely due to the simple<br />

fact that there are entropic limits to increases in ecological efficiency. According<br />

to the Second Law of Thermodynamics, the Entropy Law, it is impossible to<br />

reduce waste generated by human activities to zero. 5 It is essential to take<br />

into account the finitude of planet Earth, which is a closed system in terms<br />

of the exchange of matter with other systems in space (with the exception<br />

of occasional meteorite collisions); from an energy perspective, the planet is<br />

“calibrated” to simply absorb solar energy and radiate heat to outer space,<br />

having no significant endogenous sources of energy (geothermal sources are<br />

relatively unimportant). The unlimited increase in the production of materials/<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

1. Full professor at the Institute of Economics at the University of Campinas (IE/UNICAMP),<br />

coordinator of the Nucleus of Studies and Research on Environment (NEPAM/UNICAMP) and<br />

director of the Brazilian Society of Ecological Economics.<br />

2. Ecological efficiency is understood as the most efficient use of natural resources, producing<br />

more with the same quantity of resources and/or maintaining the level of production with the<br />

use of fewer resources, resulting in reduced emission of residues per unit of product or service.<br />

3. The recommendations of this report largely echo the viewpoints expressed for decades by the<br />

principal theoretician of sustainable development, professor Ignacy Sachs, of the University of<br />

Paris. See, for example, Sachs (2006).<br />

4. The minimum time period that should be considered as a long-term human scale is 10<br />

thousand years, since the invention of agriculture during the Neolithic age. In average, it<br />

should be considered the time period since humans controlled the use of fire, between 200 and<br />

400 thousand years ago.<br />

5. Some specialists believe that it is theoretically possible to increase current average ecological<br />

efficiency by up to 10 times. For example, current carbon emissions produced by the<br />

combustion of carbon for steel production could be reduced by up to 90% with the introduction<br />

of new processes. For a detailed discussion see the works of the Factor Ten Institute: http://<br />

www.factor10.de


121<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Agriculture for a<br />

green economy<br />

Ademar Romeiro<br />

energy based on exogenous sources of energy and materials (which can be<br />

found inert in the terrestrial crust) leads to increased thermodynamic imbalances<br />

that would eventually produce adaptive ecological processes catastrophic to<br />

mankind. 6 Thus, zero growth (of material/energy production) is inevitable (“for<br />

good or for evil”), as predicted by the Club of Rome in 1972. 7<br />

Zero growth, it must be said, does not necessarily imply the absence of<br />

human development. Indeed, human development depends on increased<br />

production of materials and energy to achieve a level of material comfort that<br />

is deemed appropriate. However, after a certain level of material comfort,<br />

human development is much more dependent on other factors, particularly<br />

those related to the emotional balance of individuals. In this sense, an index<br />

that best measures development in its various dimensions would not be the<br />

GDP, as it is currently calculated. 8<br />

In agriculture, the limits of expansion are more obvious: the agricultural area<br />

available is visibly finite and, however spectacular the gains in agricultural<br />

productivity have been, one can no longer count on further significant increases.<br />

In short, it seems clear that agricultural productivity cannot grow indefinitely.<br />

After all, Thomas Malthus was absolutely right in his fundamental intuition about<br />

the environmental limits to growth. Who disagrees with the notion that the world<br />

population cannot grow forever? Even the most obtuse economists admit this<br />

fact, although they continue believing in the perpetual growth of material and<br />

energy consumption.<br />

However, it is not sufficient to acknowledge that the expansion of agricultural<br />

production has limits. One must consider the conditions under which this<br />

production takes place, which must allow continuity for millennia! In the early<br />

20th century a debate took place among agronomists in Europe, and particularly<br />

in France, about the enormous advantages of American agriculture, with its<br />

high labor productivity but major environmental impacts, compared to European<br />

agriculture, which preserved the agricultural ecosystem but was less productive<br />

per unit of labor. Many experts argued in favor of American agriculture, saying<br />

it would not be worth losing productivity gains to conserve the soil, since in the<br />

future (around the end of the century!) agriculture would no longer be necessary<br />

for the production of food!<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

6. Exogenous energy sources include all energy sources, except solar directly received by the<br />

planet on a daily basis, such as fossil fuels and nuclear energy; inert materials in the crust<br />

(all types of mineral resources) as they are mined and processed in the ecosphere (the layer<br />

of earth where life is concentrated – from a few meters below the subsoil to several hundred<br />

meters above the ground) become active waste to the degree that they force the ecosystems<br />

of the ecosphere to absorb them.<br />

7. The fact that initial predictions have failed due to errors in modeling and in the parameters<br />

used in no way changes the rationale on which they were based.<br />

8. For an analysis of the debate on indicators that reflects these dimensions of economic<br />

development, see Veiga (2010).


122<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Agriculture for a<br />

green economy<br />

Ademar Romeiro<br />

The catastrophic effects of erosion in the U.S. eventually led to a great<br />

movement for soil conservation and for the adoption of other conservation<br />

practices that guaranteed a minimum level of sustainability for so-called modern<br />

agricultural practices. 9 However, one can question this minimum sustainability<br />

level of current practices, as has been done by movements in favor of alternative<br />

farming practices that effectively ensure agricultural productive capacity over<br />

the very long term.<br />

2. Th e e c o l o g ic a l s p e c i f i c i t y o f t h e a g r ic u l t u r a l<br />

p r o d u c t io n s e c t o r<br />

Agricultural activities depend on space. It is the primary agent responsible<br />

for the irreversible transformation of natural ecosystems. The impacts of<br />

farming practices on the natural resource base also directly affect the quality<br />

and quantity of agricultural products generated. So-called modern practices<br />

guarantee the quantity but not the quality of food, which exhibits varying degrees<br />

of contamination by agrochemicals, as well as declining nutritional quality:<br />

unbalanced fertilization and the deteriorating physical structure of soils affect<br />

the structure of amino acids and vitamin content in foods.<br />

However, even quantity is not guaranteed if we consider the very long term.<br />

Similar to the defenders of American agriculture in the early 20th century,<br />

proponents of current practices argue that adoption of agro-ecological practices<br />

would drastically reduce agricultural labor productivity, resulting in unacceptable<br />

costs to the population. In fact, so-called organic or, more generally, agroecological<br />

10 products are more expensive, because their marketing is currently<br />

limited to niche markets composed of a more aware consumer that is willing to<br />

pay higher prices for better quality products. 11<br />

It can be argued, however, that these prices could already be lower if<br />

governments devoted similar efforts to support agro-ecological practices that<br />

they dedicate to conventional agriculture, in terms of agricultural research and<br />

extension, credit, subsidies, etc. Furthermore, one must consider that proper<br />

ecological accounting would show that the higher prices of agro-ecological<br />

products incorporate a range of ecosystem services 12 that benefit society as<br />

a whole.<br />

The first, as already mentioned, is the quality of food. Healthier food in terms of<br />

nutrients and the absence of chemical contamination. Another important service<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

9. Erosion caused by wind, in particular in the semi-arid Great Plains, caused enormous dust<br />

storms referred to as “dust bowl”, which reached as far as the East Coast!<br />

10. Agro-ecological products are understood as those produced according to certain rules of<br />

cultivation based on intelligent management of natural forces, minimizing the introduction of<br />

exogenous agrochemical inputs.<br />

11. For an analysis of the problems associated with the adoption of agro-ecological practices in<br />

Brazil, see Assis and Romeiro (2004 and 2007).<br />

12. For a classification of ecosystem services, see the 2005 Report of the Millennium<br />

Ecosystem Assessment (MEA).


123<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Agriculture for a<br />

green economy<br />

Ademar Romeiro<br />

involves the provision of high quality water. An agro-ecological agricultural<br />

landscape results from soil management that enhances the infiltration of water,<br />

which eliminates erosion and contributes to the regulation of water flows in<br />

rivers. As a result, water quality is not compromised by massive inputs of<br />

sedimentary material and agrochemicals, thus reducing which reduces the cost<br />

of water treatment in urban centers (which do not eliminate the whole problem)<br />

and contributing to the preservationing of aquatic fauna.<br />

A third ecosystem service is that of maintaining a diverse flora and fauna in<br />

the agricultural landscape that is increasingly valued in most countries. This<br />

agro-ecological landscape is essential for ecotourism or rural tourism, and<br />

citizens of several countries are increasingly willing to pay for these services.<br />

The absorption and storage of carbon is a fourth service. There are others, but<br />

not all can be monetized due to a lack of information. Those that are monetizable<br />

should be calculated and taken into account in the formulation of agricultural<br />

policies that support agro-ecological practices.<br />

The necessity of accounting for the economic (monetary) dimension of<br />

the value of agro-ecology may be sufficient to justify more supportive policies.<br />

Nevertheless, we must not lose sight of the ecological and socio-cultural<br />

dimensions, which cannot be measured in monetary terms. The socio-cultural<br />

dimension is measured by the role that agricultural space may have in<br />

preserving the cultural identity of many peoples. In the case of the ecological<br />

dimension, which concerns everyone, the metric is sustainability in the very<br />

long term as defined by (a) utility (necessity for human survival) and (b) ethics<br />

(acceptance of the right to survival of species without known uses)<br />

Agricultural science has already accumulated sufficient experience to define<br />

parameters for the sustainability of farming practices in the very long term: an<br />

agro-ecosystem where a certain proportion of the remnant native flora and<br />

fauna contributes to the long-term ecological resilience of agricultural practices<br />

based on the management of natural processes.<br />

The ecological principles of agro-ecological practices<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

It can be said that modern farming practices have evolved in response to<br />

economic stimuli resulting from the advantages of monoculture in terms of the<br />

organization and productivity of agricultural labor, and the prospect of gains<br />

from the specialization in making more profitable products. 13 Technically this<br />

was made possible by the introduction of chemical-mechanical procedures that<br />

have, however, proven to be degrading to the productive base.<br />

It is necessary to be clear that monoculture contradicts a basic rule in<br />

nature, that diversity is synonymous with stability. The more simplified a given<br />

13. See Romeiro (1991, 1998) for a historic analysis of this process.


124<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Agriculture for a<br />

green economy<br />

Ademar Romeiro<br />

ecosystem, the greater the need for exogenous sources of energy and matter<br />

to maintain balance. Monoculture causes a profound imbalance, both in terms<br />

of vegetation cover (pest infestations) as well as the physical, chemical and<br />

biological activities within the soil.<br />

Destabilizing factors gain strength and force farmers to use energy-intensive<br />

techniques to maintain conditions favorable for crop development. However,<br />

these technical solutions do not seek to eliminate the causes of the imbalance,<br />

but only circumvent its effects on revenues. The initial effectiveness of these<br />

techniques and procedures made the vast majority of experts extremely<br />

optimistic.<br />

Experience has shown, however, that there was no reason for this optimism.<br />

In France, for example, due to the generally low organic matter content, the<br />

physical structure of soils has become increasingly susceptible to the action of<br />

climatic factors, as well as to the passage of heavy machinery and equipment –<br />

the use of which, in turn, was necessary to aerate soils increasingly susceptible<br />

to compaction due to low organic matter content!<br />

In other words, the degradation of physical soil structure causes a permanent<br />

contradiction in the interventions designed to improve the supply of water<br />

and nutrients to crops: the more the soil is degraded, the less natural factors<br />

(ecosystem services) provide the necessary conditions for cultivation, which<br />

must then be obtained through chemical and mechanical interventions that also<br />

contribute to degradation. However, it must be clear that these interventions<br />

do not resolve the contradiction, in that they are designed to overcome the<br />

effects of environmental degradation on productivity, without addressing the<br />

causes of the problems.<br />

The causes should be addressed through the adoption of agricultural<br />

practices designed to manage nature rather than fight against it! An agricultural<br />

ecosystem necessarily involves simplification of the original ecosystem. For<br />

this reason it is necessary that the farmer always intervenes to keep it stable.<br />

However, such interventions should be made in accordance with the laws of<br />

nature.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Extreme simplification can be avoided by crop rotation. This practice provides<br />

a remarkable means of maintaining stability of the agricultural ecosystem. In<br />

addition to dramatically reducing the risk of pest infestation of the vegetation<br />

cover, rotation effectively contributes to the maintenance of good physical<br />

soil structure. Agro-ecology seeks precisely this: based on the successful<br />

experience of ancient farming systems, to scientifically develop farming<br />

practices that manage nature in order to obtain ecosystem services useful for<br />

production.


125<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Agriculture for a<br />

green economy<br />

Ademar Romeiro<br />

3. Ag r o-e n v ir o n m e n t a l p o l i c i e s<br />

As a result of the presentation in previous section, scientific research<br />

in sustainable agro-ecosystems should be a fundamental part of an agroenvironmental<br />

policy for agriculture. In Brazil, research began over 20 years<br />

on low-impact farming practices. 14 One of the most notable results of this<br />

work is the expansion of no-tillage systems, 15 which has already expanded to<br />

over 10 million hectares. This is a farming system in which farmers create the<br />

conditions that guarantee the required organic matter content and that protect<br />

the soil from sun and rain, measures that are necessary for the activities of<br />

soil micro-fauna that result in a physical soil structure suitable for planting.<br />

This approach recognizes how the intelligent management of natural forces<br />

can provide ecosystem services that both conserve the soil and maintain high<br />

productivity. Another notable example, older and hugely successful, is the<br />

widespread fixation of atmospheric nitrogen by inoculants that strengthen this<br />

naturally occurring process associated with legumes such as soybeans. In<br />

addition, farmers are increasingly applying biological control of pests in crops,<br />

for example through viruses that attack their main insect predator of soybeans.<br />

These are techniques that use natural processes and ecosystem services, but<br />

are still mainly applied in monocultures.<br />

Currently, research organizations in Brazil are increasing efforts to research<br />

sustainable agro-ecosystems. For example, a few years ago Brazilian<br />

Agricultural Research Company (EMBRAPA) created an agro-biology research<br />

center as well as sustaining another research center in agriculture and<br />

environment. 16 These are centers of reference, but all the other EMBRAPA<br />

research centers have also expressed concern about the sustainability of<br />

agricultural practices. Recently a technological “package” was launched for<br />

livestock-agriculture integration. These are two activities that have strong<br />

ecological complementarities, so that integration increases output per hectare in<br />

a sustainable manner. This is an important step to enable the effective adoption<br />

of agro-ecological practices.<br />

Along with scientific and technological policies, it is crucial that the negative<br />

externalities of conventional practices be are measured and taxed in some<br />

way. Simultaneously, the positive externalities – such as the ecosystem<br />

services generated by farmers – should be considered. As such, the cost of<br />

adopting certain sustainable practices (opportunity cost) represents the value<br />

of the environmental conservation service offered by the farmer. Through this<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

14. For a broader analysis of the prospects for agro-environmental policies, see Romeiro (2007).<br />

15. No-tillage is a system of farming without plowing the soil. The seed is buried directly in soil<br />

covered with a layer of chopped-up crop residues (straw), which protects and at the same time<br />

provides needed organic matter to feed the chain of organisms living in the soil. The conditions<br />

needed for plant development from seed are derived precisely from the activities of these<br />

organisms; as a result, these activities translate into an ecosystem service of structuring the<br />

soil for the planting and development of crops.<br />

16. EMBRAPA Agro-biology (CNPAB) and EMBRAPA Environment (CNPMA).


126<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Agriculture for a<br />

green economy<br />

Ademar Romeiro<br />

environmental conservation service, the farmer ensures that nature (agroecosystem)<br />

produces ecosystem services such as those mentioned (healthy<br />

food, water quantity and quality, biodiversity). The best known food products<br />

certification, such as organic or biodynamic agriculture, began by emphasizing<br />

the healthy character of the food produced, but today these certifications<br />

tend to include other ecosystem services resulting from the preservation and<br />

management of a particular agricultural landscape, such as biodiversity and<br />

water in particular.<br />

It’s important to bear in mind that many of the ecosystem services produced<br />

by the adoption of agro-ecological practices also benefit the farmer. In this case<br />

one can speak of win-win technologies, which produce positive environmental<br />

externalities and at the same time are profitable for producers. This is the<br />

case for healthy food when the market recognizes its value by offering a<br />

price that makes production profitable. In the case of water, protected soil<br />

with appropriate organic matter content, increases crop resistance to drought<br />

stress, thereby saving expenses associated with supplemental irrigation and<br />

crop failures. In more balanced ecosystems, expenditures on pest control are<br />

also decreased. Greater biodiversity also improves productivity by ensuring<br />

better crop pollination.<br />

Hence, it is important to take stock of the real opportunity costs of adopting<br />

agro-ecological practices, thereby obtaining a fair reference on which to base<br />

payments for environmental services that society as a whole should make to<br />

farmers.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

References<br />

Assis, R. L. and Romeiro, A. R. (2004). Análise do processo de conversão de sistemas<br />

de produção de café convencional para orgânico: um estudo de caso. Cadernos de<br />

Ciência e Tecnologia, 21(1), 143-168. Brasília: EMBRAPA.<br />

Assis, R. L. and Romeiro, A.R. (2007). O processo de conversão de sistemas de<br />

produção convencionais para orgânicos. Revista Brasileira de Administração Pública,<br />

41, 863-885.<br />

Romeiro, A. R. (1991). O modelo euro-americano de modernização agrícola. Nova<br />

Economia, 2(21), 175-197. Belo Horizonte: UFMG.<br />

Romeiro, A. R. (1998). Meio Ambiente e Dinâmica de Inovações na Agricultura. São<br />

Paulo: FAPESP/ANNABLUME, 277 p.<br />

Romeiro, A. R. (2007). Perspectivas para políticas agroambientais. In Ramos, P. (org.)<br />

Dimensões do agronegócio brasileiro: políticas, instituições e perspectivas, 1 ed.,<br />

v. 1, 283-317. Brasília: NEAD Estudos.<br />

Sachs, I. (2006). Caminhos para o desenvolvimento sustentável. Rio de Janeiro: Editora<br />

Garamond.<br />

Veiga, J. E. (2010). Indicadores de sustentabilidade. Estudos Avançados, n. 68,<br />

Jan-Apr.


127<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy and a new<br />

cycle of rural development 1<br />

Arilson Favareto 2<br />

In t r o d u c t io n<br />

Can the “green economy” favor the poorest, especially in rural areas? The<br />

response to this question is affirmative. The “Green Economy Initiative” (GEI) 3 ,<br />

launched by the UNEP in 2008, and the subsequent “Green Economy Coalition”<br />

(GEC) 4 , headed by thirteen international organizations of consumers, workers,<br />

entrepreneurs, environmentalists and researchers, define “green economy”<br />

as that which in addition to being just and resilient, manages to improve the<br />

quality of life for everyone, within the ecological limits of this planet. Thus,<br />

the fundamental issue is not to know if such intent can favor the poorest, but<br />

especially to show how this can take place and through what initiatives.<br />

In the case of rural regions, there are two starting points for analyzing such<br />

issue. It is known that, on the one hand, there is a declining role of agriculture<br />

in the income generation of families. That is, rural family incomes increasingly<br />

originate from other non-agricultural activities, such as urban-type jobs on<br />

premises located nearby, from other activities conducted in agricultural<br />

establishments, such as the provision of services or manufacture of product<br />

parts, or even from the transfers of income via social programs. On the other<br />

hand, the impacts of the current model of agricultural production and livestock<br />

farming on the emissions of greenhouse gases are well-known, as shown by<br />

various reports available on this topic. Furthermore, this model based on the<br />

expansion of intensive agriculture, despite generating a lot of wealth and high<br />

production volumes, promotes the disposal of labor – due to the introduction of<br />

mechanization and industrialized inputs – and thereby offers little contribution<br />

to the income generation of the poorest. And, ultimately, this model severely<br />

pressures the environment through its intensive use of natural resources.<br />

However, this is only one side of the coin that reflects the extension, to recent<br />

times, of a rural development paradigm that originated in the post-war era of<br />

the previous century. That which the literature refers to as a new rurality is<br />

gradually emerging, with contours that are significantly different and in which<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

1. This article was written by request from Conservação Internacional (CI-Brasil) and is based<br />

on arguments and excerpts originally published in other works by the author.<br />

2. Sociologist, professor at the Federal University of ABC and researcher at the Brazilian Center<br />

for Analysis and Planning (Cebrap). Email: arilson.favareto@ufabc.edu.br.<br />

3. http://www.unep.org/greeneconomy/<br />

4. http://www.greeneconomycoalition.org/


128<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy<br />

and a new cycle of<br />

rural development<br />

Arilson Favareto<br />

reside great opportunities to inaugurate a new cycle of development that is<br />

compatible with the principles envisaged by a “green economy”.<br />

The objective of this article is to shed light on the contours of this emerging<br />

rurality, whose distinctive trace is the transition from an agrarian and agricultural<br />

paradigm to a paradigm organized around the environmental rooting of rural<br />

development. And also to highlight some important issues for Brazil to accelerate<br />

the transition in the direction of this new model. Thus, there are three sections<br />

that follow this brief introduction. In the first, the contours of the so-called new<br />

rurality are presented. The second, presents a brief table about the current<br />

heterogeneity of Brazilian rural regions and their different forms of economic<br />

inclusion and natural resource use. In the third, some sensitive issues are<br />

recommended for the transition towards a “green economy”.<br />

1. Th e e n v ir o n m e n t a l r o o t s o f n e w r u r a l it y<br />

According to social theory (Abramovay, 2003), there are three fundamental<br />

defining dimensions of rurality: proximity to nature, link to cities, and<br />

interpersonal relations resulting from low population density and the reduced<br />

size of rural populations. What changes in the new stage of rural development,<br />

which emerges through the so-called new rurality, is the social content and the<br />

quality of articulations between these elements.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

With regards to proximity to nature, natural resources that were previously<br />

focused towards the production of primary goods, are now increasingly subject<br />

to new forms of social use, such as for biodiversity conservation, exploiting<br />

the landscape potential of this medium, and the search for renewable energy<br />

sources. Nature is increasingly viewed as fundamental due to its unsubstitutable<br />

capacity to provide the environmental services necessary for human existence:<br />

closing the loop of certain chemicals that would be harmful to health, regulating<br />

the climate, and forming watersheds, among others. Concerning relation to<br />

cities, rural spaces have stopped being mere exporters of primary goods and<br />

now give space to greater inter-sectoral diversification and integration of their<br />

economies, and consequently dampening and in some cases even inverting<br />

the demographic flows that prevailed in the previous phase. Interpersonal<br />

relations, ultimately, no longer rely on relative homogeneity and isolation,<br />

characteristics traditionally associated with rural areas, but are now structured by<br />

growing individualization and heterogenization. This is a movement compatible<br />

with greater physical mobility, with the development of information technology<br />

and communications, with the new population profile and with the growing<br />

integration between markets that were previously more clearly dichotomized<br />

into the rural and urban – markets for goods and services, but also the job<br />

market and the market for symbolic goods (Favareto, 2007). This qualitative<br />

change can be better understood through rapid exposure, based on examples<br />

from international experiences.


129<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy<br />

and a new cycle of<br />

rural development<br />

Arilson Favareto<br />

One of the main books about rural development in the contemporary world<br />

is devoted to the analysis of the US context - “Rural Development in the<br />

United States”, by Galston and Baehler (1995). The authors highlight how<br />

the comparative advantages of rural areas have changed over the course of<br />

North American history. During the first extended phase of shaping the North<br />

American territory, the great comparative advantage was the availability of<br />

primary products: timber, coal, minerals and agricultural products. The search<br />

for these resources guided the occupation of land and represented the principal<br />

source of work and wealth for a long time.<br />

Obviously, with the passing of time the importance of this production<br />

decreased relative to other economic activities, both in terms of people<br />

employed and wealth generated. Technological innovation and the emergence<br />

of cities triggered a diversification in the productive base, with the growing<br />

development of transformation and service activities. In this phase, rural<br />

spaces have cheap labor and land, coupled with aspects such as lower levels<br />

of taxation and unionization, as factors attracting industries and investment.<br />

The main advantage becomes location, since the exploitation of these less<br />

onerous factors in rural areas was only feasible because of the distance from<br />

the more dynamic centers, which compensated for the transportation costs.<br />

However, similar to how technological advances allow for lowered production<br />

costs and the introduction of techniques that save labor in agriculture, the<br />

same thing happens in the manufacturing sector. Thus, dynamism becomes<br />

concentrated in the tertiary sector. Over the last two decades of the previous<br />

century, the counties that offered the most services related to the exploitation of<br />

rural amenities – natural or cultivated landscapes, pure air, clean water, cultural<br />

attractions – where those that presented greatest growth. Exceptions include<br />

places with very unique forms of investment such as casinos, prisons, or post<br />

distribution centers. However, for obvious reasons this type of investment cannot<br />

form the basis for a strategy to be recommended for rural areas.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

In the case of Italy, as presented by Veiga (2006), there is an evident<br />

contrast between rural areas that essentially depend on income obtained from<br />

the export of primary goods, eventually industrialized, and others where the<br />

economy is grounded in the movements of income generated and obtained in<br />

the cities. This division encounters a certain relation to natural characteristics,<br />

such as relief, with plains and plateaus being characteristic of the first case and<br />

proximity to hills and mountains the second. This division seems to have been<br />

directly influenced by a whole range of phenomena related to tourism, which<br />

in turn is narrowly determined by increases in free time and income, and as a<br />

consequence also by an increase in leisure activities by growing social tiers.<br />

In addition to natural heritage conservation, which is at the root of this type of<br />

phenomenon, and economic exploitation of amenities, whose main expression<br />

is tourism activity, the same study also shows that there is a third valuation<br />

vector of rurality: the exploitation of new energy sources.


130<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy<br />

and a new cycle of<br />

rural development<br />

Arilson Favareto<br />

Of course agriculture of commodities continues to carry great weight in<br />

shaping rural spaces, and tertiary activities will always exist in this ambit.<br />

What Galston and Baehler (1995) and Veiga (2006) point out is the growing<br />

emphasis on this second set, as much in terms of people employed as in<br />

wealth generated, but mainly in bringing something new to institutions linked<br />

to rural development: the growing importance of nature and values that are<br />

not directly monetized.<br />

In this context of changing comparative advantages, one inescapable<br />

conclusion is that not all rural areas have the same conditions for attempting<br />

a development process based on the exploitation of its amenities. Low<br />

population density, which is characteristic of these areas, complicates economic<br />

diversification. The demographic profile and the characteristics of the social<br />

fabric, mainly of stagnant rural areas or those that loose population are different:<br />

there is a vulnerability to external social ties, lack of local opportunities, low<br />

expectations of social mobility or increased interactions. Distance from urban<br />

centers can also turn into a disadvantage through increased information and<br />

transportation costs.<br />

Therefore, coupled with the emphasis on the specific attributes of these<br />

territories, the available literature draws equal attention to the form of inclusion of<br />

these locations in the extralocal space (Jacobs, 1984; Veltz, 2003), or as some<br />

authors prefer, in the relation of rural regions with cities or other parts of the<br />

world. From this perspective, it is the city economy that shapes the economy in<br />

rural regions. This takes place through the exports of primary products, through<br />

the attraction of transformation activities, or through the capture of income from<br />

urban sectors, such as from retirees or professionals in search of a second<br />

home or tourism activities. The fact is, that the closer these relations are, the<br />

greater the chance for prosperity.<br />

However, for areas located outside this proximity, there is no need to be<br />

fatalistic. It is possible to create a link between rural regions and a network of<br />

cities, or to constitute a network of cities in a rural region. This can be done<br />

by investing in communication and transport, to diminish distances, through<br />

a kind of territorial division of labor between small sites, in order to overcome<br />

necessities that would have to be fulfilled in urban centers. Or even through<br />

generating local centers for growth by forming cities that can meet these<br />

necessities. In any of these possibilities, the key word is diversification. That<br />

is what guarantees the supply of the local population, which creates the<br />

conditions for introducing innovations and the adaptation of these territories to<br />

the pressures and opportunities of general economic changes.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Implications for development<br />

These changes, which have already been on course since the last quarter<br />

of the 20th century in countries of advanced capitalism, have been noticed


131<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy<br />

and a new cycle of<br />

rural development<br />

Arilson Favareto<br />

by multilateral organizations and government agencies, and transformed into<br />

reorientations for policy design. The wear on agricultural policy by exclusively<br />

sectoral biases arose in the middle of the 1980s and made space for a series<br />

of reforms and debates on “The future of the rural world”, the title of a European<br />

Commission Declaration to Parliament in 1988. An indisputable mark on this<br />

changing vision was the creation of the “Leader Program – Links between<br />

Actions for the Development of the Rural Economy” in 1991, which to this day<br />

is the primary reference for territorial rural development programs. However, the<br />

best synopses of planning agency perceptions of these changes were expressed<br />

on two occasions, in the middle of the 1990’s: the well-known Cork Declaration,<br />

which resulted from the conference Rural Europe – future perspectives, and<br />

the workshop “Post-industrial rural development: the role of natural resources<br />

and the environment”. At these events, a basic consensus was reached about<br />

advanced rurality, synthesized in Box 1 below.<br />

These events gave rise to a progressive transition in the design and the<br />

institutional location of rural development policies. Policies began shifting<br />

from a basically sectoral vision to what is conventionally referred to as a<br />

territorial approach to rural development. This is an approach that intends to<br />

overcome the rigid separation between rural and urban and support itself on<br />

the complementarities between these two spaces (Veiga, 2000; Abramovay,<br />

2003; Favareto, 2007). As a result, the emphasis of agricultural policy began<br />

to make space for a growing approximation to regional development policy.<br />

Box 1<br />

Basic consensus, in the middle of the 1990’s, on advanced rurality<br />

1. Rural zones, that encompass the residencies of one quarter of the<br />

European population and more than more than a fifth of North American<br />

people, and more than 80% of both territories, are characterized by<br />

singular cultural, economic and social fabrics, an extraordinary mosaic<br />

of activities and a great variety of landscapes (forests and agricultural<br />

land, unharmed natural sites, villages and small towns, regional centers,<br />

small industries, etc.).<br />

2. Rural zones, as well as their inhabitants, represent an authentic<br />

wealth in their regions and countries, and can be highly competitive.<br />

3. Most of European and North American rural spaces are constituted<br />

by agricultural land and forests that strongly influence the landscape<br />

character.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

4. Given that agriculture will certainly persist as an important interface<br />

between society and the environment, farmers should increasingly<br />

exercise management functions over various natural resources and rural<br />

territories.


132<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy<br />

and a new cycle of<br />

rural development<br />

Arilson Favareto<br />

5. However, agriculture and forests no longer play predominant roles in<br />

national economies. With the declining relative weight of their economies,<br />

rural development should more than ever before involve all socio-economic<br />

sectors in rural zones.<br />

6. As European and North American citizens increasingly value quality<br />

of life in general, and in particular issues related to health, safety, personal<br />

development and leisure, rural regions occupy privileged positions to<br />

satisfy such interests and offer ample possibilities for authentically modern<br />

and high-quality development.<br />

7. Agricultural policies should adapt to the new realities and challenges<br />

posed as much by the demands and preferences of consumers as by the<br />

evolution in international trade; an adaptation that principally propels the<br />

transition from a system of price support to a system of direct support.<br />

8. The subsidies established by the respective agricultural policies are<br />

increasingly criticized. And it is already widely accepted that government<br />

financial support should be increasingly conditioned on adequate natural<br />

resource management and on maintaining and strengthening biodiversity<br />

and cultural landscapes.<br />

9. The agricultural policy reforms during the first half of the 1990’s<br />

maintained inconsistencies, duplications and legal complexities, despite<br />

undeniable advances in terms of transparency and efficiency.<br />

10. It has become absolutely necessary to promote local sustainable<br />

development capabilities in rural zones, in particular private and community<br />

initiatives that are integrated with global markets.<br />

Reproduced from: Veiga (2004)<br />

2. An d in Br a z il?<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The main medium and long term tendency that manifests itself today in<br />

Brazilian rural regions can be summarized in two statements: here, as in all<br />

countries with advanced capitalism, agriculture has a declining tendency both<br />

in generating income for farming families and in providing employment; and<br />

due to a series of reasons, rural regions no longer experience a general exodus<br />

but rather a heterogenization in their demographic profiles, such as increased<br />

schooling and social differentiation. The result of this tendency in Brazil as<br />

well, has been a change in the comparative advantage of rural regions through<br />

declines in the dynamic and inclusive potential of more traditional activities linked<br />

to strengthening the agricultural and livestock farming sector, and increases in<br />

the potential of new activities related to the exploitation of biodiversity and its


133<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy<br />

and a new cycle of<br />

rural development<br />

Arilson Favareto<br />

landscape potential, resulting in a new structure of income generation in these<br />

regions. However, this is a potential that has not been realized as expected<br />

or suggested in the new rurality literature. In a different way, the tendencies<br />

and potentials of the new phase of rural development experience multifaceted<br />

manifestations.<br />

Unfortunately, due to the inherent limitations in the organization of Brazilian<br />

statistical data, there is no good reading available about these dynamics on a<br />

micro-regional scale. Brazilian rural regions can be categorized schematically<br />

into four types. Each one of these types experiences a unique development<br />

path, with which the generation of innovations aimed at a more sustainable<br />

model necessarily need to dialogue.<br />

The first type covers rural regions where a certain model of urbanization<br />

associated with morphological territorial characteristics such as the environment<br />

and social stratification, favored the creation of a social form of natural resource<br />

use in which the search for conservation meets correspondents in the forms<br />

of dynamics of social life. There, the diversified local economy relies on a high<br />

degree of economic integration and territorial cohesion. Landscape, culture and<br />

the economy interlace in a way that associates economic dynamism with good<br />

social indicators and positive progress in environmental indicators. Something<br />

similar occurs in regions such as Vale do Itajaí, in the state of Santa Catarina<br />

(Southern Brazil). These regions combine a rurality grounded in environmental<br />

factors with a more diversified and decentralized social structure. In these<br />

areas, investment in innovations should favor the dissemination of the currently<br />

embryonic economic activities that utilize local natural resources for activities<br />

such as tourism or the management of these resources.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

In the second type, however – beyond the morphological territorial<br />

characteristics that, with respect to the environment, favor conservation –<br />

the characteristics of social stratification do not contribute to the creation of<br />

institutions capable of diminishing the fractures among social groups due to<br />

social positions. Conservation finds itself in conflict with the possibilities of give<br />

dynamism to local life. The urbanization model is still incipient or heading in a<br />

direction where there is no valuation of the rural. This is the typical case of certain<br />

areas of the Amazon (Northern Brazil), where the forest coexists with advances<br />

in business agriculture. The local social structures do not exhibit vigor nor<br />

sufficient patterns of interaction to confront the expansion of primary activities,<br />

resulting in biodiversity loss and the depletion of natural resources such as<br />

land and water. There is a high degree of conflict between institutions, which<br />

greatly affects local populations. These regions combine a rurality grounded<br />

in environmental factors with more specialized and concentrated social<br />

structures. In these areas, investments in innovation should favor economic<br />

activities with larger economies of scale that are already based on new patterns<br />

of natural resource use, and the creation of local productive arrangements


134<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy<br />

and a new cycle of<br />

rural development<br />

Arilson Favareto<br />

capable of increasing the participation of small and medium enterprises, for<br />

example creating arrangements aimed at processing forest products through<br />

sustainable methods.<br />

In the third type, morphological territorial characteristics in environmental<br />

and social terms engender a relation between exploitation and the rural,<br />

under restricted conservation possibilities and greater risks of fraying social<br />

fabrics, despite the possible economic dynamism in the primary sector and<br />

of transformation. Regions that experience an accentuated and dependent<br />

dynamism of agricultural activities fit into this type. The wealth generated in<br />

these regions establishes a relation between the municipal territorial center<br />

and the others, where all resources are concentrated and do not result in<br />

wealth spreading across a set of social groups. Environmental conservation<br />

possibilities are restricted to the minimum required by law, such as cases of<br />

preserving remnants, riparian forests and hill top vegetation. Local biodiversity<br />

is greatly compromised or threatened by a forceful expansion of commercial<br />

agriculture. In the case of more dynamic regions, such as some rural areas<br />

in the state of São Paulo (Southeastern Brazil), patterns of urbanization offer<br />

reasonable but concentrated infrastructure and services. In other less dynamic<br />

regions, sectoral specialization and rigid social structures lead to a pattern in<br />

which insecurity prevails, as is the case in the cacao regions of Bahia or the<br />

Pernambuco Zona da Mata (Northeastern Brazil). In these areas, there is a<br />

combination of a sectoral rurality with more specialized and concentrated<br />

social structures. In these regions, investment in innovation should favor<br />

economic diversification and the creation of arrangements favorable to small and<br />

medium enterprises, always with special incentives for adopting less intensive<br />

and polluting practices of natural resource use.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The fourth type is shaped by situations where, despite morphological territorial<br />

characteristics not being as promising with regards to natural resources, social<br />

structures can favor a process of change and the creation of new institutions.<br />

However, forms of economic domination impede or block this innovation. There<br />

are fissures between the sectoral and the environmental, and between social<br />

groups. An example of this type of territory is the western part of the state of<br />

Santa Catarina (Southern of Brazil). A concentration of large agroindustrial<br />

businesses coexists with a social structure based on a significant group of<br />

family farmers. The region exhibits reasonable economic dynamics, but not<br />

very good social and inequality indicators. The reproductive possibilities of local<br />

social groups depend greatly on extra-local links, which favor a loss of valuable<br />

human resources. As such, the possibility of creating greater interactions<br />

and new institutions capable of changing towards territorial development is<br />

impeded. These regions combine sectoral rurality with more diversified and<br />

deconcentrated social structures. Here, investment in innovations should<br />

favor above all, the diversification of economic activities and a new model of<br />

natural resource use.


135<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy<br />

and a new cycle of<br />

rural development<br />

Arilson Favareto<br />

As you can see, for each type of ongoing development dynamic, a determined<br />

contribution to activities to promote innovation should be constructed. However,<br />

this contribution is not the only element that can be mobilized to influence these<br />

dynamics, to invert them when negative and strengthen them when positive.<br />

There are various ongoing projects and investments that could be made more<br />

useful for countryside regions in Brazil. Despite low investments in research<br />

and development - Brazil exhibits current levels similar to Spain and Italy, but<br />

proportionally is more distant from countries such as South Korea, Germany,<br />

Japan and the United States - there are various projects and programs currently<br />

being executed by the federal government that could favor the urgency of the<br />

suggested economic activities. Just as an example, the federal government<br />

has made important investments in tourism through the Tourism Development<br />

Program, which could reach into these rural regions thanks to their environmental<br />

and cultural attractions. Similarly, the Ministry of Development, Industry and<br />

International Commerce has supported industrial decentralization, incentives<br />

from which countryside regions could benefit as long as environmental criteria<br />

are also introduced. The same is true for investments in biotechnology.<br />

Nevertheless, the existence of these opportunities does not guarantee<br />

their realization. Nor is there the allocation of resources that could favor the<br />

introduction of innovations or support for enterprises in rural regions aimed<br />

at realizing these opportunities. It is worth highlighting again that these<br />

opportunities form an environment that could be extremely favorable to starting<br />

a new cycle of development in rural areas of Brazil. It is fundamental to adopt as<br />

guiding principle the strengthening of a “new rurality economy” while recognizing<br />

the heterogeneity of rural regions, be it through promoting the adoption of new<br />

agricultural production practices such as organic production or less intensive<br />

and more conservationist technologies, through tourism activities, or in attracting<br />

new populations interested in maintaining environmental amenities, be it<br />

utilizing the great productive potential of biodiversity and biomass, through<br />

the production of for example biofuels or through the industrial exploitation of<br />

chemical, pharmaceutical or cosmetic products.<br />

3. Id e a s f o r a n a g e n d a<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Clearly, a variety of these new activities could be strengthened, and even<br />

so, increase pressures on the environment. Brazilian production of ethanol is<br />

one example: there is a utilization of biomass, but concomitantly, the production<br />

techniques and the weight of monoculture negatively pressure biodiversity and<br />

necessary natural resources such as land and water. As such, it is not only<br />

about promoting new activities in rural regions, but especially how to administer<br />

them. Similarly, this does not necessarily lead to inclusion of the poorest. Again,<br />

we can use the example of biofuels, this time biodiesel: despite an innovative<br />

design introducing a Social Seal for businesses that purchase raw materials


136<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Green economy<br />

and a new cycle of<br />

rural development<br />

Arilson Favareto<br />

from family farmers, at least during their first years of existence, the program<br />

did not succeed in including producers from the poorest regions and saw the<br />

incentives being captured by the most consolidated sectors of family agriculture,<br />

which explains the predominance of soya – produced by farmers in the Midwest<br />

and the South – as a primary raw material instead of castor or palm from the<br />

Northeast, as was initially envisioned. As such, the topic of transition to a new<br />

model or a new paradigm is not trivial.<br />

It is fundamental to recognize that formal and informal institutions – incentives,<br />

cultural patterns, programs and policies – present a bias where the inertia of<br />

the old paradigm is always present. There can be various items comprising<br />

an agenda compatible with the contours of a “new rurality economy”, which in<br />

turn is consistent with the idea of a “green economy”. Here we mention only<br />

three of them.<br />

The first is the introduction of a vigorous innovation policy aimed at<br />

exploiting biomass and biodiversity and the promotion of new production<br />

systems that are less intensive in natural resource use and less polluting.<br />

Brazil has enormous potential in this area and relies on research institutes<br />

with decades of experience and international excellence. Though, in spite<br />

of this potential, little has been done compared to the production of science,<br />

technology and innovation aimed at the old rurality, or the productivist model<br />

that is highly intensive in natural resource use. Without this, these new activities<br />

continue being niche markets and not the base of a new cycle – as is the current<br />

case of biodiversity products – or they ambiguously constitute themselves<br />

by substituting non-renewable for renewable resources but at a significant<br />

environmental cost – as in the case of biofuels.<br />

The second is the adoption of a system of incentives aimed at expanding<br />

economic activities based on new forms of social use of natural resources.<br />

The economies of scale of old activities and the transition costs involved in<br />

adopting new forms of natural resource use need to be compensated by a<br />

policy of incentives that stimulates social agents in adopting new technologies<br />

and exploiting new markets, where short term gains through intensive resource<br />

use and the depletion of natural resources makes space for activities that favor<br />

long term gains as in environmental conservation, maintaining biodiversity and<br />

the provision of environmental services.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The third item on the agenda, not any less important than the previous two, is<br />

the formation of coalitions of actors and interests consistent with these new<br />

activities and modalities of natural resource use. The actors of the old rurality<br />

are known – businesses in the agricultural food sector and organizations of rich<br />

and poor farmers. To these, it will be necessary to add more segments, detainers<br />

of other interests and above all, the social skills necessary to strengthen the<br />

paths towards a transition of paradigms. Thus, it is necessary to create new<br />

spaces for interacting with and influencing the shaping of policy.


137<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

As you can see, these are not simple tasks. However, these tasks are<br />

challenges that must be addressed to enable the transition to a green economy<br />

where environmental conservation can be added to the life-styles of much of<br />

society.<br />

Green economy<br />

and a new cycle of<br />

rural development<br />

Arilson Favareto<br />

References<br />

Abramovay, R. (2003). O futuro das regiões rurais. Porto Alegre: Ed. da UFRGS.<br />

Favareto, A. (2007). Paradigmas do desenvolvimento rural em questão. São Paulo:<br />

Fapesp/Edusp.<br />

Galston, W. A. and Baehler, K. J. (1995). Rural development in the United States:<br />

connecting theory, practice and possibilities. Washington D.C.: Island Press.<br />

Jacobs, J. (1984). Cities and the wealth of nations. London: Penguin Books.<br />

Veiga, J. E. (2000). A face rural do desenvolvimento – natureza, território e agricultura.<br />

Porto Alegre: Ed. UFRGS.<br />

Veiga, J. E. (2004). Destinos da ruralidade no processo de globalização. Estudos<br />

Avançados, 51, May-August, 51-67.<br />

Veiga, J. E. (2006). Nascimento de outra ruralidade. Estudos Avançados, 20(57).<br />

Veltz, P. (2003). Des lieux et des liens. Paris: Ed. de l´aube.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011


138<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Deforestation of the<br />

Brazilian Amazon rainforest:<br />

causes and solutions<br />

Bastiaan Philip Reydon 1<br />

1. In t r o d u c t io n<br />

The debate over the deforestation problem in the Amazon rainforest, which<br />

has been expressed, for instance, in the debates over changes to the Forest<br />

Code, has been characterized by its superficiality and ideological character.<br />

Initially, there is a necessity to clearly identify the process, and then look for its<br />

causes, and finally to think of solutions for the short, medium and long terms.<br />

It is undeniable that the forceful command and control policies 2 and economic<br />

incentives 3 implemented over recent years had a crucial role in reducing<br />

deforestation. As they depend on the direct intervention of the State, these<br />

policies are difficult to maintain in the long term, mainly because the principal<br />

productive causes of deforestation – from livestock and grain production to<br />

energy production – persist, and enduring solutions must be found.<br />

The central objective of this work is to demonstrate that the definitive solution<br />

to this problem necessarily passes through the solution to the country´s land<br />

tenure problems, which consist mainly of the Brazilian state assuming in<br />

conjunction with the nation the effective governance over land ownership.<br />

First, this article presents a brief description of the main causes of<br />

deforestation identified in the literature on this topic. Then it is shown how<br />

two problems that appear only marginally in the literature are, combined, the<br />

main determinants of deforestation of the rainforest: land speculation through<br />

the very clearing of the land and the absence of land governance. The fourth<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

1. Full Professor at Agricultural and Environmental Economics Center of the Institute of<br />

Economics at the State University of Campinas (NEAA/IE/UNICAMP), technical advisor in<br />

sustainability at the Innovation Agency (Unicamp) and consultant at the International Bank for<br />

Reconstruction and Development (World Bank) and at FAO. E-mail: basrey@eco.unicamp.br.<br />

2. The main command and control policies, direct state interventions to modify deforestation<br />

behaviors, were: a) operations Curupira (2005) and Arco de Fogo (2008) that combated<br />

illegal logging; b) decree 6321/07, which restricts credit approval by banks and obligate<br />

landowners in municipalities with high deforestation rates to re-register; c) the creation<br />

of up to 20 million hectares of Conservation Units (Brazilian protected areas) in addition<br />

to the already existing 80 million, totaling 273 CUs; d) approval of 87 Indigenous Lands<br />

and approximately 18 million hectares; and e) restrictions on agricultural products from<br />

municipalities with high deforestation rates.<br />

3. The economic incentives policies that use economic mechanisms (price and others) to<br />

encourage or discourage economic actors to diminish deforestation, were as follows: a)<br />

Arco Verde operation (2008); and b) a special credit line related to the Constitutional Fund<br />

for Financing of the North , the Constitutional Fund for Financing of the Northeast and the<br />

Constitutional Fund for Financing of the Midwest for the recuperation of degraded areas,<br />

reforestation, environmental management and compliance in the Legal Amazon.


139<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

item historically analyzes the formation of the institutional framework that lead<br />

to the absence of regulation in land markets. Ultimately, in the last section, in<br />

addition to arguing for the necessity of effective governance of land ownership,<br />

the main implantation mechanisms are demonstrated as well as the benefits<br />

generated.<br />

Deforestation of<br />

the Brazilian Amazon<br />

rainforest: causes<br />

and solutions<br />

Bastiaan Reydon<br />

2. De f o r e s t a t i o n a n d i t s m a in c a u s e s<br />

According to FAO (2010), “Brazil lost an average of 2.6 million hectares of<br />

forest per year over the past 10 years, compared to an average annual loss<br />

of 2.9 million during the 1990’s; in Indonesia the losses were 500 thousand<br />

hectares over the period 2000-2010 and 1.9 million hectares over the period<br />

1990-2000.”<br />

Diagram 1 illustrates deforestation in the Amazon based on satellite images,<br />

demonstrating that deforestation in recent years shifted around 6.4 and 7.4<br />

million hectares, which represents a substantial improvement although still a<br />

highly elevated level of deforestation for a biome with the characteristics of<br />

the Amazon. With the forest still standing, this biome possesses great wealth<br />

in its elevated biodiversity, its importance in regulating the planet’s climate, its<br />

production of freshwater and poor soil for agro pastoral activities.<br />

Diagram 1. Deforestation in the Legal Amazon<br />

Annual deforestation rate in the Legal Amazon<br />

Source: PRODES (2011)<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Km 2 / year<br />

Year


140<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Deforestation of<br />

the Brazilian Amazon<br />

rainforest: causes<br />

and solutions<br />

Bastiaan Reydon<br />

The question remains: how to derail an increase in deforestation rates<br />

and further, how to significantly reduce rates? Deforestation in the Amazon<br />

rainforest is a complex process with multiple determinants, and the object of<br />

many theoretical and empirical studies 4 . Margulis (2000:9) affirms that:<br />

“We do not believe there is a principal force that alone propels or explains<br />

deforestation in the Amazon. The causes are varied and result from a<br />

sophisticated combination of diverse variables and factors”.<br />

The principal groups of variables that induce deforestation, present in<br />

Margulis (2000) and the greater part of the literature are:<br />

a) gains associated with the use of Amazon land – determined by agricultural<br />

prices, increases in land prices, variations in input prices, increases in timber<br />

prices and a decrease in rural salaries;<br />

b) public policies and credit – the availability of affordable credit resources<br />

(Amazon Investment Fund, Constitutional Fund for Financing of the North)<br />

and policies of fiscal incentives (Superintendence of Development for the<br />

Amazon);<br />

c) accessibility – the construction of roads and/or other works that facilitate<br />

access to frontier areas;<br />

d) macroeconomics – growth cycles of GDP, population growth.<br />

Insofar as these four groupings of variables have interfered directly with<br />

deforestation in the Amazon, it can be said that after the recent interventions and<br />

the 2008/9 crisis, all were having positive impacts on deforestation, but even so<br />

deforestation increased. On the other hand, even during periods in which these<br />

variables did not grow, deforestation grew. This implies that there are other more<br />

profound factors whose relative importance has not been highlighted.<br />

3. De f o r e s t a t i o n a n d l a n d s p e c u l a t io n<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

In our understanding, deforestation in the Amazon results from the continued<br />

traditional practice of expanding the Brazilian agricultural frontier, that generally<br />

occurs in the following stages: occupation of virgin lands (private or public),<br />

extraction of its hardwood, installation of livestock farming 5 , and ultimately, the<br />

development of more modern farming practices. These economic activities<br />

play the role of generating income and legitimizing occupation of new lands<br />

in the short term, almost without a necessity for resources 6 . In the long term,<br />

the lands either remain under more intensive livestock farming, or if there is<br />

demand, are converted to grain farming or other economic activities.<br />

4. For an exhaustive revision, see Soares Filho et al. (2005).<br />

5. Reydon and Romeiro (2000) demonstrate that the primary engine of the spread of livestock<br />

farming is, on the one hand, the existence of much vacant land to be appropriated, coupled<br />

with the possibility of, at low costs, installing farming, turning deforestation into an unbeatable<br />

strategy of capital appreciation.<br />

6. These same occupants are the ones that frequently are used as slave labor.


141<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Deforestation of<br />

the Brazilian Amazon<br />

rainforest: causes<br />

and solutions<br />

Bastiaan Reydon<br />

However, what matters is the expectation that there will be demand for the<br />

land 7 , to be used at some time in the future, which ensures that prices rise<br />

significantly. And the closer the physical location of the land is to regions that<br />

permit productive use, the greater the price. The appreciation of these lands<br />

occurs as expectations rise.<br />

In the various studies by Margulis (2000 and 2003) and the already cited<br />

literature, the issue of land speculation appears, but is normally associated with<br />

increases in the price of land. However, increases in the price of land do not<br />

necessarily imply that a speculation process is taking place. As a matter of fact,<br />

the price of land in the Northern region grossly follows the price movements<br />

of land in the rest of the country, and thereby not generating great speculative<br />

gains.<br />

Land speculation is, as this article proposes, the main engine of deforestation<br />

in the Amazon rainforest, though it takes on a much more microeconomic<br />

appearance and is associated with the actual occupation of the land, and<br />

could be perceived much more clearly through field research. What happens<br />

in reality, is that any person that acquires or occupies forested land has a clear<br />

perception that his or her land, or investment, appreciates in value through the<br />

process of deforestation. In table 1 8 it can be observed that the price of forested<br />

land in the different states varies between R$108 in Acre and R$546 in Mato<br />

Grosso. It can also be observed that the land prices in the less deforested<br />

states are lower, while the states of Mato Grosso, Pará and Rondônia have<br />

more elevated prices.<br />

The most important conclusion though drawn from the table is that in all<br />

states deforestation always significantly appreciates the value of the property,<br />

that is, on an average across the states deforestation more than quadruples<br />

the land value. This occurs because the land price is fundamentally the result<br />

of the expected productive gains through the associated livestock farming,<br />

since on deforested land this use can take place immediately and without the<br />

costs of deforestation.<br />

In the most extreme case, as in Acre, deforestation multiplies this value by<br />

a factor of 14, while in the Amazon state land value multiplies by a factor of 10.<br />

Few investments have returns as elevated as these.<br />

One must take into account that these properties, beyond the capital gains<br />

from deforestation, also gain from selling the timber (in Cotriguaçú, a city in<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

7. This is due to the increase in price of fed cattle, soya, or even the announcement that the<br />

country will be the largest ethanol producer in the world. In the recent period these factors<br />

converged, resulting in an even greater increase in the demand for land and consequently<br />

also the price, which puts even more pressure on deforestation.<br />

8. The methodology of agribusiness firm Agra FNP collects average prices in homogeneous<br />

regions in the mentioned states, using non-homogeneous terminology. For the forest land, we<br />

aggregate the types of forest, that of easy access and difficult access. For the pasture land<br />

we utilize the already established pastures (easy and difficult access), already established<br />

pastures of high support and established pastures of low support.


142<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

the Mato Grosso state, the estimated liquid return is R$2,400/ha) and from the<br />

subsequent economic use (which in the case of livestock farming generates<br />

an additional liquid revenue of over R$120 per hectare/year 9 ). Therefore, the<br />

greatest catalyst of deforestation is a combination of gains from appreciated<br />

land values, in the conversion from forest to productive land, coupled with gains<br />

from timber sales and from the subsequently established livestock farming.<br />

Deforestation of<br />

the Brazilian Amazon<br />

rainforest: causes<br />

and solutions<br />

Bastiaan Reydon<br />

Table 1<br />

Average prices of forest and pasture land<br />

States of the Brazilian Amazon - in R$/ha in 2008 prices<br />

STATES Forest R$/ha Pasture R$/ha Variation %<br />

Acre 108.00 1,571.80 1,455.4<br />

Amapá 141.00 800.00 567.4<br />

Amazonas 132.43 1,243.91 939.3<br />

Pará 457.73 1,509.40 329.8<br />

Rondônia 358.50 1,762.50 491.6<br />

Mato Grosso 546.13 2,083.69 381.5<br />

Average NORTH 416.53 1,832.39 439.9<br />

Source: AgraFND (2009)<br />

This process of acquisition and deforestation that is already very profitable<br />

in private areas, becomes even more lucrative for vacant land that according<br />

to estimates 10 , represent 42% of the total Amazon land area, where most of<br />

the deforestation takes place. That is, in the occupation of vacant land, gains<br />

from timber, livestock and land value appreciation are multiplied because the<br />

land itself did not have to be acquired, but rather simply usurped from public<br />

property 11 .<br />

4. Th e o c c u p a t io n o f l a n d in t h e Am a z o n a n d<br />

in s e c u r e p r o p e r t y r i gh t s<br />

The practice of occupation can be attributed to the absence of cadastre<br />

and effective regulation of land properties in Brazil, particularly in the Amazon.<br />

Existing cadastre details, based on declarations from landowners that registered<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

9. See Margulis (2003).<br />

10. Estimate by Shiki (2007) indicates that 42 % of Amazon lands are vacant.<br />

11. Perhaps some expenditures on henchmen, arms, lawyers and licit and illicit costs of<br />

regularization in the area.


143<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Deforestation of<br />

the Brazilian Amazon<br />

rainforest: causes<br />

and solutions<br />

Bastiaan Reydon<br />

through the National Institute of Colonization and Agrarian Reform (INCRA in<br />

Portuguese acronym), demonstrate that in 2003 35% of 509 million hectares of<br />

land in the Legal Amazon were occupied under private tenure rights, whether<br />

as registered properties or occupied land. On the other hand, the recent<br />

process of creating various types of reserves, whether at federal or state level,<br />

has resulted in 42% of the Legal Amazon currently being under some type of<br />

protection; approximately half of these areas are Indigenous Lands and the<br />

other half are Conservation Units of various types. The remaining 24% are not<br />

in either of these categories and consequently are technically considered public<br />

land without allocation (Figure 1).<br />

However, the situation is more complex and uncertain than the numbers imply.<br />

Many of the protected areas are physically occupied by private users, whose<br />

occupation claims may or may not be valid in accordance with the complex<br />

legislation previously presented. The large area classified as private by the<br />

cadastre system is also questionable. Out of the 178 million hectares declared<br />

as private property, 100 million of hectares could be based on fraudulent<br />

documentation. Another 42 million hectares in this area are classified based<br />

on cadastre declarations as occupied, and may or may not be subject to land<br />

regularization, yet again, depending on circumstances such as size, history<br />

and location 12 . Consequently, 30% of the area could be legally uncertain and/<br />

or contested.<br />

Figure 1<br />

Land tenure situation in the Legal Amazon, according to data from the<br />

National System of Rural Cadastre (2003) and protected areas (2006)<br />

Hectares<br />

178.169.518 35%<br />

22.306.963 4%<br />

188.008.904 120.381.458 37%<br />

120.381.458 24%<br />

508.866.843 100%<br />

210.315.867<br />

508.866.843<br />

188.008.904<br />

178.169.518<br />

22.306.963<br />

Posses and<br />

properties proterties in in<br />

Incra´s cadastre<br />

cadaster<br />

Area Environmental for<br />

Environmental<br />

Protection Area<br />

(APA)<br />

Protection (APA)<br />

Protected areas<br />

excludings areas APAs<br />

APAs<br />

Without formal<br />

occupation and<br />

and<br />

non-protected<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Source: Barreto (2008).<br />

12. There are all types of sizes of possessions in the INCRA register: both small ones of less<br />

than 200 ha and those of more than 1,000 ha.


144<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Deforestation of<br />

the Brazilian Amazon<br />

rainforest: causes<br />

and solutions<br />

Bastiaan Reydon<br />

The Brazilian state is so aware of its incapacity to regulate the use of this land,<br />

primarily by not having a cadastre, that it obligated itself to take the following<br />

concrete actions to diminish deforestation in the Amazon and increase land<br />

governance, but always as an emergency measure and without addressing<br />

the root of the problem:<br />

a) Established Law 11.952/09 regularizing occupied land of up to 400 ha at<br />

zero cost and selling occupied land of between 401 and 1,500 ha (squatters<br />

must prove that they have lived on the land since 2004).<br />

b) The government implemented the Legal Land Program, which established<br />

criteria for land regularization in rural areas located on federal lands, in the<br />

Legal Amazon area.<br />

c) Creation of innumerable environmental protection areas (APAs)in the<br />

form of Conservation Units (based on Law 9.985 of July 2000) for protecting<br />

the edges of main roads under construction in the Amazon region to avoid<br />

occupation and deforestation.<br />

The clearest evidence of the incapacity of the Brazilian state in effectively<br />

governing the market for land, is the very formulation of Ordinance 558/99,<br />

applicable to all Brazilian territories and not just the Legal Amazon. There,<br />

INCRA imposed on all landowners with more than 10,000 ha the requirement<br />

of presenting their supporting documentation. Out of the 3,065 landowners<br />

summoned, only 1,438 (46.9%) appeared, resulting in 1,627 properties on 46<br />

million hectares being cancelled 13 . Furthermore, 53% of the area of these lands<br />

were located in the Northern states of Brazil, largely in the Amazon Rainforest.<br />

In the Amazon state alone, according to Lima (2002), the equivalent of 48.5<br />

million hectares of properties in 14 counties were cancelled by the respective<br />

land registration offices (cartórios in Portuguese) at the beginning of 21st<br />

century. There are also academic studies such as Araújo et al. (2008), providing<br />

evidence based on municipal data that uncertain property rights, such as those<br />

in the Amazon, have a positive impact on deforestation.<br />

5. In s t it u t io n a l f r a m e w o r k o f l a n d r e g u l a t io n:<br />

w h y d o l a n d c a d a s t r e a n d g o v e r n a n c e n o t e x i s t<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

This section analyzes the historical formation of the Brazilian institutional<br />

framework, which lead to the absence of regulation in land markets. It will be<br />

demonstrated that many of the characteristics that cause this absence are<br />

legacies from a historical ineptitude of the Brazilian state in relation to land<br />

governance.<br />

Before the Brazilian Land Law (1850), rules for occupying rural and urban<br />

soil were defined by the powers of the king, the church and the political and<br />

13. See Sabato (2001) for more details.


145<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Deforestation of<br />

the Brazilian Amazon<br />

rainforest: causes<br />

and solutions<br />

Bastiaan Reydon<br />

physical powers of occupants. The Land Law should be understood in the<br />

broader context of laws established to restrict land access in the entire colonial<br />

world. 14 To accommodate the interests of the country’s landowners, the Land<br />

Law maintained the possibility of regularizing occupied lands, stemming from<br />

the occupation of vacant lands, which complicated the creation of a cadastre.<br />

That is, there was always the possibility of regularizing occupied lands due to<br />

the occupations of vacant lands. In addition to usucaption (which establishes<br />

that after some years of occupation, the property can be regularized), the very<br />

states (mainly after the Republic) have conceded properties with or without title<br />

at some moments in history. This is the basic mechanism that kept and keeps<br />

an effective cadastre from being established, and that also permits the definition<br />

of vacant lands likely to be utilized by other types of land policies.<br />

Up until the Land Law, properties were basically registered together with<br />

Parochial Land Registers under the responsibility of the local vicar. This register<br />

was utilized for a long time after the Land Law was implemented. In 1864, a<br />

new institutional obligation eventually established a new tradition that persists<br />

to the present day and that has generated greater uncertainty and inability<br />

to effectively regulate the land market: the necessity to register properties,<br />

regardless of having legal ownership rights. To a certain extent, the registration<br />

of land at a registry office gives a certain air of legality to the property, without<br />

any mechanisms to guarantee this 15 .The Proclamation of the Republic in<br />

1889, passed the rights related to vacant lands to states, which led to the<br />

possibility that their representatives would pass them on through the granting<br />

of unregistered titles. This occurred with greater intensity in some states as<br />

compared to others, but irregardless created yet another ambiguity in the<br />

issuance of titles that complicated state regulation of land markets 16 .<br />

The establishment of the Public Land Registry in 1900 is perhaps the principal<br />

step towards the current system of registering land in land register offices. Under<br />

this rule, everyone needs to delimit and register their lands, whether rural or<br />

urban, but without any sort of fee and without cadastre. The state also needs<br />

to delimit and register its lands (vacant), which is impractical since these are<br />

defined by exclusion. As such, the very state acts illegally. This obligation ends<br />

up increasing the possibilities for fraud in land register offices.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

14. As in Latin America, Australia and the United States.<br />

15. The most common irregularities are the issuance of titles to non-existing or vacant<br />

properties and the overlap of several areas, that is, various landowners have title to the same<br />

land. When this happens, it is said that the land has ‘floors’: for each additional owner with an<br />

irregular title to the area another floor is added. The federal government is taking a decisive<br />

step in the regulation of the rural and urban land market by implementing, with difficulties,<br />

Law 10.267/2001, where land register offices are obligated, when there is any change in<br />

ownership, to forward the plan to INCRA with boundaries in cartographic form (latitude and<br />

longitude).<br />

16. Nevertheless, there is the failed attempt at property regulation by Registro Torrens (1891)<br />

where settlers and landowners could obtain definitive titles through non-contested petitions.<br />

And, furthermore, the possibility of legalizing occupied lands in 1895 and 1922 (referring to<br />

the occupied land between 1895 and 1921) ultimately created the conditions for occupied<br />

lands to endure and weakened the regulation of the land market as expressed in the 1850<br />

Land Law.


146<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Deforestation of<br />

the Brazilian Amazon<br />

rainforest: causes<br />

and solutions<br />

Bastiaan Reydon<br />

The promulgation of the 1916 Civil Code generated the capability to regulate<br />

land markets in Brazil, both by reaffirming the land register office as the<br />

registration institution, and enabling the possibility of public lands being objects<br />

of usucaption. In the words of Osório Silva (1996:324), “this completed the<br />

framework for the transformation of the State into a proprietor like the others.<br />

And as such, the doctrine of designation of vacant lands. Or, in other words,<br />

the possibility of usucaption of vacant land”.<br />

Thus, the Civil Code, for reasons not necessarily tied to the interests of<br />

landowners, turned out to establish the institutional corner stones for land<br />

access in Brazil, by defining that registering land in land register offices was<br />

necessary (and at times also sufficient) to prove ownership.<br />

The great institutional innovation in the sphere of Brazilian land policy and<br />

administration is the 1964 Land Statute, whose rules and concepts remain valid<br />

to the present day. Hence, in order to guide the implementation of agrarian<br />

and agricultural policies, the 1964 Statute created the Rural Land Cadastre . All<br />

private and public lands should be registered, including occupied land. Owners<br />

should furnish information on the documentation situation and land-use (to<br />

estimate productivity) for the purpose of facilitating the agrarian reform. INCRA,<br />

created in 1970, became responsible for managing the National System of Rural<br />

Cadastre (CNCR), which maintained the Rural Land Cadastre 17 . Once the land<br />

was registered, INCRA emitted a Rural Land Cadastre Certificate (CCIR) that<br />

was required for any type of transaction of the land. Squatters that registered<br />

with INCRA also received a CCIR and were obligated to pay the Rural Land<br />

Tax, though the amounts of this tax were always kept at low levels. The Land<br />

Statute also maintained the legitimation of occupied lands, thus allowing the<br />

titling of informally occupied public lands.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

17. Since the 1967 cadastre and the posterior re-registrations were implemented for tax<br />

reasons, based on landowner declarations and that were not monitored, they are not very<br />

reliable as the study by Sabato (2001) demonstrated, based on information from Decree<br />

558/98. Other recent attempts to integrate the cadastre of different public agencies to improve<br />

the quality of the information have failed due to the absence of political will and an agency to<br />

assume the role of executing land governance in the country.


147<br />

Scheme 1<br />

Current situation of Land Tenure Administration in Brazil<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Presidency of Republic with<br />

approval from the Legislative<br />

stablish: Conservation Areas and<br />

Indigenous Lands<br />

State governments with<br />

approval from the<br />

Legislative establish: State<br />

Conservation Areas<br />

Deforestation of<br />

the Brazilian Amazon<br />

rainforest: causes<br />

and solutions<br />

Bastiaan Reydon<br />

Registry of Real State: registry offices and<br />

provides legal titles based on sale and acquisition<br />

contracts (consulting only their registrations)<br />

LAW 10.267 – Real State with<br />

notary alterations present<br />

geo-referenced design for registry<br />

AGU –<br />

transfer of<br />

unclaimed<br />

state lands<br />

JUDICIARY – ratifies or<br />

creates titles in decisions of<br />

any type of conflict<br />

MUNICIPALITIES:<br />

decisions about<br />

rural and urban<br />

lands, use, and IPTU<br />

charges, etc.<br />

State Land<br />

Institutes:<br />

responsible for<br />

the state land<br />

INCRA: grants single initial<br />

registration, includes in the cadastre,<br />

grants concession use titles to<br />

settlers, discriminates between<br />

unclaimed lands and colonization<br />

Federal<br />

Revenue<br />

Agency:<br />

charges rural<br />

taxes (ITR)<br />

Settlements of<br />

landless people<br />

Colonization – destination of public<br />

lands to rural subdivisions<br />

Source: Legislation in force and Reydon (2006).<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Diagram 2 seeks to synthesize the interrelations between agencies of the<br />

land administration system in Brazil. We see that there is no link between INCRA<br />

and municipalities, leading to many land problems on the borders between<br />

rural and urban lands. Furthermore, there is no institution that centralizes<br />

cadastre and makes a link to the Judicial agencies that are responsible for<br />

issuing land titles. Though not evident from the diagram, a large proportion of<br />

land problems in Brazil, both rural and urban, which are not properly resolved<br />

in the administrative sphere, end up in the judiciary. As the judiciary has many<br />

processes throughout its tribunals, it ends up taking years to issue rulings, which<br />

results in land-related cases, whether rural or urban, almost always being ruled<br />

as historical fact. Therefore, the great problem of deforestation in the Amazon is<br />

associated with the lack of land governance in the country, which results from<br />

a historical process of formation of institutional and legal frameworks that are<br />

unsuitable for this end. Only through the construction of an institution aimed at<br />

land governance and adjusting the Brazilian legal framework to this end, will<br />

there be adequate land-use and a decrease in deforestation in this country.


148<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Deforestation of<br />

the Brazilian Amazon<br />

rainforest: causes<br />

and solutions<br />

Bastiaan Reydon<br />

6. Th e n e c e s s i t y o f l a n d g o v e r n a n c e 18 a s a<br />

n e c e s s a r y c o n d it io n t o r e d u c e d e f o r e s t a t io n<br />

Brazilian agriculture presents exemplary accomplishments, with growth<br />

in food production, supply of energy and foreign exchange, and greater<br />

international insertion, among others. However, security as relates to land<br />

ownership remains a great problem, especially in the Amazon. The solution<br />

requires adequate and participative land governance, according to among<br />

others FAO (2007) and Doelinger et al. (2010).<br />

The benefits to be gained from an adequate system of territorial management<br />

depend on clearly identifying unregistered lands and a simple and effective<br />

mechanism for obtaining and updating this information. This process needs<br />

to start without being dependent on information related to land titles and other<br />

types of formal documents, which can always be used in cases of ownership<br />

conflicts. This should begin with a process of title issuance that conciliates<br />

property information based on satellite images 19 and a survey of landowners and<br />

legitimate squatters (posse mansa in Portuguese). The effective participation<br />

of landowners and squatters, according to a study by Gessa (2008), requires<br />

that landowners, in particular the smaller ones, receive actual knowledge and<br />

“empowerment” 20 .<br />

Only through effective land governance, in particular the creation of a modern<br />

and self powered cadastre, will it be possible to:<br />

a) Guarantee private property rights for different purposes: business,<br />

leasing, guarantees for obtaining credit, for the concession of payments for<br />

environmental services, among others;<br />

b) Identify public land and guarantee its adequate use for: the creation of<br />

reserves, settlements or colonization;<br />

c) Establish the other land policies with more security: agrarian reform, land<br />

credit, land taxes;<br />

d) Regulate the process for purchasing land to: limit access to foreigners,<br />

large landowners or other types of landowners;<br />

e) Zone land uses – establish and regulate limits based on zoning for<br />

agricultural production and livestock farming in certain regions. Establish<br />

protected areas and areas prohibiting deforestation;<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

18. FAO (2008:9) works with an adequate definition of land governance: “Governance is the<br />

system of values, policies, and institutions by which a society manages its economic, political<br />

and social affairs through its interactions within and among the state, civil society and private<br />

sector. Land governance concerns the rules, processes and organizations through which<br />

decisions are made about access to land and its use, the manner in which the decisions are<br />

implemented, and the way that competing interest in land are managed.”<br />

19. The technical innovations of gathering information from satellite images, according to<br />

Doelinger et. Al. (2010), allow advances that can revolutionize the cadastre system of existing<br />

properties.<br />

20. Based on a study by Gessa (2008), which proposes mapping as an important instrument to<br />

secure property rights and create empowerment of less privileged populations in regions with<br />

insecure property rights.


149<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Deforestation of<br />

the Brazilian Amazon<br />

rainforest: causes<br />

and solutions<br />

Bastiaan Reydon<br />

f) Regulate conversion processes of agricultural to urban lands and to have<br />

a cadastre for levying property taxes (Urban Building and Land Tax and Tax<br />

on Rural Property);<br />

Land governance does not resolve the issue of deforestation in the Amazon,<br />

but is a necessary condition to confront this problem. In the case of vacant<br />

lands, by permitting the identification and possession by the State of these<br />

lands, the cadastre would greatly hinder inappropriate private occupation and<br />

deforestation. The cadastre would also enable the utilization of these vacant<br />

lands in the execution of Brazilian land policy, through organized colonization,<br />

agrarian reform and others.<br />

In the case of private lands, effective participative governance, based on<br />

understanding the context, discussing priorities for land use and determining<br />

adequate monitoring, permits planning and the regulation of land use, through<br />

zoning and other coercive instruments. Effective governance also impedes<br />

deforestation and certainly limits land speculation, which is the principal cause<br />

of deforestation.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

References<br />

AGRAFNP (2010). Relatório de análise do mercado de terras. São Paulo.<br />

Araujo, C. et al. (2008). Property rights and deforestation in the Brazilian Amazon.<br />

CERDI. Etude et Documents, E2008.20. Retrieved from: <br />

in 18/05/11.<br />

Barreto, P (2008). Quem é dono da Amazônia? Belém: IMAZON. Retrieved from: in 18/05/11.<br />

Deininger, K. (2003). Land policies for growth and poverty reduction. Washington: World<br />

Bank and Oxford University Press.<br />

Deininger, K. et al. (2010). The land governance framework: methodology and early<br />

lessons from country pilots. In Innovations in land rights recognition, administration<br />

and governance. Washington: World Bank, GLTN, FIG and FAO.<br />

FAO (2007). Buena gobernanza en la tenencia y la administración de tierras. Estudios<br />

sobre Tenencia de La Tierra, no. 9. Rome: FAO.<br />

FAO (2008). Towards good land governance. FAO Land Tenure Policy Series, Draft<br />

version 0.1. Rome/Nairobi.<br />

FAO (2010). Global forest resources assessment report. Rome: FAO.<br />

Gessa, S. D. (2008). Participatory mapping as a tool for empowerment. Rome:<br />

International land coalition.<br />

Lima (2002). Relatório das correições extraordinárias nos registros de terras rurais no<br />

estado do Amazonas. Governo do Estado do Amazonas. Secretaria da Cultura do<br />

Estado do Amazonas, 440 p.<br />

Margulis, S. (2000). Quem são os agentes dos desmatamentos na Amazônia e por<br />

que eles desmatam. Conceptual paper. Brasília: World Bank. Retrieved from: .<br />

Margulis, S. (2003). Causas do desmatamento da Amazônia brasileira. Brasília: World<br />

Bank,100 p.<br />

PRODES (2011). Taxas de desmatamento da Amazônia Legal, Projeto PRODES.<br />

Ministério da Ciência e Tecnologia. IBAMA. Ministério do Meio Ambiente. INPE.<br />

Retrieved from: in


150<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Deforestation of<br />

the Brazilian Amazon<br />

rainforest: causes<br />

and solutions<br />

Bastiaan Reydon<br />

18/05/11.<br />

Reydon, B. P. (2007). A regulação institucional da propriedade da terra no Brasil: uma<br />

necessidade urgente. In Ramos, P. (org.) Dimensões do agronegócio brasileiro:<br />

políticas, instituições e perspectivas. Brasília: MDA.<br />

Reydon, B. P. and Cornelio, F. N. M. (2006). Mercados de terras no Brasil: estrutura e<br />

dinâmica. Nead Debate, n.7. Brasília: MDA/NEAD, 444 p.<br />

Reydon, B. P. and Plata, L. O. (2000). Intervenção estatal no mercado de terras: a<br />

experiência recente no Brasil. Estudos NEAD, n.3. Campinas: NEAD, 172p.<br />

Reydon, B. P. and Romeiro, A. R. (2000). Desenvolvimento da agricultura familiar e<br />

reabilitação das terras alteradas na Amazônia. In Reforma Agrária e Desenvolvimento<br />

Sustentável. Brasília/DF, v. 1, p. 311-317.<br />

Sabbato, A. (2001). Perfil dos proprietários/detentores de grandes imóveis rurais que<br />

não atenderam à notificação da Portaria 558/99. Retrieved from: in 03.08.03.<br />

Shiki, S. (2007, March 16). Payment for ecosystem services: from local to global.<br />

[PowerPoint slides] Proambiente, Ministério do Meio Ambiente. Retrieved from:<br />

in 29.09.08.<br />

Silva, Lígia O. (1996). Terras devolutas e latifúndio: efeitos da lei de 1850. Campinas:<br />

Editora da Unicamp, 373p.<br />

Silva, Lígia O. (1997). As leis agrárias e o latifúndio improdutivo. São Paulo em<br />

Perspectiva, 11(2), 15-25.<br />

Soares-Filho, Silveira B. et al. (2005). Cenários de desmatamento para a Amazônia.<br />

Estudos Avançados, 19(54), 137-152. Retrieved from: . ISSN<br />

0103-4014. Doi: 10.1590/S0103-40142005000200008>.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011


151<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The transition to a green<br />

economy in Brazilian<br />

law: perspectives and<br />

challenges<br />

Carlos Teodoro J. Hugueney Irigaray 1<br />

Op e n in g r e m a r k s<br />

In the context of climate change, the transition to a low-carbon economy<br />

consists of an imperative that requires a shift in paradigms, with great cultural,<br />

economic and legal repercussions, that reshapes the ideas of sustainability<br />

and environmental justice.<br />

In this transition, considering the consequences of globalization and the<br />

trans-border characteristics of pollution, there are tasks that demand to be<br />

addressed by the international community, notwithstanding local actions,<br />

especially issues such as measures to contain greenhouse gas (GHG)<br />

emissions and adaptation to the effects of global warming.<br />

However, even with these actions that involve international cooperation, the<br />

list of tasks aiming to internally propitiate the transition to a green economy<br />

remains ample within the countries.<br />

Internationally, Brazil boasts a privileged position in this context, with a<br />

relatively clean energy matrix, as apart from a mega-diversity and a range<br />

of other natural attributes that secure the country in a prominent position for<br />

biodiversity conservation.<br />

However, natural wealth is not sufficient to ensure development on<br />

sustainable bases, nor to the greening of the economy. In the case of Brazil, the<br />

expansion of the agricultural frontier and the lack of consistent public policies<br />

to guide economic exploitation of natural resources, contributed to forge a<br />

predatory exploitation model that has caused the country great economic and<br />

environmental losses.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

In response to this picture, innumerable laws were enacted with significant<br />

advances in terms of environmental protection, though great challenges persist<br />

in terms of the transition towards an economy that can be defined as green.<br />

1. Professor of Environmental Law at Federal University of Mato Grosso (UFMT) (PhD), state<br />

attorney at Mato Grosso (a Brazilian state) and president of the Right for a Green Planet<br />

Institute (IDPV).


152<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The transition to<br />

a green economy<br />

in Brazilian law:<br />

perspectives and<br />

challenges<br />

Carlos Teodoro Irigaray<br />

Law can certainly offer a relevant contribution in this process, as will be<br />

analyzed in this essay. A first challenge consists of delimiting the instruments<br />

and mechanisms that can contribute to the achievement of a development on<br />

sustainable bases, which implies the revision of the implicit subsidies of polluting<br />

activities, as will be discussed in the first chapter.<br />

In the second chapter of this essay, the principal challenges to this process<br />

will also be pointed out, concluding with a discussion on the contribution of<br />

Brazilian law to the transition to a green economy.<br />

The context is greatly favorable to the necessary changes, both in terms of<br />

societal awareness and the imperatives seen in the current ecological crisis.<br />

We can only tackle these challenges and construct a new paradigm in which<br />

the right to an ecologically balanced environment is not a mere proclamation,<br />

but a reality based on intra and inter-generational solidarity.<br />

1. Gr e e n e c o n o m y a n d t h e p o s s i b l e s u s t a in a b il it y<br />

Since the conceptualization of sustainable development 2 , derived from the<br />

Brundtland Commission, a vast intellectual production was developed that aims<br />

to objectify the concept and establish parameters to quantify it. The greatest<br />

obstacle to of this task relates to the lack of indicators to measure sustainable<br />

development, since in principle none of the three objectives of sustainable<br />

development (economic, environmental and social) are currently measured in<br />

compatible parameters (Dourojeanni, 2000).<br />

It is not without purpose that Morin and Kern (1995) signals that the very<br />

notion of development, turns out to be gravely and severely underdeveloped.<br />

The same happens with sustainability: either it is translated into economic<br />

decisions and political actions, setting real limits on the utilization of natural<br />

resources and the emission of pollutants, or on the contrary, sustainable<br />

development would have been but an unrealized myth that we transmit to future<br />

generations, together with gigantic environmental liabilities that originate from<br />

a predatory civilization.<br />

Because of this, it is of utmost importance that we deepen the debates about<br />

the economic models that we select and the local and global actions that can<br />

contribute to secure growth in clean sectors, with sustainability.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

In this sense, Dourojeanni (2000) ponders that it is up to the actors and<br />

participants in the management process in each country or region to define the<br />

significance of sustainability, admitting that this is an ambiguous term that applies<br />

to production, ecology, economics, the environment, society and development.<br />

As it permeates distinct and separate areas, the concept of sustainability exerts<br />

2. In accordance with Brundtland (1987), sustainable development is the one “that meets the<br />

needs of the present without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own<br />

needs”.


153<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The transition to<br />

a green economy<br />

in Brazilian law:<br />

perspectives and<br />

challenges<br />

Carlos Teodoro Irigaray<br />

an integrative and revolutionary function, implicating a rupture of secularly<br />

consolidated patterns, beliefs and techniques linked to a context of changing<br />

patterns in the relations between man and the natural world.<br />

In this sense, sustainability can exert a transformative force, both in the<br />

economic sphere by encouraging investment in clean capital, and in the<br />

political-administrative sphere through the decentralization and democratization<br />

of decision-making centers.<br />

In any case, despite the imprecision of the sustainable development concept,<br />

it can still be considered viable and possible in the sense that it sets guidelines<br />

capable of informing political policies in this moment of transition from an<br />

industrial risk society 3 , offering guiding criteria for public intervention in the<br />

environmental sphere and especially in the economy, to foster an increase in<br />

natural capital.<br />

As such, it is indispensable to carry out a profound revision, in the economic<br />

and legal areas, of the implicitly conceded incentives of polluting activities 4 ,<br />

since the external effects of these economic activities are not frequently<br />

considered in the pricing system, generating what the economic science<br />

identifies as externalities.<br />

These externalities will only be reduced if the environmental costs were<br />

incorporated by producers and consumers, with the state intervening through<br />

economic or command and control instruments, which would imply overcoming<br />

a tradition of economic studies that view the environment as inexhaustible.<br />

Furthermore, we cannot ignore the research that alerts us to the volumes<br />

of natural resources currently consumed, considered above the replacement<br />

capacity of the planet 5 ; that is, humanity is consuming resources in an<br />

unsustainable way. This aspect is not being adequately considered in the<br />

formulation of public policy; no economic consideration has been given to the<br />

depletion of these resources that are treated as if they were inexhaustible.<br />

Consequently, economic policies are generally conceived and implemented with<br />

an extremely limited temporal horizon – short term policies, and in this context,<br />

if there is no growth in clean sectors, sustainability is compromised.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

3. In the sense of Ulrich Beck (1992), the configuration of contemporary society, as a risk society,<br />

assumes a scenario of catastrophic risks, marked by invisibility (nuclear threat, global warming,<br />

etc) and the incapacity of the State to efficiently address the problems and provide security to<br />

citizens (organized irresponsibility, security state and explosive society).<br />

4. World Watch Institute estimates that the equivalent to 3% of the global economy (or equivalent<br />

to the GDP of Italy) is spent on subsidizing activities that destroy the environment (Januzzi,<br />

G. M. A política energética e o meio ambiente apud Romeiro et al., 1999, p. 156). This index<br />

refers to explicit subsidies; the socio-environmental cost of polluting activities that are borne by<br />

the population (and not by polluters) is incalculable.<br />

5. An investigation conducted by an international team of scientists, under the coordination<br />

of Mathis Wackernagel, entitled “Tracking the ecological overshoot in consumption of the<br />

human economy”, signals the incapacity of the planet to absorb the carbon launched into<br />

its atmosphere. According to Wackernagel, economic expansion stimulates the demand for<br />

resources above the capacity of the planet to restore its goods and services: “We are no longer<br />

living off the dividends of nature, but nature’s capital. Sustainable economies are not possible if<br />

we live above the means that nature provides” (Polakovic, 2002).


154<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The transition to<br />

a green economy<br />

in Brazilian law:<br />

perspectives and<br />

challenges<br />

Carlos Teodoro Irigaray<br />

Therefore, the transition to a green economy requires substantial changes<br />

in terms of public policies that aim to redirect market mechanisms to make<br />

economic growth compatible with sustainability. From the legal perspective,<br />

the necessary measures involve restructuring a system to effectively guide<br />

public policies by combining the use of economic instruments and command<br />

and control mechanisms that should necessarily be informed by some ethical<br />

principles among which we highlight environmental justice and intra and intergenerational<br />

equity.<br />

The following chapter will focus on the challenges to this transition, considering<br />

the national context and the mega-problems that negatively reverberate in the<br />

environment of our country.<br />

2. Ch a l l e n g e s o f t h e t r a n s it io n t o a g r e e n<br />

e c o n o m y in Br a z il<br />

As mentioned, the transition to a green economy faces challenges of a<br />

global order and a national order, due to the singular spatial characteristics<br />

of Environmental Law (Martin Mateo, 1977) where environmental problems<br />

do not obey boundaries, and the globalization process keeps economies<br />

interdependent. Furthermore, there are situations where global problems<br />

reverberate in the national sphere, aggravating internal deficiencies and acting<br />

synergistically to amplify risk conditions and accentuate the multifactorial<br />

character of pollution.<br />

Three factors will be addressed in this essay that directly relate to the<br />

development model implemented in our country, which pose challenges in the<br />

transition to a green economy: poverty, deforestation, and the unsustainable<br />

expansion of agriculture.<br />

2.1 Confronting Poverty<br />

Even in the 21st Century poverty continues to be one of the most relevant<br />

socio-environmental problems affecting humanity, and it continues being<br />

endemic in developing countries with close to 1.2 billion people living on less<br />

than one dollar per day in 1999, according to a United Nations Conference on<br />

Trade and Development Information Note. 6<br />

Brazil finds itself in a privileged position among developing countries, but<br />

poverty indexes remain elevated and there is a significant income inequality,<br />

which needs to be overcome to reduce the pressure on natural resources, the<br />

lack of sanitation and ensure an improved quality of life.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

According to research conducted by the Brazilian Institute of Applied<br />

Economic Research 7 , the national situation presents expressive improvements<br />

6. UNCTAD (2004).<br />

7. Presidência da República (2007).


155<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The transition to<br />

a green economy<br />

in Brazilian law:<br />

perspectives and<br />

challenges<br />

Carlos Teodoro Irigaray<br />

in the reduction of social inequality, but the problem is still serious. The study<br />

points out that from 1995 to 2008, 13 million people got out of misery in the<br />

country, causing the number of people in this condition to be reduced by half,<br />

which in this case includes families with a per person income of below ¼ of<br />

a monthly minimum wage. However, the country still accounts for 7.5 million<br />

Brazilians with a per capita household income of below 1 dollar PPC per day.<br />

This percentage is much greater when the proportion of Brazilians in absolute<br />

poverty is considered, which according to that same study is 28.8%. This figure<br />

consists of family members with an average per person income of up to half a<br />

monthly minimum wage (close to 5 dollars per day).<br />

It is worth stressing that the UN report “Our Common Future” already<br />

highlights that pollution does not result only from development, but also from<br />

poverty and growing slums, lack of sanitation, occupation of risk areas and lack<br />

of education, among other consequences.<br />

The challenges to be addressed in order to reduce poverty in the country,<br />

according to the research conducted by the Brazilian Institute of Applied<br />

Economic Research 8 , include above all the lack of access to food, due to the<br />

low purchasing power of millions of Brazilians, a problem that is aggravated<br />

by a series of other factors such as inadequate conditions of basic sanitation,<br />

low levels of education and lacking health services.<br />

In the area of sanitation, the indicators for urban Brazil (80.5% of urban<br />

inhabitants have adequate sanitation) are inferior to urban areas in countries<br />

such as Jamaica (82%), according to data from the United Nations 9 . Despite<br />

advances during the past decade, the report adds that “the lack of an<br />

adequate solution for domestic sewage still affects around 31 million urban<br />

inhabitants”.<br />

In rural Brazil, not only is the situation worse but improvements have also<br />

been slower. In 2008, 76.9% of the population did not have adequate access<br />

to sewage; this means that the 23.1% of rural inhabitants with adequate<br />

sanitation was below that in rural areas of Afghanistan (25%), also according<br />

to UN data.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Another equally relevant aspect related to poverty and lack of sanitation, is<br />

the fact that less than 50% of sanitary sewage produced in Brazil is collected<br />

and only 1/3 of that amount is effectively treated. According to the Health<br />

Ministry, 65% of hospital admissions result from the inadequacy of these<br />

services, and close to 50 thousand children die every year in Brazil (Irigaray<br />

and Rios, 2005).<br />

8. Idem.<br />

9. UNCTAD (2004).


156<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The transition to<br />

a green economy<br />

in Brazilian law:<br />

perspectives and<br />

challenges<br />

Carlos Teodoro Irigaray<br />

As a consequence, “the lack of adequate solutions for collection and low<br />

treatment levels of domestic sewage are the primary culprits for the pollution of<br />

water resources in Brazil, a problem that is felt most acutely in densely populated<br />

municipalities of metropolitan regions and medium and large cities”, stresses<br />

the Brazilian Institute of Applied Economic Research report.<br />

Now, it is difficult to establish the relationship between poverty and<br />

unsustainable development. It is notorious that the proportion of the population<br />

without access to drinking water and sanitation, or in precarious living situations,<br />

is directly related to the quality of life and health of the population and,<br />

consequently, to environmental sustainability.<br />

In that sense, the United Nations Human Settlements Programme stresses in<br />

“The State of the World’s Cities 2006/2007” 10 document, that there is a positive<br />

correlation between living conditions and human development indicators.<br />

This report observes that the existence of one or more housing inadequacies<br />

threatens the health, education and employment opportunities of inhabitants<br />

in precarious settlements: they are hungrier, have less chances of finding wellpaid<br />

employment in the formal sector, have lower educational levels, are more<br />

vulnerable to diseases and die sooner than the rest of the urban populations.<br />

The document emphasizes: “housing location matters”.<br />

Because of this scenario, overcoming socio-environmental injustice<br />

constitutes a priority in the transition towards a green economy where economic<br />

growth occurs on a sustainable basis.<br />

2.2 The advance of deforestation<br />

In accordance with the IPCC report, the shrinking forest cover resulting from<br />

deforestation and conversions to alternative land use, as well as the degradation<br />

associated with the selected logging of species, burning and other practices<br />

that cause losses in the remaining carbon stocks, is responsible for close to<br />

18% of the total estimated greenhouse gasses in the world. 11<br />

Thereby, containing deforestation and forest burning has become a global<br />

necessity for moving towards a low-carbon economy.<br />

This challenge is of particularly high priority in our country, mainly due to the<br />

elevated rates of deforestation in the Amazon region especially, where more<br />

than 70% of deforestation results from the creation of pastures.<br />

Upon analyzing the risk of expansion of biofuels in the Amazon, we stress:<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

“Of the existing forest area on Brazilian territory, 20% has already been<br />

deforested, which corresponds to 67 million hectares. Despite government<br />

10. UNCHS (2006).<br />

11. IPCC (2007).


157<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The transition to<br />

a green economy<br />

in Brazilian law:<br />

perspectives and<br />

challenges<br />

Carlos Teodoro Irigaray<br />

actions aimed at reverting the advances of the agricultural frontier into the<br />

forest, the deforestation rates remain elevated. According to the Brazilian<br />

National Institute for Space Research, the deforested area during the period<br />

2007/2008 was equivalent to 11,968 km², and though a gradual reduction<br />

in the percentage could be found, this could have been associated with<br />

market downturns, and there is no assurance that deforestation would be<br />

contained in a heating economy, even because the absence of the Amazon<br />

State apparatus is one of the factors that aggravate the current situation,<br />

characterized by land grabbing, illegal deforestation, violence, and slave<br />

labor” (Irigaray, 2010).<br />

This situation of Amazon forest degradation is driven primarily by extensive<br />

cattle raising and by logging activities. Studies conducted by the Amazon<br />

Institute of Man and the Environment reveal that the variation in deforestation<br />

rates in the Legal Amazon oscillate in accordance with price variations of cattle<br />

and soy, that is, the greater the product value, the greater the deforestation rate.<br />

Also in accord with this study, close to ¾ of the deforestation over recent years<br />

made space for pastures that occupy around 75% to 81% of total deforested<br />

land between 1990 and 2005 (Barreto et al., 2008).<br />

The lack of an agricultural policy that dialogues with environmental<br />

management is an evidence of the weakness of political policies for the region,<br />

and sustains the latent risk that increasing deforestation rates could unleash,<br />

as has also been observed by Paulo Moutinho (2009):<br />

“Some recent studies demonstrate that the Amazon deforestation, despite<br />

recent rate declines, could increase in the decades to come (Soares et al.,<br />

2006). It is estimated that more than half of the Brazilian Amazon will be<br />

deforested or degraded due to logging and burning, in case the occupation<br />

patterns continue along the trajectory of the past two decades”.<br />

It should be noted that the advances in Amazon deforestation imply significant<br />

increases in the carbon emissions indexes for Brazil, aggravated by the fact that,<br />

as a rule, deforestation occurs illegally and frequently is followed by burning.<br />

As such, containing deforestation becomes a priority, which puts our country<br />

in an evident position, as André Lima (2009) expresses:<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

“The Brazilian Federal Constitution of 1988 concluded 20 years of existence<br />

in 2008. During the period from 1988 to 2008, 348 thousand km 2 of tropical<br />

forest vanished into space, only in the Amazon region. In only two decades,<br />

less than one generation. This corresponds, using conservative data from<br />

the federal Brazilian government, to somewhere around 12.3 billion tons of<br />

carbon in the atmosphere. All the Amazon forestal carbon that Brazil emitted<br />

in the 21 years of our citizens’ Constitution, corresponds to almost twice the<br />

emissions reduction efforts pledged by the Annex 1 countries of the Kyoto<br />

Protocol for the first commitment period (2008-2012).”


158<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The transition to<br />

a green economy<br />

in Brazilian law:<br />

perspectives and<br />

challenges<br />

Carlos Teodoro Irigaray<br />

It is worth nothing that despite federal government efforts to contain<br />

deforestation in the Amazon, and the significant decreases of recent years,<br />

7 thousand km 2 of forest were cut down in 2010. In the Brazilian savannah<br />

(Cerrado), control turns out to be even weaker, with conversion indexes that<br />

have increased significantly in recent decades, currently making it the most<br />

threatened Brazilian biome.<br />

It is estimated that the Cerrado has already lost 49% of its native vegetation<br />

and close to 14.2 thousand km 2 are deforested per year, especially due to<br />

the creation of pastures, according to data from the Brazilian Institute of<br />

Environment and Renewable Natural Resource.<br />

However, deforestation is only the tip of an iceberg that needs to be addressed<br />

in the transition to a green economy, since associated with this problem are<br />

persisting cultural practices such as burning that degrades the soil, or the<br />

excessive use of pesticides that contaminate soil and water resources, as well<br />

as other environmental impacts associated with agricultural expansion, as will<br />

be discussed in the following section.<br />

2.3 The expansion of agriculture and cattle raising<br />

Brazil stands out internationally as the granary of the world, by occupying<br />

a prominent position in the production of grains, meat, poultry and other<br />

agricultural products. Both agriculture and cattle raising are responsible for the<br />

primary surplus obtained by the country in its trade balance.<br />

While recognizing the importance of agriculture in the country and the<br />

possibilities to expand agribusiness with a sustainable basis, there is still a<br />

great distance between sector practices and the objectives of an agricultural<br />

and livestock sector that can be considered “green” in Brazil.<br />

Overcoming this distance between the real and the ideal implies recognizing<br />

that in this surplus so hailed by the government, the subsidies that these<br />

activities receive (implicitly and explicitly) are not accounted for, and neither<br />

are the shortfalls in compliance with environmental legislation that causes<br />

significant environmental impacts.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

As noted, the raising of livestock is responsible for over 70% of the<br />

deforestation in the Amazon. According to the Brazilian Institute of Geography<br />

and Statistics, from 1990 to 2008 the stock in this region went from 21.1 million<br />

to 71.4 million livestock. This growth was driven by various factors: low prices<br />

or free land use (generally public lands occupied illegally), subsidized credit<br />

and cheap labor or labor in conditions analogous with slavery.<br />

The deforested areas of the Amazon generally house extensive cattle farms<br />

with large-scale livestock raising and low productivity that advance across<br />

protected areas (Legal Reserves and Permanent Preservation Areas). These


159<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The transition to<br />

a green economy<br />

in Brazilian law:<br />

perspectives and<br />

challenges<br />

Carlos Teodoro Irigaray<br />

practices cause severe degradation especially when analyzed from a biological<br />

perspective because according to a study conducted by the Amazon Institute<br />

of Man and the Environment in partnership with the World Bank, the Amazon<br />

possesses some peculiarities, such as: poor soils and excessive rainfall in<br />

around 80% of the region. These attributes are sufficient to make, from a purely<br />

economic point of view, any traditional farming undertaking unviable 12 .<br />

In the case of agriculture, the problems are not any smaller. The expansion<br />

of agribusiness has typically occurred without respect for forest legislation,<br />

through the planting of intensive monocultures that are highly dependent on<br />

pesticides and fertilizers.<br />

It is worth observing that opting for monocultures has been constructed as<br />

a strategy by agribusinesses to reduce costs and increase production, which<br />

today corresponds to a third of GDP and 42% of exports in Brazil. However, as<br />

journalists Safatle and Pardini stress: “The strength of agribusiness is only one<br />

side of the story. Socio-environmental damage still needs to be accounted for” 13 .<br />

According to the Brazilian Institute of Applied Economic Research economist<br />

Guilherme Delgado, “Brazilian agribusiness mixes technological modernity<br />

with a delay in social relations”. They alert that there are still 3.6 million rural<br />

families living in extreme poverty, living on less than one dollar per capita a<br />

day. This contingent is being alienated since large-scale agriculture generates<br />

little employment and causes a rural exodus that the urban centers are not<br />

capable of absorbing with dignity. That is, in addition to the environmental<br />

liability, since monocultures do not generally respect the legal reserves, there<br />

are other repercussions of a social kind that should be considered.<br />

According to Feltran-Barbieri and Kassai (2008): “the tangible environmental<br />

liability generated by the non-existence of legal reserves could exceed R$ 112<br />

million in the sampled regions, and could reach R$ 16 billion if extrapolated<br />

to the realm of the Cerrado, that is, almost 0.5% of the Brazilian GDP in<br />

2006. This liability does not account for the intangible losses to biodiversity<br />

and other environmental services, but only the externalities generated by<br />

agribusiness”.<br />

Furthermore, beyond the enormous environmental liability generated by the<br />

activity, this is a business that is highly exposed to international competition<br />

and open to the creation of non-tariff barriers, resulting in non-compliance with<br />

environmental legislation and the employment of slave labor.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

3. Th e c o n t r ib u t io n o f Br a z il ia n l a w t o a g r e e n<br />

12. Report: “Manejo Florestal Sustentável, Mudanças Econômicas no Uso do Solo e<br />

Implicações para Políticas Públicas na Amazônia”, Folha de S. Paulo, 22 October, 2000.<br />

13. Safatle and Pardini (2004).


160<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The transition to<br />

a green economy<br />

in Brazilian law:<br />

perspectives and<br />

challenges<br />

Carlos Teodoro Irigaray<br />

e c o n o m y: p e r s p e c t i v e s<br />

Among the mega-diverse countries, Brazil holds a special position with<br />

more than 13.2% of the total number of species on the planet, exceptional<br />

water availability and the greatest forest reserve on the planet, among other<br />

natural attributes.<br />

The threats that hover above this diversity of biomes and ecosystems cannot<br />

be ignored, and are mainly due to the expansion of the agricultural frontier that<br />

conflicts with existing environmental legislation, and causes economic damage<br />

through the loss of exploited natural resources through predatory practices,<br />

and ecological damage through the erosion of biodiversity.<br />

However, since the 1988 Federal Constitution a broader regulatory framework<br />

has been developed, which is capable of making economic growth compatible<br />

with sustainability, given that Brazil holds the conditions to exercise strong<br />

leadership in this transition towards a green economy characterized by low<br />

carbon emissions.<br />

Some principles are assured by the Federal Constitution that should guide<br />

not only the operations of the government, but also the business sector and<br />

civil society, such as recognizing the fundamental right to an ecologically<br />

balanced environment, associated with the duty of the government and<br />

society in defending and preserving this right. This duty is complemented by<br />

the recognition of environmental defense as a principle that should inform the<br />

economic sphere, and with the definition of a government task list assigned<br />

by the Constitution to secure the effectiveness of the right recognized in art.<br />

225.<br />

Among the principal norms that provide the basis for sustainable development<br />

in our country, are the Forest Code (Law n. 4.771/65), the National Environmental<br />

Policy Law (Law n. 6.938/81), the Public Civil Action Law (Law n. 7.347/85), the<br />

National Water Resource Policy Law (Law nº 9.433/97), the Law that instituted<br />

the National System of Conservation Units (Law n. 9.985/00), the National<br />

Solid Waste Policy Law (12.305/10) and the National Climate Change Policy<br />

Law (Law n. 12.187/09).<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

In these laws, especially the last one, certain principles, objectives and<br />

directives are defined for the transition towards a green economy, where<br />

development can materialize on a sustainable basis and with socio-environmental<br />

justice. Along these lines, that law stresses that: “the objectives of the National<br />

Climate Change Policy should be in line with sustainable development in order<br />

to seek economic growth, the eradication of poverty and the reduction of social<br />

inequality” (art. 4th).<br />

The great challenge of this task is to increase the level of implementation of<br />

these norms, above all the Forest Code, to be able to contain the advancing<br />

agricultural frontier in fragile ecosystems, but which has met great rural


161<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The transition to<br />

a green economy<br />

in Brazilian law:<br />

perspectives and<br />

challenges<br />

Carlos Teodoro Irigaray<br />

resistance. Along these lines, it is worrying to see the efforts of rural lobbyists<br />

in the National Congress to adapt the Forest Code in favor of agricultural<br />

expansion onto the last standing remnants of the Cerrado, eliminating judicial<br />

protection for the existent forest assets, which runs counter to government<br />

efforts to reduce emissions caused by deforestation.<br />

Equally worrying is the dubious position of the Brazilian government that,<br />

on the one hand, presents an ambitious plan to reduce carbon emissions and,<br />

on the other, does not seem determined to exercise an efficient environmental<br />

policy by maintaining insignificant budgets for environmental agencies while<br />

investing in high impact ventures such as the Belo Monte hydroelectricity plant,<br />

or paving the BR 163 (Cuiabá/Santarém) and BR 319 (Manaus/Porto Velho)<br />

federal highways, among others.<br />

This contradiction is externalized through the dismantling of environmental<br />

agencies and the lacking political will to implement efficient environmental<br />

management, in such a way that impunity remains the rule in cases of<br />

environmental infractions: the fines issued by environmental agencies are<br />

not paid and few polluters are held civilly or criminally accountable for the<br />

damages caused, characteristic of the “organized irresponsibility” described<br />

by Ulrich Beck.<br />

Beyond overcoming these limiting factors, new mechanisms should join<br />

the effort of containing deforestation and appreciating sustainable production.<br />

To this end, the employment of instruments such as REDD, payments for<br />

environmental services and charging for water use, constitute experiences<br />

that confirm the necessity of legal structures supporting the environmental<br />

management system that combines the employment of economic instruments<br />

with the provision of sanctions and efficient procedures for reparation and<br />

compensation for damages caused to the environment.<br />

It is worth registering that, though the actions implemented to contain climate<br />

change have focused on reducing emissions associated with the burning of<br />

fossil fuels, deforestation and forest degradation are currently at the center of<br />

the debate because they constitute significant causes of global warming since<br />

they collectively compose 17.4% of global emissions of greenhouse gases (more<br />

than a third of the emissions from developing countries), and also because the<br />

reduction of these emissions can be obtained at a lower cost than other sources<br />

of emissions (Irigaray, 2010).<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Our country holds an unparalleled natural heritage and a legal foundation<br />

capable of assisting the transition to a green economy. Nevertheless, these<br />

values should materialize in terms of social awareness, supported by political<br />

actions that enable the configuration of a Rule of Environmental Law.


162<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The transition to<br />

a green economy<br />

in Brazilian law:<br />

perspectives and<br />

challenges<br />

Carlos Teodoro Irigaray<br />

5. Fin a l r e m a r k s<br />

The transition to a green economy presupposes environmental justice<br />

and improved living conditions for the population. As such, policies should<br />

be prioritized that confront poverty, promote inclusive growth and provide to<br />

everyone a more active participation in the economic growth process and the<br />

sharing of its benefits, through social inclusion and the reduction of inequality.<br />

This is not a difficult task in Brazil, where hunger and malnutrition are not caused<br />

by scarcity in food production, since the domestic agricultural sector produces<br />

more than enough to provide for the needs of the Brazilian population.<br />

Similarly, conditions have been set for adapting economic activities to new<br />

patterns of sustainability, as outlined by Brazilian legislation, considering the<br />

agricultural industry and the notable agro-industrial development in the country<br />

over the past few years.<br />

However, the legislative advances are echoed quietly in the countryside.<br />

There is a significant deficit in the implementation of these laws that possess<br />

a merely symbolic character, since they continue to be disregarded without<br />

major consequences, and encounter resistance from sectors that bet on<br />

increased productivity in an unsustainable manner, that is, without considering<br />

the environmental costs.<br />

This dispute between maintaining a rigorous legislation and its attenuation<br />

has as its backdrop the global debate on the consequences of climate change<br />

and the need for mitigative and adaptive measures.<br />

In the context of Brazil, which assumed international commitments to reduce<br />

emissions, especially those originating from illegal deforestation and forest<br />

burning, there is the risk of seeing an upswing in deforestation if the country<br />

responds to pressures to relax its forest law.<br />

Reverting this picture presupposes not only measures of command and<br />

control mechanisms and adjustments to environmental management in the<br />

forestry sector, but also economic measures that provide realignment of<br />

economic incentives in favor of the conservation of forest assets, and the<br />

structuring of a forest-based economy with the promotion of alternative means<br />

of subsistence that are attractive to the population that depends on these<br />

resources (Irigaray, 2010).<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Among the economic instruments, payments for the ecological services<br />

performed by the forest play a relevant role in the construction of alternatives<br />

that contain deforestation and degradation of these ecosystems. Therefore,<br />

the implementation of a REDD policy in Brazil appears as a solid alternative,<br />

and given the magnitude of the emissions from deforestation and the low cost<br />

of reducing these emissions, it plays an important role in the global strategy to<br />

reduce emissions of greenhouse gases (Myers, 2009).


163<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The transition to<br />

a green economy<br />

in Brazilian law:<br />

perspectives and<br />

challenges<br />

Carlos Teodoro Irigaray<br />

Unfortunately, the requirements for sustainable use of natural resources in<br />

our country, although constitutionally backed, have still not managed to find solid<br />

mechanisms in environmental policy that allow thorough implementation. This<br />

is so, because a management approach that considers the support capacity of<br />

ecosystems and does not compromise their availability to future generations is<br />

needed and may be considered a goal that can only be materialized if articulated<br />

with other public policies, especially economic ones, which are directed towards<br />

the same goal.<br />

Furthermore, no country can produce and improve its environmental quality<br />

without a government that restrains unsustainable practices and encourages<br />

proper environmental behavior and sustainable use of environmental resources.<br />

Therefore, our country needs to overcome this picture of institutional vulnerability<br />

and strengthen the implementation of the existing regulatory framework,<br />

principally by integrating agricultural policies with environmental protection as<br />

a condition to secure the transition to a green economy.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

References<br />

Barreto, P. et al. (2008). A pecuária e o desmatamento na Amazônia na era das<br />

mudanças climáticas. Belém: Instituto do Homem e Meio Ambiente da Amazônia.<br />

Beck, Ulrich. (1998). La sociedade del riesgo. Hacia una nueva modernidad. Barcelona:<br />

Ediciones Piados Ibérica.<br />

Brundtland, G. H. et al. (1988). Nosso futuro comum. Relatório de 1987 da Comissão<br />

Mundial de Meio Ambiente e Desenvolvimento. Rio de Janeiro: Fundação Getúlio<br />

Vargas.<br />

Dourojeanni, A. (2000). Procedimientos de gestión para el desarrollo sustentable. Série<br />

Manual - Vol. 10. CEPAL/ECLAC. Santiago: United Nations.<br />

Feltran-Barbiberi, R. and Kassai, J. R. (2008). Passivo ambiental das reservas legais<br />

inexistentes no cerrado. Paper presented at the IX Simpósio Nacional Cerrado -<br />

Desafios e estratégias para o equilíbrio entre sociedade, agronegócio e recursos<br />

naturais. Brasília: EMBRAPA.<br />

IPCC (2007). Quarto relatório de avaliação do Painel Intergovernamental sobre Mudança<br />

Climática.<br />

Irigaray, C. T. J. H. (2004). O emprego de instrumentos econômicos na gestão<br />

ambiental. In Figueiredo, G. P. Direito Ambiental em Debate, Vol. 2. Rio de Janeiro:<br />

Esplanada.<br />

Irigaray, C. T. J. H. (2010a). A expansão dos biocombustíveis na Amazônia: riscos<br />

e desafios. In Heline Sivini Ferreira and José Rubens Morato Leite (org.).<br />

Biocombustíveis - fonte de energia sustentável?: considerações jurídicas, técnicas<br />

e éticas. São Paulo: Saraiva.<br />

Irigaray, C. T. J. H. (2010b). Pagamento por serviços ecológicos e o emprego do REDD<br />

na Amazônia. In Paula Lavratti, V. P. et al. (org.). Direito e Mudanças Climáticas: 3.<br />

Serviços Ecológicos. São Paulo: Instituto O Direito por um Planeta Verde.<br />

Irigaray, C. T. J. H. and Rios, Aurélio V. (org.) (2005). O Direito e o desenvolvimento<br />

sustentável. Brasília: IEB.<br />

Irigaray, C. T. J. H., Vieira, G. F and Silva, L. R. (2009). Regularização fundiária na<br />

Amazônia: a lei e os limites. Revista de Estudos Socio-Jurídico-Ambientais Amazônia<br />

Legal, 5. Cuiabá: EditUFMT.


164<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The transition to<br />

a green economy<br />

in Brazilian law:<br />

perspectives and<br />

challenges<br />

Carlos Teodoro Irigaray<br />

Lima, A. (2009). Desafios jurídicos para a governança sobre as emissões de CO2<br />

por desmatamento e a titularidade do carbono florestal. Retrieved from: in<br />

05.12.2009.<br />

Martin Mateo, R. (1977). Derecho ambiental. Madrid: Instituto de Estúdios de<br />

Administración Local.<br />

Morin, E. and Kern, A. B. (1995). Terra-Pátria. Porto Alegre: Sulina.<br />

Moutinho, P. (2009). Desmatamento na Amazônia: desafios para reduzir as emissões<br />

de gases de efeito estufa do Brasil. p. 2-3. Retrieved from: in 05.12.2009.<br />

Myers, E. (2009). Mudança climática e setor florestal: cartilha de REDD. In Florestas:<br />

o setor florestal nos mercados voluntários de carbono, segunda edição. Revista<br />

Ecosystem Marketplace. The Katoomba Group’s.<br />

Polakovic, F. (2002, June 06). O homem consome e a Terra não consegue repor. O<br />

Estado de São Paulo, Geral/Ambiente, p. A15.<br />

Presidência da República (2007). Objetivos de desenvolvimento do milênio:<br />

relatório nacional de acompanhamento / coordenação: Instituto de Pesquisa<br />

Econômica Aplicada e Secretaria de Planejamento e Investimentos Estratégicos;<br />

supervisão:Grupo Técnico para o acompanhamento dos ODM. Brasília: IPEA, MP,<br />

SPI.<br />

Romeiro, A. R. et al. (org.) (1999). Economia do meio ambiente: teoria, políticas e a<br />

gestão de espaços regionais. Campinas: UNICAMP-IE.<br />

Safatle, A. and Pardini, F. (2004, Setembro 01). Grãos na balança. Carta Capital, n°<br />

306.<br />

UNCTAD (2004). Assegurando ganhos de desenvolvimento a partir do sistema comercial<br />

internacional e das negociações de comércio. Nota de Informação, TD/397. Retrieved<br />

from: < http://www.unctad.org/pt/docs/td397_pt.pdf><br />

UNCHS (2006). The state of the world’s cities 2006/2007: the millennium development<br />

goals and urban sustainability, 30 years of shaping the Habitat agenda. Sterling:<br />

Earthscan. Overview; 1.1-1.2.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011


165<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Market mechanisms for<br />

a green economy<br />

Peter H. May 1<br />

Ar g u m e n t s in f a v o r o f a g r e e n e c o n o m y<br />

To reach a “green economy” it is necessary to ensure a reduction in materials<br />

and energy use in the production process, to allow society to prosper without<br />

necessitating economic growth (Daly, 1996, Jackson, 2009, Victor, 2008). On<br />

the other hand, social actors deprived of the bounties of modern capitalism<br />

– owing to the inequitable distribution of wealth – can attain higher levels of<br />

consumption without necessarily furtherdepleting natural capital. From this<br />

perspective, the apparently contradictory goals of durable stability or degrowth<br />

in the North and “greening” of growth (with equity) in the South represent the<br />

basis for a meaningful dialogue about a sustainable future and, furthermore,<br />

configure the platform of debate for <strong>Rio+20</strong>.<br />

This brief contribution discusses the following question: to what point can we<br />

resort to so-called “market mechanisms” to ensure this necessary transformation<br />

in natural resource utilization? More specifically, how can we most effectively<br />

guide the transition toward resource renewal and convert wastes into inputs<br />

rather than residuals?<br />

This analysis may appear contradictory in that it seems diametrically opposed<br />

to what has moved economic actors historically, i.e., their single-minded pursuit<br />

of maximum profit. Added to this is the recognition that the market has pushed<br />

economic actors toward a growth regime based on the rapid depletion of natural<br />

resources and the generation of pollution combined with a growing abyss<br />

between rich and poor, within and among countries. This work is aligned with<br />

a contemporary perspective that recognizes the limits of market mechanisms,<br />

and thus makes reference to a discourse grounded on the economics of the<br />

environment.<br />

In this chapter, some of the main arguments of the economics of the<br />

environment are introduced, including both those aimed at regulating public<br />

goods and those that propose solutions to adverse effects arising from the<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

1. Associate professor at the Pos-Graduate Program in Social Sciences for Development,<br />

Agriculture and Society at the Federal Rural University of Rio de Janeiro (CPDA/UFRRJ),<br />

vice-coordinator of the Master’s in Sustainable Development Practice (PPGDPS/UFRRJ),<br />

coordinator of the research component on Biodiversity, Natural and Cultural Resources of the<br />

National Institute of Science and Technology in Public Policies for Development Strategies<br />

(INCT/PPED), past president of the International Society for Ecological Economics (ISEE),<br />

advisor of the Brazilian Society for Ecological Economics and collaborator at Friends of the<br />

Earth-Brazilian Amazonia.


166<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Market mechanisms<br />

for a green economy<br />

Peter H. May<br />

modern economy. Such arguments question the relative superiority of market<br />

mechanisms, adopted in many countries as the most efficient mechanism to<br />

ensure the provision of environmental services. Along these lines, we discuss<br />

payments for environmental services (PES) and its application, as a means<br />

to complement command and control mechanisms aimed at efforts to reduce<br />

and revert carbon emissions, above all those stemming from deforestation in<br />

tropical countries (REDD+).<br />

In s t it u t io n s f o r e n v ir o n m e n t a l m a n a g e m e n t<br />

What institutions does society possess to signal and support the transition<br />

to a green economy? It should be recognized, before anything else, that the<br />

market is only one of many institutions created by human societies to administer<br />

relations of exchange and production (North, 1990). In many cases, the market<br />

may not be the most adequate institution to signal change along technological<br />

trajectories, even if such a trajectory is underpinned by high wastage and<br />

exhaustible inputs, due to the fact that the market does not adequately reflect the<br />

value of public goods (Vatn, 2010). Thus, under what conditions is it acceptable<br />

to rely on the allocative efficiency of the market to produce “green” outcomes<br />

for economic processes?<br />

A first step is to suggest how more adequate policies can be selected, which<br />

in turn requires that available instruments be differentiated along a continuum,<br />

ranging from activity regulation – based on physical standards – to mechanisms<br />

based on motivating the actions of individuals in their own self-interest and in<br />

response to the laws of supply and demand. Along this continuum, there is a<br />

range of options with greater or lesser degrees of dependence on market forces.<br />

The relative convenience and efficacy of such options, for regulating economic<br />

activities in the context of environmental restrictions, have been the object of<br />

innumerable studies (see Seroa da Motta, Ruitenbeek et al., 1996).<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The criteria for selecting the appropriate mechanism differ when derived<br />

from an ecological economic perspective. In this regard, we can classify the<br />

instruments of environmental resource management in accordance with two<br />

principal variables: (1) the relative importance (non-substitutable character) of<br />

the resource in question, and (2) its resilience (capacity to recover from stress<br />

or degradation). These two variables reveal, without resorting to devices of<br />

market valuation, the biophysical constraints of human intervention. Situations<br />

where the biota has little capacity to withstand disturbances and simultaneously<br />

is constituted by endemic or endangered species, make perfect candidates for<br />

the application of “sanctuary” measures, that is, the access and use of such<br />

resources should be prohibited. As extinction is irreversible, there are no ways to<br />

substitute species or populations, whose survival depends on the maintenance<br />

of intact ecosystems.


167<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Market mechanisms<br />

for a green economy<br />

Peter H. May<br />

On the other side of the spectrum, resilient natural resources (whose losses<br />

associated with exhaustion/modification are less relevant), offer the opportunity<br />

to take advantage of the market’s allocative efficiency, insofar as it provides<br />

resources through rewards and may even reinforce cleaner behaviors. This<br />

enables the creation of markets that negotiate quotas for pollutant emission<br />

permits, for example. In the middle of the spectrum, intermediate restrictions<br />

can be found, such as fishing quotas or permitted fishing net size (King, 1994).<br />

The specific locations of boundaries between different modes of intervention are<br />

not measurable, and management adaptations are necessary in response to<br />

the different evolutionary characteristics of the ecosystems being analyzed.<br />

Unfortunately, there are difficulties in developing efficient policies due to<br />

uncertainty or total ignorance about the resilience of ecosystems and their<br />

“tipping points”: thresholds associated with radical changes in these systems.<br />

In a first evaluation, it seems prudent to err on the side of caution, given that<br />

the unintended or unforeseeable consequences of human actions can cause<br />

irreversible losses, thereby leading to damage to human well-being (Ring and<br />

Schroter-Schlak, 2011). Thus, the formulation of policies to combat biodiversity<br />

losses should include instruments that can protect a “safe minimum standard”<br />

(Ciriacy-Wantrup, 1952) of biodiversity conservation, independent of the<br />

potential efficiency of available economic instruments, or their estimated<br />

benefit/cost ratios. Direct regulation (command and control – C&C), establishing<br />

protected areas, no-take fishing zones or prohibiting the use of certain products<br />

or substances (e.g., GMOs) that can lead to impacts on biodiversity, is a key<br />

regulatory component in these contexts.<br />

At an intermediate stage, uncertainty or ignorance of limits can warrant the<br />

creation of permit schemes based on the “cap and trade” approach (establishing<br />

a ceiling for the production or utilization of a certain resource, or the emission of<br />

pollutants generated by this production, and then commercializing all or part of<br />

the excess or gap in relation to the ceiling). This imposes an aggregate limit on<br />

the exploitation of species or habitats, and leaves the allocation within this limit<br />

to the market, and thus combines efficient allocation with conservation efforts<br />

ensured by the limit. The emergence of the carbon market stemmed from this<br />

approach. If a limit is not established by regulation, there would be no incentive<br />

to seek cost reduction through a market structured around emission permits.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The emergence of markets for environmental services owes its theoretical<br />

inspiration to the seminal work of Ronald Coase, in 1960, that established that<br />

an “optimal” point of environmental degradation is identified under the rule of<br />

law through the interaction of actors interested in negotiating permits for natural<br />

resource use. In this hypothetically constructed world, the legal responsibility of<br />

each actor in the negotiation is mandatorily defined and obeyed. Equilibrium is<br />

reached through free negotiation among actors. Those that feel prejudiced in a<br />

negotiation are compensated by an amount greater than the minimum that they


168<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Market mechanisms<br />

for a green economy<br />

Peter H. May<br />

would accept to give up their desired outcome. The solution will be symmetric<br />

if the agent harmed by environmental degradation is held accountable, having<br />

to pay compensation to the perpetrator of damage to desist.<br />

However, for the economic optimum to be attained, the Coase theorem posits<br />

that there be zero transaction costs 2 necessary to reach a negotiated solution.<br />

That way, there would be negotiation if the benefits of reaching a negotiated<br />

solution exceed the costs. In the opposite case, there would be no solution.<br />

This, however, according to Coase would also imply an equilibrium solution,<br />

since the lowest cost outcome is achieved. Therefore it is argued that if there<br />

is no negotiation, it is because the status quo situation is better than incurring<br />

the costs of searching for a solution. In analogous fashion, the perpetuation of<br />

externalities would be considered optimal (because too costly to satisfy those<br />

harmed), and consequently the government would not need to intervene.<br />

One problem to this type of solution to market failures, lies with the premise<br />

that information is symmetrical between the actors involved in a negotiation;<br />

on the contrary, polluters are normally few, know the amount of emissions they<br />

produce, and how much they are willing to invest in mitigation. The affected are<br />

many, disorganized, without information about the source or characteristics of<br />

the damage suffered and without easily mobilized resources to bring polluters<br />

to justice or even to the bargaining table. Not only is the “the power to exercise<br />

knowledge” (Lewontin, 1992) missing, but also the knowledge to exercise power<br />

among the actors.<br />

Pa y m e n t s f o r e n v ir o n m e n t a l s e r v i c e s<br />

Though the majority of prior studies focused on market mechanisms<br />

concentrate on problems related to pollution, there is now a major movement<br />

in favor of the utilization of this type of instrument as a means to stimulate the<br />

participation of rural landowners in a collective effort to conserve biodiversity,<br />

water sources and carbon stocks in forests. In this sense, instead of being held<br />

accountable for the emissions caused by deforestation and brought to justice,<br />

they may be treated as potential providers of environmental services beneficial<br />

to society. The negotiation between service providers and society stimulates<br />

the participation of rural landowners, whether motivating them to refrain from<br />

using forestlands for productive purposes, or stimulating them to incorporate<br />

better land use practices, and consequently diminishing emissions. This great<br />

Coasean bargain is called Payments for Environmental Services (PES).<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

One of the main theorists on the subject (Wunder, 2005) classifies PES as any<br />

transaction involving at least one buyer, one seller and one environmental service<br />

2. Note that transaction costs, according to Williamson (1979, 1985), depend on the frequency<br />

of transactions, degree of specificity of the transaction and the level of uncertainty that the<br />

transaction involves.


169<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Market mechanisms<br />

for a green economy<br />

Peter H. May<br />

being provided contingent on payments between the parties. Consequently,<br />

there are terms for a negotiation if the cost of providing the service added to the<br />

transaction costs of carrying out the arrangement are less than the collective<br />

socio-environmental benefit obtained by the buyers (whether local or global<br />

or both). The problem in this situation is that the benefits of environmental<br />

services are enjoyed by many –some can free-ride on the efforts of others, which<br />

lowers the incentive to contribute. Therefore, when information is asymmetrical,<br />

transaction costs yet again tend to be high. That is, there is an abundance of<br />

market failures to surmount in negotiations of this sort.<br />

Furthermore, there are problems of contractual insecurity: in the carbon<br />

market, for example, the buyer is the only one responsible for fulfilling what<br />

has been agreed with the seller of carbon credits with relation to emissions<br />

reductions. In this case, it is advantageous for a seller of credits to deforest<br />

and afterwards claim “what a shame, a fire on the neighboring farm got out of<br />

control”. It becomes the buyer’s problem to seek alternative carbon sources,<br />

or to securitize to fulfill reduction obligations. This is why, on the only regulated<br />

carbon market that reaches developing countries – that motivated by the Clean<br />

Development Mechanism (CDM) – primarily projects that imply emissions<br />

reductions at the source can be found, typically in ventures that involve changing<br />

energy sources or altering industrial processes and not projects involving forests<br />

or land use change. This is the problem of moral hazard.<br />

There are three solutions to the problem of moral hazard in PES contracts.<br />

The first is that of internalization: the actual buyer of the environmental benefit<br />

promotes the provision of environmental services as part of his or her own<br />

business. Multinational businesses can reduce emissions in a region of low<br />

efficiency and credit the gains internally in another subsidiary.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

In many cases a governmental solution is adopted to guarantee PES<br />

programs. In this case the State assumes responsibility, whether by<br />

guaranteeing or ultimately paying for the environmental benefits (Veiga and<br />

May, 2010). The principal national PES programs in Latin America (Costa Rica<br />

and Mexico, for example) adopt this procedure, since economic actors do not<br />

possess the necessary institutional framework to mediate negotiations between<br />

demanders and providers of services. In the case of Brazil, the remuneration<br />

for environmental services by private landowners is prohibited, due to the<br />

inexistence of such service provision in legislation. As a result, businesses,<br />

cooperatives or associations are brought into the process as intermediaries,<br />

with their respective transaction costs, that thereby dilute the revenue of the<br />

provider.<br />

The final case refers to voluntary action of private sector actors. In these<br />

cases, a third party certifies fulfillment of the objective of the contract in terms<br />

of emissions reduction and other aspects, such as the contribution of a project<br />

to processes of local and regional development, conservation of biodiversity


170<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Market mechanisms<br />

for a green economy<br />

Peter H. May<br />

or water resource protection. Independent certification is a type of “non-state”<br />

regulation, in which there is mediation of the relation between producers and<br />

consumers, establishing rules that prove – through an adequate degree of<br />

trust – that productive processes obey sustainability criteria (Kaechele, May<br />

et al., 2011). The proliferation of independent certification models, such as<br />

those being promoted by leading NGOs, creates a mechanism capable of<br />

overcoming one of the main obstacles to attract resources for environmental<br />

service markets. As of 2009, 96% of the volume of CO 2 credits commercialized<br />

in forest projects was already subject to independent certification (Hamilton,<br />

Chokkalingam et al., 2009).<br />

“Be t t e r REDD t h a n d e a d?”<br />

The topic of reducing deforestation as an aim of negotiations emerged in<br />

the area of global regulation when constructing a post Kyoto agenda, due to<br />

the lack of options capable of achieving the planned targets.<br />

Brazil – that is not attracting a lot of investments intended for reducing<br />

emissions in other sectors, since these are already considered relatively “green”<br />

- is one of the largest greenhouse gas emitters due to persistent deforestation.<br />

Despite having refused for years to enter into negotiations with Northern<br />

countries to define issues related to what it considered matters of national<br />

sovereignty, Brazil evidently decided not to enter the negotiations of the new<br />

climate accord as a pariah. Brazil therefore committed at the Conference of the<br />

Parties in Copenhagen in 2009 to make radical cuts in deforestation over the<br />

period up to 2020, reducing the deforestation rate in the Amazon by 80% and<br />

by 50% in the Cerrado (Brazilian savannah) as compared with a baseline of the<br />

previous 10 years. This accord was facilitated by the fact that deforestation has<br />

declined since a peak in 2005, with a level in 2010 of almost 70% below that<br />

peak. However, there is still a need to combat the persistent deforestation of<br />

large areas every year. A principal share of this new deforestation results from<br />

the expansion of cattle pastures in municipalities having low environmental<br />

governance capabilities.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

At the Conferences of the Parties (COP) of the United Nations Framework<br />

Convention on Climate Change and especially since COP12 in Nairobi (2006),<br />

the topic of “deforestation”, which was always postponed due to issues of<br />

national sovereignty, has received increased attention. At COP15 in Copenhagen<br />

(2009), considerable resources were committed to avoid deforestation through<br />

voluntary transfers between North and South. Resources are specifically aimed<br />

to support actions initiated by countries that seek to promote the Reduction<br />

of Emissions from Deforestation and Forest Degradation (REDD). Other<br />

complementary actions that seek to enrich and restore ecosystem functions<br />

of tropical rainforests were also contemplated (REDD+).


171<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Market mechanisms<br />

for a green economy<br />

Peter H. May<br />

The deforestation reductions that have taken place since 2005 elevated<br />

Brazil to a distinguished position at the climate negotiations. According to the<br />

government, the reduction resulted from a great effort to punish offenders and<br />

remove “pirate cattle” 3 from protected areas. In compensation, the Norwegian<br />

government committed to donate a total of US$ 1 billion to Brazil over the<br />

course of 10 years, deposited in the Amazon Fund created by the Brazilian<br />

National Bank of Economic and Social Development (BNDES) specifically to<br />

execute grant-financed actions that reinforce municipal monitoring and land<br />

regularization, and thus stimulating more sustainable natural resource uses.<br />

However, according to analyses by environmental entities, the observed<br />

reduction in deforestation can also be attributed to the price declines of<br />

agricultural commodities and a repercussion of the financial market crisis<br />

beginning in 2008. As some of these analysts argue, it would be more<br />

interesting to establish instruments that compensate those that would engage<br />

in deforestation, such as through PES, instead of focusing all resources on<br />

regulation. The question remains: should market mechanisms or C&C be<br />

favored in attaining the goals to reduce deforestation? If primarily market<br />

(PES), how much needs to be paid? What is the cost to society, to affected<br />

economic actors, and to communities dependent on forest resources for their<br />

sustenance? Who benefits?<br />

In this challenging context, Brazil is aided by the existing land use legislation<br />

that has a firm foothold in C&C. The Forest Code, with consecutive re-editions<br />

of Provisional Measures since 1998, permits alteration of native vegetation with<br />

productive purposes on only 20% of properties in the Amazon and 65% in the<br />

Cerrado. The rest has to remain as Legal Reserves. The problem is that few<br />

obey the Code, that even so is being targeted for dilution by the Congressional<br />

ruralist lobby (PL 00740/2011 replacement of Law 4.771, reported by Deputy<br />

Aldo Rebelo). On the other hand, state programs aimed at strengthening the<br />

Forest Code requirements through environmental licensing of rural land-use,<br />

have been deployed with some success in recent years. Licensing – that<br />

establishes the boundaries of each property and the location of legal reserves<br />

and permanent preservation areas -, when combined with the monitoring of<br />

changes in land use via satellite and verification in the field, allows assessment<br />

of compliance with the Code in practice. This set of legal instruments and<br />

monitoring resources makes Brazil one of the few countries that possesses the<br />

capacity to monitor and verify deforestation, and as such could gain access to<br />

resources pledged by countries in the North under REDD.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

One advantage of the Forest Code not yet utilized in many states is to operate<br />

as a ceiling (cap) on deforestation, because it establishes the maximum area<br />

that each property can modify. This could conceivably allow market mechanisms<br />

3. This refers to the presence of cattle on illegal properties (generally state-owned).


172<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Market mechanisms<br />

for a green economy<br />

Peter H. May<br />

to compensate those that observe the law. According to the stance of rural<br />

producers, they need an incentive to restore unduly deforested areas and they<br />

demand resources to cover the opportunity cost of retiring productive areas,<br />

as well as some compensation for the benefits provided to other members of<br />

society by restoring ecosystem functions. Others argue that rural producers<br />

already have received substantial incentives to deforest and now they need to<br />

observe the minimum safe standards of the Law, and that only those already<br />

observing the Forest Code should be compensated by PES.<br />

Despite discussions and various exercises to estimate the cost of reducing<br />

deforestation, the issue persists of how to better structure institutions to regulate<br />

the provision of public goods. A review of the experience with economic<br />

instruments and C&C regulation applied to biodiversity conservation (Ring and<br />

Schroter-Schlak, 2011) suggests that the best path in terms of cost effectiveness<br />

is a mix of instruments grounded in regulation. In this sense, strengthening<br />

the Forest Code (and not weakening it) should serve as the basis from which<br />

institutional innovations can flourish in Brazil.<br />

We conclude that market instruments, such as those associated with PES<br />

and REDD+, should assume an important role in the transition to a green<br />

economy. Such a role should be mediated by regulation that defines natural<br />

resources access and control criteria, reflected by biophysical limits established<br />

with reference to scientific knowledge and by extensive and prior consultation<br />

with populations that depend on those resources for their sustenance. Based<br />

on duly established parameters, it is possible in restricted circumstances to<br />

utilize the market’s allocative efficiency as a complement to other institutions<br />

to achieve society’s goals.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

References<br />

Ciriacy-Wantrup, S. V. (1952). Resource conservation: economics and policies. Berkeley,<br />

California: University of California Press.<br />

Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3<br />

(Oktober, 1960), 1-44.<br />

Daly, H. E. (1996). Beyond growth: the economics of sustainable development. Boston:<br />

Beacon Press.<br />

Hamilton, K., U. Chokkalingam et al. (2009). State of the forest carbon markets; taking<br />

root and branching out. Washington, D.C.: Forest Trends.<br />

Jackson, T. (2009). Prosperity without growth: economics for a finite planet. London;<br />

Sterling, VA: Earthscan.<br />

Kaechele, K., May, P. H. et al. (2011). Forest certification: a voluntary instrument for<br />

environmental governance. In Shleuter, I. R., Instrument mixes for biodiversity policies.<br />

Leipzig: Policymix Project.<br />

King, D. M. (1994). Can we justify sustainability? New challenges facing ecological<br />

economics. In Jansson, M. H., Folke, C. and Costanza, R., Investing in natural capital;<br />

the ecological economics approach to sustainability. Washington: Island Press.<br />

Lewontin, R. C. (1992). Biology as ideology: the doctrine of DNA. New York:<br />

HarperPerennial.


173<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Market mechanisms<br />

for a green economy<br />

Peter H. May<br />

North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance.<br />

Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Ring, I. and C. Schroter-Schlak (2011). Instrument mixes for biodiversity policies (draft).<br />

Leipzig: Helmholz Institute.<br />

Serôa da Motta, R. and Ruitenbeek, J. et al. (1996). Uso de instrumentos econômicos<br />

na gestão ambiental da América Latina e Caribe: lições e recomendações. Rio de<br />

Janeiro: IPEA.<br />

Vatn, A. (2010). An institutional analysis of payments for environmental services.<br />

Ecological Economics, 69(6), 1245-1252.<br />

Veiga, F. C. N. and May, P. H. (2010). Mercados para serviços ambientais. In May, P.<br />

H., Economia do meio ambiente: teoria e prática. Rio de Janeiro: Elsevier.<br />

Victor, P. A. (2008). Managing without growth: slower by design, not disaster. Cheltenham;<br />

Northampton: Edward Elgar.<br />

Williamson, O. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: The<br />

FrePress.<br />

Williamson, O. (1979). Transaction-cost economics: the governance of contractual<br />

relations. Journal of Law and Economics, 22(2), 233-61.<br />

Wunder, S. (2005). Payments for environmental services: some nuts and bolts. In CIFOR<br />

Occasional Paper. CIFOR. 42.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011


174<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Valuation and pricing of<br />

environmental resources for<br />

a green economy 1<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta 2<br />

In t r o d u c t io n<br />

The green economy concept means that economic growth can be based on<br />

investments in natural capital, whereby the structure of the economy changes<br />

in the direction of “green” or “clean” sectors/technologies to substitute “dirty”<br />

or “brown” sectors/technologies. The United Nations Environment Programme<br />

report “Towards a Green Economy: Pathways to Sustainable Development<br />

and Poverty Eradication” (UNEP, 2011), seeks to demonstrate that this<br />

transformation can be achieved without a loss of income and employment, and<br />

yet, with reductions in poverty.<br />

This task of natural capital appreciation imposes the necessity of responding<br />

to at least two questions, namely:<br />

(i)<br />

(ii)<br />

What is the value of an environmental resource? And<br />

What policy instrument should we use to capture this value?<br />

Another recent report “The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity”<br />

(TEEB, 2011), for example, offers some estimates of ecosystem and biodiversity<br />

costs on a global scale and examples of how to capture these values using<br />

economic instruments. As stated in the report, estimating the values associated<br />

with environmental goods and services and the ways they are captured by the<br />

market is a controversial and complex task, but even so, the resulting estimates<br />

ultimately indicate opportunities to generate income and employment through<br />

the recognition of the economic values of natural resources.<br />

That is, in order to finance investments in natural capital, we must recognize<br />

its economic and social contribution and price these according to their<br />

contribution to the welfare of society.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

In the following section, concepts and techniques, as well as limitations,<br />

of the valuation of environmental goods and services are discussed. In the<br />

third section, the ways to price these goods and services to construct a green<br />

economy are analyzed. The last section concludes with some final remarks.<br />

1. Senior Researcher at the Research Institute for Applied Economics (IPEA) and member of<br />

the IPCC 3rd and 5th Assessment Reports.<br />

2. For a more detailed introduction see for example, Hanley, Shogren and White (2007), Seroa<br />

da Motta (1988 e 2006), UNEP (2000a), Kolstad (2000), Freeman (1993) and Pearce and<br />

Turner (1990).


175<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Valuation and pricing<br />

of environmental<br />

resources for a green<br />

economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

Va l u in g e n v ir o n m e n t a l g o o d s a n d s e r v i c e s 3<br />

If we can identify the importance of environmental quality to guarantee<br />

the maximization of well-being, how come economic growth policies do not<br />

incorporate it from the beginning? Or better yet, why does the economic system<br />

not naturally optimize the use of natural resources?<br />

According to economic theory, the use of natural resources almost always<br />

generates negative economic externalities in the economic system. These<br />

externalities are not entirely captured by the pricing system, because enforcing<br />

the property or use rights of these resources results in high transaction costs,<br />

owed to the technical or cultural difficulties of fixing exclusive and rival rights.<br />

So, it is not possible to establish exchange relationships between these rights<br />

that ensure optimal resource use.<br />

In summary, these technical and institutional difficulties in defining the property<br />

rights between contemporary, and present and past generations, impede the<br />

existence of a market that signals the value of the resources or, when it exists,<br />

these imperfections result in prices and costs of use that do not reflect the<br />

economic (or social) value of the resource, and as such, introduces inefficiencies<br />

in the economic system. That is, the use of environmental resources generates<br />

negative external costs that are intra and inter-temporal.<br />

The economic value or the opportunity cost of environmental resources<br />

normally is not observed in the market by means of the pricing system. However,<br />

as with the other goods and services present in the market, its economic value<br />

derives from its attributes, with the peculiarity that these attributes may or may<br />

not be associated with use.<br />

The economic value of environmental resources (EVER) can be broken<br />

down into use value (UV) and non-use value (NUV) and is expressed in the<br />

following way:<br />

EVER = (DUV + IUV + OV) + EV<br />

where:<br />

Direct Use Value (DUV): value that individuals assign to an environmental<br />

resource through its direct use, such as extraction, visitation or another activity<br />

of direct production or consumption. For example, resource extraction, tourism,<br />

recreation and scientific research activities 3 ;<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Indirect Use Value (IUV): value that individuals assign to an environmental<br />

resource when the benefit of use derives from ecosystem functions, such as,<br />

containing erosion, controlling climate and protecting water springs 4 ;<br />

3. Benefits in-situ.<br />

4. Benefits ex-situ.


176<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Valuation and pricing<br />

of environmental<br />

resources for a green<br />

economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

Option Value (OV): value that individuals assign to the conservation of<br />

resources, that may be threatened, for direct and indirect use in the near future<br />

but not fully known today. For example, the benefit from gene therapies based<br />

on properties of genes not yet discovered from tropical forest plants.<br />

Non-use value, Passive or Existence Value (EV): value that is disassociated<br />

with use (though represents environmental consumption) and derives from<br />

a moral, cultural, ethical or altruistic position in relation to the rights of other<br />

species than the human to exist and other natural wealth, even if they do not<br />

represent actual or future use for anybody. A clear example of this value is<br />

the great mobilization of public opinion to save the panda bears or whales,<br />

even in regions where people would never be able to make any use from their<br />

existence.<br />

There is also another way to classify the economic value of an environmental<br />

resource by its capacity to generate flows of ecosystem services, as was<br />

established in the “Millennium Ecosystem Assessment Report” (MEA, 2005),<br />

that categorizes or typifies environmental services in provision, regulation,<br />

support and cultural services in the following manner:<br />

Provisioning services: those that generate direct material consumption, for<br />

example, foods, water, medicines and energy.<br />

Regulating services: services that regulate ecosystem functions, for example,<br />

carbon sequestration, solid waste decomposition, water and air purification<br />

and pest control.<br />

Supporting services: those that support ecosystem functions, such as soil<br />

formation, photosynthesis, and dispersion of nutrients and seeds.<br />

Cultural services: services that generate non-material consumption in the<br />

form of cultural, intellectual, recreational, spiritual and scientific activities.<br />

The table below relates and exemplifies these taxonomies.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

5. Benefícios ex-situ.


177<br />

General taxonomy of the value of environmental resources<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Economic value of environmental resources<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Direct<br />

use value<br />

Indirected<br />

use value<br />

Option<br />

value<br />

Existence<br />

value<br />

Valuation and pricing<br />

of environmental<br />

resources for a green<br />

economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

Value<br />

Environmental<br />

goods and<br />

services directly<br />

appropriated<br />

through present<br />

resource<br />

exploitation and<br />

consumption<br />

Environmental<br />

goods and<br />

services that<br />

are generated<br />

through<br />

ecosystem<br />

functions and<br />

appropriated<br />

and consumed<br />

indirectly in the<br />

present<br />

Environmental<br />

goods and<br />

services of<br />

direct and<br />

indirect<br />

use to be<br />

appropriated<br />

and<br />

consumed in<br />

the future<br />

Value not<br />

associated<br />

with present<br />

or future use<br />

and reflects<br />

moral,<br />

cultural,<br />

ethical and<br />

altruistic<br />

attitudes<br />

Related<br />

services<br />

Provisioning<br />

and regulating<br />

services<br />

Regulating,<br />

supporting<br />

and cultural<br />

services<br />

Provisioning,<br />

regulating,<br />

supporting<br />

and cultural<br />

services not<br />

yet discovered<br />

Cultural<br />

services<br />

In the literature, there is still some controversy in relation to the existence<br />

value as a representation of the value an individual assigns to maintain certain<br />

environmental resources so that their offspring (future generations) can enjoy<br />

their direct and indirect uses (bequest value). This is a conceptual issue that in<br />

some ways is irrelevant, since the challenge of environmental valuation consists<br />

of admitting that an individual attributes value to resources, even if he or she<br />

does not make any use of them.<br />

The use and non-use of environmental resources imply values, which need<br />

to be measured in order to make informed decisions of the various uses and<br />

non-uses, even when they are conflicting, that is, when one type of use or nonuse<br />

excludes other types of use or non-use. For example, the use of a beach<br />

for dumping sewage excludes (or at least limits) its use for recreation.<br />

Once the uses and non-uses and the respective environmental services<br />

have been identified, we can proceed to valuation, and its methodology will<br />

be presented next.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

The methods of economic valuation of the environment are part of welfare<br />

economics and are necessary in the evaluation of social costs and benefits when<br />

public investments affect the consumption of the population and, consequently,<br />

its level of welfare.<br />

The reader can now evaluate with more clarity the degree of difficulty in<br />

identifying market prices (adequate or not) that reflect the values attributed to


178<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Valuation and pricing<br />

of environmental<br />

resources for a green<br />

economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

environmental resources. This difficulty increases as we move from use values<br />

to non-use values. Among use values, indirect use and option values present,<br />

in turn, even greater difficulties than direct use values.<br />

As we have sought to demonstrate up to now, the task of economically<br />

valuing an environmental resource consists of determining how much better<br />

or worse the welfare of individuals becomes based on changes in the quantity<br />

of environmental goods and services, whether appropriated as use or not.<br />

Consequently, the environmental valuation methods correspond to this<br />

objective based on their capacity to capture these distinct bundles of economic<br />

value of the environmental resource. Nevertheless, as will be discussed below,<br />

each method presents limitations in covering these values that are almost always<br />

associated with the degree of sophistication (methodological and database)<br />

required, and with the assumptions on the individual consumer behavior and<br />

the effects of environmental consumption on other sectors of the economy.<br />

Bearing in mind that such a balance is almost always pragmatic and<br />

determined in a restricted way, it is up to the analyst that evaluates to explain,<br />

with precision, the limits of the estimated values and the degree of validity of<br />

the measurements for the intended end. As will be discussed next, the adoption<br />

of each method depends on the valuation objective, the assumed hypotheses,<br />

the availability of data and knowledge of the ecological dynamics of the object<br />

that is being valued.<br />

The valuation methods analyzed here are classified as follows: production<br />

function methods and demand function methods.<br />

Production function methods: marginal productivity and substitute goods<br />

market methods (replacement, defensive spending or avoided costs and<br />

control costs)<br />

If the environmental resource is an input or a substitute of a private good<br />

or service, these methods utilize market prices for the private good or service<br />

to estimate the economic value of the environmental resource. As such,<br />

the environmental benefits and costs of the varying availability of these<br />

environmental resources to society can be estimated.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Based on the prices of these private resources, generally assuming that they<br />

do not alter against these variations, economic values are indirectly estimated<br />

(shadow prices) of the environmental resources whose varying availability<br />

is being analyzed. The benefit (or cost) of the variation in availability of the<br />

environmental resource is reached by the product of varied quantity of the<br />

resource times its estimated economic value. For example, the soil nutrient<br />

loss caused by deforestation may affect agricultural productivity. Or the reduced<br />

sedimentation levels in a basin, due to a revegetation project, may increase<br />

the life-span and productivity of a hydroelectric plant.


179<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Valuation and pricing<br />

of environmental<br />

resources for a green<br />

economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

Demand function methods: complementary goods market methods (hedonic<br />

prices and travel cost) and the contingent valuation method.<br />

These methods assume that the variation in availability of an environmental<br />

resource alters the willingness of economic agents to pay or receive in relation<br />

to the resource or its complementary private good. Thus, these methods directly<br />

estimate the economic values (shadow prices) based on demand functions<br />

for these resources derived from (i) markets of private goods and services<br />

complementary to the environmental resource or (ii) hypothetical markets<br />

constructed specifically for the environmental resource being analyzed.<br />

Utilizing demand functions, these methods permit the capture measurements<br />

of individual’s willingness to pay (or accept) relative to variations in the<br />

environmental resource availability. Based on these measurements, variations<br />

in the level of welfare are estimated through the excess satisfaction that the<br />

consumer obtains by paying a price (or pays nothing) for the resource below<br />

what he would be willing to pay. The consumer surplus is, thereby, measured<br />

by the area below the demand curve and above the price curve. Thus, there<br />

are variations in consumer surplus relative to variations in the availability of<br />

the environmental resource. Therefore, the benefit (or cost) of the variation<br />

in the availability of the environmental resource will be given by the variation<br />

in consumer surplus measured by the demand function for this resource. For<br />

example, the travel costs that individuals incur to visit a national park could<br />

represent an approximation of the willingness to pay related to the recreational<br />

benefits of the park.<br />

These measurements of willingness to pay can also be identified through<br />

research that asks a sample of the population about the size of a tax aimed<br />

at environmental investments for biodiversity protection with the contingent<br />

valuation method. Identifying these measurements of willingness to pay, we<br />

can construct the respective demand functions.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Note that these two general methods can, in accordance with their<br />

hypotheses, estimate environmental values derived from production or demand<br />

functions based on the current economic condition. So that these values<br />

(costs and benefits) can occur within a time-period, it is necessary to identify<br />

these values in time. That is, identifying values resulting not only from actual<br />

conditions, but also from future conditions. Prospecting future conditions can<br />

be done through alternative scenarios in order to minimize the high degree of<br />

uncertainty. Anyhow, the future values will have to be discounted over time, that<br />

is, calculated in terms of present values utilizing a social discount rate. This rate<br />

differs from the one observed in the market due to capital market imperfections<br />

and its determination is not trivial, even though it can significantly affect the<br />

results of a cost-benefit analysis.


180<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Valuation and pricing<br />

of environmental<br />

resources for a green<br />

economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

In the environmental context, the complexity is even greater. For example,<br />

due to the possibility of exhaustion, the value of environmental resources tend<br />

to grow over time, if we assume that its use increases with economic growth.<br />

Estimating this future scarcity and translating it into a monetary value is a<br />

complex issue that requires a certain exercise of futurology. As such, some<br />

specialists suggest the use of smaller discount rates for projects with significant<br />

environmental benefits or costs or adding the necessary investments to<br />

eliminate environmental risk. It is therefore considered that the environmental<br />

costs and benefits would be adequately valued and that scenarios with distinct<br />

discount rate values should be utilized to evaluate its indetermination.<br />

This complexity will also be reflected when constructing a National System<br />

of Environmental Accounts to measure the national income (GDP), deducing<br />

the amounts that the economy “consumed” (depreciation) or “invested”<br />

(appreciation) in natural capital 5 . In disaggregated levels, Environmental<br />

Accounts approach a cost-benefit analysis, where GDP reflects a measure<br />

of benefit and consumption of natural capital represents the cost. Thus, the<br />

valuation concepts and techniques will be the same as herein discussed 6 .<br />

To summarize, selecting an economic method for valuing the environment<br />

depends on the objective of the valuation, the assumed hypotheses, the<br />

availability of data, and scientific knowledge of the ecological dynamics of the<br />

object in question.<br />

Pr ic in g e n v ir o n m e n t a l g o o d s a n d s e r v i c e s 7<br />

Although internalizing environmental externalities increases the efficiency of<br />

the system, these gains are perceived differently by economic agents and are<br />

dispersed over time. That is, they affect the intra and inter-temporal income<br />

distribution. So how can we internalize this amount in the pricing system so<br />

that consumers can perceive the value?<br />

Economic theory proposes that in order to correct this market failure (“the<br />

tragedy of the commons”), defined user rights would be exchanged in a market<br />

and thereby set an equilibrium price that represents the social cost of these<br />

resources.<br />

This possibility could take the form of a fee for using the natural resource<br />

or through the creation of markets. That is, economic instruments that signal<br />

prices that reflect the social opportunity cost of the resources that, thereby,<br />

internalizes the correct price of the resource in the economic system.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

5. It would be a measure of the net domestic product (NDP) of an economy, represented by<br />

GDP minus the consumption of capital.<br />

6. See for example Seroa da Motta (1995 and 1998b) for a detailed discussion of how to apply<br />

valuation techniques in Environmental Accounts and some estimates of capital consumption<br />

in Brazil.<br />

7. For a more extensive discussion see for example, Hanley, Shogren and White (2007), Seroa<br />

da Motta (2006), UNEP (2000b), Kolstad (2000) and Pearce and Turner (1990).


181<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Valuation and pricing<br />

of environmental<br />

resources for a green<br />

economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

Note that the efficiency gain of an economic instrument is associated with<br />

the heterogeneity of control or use costs among economic agents. This cost<br />

differentiation makes individual decisions more flexible when comparing the<br />

amount charged or the right to issue or use with the control or usage costs.<br />

This leads to users with smaller control costs to control more at lower costs<br />

than what is collected or earned by selling rights.<br />

Nevertheless, these efficiency gains cannot be canceled by high transaction<br />

costs (of information or implementation), whether through collection or the<br />

creation of markets. When this occurs, introducing economic instruments<br />

should be avoided.<br />

Ch a r g in g<br />

Theoretically a pigouvian tax is equivalent to the marginal environmental<br />

damage that allows an economic optimal degradation to be reached. Such<br />

nomenclature was formulated by the economist Arthur Cecil Pigou, who<br />

formulated it for the first time during the 1920s of the past century.<br />

This tax adopts the economically optimal level of resource use criteria where<br />

negative externalities, such as environmental damage, are internalized in the<br />

resource price both in the production process as well as consumption. Once this<br />

new externality price is determined and imposed on each user, aggregated to<br />

its market price, each level of individual use is altered as well as the aggregate<br />

level of use.<br />

In this way, the new levels reflect a socially optimized use, because now the<br />

benefits of use are counterbalanced by all the associated costs, that is, each<br />

user pays for exactly the damage caused by his or her use. The calculation of<br />

this tax does not exist in practice, given the difficulties of precisely measuring<br />

environmental damage, as discussed in the previous section.<br />

The optimal level of use is determined in the political process by the affected<br />

social agents, and from there payment levels for use of the natural resource<br />

are derived. In these cases, the economic price can be of two types: induction<br />

price and fianacing price; each one with its distinct criteria that generates also<br />

distinct values, but both aiming to reduce negative externalities.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Induction price: the new price of the resource is determined to obtain<br />

a certain aggregate level of technically adequate use (and not aggregate<br />

revenue). It is determined so that the sum of the induced change in individual<br />

use results in a new desired aggregate level. As such, the estimate should<br />

be based on simulations to identify how individuals would alter their resource<br />

use against different prices. The induction price is related to the “polluter/user<br />

pays” principle 8 .<br />

8. In the ex-ante conception, the user perceives the damage payment before the act of using.<br />

The ex-post formulation is more associated with repairing the damage through judicial means<br />

after the user has generated damage.


182<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Valuation and pricing<br />

of environmental<br />

resources for a green<br />

economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

For example, this would be the case of charging for water to induce an<br />

aggregate reduction in use by X% or a fee that encourages an increase in<br />

certification of Y%.<br />

Determining the induction price is based on demand or cost functions of each<br />

user, differentiating the prices in order to induce users in the aggregate to obtain<br />

a level of desired use. The general rule for this price differentiation would be a<br />

higher price for the most price-sensitive users (greater price elasticity). This is<br />

because those are the users that will reduce their use the most for each unit<br />

of price increase.<br />

Fianancing price: adopts the criterion of optimal financing levels where the<br />

price is determined to obtain a desired level of revenue. As such, the financing<br />

price is associated with a predetermined budget and not with a desired level of<br />

resource use. Its application is associated with the “protector-receiver principle”,<br />

such as, charging for resource use to generate the revenue that is necessary for<br />

a determined investment in a conservation unit or payments for environmental<br />

services expenditures. 9<br />

Contrary to the induction price, the general rule for price differentiation would<br />

be a lower price for the most price-sensitive users (greater price elasticity). This<br />

is because these users would be the ones to reduce most their use for each<br />

additional unit increase in price and, consequently, reducing revenues.<br />

To summarize, the financing price aims to attain an aggregate revenue target<br />

and the induction price, instead of aiming for a certain total revenue, seeks to<br />

alter the level of individual use. Whatever its form is, the economic instrument<br />

always represents an economic price of the negative externalities.<br />

Ma r k e t Cr e a t io n<br />

Another pricing possibility is the creation of a market of transferable rights<br />

of usage or to pollute.<br />

In these markets, rights to use or pollute are distributed or sold in a way that<br />

in the aggregate the desired levels of use or pollution are no exceeded. Once<br />

the initial allocation is realized, levels of use or pollution above the individual<br />

quotas would require the transaction of these rights between users/polluters.<br />

For example, the user/polluter that has the highest control costs would have<br />

incentives to buy quotas from those will lower costs.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Note that it is the absence of (or difficulty in signaling) complete property<br />

rights for environmental resources that makes their usage less efficient. In<br />

the case that specifying complete rights were possible, a negotiation between<br />

users could take place in order for uses with greater returns (more efficient)<br />

9. In the economic literature this price would adopt the “Ramsey rule”, named after its first<br />

proponent.


183<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Valuation and pricing<br />

of environmental<br />

resources for a green<br />

economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

to be prioritized, that is, the exchange of rights in the market would induce<br />

users that most benefitted from its use (or with smaller costs) to pay more for<br />

the rights. The terms of negotiation would be based on the costs and benefits<br />

perceived by the parties.<br />

However, for a market of rights to exist, the property rights would need to<br />

be clearly defined and there would need to be a great number of participants<br />

with different costs and benefits, buying and selling in the market. On the<br />

other hand, an institutionalized, diversified and fragmented market requires<br />

sophisticated institutional and legal support. Thus, we must look into these<br />

three qualifying principles:<br />

a) initial allocation: the rights could be initially allocated in a way that (i) is<br />

neutral in the proportion to current levels of use or pollution 10 ; (ii) has distributive<br />

criteria with greater allocations to some segments of society; and in both<br />

cases the allocation could either be free or achieved through an auction that<br />

generates revenue. In the case of an auction, each user/polluter would pay for<br />

the quotas in accordance with their value for that specific activity. In the case<br />

of free distribution, distributive issues would need to be addressed given that<br />

holders would consider these rights a real source of costs and benefits.<br />

b) imperfect information: government and users/polluters would not be<br />

perfectly informed about the level of use or pollution of the resource and the<br />

associated costs. Thus, the transaction costs of these rights would be greatly<br />

elevated and the transaction levels lower, and consequently less efficient.<br />

Though such imperfection could be mitigated in future markets, the management<br />

of such a system is complex to implement comprehensively in extensive regions<br />

with large varieties of users/polluters; and<br />

c)market power: users or polluters with market power 11 tend to manipulate<br />

the purchase of rights to create barriers of entry for competitors (or regional<br />

competition) or engage in price arbitrage aimed at abnormal profit. Such<br />

imperfections could be corrected through limits of use or emissions per user, or<br />

transfer restrictions, though this would complicate management by demanding<br />

an extensive range of information from principal users.<br />

To summarize, the pricing of an environmental resource generates an<br />

immediate dividend for society by increasing environmental efficiency. But<br />

there is also an additional efficiency gain, a second dividend, in the possibility<br />

of improving the economic efficiency of taxation through the substitution of the<br />

distorted tax revenueon consumption and capital, for revenues resulting from<br />

environmental taxation or revenues generated by user rights.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

10. “Grandfather system”.<br />

11. Oligopolistic or oligopsonic.


184<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Thus, a tax reform where environmental taxation is introduced and the<br />

revenue is used to finance reductions in other taxes generates a so-called<br />

double dividend. In this case, the fiscal recycling permits an environmental<br />

tax of neutral revenue that reduces environmental degradation and improves<br />

economic efficiency by reducing the distorting tax load.<br />

Valuation and pricing<br />

of environmental<br />

resources for a green<br />

economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

Fin a l Re m a r k s<br />

An ecological evaluation should precede any initiative of applying economic<br />

criteria, as it is critical for determining how the environmental services are<br />

correlated with the stock levels of natural capital. Thus, the use of economic<br />

criteria requires explicitly stated ecological impacts (physicochemical and<br />

biological) to guide the application.<br />

An additional limitation in the use of economic criteria is associated with<br />

determining discounts over time of costs and benefits, since the type and value<br />

of the discount rate depend on hypotheses about future growth in consumption<br />

and future alterations in individual preferences. The exercise of capturing<br />

values associated with future generations carries a degree of uncertainty and,<br />

consequently, cannot be estimated deterministically. As such, we must consider<br />

a sensitivity analysis of the results from different discount rates.<br />

We must also identify the sensitivity of various distinct statistical models in<br />

the estimation of ecological impacts as well as in economic measurements.<br />

Lastly, it is worth noting that the magnitude of the environmental impact of a<br />

specific sector could be significant enough to affect other sectors in its supply<br />

chain. That is, if there is evidence of significant inter-sectoral effects, these<br />

sectoral relations in the economy must be considered and captured through<br />

general equilibrium models. 12 Impacts do not always have this extension 13<br />

, but it is worthwhile to highlight that these general equilibrium models require<br />

a high level of statistical and database sophistication.<br />

The valuation and pricing of environmental resources do not only identify total<br />

costs and benefits, but also, if not principally, how these are distributed within<br />

society (i.e., who is bearing the costs and who receives the benefits).<br />

This process of valuation and pricing, thus, is very important because it guides<br />

decision-makers in finding ways to conciliate other alternatives that harmonize<br />

this distribution of gains and losses and, from this point, construct consensus<br />

and stimulate participation, support and commitment among various economic<br />

regulators in the construction of the basis for a green economy.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

12. A more simplified version of this model is an input-output matrix where the elasticities of<br />

substitution are null. A general equilibrium model abandons this hypothesis with specific<br />

estimates of elasticities for each activity, as well as adopting technical coefficients of a matrix<br />

for production and consumption functions.<br />

13. As generally occurs, for example, in climate change impacts where analysts almost always<br />

use such models.


185<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Valuation and pricing<br />

of environmental<br />

resources for a green<br />

economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

References<br />

Freeman, A. M. (1993). The measurement of environmental and resource values.<br />

Washington: Resources for the Future.<br />

Hanley, N., Shogren, J. F. and White, B. (2007). Environmental economics in theory<br />

and practice. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 2a. ed.<br />

Kolstad, C. D. (2000). Environmental economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.<br />

MEA (2005). Millennium ecosystem assessment, general synthesis report. Washington:<br />

Island Press.<br />

Pearce, D. W. and Turner, K. R. (1990). Economics of natural resources and the environment.<br />

Nova York: Harvester Wheatsheaf.<br />

Seroa da Motta, R. (coord.) (1995). Contabilidade Ambiental: Teoria, Metodologia e<br />

Estudos de Casos no Brasil. Rio de Janeiro: IPEA.<br />

Seroa da Motta, R. (1998a). Manual para valoração econômica de recursos ambientais.<br />

Brasília: Ministério do Meio Ambiente.<br />

Seroa da Motta, R. (1998b). Sustainability principles and depreciation estimates of<br />

natural capital in Brazil. In Faucheux, S; O’Connor, M. and van Straaten, J (eds.),<br />

Sustainable Development: Concepts, Rationalities and Strategies. Amsterdam:<br />

Kluwer Academic Publishers.<br />

Seroa da Motta, R. (2006). Economia ambiental. Rio de Janeiro: FGV Editora.<br />

TEEB (2011). The economics of ecosystems and biodiversity: mainstreaming the economics<br />

of nature: a synthesis of the approach, conclusions and recommendations<br />

of TEEB.<br />

UNEP (2011). Towards a green economy: pathways to sustainable development and<br />

poverty eradication - a synthesis for policy makers. Retrieved from: .<br />

UNEP (2000a). Environmental valuation - a worldwide compendium of case studies.<br />

UNEP.<br />

UNEP (2000b). Economic instruments for environmental management - A worldwide<br />

compendium of case studies. UNEP.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

13. As generally occurs, for example, in climate change impacts where analysts almost always<br />

use such models.


186<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The role of financial<br />

institutions in the transition<br />

to a green economy<br />

Mário Sérgio Vasconcelos 1<br />

The debate began to take shape in the 1970s and intensified at the turn of<br />

the century: there must be a limit to growth, since the economy is part of a<br />

system, planet Earth, whose equilibrium must be respected in the exploitation<br />

of its resources. The disruption of this equilibrium does not interest anyone<br />

in the long term. Therefore, the great forefront of sustainability is perhaps<br />

addressing how companies ought to take this context into account in their<br />

business models.<br />

Furthermore: a company’s good results do not guarantee the continuity of<br />

its business per se. More than just the bottom line of balance sheets, investors<br />

and society increasingly want to know what actions were necessary in order<br />

to achieve such results. In other words, sustainability is an integrated part of<br />

management and not a mere addendum.<br />

To financial institutions, the concern with sustainable development began<br />

in the 1980s. However, it was in the 1990s that the subject gained greater<br />

response, culminating in the launch of the Equator Principles, discussed<br />

below. Since then, a series of voluntary commitments, self-regulations and<br />

regulations have been encouraging banks to assume a sustainable role and<br />

include sustainability concepts in their management.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

During the past decade, Brazilian financial institutions have adopted a series<br />

of practices aimed at incorporating sustainable elements into their activities,<br />

which transformed Brazil into a unique case among emerging countries, where<br />

institutions manage projects of environmental improvements related to their<br />

operations, promote community environmental education, and hire a growing<br />

number of staff specialized in environmental risk and opportunities. Many<br />

institutions consider socio-environmental aspects in credit approvals, promote<br />

training on socio-environmental issues related to business management for<br />

internal auditors and relationship managers of different divisions, such as<br />

wholesale business, asset management and compliance. Training managers<br />

and analysts to disseminate the socio-environmental risk policy and promoting<br />

the evaluation of socio-environmental risk in the entire credit area, is another<br />

1. Director of institutional relations at Brazilian Federation of Banks (FEBRABAN).


187<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The role of financial<br />

institutions in the<br />

transition to a<br />

green economy<br />

Mário Sérgio Vasconcelos<br />

common practice. Its objective is concerned with instructing teams to identify<br />

risks in economic groups and sectors considered critical, such as those related<br />

to the petroleum, chemicals, petrochemicals, pulp and steel.<br />

Brazilian banks have been aware of socio-environmental responsibility<br />

issues throughout the decade and massively adhered to international and<br />

national pacts. This adhesion is connected to the institutional positioning of<br />

the businesses, to the recognition of the importance of these pacts, to ethical<br />

posture, reputation and image. Some examples of these commitments, assumed<br />

gradually and to different extents by various Brazilian banks, are:<br />

• Equator Principles: launched in 2002 by ten of the world’s largest banks in<br />

project financing. They establish minimum criteria for credit extension to projects<br />

that require investments above R$ 10 million, to ensure that financed projects<br />

are developed in a socially and environmentally sustainable manner;<br />

• Global Compact: officially launched by the United Nations in 2000.<br />

Encourages businesses to adopt policies of corporate social responsibility<br />

and sustainability, and guides organizations in redefining their strategies and<br />

activities through ten principles in the areas of human rights, labor, environment<br />

and anti-corruption;<br />

• United Nations Environment Programme Finance Initiative (UNEP FI):<br />

a partnership between UNEP and the global financial sector, enacted since<br />

1991, whose mission is identifying and promoting practical improvements<br />

related to sustainability. All members sign a declaration through which they<br />

commit themselves to increasingly integrate sustainable development in their<br />

operations;<br />

• Millennium Development Goals (MDG): the Millennium Development<br />

Goals (MDG) establish commitments approved by leaders from 191 United<br />

Nations member-states in 2000. There are eight millennium goals: to eradicate<br />

extreme poverty and hunger, achieve universal primary education, promote<br />

gender equality and empower women, reduce child mortality, improve maternal<br />

health, combat HIV/AIDS, malaria and other diseases, ensure environmental<br />

sustainability and establish a Global Partnership for Development. Collective<br />

efforts should guarantee the fulfillment of these objectives by 2015;<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

• Principles for Responsible Investment (PRI): one of the achievements<br />

of UNEP FI, in conjunction with the Global Compact, was the creation of<br />

the Principles of Responsible Investment (PRI) in 2006. The objective of<br />

this initiative is for investors all over the world to voluntarily incorporate<br />

environmental, social and corporate governance aspects at the time that their<br />

applications are executed. By April 2011, more than 850 investment institutions<br />

have become signatories;<br />

• Business Pact for Integrity and Against Corruption: launched in<br />

2006 during the Ethos International Conference, the pact contains a set of


188<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The role of financial<br />

institutions in the<br />

transition to a<br />

green economy<br />

Mário Sérgio Vasconcelos<br />

suggestions, directives and proceedings to be adopted by businesses and<br />

entities in their relations with government;<br />

• National Pact to Eradicate Slave Labor in Brazil: created in May 2005,<br />

the pact is coordinated and monitored by the Ethos Institute of Business and<br />

Social Responsibility, the Social Observatory Institute, the Brazil Reporter NGO<br />

and by the International Labor Organization. Its mission is to implement tools<br />

that inhibit the business sector and Brazilian society to market products from<br />

producers that utilize slave labor;<br />

• Carbon Disclosure Project (CDP): is a collective petition formulated by<br />

a group of 534 institutional investors responsible for the administration of an<br />

estimated US$ 64 trillion worth of assets. The project was designed so that<br />

businesses and investors all over the world would have access to information<br />

about the impacts caused by greenhouse gas emissions and climate change<br />

on company results. CDP is coordinated by a non-profit entity financed by<br />

the British government’s Carbon Trust, and a group of foundations led by the<br />

Rockefeller Foundation.<br />

The Green Protocol<br />

A more concrete step in the commitment of Brazilian private banks<br />

to sustainable finances was taken in April 2009, with the adoption of a<br />

protocol of intent by the Brazilian Bank Federation (FEBRABAN) and the<br />

Ministry of the Environment, known as the Green Protocol. The protocol is<br />

a fruit of the common effort to adopt socio-environmental policies that are<br />

precursory, multiplicative, demonstrative or examples of banking practices,<br />

and that are in harmony with the objective of promoting sustainable<br />

development.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

To construct and implement a common sustainability agenda in the<br />

sector that is aligned with the principles and directives of the Green<br />

Protocol, FEBRABAN, with support from the Getulio Vargas Foundation<br />

(FGV), began the construction of a matrix of sustainability indicators for<br />

financial institutions in 2009. In addition to creating its own indicators,<br />

the project draws inspiration from other existing and recognized<br />

references in the market, such as the Global Reporting Initiative’s (GRI)<br />

financial services sector supplement, the Ethos/FEBRABAN indicators<br />

and the Securities, Commodities and Futures Exchange of Sao Paulo<br />

(BM&FBovespa) Business Sustainability Index (ISE) evaluation<br />

questionnaire. Besides the participation of associated banks, this process<br />

of collective construction counts on collaboration with representatives of<br />

civil society organizations.


189<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The role of financial<br />

institutions in the<br />

transition to a<br />

green economy<br />

Mário Sérgio Vasconcelos<br />

The objective is to offer a management tool that plots a diagnosis of<br />

individual and sectoral performances, which evaluates the contribution<br />

of banks to wealth generation that takes sustainability into account. The<br />

matrix is also intended to serve as an instrument of communicating with<br />

and accounting for society, including the development of new products<br />

and services that contribute to the rapid transition to a green and more<br />

inclusive economy. Banks should individually confirm their commitments to<br />

the directives of the Green Protocol. In 2009, the State Bank of Rio Grande<br />

do Sul, BIC Banco, Banco Sofisa, Banco Votorantim, Bancoob, BNP<br />

Paribas Brasil, Banrisul, Bradesco, Cacique, Citi, HSBC, Itaú Unibanco,<br />

Safra and Santander Brasil became signatories of the document.<br />

Various banks have also offered products focused on financing schemes,<br />

investment funds and loyalty cards with fees going to NGOs dedicated to<br />

environmental issues. The equity funds of the businesses that compose the<br />

Business Sustainability Index (ISE) are emblematic, as well as the financing<br />

programs for environmental conservation and recuperation that aim to improve<br />

and recuperate degraded legal reserves and permanent preservation areas.<br />

The progress of these “green” funds reveals the effectiveness and<br />

competence of businesses that adopt sustainable practices. In 2010, a weak<br />

year on the stock exchanges, funds registered as sustainable and governed<br />

by the Brazilian Association of Financial and Capital Market Entities (Anbima,<br />

representing 340 institutions acting in the financial and capital markets)<br />

presented an appreciation in quotations of 7.96%, compared to the 1.04%<br />

appreciation of the Stock Exchange Index.<br />

In the area of credit and financing, new environmental lines were created for<br />

financing reforestation, development of agroforestry systems and investment in<br />

renewable energy. Banks also offer credit lines for the acquisition of machinery<br />

and equipment at reduced interest rates for businesses that seek to develop<br />

cleaner production processes. To reduce environmental impacts, there are<br />

also programs aimed at remediation of hydrographic basins, environmental<br />

compensation, implementation and maintenance of Conservation Units,<br />

biodiesel use and organic production.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

To evaluate and classify the socio-environmental risks of business lines, the<br />

most common tool used by banks is the socio-environmental questionnaire,<br />

which includes checking information related to compliance, environmental<br />

licensing requirements and site visits. There are banks that expand these<br />

evaluations by analyzing the potential socio-environmental risks of the client,<br />

sector or project, through practice management by specialized teams that<br />

carry out research of public information, consulting and independent audits


190<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The role of financial<br />

institutions in the<br />

transition to a<br />

green economy<br />

Mário Sérgio Vasconcelos<br />

and, when necessary, through technical assistance for the financing of socioenvironmental<br />

improvements.<br />

To ensure that the client is in fact complying with the socio-environmental<br />

requirements stated in the contract, banks carry out environmental audits,<br />

technical visits, property evaluations, monitoring of credit portfolios and project<br />

reevaluations. Despite all these practices, the auditing process of socioenvironmental<br />

policies and risks is a challenge to the sector. Most banks do not<br />

carry out verifications focused on sustainability, but intend to implement it over<br />

the coming years. The objective is to prevent risks and promote the adoption<br />

of best practices among clients.<br />

Meanwhile, some banks have already developed this process for certain<br />

project lines, based on the Equator Principles. The emphasis is on the<br />

periodic application of the socio-environmental risk policy to the credit of a<br />

legal entity, under the technical supervision of the internal audit committee<br />

and the application of effectiveness tests. The results of these evaluations are<br />

reported to main executives, such as members of the board of directors and<br />

the sustainability committee.<br />

Training and engaging professionals in socio-environmental policies is<br />

another challenge to the incorporation and evaluation of sustainability criteria,<br />

and thus has become a strategic goal of business areas within banks. Among<br />

the main existing initiatives is conceptual and analytical socio-environmental risk<br />

training for relationship managers, internal auditors and analysts. However, a<br />

majority of banks have set objectives to expand training provisions to a greater<br />

portion of the internal public.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

It should be highlighted that this movement is not based on a do-gooder<br />

ethos, because risk and the management of risk, is at the core of the financial<br />

business. And environmental risk has an effective and growing impact on the<br />

four large risks faced by banking institutions – market risk, legal risk, operational,<br />

and most importantly, reputation risk. Reputation is perhaps the greatest asset<br />

of businesses that deal with an activity – financial intermediation – where trust<br />

and credibility are the difference between life and death. Just remember that<br />

the word credit comes from the Latin credere, believe, trust. During the last<br />

crisis, images of clients camping outside the UK bank Northern Rock circled the<br />

world, similar to the faded photos of the old bank runs so common in the 19th<br />

century and the beginning of the 20th century. Moreover, it is not by accident<br />

that research carried out by the consulting firm Accenture of senior executives<br />

around the world, revealed that 72% of those interviewed highlighted the<br />

importance of visible and authentic commitments to sustainability as an urgent<br />

necessity, in order to reconquer the confidence and reconstruct the reputation<br />

shattered by the international financial crisis.<br />

One example, however, illustrates the size of the role played by financial<br />

institutions as inducers of good practices in the sectors where they invest and


191<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

The role of financial<br />

institutions in the<br />

transition to a<br />

green economy<br />

Mário Sérgio Vasconcelos<br />

finance: the media increasingly holds banks co-responsible for the projects<br />

that they finance, such as the case of Belo Monte hydroelectric power plant.<br />

The whole world is looking at Brazil and wondering: how are the local and<br />

indigenous communities being treated? Are the environmental impacts being<br />

considered? This leads to the following question: are the business members<br />

of the consortium taking appropriate action? And finally: how are the banks<br />

positioning themselves in relation to all this?<br />

Just by this example we can assess the immense responsibility and why a<br />

proactive posture is decisive. Especially as many markets are being put in check<br />

nowadays. The energy model is one example, and we already observe how<br />

universities, research institutes and businesses are working to discover new<br />

technologies. The inclusion of the base of the pyramid is also challenging and<br />

large and small organizations are already positioning themselves and offering<br />

innovative solutions. Among the innumerable new companies that are surfacing,<br />

there are certainly embryos of large businesses that will be very profitable in<br />

ten years. The banks should be the propellants of these waves; they should<br />

understand the trends, promote, invest and finance these types of businesses,<br />

and thereby inducing the process of transitioning to a new economy.<br />

Leaders of financial institutions must be ready to take this turn. Presently<br />

Bloomberg and Reuters, for example, are creating mechanisms to help<br />

analysts in considering environmental, social and governance variables. But it<br />

is necessary to go farther. Each bank must recognize the impact of its portfolio<br />

of clients and have a strategic plan to make this transition. Being close to<br />

universities or incubators, for example, will help to identify the trends.<br />

All this to say that it is no longer suitable for banks to play a passive and<br />

purely monitoring role, but rather an active role of identifying entrepreneurs,<br />

technologies and new business models. Only then will we have a positive<br />

balance for all parts.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011


192<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Measurement in policies<br />

for transition to a green<br />

economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta 1<br />

Carolina Burle Schmidt Dubeux 2<br />

In t r o d u c t io n<br />

The report “Towards a green economy: pathways to sustainable development<br />

and poverty eradication”, produced by the United Nations Environment<br />

Programme (UNEP, 2011), seeks to demonstrate that sustainable development<br />

can be reached without losses in income and employment, or increases in<br />

poverty. Along these lines, the report models the macroeconomic effects<br />

(income, employment and consumption) of a green economy.<br />

The results of the growth models adopted in the report estimate that in the<br />

medium term (in the spam time of six years) investments in natural capital, in<br />

the magnitude of 2% of the global GDP between 2011 and 2050, will generate<br />

growth in clean sectors that would more than compensate the income and job<br />

losses in the constricting brown sectors. And that these investments also reduce<br />

the poverty levels of those that depend directly on environmental services. The<br />

green economy concept is not a substitute for sustainable development, but<br />

rather, instrumental to it.<br />

Financing these investments in a sustained manner requires regulations that<br />

cut perverse subsidies and the pricing of environmental goods and services,<br />

as well as a system of environmental indicators.<br />

In the following section we will discuss how sustainability theory incorporates<br />

the principles of a green economy. Lastly, we will outline briefly the basic<br />

strategies for the construction of a green economy in Brazil.<br />

Su s t a in a b il it y a n d g r e e n e c o n o m y 3<br />

The sustainable development concept was formally adopted in the Brundtland<br />

report (World Commission on Environment and Development, 1987) 4 . This<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

1. Senior Researcher at the Research Institute for Applied Economics (IPEA) and member of<br />

the IPCC 3rd and 5th Assessment Reports.<br />

2. Researcher at the Center for Integrated Studies on Environment and Climate Change (Centro<br />

Clima/COPPE/UFRJ) and member of the 5th Assessment Report..<br />

3. This section was based on Seroa da Motta (2011).<br />

4. The idea of making economic growth and nature compatible was already a recurrent theme<br />

before the publication of the Brundtland report, but the report was most successful in<br />

formalizing it.


193<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Measurement in<br />

policies for transition<br />

to a green economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

Carolina Dubeux<br />

document definitively introduced the idea that economic development should<br />

be undertaken without compromising the economic development of future<br />

generations.<br />

In a rather simplified way, the novelty of this approach of sustainable<br />

development, resides in the inclusion of an environmental dimension to the<br />

models of economic growth.<br />

The sustainability of economic growth was always a central question in<br />

development models. However, the development models adopted by countries<br />

over the past fifty years, only exceptionally referred to environmental issues<br />

as a restriction. The natural basis for the planning strategies was considered<br />

infinite, that is, as a capital factor without scarcity restrictions.<br />

Although the natural basis is intrinsically associated with the comparative<br />

advantages of economies in their international insertion, and closely associated<br />

with the subsistence activities of the poorest segments of the population, as in<br />

the majority of developing countries, there are few references to environmental<br />

issues in the economic development literature.<br />

Despite the finitude of these resources posing as an obstacle to the adopted<br />

development trajectory and generating significant social problems, the<br />

perception of scarcity does not exist in the design of these models. 5<br />

The sustainable development concept, though it may have several<br />

descriptions and its utilization in the communications media generally occurs in<br />

vague contexts, can be discussed objectively the same way that sustainability of<br />

economic growth is discussed when considering the importance of maintaining<br />

non-declining asset values in an economy. That is, sustainability in an economy<br />

occurs when its capital stock, that defines the future flow of goods and services,<br />

is maintained at least constant.<br />

The current sustainability issue only introduces the necessity of treating<br />

natural capital differently from material capital. A differentiation with a theoretic<br />

and methodological basis similar to that which introduced the theory of human<br />

and technological capital into these same models.<br />

The economic growth models developed in the 70’s, that analyzed the<br />

inter-temporal optimization of natural resources in production 6 , depended on<br />

hypotheses about the essentiality of resources and their impacts on the levels<br />

of growth in the economy.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

According to Perrings et al. (1995), the essentiality of environmental resources<br />

can be analyzed by the degree of complementarity and substitution between<br />

natural capital and material capital among the possibilities of production and<br />

consumption in an economy. That is, the elasticity of substitution between these<br />

5. See for example, Dasgupta and Maller (1996) for an analysis of this gap in the literature.<br />

6. See Hartwick (1977), Solow (1978) and Dasgupta and Heal (1979).


194<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Measurement in<br />

policies for transition<br />

to a green economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

Carolina Dubeux<br />

two types of capital is what defines the degree of essentiality. The greater the<br />

elasticity of substitution, the less essential is the resource.<br />

In traditional models, it is assumed that the elasticity of substitution is greater<br />

than or equal to one. That is, the level of natural capital stock may decrease<br />

as long as the economy can make the compensatory investments in material<br />

capital.<br />

This is the well-known Solow-Hartwick rule, in which the sustainability of<br />

an economy, understood as the capacity of an economy to maintain a certain<br />

level of consumption, is determined by the capacity to avoid that revenues<br />

generated through the exploitation of non-renewable natural resources is<br />

wholly transformed into present consumption. Thus, it would suffice to reinvest<br />

part of the revenue generated from the exploitation of natural resources in the<br />

formation of capital, whether material or natural, equivalent to the consumption<br />

of natural capital 7 .<br />

According to these models, maintaining the total stock of capital “constant”<br />

over time is what matters in order to maximize welfare. 8<br />

Thus, environmental issues are not considered as relevant or restrictive to<br />

growth. What matters is the political capacity to immobilize part of the income<br />

resulting from the exploitation of natural resources.<br />

However, the capacity of ecosystems to generate services depends on<br />

maintaining certain ecosystem components, such as the population and food<br />

chain, within specific limits. Once these limits are surpassed, the ecosystem<br />

could enter into a collapse and its productivity become null. The definition of<br />

these limits identifies the limits to growth and, consequently, determines the<br />

sustainable growth trajectory of an economy.<br />

As such, it is prudent to identify the minimum secure levels or support capacities<br />

of the natural resources that are being utilized for the generation of revenue.<br />

Thereby we can define the critical natural capital as that where the level of<br />

consumption already exceeds its support capacity, and therefore productivity<br />

declines to zero. In these cases, the elasticity of substitution is less than one<br />

and the possibilities to substitute between natural and material capital tend to<br />

decline when the product grows.<br />

In these critical cases, a declining level of natural stock represents a nonsustainable<br />

trajectory and losses in welfare should be considered. Thus the<br />

consumption of this capital has to be negative, that is, it should be appreciated<br />

and not depreciated.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

7. That is, the environmental costs are inferior to the resultant benefits or income generation<br />

could compensate or recuperate environmental losses and still add aggregate value to the<br />

economy.<br />

8. Beyond other restrictive hypotheses, such as: valuation of capital over time and a fixed<br />

discount rate over time.


195<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Measurement in<br />

policies for transition<br />

to a green economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

Carolina Dubeux<br />

The non-critical natural capital would be that where the stock level still has<br />

not reached its support capacity. In the meanwhile, this does not imply that<br />

the capital does not have a minimal level of security below which it becomes<br />

critical.<br />

However, the consumption of this capital can be compensated by investments<br />

in material capital without losses to welfare. Whether it be investing in the<br />

recuperation of rivers, contaminated areas or in controlling impacts, as in the<br />

case of climate change through mitigation and adaptation efforts.<br />

The hypothesis of very weak sustainability, “economic growth without<br />

environmental restrictions”, assumes that substitution possibilities are infinite,<br />

as long as the total capital stock in the economy does not decline. On the other<br />

extreme, the hypothesis of strong sustainability, of “zero growth”, assumes that<br />

there are no more substitution possibilities, since all forms of natural capital<br />

are critical and no more natural capital should be consumed.<br />

Intermediately is the hypothesis of weak sustainability, which distinguishes<br />

between the critical and non-critical forms of natural capital and determines<br />

differentiated treatments in accordance with the critical levels of identified stock.<br />

In this approach, technological progress is considered an agent of sustainability<br />

when it reduces the intensity of environmental consumption.<br />

Ultimately, sustainability would be possible with greater environmental<br />

efficiency resulting from (i) changes in production processes and product<br />

designs; (ii) changes in the structure of production and consumption; and (iii)<br />

reductions in the levels of production and consumption.<br />

In this spectrum, the green economy is characterized by a continuous<br />

increase in natural capital, that is, an appreciation and not a depreciation.<br />

This would enable lower levels of material intensity and less pollution per unit<br />

of revenue, which in turn would induce “detachment” / “decoupling”, or the<br />

separation of economic activity from environmental impacts.<br />

This proposition holds that economic policies aimed at natural capital<br />

can accelerate this detachment without reducing levels of consumption and<br />

production. To a certain extent, this possibility opposes that which claims that<br />

decoupling occurs spontaneously within the economic growth process when<br />

the economy reaches a threshold in income levels (Environmental Kuznets<br />

Curve – EKC) 9 .<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Presently, the challenge to constructing a green economy is creating<br />

institutional capacity to integrate environmental policies with economic policies,<br />

and a system of environmental indicators capable of measuring and monitoring<br />

the benefits of natural capital investments.<br />

9. See a critical revision of the EKC in Galeotti, Manera and Lanza (2009).


196<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Measurement in<br />

policies for transition<br />

to a green economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

Carolina Dubeux<br />

Go v e r n a n c e s t r a t e g i e s in a g r e e n e c o n o m y<br />

In the previous sections we have seen that in accordance with the theoretical<br />

economic assumptions, the appreciation of natural capital does not necessarily<br />

reduce the efficiency of an economy. Or better yet, the environmental costs<br />

generated by the inefficient exploitation of environmental resources reduce<br />

growth possibilities.<br />

Challenging conventional wisdom, environmental cost is not associated with<br />

poverty, but rather on the contrary, poverty is part of the environmental cost. It is<br />

common to observe constant references in the literature to population pressures<br />

on the environment 10 and that poverty exacerbates the pressure on the natural<br />

base of economies and thereby amplifies the environmental crisis. Evidence of<br />

this positive relation between poverty and degradation have been contested in<br />

the literature that measures the relationship between income and degradation in<br />

light of the environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis (see for example Heerink,<br />

Mulatu and Bulte, 2001) and Environmental Justice (see Acselrad, Herculano<br />

and Pádua, 2004 and Shepard and Cobin-Mark, 2009).<br />

For example, the lower consumption levels of the low-income population,<br />

especially of energy, generate low levels of greenhouse gases. Reports by the<br />

IPCC 11 , on the other hand, confirm that the lacking earnings capacity of this<br />

population results in a low adaptation capacity and that they will suffer most<br />

from the impacts of climate change.<br />

Seroa da Motta (2004) measures the contributions by income-level to water<br />

and air pollution in Brazil, and finds that the great concentration of degradation<br />

pressure comes from the consumption patterns of the richest people, which adds<br />

yet another negative aspect to the unequal distribution of income in Brazil.<br />

That is, degradation pressure comes mainly from the consumption patterns<br />

of the highest income classes, and relaxing environmental controls indirectly<br />

creates a subsidy for the consumption of the rich at the expense of the poor.<br />

Thus, the distribution of costs and benefits of environmental controls should<br />

be equitable. And the environmental issue can stop being a problem and instead<br />

turn into a solution. As such, it would be necessary to consolidate the real<br />

life scenarios previously described and design policy options that harmonize<br />

environmental and economic policies. Next, we will elaborate on some of these<br />

options, namely: systematizing environmental indicators, amplifying economic<br />

instruments and removing perverse incentives.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

10. This hypothesis stems from the seminal work of Ehrlich (1968), who introduces the concept<br />

of environmental risk due to population pressure, which became known as the “neomalthusian”<br />

thesis.<br />

11. See for example IPCC (2007).


197<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Measurement in<br />

policies for transition<br />

to a green economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

Carolina Dubeux<br />

Sy s t e m a t i z i n g e n v ir o n m e n t a l in d ic a t o r s<br />

The economic and ecological magnitudes of environmental issues are distinct<br />

and their relative importance must be outlined. Therefore, it is necessary to<br />

prioritize the objectives of political actions to construct a green economy.<br />

However, such efforts must come from inside the planning system with the<br />

objective of generating physiochemical indicators that evaluate the patterns of<br />

environmental resource use, associated with economic and social indicators<br />

that evaluate their connections to the real economy. 12<br />

A report by the Stiglitz-Sen-Fitoussi Commission that details an<br />

extensive analysis of measurements of economic performance and social<br />

progress, reveals that actions taken by decision-makers depend on what is<br />

measured, of how good the measurements are and how well the measurements<br />

are understood 13 .<br />

Essentials conditions to realize these initiatives are: a) the creation of<br />

an environmental statistics system that includes environmental indicators; and<br />

b) the establishment of a relationship between these and traditional economic<br />

and social indicators.<br />

Environmental indicators can reflect the pressure of economic activities<br />

(production and consumption) on the environment (such as, greenhouse gas<br />

emissions, consumption of renewable energy and deforestation rates) or the<br />

state of the environment (such as, concentration of pollutants in the atmosphere<br />

and water resources and levels of species extinction) 14 . These indicators thus<br />

permit specific evaluation of an environmental resource.<br />

A more general evaluation of environmental progress in a region or biome<br />

must rely on compounded environmental indexes that aggregate and synthesize<br />

environmental indicators of pressure and state, such as the “Environmental<br />

Sustainability Index” (ESI) or the “Environmental Performance Index” (EPI),<br />

as well as compounded indexes that measure “environmental footprints” (for<br />

example, the Ecological Footprint Index) 15 .<br />

Ultimately, there are indicators that correlate environmental indicators with<br />

economic indicators that measure production and consumption and are derived<br />

from a system of national accounts. A system of environmental accounts (SEA)<br />

has been proposed in order to include the environmental variable in the current<br />

system of national accounts (SNA). The performance of economic activities is<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

12. See Seroa da Motta (1996) for the evaluation of an effort to generate environmental<br />

indicators in Brazil.<br />

13. Stiglitz, Sen and Fitoussi (2009), p. 9.<br />

14. See OECD (1993) where the proposal for indicators in this category was first presented.<br />

15. See Stiglitz, Sen and Fitoussi (2009) for a detailed discussion of these indexes, especially<br />

the footprints that to the authors do not consider trade between countries, nor do they<br />

account for the substitution of natural capital for material capital, that is, environmental<br />

productivity gains over time.


198<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Measurement in<br />

policies for transition<br />

to a green economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

Carolina Dubeux<br />

reflected in the SNA by macroeconomic aggregates, such as the gross domestic<br />

product (GDP), investments and capital depreciation.<br />

The greater the stock of capital in an economy, the greater is its capacity<br />

to generate revenue. The GDP is the revenue generated by the economy.<br />

Investments represent how much capital the economy “created” in order<br />

to generate the GDP and, consequently are part of the GDP. Depreciation<br />

represents how much capital the economy “consumed” to generate the GDP<br />

and, consequently is not included in the GDP. Thus, the net domestic product<br />

(NDP) of an economy is the GDP minus the consumption of capital.<br />

These measurements from SNA are estimated based on the information<br />

collected by production units through survey research (for example, the census).<br />

As has been discussed, the use of natural capital generates costs that economic<br />

actors do not internalize in their activities. The SNA was not initially designed<br />

to capture the environmental costs associated with the depreciation of natural<br />

capital. Efforts have been made by the United Nations Statistics Division (see<br />

SEEA, 2003) to standardize a methodology that permits the estimation of the<br />

consumption of natural capital to be included in SNA in the form of a system<br />

of environmental accounts.<br />

Observe that the estimation of natural capital consumption generates an<br />

indicator of how much society is relying on its natural assets to generate<br />

revenue, i.e., swapping sustainability for present consumption. This indicator<br />

could offer good guidance for the environmental investment efforts necessary<br />

to maintain a sustainable level of natural capital. For example, the World Bank<br />

(World Bank, 2006) estimated an indicator of net savings or net adjusted<br />

savings to measure how much of national income is due to the consumption<br />

of natural capital.<br />

Determining the adequate level of sustainability has been one of the main<br />

problems in the valuation of natural capital consumption. For example, Seroa da<br />

Motta (1998) estimated that 2.40% of Brazil’s GDP in 2005 could be considered<br />

consumption of natural capital by weak sustainability criteria, but that this<br />

percentage could reach 29% in the case of a strong sustainability scenario.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

A System of Environmental Accounts is not limited to, for example, the<br />

measurement of a green GDP. The integration of all economic indicators<br />

from the National Accounts offers innumerable options of measurements<br />

of environmental performance. The most simple would be the intensity of<br />

environmental consumption (pollution emissions, energy, etc) per unit of revenue<br />

and consumption (national revenue, family incomes, government consumption,<br />

imports and exports) to those that are related to the formation of capital that<br />

measure the appreciations and depreciations of the natural capital stock 16 .<br />

16. In the case of measuring the consumption of natural capital, there are more complex and<br />

controversial conceptual and methodological issues related to the monetization of the value<br />

of the natural resource and its services. See SEEA (2003) and the chapter about valuation in<br />

this publication.


199<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Measurement in<br />

policies for transition<br />

to a green economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

Carolina Dubeux<br />

Studies realized so far 17 also indicate that the contribution of the SNA<br />

for environmental management is strongly associated with the degree of<br />

disaggregation of the indicators in terms of sectors, locations and time.<br />

As such, the planning of a green economy must define an Environmental<br />

Indicators Plan to take immediate effect with a minimum and viable set of<br />

environmental indicators that can be, for example, already consolidated with<br />

administrative registers from environmental agencies (organized for monitoring<br />

and supervision, such as inventories of emissions, flora and fauna) and from<br />

existing continuous research that investigate environmental aspects (sanitation,<br />

solid waste, deforestation, etc).<br />

To summarize, without knowledge of the natural basis and how it transforms<br />

in relation to economic activities, all and any efforts towards a green economy<br />

cannot be conducted nor verified.<br />

Am p l i f y i n g e c o n o m ic in s t r u m e n t s<br />

The structural change in the economy in the direction of green sectors<br />

will require the correct pricing of environmental goods and services to reflect<br />

their true opportunity costs. This price correction can be done with economic<br />

instruments for collections (tax or payments) through environmental resource<br />

use or through creating markets for use rights.<br />

Beyond the aspect of generating efficiency, these instruments can generate<br />

additional fiscal or administrative revenue to: a) finance the institutional<br />

capacity building of environmental agencies; b) realize environmental payments<br />

or compensation; and c) when designed in a progressive way, implement<br />

compensatory policies to alleviate environmental impacts on the poor 18 .<br />

As such, the first condition is the consolidation and codification of environmental<br />

legislation and the creation of the legal space to adopt instruments. The second<br />

is the recognition of the fiscal space of these instruments in the tax system.<br />

However, their amplified use should be cautious due to the associated<br />

technical and administrative difficulties. Flexibility, institutional compatibilization,<br />

gradualism and participation of stakeholders should be criteria to be respected<br />

in their introduction.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Before any attempts to develop an economic instrument, regulators should<br />

first analyze the political objectives and the current state of the natural resource<br />

use. This is an obvious step, although frequently overlooked, especially<br />

when regulators are anxious to transfer a “good” experience of a certain<br />

instrument applied in another country. Regulators should first make explicit the<br />

environmental policy and its objectives for which the economic instrument will<br />

17. See a recent review in Stigliz, Sen and Fitoussi (2009).<br />

18. See, for example, Seroa da Motta (2006).


200<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Measurement in<br />

policies for transition<br />

to a green economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

Carolina Dubeux<br />

be used. Note that an instrument is a means and therefore cannot substitute<br />

the objectives of the policies. In summary, an instrument is intended to serve<br />

a policy, not the other way around.<br />

Re m o v i n g p e r v e r s e in c e n t iv e s<br />

The greatest challenge to the planning of a green economy will be in the<br />

adjustments to be made to economic instruments that are currently used or<br />

under development by economic, social and sectoral policies. The inclusion<br />

of the environmental issue in these policies is crucial to eliminate perverse<br />

incentives in the use of environmental resources, which contradict and/or annul<br />

the efforts of pricing and preserving environmental resources. Among these<br />

policies, we highlight:<br />

a) those aimed at natural resources and infrastructure, such as energy, water<br />

supply, roads and others;<br />

b) typically sectoral ones, such as the expansion of farming, cattle raising<br />

and industry;<br />

c) those of a macroeconomic nature, aimed at stimulating exports, generating<br />

employment and investments;<br />

d) those with structural content, such as agrarian reform and privatizations;<br />

and<br />

e) those with a distributive objective, that stimulate small businesses, urban<br />

settlements and others.<br />

The removal of perverse incentives in the construction of a green economy<br />

will only be viable through a joint effort between the system of environmental<br />

regulation and sectoral regulations that enable commitments to diagnose,<br />

evaluate and route the actions of redefining these sectoral policies.<br />

The uncertainty of various environmental impacts vis-a-vis the desired<br />

benefits can, in some cases, certainly lead to indeterminate decisions.<br />

However, a common and participative effort contributes to pinpoint these<br />

areas of uncertainty, evaluate the costs and eliminate distorted perceptions.<br />

Only then will a less costly and more efficient adjustment to these policies be<br />

possible. To summarize, in these cases of indetermination and uncertainty,<br />

the recommended posture would be to identify losers and winners, and their<br />

losses and gains resulting from the environmental impacts as well as possible<br />

mitigative and compensatory actions.<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

In conclusion, the options that were briefly outlined here confirm the<br />

hypothesis that environmental regulation should not be understood as a problem<br />

and, beyond being a solution, it can represent a source of economic and social<br />

benefits for Brazil in the 21st century through a green economy that generates<br />

growth with preservation and alleviates poverty.


201<br />

GREEN ECONOMY<br />

Challenges and<br />

opportunities<br />

Measurement in<br />

policies for transition<br />

to a green economy<br />

Ronaldo Seroa da Motta<br />

Carolina Dubeux<br />

Nº 8 • June 2011<br />

Referências bibliográficas<br />

Acselrad, H; Herculano, S. e Pádua, J. A. (eds.) (2004). Justiça ambiental e cidadania.<br />

Rio de Janeiro: Relume Dumará.<br />

Arrow, K. et al. (1996). Economic growth, carrying capacity, and the environment. Environment<br />

and Development Economics, 1, 104-110.<br />

Dasgupta, P. e Heal, G. (1979). Economic theory and exhaustible resources. Cambridge:<br />

Cambridge University Press.<br />

Dasgupta, P., Maller, K. G. (1996). Environmental economics in poor countries: the<br />

current state and a programme for improvement. Environment and Development<br />

Economics, 1, 3-7.<br />

Ehrlich, P. R. (1968). The Population Boom. Nova York: Ballantine.<br />

Galeotti, M., Manera, M. e Lanza A. (2009). On the robustness of robustness checks of<br />

the Environmental Kuznets Curve. Environmental and Resource Economics, 42(4),<br />

551-574.<br />

Hartwick, J. (1977). Intergenerational equity and the investing of rents of exhaustible<br />

resources. American Economic Review, 66, 972-974.<br />

Heerink, N., Mulatu, A. e Bulte, E. (2001). Income inequality and the environment: aggregation<br />

bias in environmental Kuznets curves. Ecological Economics, 38, 359–367.<br />

IPCC (2007). Fourth assessment report: climate change 2007 (AR4). Cambridge:<br />

Cambridge University Press, United Kingdom and New York.<br />

OECD (1993). OECD core set of indicators for environmental performance reviews. A<br />

synthesis report by the Group on the State of the Environment. OECD, Paris. 35 p.<br />

Perrings, C. A. et al. (1995). Biodiversity conservation and economic development: the<br />

policy problem. In Perrings et al. (eds.), Biodiversity conservation. Dordrecht: Kluwer<br />

Academic Publishers.<br />

SEEA (2003). Handbook of national accounting: integrated environmental and economic<br />

accounting. Nova York: ONU.<br />

Seroa da Motta, R. (coord.) (1995). Contabilidade ambiental: teoria, metodologia e<br />

estudos de casos no Brasil. Rio de Janeiro: IPEA.<br />

Seroa da Motta, R. (1996). Indicadores ambientais no Brasil: aspectos ecológicos, de<br />

eficiência e distributivos. Texto para Discussão 403. Rio de Janeiro: IPEA.<br />

Seroa da Motta, R. (1998). Sustainability principles and depreciation estimates of natural<br />

capital in Brazil. In Faucheux, S, O’Connor, M. e van Straaten, J (eds.), Sustainable<br />

development: concepts, rationalities and strategies. Amsterdam: Kluwer Academic<br />

Publishers.<br />

Seroa da Motta, R. (2004). Padrão de consumo e degradação ambiental no Brasil.<br />

Ciência Hoje, 35(211), 35-38.<br />

Seroa da Motta, R. (2006). Economia ambiental. Rio de Janeiro: FGV Editora.<br />

Seroa da Motta, R. (2011). A sustentabilidade do desenvolvimento. In Netto, D. et al.<br />

(eds.), O Brasil e a ciência econômica no século XXI – Volume II. São Paulo: Saraiva<br />

(no prelo).<br />

Shepard, P. M., Corbin-Mark, C. (2009). Climate justice. Environmental Justice, 2(4),<br />

163-166.<br />

Stiglitz, J; Sen, A. e Fitoussi, J. (2009). Report by the Commission on the Measurement<br />

of Economic Performance and Social Progress. Paris.<br />

Solow, R. M. (1978). Intergenerational equity and exhaustible resources. Review of<br />

Economic Studies, 41, 29-45.<br />

Turner, R. K. (1992). Speculations on weak and strong sustainability. Cserge, Working<br />

Paper GEC, 92-26.<br />

UNEP (2011). Towards a green economy: pathways to sustainable development and<br />

poverty eradication - a synthesis for policy makers. Disponível em: .<br />

World Bank (2006). Where is the wealth of nations? measuring capital in the 21st<br />

Century. Washington: World Bank.<br />

WCED (1987). Our common future. United Nations, The World Commission on Environment<br />

and Development (The Brundtland Report).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!