01.11.2014 Views

Gaming the Float: How Managers Respond to EPS-based Incentives

Gaming the Float: How Managers Respond to EPS-based Incentives

Gaming the Float: How Managers Respond to EPS-based Incentives

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Gaming</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Float</strong>:<br />

<strong>How</strong> <strong>Managers</strong> <strong>Respond</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>EPS</strong>-<strong>based</strong> <strong>Incentives</strong> ∗<br />

Alan D. Crane †<br />

Jones Graduate School of Business<br />

Rice University<br />

Chishen Wei §<br />

Nanyang Business School<br />

Nanyang Technological University<br />

July 11, 2013<br />

Andrew Koch ‡<br />

Katz Graduate School of Business<br />

University of Pittsburgh<br />

Abstract<br />

We show that <strong>the</strong> likelihood of meeting earnings per share (<strong>EPS</strong>) forecasts is mechanically positively<br />

related <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> number of shares outstanding. As a result, by changing shares outstanding, managers can<br />

affect <strong>the</strong> long run probability of meeting future <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts without affecting earnings or analysts’<br />

forecasts. We find that firms with unpredictable earnings and firms with managers that have compensation<br />

more sensitive <strong>to</strong> <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes have more shares outstanding. To address causality, we find that an<br />

exogenous drop in <strong>the</strong> likelihood of meeting a forecast causes managers <strong>to</strong> increase shares outstanding,<br />

primarily through s<strong>to</strong>ck splits. Following an increase in shares, accounting and real earnings management<br />

drop and <strong>the</strong> firm meets <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts more frequently going forward. Our results suggest that managers<br />

use s<strong>to</strong>ck splits as a long term substitute for traditional earnings management <strong>to</strong>ols. This provides an<br />

important link between <strong>EPS</strong> reporting and capital market activities.<br />

Keywords. Earnings per share; Earnings management; S<strong>to</strong>ck splits<br />

∗ We thank Brian Akins, Leonce Bargeron, Alex Butler, Mike Crawley, Dave Denis, Diane Denis, Steve Dimmock, Mei Feng,<br />

Nishad Kapadia, Bin Ke, Paul Malatesta, Sebastien Michenaud, K. Ramesh, Shawn Thomas, K.C. John Wei, James Wes<strong>to</strong>n<br />

and seminar participants at Rice University and University of Pittsburgh for <strong>the</strong>ir helpful comments.<br />

† acrane@rice.edu<br />

‡ awkoch@pitt.edu. Corresponding author. 326 Mervis Hall, Rober<strong>to</strong> Clemente Drive, Pittsburgh, PA, 15260. 412-648-1187.<br />

§ cswei@ntu.edu.sg


1 Introduction<br />

Earnings per share (<strong>EPS</strong>) is a widely followed and heavily scrutinized financial indica<strong>to</strong>r in <strong>the</strong> US. Evidence<br />

suggests that managers care about <strong>EPS</strong> targets (Graham et al. (2005)). A large literature documents a<br />

variety of actions that managers take <strong>to</strong> affect <strong>the</strong> gap between earnings realizations and <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts by<br />

changing earnings, forecasts, or both. 1 This literature generally takes <strong>the</strong> concept of “meeting”, “beating”,<br />

or “missing” forecasts as given. We show that, even if two managers have identical earnings and forecasts,<br />

one can “miss” while <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r “meets”. The rules of <strong>the</strong> game are actually <strong>the</strong> manager’s choice. In this<br />

paper, we show that managers can affect <strong>the</strong> likelihood that <strong>the</strong>ir firm meets future <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts without<br />

affecting <strong>the</strong>ir firm’s reported earnings or guiding forecasts. They do so by choosing <strong>the</strong> number of shares<br />

outstanding.<br />

For any given <strong>EPS</strong> forecast, <strong>the</strong>re exists a range of <strong>to</strong>tal earnings that will meet that <strong>EPS</strong> forecast.<br />

For example, a firm with 1000 shares outstanding and <strong>EPS</strong> forecast of $0.20 will meet <strong>the</strong> forecast with any<br />

earnings ∈ [$195, $205). This range exists because per-share earnings are rounded <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> penny. Importantly,<br />

<strong>the</strong> amount of rounding is a choice variable; it is an increasing function of <strong>the</strong> number of shares outstanding.<br />

If <strong>the</strong> same firm has twice as many shares outstanding, <strong>the</strong> firm meets <strong>the</strong> forecast for any earnings ∈ [$190,<br />

$210). The wider this range, <strong>the</strong> higher <strong>the</strong> probability of meeting <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts, more specifically:<br />

P r(meet) = P r(µ − s ∗ 0.5¢ ≤ x < µ + s ∗ 0.5¢)<br />

where x represents <strong>the</strong> realization of <strong>to</strong>tal earnings, s is <strong>the</strong> number of shares outstanding, and µ is <strong>the</strong><br />

forecasted <strong>to</strong>tal earnings implied by <strong>the</strong> <strong>EPS</strong> forecast. Increasing <strong>the</strong> number of shares increases <strong>the</strong> size of<br />

this range (<strong>the</strong> “target size”). To put it simply, <strong>the</strong> practice of rounding <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes has a bigger effect<br />

<strong>the</strong> more shares a firm has. <strong>Managers</strong> can exploit this fact <strong>to</strong> influence <strong>the</strong> probability of meeting all <strong>EPS</strong><br />

forecasts going forward. <strong>How</strong>ever, this is not costless; as managers increase <strong>the</strong> number of shares, <strong>the</strong> share<br />

price drops mechanically. This can have liquidity costs and, in <strong>the</strong> limit, result in delisting.<br />

We develop and test several implications of <strong>the</strong> hypo<strong>the</strong>sis that managers engage in target size management<br />

(TSM) - adjusting shares outstanding <strong>to</strong> affect <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> range of <strong>to</strong>tal earnings that meets<br />

<strong>EPS</strong> forecasts. 2 Our primary hypo<strong>the</strong>sis is that managers of firms that are likely <strong>to</strong> miss <strong>EPS</strong> targets due <strong>to</strong><br />

chance in <strong>the</strong> future will choose a larger target size. This is equivalent <strong>to</strong> saying that firms with unpredictable<br />

1 For comprehensive reviews of <strong>the</strong> earnings management literature, see Healy and Wahlen (1999), Dechow and Skinner<br />

(2000) and Dechow et al. (2010).<br />

2 We focus on <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts as <strong>the</strong> relevant threshold, however target size management could apply <strong>to</strong> any threshold, as long<br />

as <strong>the</strong> threshold is measured and rounded at <strong>the</strong> share level.<br />

2


earnings will choose more shares outstanding, all else equal. By choosing this larger target, a larger range<br />

of earnings outcomes will round <strong>to</strong> any given <strong>EPS</strong> forecast. If firms with unpredictable earnings did not<br />

choose larger targets, <strong>the</strong>y would miss <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts more often than similar firms with earnings that are<br />

easy <strong>to</strong> forecast. We proxy for unpredictable earnings in several ways, one of which is net income volatility. 3<br />

We find that firms in <strong>the</strong> highest decile of net income volatility have over three times <strong>the</strong> number of shares<br />

outstanding compared <strong>to</strong> firms with <strong>the</strong> lowest volatility.<br />

We also expect target size <strong>to</strong> be related <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> manager’s incentives <strong>to</strong> meet or beat <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts. A<br />

large target makes a firm less likely <strong>to</strong> miss <strong>the</strong> <strong>EPS</strong> forecast. <strong>How</strong>ever, it also makes it more difficult for <strong>the</strong><br />

firm <strong>to</strong> beat that forecast. Therefore, we expect <strong>to</strong> find larger targets among managers with a high cost <strong>to</strong><br />

missing forecasts relative <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> benefits of beating those same <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts. Using data on executive bonus<br />

and option ownership, we proxy for <strong>the</strong> sensitivity of <strong>the</strong> manager’s compensation in <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes. 4<br />

We<br />

find that firms with managers in <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>p decile of incentive compensation have 40% more shares outstanding<br />

relative <strong>to</strong> firms with managers in <strong>the</strong> bot<strong>to</strong>m decile.<br />

Next, we examine <strong>the</strong> implications of target size management for time series variation in shares outstanding<br />

and how this impacts firms’ usage of earnings management. Over time, <strong>the</strong> fundamentals of a firm<br />

may change, and <strong>the</strong>refore <strong>the</strong> optimal target size may also change. For example, if <strong>the</strong> firm’s net income<br />

grows, <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> target relative <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm will shrink simply as a result of this growth. As <strong>the</strong> target<br />

size shrinks, <strong>the</strong> probability of rounding <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>EPS</strong> forecast will decrease and <strong>the</strong> manager may need <strong>to</strong> use<br />

more accounting and real earnings management <strong>to</strong>ols in order <strong>to</strong> meet this shrinking target. <strong>Managers</strong> can<br />

increase <strong>the</strong> firm’s number of shares in order <strong>to</strong> change <strong>the</strong> target <strong>to</strong> a size appropriate for that of <strong>the</strong> larger<br />

firm. 5<br />

We expect an increase in shares <strong>to</strong> have one or both of <strong>the</strong> following effects: <strong>the</strong> firm should meet<br />

<strong>EPS</strong> forecasts more frequently, and/or <strong>the</strong> usage of o<strong>the</strong>r earnings management <strong>to</strong>ols should drop. We find<br />

evidence of both. The magnitudes of accruals and discretionary investment drop significantly following an<br />

increase in shares outstanding, and simultaneously <strong>the</strong> firm is 18% less likely <strong>to</strong> miss <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts.<br />

<strong>Managers</strong> have numerous mechanisms <strong>to</strong> adjust share float.<br />

We find that target size management is<br />

primarily achieved through s<strong>to</strong>ck splits. There is little evidence that <strong>the</strong> target size is adjusted through <strong>the</strong><br />

issuance (or repurchase) of new shares. This is not surprising given that splits are simply an accounting<br />

change in <strong>the</strong> number of tradeable securities, whereas issuances have direct economic effects unrelated <strong>to</strong><br />

3 We often use <strong>the</strong> term net income interchangeably with <strong>to</strong>tal earnings. We recognize that <strong>EPS</strong> may reflect adjustments <strong>to</strong><br />

net income. Our results are robust <strong>to</strong> using various definitions of <strong>to</strong>tal earnings.<br />

4 Cheng and Warfield (2005) and Bergstresser and Philippon (2006) find that higher option and s<strong>to</strong>ck compensation is<br />

associated with <strong>EPS</strong> incentives.<br />

5 This is consistent with <strong>the</strong> prior evidence that s<strong>to</strong>ck splits follow net income growth. We discuss how our results relate <strong>to</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> literature on s<strong>to</strong>ck splits in later sections.<br />

3


target size. 6<br />

Importantly, changes <strong>to</strong> target size as a result of s<strong>to</strong>ck splits are quite common. In a typical<br />

year, roughly 5% of firms split. Over <strong>the</strong> full sample, almost all firms adjust <strong>the</strong> target size <strong>to</strong> keep up with<br />

firm growth. 7<br />

This suggests that TSM is economically important and widely used. Some firms, however,<br />

may find it <strong>to</strong>o costly <strong>to</strong> manage <strong>the</strong> target size. We find that TSM is limited by costs associated with<br />

having a large quantity of shares. A firm with a large target size will have a low s<strong>to</strong>ck price. A low s<strong>to</strong>ck<br />

price may lower s<strong>to</strong>ck liquidity, potentially <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> point of delisting. For firms with low liquidity, we find a<br />

minimal response <strong>to</strong> exogenous changes in net income volatility.<br />

Our analysis is complicated by <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> predictability of earnings is itself a managerial choice<br />

variable. <strong>Managers</strong> can explicitly manage <strong>the</strong> volatility of net income using accruals or real investments<br />

(e.g. Beidleman (1973), Subramanyam (1996), Healy and Wahlen (1999)), and <strong>the</strong>y can use guidance <strong>to</strong><br />

manage <strong>the</strong> forecast. In order <strong>to</strong> demonstrate that our effects are evidence of TSM and not due <strong>to</strong> some o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

fac<strong>to</strong>r related <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> use of accruals or guidance, we employ an instrumental variable approach that uses an<br />

exogenous change in analyst coverage (Hong and Kacperczyk (2010), Degeorge et al. (2012), Derrien and<br />

Kecskés (2012), Kelly and Ljungqvist (2012)) <strong>to</strong> instrument for changes in <strong>the</strong> predictability of <strong>the</strong> firm’s<br />

net income. This instrument captures <strong>the</strong> fact that fewer analysts will result in noisier estimates on average.<br />

Therefore, <strong>the</strong> firm experiences an increase in <strong>the</strong> probability of missing earnings forecasts that is unlikely<br />

<strong>to</strong> be related <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> fundamentals of <strong>the</strong> firm. The causal effect is large. A one standard deviation increase<br />

in instrumented volatility results in an increase in shares of one-half of one standard deviation.<br />

Managerial payoffs are also endogenous. Compensation contracts and <strong>the</strong> market reaction <strong>to</strong> <strong>EPS</strong> surprises<br />

(and <strong>the</strong>refore <strong>the</strong> change in value of <strong>the</strong> manager’s s<strong>to</strong>ck and option holdings) are likely <strong>to</strong> be<br />

determined <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> underlying fundamentals of <strong>the</strong> firm, including <strong>the</strong> predictability of <strong>the</strong> earnings. 8<br />

Using <strong>the</strong> same instrumental variable approach, we examine if an exogenous shock <strong>to</strong> this predictability has<br />

a greater effect on shares among firms whose managers have pay that is ex-ante highly sensitive <strong>to</strong> <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes.<br />

We find that <strong>the</strong> relation between shares and instrumented volatility is primarily driven by managers<br />

with high incentive compensation.<br />

To summarize, on balance our evidence is consistent with TSM. In <strong>the</strong> cross section, firms with more<br />

unpredictable earnings and firms with managers more sensitive <strong>to</strong> negative <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes choose larger<br />

6 Passive changes <strong>to</strong> float occur as a result of certain policies, such as ESOP plans. We find that <strong>the</strong>se changes do not drive<br />

our results.<br />

7 Berkshire Hathaway is a notable example of a firm that does not appear <strong>to</strong> engage in TSM. The size of Berkshire Hathaway’s<br />

earnings target is small relative <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> firm’s earnings. They must realize earnings within ±0.00005% of <strong>the</strong> consensus<br />

forecasts <strong>to</strong> meet expectations.<br />

8 Evidence of this endogeneity can be seen in Dechow and You (2012). They document that <strong>the</strong> market reaction <strong>to</strong> <strong>EPS</strong><br />

surprises is weaker for firms with higher <strong>EPS</strong> levels which, holding earnings fixed, is equivalent <strong>to</strong> firms with lower shares<br />

outstanding.<br />

4


targets.<br />

<strong>Managers</strong> change <strong>the</strong> target size in response <strong>to</strong> changes in <strong>the</strong> predictability of those earnings.<br />

Importantly, <strong>the</strong>se effects are stronger for firms with higher incentive compensation, weaker for firms with<br />

low liquidity.<br />

Finally, following an increase in <strong>the</strong> target size, firms meet forecasts more frequently and<br />

earnings management drops.<br />

Our paper is related <strong>to</strong>, but distinct from, <strong>the</strong> broad literature on earnings management. Prior evidence<br />

suggests that earnings management occurs when managers face short term incentives <strong>to</strong> meet or beat a<br />

threshold.<br />

The manager privately observes <strong>the</strong> firm’s earnings, and chooses accruals, investment, s<strong>to</strong>ck<br />

repurchases, or some o<strong>the</strong>r corporate action such that <strong>the</strong> firm’s reported earnings meet <strong>the</strong> threshold. In<br />

contrast, our evidence suggests that managers manage <strong>the</strong> target size not <strong>to</strong> affect <strong>the</strong> current period <strong>EPS</strong>,<br />

but <strong>to</strong> affect <strong>the</strong> ease with which <strong>the</strong> firm will meet future <strong>EPS</strong> thresholds in <strong>the</strong> long run.<br />

No private<br />

information is required by <strong>the</strong> manager for TSM <strong>to</strong> be effective, and markets need not be fooled. TSM<br />

and earnings management are related, however, in <strong>the</strong> sense that TSM is a long-term substitute for earnings<br />

management. By setting <strong>the</strong> target size <strong>to</strong>day, <strong>the</strong> manager is effectively determining <strong>the</strong> amount of earnings<br />

that will need <strong>to</strong> be managed in expectation over multiple periods in <strong>the</strong> future. 9<br />

Our findings contribute most directly <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> literature on <strong>the</strong> choice of earnings management <strong>to</strong>ols. For<br />

example, recent literature focuses on <strong>the</strong> tradeoffs between earnings management <strong>to</strong>ols (e.g.<br />

Cohen and<br />

Zarowin (2010) and Zang (2011)). As noted by Fields et al. (2001), it is important <strong>to</strong> examine <strong>the</strong> combined,<br />

net effect of all earnings management <strong>to</strong>ols used <strong>to</strong>ge<strong>the</strong>r <strong>to</strong> meet <strong>EPS</strong> thresholds. Our results are important<br />

because <strong>the</strong>y suggest that, prior <strong>to</strong> trading off <strong>the</strong>se earnings management <strong>to</strong>ols, managers decide <strong>the</strong> extent<br />

<strong>to</strong> which <strong>the</strong>y will need <strong>to</strong> manage earnings in <strong>the</strong> first place.<br />

Our study highlights an important link between <strong>EPS</strong> reporting and capital market activities through<br />

<strong>the</strong> real effects of s<strong>to</strong>ck splits. Our evidence offers a new explanation for s<strong>to</strong>cks splits <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> need<br />

for target size management. While previous explanations typically involve signaling motives or s<strong>to</strong>ck price<br />

levels, we show that s<strong>to</strong>ck splits could be a result of managerial concerns regarding <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes. Thus,<br />

we extend <strong>the</strong> prior literature that examines patterns in accounting metrics and <strong>the</strong>ir relationship <strong>to</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ck<br />

splits (e.g. Louis and Robinson (2005)). Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, a TSM-<strong>based</strong> explanation of s<strong>to</strong>ck splits is consistent<br />

with prior literature that finds that splits follow earnings growth (Lakonishok and Lev (1987), Asquith et al.<br />

(1989)), as well as <strong>the</strong> literature that documents a “nominal price puzzle”(Weld et al. (2009)). We discuss<br />

this in more detail in Section 3.3.<br />

9 Prior literature finds that firms use repurchases (which result in a change <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> quantity of shares) <strong>to</strong> have an accretive<br />

effect on current period <strong>EPS</strong> (e.g. Hribar et al. (2006) and Bens et al. (2003)). Our results do not dispute <strong>the</strong>se findings, but<br />

ra<strong>the</strong>r show that share changes can have long term effects on <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes. TSM is driven primarily through s<strong>to</strong>ck splits and<br />

not through repurchases. We find little evidence that s<strong>to</strong>ck splits have an accretive effect on <strong>EPS</strong> in <strong>the</strong> short run.<br />

5


Finally, TSM has implications for a variety of per-share metrics such as analyst dispersion and forecast<br />

error.<br />

In this sense, our findings compliment Dechow and You (2012), in which <strong>the</strong> authors make <strong>the</strong><br />

observation that <strong>the</strong> precision of an <strong>EPS</strong> number is greater for higher levels of <strong>EPS</strong>. 10 We show in Section<br />

3.3 that <strong>the</strong> scale invariance of analysts’ forecast errors (Degeorge et al. (1999), Cheong and Thomas (2011),<br />

and Ball (2011)) is <strong>the</strong> expected endogenous outcome of target size management.<br />

Our paper proceeds as follows: Section 2 motivates our hypo<strong>the</strong>sis and describes <strong>the</strong> mechanism we test.<br />

Section 3 describes <strong>the</strong> data and empirical results. Section 3.3 discusses <strong>the</strong> implications of our findings, and<br />

Section 4 concludes.<br />

2 Discussion and Hypo<strong>the</strong>sis Development<br />

The convention of rounding <strong>EPS</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> nearest penny creates a range of net income that will generate a<br />

given <strong>EPS</strong> number. The size of this range is determined by <strong>the</strong> number of shares outstanding. Specifically,<br />

<strong>the</strong> range of net income that meets expectations is: (E[EP S] ∗ s −<br />

s<br />

s<br />

200<br />

, E[EP S] ∗ s +<br />

200<br />

), where E[EP S]<br />

is <strong>the</strong> analysts’ <strong>EPS</strong> expectation and s is <strong>the</strong> number of shares outstanding. The expected Net Income,<br />

E[EP S] ∗ s, is <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal earnings implied by <strong>the</strong> per share forecast and is <strong>the</strong> midpoint of this range. The<br />

highest and lowest earnings that will round <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> forecast are determined by s. At a maximum, each share’s<br />

1<br />

worth of earnings will be rounded by half a penny (or in dollar terms,<br />

200<br />

). For example, Microsoft Corp.<br />

has roughly 8 billion shares outstanding. So, in any given quarter <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal size of <strong>the</strong>ir earnings target is 80<br />

million dollars, ± 40 million centered around <strong>the</strong> amount of <strong>to</strong>tal earnings implied by <strong>the</strong> forecast. In dollar<br />

terms this amount might seem large, but relative <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> magnitude of <strong>the</strong> firm’s earnings, perhaps less so.<br />

The size of <strong>the</strong> earnings target relative <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> firm’s <strong>to</strong>tal earnings is ± 0.5<br />

E[|EP S|]<br />

%. The average<br />

firm in our sample has <strong>EPS</strong> of $0.20.<br />

So, <strong>the</strong> typical firm will meet <strong>the</strong> earnings forecast by producing<br />

earnings within ±2.50% of expected earnings. This amount of flexibility might be considered large by some<br />

managers and small by o<strong>the</strong>rs. For example, 2.50% may be relatively large for a firm with stable business<br />

fundamentals and predictable net income. <strong>How</strong>ever, a manager whose compensation is highly concave in<br />

earnings surprises may consider this range <strong>to</strong> be small.<br />

<strong>Managers</strong> have flexibility over <strong>the</strong> size of this earnings target. In dollar terms, <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> target is<br />

fixed solely by <strong>the</strong> number of shares. If <strong>the</strong> manager prefers an earnings target twice as large, she can simply<br />

double <strong>the</strong> number of shares outstanding. Because <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> earnings target measured in dollars is fixed,<br />

10 In <strong>the</strong> next section, we show that <strong>the</strong> target size as a percentage of <strong>the</strong> firm’s expected net income equals one-half of <strong>the</strong><br />

inverse of <strong>EPS</strong>.<br />

6


it does not increase as <strong>the</strong> firm’s earnings increase. Equivalently, <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> earnings target measured<br />

as a percent of <strong>the</strong> firm’s earnings shrinks as <strong>the</strong> firm’s earnings grow. The manager can counteract this by<br />

adjusting shares outstanding. An example that highlights <strong>the</strong>se effects is shown in Figure 1.<br />

[Insert Figure 1 Here]<br />

Our testable predictions focus on <strong>the</strong> manager’s choice for shares outstanding. First, we discuss predictions<br />

on <strong>the</strong> firm and manager characteristics that are related <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> cross sectional distribution of shares<br />

outstanding. We discuss an identification strategy <strong>to</strong> address causality - that managers’ <strong>EPS</strong>-<strong>based</strong> incentives<br />

cause <strong>the</strong>m <strong>to</strong> choose shares outstanding. Last, we explore <strong>the</strong> conditions under which managers change<br />

shares outstanding, how <strong>the</strong>se changes relate <strong>to</strong> <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes, and how <strong>the</strong>y relate <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> usage of o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

earnings management <strong>to</strong>ols.<br />

2.1 Determinants of <strong>the</strong> cross sectional distribution of shares outstanding<br />

We expect <strong>the</strong> manager’s choice of target size <strong>to</strong> be a function of <strong>the</strong> incentives she faces <strong>to</strong> generate certain<br />

<strong>EPS</strong> outcomes. Conceptually, <strong>the</strong>se incentives can be summarized by <strong>the</strong> set of payoffs <strong>the</strong> manager receives<br />

for generating certain <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes, and <strong>the</strong> probabilities that <strong>the</strong>se outcomes occur. Nei<strong>the</strong>r payoffs nor<br />

probabilities associated with a specific earnings realization can be directly measured.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>r, both are<br />

likely endogenously determined along with <strong>the</strong> manager’s choice for shares outstanding. This makes both<br />

hypo<strong>the</strong>sis development and empirical design challenging. We begin by assuming probabilities and payoffs<br />

are exogenous and measurable.<br />

First, we hold payoffs fixed (e.g., managers receive <strong>the</strong> same bonus for beating <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts, <strong>the</strong> market<br />

response <strong>to</strong> a negative earnings surprise is <strong>the</strong> same across firms, managerial ownership is constant, etc.)<br />

and examine how variation in probabilities should relate <strong>to</strong> variation in <strong>the</strong> number of shares. For any firm,<br />

<strong>the</strong> probability of meeting <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts is:<br />

P r(meet) = P r(µ −<br />

∫ s µ+ s<br />

200 ≤ x < µ + s<br />

200 ) = 200<br />

µ− s<br />

200<br />

f(x) dx,<br />

where f(x) is <strong>the</strong> pdf of <strong>the</strong> firm’s earnings, µ is analysts’ forecasted earnings (which equals s ∗ E[EP S]),<br />

and s is <strong>the</strong> number of shares.<br />

If we assume <strong>the</strong> firm has earnings distributed uniformly over [-e, e] and <strong>the</strong> consensus forecast is nei<strong>the</strong>r<br />

noisy nor biased (and <strong>the</strong>refore equals $0.00), <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> probability of meeting earnings is: P r(meet) =<br />

∫ s<br />

200<br />

−<br />

s<br />

200<br />

( 1<br />

e+e ) dx =<br />

s<br />

200e<br />

. From here it is easy <strong>to</strong> see that <strong>the</strong> probability of meeting forecasts is negatively<br />

7


elated <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> variance (variance is e2<br />

12<br />

) of <strong>the</strong> earnings and positively related <strong>to</strong> s. If payoffs are fixed and<br />

homogenous across managers, <strong>the</strong>n all managers will prefer <strong>the</strong> same probabilities of meeting, beating, and<br />

missing <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts. Holding <strong>the</strong>se payoffs constant, it follows directly that managers of firms with volatile<br />

earnings will need <strong>to</strong> choose higher shares in order <strong>to</strong> obtain <strong>the</strong> same <strong>EPS</strong> outcome likelihoods. This positive<br />

relation between net income volatility and shares outstanding is our main prediction:<br />

H1: <strong>Managers</strong> of firms with highly volatile and unpredictable earnings will choose more shares outstanding<br />

compared <strong>to</strong> firms with stable, predictable earnings, all else equal.<br />

This prediction is difficult <strong>to</strong> test empirically for a variety of reasons. First, forward-looking volatility<br />

is not observable.<br />

Second, <strong>the</strong> volatility of earnings that is important for our purposes is <strong>the</strong> part that<br />

is unpredictable. More precisely, <strong>the</strong> variance that is important is <strong>the</strong> variance in <strong>the</strong> difference between<br />

realized earnings and expected earnings.<br />

For example, if a firm has volatile earnings due <strong>to</strong> predictable<br />

seasonal variation, <strong>the</strong>n this volatility would not reflect <strong>the</strong> likelihood that <strong>the</strong> firm will generate earnings<br />

different from forecasts. Third, as pointed out in <strong>the</strong> large literature on earnings smoothing (e.g. Beidleman<br />

(1973), Subramanyam (1996), Healy and Wahlen (1999)), <strong>the</strong> variance in earnings is itself a choice variable.<br />

To address <strong>the</strong> first two concerns, we use three proxies for net income volatility; i) variance around <strong>the</strong><br />

mean over <strong>the</strong> last twelve quarters, ii) variance around a seasonally adjusted expected mean over <strong>the</strong> last<br />

twelve quarters, and iii) variance around <strong>the</strong> expectation implied by analysts’ forecasts over <strong>the</strong> last twelve<br />

quarters.<br />

We expect <strong>to</strong> find a positive relationship between <strong>the</strong>se measures of net income volatility and<br />

shares outstanding.<br />

The last concern, that net income volatility is jointly determined with <strong>the</strong> number of shares, makes identification<br />

difficult. To address causality, we use a source of plausibly exogenous variation in <strong>the</strong> probability<br />

that <strong>the</strong> firm meets <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts and relate this <strong>to</strong> changes in shares outstanding. Specifically, we use an<br />

exogenous drop in analyst coverage as a shock <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> probability that <strong>the</strong> firm meets earnings forecasts. Our<br />

reasoning is simple, if <strong>the</strong> consensus forecast is thought of as <strong>the</strong> sample mean (or median) of individual<br />

analysts’ noisy forecasts, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> variance of this estimate is decreasing in <strong>the</strong> number of analysts, i.e.<br />

<strong>the</strong> noise in <strong>the</strong> forecast is a decreasing function of <strong>the</strong> sample size. Therefore, a drop in analyst coverage<br />

increases <strong>the</strong> variance in <strong>the</strong> <strong>EPS</strong> forecast simply because fewer analysts are sampled.<br />

Increasing <strong>the</strong> volatility of <strong>the</strong> forecast is equivalent <strong>to</strong> increasing <strong>the</strong> volatility of earnings around <strong>the</strong><br />

forecast. In <strong>the</strong> Appendix, we show explicitly that an increase in forecast noise decreases <strong>the</strong> probability of<br />

8


meeting that forecast. This leads <strong>to</strong> a variant of our main hypo<strong>the</strong>sis:<br />

H1a: <strong>Managers</strong> increase shares in response <strong>to</strong> an exogenous decrease in analyst coverage.<br />

Next, we discuss how manager payoffs might relate <strong>to</strong> variation in shares outstanding. All else equal,<br />

we expect a positive relationship between <strong>the</strong> sensitivity of payoffs <strong>to</strong> negative earnings surprises relative<br />

<strong>to</strong> positive surprises (concavity) and shares outstanding. The more shares are outstanding, <strong>the</strong> lower is <strong>the</strong><br />

probability of missing earnings. <strong>How</strong>ever, because this rounding effect is symmetric, it also decreases <strong>the</strong><br />

probability of beating earnings. A manager with convex payoffs (higher sensitivity <strong>to</strong> meeting than missing)<br />

should prefer a small range. In this case, <strong>the</strong> probability of missing is high, but <strong>the</strong> probability of beating<br />

is high as well. A manager who incurs large costs when missing relative <strong>to</strong> beating (concave payoffs) will<br />

prefer a larger range <strong>to</strong> minimize <strong>the</strong> chances of incurring those costs.<br />

H2: <strong>Managers</strong> with payoffs that are concave (convex) in earnings surprises will choose higher (lower) level<br />

of shares outstanding.<br />

Similar <strong>to</strong> net income volatility, payoffs are nei<strong>the</strong>r observable nor exogenous. <strong>How</strong>ever, <strong>the</strong>re is considerable<br />

evidence that CEO’s receive compensation that is concave in earnings surprises. Bonuses in CEO<br />

compensation contracts are often tied <strong>to</strong> <strong>EPS</strong> thresholds <strong>based</strong> on analyst forecasts (Murphy (1999), De Angelis<br />

and Grinstein (2011) and Kim and Yang (2012)). Also, <strong>the</strong> negative s<strong>to</strong>ck price reactions <strong>to</strong> negative<br />

earnings surprises are significantly larger than <strong>the</strong> positive reactions associated with beating forecasts. 11<br />

Given that most CEOs have substantial ownership stakes in <strong>the</strong> company, this creates a stronger incentive<br />

<strong>to</strong> avoid missing earnings expectations compared <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> incentive <strong>to</strong> beat those targets. Burgstahler and<br />

Dichev (1997) and Degeorge et al. (1999) show empirically that <strong>the</strong> distribution of <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes is consistent<br />

with <strong>the</strong> view that managers respond <strong>to</strong> incentives <strong>to</strong> meet or beat <strong>EPS</strong> targets. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, prior<br />

literature has documented a connection between <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes and managerial compensation. For example,<br />

Cheng and Warfield (2005) find that managers with high equity ownership are less likely <strong>to</strong> miss <strong>EPS</strong> targets.<br />

We expect managers with larger bonuses tied <strong>to</strong> accounting targets <strong>to</strong> have more shares outstanding, and<br />

hence wider rounding ranges. We would also expect managers who have more ownership and more equity<br />

11 Payne and Thomas (2003) and Skinner and Sloan (2002) show differences in <strong>the</strong> source of this effect, but both generally<br />

find stronger negative reactions.<br />

9


ased compensation <strong>to</strong> have similar incentives. The amount of incentive compensation as a percent of <strong>to</strong>tal<br />

compensation captures both of <strong>the</strong>se effects. Consequently, <strong>the</strong> percentage of incentive compensation will be<br />

positively related <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> number of shares outstanding.<br />

Because compensation contracts are endogenous, we again utilize <strong>the</strong> exogenous drop in analyst coverage<br />

<strong>to</strong> empirically test a variant of H2:<br />

H2a: The effect of an exogenous drop in analyst coverage should be stronger (weaker) among firms whose<br />

managers have high (low) incentive compensation.<br />

2.1.1 Additional costs and benefits relating <strong>to</strong> shares outstanding<br />

Discussion so far has focused on benefits and costs of shares outstanding as <strong>the</strong>y relate <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> rounding<br />

effects and <strong>EPS</strong>-<strong>based</strong> incentives. If <strong>the</strong>se were <strong>the</strong> only trade-offs faced by managers, <strong>the</strong>n any manager<br />

with concave payoffs should choose infinite shares outstanding. We do not observe this because <strong>the</strong>re are<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r costs and benefits related <strong>to</strong> shares outstanding. Prior literature has shown that s<strong>to</strong>ck liquidity is a<br />

function of per-share price levels. In <strong>the</strong> extreme, if <strong>the</strong> price is <strong>to</strong>o low <strong>the</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ck is de-listed, which severely<br />

inhibits liquidity. Therefore, we expect that <strong>the</strong> relationships described in H1 and H2 <strong>to</strong> be weaker for illiquid<br />

firms or those close <strong>to</strong> delisting. In this case, market microstructure considerations are likely <strong>to</strong> outweigh<br />

<strong>EPS</strong>-<strong>based</strong> incentives when <strong>the</strong> manager is choosing shares outstanding.<br />

H3: <strong>Managers</strong> will increase shares as a response <strong>to</strong> an exogenous decrease in analyst coverage, but only for<br />

liquid firms.<br />

Similarly, some corporate decisions are made for reasons not primarily related <strong>to</strong> shares outstanding, yet<br />

<strong>the</strong>se decisions result in a change in shares. For example, firms often repurchase or issue s<strong>to</strong>ck. While <strong>the</strong>se<br />

actions change <strong>the</strong> number of shares, this change is a byproduct, not <strong>the</strong> goal of <strong>the</strong> decision. We do not<br />

expect our hypo<strong>the</strong>ses <strong>to</strong> hold for changes in shares that result from repurchases or issuances. We expect our<br />

results <strong>to</strong> be driven primarily by s<strong>to</strong>ck splits, which do not result in changes <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> firms capital structure.<br />

H4: Changes <strong>to</strong> shares outstanding as a response <strong>to</strong> an exogenous decrease in analyst coverage are driven<br />

by s<strong>to</strong>ck splits.<br />

10


2.2 Time series determinants of shares outstanding<br />

In this section, we examine <strong>the</strong> conditions under which managers might choose <strong>to</strong> change shares outstanding.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> previous section, we discuss how <strong>the</strong> level of shares should be related <strong>to</strong> earnings volatility and <strong>the</strong><br />

concavity of payoffs. If one of <strong>the</strong>se cross sectional determinants were <strong>to</strong> change, <strong>the</strong>n we would expect <strong>the</strong><br />

manager <strong>to</strong> correspondingly change shares outstanding and, in fact, we use a shock <strong>to</strong> net income volatility<br />

(relative <strong>to</strong> forecasts) <strong>to</strong> address causality. <strong>How</strong>ever, we expect that much of <strong>the</strong> within-firm variation in<br />

shares is driven not by changes in compensation contracts or analyst coverage, but simply by firm growth.<br />

Dechow and You (2012) make <strong>the</strong> observation that <strong>the</strong> precision of an <strong>EPS</strong> number is increasing in <strong>the</strong><br />

level of <strong>EPS</strong>. We offer one way <strong>to</strong> quantify this effect; - <strong>the</strong> firm needs <strong>to</strong> produce net income within ± 0.5<br />

E[|EP S|]<br />

% of expected net income <strong>to</strong> meet expectations. Therefore as <strong>the</strong> firm’s net income grows, <strong>the</strong> target size as<br />

a fraction of <strong>the</strong> firm’s expected net income shrinks. 12<br />

It is well known that managers increase shares following earnings growth (see e.g.<br />

Lakonishok and<br />

Lev (1987) and Asquith et al. (1989)). We examine a conditional hypo<strong>the</strong>sis that is unique <strong>to</strong> target size<br />

management. This helps distinguish TSM from o<strong>the</strong>r explanations that also predict an increase in shares<br />

following earnings growth.<br />

The relationship between earnings growth and target size is non-mono<strong>to</strong>nic, with a kink at <strong>EPS</strong>=0.<br />

Earnings growth shrinks <strong>the</strong> target size, but only for firms with positive earnings. If <strong>the</strong> firm has negative<br />

earnings and experiences earnings growth (a positive change in earnings), <strong>the</strong>n this growth actually widens<br />

<strong>the</strong> range making it easier <strong>to</strong> meet expectations, not harder. Therefore, we expect increases in shares <strong>to</strong><br />

follow earnings growth, but only among positive <strong>EPS</strong> firms.<br />

H5: <strong>Managers</strong> increase shares following earnings growth, but only for firms with positive earnings.<br />

A manager can compensate for a shrinking target by using more accruals, guidance, and o<strong>the</strong>r earnings<br />

management <strong>to</strong>ols. <strong>How</strong>ever, usage of <strong>the</strong>se earnings management <strong>to</strong>ols is costly. As <strong>the</strong> costs of <strong>the</strong> usage<br />

of <strong>the</strong>se alternatives increase, <strong>the</strong> manager can choose <strong>to</strong> “reset” <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> earnings target, res<strong>to</strong>ring<br />

it <strong>to</strong> a size appropriate for <strong>the</strong> now-larger firm. Therefore, we expect that <strong>the</strong> manager will ei<strong>the</strong>r meet<br />

12 To be clear, if <strong>the</strong> firm’s mean earnings grows but <strong>the</strong>re is no growth in variance, <strong>the</strong>n this growth has no effect on <strong>the</strong><br />

probability of meeting forecasts, despite <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> target size relative <strong>to</strong> firm size has shrunk. Therefore, thinking of<br />

target size relative <strong>to</strong> firm size is useful only if <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> firm in terms of expected net income is related <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> volatility<br />

of <strong>the</strong> firm’s net income. Not surprisingly, we find empirically that earnings growth is associated with higher levels of earnings<br />

volatility going forward.<br />

11


<strong>EPS</strong> forecasts more frequently or will use less earnings management (or both) following an increase in shares<br />

outstanding.<br />

H6: The likelihood of meeting (missing or beating) <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts increases (decreases) following increases<br />

in shares.<br />

H7: The usage of accounting and real earnings management <strong>to</strong>ols decreases following increases in shares.<br />

2.3 Short-term rounding effects<br />

Discussion up <strong>to</strong> this point has focused on <strong>the</strong> long-run effects of shares on <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> earnings target.<br />

Given that <strong>the</strong> number of shares persists from quarter-<strong>to</strong>-quarter, we expect managers <strong>to</strong> choose shares in<br />

response <strong>to</strong> long horizon trade-offs and expectations. <strong>How</strong>ever, it is possible that managers ignore long term<br />

effects and adjust shares outstanding in light of private information regarding current period earnings. To<br />

<strong>the</strong> best of our knowledge, reported earnings must reflect splits that occur during <strong>the</strong> period between <strong>the</strong><br />

fiscal quarter end and actual earnings report date. Therefore, it is possible that managers adjust shares in<br />

order <strong>to</strong> affect current period <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes. Prior evidence suggests that managers use s<strong>to</strong>ck repurchases<br />

<strong>to</strong> affect current period <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes (Bens et al. (2003) and Hribar et al. (2006)).<br />

If managers observe that current period earnings are lower than expectations, <strong>the</strong>y may choose <strong>to</strong> increase<br />

<strong>the</strong> target size such that <strong>the</strong>y meet (<strong>the</strong> split adjusted) <strong>EPS</strong> expectation. This seems unlikely for a few<br />

reasons. First, we do not observe managers rebalancing shares each quarter - if a firm splits in one quarter<br />

for short-term reasons, <strong>the</strong> firm would prefer <strong>to</strong> reverse split in <strong>the</strong> next quarter <strong>to</strong> return <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> optimal<br />

target size. More importantly, <strong>the</strong>re is a well established positive market reaction <strong>to</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ck splits. This<br />

evidence is not consistent with managers splitting because of negative temporary earnings shocks.<br />

<strong>How</strong>ever, <strong>the</strong>re may be scope for short term considerations <strong>to</strong> affect not whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> firm should split, but<br />

by how much. For example, perhaps <strong>the</strong> manager has determined that <strong>the</strong> firm needs <strong>to</strong> roughly double <strong>the</strong><br />

number of shares. The manager might choose a 7-for-3 split instead of a 2-for-1 split, so that <strong>the</strong> change has<br />

an accretive effect on current period <strong>EPS</strong>. 13 We hypo<strong>the</strong>size that if managers choose split ratios out of short<br />

term considerations, <strong>the</strong>n we should observe atypical ratios more frequently in <strong>the</strong> period after earnings are<br />

13 An example of an accretive split is <strong>the</strong> following: The manager observes current period net income <strong>to</strong> be $15.4. The firm<br />

has 100 shares outstanding, and analysts’ forecasted <strong>EPS</strong> is 0.15. If <strong>the</strong> manager issues a 7-for-3 split, split-adjusted expectation<br />

is 0.06. <strong>How</strong>ever, <strong>the</strong> manager will report split-adjusted <strong>EPS</strong> as 0.07.<br />

12


ealized but before <strong>the</strong>y are reported. We also expect that <strong>the</strong>se splits should more frequently be accretive<br />

than dilutive.<br />

3 Data and Results<br />

3.1 Data<br />

The sample analyzed in this study is compiled from four major databases.<br />

The primary data sample is<br />

ga<strong>the</strong>red from <strong>the</strong> quarterly CRSP/COMPUSTAT Merged database and combined with analyst forecast<br />

data obtained from I/B/E/S. Our sample starts in 1984 since we require 12 previous quarters of analyst<br />

forecasts in our main tests. Our sample ends in 2011. We include s<strong>to</strong>ck return data from CRSP. Only common<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ck with CRSP share code 10 or 11 are included. We merge in institutional ownership obtained from <strong>the</strong><br />

Thomson Reuters 13(f) institutional holdings database. For a subset of tests, we include compensation data<br />

from ExecuComp.<br />

To distinguish between changes in shares outstanding due <strong>to</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ck splits, repurchases, or equity issuances,<br />

we use distribution codes from CRSP. S<strong>to</strong>ck splits have a distribution code equal <strong>to</strong> 5523. In our sample,<br />

we assign a split <strong>to</strong> a fiscal quarter if <strong>the</strong> CRSP payment date (PAYDT) occurs after <strong>the</strong> prior earnings<br />

report date, but before <strong>the</strong> earnings report date as reported in COMPUSTAT. If <strong>the</strong> earnings report date is<br />

missing, a split is assigned <strong>to</strong> a fiscal quarter if it occurs within <strong>the</strong> fiscal quarter begin and end dates.<br />

A key prediction in our study centers on <strong>the</strong> link between shares outstanding and <strong>the</strong> volatility of earnings.<br />

We create three measures of earnings volatility. Net Income Volatility is calculated as <strong>the</strong> standard deviation<br />

of net income over <strong>the</strong> past 12 quarters.<br />

This directly measures <strong>the</strong> variance in net income, however it<br />

does not capture predictable, seasonal net income variation. Net Income Volatility - Naive Forecast is <strong>the</strong><br />

standard deviation of seasonally adjusted net income over <strong>the</strong> past 12 quarters. This proxy captures <strong>the</strong><br />

variance around a time-varying mean using a simple forecast for <strong>the</strong> mean <strong>based</strong> on seasonality and prior<br />

growth in net income. Net Income Volatility - Analysts Forecast is calculated as <strong>the</strong> standard deviation of<br />

(Net Income - median IBES forecasted earnings) over <strong>the</strong> past 12 quarters, where median IBES forecasted<br />

earnings is <strong>the</strong> median <strong>EPS</strong> forecast multiplied by shares outstanding. The benefit of this measure is that it<br />

captures actual earnings expectations in each period. <strong>How</strong>ever, <strong>the</strong> drawback is that it requires data from<br />

IBES which reduces <strong>the</strong> sample.<br />

[Insert Table 1 Here]<br />

13


Table 1 presents <strong>the</strong> summary statistics of <strong>the</strong> sample. The key dependent variable used in this study is<br />

shares outstanding (median = 23.55 million, mean = 83.85 million). <strong>EPS</strong> has a median of $0.19 and mean<br />

of $0.20. This translates <strong>to</strong> a median and mean earnings target size of ±2.6% and ±2.5% of expected net<br />

income.<br />

3.2 Results<br />

We begin by examining if data are consistent with <strong>the</strong> view that managers recognize <strong>the</strong> effects of rounding<br />

and <strong>the</strong> earnings target size, and in particular <strong>the</strong> lower bound of earnings required <strong>to</strong> meet forecasts.<br />

Evidence in prior literature is consistent with this.<br />

For example, Das and Zhang (2003) document an<br />

abnormally large number of net income realizations that round upwards when translating net income <strong>to</strong><br />

<strong>EPS</strong>. Given this evidence, we expect that an abnormal number of net income realizations will be just above<br />

<strong>the</strong> minimum that will round <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>EPS</strong> forecast.<br />

We present a figure that is similar in spirit <strong>to</strong> analyses presented in Burgstahler and Dichev (1997)<br />

and Degeorge et al. (1999), who find an abnormal number of <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes that are just enough <strong>to</strong> clear<br />

certain thresholds. Instead of examining <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes, we plot net income realizations around <strong>the</strong> threshold<br />

E[EP S] ∗ s −<br />

s<br />

200<br />

, which is <strong>the</strong> minimum net income required <strong>to</strong> meet <strong>the</strong> median analyst <strong>EPS</strong> forecast.<br />

We scale each firm’s realized net income by E[EP S] ∗ s − s<br />

200<br />

and plot frequencies in Figure 2. Any value<br />

< 1 means <strong>the</strong> firm missed <strong>the</strong> <strong>EPS</strong> forecast, and a value of 1 indicates that <strong>the</strong> firm reported just enough<br />

net income such that it rounds <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>EPS</strong> forecast.<br />

[Insert Figure 2 Here]<br />

The red line (left line) in <strong>the</strong> figure indicates <strong>the</strong> minimum net income that meets forecasts - <strong>the</strong> lower<br />

bound of <strong>the</strong> target size. The green line (right line) indicates, for <strong>the</strong> average firm, <strong>the</strong> net income implied by<br />

analysts’ forecasts (E[EP S] ∗ s). The figure shows a disproportionate occurrence of net income realizations<br />

that are just enough <strong>to</strong> meet <strong>the</strong> minimum net income required <strong>to</strong> satisfy <strong>the</strong> <strong>EPS</strong> forecast.<br />

In what follows, we examine if managers recognize that <strong>the</strong> location of this threshold is a choice variable<br />

and choose <strong>the</strong> number of shares accordingly.<br />

Our main hypo<strong>the</strong>sis is that managers of firms with<br />

unpredictable net income will choose high levels of shares outstanding so that a wide range of net income<br />

realizations will meet forecasts. We also expect that managers with high incentive compensation will choose<br />

more shares outstanding for similar reasons. We briefly examine <strong>the</strong>se relationships using multivariate sorts.<br />

Figure 3 presents <strong>the</strong> average median shares outstanding across deciles of net income volatility in Panel<br />

14


A and incentive compensation in Panel B. We present medians <strong>to</strong> alleviate concerns of extreme outliers. 14 In<br />

each quarter, we first sort <strong>the</strong> sample in<strong>to</strong> 20 groups <strong>based</strong> on net income, <strong>the</strong>n within each net income group<br />

we sort in<strong>to</strong> deciles <strong>based</strong> on net income volatility or incentive compensation. This allows us <strong>to</strong> compare<br />

firms with roughly equivalent net income. We plot median shares (bar height) across net income deciles. We<br />

also report median net income (line) <strong>to</strong> confirm that we are comparing firms of similar size.<br />

[Insert Figure 3 Here]<br />

We find a strong association between shares outstanding and both net income volatility and incentive<br />

compensation. Shares outstanding mono<strong>to</strong>nically increases across net income volatility deciles. We also<br />

observe a positive trend in shares outstanding across incentive compensation deciles, although <strong>the</strong> pattern<br />

is weaker. In both figures, <strong>the</strong> average net income (line-plot) is stable across <strong>the</strong> decile ranks. 15<br />

While <strong>the</strong><br />

extreme deciles have similar net income, <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>p net income volatility decile has three times as many shares<br />

outstanding (in thousands) than its bot<strong>to</strong>m decile counterpart (33,162 vs. 10,037, p-value < 0.01). In Panel<br />

B, <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>p incentive compensation decile has nearly 40% more shares outstanding than <strong>the</strong> bot<strong>to</strong>m decile<br />

(49,774 vs. 70,898, p-value < 0.01).<br />

3.2.1 Regression Analysis<br />

Results from <strong>the</strong> dependent sorts indicate that firms with similar mean net income but different variance<br />

have drastically different shares outstanding. In this section, we examine cross sectional variation in shares<br />

outstanding in more detail.<br />

Table 2 presents pooled OLS regression models of shares outstanding as a function of firm characteristics.<br />

These results are suggestive of <strong>the</strong> cross sectional determinants of <strong>the</strong> level of shares outstanding. Regression<br />

coefficients are standardized <strong>to</strong> represent standard deviation effects in shares outstanding for a one standard<br />

deviation difference in a given covariate. All determinants of shares outstanding are lagged one period. Column<br />

1 presents a basic specification, including variables representing size (Market Cap), liquidity (Amihud),<br />

and ownership (Percent Institutional Ownership). These determinants have previously been associated with<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ck splits and, as such, we expect <strong>the</strong>m <strong>to</strong> be related <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> level of shares outstanding. This specification<br />

includes a proxy for earnings volatility, Net Income Volatility t−1 , defined as <strong>the</strong> standard deviation of Net<br />

Income over <strong>the</strong> last twelve quarters. These results are robust <strong>to</strong> using various income definitions including<br />

Operating Income Before Depreciation as well as Income Before Extraordinary Items.<br />

14 The patterns in both figures are stronger using averages.<br />

15 The higher level of average net income in Panel B reflects <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> ExecuComp sample of firms are larger.<br />

15


Column 2 presents <strong>the</strong> same specification as column 1, but uses an earnings volatility proxy adjusted<br />

for expectations <strong>based</strong> on prior earnings. Specifically, Net Income Volatility - Naive Forecast t−1 is measured<br />

as <strong>the</strong> standard deviation of <strong>the</strong> difference between actual earnings and a seasonally adjusted proxy for<br />

expected earnings. The expected earnings is earnings from 4 quarters prior, plus <strong>the</strong> difference between <strong>the</strong><br />

earnings 4 quarters and 8 quarters before. Column 3 presents ano<strong>the</strong>r specification using a third proxy for<br />

earnings volatility, Net Income Volatility - Analyst Forecast t−1 . This is <strong>the</strong> volatility of earnings adjusted for<br />

analysts’ forecasts over <strong>the</strong> last twelve quarters. Finally, column 4 presents <strong>the</strong> same specification as column<br />

1, but includes a measure for <strong>the</strong> level of incentive compensation. This is measured as 1 − (<br />

salary<br />

<strong>to</strong>talcompensation )<br />

and is meant <strong>to</strong> capture both explicit <strong>EPS</strong> incentives (through bonuses) and implicit incentives including<br />

sensitivity <strong>to</strong> market reactions due <strong>to</strong> unexpected earnings (through grants and options). This measure is<br />

available only for firms in <strong>the</strong> ExecuComp database.<br />

[Insert Table 2 Here]<br />

The hypo<strong>the</strong>sis described in Section 2 suggests that <strong>the</strong> number of shares outstanding should be related<br />

<strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> volatility of earnings relative <strong>to</strong> expectations as well as <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> payoffs <strong>to</strong> managers, conditional on<br />

meeting earnings. We examine both of <strong>the</strong>se aspects. The higher <strong>the</strong> volatility, <strong>the</strong> more likely a firm<br />

misses earnings by chance, while <strong>the</strong> lower <strong>the</strong> volatility, <strong>the</strong> higher <strong>the</strong> probability of meeting or beating<br />

earnings. In column 1, we see that <strong>the</strong> higher <strong>the</strong> level of Net Income Volatility t−1 , <strong>the</strong> higher <strong>the</strong> number<br />

of shares outstanding. This is strongly significant, both economically and statistically. A firm with earnings<br />

volatility one standard deviation above <strong>the</strong> mean has 0.21 standard deviations more shares outstanding.<br />

The association is consistent across columns 1-3 using different proxies for earnings volatility. In fact, when<br />

looking at volatility relative <strong>to</strong> analyst forecasts, <strong>the</strong> effect is even larger. One standard deviation higher<br />

earnings volatility is associated with 0.30 standard deviations more shares.<br />

We also examine payoffs <strong>to</strong> managers conditional on meeting or beating earnings. Under our hypo<strong>the</strong>sis,<br />

we expect that <strong>the</strong> stronger <strong>the</strong> incentives for managers <strong>to</strong> avoid missing earnings forecasts, <strong>the</strong> more shares<br />

outstanding. In column 4, we proxy for <strong>the</strong>se incentives with <strong>the</strong> fraction of CEO compensation that is<br />

performance <strong>based</strong>. S<strong>to</strong>ck and option ownership should be associated with strong incentives <strong>to</strong> meet or beat<br />

earnings due <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> strong negative s<strong>to</strong>ck market reaction <strong>to</strong> missing forecasts. Bonuses paid <strong>to</strong> managers<br />

are often paid <strong>based</strong> on meeting <strong>EPS</strong> targets (De Angelis and Grinstein (2011), Young and Yang (2011),<br />

Kim and Yang (2012)). The measure of <strong>to</strong>tal incentive compensation should capture both of <strong>the</strong>se aspects<br />

of a manager’s incentive <strong>to</strong> meet earnings. Consistent with this, we see a small but significantly positive<br />

16


elationship between incentive compensation and shares outstanding. Specifically, a one standard deviation<br />

larger incentive compensation is associated with 0.05 standard deviations more shares outstanding.<br />

Consistent with <strong>the</strong> nominal price puzzle (Weld et al. (2009)), we see that larger firms have more shares<br />

outstanding.<br />

A one standard deviation change in size is associated with 0.76 standard deviations more<br />

shares outstanding. We also find that a one standard deviation larger Amihud measure is associated with a<br />

small (0.11 of a standard deviation), but statistically significant lower number of shares outstanding. This<br />

is consistent with <strong>the</strong> evidence that liquidity tends <strong>to</strong> improve after a s<strong>to</strong>ck splits. In column 1, we see<br />

no evidence of Institutional Ownership relating <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> share structure of <strong>the</strong> firm. <strong>How</strong>ever, in column 4,<br />

controlling for incentive compensation (which reduces <strong>the</strong> sample due <strong>to</strong> data requirements), we see that<br />

Institutional Ownership is negatively related <strong>to</strong> shares outstanding. This is consistent with Dyl and Elliott<br />

(2006) who find that smaller share price s<strong>to</strong>cks have lower institutional ownership.<br />

While our evidence on <strong>the</strong> volatility of earnings and incentive compensation is consistent with our hypo<strong>the</strong>sis,<br />

we find evidence that <strong>the</strong> level of net income is negatively associated with shares outstanding.<br />

This is not entirely surprising. After controlling for size, <strong>the</strong>re is significantly less variation in net income.<br />

Moreover, <strong>the</strong>se findings highlight <strong>the</strong> thorny fact that <strong>the</strong>se firm characteristics are jointly determined and<br />

are likely related <strong>to</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r, unobserved characteristics. Therefore, fully understanding what is driving <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> shares outstanding choice requires a different identification strategy.<br />

To <strong>the</strong> extent that firms have unobserved characteristics that determine share structure and managerial<br />

incentives, <strong>the</strong> simple pooled OLS estimates will be biased and inconsistent. The first step we take <strong>to</strong> mitigate<br />

<strong>the</strong>se issues is <strong>to</strong> examine a simple first difference model. This specification will measure <strong>the</strong> relationship<br />

between changes in firm characteristics and changes in shares outstanding. To <strong>the</strong> extent that a firm’s level<br />

of shares is determined by some variety of unobserved firm characteristics, focusing on changes will allow us<br />

<strong>to</strong> identify <strong>the</strong> effect of firm observable characteristics that change over time. While <strong>the</strong> specification itself<br />

mitigates issues with unobserved time invariant heterogeneity, it does not rule out <strong>the</strong> possibility of reverse<br />

causality.<br />

In Table 3, we present three specifications, one for each of <strong>the</strong> earnings volatility proxies described in<br />

Table 2. Consistent with prior results, earnings volatility is an important determinant of shares outstanding.<br />

In this case, a one standard deviation change in earnings volatility is associated with between 0.03 and 0.07<br />

standard deviations of changes in shares outstanding. This effect is statistically significant at <strong>the</strong> 1% level<br />

and is still economically large when considering it is an estimate of changes.<br />

[Insert Table 3 Here]<br />

17


While Table 2 and Table 3 establish a relationship between earnings volatility and shares outstanding<br />

in both <strong>the</strong> cross section and time series, <strong>the</strong>y do not establish a clear causal link due <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> presence of<br />

unobserved firm characteristics that likely change through time. In order <strong>to</strong> examine this question more<br />

carefully and test <strong>the</strong> explicit hypo<strong>the</strong>ses outlined above, we use exogenous variation in <strong>the</strong> volatility of<br />

earnings around <strong>the</strong> expectation <strong>to</strong> establish a causal link between incentives and share structure.<br />

In Table 4 we use an instrumental variable approach for <strong>the</strong> first difference model described above. We<br />

instrument for <strong>the</strong> volatility of earnings (proxied for in Table 2 using <strong>the</strong> volatility of earnings relative <strong>to</strong><br />

analyst forecasts) by using exogenous drops in analyst coverage. Our identification strategy is similar <strong>to</strong><br />

those used in Hong and Kacperczyk (2010), Kelly and Ljungqvist (2012), and Derrien and Kecskés (2012)<br />

who argue that <strong>the</strong> consolidation of analyst coverage following brokerage house mergers leads <strong>to</strong> exogenous<br />

drops in overall coverage. When brokerage houses merge, <strong>the</strong> combined houses will often have more than<br />

one analyst covering a s<strong>to</strong>ck. As brokerages reduce coverage <strong>to</strong> eliminate this duplication of effort, <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal<br />

number of analysts following certain s<strong>to</strong>cks drops; however, this drop in coverage is exogenous <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm’s<br />

fundamentals.<br />

[Insert Table 4 Here]<br />

We use a slight variation in <strong>the</strong> brokerage house strategy employed by Degeorge et al. (2012). We use<br />

drops in analyst coverage brought on by analysts that leave <strong>the</strong> IBES database permanently in that period.<br />

As shown in Degeorge et al. (2012), <strong>the</strong>se drops match <strong>the</strong> distribution of those from brokerage mergers.<br />

After a drop in analyst coverage, <strong>the</strong> consensus forecasts will be noisier because <strong>the</strong> consensus is formed over<br />

a smaller sampling of analysts - <strong>the</strong> variance of <strong>the</strong> sample mean is decreasing in n. Therefore, it is less<br />

likely that realized <strong>EPS</strong> will meet forecasts solely as a result of <strong>the</strong> drop.<br />

In Table 4, we show results from <strong>the</strong> second stage of a 2SLS regression using <strong>the</strong> drop in a analyst<br />

coverage as an instrument for Net Income Volatility-Analyst Forecast t−1 . Our instrument is strong. In <strong>the</strong><br />

first stage regression, <strong>the</strong> t-statistic on <strong>the</strong> instrument is > 5 and <strong>the</strong> F-statistic is > 25, both well above<br />

<strong>the</strong> benchmarks established in S<strong>to</strong>ck et al. (2002). Using <strong>the</strong> instrumental variable approach, we see still<br />

see a strong causal relationship between changes in <strong>the</strong> volatility of forecast errors and shares outstanding.<br />

Specifically, a one standard deviation increase in Net Income Volatility-Analyst Forecast t−1 is associated<br />

with a 0.53-0.58 standard deviation increase in <strong>the</strong> number of shares outstanding. This is an economically<br />

large effect, as one standard deviation is measured over <strong>the</strong> entire cross sectional distribution of shares<br />

outstanding. Given <strong>the</strong> exogenous nature of <strong>the</strong> instrument, we can now document evidence consistent with<br />

18


<strong>the</strong> view that increases in forecast volatility cause managers <strong>to</strong> increase <strong>the</strong> number of shares outstanding.<br />

Comparing <strong>the</strong>se coefficients <strong>to</strong> Table 3 we see a much larger effect. This difference provides strong evidence<br />

of <strong>the</strong> endogenous relationship between <strong>the</strong>se variables and shows <strong>the</strong> importance of <strong>the</strong> exogenous shock in<br />

terms of measuring magnitudes.<br />

We also see a clearer relationship with respect <strong>to</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r incentives and share structures. Changes in Market<br />

<strong>to</strong> Book are negatively related <strong>to</strong> shares outstanding. A one standard deviation increase in Market <strong>to</strong> Book<br />

is associated with 0.03 standard deviation decrease in shares outstanding, but this effect is insignificant<br />

when we control for incentive compensation. We also find a positive effect of 0.08 standard deviations due<br />

<strong>to</strong> a change in Market Cap. These two results are consistent with De Angelis and Grinstein (2011) who<br />

show that small, high growth firms compensate managers less on accounting <strong>based</strong> criteria. We also observe<br />

that as Net Income grows, shares outstanding increase. Finally, in column 2 of Table 4 <strong>the</strong>re is a small<br />

but significant positive relationship between increases in incentive compensation and <strong>the</strong> change in shares<br />

outstanding. Overall, we find that changes in forecast error volatility cause an increase in shares and that<br />

net income growth and incentive compensation increases are also associated with an increase in shares. This<br />

evidence supports our hypo<strong>the</strong>sis H1A described in Section 2.<br />

In Table 5, we explore in more detail <strong>the</strong> mechanism by which managers increase <strong>the</strong>ir shares outstanding.<br />

In order <strong>to</strong> compare across columns, we use standardized independent variables and unstandardized measures<br />

for changes in shares outstanding.<br />

This allows us <strong>to</strong> interpret <strong>the</strong> coefficients as <strong>the</strong> number of shares<br />

increased (or decreased) due <strong>to</strong> a one standard deviation change in a given independent variable. We do<br />

this <strong>to</strong> compare across different sources of share increases which have different cross sectional distributions.<br />

Column 1 reports <strong>the</strong> effect of changes in characteristics on increases in shares from sources o<strong>the</strong>r than s<strong>to</strong>ck<br />

splits. While <strong>the</strong> point estimate for changes in Net Income Volatility as instrumented by analyst coverage<br />

drops shows an increase in shares outstanding from a combination of issuances, treasury shares, and s<strong>to</strong>ck<br />

awards, <strong>the</strong> effect is not statistically significant. In contrast, column 2 shows a large and significant increase<br />

in shares due <strong>to</strong> an increase in Net Income Volatility (as instrumented by analyst coverage) as a result of<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ck splits. These results suggest that <strong>the</strong> channel managers use <strong>to</strong> increase <strong>the</strong> range of Net Income that<br />

will round <strong>to</strong> analyst expectations is through s<strong>to</strong>ck splits, not through issuances or use of treasury s<strong>to</strong>ck.<br />

This evidence is consistent with hypo<strong>the</strong>sis H4.<br />

To provide fur<strong>the</strong>r evidence that managers engage in target size management, we explore a unique feature<br />

of <strong>the</strong> relationship between shares, net income, and target size. The size of <strong>the</strong> earnings target is a function of<br />

<strong>the</strong> magnitude of <strong>the</strong> <strong>EPS</strong> forecast, not <strong>the</strong> sign. Therefore, earnings growth has opposite effects, depending<br />

19


on whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> firm has positive or negative earnings. As such, we expect differential results depending on<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r firms have positive or negative <strong>EPS</strong> (see Section 2 H5).<br />

[Insert Table 5 Here]<br />

Columns 3 and 4 test this discontinuity in our prediction explicitly. We split <strong>the</strong> sample <strong>based</strong> on firms<br />

that have negative earnings (column 3) and firms with positive earnings (column 4). The effect of Net Income<br />

Volatility is driven largely by <strong>the</strong> positive <strong>EPS</strong> firms. Consistent with our predictions, <strong>the</strong> coefficient on Net<br />

Income growth is negative for those firms with negative <strong>EPS</strong>. The net income of <strong>the</strong>se firms is growing (i.e.<br />

getting closer <strong>to</strong> zero) which suggests that <strong>the</strong> rounding range is actually increasing. As a result, <strong>the</strong>se firms<br />

are less likely <strong>to</strong> split.<br />

In columns 5 and 6, we examine in fur<strong>the</strong>r detail <strong>the</strong> effect that compensation structure has on <strong>the</strong> response<br />

of firms <strong>to</strong> volatility shocks. We split <strong>the</strong> sample <strong>based</strong> on Incentive Compensation. We expect that<br />

<strong>the</strong> stronger <strong>the</strong> <strong>EPS</strong> incentives, <strong>the</strong> stronger <strong>the</strong> observed effect of forecast volatility on s<strong>to</strong>ck splits (hypo<strong>the</strong>sis<br />

H2a). We see that <strong>the</strong> coefficient is substantially larger for firms with high incentive compensation<br />

(column 5) compared <strong>to</strong> low incentive compensation (column 6), for which <strong>the</strong> coefficient is not statistically<br />

different from zero. While we cannot reject <strong>the</strong> null that <strong>the</strong>se two coefficients are statistically <strong>the</strong> same,<br />

<strong>the</strong> point estimates suggest a strong relationship between incentive compensation and <strong>the</strong> magnitude of our<br />

effect.<br />

3.2.2 Costs of Splitting<br />

The evidence so far is consistent with managers adjusting shares <strong>to</strong> manage <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> <strong>EPS</strong> target. In<br />

this section, we examine if target size management is conditional on o<strong>the</strong>r costs or benefits relating <strong>to</strong> shares.<br />

<strong>How</strong>ever, we also recognize that a change in <strong>the</strong> quantity of tradeable securities affects things o<strong>the</strong>r than<br />

just <strong>the</strong> target, and that managers likely trade off o<strong>the</strong>r costs or benefits when choosing <strong>to</strong> adjust shares. In<br />

certain cases, <strong>the</strong> manager might find it <strong>to</strong>o costly <strong>to</strong> increase <strong>the</strong> target size for o<strong>the</strong>r share-related reasons,<br />

such as liquidity/delisting.<br />

In Table 6, we estimate models <strong>the</strong> using same specification presented in Table 5. Motivated by <strong>the</strong><br />

“optimal trading range” (see, e.g., Baker and Gallagher (1980)), we include indica<strong>to</strong>r variables for high<br />

priced s<strong>to</strong>cks (above $80) and low priced s<strong>to</strong>cks (below $20). While we control for price (market value) in<br />

all previous regressions, <strong>the</strong> optimal trading range suggests a non-linear relationship. High priced s<strong>to</strong>cks are<br />

much more likely <strong>to</strong> split, but our results are not driven by <strong>the</strong>se firms. The results are robust <strong>to</strong> using o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

price level cu<strong>to</strong>ffs as well.<br />

20


In columns 2 and 3, we measure our effect conditional on illiquidity. We split <strong>the</strong> sample <strong>based</strong> on median<br />

Amihud. We expect <strong>the</strong> cost of splitting <strong>to</strong> be significantly higher for less liquid s<strong>to</strong>cks due <strong>to</strong> microstructure<br />

constraints (hypo<strong>the</strong>sis H3). Consistent with this, we see little effect in <strong>the</strong> highly illiquid s<strong>to</strong>cks. Conversely,<br />

we see a large effect in column 3 for those that are highly liquid.<br />

[Insert Table 6 Here]<br />

3.2.3 Changes in shares, earnings management, and <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes<br />

If managers increase shares in order <strong>to</strong> increase <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> earnings target, <strong>the</strong>n increases in shares should<br />

be associated with an increase in <strong>the</strong> frequency with which <strong>the</strong> firms meets <strong>EPS</strong> expectations (H6) and with<br />

a decrease in <strong>the</strong> usage of o<strong>the</strong>r earnings management <strong>to</strong>ols (H7). To examine potential associations, we<br />

distinguish quarters in which <strong>the</strong> firm’s shares increased by at least 25% (a split ratio of at least 5-for-4).<br />

In Table 7, we examine changes in <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes over time and distinguish between changes around share<br />

increases from those without.<br />

[Insert Table 7 Here]<br />

In Panel A, we compare <strong>the</strong> frequencies with which firms meet, beat, or miss <strong>EPS</strong> targets at quarter<br />

t − 1 (<strong>the</strong> “pre” period) <strong>to</strong> those at quarter t + 1 (“post”). We compute <strong>the</strong> difference in <strong>the</strong> pre and post<br />

period, and <strong>the</strong>n differentiate firms that increase shares at t = 0 (<strong>the</strong> treatment group) from those that do<br />

not (control) and compute <strong>the</strong> difference in <strong>the</strong> sample mean differences.<br />

Among firms that increase shares in quarter t = 0, we find that <strong>the</strong>y meet <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts 71% on average<br />

in quarter t − 1 and this increases <strong>to</strong> 76% in <strong>the</strong> quarter after <strong>the</strong> share increase. This is statistically and<br />

economically different from <strong>the</strong> difference among <strong>the</strong> control group. We also find that <strong>the</strong> treatment firms<br />

miss and beat <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts less frequently following share increases. These differences relative <strong>to</strong> those<br />

of <strong>the</strong> control group are also significant - firms miss <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts 22% of <strong>the</strong> time in <strong>the</strong> quarter prior <strong>to</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> share increase and this drops <strong>to</strong> 18% in <strong>the</strong> quarter following <strong>the</strong> increase. Firms beat <strong>EPS</strong> 7.3% pre<br />

increase, and this drops <strong>to</strong> 6.1%. We find similar effects in Panel B which uses four quarter averages for <strong>the</strong><br />

pre and post periods.<br />

We also examine <strong>the</strong> association between increases in shares and <strong>the</strong> usage of accruals and real earnings<br />

management <strong>to</strong>ols in a similar manner. We use two measures of accruals and three measures of real earnings<br />

management. Discretionary accruals are residuals from industry <strong>to</strong>tal accruals regressions including performance<br />

controls following Ecker et al. (2011). Total accruals are defined as <strong>the</strong> change in current assets,<br />

21


adjusted for <strong>the</strong> change in cash, minus <strong>the</strong> change in current liabilities, adjusted for current liabilities used<br />

for financing, minus depreciation expense. Measures of real earnings management are estimated by abnormal<br />

cash flow, production costs, and expenditure following <strong>the</strong> methodology in Roychowdhury (2006). We do<br />

not have predictions on <strong>the</strong> sign of accruals or real earnings management, only on <strong>the</strong> magnitude of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

usage because increasing <strong>the</strong> target size makes it easier <strong>to</strong> meet <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts from above as well as from<br />

below. Therefore, we examine changes in <strong>the</strong> absolute values of <strong>the</strong>se earnings management <strong>to</strong>ols. Results<br />

are reported in Table 8.<br />

[Insert Table 8 Here]<br />

We find evidence that <strong>the</strong> usage of accruals and real earnings management drops after <strong>the</strong> manager<br />

increases shares outstanding. This is broadly consistent with Cheong and Thomas (2012) who show that<br />

higher accruals are associated with higher <strong>EPS</strong> levels. For example, among firms that increase shares, <strong>the</strong><br />

usage of <strong>to</strong>tal accruals drops from 3.76% of assets over t − 1 <strong>to</strong> 3.30% over t + 1. This is compared <strong>to</strong> a slight<br />

increase (3.09% <strong>to</strong> 3.10%) over time among <strong>the</strong> control group. There are similar drops in <strong>the</strong> usage of o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

measures of accounting and real earnings management surrounding increases in shares, and <strong>the</strong>se hold using<br />

four quarter averages as well (Panel B). Overall, <strong>the</strong> results indicate that an increase in <strong>the</strong> target size is<br />

associated with significant, real effects on <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes and <strong>the</strong> usage of o<strong>the</strong>r earnings management <strong>to</strong>ols.<br />

3.2.4 Short term rounding effects<br />

As discussed in Section 2, managers might choose <strong>the</strong> amount by which <strong>the</strong>y change shares in light of current<br />

period earnings. To examine this, we distinguish splits by <strong>the</strong> timing in which <strong>the</strong>y are declared and <strong>the</strong><br />

magnitude of <strong>the</strong> split fac<strong>to</strong>r. First, we identify a split as late if it occurs after <strong>the</strong> quarter end but before<br />

<strong>the</strong> earnings report date. Also, for each split we set a dummy variable atypical equal <strong>to</strong> one if <strong>the</strong> split fac<strong>to</strong>r<br />

is not in (1.25, 1.33, 1.5, 1.75, 2, 2.5, 3, 4, 5, 10).<br />

Similar <strong>to</strong> Bens et al. (2003) and Hribar et al. (2006), we determine if each split had an accretive or<br />

dilutive effect (or nei<strong>the</strong>r) on that quarter-end’s <strong>EPS</strong> by comparing <strong>the</strong> post-split <strong>EPS</strong> <strong>to</strong> what <strong>the</strong> <strong>EPS</strong><br />

would have been had <strong>the</strong> firm not split. We compute post-split as IBADJQ/CSHPRQ (from Compustat)<br />

rounded <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> penny. We compute pre-split <strong>EPS</strong> as IBADJQ/CSHPRQ*FACSHR, rounded <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> penny,<br />

<strong>the</strong>n divided by <strong>the</strong> split fac<strong>to</strong>r. If <strong>the</strong> post-split <strong>EPS</strong> is greater than <strong>the</strong> pre-split <strong>EPS</strong> <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> split is<br />

accretive. The split is dilutive if <strong>the</strong> post-split <strong>EPS</strong> is less than pre-split, and nei<strong>the</strong>r if <strong>the</strong>re is no difference.<br />

We expect that, if firms choose <strong>the</strong> magnitude of <strong>the</strong> split out of concern for its accretive or dilutive<br />

effects on current period <strong>EPS</strong>, <strong>the</strong>se splits will occur late in <strong>the</strong> quarter, and will, on average, be in an<br />

22


atypical amount. In Table 9, we report <strong>the</strong> percentage of splits that are accretive, dilutive, or nei<strong>the</strong>r for<br />

<strong>the</strong> full sample and subsamples. We find little evidence that managers use atypical split ratios and timing<br />

<strong>to</strong> generate accretive rounding effects. Given <strong>the</strong> lack of economic significance, we do not formally report<br />

statistical significance. Across all splits, 31.8% have an accretive effect and 29% have a dilutive effect. This<br />

difference is roughly <strong>the</strong> same whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> split occurred during <strong>the</strong> quarter or after quarter end. Similarly,<br />

we see no meaningful difference between accretive and dilutive when distinguishing between typical and<br />

atypical split ratios.<br />

[Insert Table 9 Here]<br />

When we look exactly where we expect <strong>to</strong> see an effect - late splits that are of atypical split fac<strong>to</strong>rs -<br />

we see a large difference. <strong>How</strong>ever, only 13 splits satisfy <strong>the</strong>se criteria, far from an economically meaningful<br />

effect. To summarize, we find very little evidence that splits are used <strong>to</strong> have an accretive effect on current<br />

period <strong>EPS</strong>.<br />

3.3 Additional Implications<br />

In this section, we discuss a few additional implication of TSM. Because TSM is achieved by changing shares,<br />

any per-share metric will be affected. This suggests that cross sectional variation in a variety of per share<br />

metrics such as analyst forecast error or dispersion, and even s<strong>to</strong>ck prices, may be <strong>the</strong> endogenous outcome<br />

of TSM. We briefly examine how TSM may relate <strong>to</strong> i) analysts’ forecast errors, ii) <strong>the</strong> nominal s<strong>to</strong>ck price<br />

puzzle, and iii) idiosyncratic return volatility.<br />

3.3.1 Scale invariance of forecast volatility<br />

The observation that firms with higher <strong>EPS</strong> levels have lower variance in forecast errors than what would<br />

o<strong>the</strong>rwise be expected was first documented in Degeorge et al. (1999). More recent work has attempted <strong>to</strong><br />

understand why this scale invariance exists. Cheong and Thomas (2011) test three potential explanations<br />

and find results that, on net, suggest managers suppress <strong>the</strong> natural variation due <strong>to</strong> scale. Importantly,<br />

forecast error variance is computed at <strong>the</strong> per-share level, which means it is a function of <strong>the</strong> magnitude<br />

of rounding. Ball (2011) describes how rounding net income at <strong>the</strong> share level can introduce noise, and<br />

suggests that this could contribute <strong>to</strong> a lack of variance with scale. We build on this by positing that scale<br />

invariance is <strong>the</strong> endogenous outcome of TSM. In fact, <strong>the</strong> lack of variation with scale is essentially our main<br />

prediction. To see this, consider a simple example.<br />

23


Two firms are <strong>the</strong> same in all ways except for <strong>the</strong>ir distributions of net income. Firm A’s net income is<br />

distributed uniformly over [9, 11), and Firm B’s net income is uniformly distributed over [8, 12). So both firms<br />

have <strong>the</strong> same expected net income but B is more volatile than A. If both managers equally value meeting<br />

<strong>EPS</strong> forecasts, <strong>the</strong>n each will choose shares outstanding such that <strong>the</strong> probability of meeting expectations is<br />

<strong>the</strong> same across both firms. If Firm A has 100 shares outstanding, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> probability that <strong>the</strong> firm meets<br />

earnings is 1/2. 16 If <strong>the</strong> manager of B also wants <strong>to</strong> meet forecasts half of <strong>the</strong> time, <strong>the</strong> firm will need 200<br />

shares outstanding. 17<br />

From here it is easy <strong>to</strong> show that <strong>the</strong> two firms will have identical variance in forecast errors.<br />

For<br />

each firm, one fourth of <strong>the</strong> time <strong>the</strong> firm will miss <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts by one penny, one-half of <strong>the</strong> time <strong>the</strong>y<br />

meet expectations, and one-fourth of <strong>the</strong> time <strong>the</strong>y beat expectations by a penny. 18<br />

In this way, <strong>the</strong> scale<br />

invariance of forecast errors is <strong>the</strong> equilibrium outcome of managers’ incentive <strong>to</strong> meet <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, we would expect forecast error variance <strong>to</strong> drop after a split. If nothing changes about<br />

Firm A o<strong>the</strong>r than that it issues a two-for-one s<strong>to</strong>ck split, <strong>the</strong> variance in forecast errors drops <strong>to</strong> zero (all<br />

possible net income outcomes generate <strong>EPS</strong> = 0.05).<br />

We do not think our results completely explain <strong>the</strong> puzzle of scale invariant forecast errors. Cheong and<br />

Thomas (2011) find that <strong>the</strong> scale invariance is not present in per share cash flow forecasts, for example.<br />

A simple rounding <strong>based</strong> explanation is not consistent with this important finding.<br />

Therefore, it seems<br />

reasonable <strong>to</strong> conclude that target size management can explain some of <strong>the</strong> scale invariance results, but <strong>the</strong><br />

active smoothing of earnings by managers also plays an important role.<br />

3.3.2 Nominal price puzzle<br />

Weld et al. (2009) document that nominal per-share s<strong>to</strong>ck prices have remained remarkably constant across<br />

time (1933-2007). This is surprising given significant inflation over <strong>the</strong> same period. The authors estimate<br />

that if real s<strong>to</strong>ck prices had remained constant over this period, prices <strong>to</strong>day would average around $450.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> authors make <strong>the</strong> observation that existing <strong>the</strong>ories of s<strong>to</strong>ck splits fail <strong>to</strong> predict that<br />

nominal share prices would remain constant. The authors conclude that social norms drive managers <strong>to</strong> use<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ck splits <strong>to</strong> keep nominal prices at some fixed level.<br />

While our results may not fully explain <strong>the</strong> nominal price puzzle, TSM may contribute <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> constant<br />

16 For simplicity assume that forecasts are unbiased. The firm needs net income within ± 0.5 = 5%, or any net income<br />

|E[EP S]|<br />

∈ [9.5, 10.5). The firm will generate net income in this range 10.5−9.5 = 1 of <strong>the</strong> time.<br />

11−9 2<br />

s<br />

17 Set <strong>the</strong> probability of meeting forecasts equal <strong>to</strong> 1/2 and solve for s: 1/2 = 100<br />

12−8 .<br />

18 For Firm A, Var = 1 4 (0.09 − 0.10)2 + 1 2 (0)2 + 1 4 (0.11 − 0.10)2 = 1 2 (0.01)2 . For Firm B, Var = 1 4 (0.04 − 0.5)2 + 1 2 (0)2 +<br />

1<br />

4 (0.06 − 0.05)2 = 1 2 (0.01)2 .<br />

24


price levels observed in <strong>the</strong> data. Firms are required <strong>to</strong> round <strong>EPS</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> penny, and this remains true<br />

despite <strong>the</strong> penny declining in real value. Because <strong>the</strong> norm of rounding <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> penny has been stable, so<br />

should nominal <strong>EPS</strong> levels. If managers choose shares outstanding <strong>to</strong> maintain a constant nominal level of<br />

<strong>EPS</strong>, <strong>the</strong>n it may not be surprising <strong>to</strong> also find constant nominal price levels over time.<br />

In each quarter, we compute <strong>the</strong> median price-per-share and median earnings-per-share. We plot <strong>the</strong>se<br />

median values over time in Figure 3. Due <strong>to</strong> Compustat earnings data limitations, we limit <strong>the</strong> sample <strong>to</strong><br />

post 1970. Weld et al (2009) argue that managers choose shares outstanding <strong>to</strong> keep prices constant, whereas<br />

we argue that managers choose shares outstanding <strong>to</strong> keep earnings per share constant. The figure shows<br />

that, not surprisingly, prices and earnings levels are strongly related. It is also evident that <strong>the</strong>re is variation<br />

in both price-per-share and earnings-per-share medians.<br />

[Insert Figure 4 about here]<br />

It is difficult <strong>to</strong> distinguish between <strong>the</strong> incentive for constant nominal <strong>EPS</strong> generating constant nominal<br />

prices from <strong>the</strong> incentive for constant nominal prices generating nominal <strong>EPS</strong>. We attempt <strong>to</strong> provide some<br />

evidence that <strong>the</strong> incentive for constant <strong>EPS</strong> does affect aggregate price levels. To do so, we use time series<br />

variation in net income volatility. Our earlier results suggest that firms respond <strong>to</strong> increases in net income<br />

volatility by reducing <strong>EPS</strong> levels.<br />

Therefore, we predict that changes in aggregate net income volatility<br />

should predict changes in aggregate <strong>EPS</strong> levels.<br />

If managers are choosing constant <strong>EPS</strong> levels and not<br />

constant price levels, <strong>the</strong>n this variation should also show up in price levels. O<strong>the</strong>rwise, it is less clear why<br />

aggregate per share price levels should be a function of lagged aggregate net income volatility.<br />

We compute correlations between median price-per-share, median earnings-per-share, and median Net<br />

Income volatility (measured for each firm using <strong>the</strong> prior 12 quarters) over time. Median prices and median<br />

earnings are highly correlated, 0.68. The correlation between median <strong>EPS</strong> and median NI volatility is -0.38,<br />

and significant at <strong>the</strong> 1% level. This is consistent with our cross-sectional results which suggest that firms<br />

decrease <strong>EPS</strong> as a response <strong>to</strong> an increase in volatility. More interestingly, median nominal prices are also<br />

negatively correlated with trailing 12-quarter NI volatility (ρ = −0.16, pvalue = 0.025). This suggests that<br />

managers’ incentives for certain <strong>EPS</strong> levels contribute <strong>to</strong> variation in price levels.<br />

Our results do not suggest that social norms have no role. In fact norms may be <strong>the</strong> primary determinant<br />

of constant nominal prices. We merely suggest that TSM is an explanation for s<strong>to</strong>ck splits that is consistent<br />

with constant nominal price levels.<br />

25


3.3.3 S<strong>to</strong>ck price levels and idiosyncratic volatility<br />

Target Size Management has implications for <strong>the</strong> relationship between per share s<strong>to</strong>ck price levels and return<br />

volatility. One result documented in Brandt et al. (2010) is that lower priced s<strong>to</strong>cks have higher return<br />

volatility. An interpretation of this relationship is that low priced s<strong>to</strong>cks have higher volatility because <strong>the</strong>y<br />

have a low price, and that this is a result of a retail trader clientele effect. TSM suggest that causality may<br />

run in <strong>the</strong> opposite direction. Firms with high earnings volatility may choose low prices as a result of <strong>EPS</strong><br />

incentives. To <strong>the</strong> extent that earnings volatility and return volatility are correlated, we would expect <strong>to</strong> see<br />

similar empirical outcomes but with causality running in <strong>the</strong> opposite direction.<br />

In unreported tests, we observe a nearly identical relationship between per share price levels and return<br />

volatility (Brandt et al. (2010)) and per share price level and net income volatility (TSM). Distinguishing<br />

between <strong>the</strong>se two possible explanations is beyond <strong>the</strong> scope of this paper.<br />

<strong>How</strong>ever, this highlights an<br />

example of potential implications of target size management that are beyond financial reporting and <strong>EPS</strong><br />

outcomes.<br />

4 Conclusion<br />

A range of net income numbers will generate <strong>the</strong> same <strong>EPS</strong> number. This is because earnings per share<br />

are rounded <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> nearest penny. So, for any given <strong>EPS</strong> forecast, <strong>the</strong>re is a range of <strong>to</strong>tal earnings that<br />

will meet that forecast. We refer <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> magnitude of this range as <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> earnings target. The<br />

size of <strong>the</strong> earnings target is a function of <strong>the</strong> number of shares outstanding. We find evidence consistent<br />

with <strong>the</strong> view that managers engage in target size management - adjusting <strong>the</strong> firm’s quantity of tradeable<br />

securities <strong>to</strong> affect <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> range of net income numbers that meet <strong>EPS</strong> forecasts. We find that an<br />

exogenous decrease in <strong>the</strong> probability of meeting earnings estimates causes managers <strong>to</strong> split <strong>the</strong>ir s<strong>to</strong>cks,<br />

<strong>the</strong>reby increasing <strong>the</strong> earnings target size. We find that this effect is stronger among firms whose managers’<br />

compensation is highly sensitive <strong>to</strong> <strong>EPS</strong> surprises, and weaker among firms for which an increase in shares<br />

would be highly costly (e.g., highly illiquid firms).<br />

Target size management has real effects. We find that firms are more likely <strong>to</strong> meet <strong>EPS</strong> expectations<br />

following an increase in shares. Simultaneously, <strong>the</strong>se firms use less accounting and real earnings management<br />

<strong>to</strong>ols. Both of <strong>the</strong>se associations are consistent with an increase in shares increasing <strong>the</strong> earnings target size.<br />

Our results suggest that <strong>the</strong> magnitude of <strong>the</strong> firm’s long run usage of earnings management <strong>to</strong>ols is a<br />

managerial choice. This has implications for research examining <strong>the</strong> determinants of traditional earnings<br />

26


management <strong>to</strong>ols.<br />

27


References<br />

Asquith, P., P. Healy, and K. Palepu (1989). Earnings and s<strong>to</strong>ck splits. The Accounting Review 64 (3), pp.<br />

387–403.<br />

Baker, H. K. and P. L. Gallagher (1980). Management’s view of s<strong>to</strong>ck splits. Financial Management 9 (2),<br />

pp. 73–77.<br />

Ball, R. T. (2011). Discussion of why do eps forecast error and dispersion not vary with scale? implications<br />

for analyst and managerial behavior. Journal of Accounting Research 49 (2), 403–412.<br />

Beidleman, C. R. (1973). Income smoothing: The role of management. The Accounting Review 48 (4), pp.<br />

653–667.<br />

Bens, D. A., V. Nagar, D. J. Skinner, and M. Wong (2003). Employee s<strong>to</strong>ck options, {<strong>EPS</strong>} dilution, and<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ck repurchases. Journal of Accounting and Economics 36 (1-3), 51 – 90.<br />

Bergstresser, D. and T. Philippon (2006). CEO incentives and earnings management. Journal of Financial<br />

Economics 80 (3), 511 – 529.<br />

Brandt, M. W., A. Brav, J. R. Graham, and A. Kumar (2010). The idiosyncratic volatility puzzle: Time<br />

trend or speculative episodes? Review of Financial Studies 23 (2), 863–899.<br />

Burgstahler, D. and I. Dichev (1997). Earnings management <strong>to</strong> avoid earnings decreases and losses. Journal<br />

of Accounting and Economics 24 (1), 99–126.<br />

Cheng, Q. and T. D. Warfield (2005). Equity incentives and earnings management. The Accounting Review<br />

80 (2), pp. 441–476.<br />

Cheong, F. S. and J. Thomas (2011).<br />

Why do eps forecast error and dispersion not vary with scale?<br />

implications for analyst and managerial behavior. Journal of Accounting Research 49 (2), 359–401.<br />

Cheong, F. S. and J. Thomas (2012). <strong>How</strong> do managers suppress scale variation in analysts’ eps forecast<br />

errors? Working Paper.<br />

Cohen, D. A. and P. Zarowin (2010). Accrual-<strong>based</strong> and real earnings management activities around seasoned<br />

equity offerings. Journal of Accounting and Economics 50 (1), 2–19.<br />

Das, S. and H. Zhang (2003). Rounding-up in reported eps, behavioral thresholds, and earnings management.<br />

Journal of Accounting and Economics 35 (1), 31 – 50.<br />

28


De Angelis, D. and Y. Grinstein (2011). Pay for <strong>the</strong> right performance. Johnson School Research Paper<br />

Series (03-2011).<br />

Dechow, P., W. Ge, and C. Schrand (2010). Understanding earnings quality: A review of <strong>the</strong> proxies, <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

determinants and <strong>the</strong>ir consequences. Journal of Accounting and Economics 50 (2), 344–401.<br />

Dechow, P. M. and D. J. Skinner (2000).<br />

Earnings management: Reconciling <strong>the</strong> views of accounting<br />

academics, practitioners, and regula<strong>to</strong>rs. Accounting Horizons 14 (2), 235–250.<br />

Dechow, P. M. and H. You (2012). Analysts’ motives for rounding eps forecasts. The Accounting Review<br />

87 (6), 1939–1966.<br />

Degeorge, F., F. Derrien, A. Kecskés, and S. Michenaud (2012). Playing <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> gallery: Corporate policies<br />

and equity research analysts. Available at SSRN 2023137 .<br />

Degeorge, F., J. Patel, and R. Zeckhauser (1999). Earnings management <strong>to</strong> exceed thresholds. The Journal<br />

of Business 72 (1), 1–33.<br />

Derrien, F. and A. Kecskés (2012). The real effects of financial shocks: Evidence from exogenous changes in<br />

analyst coverage. Journal of Finance, forthcoming.<br />

Dyl, E. A. and W. B. Elliott (2006). The share price puzzle. The Journal of Business 79 (4), 2045–2066.<br />

Ecker, F., J. Francis, P. Olsson, and K. Schipper (2011). Peer firm selection for discretionary accruals models.<br />

Unpublished paper, Duke University.<br />

Fields, T. D., T. Z. Lys, and L. Vincent (2001). Empirical research on accounting choice. Journal of<br />

accounting and economics 31 (1), 255–307.<br />

Graham, J. R., C. R. Harvey, and S. Rajgopal (2005). The economic implications of corporate financial<br />

reporting. Journal of accounting and economics 40 (1), 3–73.<br />

Healy, P. M. and J. M. Wahlen (1999). A review of <strong>the</strong> earnings management literature and its implications<br />

for standard setting. Accounting horizons 13 (4), 365–383.<br />

Hong, H. and M. Kacperczyk (2010). Competition and bias. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 125 (4),<br />

1683–1725.<br />

Hribar, P., N. T. Jenkins, and W. B. Johnson (2006). S<strong>to</strong>ck repurchases as an earnings management device.<br />

Journal of Accounting and Economics 41 (12), 3 – 27.<br />

29


Kelly, B. and A. Ljungqvist (2012). Testing asymmetric-information asset pricing models. Review of Financial<br />

Studies 25 (5), 1366–1413.<br />

Kim, D. and J. Yang (2012). Beating <strong>the</strong> target: A closer look at annual incentive plans.<br />

Lakonishok, J. and B. Lev (1987). S<strong>to</strong>ck splits and s<strong>to</strong>ck dividends: Why, who, and when. The Journal of<br />

Finance 42 (4), 913–932.<br />

Louis, H. and D. Robinson (2005). Do managers credibly use accruals <strong>to</strong> signal private information? evidence<br />

from <strong>the</strong> pricing of discretionary accruals around s<strong>to</strong>ck splits. Journal of Accounting and Economics 39 (2),<br />

361 – 380.<br />

Murphy, K. J. (1999). Executive compensation. Handbook of labor economics 3, 2485–2563.<br />

Payne, J. L. and W. B. Thomas (2003).<br />

The implications of using s<strong>to</strong>ck-split adjusted i/b/e/s data in<br />

empirical research. The Accounting Review 78 (4), 1049–1067.<br />

Roychowdhury, S. (2006). Earnings management through real activities manipulation. Journal of Accounting<br />

and Economics 42 (3), 335 – 370.<br />

Skinner, D. J. and R. G. Sloan (2002). Earnings surprises, growth expectations, and s<strong>to</strong>ck returns or don’t<br />

let an earnings <strong>to</strong>rpedo sink your portfolio. Review of Accounting Studies 7 (2), 289–312.<br />

S<strong>to</strong>ck, J. H., J. H. Wright, and M. Yogo (2002). A survey of weak instruments and weak identification in<br />

generalized method of moments. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 20 (4).<br />

Subramanyam, K. (1996). The pricing of discretionary accruals. Journal of Accounting and Economics<br />

22 (13), 249 – 281.<br />

Weld, W. C., R. Michaely, R. H. Thaler, and S. Benartzi (2009). The nominal share price puzzle. The<br />

Journal of Economic Perspectives 23 (2), pp. 121–142.<br />

Young, S. and J. Yang (2011). S<strong>to</strong>ck repurchases and executive compensation contract design: The role of<br />

earnings per share performance conditions. The Accounting Review 86 (2), 703–733.<br />

Zang, A. Y. (2011). Evidence on <strong>the</strong> trade-off between real activities manipulation and accrual-<strong>based</strong> earnings<br />

management. The Accounting Review 87 (2), 675–703.<br />

30


A<br />

Appendix<br />

We show that a drop in analyst coverage decreases <strong>the</strong> probability of meeting <strong>the</strong> earnings forecast. Consider<br />

a firm with s shares outstanding and net income uniformly distributed [−e, e]), where e is in dollars. Assume<br />

that each analyst issues a forecast that is independently drawn from a uniform distribution over [−e, e]), and<br />

that <strong>the</strong> consensus forecast is <strong>the</strong> sample mean. With infinite analysts, <strong>the</strong> forecast equals <strong>the</strong> mean and<br />

<strong>the</strong>re is no variance. In this benchmark case <strong>the</strong> forecast is unbiased and has no noise, and <strong>the</strong> probability<br />

that <strong>the</strong> firm meets earnings forecasts is<br />

s<br />

200e .<br />

For simplicity, we compare <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> case in which <strong>the</strong>re is only one analyst. The variance in <strong>the</strong> estimate<br />

will <strong>the</strong>refore be much higher than <strong>the</strong> benchmark case (<strong>the</strong> variance of <strong>the</strong> sample mean is decreasing in<br />

N). Because <strong>the</strong> variance is higher, <strong>the</strong> probability of meeting <strong>the</strong> forecast is lower. The intuition for this is<br />

straightforward. If <strong>the</strong> forecast is relatively close <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> mean, <strong>the</strong>n P r(meet) =<br />

is close <strong>to</strong> one of <strong>the</strong> tails of <strong>the</strong> distribution, <strong>the</strong>n P r(meet) <<br />

s<br />

200e<br />

. But if <strong>the</strong> forecast<br />

s<br />

200e<br />

. No matter where <strong>the</strong> forecast is, <strong>the</strong><br />

target size around <strong>the</strong> forecast is always ± s<br />

200<br />

, but integrating over this range results in different probabilities<br />

depending on where in <strong>the</strong> distribution <strong>the</strong> forecast is. When <strong>the</strong> forecast deviates from <strong>the</strong> mean, <strong>the</strong> result<br />

is a lower probability simply because <strong>the</strong> outcomes in <strong>the</strong> tails are less likely <strong>to</strong> occur.<br />

With probability 1 −<br />

With probability<br />

P r(meet) =<br />

s<br />

200e<br />

<strong>the</strong> forecast will be close enough <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> mean such that P r(meet) =<br />

s<br />

200e .<br />

s<br />

400e<br />

<strong>the</strong> forecast will be on <strong>the</strong> left tail of <strong>the</strong> uniform distribution such that in expectation<br />

3s<br />

800e<br />

. Because <strong>the</strong> forecast is unbiased <strong>the</strong> effect is <strong>the</strong> same on <strong>the</strong> right tail. Therefore, with<br />

a noisy, unbiased forecast:<br />

E[P r(meet)] = (1 −<br />

s<br />

200e ) s<br />

200e + 2( s<br />

400e ) 3s<br />

400e =<br />

s<br />

200e (1 −<br />

s<br />

800e ).<br />

We can compare this probability <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> case in which <strong>the</strong> forecast is not noisy (infinite analysts). It<br />

is easy <strong>to</strong> show that if <strong>the</strong> manager prefers <strong>the</strong> same Pr(meet), shares need <strong>to</strong> increase in response <strong>to</strong><br />

a drop in analyst coverage.<br />

Using s ∗ <strong>to</strong> denote <strong>the</strong> shares in <strong>the</strong> case of a forecast without noise, <strong>the</strong>n<br />

s<br />

200e (1 −<br />

s<br />

800e ) =<br />

s∗<br />

200e → s > s∗ .<br />

The result shown above assumes analysts are unbiased. It can be shown that an increase in forecast bias<br />

has <strong>the</strong> same qualitative effect. Intuitively, integrating over <strong>the</strong> ± s<br />

200<br />

range results in a lower probability<br />

when <strong>the</strong> forecast is far<strong>the</strong>r away from <strong>the</strong> mean. In this way an increase in bias has an effect similar <strong>to</strong> an<br />

increase in forecast variance.<br />

31


Table 1: Summary Statistics<br />

This table presents summary statistics of <strong>the</strong> key variables used in this study. Shares outstanding (millions) is<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal number of shares outstanding (CRSP) at <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> quarter. <strong>EPS</strong> is <strong>the</strong> primary earnings per share<br />

(COMPUSTAT). Net Income is <strong>the</strong> reported net income at <strong>the</strong> fiscal quarter end. Net Income Vol is <strong>the</strong> standard<br />

deviation of net income over <strong>the</strong> past 12 qtrs. Net Income Vol - Naive is <strong>the</strong> standard deviation of seasonally adjusted<br />

net income over <strong>the</strong> past 12 qtrs. Net Income Vol - Analyst is <strong>the</strong> standard deviation of net income minus <strong>the</strong> consensus<br />

IBES median forecast of net income over <strong>the</strong> previous 12 qtrs. S<strong>to</strong>ck Volatility is <strong>the</strong> standard deviation of daily<br />

s<strong>to</strong>ck returns over <strong>the</strong> past year. Market Capitalization is <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal market capitalization in millions at <strong>the</strong> quarter<br />

end. Institutional Ownership is <strong>the</strong> % of institutional ownership from Thomson 13(f). Incentive Compensation is<br />

calculated as 1-(Salary/TDC1). Num of Analysts is <strong>the</strong> number of analysts cover <strong>the</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ck during <strong>the</strong> quarter.<br />

Annual S<strong>to</strong>ck Return is <strong>the</strong> past 12 month s<strong>to</strong>ck return. Amihud is <strong>the</strong> log of <strong>the</strong> Amihud ratio calculated over <strong>the</strong><br />

past year. Split ratio is <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>to</strong> adjust shares at s<strong>to</strong>ck split announcement. Share price is <strong>the</strong> s<strong>to</strong>ck price at <strong>the</strong><br />

end of <strong>the</strong> quarter. Age is <strong>the</strong> years since IPO. The sample is from 1984-2012.<br />

Variable Mean P25 Median P75 STD<br />

Shares Outstanding 83.85 10.16 23.55 56.75 346.78<br />

<strong>EPS</strong> 0.20 -0.02 0.19 0.47 1.19<br />

Net Income 34.48 -0.30 3.05 17.65 388.95<br />

Net Income Vol 51.48 1.59 5.23 20.57 347.76<br />

Net Income Vol - Naive 40.38 1.47 4.75 18.20 264.06<br />

Net Income Vol - Analyst 32.04 0.58 2.38 11.01 250.83<br />

S<strong>to</strong>ck Volatility 3.30 1.82 2.68 4.04 2.35<br />

Market Capitalization 2766 95 338 1316 13069<br />

Institutional Ownership 47.97 24.34 46.85 70.22 27.78<br />

Incentive Compensation 66.65 54.04 73.24 85.19 24.46<br />

Num of Analysts 4.24 1 3 5 4.35<br />

Annual S<strong>to</strong>ck Return 15.74 -21.13 5.96 34.78 81.12<br />

Amihud -1.05 -2.90 -0.98 0.80 2.57<br />

Split Ratio 1.64 1.50 1.50 2.00 0.68<br />

Share Price 22.68 7.70 17.25 30.75 24.94<br />

Age 16.1 5.5 11.2 21.2 15.2<br />

32


Figure 1: Example of <strong>the</strong> relationship between earnings growth, shares outstanding and <strong>EPS</strong>.<br />

This figure shows <strong>the</strong> mechanical relationship between earnings growth, shares outstanding, and <strong>EPS</strong> as a result<br />

of <strong>EPS</strong> rounding. The Base Case presents an example of a firm with $100 of expected earnings and 1000 shares<br />

outstanding with a target size of ±5% of expected earings. Earnings Growth (1000 shares) presents an example of<br />

<strong>the</strong> same 1000 shares outstanding and expected earnings of $200. The target size is ±2.5% of expected earnings.<br />

Earnings Growth and 2:1 Split presents <strong>the</strong> same example but with 2000 shares outstanding. The target size returns<br />

<strong>to</strong> ±5%.<br />

Base Case (1000 Shares)<br />

<strong>EPS</strong>= $0.10<br />

Earnings=$95<br />

E[Earnings]=$100<br />

+/- 5% of E[Earnings]<br />

Earnings=$105<br />

Earnings Growth (1000 Shares)<br />

<strong>EPS</strong>= $0.20<br />

E[Earnings]=$200<br />

Earnings=$195<br />

Earnings=$205<br />

+/- 2.5% of E[Earnings]<br />

Earnings Growth and 2:1 Split (2000 Shares)<br />

<strong>EPS</strong>= $0.10<br />

Earnings=$190<br />

E[Earnings]=$200<br />

+/- 5% of E[Earnings]<br />

Earnings=$210<br />

33


Figure 2: His<strong>to</strong>gram of net income scaled by <strong>the</strong> minimum necessary <strong>to</strong> meet <strong>the</strong> median analyst forecast.<br />

This figure presents a his<strong>to</strong>gram of earnings outcomes. For each firm-quarter, we compute <strong>the</strong> minimum net income<br />

needed <strong>to</strong> meet <strong>the</strong> median forecast. We scale each firm-quarter reported net income by this minimum. The dark<br />

vertical line that intersects <strong>the</strong> x-axis at a value of 1 indicates <strong>the</strong> point at which <strong>the</strong> firm generates just enough net<br />

income <strong>to</strong> meet <strong>the</strong> median forecast. The lighter line that intersects <strong>the</strong> x-axis near 1.02 reflects <strong>the</strong> average amount<br />

of net income that would equal <strong>the</strong> forecasted net income (<strong>EPS</strong> forecast times shares).<br />

34


Figure 3: Median Shares Outstanding across Net Income Volatility and Incentive Compensation Deciles<br />

This figure presents median shares outstanding (bar chart) and median net income (line-plot) across deciles sorted<br />

on Net Income Volatility (Panel A) and Incentive Compensation (Panel B). Shares outstanding are adjusted for net<br />

income by first sorting <strong>the</strong> sample firms in<strong>to</strong> 20 groups <strong>based</strong> on net income each quarter, and <strong>the</strong>n sorting in<strong>to</strong> deciles<br />

<strong>based</strong> on Net Income Volatility or Incentive Compensation. Net Income Volatility is <strong>the</strong> standard deviation of <strong>the</strong><br />

previous 12 quarters of net income. Incentive Compensation is calculated as 1-(Salary/TDC1). Shares outstanding<br />

is represented on <strong>the</strong> left axis and net income is on <strong>the</strong> right axis. The sample period is 1984-2011.<br />

Panel A. Shares Outstanding across Net Income Volatility Deciles<br />

Shares Outstanding<br />

40,000<br />

35,000<br />

30,000<br />

25,000<br />

20,000<br />

15,000<br />

10,000<br />

5,000<br />

0<br />

Bot<strong>to</strong>m Net<br />

Income Volatility<br />

Decile<br />

2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9<br />

Net Income<br />

5<br />

Top Net Income<br />

Volatility<br />

Decile<br />

4<br />

3<br />

2<br />

1<br />

0<br />

Shares Outstanding<br />

Net Income<br />

Panel B. Shares Outstanding across Incentive Compensation Deciles<br />

Shares Outstanding<br />

80,000<br />

70,000<br />

60,000<br />

50,000<br />

40,000<br />

30,000<br />

20,000<br />

Bot<strong>to</strong>m<br />

Incentive<br />

Comp Decile<br />

2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9<br />

Net Income<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

Top<br />

Incentive<br />

Comp Decile<br />

Shares Outstanding<br />

Net Income<br />

35


Figure 4: Median nominal price-per-share and earnings-per-share, 1971-2011.<br />

This figure shows median nominal price-per-share and earnings-per-share, 1971-2011 for all US firms with price and<br />

earnings data in Compustat.<br />

36


Table 2: Determinants of Shares Outstanding<br />

This table presents OLS cross sectional regression models of shares outstanding as a function of firm characteristics. Shares outstanding<br />

is measured as <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal number of shares outstanding (1000’s) from CRSP at <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> quarter. Net Income Volatility is <strong>the</strong><br />

standard deviation of Net Income over <strong>the</strong> previous 12 quarters. Net Income Forecast Error Volatility - Naive is <strong>the</strong> standard deviation of<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong> difference between actual earnings and an expectation of earnings <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> earnings from 4 quarters prior plus <strong>the</strong> difference<br />

between <strong>the</strong> earnings 4 quarters and 8 quarters prior. Net Income Forecast Error Volatility - Analyst is <strong>the</strong> standard deviation of <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> difference between actual earnings and median IBES forecast of earnings. Market <strong>to</strong> Book is <strong>to</strong>tal market equity plus <strong>the</strong> book value<br />

of <strong>to</strong>tal debt divided by <strong>to</strong>tal assets. Net Income is from Compustat at quarter end. Market Cap is <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal market capitalization in<br />

millions at <strong>the</strong> quarter end. Institutional ownership is percent ownership of all institutions. Return Volatility is <strong>the</strong> standard deviation<br />

of daily s<strong>to</strong>ck returns over <strong>the</strong> prior 90 days. Annual Return is <strong>the</strong> past 12 month s<strong>to</strong>ck return. The Amihud measure of illiquidity<br />

calculated over <strong>the</strong> previous 90 days. Incentive Comp is <strong>the</strong> percent of <strong>to</strong>tal compensation made up by bonus, s<strong>to</strong>ck, and option grants.<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4)<br />

Shares Shares Shares Shares<br />

VARIABLES Outstanding Outstanding Outstanding Outstanding<br />

Net Income Volatility t−1 0.21*** 0.25***<br />

(0.01) (0.01)<br />

Net Income Volatility - Naive Forecast t−1 0.21***<br />

(0.01)<br />

Net Income Volatility - Analyst Forecast t−1 0.30***<br />

(0.02)<br />

Market <strong>to</strong> Book t−1 0.01*** 0.01*** -0.01** -0.02**<br />

(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.01)<br />

Net Income t−1 -0.11*** -0.11*** -0.09*** -0.07***<br />

(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)<br />

Institutional Ownership t−1 0.01** 0.01*** 0.00 -0.14***<br />

(0.00) (0.00) (0.01) (0.02)<br />

Market Cap t−1 0.84*** 0.85*** 0.77*** 0.76***<br />

(0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01)<br />

Annual Return t−1 -0.04*** -0.04*** -0.05*** -0.10***<br />

(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.01)<br />

Amihud t−1 -0.05*** -0.06*** -0.11*** -0.43***<br />

(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.13)<br />

Return Volatility t−1 0.05*** 0.06*** 0.06*** 0.12***<br />

(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.01)<br />

Incentive Comp t−1 0.05***<br />

(0.01)<br />

Constant -0.04*** -0.03*** 0.03** 0.11*<br />

(0.01) (0.01) (0.02) (0.06)<br />

Year Effects Y Y<br />

Observations 582,754 486,137 332,578 120,635<br />

R-squared 0.81 0.81 0.81 0.82<br />

Standard errors clustered by firm in paren<strong>the</strong>ses<br />

*** p


Table 3: Shares Outstanding: First Differences<br />

This table presents First Differences regression models of changes in shares outstanding as a function of changes in firm characteristics.<br />

Shares outstanding is measured as <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal number of shares outstanding (1000’s) from CRSP at <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> quarter. Net Income<br />

Volatility is <strong>the</strong> standard deviation of Net Income over <strong>the</strong> previous 12 quarters. Net Income Forecast Error Volatility - Naive is <strong>the</strong><br />

standard deviation of <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong> difference between actual earnings and an expectation of earnings <strong>based</strong> on <strong>the</strong> earnings from 4 quarters<br />

prior plus <strong>the</strong> difference between <strong>the</strong> earnings 4 quarters and 8 quarters prior. Net Income Forecast Error Volatility - Analyst is <strong>the</strong><br />

standard deviation of <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong> difference between actual earnings and median IBES forecast of earnings. Market <strong>to</strong> Book is <strong>to</strong>tal market<br />

equity plus <strong>the</strong> book value of <strong>to</strong>tal debt divided by <strong>to</strong>tal assets. Net Income is from Compustat at quarter end. Market Cap is <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal<br />

market capitalization in millions at <strong>the</strong> quarter end. Institutional ownership is percent ownership of all institutions. Return Volatility<br />

is <strong>the</strong> standard deviation of daily s<strong>to</strong>ck returns over <strong>the</strong> prior 90 days. Annual Return is <strong>the</strong> past 12 month s<strong>to</strong>ck return. The Amihud<br />

measure of illiquidity calculated over <strong>the</strong> previous 90 days.<br />

(1) (2) (3)<br />

∆ Shares ∆ Shares ∆ Shares<br />

VARIABLES Outstanding Outstanding Outstanding<br />

∆ Net Income Volatility t−1 0.04***<br />

(0.00)<br />

∆ Net Income Volatility - Naive Forecast t−1 0.03***<br />

(0.00)<br />

∆ Net Income Volatility - Analyst Forecast t−1 0.07***<br />

(0.01)<br />

∆ Market <strong>to</strong> Book t−1 0.01*** 0.02*** 0.02***<br />

(0.00) (0.00) (0.00)<br />

∆ Net Income t−1 0.00 0.00 0.01***<br />

(0.00) (0.00) (0.00)<br />

∆ Institutional Ownership t−1 0.12*** 0.13*** 0.13***<br />

(0.00) (0.00) (0.00)<br />

∆ Market Cap t−1 0.10*** 0.10*** 0.10***<br />

(0.00) (0.00) (0.00)<br />

∆ Annual Return t−1 0.00 -0.00 -0.00<br />

(0.00) (0.00) (0.00)<br />

∆ Amihud t−1 -0.01*** -0.01*** -0.02***<br />

(0.00) (0.00) (0.00)<br />

∆ Return Volatility t−1 0.01*** 0.01*** 0.02***<br />

(0.00) (0.00) (0.00)<br />

∆ Incentive Comp t−1<br />

Constant 0.02 0.02 0.24<br />

(0.02) (0.02) (0.29)<br />

Year Effects Y Y Y<br />

Observations 543,355 454,258 313,297<br />

R-squared 0.03 0.03 0.03<br />

Standard errors clustered by firm in paren<strong>the</strong>ses<br />

*** p


Table 4: Shares Outstanding: First Differences and IV<br />

This table presents IV regression models of changes in shares outstanding as a function of changes in firm characteristics. Net Income<br />

Forecast Error Volatility - Analyst is instrumented for using exogenous changes in analyst coverage. Shares outstanding is measured as<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal number of shares outstanding (1000’s) from CRSP at <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> quarter. Net Income Forecast Error Volatility - Analyst<br />

is <strong>the</strong> standard deviation of <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong> difference between actual earnings and median IBES forecast of earnings. Market <strong>to</strong> Book is <strong>to</strong>tal<br />

market equity plus <strong>the</strong> book value of <strong>to</strong>tal debt divided by <strong>to</strong>tal assets. Net Income is from Compustat at quarter end. Market Cap is<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal market capitalization in millions at <strong>the</strong> quarter end. Institutional ownership is percent ownership of all institutions. Return<br />

Volatility is <strong>the</strong> standard deviation of daily s<strong>to</strong>ck returns over <strong>the</strong> prior 90 days. Annual Return is <strong>the</strong> past 12 month s<strong>to</strong>ck return.<br />

The Amihud measure of illiquidity calculated over <strong>the</strong> previous 90 days.<br />

(1) (2)<br />

∆ Shares ∆ Shares<br />

VARIABLES Outstanding Outstanding<br />

∆ Net Income Volatility - Analyst Forecast t−1 0.53*** 0.58**<br />

(0.17) (0.26)<br />

∆ Market <strong>to</strong> Book t−1 0.03*** 0.02<br />

(0.01) (0.01)<br />

∆ Net Income t−1 0.03*** 0.04**<br />

(0.01) (0.02)<br />

∆ Institutional Ownership t−1 0.15*** 0.20***<br />

(0.00) (0.01)<br />

∆ Market Cap t−1 0.08*** 0.08***<br />

(0.01) (0.01)<br />

∆ Annual Return t−1 0.01 0.01<br />

(0.01) (0.02)<br />

∆ Amihud t−1 -0.02*** -0.03<br />

(0.00) (0.05)<br />

∆ Return Volatility t−1 0.02*** 0.04***<br />

(0.00) (0.01)<br />

∆ Incentive Comp t−1 0.01**<br />

(0.00)<br />

Constant 0.02 -0.14***<br />

(0.02) (0.03)<br />

Year Effects Y Y<br />

Observations 246,077 105,571<br />

R-squared 0.04 0.04<br />

Standard errors clustered by firm in paren<strong>the</strong>ses<br />

*** p


Table 5: Changes in Shares Outstanding: S<strong>to</strong>ck Splits and <strong>EPS</strong><br />

This table presents IV regression models of shares outstanding as a function of firm characteristics. In <strong>the</strong>se specifications, Net Income Error Volatility is instrumented for using<br />

exogenous changes in analyst coverage. Columns 1 presents standardized regression coefficients. Columns 1 and 2 show changes in shares outstanding due <strong>to</strong> splits and o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

than splits respectively. Column 3 controls for high and low s<strong>to</strong>ck prices where High is defined as s<strong>to</strong>cks above $80 and Low is defined as below $20. Columns 4 and 5 show<br />

results for share changes due <strong>to</strong> splits for firms with negative <strong>EPS</strong> and positive <strong>EPS</strong>. Column 6 and 7 shows results for share changes do <strong>to</strong> splits for firms with above median<br />

incentive compensation and below median incentive compensation. Shares outstanding is measured as <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal number of shares outstanding (1000’s) from CRSP at <strong>the</strong> end of<br />

<strong>the</strong> quarter. Net Income Error volatility is <strong>the</strong> standard deviation of <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong> difference between actual earnings and median IBES forecast of earnings. Market <strong>to</strong> Book is <strong>to</strong>tal<br />

market equity plus <strong>the</strong> book value of <strong>to</strong>tal debt divided by <strong>to</strong>tal assets. Operating income is defined as operating income before interest and depreciation from Compustat at<br />

quarter end. Market Cap is <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal market capitalization in millions at <strong>the</strong> quarter end. Institutional ownership is percent ownership of all institutions. Return Volatility is <strong>the</strong><br />

standard deviation of daily s<strong>to</strong>ck returns over <strong>the</strong> prior 90 days. Annual Return is <strong>the</strong> past 12 month s<strong>to</strong>ck return.<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)<br />

∆ Shares ∆ Shares s ∆ Shares ∆ Shares ∆ Shares ∆ Shares<br />

VARIABLES non-Splits from Splits from Splits from Splits from Splits from Splits<br />

Full Sample Full Sample Negative <strong>EPS</strong> Positive <strong>EPS</strong> Low Incent. Comp High Incent. Comp<br />

∆ Net Income Volatility - Analyst Forecastt−1 136 6,676*** 2,115 7,204*** 4,142 15,867*<br />

(268) (1,709) (1,714) (1,907) (3,146) (9,302)<br />

∆ Market <strong>to</strong> Bookt−1 -11 241*** 38 458*** 989*** 312*<br />

(9) (61) (31) (112) (223) (182)<br />

∆ Net Incomet−1 13 408*** 51 536*** 412* 632*<br />

(14) (106) (43) (145) (230) (332)<br />

∆ Institutional Ownershipt−1 196*** 282*** -36 422*** 752*** 307***<br />

(6) (44) (37) (63) (169) (102)<br />

∆ Market Capt−1 114*** 587*** 412*** 547*** 635*** 332<br />

(10) (72) (107) (95) (112) (277)<br />

∆ Annual Returnt−1 3 -45 -32 -30 -239 162<br />

(10) (62) (25) (94) (249) (297)<br />

∆ Amihudt−1 -40*** 1 11 -20 44 147<br />

(6) (22) (24) (21) (481) (532)<br />

∆ Return Volatilityt−1 22*** 150*** 27* 244*** 464*** 117<br />

(5) (23) (14) (37) (100) (113)<br />

Constant 246*** 255* 281 39 99 713<br />

(28) (139) (204) (184) (271) (738)<br />

Year Effects Y Y Y Y Y Y<br />

Observations 245,267 245,281 60,781 184,144 55,820 51,195<br />

Standard errors clustered by firm in paren<strong>the</strong>ses<br />

*** p


Table 6: Changes in Shares Outstanding: High Cost <strong>to</strong> Splitting<br />

This table presents IV regression models of shares outstanding as a function of firm characteristics. In <strong>the</strong>se specifications, Net Income<br />

Error Volatility is instrumented for using exogenous changes in analyst coverage. Column presents <strong>the</strong> regression specification from table<br />

5 and controls for high and low s<strong>to</strong>ck prices where High is defined as s<strong>to</strong>cks above $80 and Low is defined as below $20. Columns 2 and 3<br />

show show results for share changes due <strong>to</strong> splits for firms with above median illiquidity and below median illiquidity respectively.Shares<br />

outstanding is measured as <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal number of shares outstanding (1000’s) from CRSP at <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> quarter. Net Income Error<br />

volatility is <strong>the</strong> standard deviation of <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong> difference between actual earnings and median IBES forecast of earnings. Market <strong>to</strong> Book<br />

is <strong>to</strong>tal market equity plus <strong>the</strong> book value of <strong>to</strong>tal debt divided by <strong>to</strong>tal assets. Operating income is defined as operating income before<br />

interest and depreciation from Compustat at quarter end. Market Cap is <strong>the</strong> <strong>to</strong>tal market capitalization in millions at <strong>the</strong> quarter end.<br />

Institutional ownership is percent ownership of all institutions. Return Volatility is <strong>the</strong> standard deviation of daily s<strong>to</strong>ck returns over<br />

<strong>the</strong> prior 90 days. Annual Return is <strong>the</strong> past 12 month s<strong>to</strong>ck return.<br />

(1) (2) (3)<br />

∆ Shares ∆ Shares ∆ Shares<br />

VARIABLES Full Sample High Illiquidity Low Illiquidity<br />

∆ Net Income Volatility - Analyst Forecast t−1 4,796** -1,295 6,263**<br />

(1,882) (4,037) (2,477)<br />

∆ Market <strong>to</strong> Book t−1 204*** 21 482***<br />

(60) (15) (119)<br />

∆ Net Income t−1 301*** 27 446***<br />

(110) (82) (159)<br />

∆ Institutional Ownership t−1 280*** 43*** 561***<br />

(43) (10) (88)<br />

∆ Market Cap t−1 451*** 424*** 569***<br />

(57) (51) (90)<br />

∆ Annual Return t−1 -56 -27 -40<br />

(61) (18) (155)<br />

∆ Amihud t−1 5 -9 58,847<br />

(16) (8) (59,775)<br />

∆ Return Volatility t−1 118*** 14** 417***<br />

(19) (6) (66)<br />

High Price t−1 13,008*<br />

(1,335)<br />

Low Price t−1 -101<br />

(244)<br />

Constant -155 -87 2,924<br />

(155) (381) (2,886)<br />

Year Effects Y Y Y<br />

Observations 280,067 146,010 134,048<br />

Standard errors clustered by firm in paren<strong>the</strong>ses<br />

*** p


Table 7: Changes in Shares and <strong>EPS</strong> Outcomes<br />

This table presents results from a difference-in-difference analysis examining <strong>the</strong> association between increases in<br />

shares outstanding and <strong>EPS</strong> outcomes, and earnings management. We distinguish firms that significantly increase<br />

<strong>the</strong> number of shares outstanding in quarter t from those that do not. We define a significant increase as any change<br />

that results in a 25% increase or greater (a split fac<strong>to</strong>r of 5-for-4 or greater). Then we compare how changes in <strong>EPS</strong><br />

outcomes differs across samples. Miss, Beat and Meet are dummies set <strong>to</strong> one if <strong>the</strong> firm’s reported <strong>EPS</strong> was below,<br />

above, or equal <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> median analyst forecast, respectively, zero o<strong>the</strong>rwise. Panel A reports <strong>the</strong> average of <strong>the</strong>se<br />

dummy variables over quarter t − 1 (<strong>the</strong> ‘pre’ period) and that over quarter t + 1 (post). We distinguish firms that<br />

increased shares at t = 0 from those that did not, and report <strong>the</strong> difference across <strong>the</strong>se two groups in <strong>the</strong> differences<br />

across time. Panel B uses <strong>the</strong> firm average over <strong>the</strong> 4 quarters prior <strong>to</strong> t = 0 and compares this <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> firm average<br />

over <strong>the</strong> t + 1 <strong>to</strong> t + 4. t-statistics on <strong>the</strong> differences in differences are clustered at <strong>the</strong> firm-level.<br />

Panel A: 1 quarter pre and post evaluation period<br />

split? pre post dif t-stat<br />

Miss N 16.70% 16.83% 0.13%<br />

Y 21.97% 17.94% -4.03%<br />

-4.16% (-6.64)<br />

Beat N 4.98% 5.01% 0.03%<br />

Y 7.32% 6.08% -1.24%<br />

-1.27% (-3.04)<br />

Meet N 78.33% 78.16% -0.17%<br />

Y 70.71% 75.99% 5.28%<br />

5.45% (7.80)<br />

Panel B: 4 quarter pre and post evaluation period<br />

split? pre post dif t-stat<br />

Miss N 17.71% 17.54% -0.17%<br />

Y 19.75% 18.43% -1.32%<br />

-1.15% (-3.34)<br />

Beat N 4.71% 4.68% -0.03%<br />

Y 7.03% 5.68% -1.35%<br />

-1.32% (-5.86)<br />

Meet N 77.58% 77.78% 0.20%<br />

Y 73.22% 75.89% 2.67%<br />

2.47% (6.29)<br />

42


Table 8: Changes in Shares and Accounting and Real Earnings Management<br />

This table presents results from a difference-in-difference analysis examining <strong>the</strong> association between increases in<br />

shares outstanding and measures of accounting and real earnings management. We distinguish firms that significantly<br />

increase <strong>the</strong> number of shares outstanding in quarter t from those that do not. We define a significant increase as<br />

any change that results in a 25% increase or greater (a split fac<strong>to</strong>r of 5-for-4 or greater). Then we compare how<br />

changes in <strong>the</strong> usage of earnings management <strong>to</strong>ols differs across samples. Discretionary accruals are residuals from<br />

industry <strong>to</strong>tal accruals regressions including performance controls following Ecker et al. (2011). Total accruals are<br />

defined as <strong>the</strong> change in current assets, adjusted for <strong>the</strong> change in cash, minus <strong>the</strong> change in current liabilities,<br />

adjusted for current liabilities used for financing, minus depreciation expense. Measures of real earnings management<br />

are estimated by abnormal cash flow (RealEM CF ), production costs (RealEM P rod ), and expenditure (RealEM CF )<br />

following <strong>the</strong> methodology in Roychowdhury (2006). In Panel A report <strong>the</strong> average of <strong>the</strong> absolute value of <strong>the</strong>se<br />

variables over quarter t − 1 (<strong>the</strong> ‘pre’ period) and compare it <strong>to</strong> that over quarter t + 1 (post). We distinguish firms<br />

that increased shares at t = 0 from those that did not, and report <strong>the</strong> difference across <strong>the</strong>se two groups in <strong>the</strong><br />

differences across time. Panel B uses <strong>the</strong> firm average over <strong>the</strong> 4 quarters prior <strong>to</strong> t = 0 and compares this <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

firm average over <strong>the</strong> t + 1 <strong>to</strong> t + 4. t-statistics on <strong>the</strong> differences across samples are clustered at <strong>the</strong> firm-level.<br />

Panel A: 1 quarter pre and post evaluation period<br />

split? pre post dif<br />

|Accruals T otal | N 3.09% 3.10% 0.01%<br />

Y 3.76% 3.30% -0.46%<br />

-0.47% (-7.07)<br />

|Accruals Disc | N 6.66% 6.67% 0.01%<br />

Y 7.38% 6.59% -0.79%<br />

-0.80% (-4.21)<br />

|RealEM CF | N 2.83% 2.83% 0.01%<br />

Y 3.31% 3.03% -0.28%<br />

-0.29% (-5.50)<br />

|RealEM P rod | N 3.62% 3.63% 0.01%<br />

Y 4.31% 3.96% -0.34%<br />

-0.35% (-6.31)<br />

|RealEM Exp | N 3.43% 3.45% 0.02%<br />

Y 3.84% 3.40% -0.43%<br />

-0.45% (-8.62)<br />

Panel B: 4 quarter pre and post evaluation period<br />

split? pre post dif<br />

|Accruals T otal | N 2.97% 2.88% -0.09%<br />

Y 3.49% 3.17% -0.32%<br />

-0.23% (-3.98)<br />

|Accruals Disc | N 6.14% 6.34% 0.20%<br />

Y 6.65% 6.23% -0.42%<br />

-0.62% (-4.88)<br />

|RealEM CF | N 2.67% 2.63% -0.05%<br />

Y 3.18% 2.89% -0.29%<br />

-0.24% (-6.63)<br />

|RealEM P rod | N 3.52% 3.43% -0.09%<br />

Y 4.21% 3.87% -0.34%<br />

-0.25% (-4.19)<br />

|RealEM Exp | N 3.30% 3.29% -0.01%<br />

Y 3.79% 3.35% -0.44%<br />

-0.43% (-8.86)<br />

43


Table 9: Short-term Accretive and Dilutive Effects<br />

This table presents summary statistics on <strong>the</strong> accretive and dilutive effect of s<strong>to</strong>ck splits on quarter-end <strong>EPS</strong>. A split<br />

is determined <strong>to</strong> be accretive if <strong>the</strong> firm’s <strong>EPS</strong> (measured as Compustat IBADJQ/CSHPRQ rounded <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> penny)<br />

is greater than <strong>the</strong> <strong>EPS</strong> had <strong>the</strong> firm not split (measured as IBADJQ/CSHPRQ*facshr, rounded <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> penny, <strong>the</strong>n<br />

divided by <strong>the</strong> split fac<strong>to</strong>r). The split is dilutive if <strong>the</strong> post-split <strong>EPS</strong> is less than pre-split, and nei<strong>the</strong>r if <strong>the</strong>re is no<br />

difference. Atypical split ratios are defined as any split fac<strong>to</strong>r not in (1.25,1.33,1.5,1.75,2,2.5,3,4,5,10). A split is late<br />

if it occurs after <strong>the</strong> quarter end but before <strong>the</strong> earnings report date. Accretive, nei<strong>the</strong>r, dilutive, atypical, and late<br />

are all indica<strong>to</strong>r variables.<br />

Sample Means<br />

all splits late=0 late=1 atypical=0 atypical=1<br />

N 11447 11016 431 11148 299<br />

accretive 0.318 0.319 0.309 0.315 0.431<br />

nei<strong>the</strong>r 0.393 0.392 0.415 0.401 0.097<br />

dilutive 0.290 0.290 0.276 0.285 0.472<br />

atypical 0.026 0.026 0.030<br />

late 0.037 0.043<br />

late=0 late=1 late=0 late=1<br />

atypical=0 atypical=0 atypical=1 atypical=1<br />

N 10730 418 286 13<br />

accretive 0.316 0.300 0.423 0.615<br />

nei<strong>the</strong>r 0.400 0.426 0.098 0.077<br />

dilutive 0.285 0.275 0.479 0.308<br />

44

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!