28.11.2014 Views

Royal Society - David Keith

Royal Society - David Keith

Royal Society - David Keith

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

of start-up companies active in engineered CDR and ocean<br />

fertilisation. This may be positive, as it mobilises innovation<br />

and capital, which could lead to the development of more<br />

effective and less costly technology at a faster rate than<br />

in the public sector. On the other hand, commercial<br />

involvement could bypass or neglect the socio-economic,<br />

environmental and regulatory dimensions of geoengineering.<br />

Commercial activities have so far been concentrated on<br />

CDR methods, where there is clear potential for future<br />

earnings through carbon trading mechanisms. For SRM<br />

methods, a clear financial incentive does not yet exist,<br />

although there may be future income opportunities from<br />

publicly funded deployment (especially of proprietary<br />

technology). A sufficiently high carbon price, credits<br />

for sequestration, and financial support for reduced<br />

radiative forcing would be necessary to stimulate greater<br />

entrepreneurial activity in developing geoengineering<br />

technology. It is not yet clear if this would be desirable.<br />

4.7 Economic factors<br />

Economists have already started to try to model optimal,<br />

least-cost paths to geoengineering development and even<br />

to develop comparisons with mitigation in a common<br />

framework. These attempts are of scientific interest but are<br />

of limited practical or policy value. This is partly because<br />

the present lack of knowledge about geoengineering costs<br />

and risks means that the outputs of any cost modelling are<br />

determined by uncertain input assumptions. Also, quite<br />

apart from the limited capacity of simple economically<br />

focussed cost-benefit climate impacts assessment models<br />

to provide policy-relevant results, analyses of whether to<br />

do either geoengineering or emissions mitigation are<br />

inappropriate. A more relevant question is what combination<br />

of mitigation and geoengineering might be desirable?<br />

There is therefore significant potential for further economic<br />

research to contribute to policy decisions about<br />

geoengineering.<br />

Costs<br />

According to Stern (2007) the costs of conventional<br />

mitigation are likely to be of the order of 1 or 2% of global<br />

GDP (currently ~$70 trillion per year), that is about $1<br />

trillion per year, to avoid current emissions, which are<br />

approaching 10 GtC/yr. This corresponds to a carbon price<br />

of around $100 per tonne of carbon (equivalent to ~$27<br />

per tonne of CO 2 ). To be affordable, the costs of SRM<br />

methods to offset a doubling of CO 2 would need to be<br />

in the order of $1 trillion per year. Similarly the costs of<br />

CDR methods would need to be comparable to mitigation<br />

costs of $100 per tonne of carbon.<br />

Establishing accurate cost estimates for geoengineering<br />

technologies is however an inherently difficult process,<br />

and only extremely tentative estimates are available for<br />

most of the methods considered. There are two reasons for<br />

this uncertainty. The first is that there is genuine technical<br />

uncertainty about all the geoengineering options covered in<br />

this report, as little serious research and development has<br />

yet been carried out, let alone commercial scale<br />

demonstration. The second is that there are systematic<br />

biases towards under-estimating the costs of novel projects<br />

and technologies of these kinds (Merrow et al. 1979; Bacon<br />

et al. 1996; Flyvjberg et al. 2003).<br />

These biases towards what the UK Treasury calls ‘appraisal<br />

optimism’ arise from relatively straightforward political and<br />

economic factors. Those players who stand to gain most<br />

from the approval of large, new and risky projects are<br />

rarely those who stand to lose if the costs of those projects<br />

turn out to be far higher than forecast, or the benefits far<br />

lower. This creates a powerful incentive for advocates of<br />

new projects to underplay the risks and costs.<br />

In addition, cost-benefit comparisons between<br />

geoengineering and mitigation options need to be handled<br />

with care. For many mitigation options, there is substantial<br />

commercial-scale experience and estimates will usually be<br />

based on solid empirical evidence. Attempts to establish<br />

the relative cheapness of geoengineering should therefore<br />

be treated with caution.<br />

Financing<br />

The tendency towards appraisal optimism usually extends<br />

to estimates of R&D costs. However, when measured<br />

against current international expenditure on energy or<br />

mitigation R&D, it is likely that a relatively modest<br />

investment in geoengineering research would enable<br />

substantial progress to be made. Already there are moves<br />

underway to support international collaborative research,<br />

within Europe, the United States and across the G8. At this<br />

early stage in the development of the field, government<br />

and public sources can reasonably be expected to bear<br />

many of the costs.<br />

The economic attractiveness of CDR activities clearly<br />

improves if there is a well-established international<br />

valuation and trading system for carbon. Views on the<br />

merits of carbon trading vary widely and it is easy to place<br />

excessive reliance on emissions trading as a policy<br />

instrument. However other systems of carbon valuation are<br />

also plausible within the next few years, including a carbon<br />

tax, or more likely, international agreement within a carbon<br />

trading system to establish a stable minimum carbon price.<br />

Should such a minimum value of carbon be established,<br />

the economic attractiveness of CDR methods (as well as<br />

mitigation) R&D would be much improved. However it is<br />

important to stress that the absolute cost of geoengineering<br />

R&D, even on a national UK basis, is unlikely to be a critical<br />

constraint, provided that political approval and sufficient<br />

public support for such R&D is forthcoming.<br />

4.8 Option of last resort?<br />

Even vocal advocates of geoengineering are mostly<br />

somewhat reluctant champions. It is usually presented<br />

as an insurance policy against the possible failure of<br />

conventional mitigation policies; an option of last resort<br />

44 I September 2009 I Geoengineering the Climate The <strong>Royal</strong> <strong>Society</strong>

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!