23.11.2012 Views

2012 INFORMS Marketing Science Conference June 7

2012 INFORMS Marketing Science Conference June 7

2012 INFORMS Marketing Science Conference June 7

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

shift in the demand curve. Most of the explanations proposed for this phenomenon<br />

are based on competitive interactions among firms. I focus on consumer-level insights<br />

that could provide a rationale for a countercyclical pricing scheme. I show<br />

theoretically that the optimal pricing scheme for a seasonal product could be<br />

countercyclical due to consumer heterogeneity with respect to seasonal shifts in<br />

demand. The monopolist then makes use of this heterogeneity to sell only to the<br />

higher valuation segment during low season. I also provide empirical support for this<br />

theory using two different datasets of canned soup sales. Using a store-level aggregate<br />

sales dataset, I provide evidence against alternative explanations and I document that<br />

the demand appears to become more price inelastic during high season. I show that<br />

this finding can be explained by the existence of a break in the demand curve due to<br />

presence of different consumer segments. On a different dataset of consumer-level<br />

purchases, I show that the fit of a purchase incidence model improves when it allows<br />

for consumer segments that differ in their valuations across seasons. The estimates<br />

obtained for segment specific product valuations are in line with the predictions of<br />

the proposed model.<br />

2 - A Structural Model for a “Name Your Own Price” Mechanism with a<br />

Fixed Price Option<br />

Kerem Yener Toklu, Rice University, 6100 Main St, Houston, TX,<br />

United States of America, kt3@rice.edu<br />

This paper provides an empirical analysis for a version of the “Name Your Own Price”<br />

mechanism used in an online marketplace where buyers also have the option to<br />

purchase the item at a fixed price determined by the seller. This particular sale type<br />

with the additional fixed price feature has not been paid much attention in the<br />

literature. Structural econometric techniques are employed to estimate the<br />

distribution of buyers’ valuations which is then used to find the optimal fixed price<br />

for the seller and quantify the value of information. First, a decision theoretic model<br />

is used and the optimal buying strategy is characterized. A nonparametric method is<br />

then proposed to estimate the distribution of values. To generalize the model for<br />

different buying strategies a behavioral model is also considered under weaker<br />

assumptions and parametric estimation is used to capture a number of sale and item<br />

covariates. Calibrated models are then used to run counterfactual simulations to find<br />

revenue maximizing fixed prices for sellers. Aside from characterizing buyer behavior<br />

and optimal selling strategies, the paper also studies the information asymmetry<br />

between sellers and buyers, and provides a way to quantify the value of information.<br />

It is prevalent in online market places that the quality of the item being sold may not<br />

be reflected perfectly on the sale webpage which raises an information asymmetry<br />

between sellers and buyers. The uncertainty in the quality of the item directly<br />

influences the value of buyers, and knowing this, sellers reveal information using<br />

different channels on the webpage. Amount of this information is used as a variable<br />

and simulations are run to measure the effect of information asymmetry on sale<br />

prices and quantify the value of information for buyers.<br />

3 - Framing Effects and Consumers’ Reactions to Corporate<br />

Social Responsibility<br />

Carmelo J. Leon, Department of Applied Economic Analysis,<br />

University of Las Palmas de Gran Canaria, C/Juan de Quesada, n∫ 30,<br />

Las Palmas de Gran Canaria, Spain, cleon@daea.ulpgc.es,<br />

Jorge Araña, Christine Eckert<br />

Corporate social responsibility (CSR) might raise different reactions across consumers<br />

depending on the way they are framed in their marketing and selling process. In this<br />

paper we focus on the effects of alternative frames for CSR measures. Whereas<br />

previous research only focused on single evaluations of each CSR policy separately<br />

and thus ignored potential trade-offs consumers face when deciding between<br />

different CSR-policies companies offer, we utilize discrete choice experiments (DCE)<br />

that more realistically picture consumers’ every-day choices. Subjects were presented<br />

with alternative profiles of CSR measures and were divided into two treatments that<br />

varied according to the definition of the status quo alternative and the valuation<br />

question. The design of the experiments allowed us to compare the willingness to pay<br />

(WTP) a higher price for a product undertaking CSR measures and the willingness to<br />

accept (WTA) a lower price for a product with a lower CSR profile. By disentangling<br />

the effects of differences in choice uncertainty (i.e. choice scale) and preferences<br />

between the two scenarios, we are able to show that the WTA/WTP gap exists only<br />

for some CSR policies but doesn’t show up for others. Our results further<br />

demonstrate that measures for WTA and WTP are significantly more dispersed in<br />

choice experiments with joint evaluations of different CSR policies than in single<br />

evaluation – which is likely to be caused by the availability of reference alternatives<br />

consumers use to form preferences in the former situation.<br />

4 - Pricing and Willingness-to-pay Estimation in B2B Markets<br />

Neil Biehn, Senior Director, PROS Pricing, 3100 Main Street, Houston,<br />

TX, 77002, United States of America, nbiehn@prospricing.com<br />

There has been considerable research, as well as the application of various marketing<br />

techniques, to capture consumers’ Willingness-to-Pay. In this talk, we discuss why<br />

many of the common techniques are difficult to implement in a B2B environment.<br />

We will also explore a more data driven approach to capturing the Willingness-to-Pay<br />

of a B2B customer and present results from its implementation.<br />

MARKETING SCIENCE CONFERENCE – 2011 TA15<br />

9<br />

■ TA15<br />

Champions Center V<br />

B2B: Relationships<br />

Contributed Session<br />

Chair: Alfred Zerres, Institute of Business-to-Business <strong>Marketing</strong>,<br />

University of Muenster, Am Stadtgraben 13-15, Münster, 48143, Germany,<br />

alfred.zerres@uni-muenster.de<br />

1 - A Theory of Bargaining Costs and Price Terms in the Absence of<br />

Relationship-specific Investments<br />

Desmond (Ho-Fu) Lo, Assistant Professor, Santa Clara University,<br />

500 El Camino Real, Santa Clara, CA, 95050,<br />

United States of America, hlo@scu.edu, Giorgio Zanarone<br />

Firms often bring pre-existing assets such as brand and market strength into joint<br />

business ventures. We model a bargaining process and price terms in these ventures<br />

as a tension between saving ex ante contract design costs and facing ex post<br />

opportunism, in the shadow of judicial behavior. On the one hand, to save on design<br />

costs, parties can leave price open for future negotiations and face ex post dilution in<br />

their pre-existing assets through wasteful bargaining actions. On the other hand,<br />

parties can go through the effort of fixing the contract price ex ante and thus prevent<br />

opportunistic renegotiations through a credible threat of having the contract<br />

reinstated by courts. We show that firms prefer to specify the contract terms ex ante<br />

when the value of their pre-existing assets is high and the environment is not<br />

complex. Our theory adds to Transaction Cost Economics (TCE) by (1) formalizing a<br />

bargaining process that is observed in the real world and its effect, together with the<br />

judicial principle of contract reinstatement, on price terms and (2) extending the TCE<br />

rationale to settings where the assets brought into production are not relationshipspecific.<br />

2 - Assessment of Purchasing Maturity in Small Business<br />

Jeffery Adams, Assistant Professor, University of Houston-Downtown,<br />

College of Business, 320 N Main St, Houston, TX, 77002,<br />

United States of America, adamsjeff@uhd.edu, Ralph Kauffman<br />

Relatively little research has been done on B-to-B buyer-supplier relationships in<br />

small and medium size business, and perhaps even less has been done on how to<br />

assess the level of purchasing development in such businesses. Successful marketing<br />

relationships with these smaller firms can hinge on the ability of marketers to assess<br />

the degree of purchasing maturity in such customers. “Purchasing maturity” can be<br />

defined as the readiness and ability of customer firms to engage in more highly<br />

developed complex and longer-term buyer-seller relationships. The primary objective<br />

of this study is to develop a means that marketers can use to measure purchasing<br />

maturity in particular small and medium size business customers or potential<br />

customers. Using data collected from a cross-sectional sample of small and medium<br />

size businesses in four NAICS sub-sectors, a measurement model is developed. Factor<br />

analysis, Pearson correlation, and stepwise regression are used in development of the<br />

model to identify factors that, to the degree that they are present, give indication of<br />

the level or degree of purchasing maturity in a business. A scorecard is developed for<br />

application of the model to individual firms. The scorecard can be used by both<br />

marketers and customer management to assess the level of purchasing maturity that<br />

exists in the buying firm. The primary contribution of this research is the<br />

development of an additional tool for B-to-B marketers to assess the readiness of<br />

existing or potential small and medium size customers to engage in higher-level<br />

buyer-seller relationships and thereby increase the seller’s market potential.<br />

3 - Integrative Negotiation Training: Enduring Effects of Asymmetrical<br />

and Symmetrical Training<br />

Alfred Zerres, Institute of Business-to-Business <strong>Marketing</strong>, University<br />

of Muenster, Am Stadtgraben 13-15, Münster, 48143, Germany,<br />

alfred.zerres@uni-muenster.de, Joachim Hüffmeier, Alexander<br />

Freund, Klaus Backhaus<br />

Almost every business deal in practice is shaped by negotiations as a dominant<br />

transaction mechanism (Anderson/Narus/Narayandas, 2009; Thompson, 2009). Thus,<br />

negotiation skills are crucial to ensure successful transactions for every business<br />

marketing manager and companies consequentially try to improve their marketing<br />

managers’ negotiation skills through respective training programs. As a consequence,<br />

negotiation training has become a multi-billion dollar industry alone in the US. But<br />

are these trainings worth their money? To address this question, we focus on two<br />

gaps in the negotiation training literature. While research has shown that negotiation<br />

training can successfully increase negotiation outcomes immediately after the<br />

training, little is known about its effectiveness across time. Furthermore, in all<br />

previous studies both conflicting parties were trained. From an applied perspective,<br />

this may well be a problematic feature of the literature, as firms can hardly train both<br />

parties in business negotiations. To address the related open questions, we conducted<br />

an integrative negotiation training experiment with a total of 360 participants (180<br />

dyads). We used a one-factorial design with training (no training, only seller trained,<br />

only buyer trained, and both parties trained) as between- and three measurement<br />

times as within-subjects factor (assessments before, immediately after, and 30 days<br />

after the training). Results reveal that integrative negotiation training is not only<br />

effective, but even increases in periods of non-practice. However, one-party<br />

negotiation training was only successful if the trained party was the seller and failed if<br />

the buyer received the training. This results pattern is discussed with respect to the<br />

broader negotiation literature.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!