13.07.2015 Views

Publication (PDF format) - Institut économique de Montréal

Publication (PDF format) - Institut économique de Montréal

Publication (PDF format) - Institut économique de Montréal

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

910 Peel Street, Suite 600Montreal (Quebec)H3C 2H8 CanadaPhone: 514-273-0969Fax: 514-273-2581Website: www.iedm.orgThe Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e is an in<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nt, non-partisan,not-for-profit research and educational organization. Through itspublications, media appearances and conferences, the MEI stimulates<strong>de</strong>bate on public policies in Quebec and across Canada by proposingwealth-creating reforms based on market mechanisms. It does notaccept any government funding.The opinions expressed in this study do not necessarily represent thoseof the Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e or of the members of its board ofdirectors.The publication of this study in no way implies that the MontrealEconomic <strong>Institut</strong>e or the members of its board of directors are infavour of or oppose the passage of any bill.Reproduction is authorized for non-commercial educational purposesprovi<strong>de</strong>d the source is mentioned.Graphic Design: Mireille Dufour©2013 Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>eISBN 978-2-922687-43-9Legal <strong>de</strong>posit: 4 th quarter 2013Bibliothèque et Archives nationales du QuébecLibrary and Archives CanadaPrinted in Canada


Youri Chassinwith the collaboration ofPierre LemieuxWhy New International Taxesfor Development Are InefficientMontreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e Research PaperOctober 2013


Table of ContentsEXECUTIVE SUMMARY ......................................................................................................................... 5CHAPTER 1 – IFD AND IFD TAXES1.1 What is IFD? ..................................................................................................................................... 71.2 IFD Taxes ........................................................................................................................................... 9CHAPTER 2 – ARE IFD TAXES EFFICIENT? A STANDARD PUBLIC FINANCE APPROACH2.1 Market Failure and Specific Criteria for “Good” Taxes ....................................................................... 152.2 Efficiency ........................................................................................................................................ 172.3 Administrative Costs ........................................................................................................................ 232.4 Flexibility ......................................................................................................................................... 242.5 Political Responsibility and Accountability: Transparency ................................................................... 242.6 Fairness and Tax Inci<strong>de</strong>nce ............................................................................................................... 252.7 Serious Questions about IFD Taxes ................................................................................................... 26CHAPTER 3 – ARE IFD TAXES EFFICIENT? A PUBLIC CHOICE APPROACH3.1 Tax Exploitation ............................................................................................................................... 273.2 Rent-Seeking ................................................................................................................................... 283.3 Hid<strong>de</strong>n and Inefficient Taxes: Transparency Again ............................................................................. 31CHAPTER 4 – DOES DEVELOPMENT AID ACTUALLY PROMOTE DEVELOPMENT?4.1 Development Aid and Development Resources: The Fungibility of Money .......................................... 334.2 Evi<strong>de</strong>nce on the Impact of Development Aid .................................................................................... 344.3 <strong>Institut</strong>ions and Economic Freedom .................................................................................................. 36CONCLUSION ...................................................................................................................................... 41BIBLIOGRAPHY .................................................................................................................................... 42Chart 1: Revenues from the Tax on Airline Tickets in France (Millions of Euros) .......................................... 10Chart 2: Important IFD Mechanisms and Agencies, Implemented or Proposed as of 2010 ......................... 11Chart 3: Potential of Current and Proposed IFD Taxes Compared to Official DevelopmentAssistance (Billions of US$ per Year) ........................................................................................................ 12Chart 4: Qualitative Evaluation of Current or Proposed IFD Taxes Using StandardCriteria for Good Taxes ............................................................................................................................ 17Chart 5: Econometric Estimates of the Elasticity of Demand for Passenger Air Transport ............................ 19Chart 6: Estimated Elasticities of Trading Volume with Respect to Transaction Costs .................................. 21Chart 7: GAVI’s Remuneration Costs and Average Remuneration in Full-Time Equivalent .......................... 30Chart 8: Development Aid and Economic Growth in Africa ....................................................................... 35Chart 9: Correlation Between Economic Growth (Combined with Good Domestic Policies)and Development Aid, 1970-1997 ........................................................................................................... 36Chart 10: Economic Freedom and GDP per Capita, 2010 ......................................................................... 37Chart 11: Correlation Between Economic Freedom and GDP per Capita, 2010 ......................................... 38Chart 12: Economic Freedom and Economic Growth, 1990 to 2010 ......................................................... 39


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientExecutive SummaryDeveloped since the early2000s, innovative financing for<strong>de</strong>velopment, or IFD, is a collectionof disparate spending projects, organizationsand financing mechanismsin the field of <strong>de</strong>velopmentassistance. It is first and foremosta set of current or proposed newtaxes. The current IFD taxes arethe airline ticket tax and part ofthe proceeds from pollution allowancesin Germany. Several newIFD taxes have been, and are being,proposed, including financial transaction taxes(FTTs), a carbon tax, a tobacco tax, and new specialdrawing rights (SDRs)—a hid<strong>de</strong>n tax.IFD taxes do not meet the criteria of “good”taxes suggested by the standard or orthodox theoryof public finance: efficiency, low administrativecosts, flexibility, political accountability, andfairness. The airline ticket tax hits relatively elastic<strong>de</strong>mand, which implies a large excess bur<strong>de</strong>n(economic cost). FTTs are probably inefficient,<strong>de</strong>spite the fact that many economists favourthem (for reasons unrelated to IFD objectives).Higher tobacco taxes would likely be inefficient,and raise less revenue than anticipated. New SDRscould generate inflation. Only carbon taxes, to theextent that they correct pollution externalities,could possibly be justified from a standard publicfinanceviewpoint. Many IFD taxes may carryhigh administrative costs, especially a tobacco tax,and probably an FTT and a carbon tax as well. AllIFD taxes have inflexible rates, except perhaps forthe hid<strong>de</strong>n tax represented by SDRs. IFD taxesalso fare badly against the criterion of politicalaccountability: They are hid<strong>de</strong>n, and the linkbetween the taxes and what they finance is brokenor obscure.Market failures exist, but so do governmentfailures. Analyzing IFD taxes using this approach—called “Public Choice”—reveals further problems.The danger is that these taxes willserve more for tax exploitationthan for providing the public servicesthat taxpayers want. New taxescreate new rent-seeking opportunities.Rent-seeking also occurswithin governments, on the partof bureaucrats who, like everybodyelse, naturally pursue their own interests.It comes as no surprise thatbureaucrats in <strong>de</strong>velopment agencieshave attractive working conditionsand perks. Most IFD taxes(the proposed tobacco tax being the only possibleexception) levy small amounts of money from alarge number of people who will, therefore, notbe motivated to protest, while the immediate recipientsare a small number of bureaucrats in nationalor international bureaucracies. The incentivesof politicians are misaligned too. The fact thatIFD taxes are hid<strong>de</strong>n and non-transparent is afeature of such taxes, not a bug. International aidagencies are also particularly opaque, and theirauditing procedures often questionable. IFD taxesappear to be more a <strong>de</strong>monstration of governmentfailure than an efficient way to raise moneyto correct market failures.IFD taxes do not, and would not, increase<strong>de</strong>velopment resources as much as it appears theymight at first glance. Money is fungible and asubsidy can just replace other money that wouldhave otherwise been spent on the same things.On top of this, there is much empirical evi<strong>de</strong>ncethat <strong>de</strong>velopment aid has not served to furtherreal and sustainable growth. The importance ofgood institutions, including economic freedomand free international tra<strong>de</strong>, was obscured, if notcountered, by <strong>de</strong>velopment aid.IFD taxes are in many ways the epitome ofinefficient <strong>de</strong>velopment aid.Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 5


Why New International Taxes for Development Are Inefficient6Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientCHAPTER 1IFD and IFD Taxes1.1 What is IFD?Clearly <strong>de</strong>fining Innovative Financing forDevelopment, or IFD, is not easy. An illustrationof this difficulty is given by a <strong>de</strong>finition from theWorld Bank:Innovative financing involves non-traditionalapplications of solidarity, PPPs, and catalyticmechanisms that (i) support fundraising bytapping new sources and engaging investorsbeyond the financial dimension of transactions,as partners and stakehol<strong>de</strong>rs in <strong>de</strong>velopment;or (ii) <strong>de</strong>liver financial solutions to<strong>de</strong>velopment problems on the ground. 1Like this one, many <strong>de</strong>finitions are obscure. It iseasier to see what IFD is from its history.IFD <strong>de</strong>veloped over the last dozen years froma vague concept into a complex set of projects andfinancing instruments. The i<strong>de</strong>a of finding newforms of financing for <strong>de</strong>velopment evolved fromthe Millennium Development Goals (MDGs) adoptedby the United Nations Millennium Summitin 2000. The concept of innovative financing wasformalized at the United Nations InternationalConference on Financing for Development heldin Monterrey, Mexico, in 2002. 2 The “MonterreyConsensus” <strong>de</strong>clared:We recognize the value of exploring innovativesources of finance provi<strong>de</strong>d that those sourcesdo not unduly bur<strong>de</strong>n <strong>de</strong>veloping countries.In that regard, we agree to study, in the appropriateforums, the results of the analysisrequested from the Secretary-General on possibleinnovative sources of finance. 3The study commissioned by the 2000 GeneralAssembly and completed by 2004 envisioned “arange of innovative sources of finance,” includinga tax on currency transactions and a carbon taxlevied on fuel use. 4 It was also in 2004 that a taskforce set up by French Presi<strong>de</strong>nt Jacques Chiracproposed a series of international solidarity taxes tofinance the pursuit of the Millennium DevelopmentGoals. 5 A few international meetings of heads ofstate and government culminated in the 2005Declaration on Innovative Sources of Financing forDevelopment and the creation, one year later, of theLeading Group on Solidarity Levies, later renamedthe Leading Group on Innovative Financing forDevelopment. In 2006, the French governmentintroduced an IFD tax on airline tickets. By thattime, public health organizations had startedoperations to tap IFD funds. 6,,IFD is a collection of disparatespending projects, organizations andfinancing mechanisms in the field of<strong>de</strong>velopment assistance. Their common<strong>de</strong>nominator is that they are differentfrom traditional <strong>de</strong>velopment aid. ,,The 2008 International Conference onFinancing for Development called for scalingup IFD. A High Level Taskforce on InnovativeInternational Financing for Health Systems wasalso created in 2008, which proposed new formsof financing. The 2009 G8 meeting committed to“explore the potential of new innovative financingmechanisms.” 7 In a report produced for a 2011 G20meeting, Bill Gates, Microsoft foun<strong>de</strong>r and cochairmanof the Bill and Melinda Gates Foundation,proposed several IFD initiatives. 8 In 2011, a UnitedNations General Assembly resolution stressed “theimportance of scaling up present initiatives and<strong>de</strong>veloping new mechanisms, as appropriate.” 9And the process continues: the Leading Group onInnovative Financing for Development held its 11 thPlenary Session in Helsinki in early February 2013. 101. Quoted in Sandor et al. (2009), p. 3.2. UNDP (2012), p. 5.3. UN (2003), par. 44.4. Atkinson (2005), p. vii.5. Landau (2004).6. Sandor et al. (2009), p. 4.7. Ibid., p. 1.8. Gates (2011).9. UNDP (2012), p. 5.10. See http://leadinggroup.org/article1152.html.Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 7


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientIFD is a collection of disparate spending projects,organizations and financing mechanisms in thefield of <strong>de</strong>velopment assistance. Their common<strong>de</strong>nominator is that they are different fromtraditional <strong>de</strong>velopment aid. The World Bankrecognizes the difficulty of <strong>de</strong>fining the concept:There is no internationally agreed <strong>de</strong>finitionof “innovative financing for <strong>de</strong>velopment”. Inreality, the term encompasses a heterogeneousmix of innovations in fundraising and innovationsin spending, i.e. innovative financing for<strong>de</strong>velopment comprises both innovations inthe way funds are raised as well as innovationsin the ways funds are spent on international<strong>de</strong>velopment. 11On the spending si<strong>de</strong> of IFD, a number ofinternational projects and agencies have beencreated. The most important are: 12 Immunization or IFFIm (foun<strong>de</strong>d in 2006)raises funds on the capital market to financeGAVI. as the Global Alliance for Vaccines andImmunization and now sometimes called the“GAVI Alliance,” subsidizes vaccination ofchildren in poor countries. It is often thoughtof as an NGO but is in fact an internationalgovernmental organization. Its board is ma<strong>de</strong>up of the World Bank, the World HealthOrganization (WHO) and UNICEF, plus fiverepresentatives of governments of <strong>de</strong>velopingcountries and five of donor governments. It isthe only member of IFFIm. distributes funds to fight AIDS, tuberculosisand Malaria in <strong>de</strong>veloping countries. in 2006 to channel the revenue from an airlineticket tax (see below) to the diagnosis andtreatment of HIV/AIDS, tuberculosis, andmalaria in <strong>de</strong>veloping countries. More thanhalf of its revenue comes from the airline tickettax in France; the rest comes from “voluntary”contributions from other countries, as well asfrom the Bill and Melinda Gates Foundation.The field work is done by field partners, whichinclu<strong>de</strong> international health organizations (aswell as the Clinton Foundation). UNITAID’schairman <strong>de</strong>scribes his organization as “averitable laboratory of innovative financing for<strong>de</strong>velopment.” 13IFD initiatives implemented thus far focusmainly on health and especially childhoodimmunization and the fight against HIV/AIDS.Some IFD financing has also gone to environmentalprotection.,,IFD initiatives implemented thusfar focus mainly on health and especiallychildhood immunization and the fightagainst HIV/AIDS. Some IFD financinghas also gone to environmentalprotection. ,,On the financing si<strong>de</strong> of IFD, many differentmechanisms are used. The United NationsDevelopment Programme (UNDP) distinguishesfour broad categories: 141) Taxes, dues or other obligatory charges:These are taxes un<strong>de</strong>r different names,and inclu<strong>de</strong> the current “solidarity levy onair tickets.” The other current IFD tax isthe portion of the sales of EU allowances(permits to emit carbon dioxi<strong>de</strong>) that theGerman government <strong>de</strong>votes to climateprotection in <strong>de</strong>veloping countries. 15Other international taxes are beingconsi<strong>de</strong>red, such as financial transactiontaxes, carbon taxes, and a “solidaritytobacco contribution.”11. Quoted in UNDP (2012), p. 7.12. See Sandor et al. (2009) and UNDP (2012) for a summary. See alsoCour <strong>de</strong>s comptes (2010), pp. 65, 109, and passim; Fan and Silverman(2012).813. UNITAID (2011), p. 1.14. UNDP (2012). See also Sandor et al. (2009), Girishankar (2009), andOECD (2011). These categories are not always mutually exclusive.15. Girishankar (2009), p. 59; UNDP (2012), p. 15.Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are Inefficient2) Voluntary solidarity contributions:These are private initiatives, encouragedand facilitated by governments, wherebyprivate companies allow their customersto voluntarily contribute to the financingof international <strong>de</strong>velopment projects.“(Red),” for instance, is a licencedtra<strong>de</strong>mark that tells consumers that theproducer gives 50% of its profits for goodsso tagged to the Global Fund for thepurpose of fighting HIV/AIDS. 163) Frontloading and <strong>de</strong>bt-based instruments:The International Finance Facility forImmunization (IFFIm) issues bonds oncapital markets that are guaranteed byfuture official <strong>de</strong>velopment assistancecommitments from eight donorgovernments. The World Bank issues bondsto finance <strong>de</strong>velopment or climate changeadaptation and mitigation projects. 17 Donorgovernments may also reduce the <strong>de</strong>bts of<strong>de</strong>btor governments as a way for the latterto finance health expenditures (through theGlobal Fund, for example). 184) State guarantees, public-private incentives,insurance and other market-basedmechanisms: Un<strong>de</strong>r this title, UNDPinclu<strong>de</strong>s different forms of subsidies—forvaccines, for pollution reduction in <strong>de</strong>velopingcountries, for insurance againstnatural catastrophes, etc. 19IFD financing mechanisms have raisedrelatively little money thus far, but estimates varywi<strong>de</strong>ly <strong>de</strong>pending on what counts as IFD. Theyrange from US$6 billion to US$57 billion between2000 and 2008, 20 compared to US$133 billion inofficial <strong>de</strong>velopment assistance for 2011 alone.According to a World Bank study, less than 7% of<strong>de</strong>velopment assistance is financed by IFD. 2116. UNDP (2012), pp. 11 and 44. See also www.joinred.com.17. UNDP (2012), p. 11.18. Sandor (2009), p. 1.19. UNDP (2012), pp. 14-16.20. Ibid., p. 9; Sandor et al. (2009), p. 3.21. Girishankar (2009), p. 8.1.2 IFD TaxesAsi<strong>de</strong> from the German government’s allocationto environmental projects from its sales of pollutionallowances, the airline ticket tax is the only currentIFD tax. 22Asi<strong>de</strong> from the German government’sallocation to environmental projectsfrom its sales of pollution allowances,the airline ticket tax is theonly current IFD tax. ,,Launched in 2006, it is now fully implementedby the governments of Cameroon, Chile, Congo,France, Madagascar, Mali, Mauritius, Niger, andthe Republic of Korea. 23 The tax is ad<strong>de</strong>d to individualpassengers’ ticket prices, and collected byairlines, on flights <strong>de</strong>parting from these participatingcountries. The schedule usually levies alow amount on domestic and economy flights,and higher amounts on business or first class. InFrance, for example, the schedule is the following:,, €1 perpassenger <strong>de</strong>parting from France in economyclass; €10 in business and first class; €4 per passenger<strong>de</strong>parting from France in economy class; €40in business and first class. 24Participating governments channel the proceedsof their airline ticket tax into UNITAID, which<strong>de</strong>rives two thirds of its resources from this source. 25Thus far, the tax has raised about US$200 milliona year on average over the past six years, mostlyfrom France. Chart 1 shows the amounts (in euros)collected by the French government since 2006. TheUN estimates its potential at between US$1 billion22. The government of Norway pays part of a carbon tax into UNITAID,but this is not usually consi<strong>de</strong>red as an IFD tax. An exception isAssemblée nationale (2011), which suggests that it is an IFD tax (p. 9).23. See http://www.unitaid.eu/fr/les-financements-innovants.24. République Française (2013). As we are going to press, the Frenchgovernment is announcing an increase of the tax of 12.7% in 2014; see“La taxe Chirac sur les billets d’avion revalorisée <strong>de</strong> 12,7% en 2014”,Le Figaro, July 31, 2013.25. UNDP (2012), p. 10.Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 9


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientChart 1Revenues from the Tax on Airline Tickets in France (Millions of Euros)Year 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 201245 164 173 162 163 175 185Source: République Française (2013).and US$10 billion per year if it were to be exten<strong>de</strong>dto other countries. 26The German government <strong>de</strong>votes about 10% ofits revenues from the sale of EU allowances (permitsto issue carbon dioxi<strong>de</strong>) to climate protection in <strong>de</strong>velopingcountries. This is the other current IFD tax(excluding future taxes that will be necessary to repayIFD bonds).Chart 2 shows how taxes constitute (currentlyand in the future) the largest part of IFD revenues.Bond financing has reached US$2.4 billion,the ultimate goal being US$4 billion. Donorgovernments and the Gates Foundation havealso pledged US$1.5 billion for subsidizing andpurchasing vaccines. But these are stocks, asopposed to annual flows of financing. Moreover,public bonds and other government commitments(as opposed to private donations) have to befinanced by future taxes. Looking at current taxesas annual flows, we see more clearly how IFD isdominated by taxes. IFD tax revenues from the saleof German pollution allowances totaled 120 millioneuros in 2008 and 230 million euros in both 2009and 2010. 27 (Note that selling pollution permits isequivalent to a tax.) The air ticket levy now raisesabout US$250 million a year.Moreover, proposals for extending current IFDtaxes and creating new ones would greatly increasetheir potential, as shown on Chart 3 (borrowedfrom the UN). The UNDP <strong>de</strong>clares that “thescope for more innovations in the future is both26. UN (2012), p. 4.27. See this webpage from the German Ministry for EconomicCooperation and Development: http://www.bmz.<strong>de</strong>/en/what_we_do/issues/<strong>de</strong>velopment-financing/innovative-<strong>de</strong>velopment-financinginstruments/Auctioning-emission-certificates/in<strong>de</strong>x.html.IFD taxrevenues are likely to have gone done since because of the <strong>de</strong>crease inthe price of carbon allowances.10enormous and probably inevitable.” 28 The currenttaxes—the air ticket tax and pollution allowancesearmarked for <strong>de</strong>veloping countries—could beexten<strong>de</strong>d to other countries. The chart also showsthe potential of the new taxes currently proposed:Special Drawing Rights (SDRs) for thegovernments of <strong>de</strong>veloping countries (We willsee later in this chapter how this would amountto an inflation tax.) part of the trading schemes proposed by theKyoto agreement, and we will inclu<strong>de</strong> it in thecategory of carbon taxes.),,This Research Paper will focus onthe most important of the IFD taxesnow proposed: FTTs, carbon taxes,tobacco taxes, and SDR allocations. ,,This Research Paper will focus on the mostimportant of the IFD taxes now proposed: FTTs,carbon taxes, tobacco taxes, and SDR allocations.Financial transaction taxes are one sort ofproposed IFD taxes. Taxes on different financial28. UNDP (2012), p. 17.Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientChart 2 Important IFD Mechanisms and Agencies, Implemented or Proposed as of 2010*INITIATIVEPURPOSEHOW DOES IT WORK?REVENUESIS IT OFFICIALDEVELOPMENTASSISTANCE?NEW AGENCIESGAVI Alliance (2000)Public-private partnership forimmunisations.Pooled funds distributed, basedon proposals from poorer<strong>de</strong>veloping countries.About USD 300m. a year. USD3.7b. approved for 2000-15, asof 2009.Yes, but only for officialcontributions.The Global Fund (2002)NEW MECHANISMSPublic-private partnership tofight AIDS, TB and malaria.Pooled funds distributed, basedon proposals from poorer<strong>de</strong>veloping coountries.About USD 3.2b. a year. Total ofUSD 14b. raised by 2009.Yes, but only for officialcontributions.(a) New revenue raisingAir-ticket levy (2006)Fund a purchase facility(UNTAID) for AIDS, TB andmalaria treatments.13 countries apply a domestictax (2009). UNITAID funds arechanneled through existinginstitutions, esp. ClintonFoundation.USD 251m. a year.Yes, when funds collectedare paid to UNITAID or otherinternational agencies.Auctioning/sales of emissionpermits (2009)Currency Transaction Levy(b(b) Bonds (front-loading)International Finance Facility forImmunization (IFFIm, 2006)(c ) Voluntary contributionsGlobal Digital Solidarity fund(2003)(PRODUCT) RED (2006)Airline ticket voluntary solidaritycontribution(d) Guarantees (incentives)Advance Market Commitment(AMC, 2007)In<strong>de</strong>x-based weather insuranceProvi<strong>de</strong> funds for climatemitigation and adaptation.Increase the funds allocated tofinance <strong>de</strong>velopment.Fund GAVI campaigns.Promote an inclusivein<strong>format</strong>ion society.Provi<strong>de</strong> additional funding toGlobal Fund’s activities in sub-Saharan Africa.Provi<strong>de</strong> additional resources tofund UNITAID activities.Provi<strong>de</strong> incentive to <strong>de</strong>velopnew vaccines.Un<strong>de</strong>r EU regulations, EUAllowances (EUA) for carbondioxi<strong>de</strong> emissions are sold toemitters.Governments apply a tax onforeign exchange transactions.Bonds are sold in theinternational capital marketsagainst legally binding longtermODA commitments from 8donor countries.Public or private bodiesvoluntarily contribute 1% ofdigital procurement contracts.Product RED tra<strong>de</strong>mark licensedto global companies that pledgea share of profits from sales ofRED Products to Global Fundprograms.Individuals or corporations electto contribute to <strong>de</strong>velopementwhen booking flights.Donors commit to buy asuccesful vaccine from vaccinemakers at a negotiated pricewhich covers <strong>de</strong>velopment costs.Reduce the vulnerability of rural IFAD-WFP partnership provi<strong>de</strong>spoor to extreme weather events. farmers with weather-in<strong>de</strong>xedinsurance.Germany’s 2009 budgetallocates EUR 225m. in EUAsales to <strong>de</strong>velopment.Levying 0,005% on majorcurrencies would yield USD 33b.a year.USD 2.4b. raised by 2009; aim isto raise a total of USD 4b.Since 2003, more thanEUR 30m. allocated to300 grantees.USD 134.5m. tranfered to GlobalFund to date.USD 2 per ticket contributionmight raise up to USD 960m.a year.USD 1.5b. pledged by 5donors and Bill & MelindaGates Foundation for AMC forpneumococcal disease.Weather insurance schemesalready piloted in Ethiopia,Malawi, Nicaragua, Hondurasand India.Yes, when proceeds are spenton <strong>de</strong>velopment.Yes, when funds collectedare spent on <strong>de</strong>velopmentassistance.Yes, for governement paymentsto meet bond interest andprincipal.Yes, but only for officialcontributions.No, only when private fundsare involved.No, only when private funds areinvolved.Yes, but only when donorgovernments pay for vaccines.Yes, but only for officialcontributions to insurancepremiums.* Italics represent proposed schemes as of 2010. As suggested in the text, many projects have changed since. Source: Sandor et al. (2009), p. 4.Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 11


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientChart 3Potential of Current and Proposed IFD Taxes Compared to OfficialDevelopment Assistance (Billions of US$ per Year)300Upper bound250200150Lower bound100500New issuance SDRsCarbon taxesLeveraging SDRsFinancial transaction taxesBillionaire taxCurrency transaction taxEU Emission Trading SchemeAir passenger levyCertified emisssion reduction taxCurrent ODA flowSource: UN (2012), p. 3.instruments have been un<strong>de</strong>r discussion since the1970s, when James Tobin proposed a tax on currencytra<strong>de</strong>s with the goal of taming speculation. 29 Theproposal has since been resurrected and appliedto other financial instruments, and with differentgoals in mind, from raising general revenuesto financing <strong>de</strong>velopment or environmentalprotection, making the financial sector pay for therecent economic crisis, or redistributing revenuesat the global level. 30 The EU plans to introduceits own financial transaction tax but this projectis not related to IFD. 31 The rate envisioned by the29. The Economist (2013b).30. UNDP (2012), pp. 17-18.31. “Wi<strong>de</strong>r Euro ‘Tobin Tax’ will Net €35bn,” Financial Times, January 29,2013; The Economist (2013f).EU was to be 0.1% on the exchange of stocks andbonds, and 0.01% on <strong>de</strong>rivative contracts, but thecontroversial project has been watered down. 32Carbon taxes are a second main type of newtax that has been proposed by IFD advocates. Twodistinct proposals have been ma<strong>de</strong>: (1) carbontaxes on specific fuels; and (2) emission permitsas they exist un<strong>de</strong>r the EU’s cap-and-tra<strong>de</strong> system,called the Emissions Trading System. Regardingthe latter, it has been proposed that part of therevenues from such permits be earmarked forinternational <strong>de</strong>velopment purposes, “eradicating32. “European Lawmakers Vote for Transaction Tax,” Financial Times,June 18, 2013.12Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are Inefficientpoverty and hunger,” or environmental projects—as the German government now does. 33 Regardingthe former proposal, specific global carbon taxeswould be imposed on fuels used in internationalaviation and maritime transport (both goods andpassengers). 34 The purpose of these specific taxeswould be both to help “reduce carbon emissions”and “to generate a sizeable flow of revenues.” 35The proposed tax rate would be US$25 per ton ofCO 2 emissions—several times what an allowancefor a ton of carbon currently costs in the EU. 36Revenues from these taxes would be earmarked forenvironmental protection in <strong>de</strong>veloping countries.A third sort of tax, the “solidarity tobaccocontribution,” was suggested by the High LevelTaskforce on Innovative Financing for HealthSystems in 2009. The starting i<strong>de</strong>a was to “expandthe mandatory solidarity levy on airline tickets an<strong>de</strong>xplore the technical viability of other solidaritylevies on tobacco and currency transactions.” 37The concept of an international tobacco tax, whichwould be levied on top of existing national tobaccotaxes, was <strong>de</strong>veloped by the WHO in a subsequentreport. This micro-levy of perhaps $0.05/packwould be “voluntary” 38 in the sense that memberstates of the WHO could choose whether or not toimpose it on their taxpayers—for whom, of course,it would not be voluntary at all. The tax proceedswould serve to finance health and <strong>de</strong>velopmentprojects. The WHO estimated that it could raise atleast US$5.5 billion in G20+ countries; 39 Bill Gates,who endorses the project of a tobacco tax, evaluatesits potential at US$9 billion. 4033. UN (2009), pp. 71-73; OECD (2010), p. 20.34. IMF (2011), p. 6 and passim.35. UNDP (2012), p. 19.36. About US$4 per ton in the spring of 2013: see “The Collapse of theCarbon Market,” Financial Times, May 23, 2013; and “Worry OverScarcer Credits Propels US Carbon Market RGGI’’, Financial Times,June 9, 2013. See also The Economist (2013a).37. WHO (2011), p. 4.38. Ibid.39. WHO (2011), pp. 12, 21, 34 and passim. The G20+ is ma<strong>de</strong> of thegovernments of Argentina, Australia, Austria, Belgium, Brazil,Bulgaria, Canada, Chile, China, Cyprus, the Czech Republic,Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, India,Indonesia, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Latvia, Lithuania, Malta, Mexico, theNetherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Romania, the Republic ofKorea, Russia, Saudi Arabia, Slovakia, Slovenia, South Africa, Spain,Swe<strong>de</strong>n, Turkey, the United Kingdom, and the United States. (WHO2011, p. 24)40. UNDP (2012), p. 20.A fourth category of proposed IFD tax is fora completely disguised tax. The project wouldallocate Special Drawing Rights (SDRs) togovernments of <strong>de</strong>veloping countries, perhaps evenon a regular basis. 41 SDRs are an international assetcreated by the International Monetary Fund (IMF)that can play the role of an international currency. 42Issuance of new SDRs is a hid<strong>de</strong>n tax because itwould generate inflation. Inflation amounts toa tax, as higher prices harm everybody but thefirst recipients of the newly created money; laterrecipients have to pay more for their goods andservices and, thus, are forced to consume less.,,Although IFD revenue-raisingactivities do inclu<strong>de</strong> somevoluntary programs, they relymainly on taxes. ,,Taxes thus occupy a central place in what iscalled IFD. Although IFD revenue-raising activitiesdo inclu<strong>de</strong> some voluntary programs, they relymainly on taxes. One can find other indications ofthe central place of taxes in IFD. Keeping in mindthat illicit flows of capital inclu<strong>de</strong> “commercialtax evasion and avoidance,” the Leading Groupon Solidarity Levies “consi<strong>de</strong>rs the fight against‘illicit financial flows’ as an innovative source of<strong>de</strong>velopment finance,” and inclu<strong>de</strong>s “commercialtax invasion and avoidance” in illicit financialflows. 43 The OECD seems to put transfer pricing inmultinational corporations in the same basket. 44Taxes are the backbone of IFD, which is whythis paper focusses on them.41. Ibid., p. 20.42. IMF (2012).43. UNDP (2012), p. 39.44. OECD (2010), par. 41.Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 13


Why New International Taxes for Development Are Inefficient14Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientCHAPTER 2Are IFD Taxes Efficient?A Standard PublicFinance ApproachThe wi<strong>de</strong> heterogeneity of IFD taxes makesan economic evaluation of them difficult. Eachtax, current or proposed, would require a specificanalysis that would constitute a research projectof its own. In this short paper, we can only hopeto provi<strong>de</strong> general indications of how the IFDtaxes and their main features meet economicevaluation criteria.2.1 Market Failure and SpecificCriteria for “Good” TaxesWhat are the criteria that economists use toevaluate a tax? In the standard theory of publicfinance, the raising of taxes is justified by thenecessity of financing public expenditures,which are themselves required to correct“market failures.” A market failure is a situationwhere markets—that is, the free and voluntaryinteraction of individuals—do not correctlytransmit participants’ preferences and <strong>de</strong>mand,even when the cost of satisfying them is taken intoaccount. The insufficient production of “publicgoods” is one sort of market failure. A public goodis a good or service that everybody wants but forwhich it is impossible to charge consumers. Theimpossibility for private enterprise to charge theprice of a public good comes from a simple fact:by the very <strong>de</strong>finition of a public good, everybodygets it for free if anybody gets it and, thus,everybody will try to eva<strong>de</strong> payment (i.e., to be afree ri<strong>de</strong>r), hoping that his neighbor will financeit. National <strong>de</strong>fence is a standard example of apublic good. The concept of market failures, likethe concept of public goods, has been subjectedto constant extensions, but it should suffice hereto un<strong>de</strong>rstand that, in standard public financeanalysis, taxes are ultimately used to correct suchfailures. 45In line with the standard public financeapproach, IFD is said by its <strong>de</strong>fen<strong>de</strong>rs “to addressmarket failures” and to be “linked to the i<strong>de</strong>a ofglobal public goods” and “aimed at correctingthe negative effects of globalization.” 46 For thepurpose of the present chapter, let us accept thatIFD activities are meant to correct market failuresand offer public goods (even if this requires avery wi<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>finition of these concepts). Even so,taxes presumably still need to meet more specificcriteria: they must be “good” taxes in the sensethat they carry the lowest possible costs, that theyare the best among all possible taxes in the case athand. The question, then, becomes: Do IFD taxesmeet the standard public finance criteria for goodtaxes? In other words, are they the best taxes thatcan be levied to finance the public expendituresthey finance? The present chapter addresses thisquestion.,,Do IFD taxes meet thestandard public finance criteria forgood taxes? In other words, are theythe best taxes that can be levied tofinance the public expendituresthey finance? ,,Joseph Stiglitz, winner of the 2001 NobelPrize in economics, lists five criteria for a good taxsystem: efficiency, administrative costs, flexibility,political responsibility (or accountability), andfairness. 47 We can use these standard public45. Any economics textbook explains these concepts. Stiglitz (1988)provi<strong>de</strong>s the standard public finance perspective. For a simple but<strong>de</strong>tailed and critical explanation, see Lemieux (2008), pp. 259-305.46. See UNDP (2012), p. 7. The “negative effects of globalization” is anexample of the vast extension that some want to give to the conceptsof market failure and public goods.47. Stiglitz (1988), pp. 385-410. Professor Stiglitz is recognized as aneconomist who does not object to taxes and big government; thus,by using the criteria he proposes, we avoid being prejudiced in theother direction. A third edition of Stiglitz’s book has been published(Stiglitz, 2000), but does not materially differ from the one we usewith regard to the criteria of a good tax.Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 15


Why New International Taxes for Development Are Inefficientfinance criteria to evaluate specific taxes, like IFDtaxes. More precisely, the requirements are thefollowing:1) Efficiency – In the economic sense,efficiency refers to the capacity ofindividuals to maximize their utility (orsatisfaction) by making choices basedon the real costs of things. Hence a tax isinefficient to the extent that it introducesdistortions in these choices. Most taxescreate distortions and generate a specialcost that is called a <strong>de</strong>adweight loss or excessbur<strong>de</strong>n. The easiest way to un<strong>de</strong>rstand thisis to consi<strong>de</strong>r the case of an indirect tax ona specific good, called an “excise tax.” Byincreasing the price of the good, the taxreduces its consumption (technically, its“quantity <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d”), and the consumerloses part of the utility he previouslyobtained. This loss in welfare is the excessbur<strong>de</strong>n of the tax. The excess bur<strong>de</strong>n of atax is its net cost, that is, what the consumerloses in excess of what is transferred to thepublic treasury. If the expenditures ma<strong>de</strong>with the tax revenues create more benefitsthan the <strong>de</strong>adweight loss (plus the othercosts of the tax), the total package (tax plusexpenditure) will have been efficient. Yet,the less inefficient the tax is in itself—thatis, the lower its excess bur<strong>de</strong>n—the betterit is. Moreover, if a tax corrects a distortioncreated by market failures (pollution, forexample), it increases welfare by itself. Suchtaxes are called “Pigovian taxes,” followingthe late British economist Arthur CecilPigou. 48 But note that a Pigovian tax stillneeds to be the most efficient one available,the one that is best at correcting the marketfailure involved.2) Administrative costs – Collecting an<strong>de</strong>nforcing a tax imposes a real cost upongovernment, in terms of resources used:48. See Pigou (1932).labour, computers, buildings, etc. Anotherform of cost to be inclu<strong>de</strong>d is the compliancecost to individuals and companies, whichinclu<strong>de</strong>s time, the hiring of accountants, andthe keeping of records. The less generallyaccepted a tax is, the higher the cost ofcollection and enforcement. Also, the morecomplex a tax, the higher the compliancecosts.3) Flexibility – According to Stiglitz, a taxshould be flexible in the sense that eitherits rate or rates should move automaticallywith the business cycle (lower rates inrecession time, like with the income taxwhen incomes <strong>de</strong>cline), or changing therates with changing circumstances shouldnot be too difficult politically.4) Political responsibility (accountability) –The accountability criterion has two relatedaspects. First, taxes should not be hid<strong>de</strong>n, astaxpayers should know what they are paying.Second, a government should be accountableto its citizens for the taxes it levies.5) Fairness – Again according to standardpublic finance theory, a tax should be fair orcontribute to the fairness of the tax systemin which it is imbed<strong>de</strong>d. This is obviouslythe most subjective criterion of a good tax,as it <strong>de</strong>pends on conflicting philosophicaltheories of fairness and justice. Traditionalpublic finance usually assumes that a tax thattreats all individuals equally is a good tax. 49A rapid analysis will show that each of the mainIFD taxes (current and proposed) violate some orall of these criteria (see Chart 4 for a summary ofthe analysis).49. Of course, <strong>de</strong>fining what equal treatment is and which are thetaxpayers’ characteristics according to which the tax should be equalgets us back to philosophical issues.16Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientChart 4Qualitative Evaluation of Current or Proposed IFD Taxes Using Standard Criteria for Good TaxesSolidarity Levyon AirlineTicketsFinancialTransactionTaxes (FTTs)CarbonTaxesSolidarityTobaccoContributionSDRAllocationsEfficiencygenerally poorGillen et al. (2002),probably poorMatheson (2011)averageIMF (2011)probably poorSee references in textprobably poorCooper (2011)IMF (2011)The Economist (2013b)Coto-Millán et al.as discussed(2005)in textAdministrativecostslow to averageCour <strong>de</strong>s comptesaverage to highBronolo (2011)average to highIMF (2011)probably highlow(2010)FlexibilitypoorpoorpoorpooruncertainPoliticalresponsibility(accountability)mostly poormostly poormostly poormostly poorpoorFairness and taxinci<strong>de</strong>ncegoodCour <strong>de</strong>s comptes(2010)probably poor inthe long runMatheson (2011)poor exceptwith elaboratecompensationarrangementspoorprobably poorIMF (2011)Source: See text. The criteria are borrowed from Stiglitz (1988), pp. 385-410.2.2 EfficiencyFirst, let us apply the efficiency criteria. A taxcan be called efficient if its excess bur<strong>de</strong>n is as smallas possible for the required revenues to be raised. Wecan measure the extent of the excess bur<strong>de</strong>n if weknow the price elasticity of <strong>de</strong>mandfor the good orservice in question. 50 Here, we need to un<strong>de</strong>rstandthat, other things being equal, the lower the priceelasticity of <strong>de</strong>mand of a good, the smaller will bethe excess bur<strong>de</strong>n imposed by a tax on this good.Price elasticity of <strong>de</strong>mand, or “price elasticity”for short, is a technical concept that <strong>de</strong>scribesresponsiveness to price changes. Demand is more50. For a technical discussion of elasticities, see IMF (2011), pp. 23-26. Other elasticities are used in scientific literature, such as supplyelasticity.elastic if quantity <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d changes more inresponse to price changes; it is less elastic (or moreinelastic) if quantity <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d is less sensitive toprice changes. If, for example, a price increase of10% brings a 15% drop in quantity <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d, wesay that the elasticity of <strong>de</strong>mand is 1.5—for theproportional change in quantity <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d is oneand a half times the change in price. To take anotherexample, if the resulting drop in quantity <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>dis only 3%, the elasticity of <strong>de</strong>mand would be 0.3—for the proportional change in quantity <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>dis 30% of the change in price. 51 The convention is51. Technically, the coefficient of elasticity has a negative sign, for there isan inverse relation between a price change and the resulting change inquantity <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d. Properly speaking, then, the coefficients we usedas examples should be written as -1.5 and -0.3. We will neglect thenegative signs for purposes of simplicity. (They will appear in Chart 6,though, which is reproduced from an econometric evaluation.)Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 17


Why New International Taxes for Development Are Inefficientto call <strong>de</strong>mand “elastic” when its elasticity is largerthan one, “inelastic” when it is lower than one,and of “unit elasticity” when it is exactly one. Thereason why a smaller excess bur<strong>de</strong>n results from amore inelastic <strong>de</strong>mand is that quantity <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>dchanges less (consumers react less), which meansless distortion of consumer behaviour and thus asmaller loss of consumer welfare. If a tax does littleto change your quantity <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d, you will pay alot of tax (which is mainly a transfer to the publictreasury) but you will keep more of the benefitsthat you obtained before from this consumptionactivity. Inversely, if your <strong>de</strong>mand is more elastic,you will change your consumption a lot, and losemuch of your previous gains as a consumer. It isimportant to note that long-term elasticities arehigher than short-term ones because, as timepasses, people adapt and change their behaviourmore easily; thus, excess bur<strong>de</strong>ns normally increasewith time.Efficiency in the sense we are consi<strong>de</strong>ring here(i.e., in the standard public finance way) favoursbroad-based taxes such as value-ad<strong>de</strong>d taxes on allconsumption goods as opposed to taxes on specificgoods. This is because a broad-based tax does notdiscriminate against certain goods and thereforemakes it more difficult for consumers to changetheir behaviour by switching to substitutes. Forgiven tax revenues, a broad-based tax thus carries asmaller excess bur<strong>de</strong>n than a specific tax.It can be verified that most IFD taxes are likelyto carry a high excess bur<strong>de</strong>n and can thus be judgedinefficient. They consequently also raise relativelyless government revenue compared to moreefficient taxes for a given rate. Contrary to broadbasedtaxes, IFD taxes have a narrow tax base (themain exception being inflation created by SDRs)and are thus discriminatory and distortionary. Wecan see this by analyzing each tax separately froman efficiency perspective.,,Contrary to broad-based taxes,IFD taxes have a narrow tax baseand are thus discriminatoryand distortionary. ,,Air ticket taxLet us begin with the air ticket tax. Econometricestimations show that <strong>de</strong>mand for many types ofair passenger transport is elastic, as reported inChart 5. The most elastic <strong>de</strong>mand is for short-haulleisure trips: a 10% increase in prices causes a 15.2%drop in quantity <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d (median elasticity).Faced with a higher price, consumers substituteother means of transportation, or simply avoidsome trips. Other leisure trips are also elastic. Thesame can be said of long-haul domestic businesstrips. 52 Most air travel (perhaps as much as 80%) isfor leisure. 53 A tax on passengers, to the extent thatit is partly ad<strong>de</strong>d to the ticket price, will result ina price increase, which will <strong>de</strong>crease the quantityof air travel <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d, thereby creating an excessbur<strong>de</strong>n. We thus have good reason to question theeconomic efficiency of taxes on the elastic submarketsfor passenger air transport. (Demand forother business trips is generally less elastic, whichmeans that the excess bur<strong>de</strong>n will be lower, notthat it will disappear.) A low tax of course meansthat the price impact and the excess bur<strong>de</strong>n will belower, not nonexistent.As we have seen, the airline tax accountsfor a large part of IFD revenues. However, it issmall compared to total tax revenues. In France,for example, it amounts to only 0.03% of totalgovernment tax revenues (excluding socialcontributions). The Cour <strong>de</strong>s comptes (the Frenchgovernment’s auditor) writes that the receiptsfrom the tax have been lower than originallyanticipated, 54 and this may have something todo with a larger elasticity of <strong>de</strong>mand (and thushigher excess bur<strong>de</strong>n) than was assumed. Theauditor assumed that <strong>de</strong>mand was less elastic in thebusiness market, 55 but the data in Chart 5 suggestotherwise for long-haul domestic business trips.Financial transaction taxes (FTTs)A similar analysis can be applied to FTTs.As FTTs come in many varieties, target different52. Gillen et al. (2002). See also Oum et al. (1992).53. IMF (2011), p. 17.54. Cour <strong>de</strong>s comptes (2010), p. iii.55. Ibid., p. 2.18Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientChart 5Econometric Estimates of the Elasticity of Demand for Passenger Air TransportType of tripLong-haul international businessLong-haul international leisureLong-haul domestic businessLong-haul domestic leisureShort-haul businessShort-haul leisureMedian estimate0.271.041.151.100.701.52Range of estimates0.20 to 0.480.56 to 1.700.84 to 1.430.79 to 1.230.60 to 0.781.29 to 1.74Sources: Gillen et al. (2002); IMF (2011).financial instruments, and are charged tointermediaries (as opposed to final individual usersof savings and investment vehicles), estimating theirexcess bur<strong>de</strong>n is difficult. Yet, they have been much<strong>de</strong>bated, and are generally thought to be inefficienttaxes. An FTT increases transaction costs—thecost of trading—for any financial instrument towhich it applies. Even with low rates (like the oneproposed for IFD), an FTT can end up increasingtransaction costs significantly because it is paid eachtime a financial instrument is tra<strong>de</strong>d. 56 If the priceof trading increases, the number of transactions<strong>de</strong>creases. Looked at from another point of view, anFTT increases the cost of capital, which means thatless capital will be <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d. If a company issuesshares, investors will want to buy fewer of thembecause they will have to pay a tax to tra<strong>de</strong> them.This distortion creates an excess bur<strong>de</strong>n, as somefinancial transactions that would otherwise havebeen ma<strong>de</strong>, and would have benefited all partiesconcerned, are not ma<strong>de</strong>. The extent of this excessbur<strong>de</strong>n <strong>de</strong>pends on the elasticity of <strong>de</strong>mand—inthis case, on the elasticity of <strong>de</strong>mand with respectto financial transaction costs.,,Even with low rates (like the oneproposed for IFD), an FTT can end upincreasing transaction costs significantlybecause it is paid each time a financialinstrument is tra<strong>de</strong>d. ,,Chart 6 gives some econometric estimates ofthe elasticity of trading with respect to transactioncosts for different financial instruments. In theUK, for example, the long-term elasticity of tradingshares with respect to financial transaction costshas been estimated at 1.7, which means that a 0.1%tax on stock trading will reduce tra<strong>de</strong>s by 0.17%.As we can see in the chart, many of the estimate<strong>de</strong>lasticities are close to one or even higher,meaning that financial trading is quite sensitive totransaction costs. In the case of transactions thatare repeated often—certain repo transactions, forexample—the increase in transaction costs couldreach 22% per year, 57 which would obviously leadto a large drop in the volume of transactions. Theexcess bur<strong>de</strong>n of FTTs would not be insignificant.This excess bur<strong>de</strong>n would show up in numerousways. An FTT could distort financial activityaway from the shares of smaller firms (which areriskier and thus less likely to justify high financialtransaction costs), as apparently happened inFrance, where a limited FTT was introduced in2012. 58 An FTT would <strong>de</strong>crease market liquidity,as shares would be tra<strong>de</strong>d less often. It would shiftsome financial activities to any remaining countrywithout such a tax, like the United States, thissubstitution being one source of high excess bur<strong>de</strong>n.Some transactions, such as overnight securitiesrepurchases (repos), might have to be exclu<strong>de</strong>d, lesttheir market collapse, ren<strong>de</strong>ring the tax even morediscriminatory and distortionary.56. The Economist (2013c).57. The Economist (2013f).58. The Economist (2013b).Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 19


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientBecause of these problems, the governmentsof many countries have repealed or reduced theirtransaction taxes on shares trading over the pastfew <strong>de</strong>ca<strong>de</strong>s. 59 The Swedish government repealedits own FTT in 1991, after 60% of trading inthe most actively tra<strong>de</strong>d shares had moved toLondon. 60 After an extensive review of the literature,an IMF analyst, Thorton Matheson, conclu<strong>de</strong>s thatFTTs are not a <strong>de</strong>sirable form of taxation. 61 It isstrange that the i<strong>de</strong>a is now being recycled for IFD.In Chart 4, we say that the efficiency of FTTsis probably poor in or<strong>de</strong>r to be fair to Stiglitz, whohimself favours such a tax. 62 But he has arguedfor it because, in his opinion, it would curbunnecessary short-term speculation, not becauseit does not carry an excess bur<strong>de</strong>n. The IMFanalysis by Matheson, reported in the precedingparagraph, seems more convincing than Stiglitz’s.The revenues of the planned European FTT arenot likely to be earmarked for IFD anyway, as theUNDP has admitted. 63Carbon taxesAssuming that the benefits of carbon reductionoutweigh the <strong>de</strong>adweight loss caused by efficientcarbon taxes, the relative efficiency of carbon taxes<strong>de</strong>pends on their type. As mentioned before, carbontaxes come in two varieties: specific taxes per tonof CO 2 emitted; and emission trading systems,also called “cap-and-tra<strong>de</strong>.” Both methods can belikened to Pigovian taxes, for they have the sameeffect: They add an extra cost to the production ofeach unit of the “bad” being taxed, and thus reduceoutput. Pigovian taxes are specifically <strong>de</strong>signedto change behaviour so as to avoid an existing<strong>de</strong>adweight loss, such as the one created by pollutionwhen people do not take into consi<strong>de</strong>ration the realcosts of their actions. IFD taxes, on the contrary,are <strong>de</strong>signed to raise revenue. Some proponents ofcarbon taxes wish for a tax that would be both arevenue-raiser and a Pigovian tax, thus eliminatingthe excess bur<strong>de</strong>n of raising revenues. If revenuescan be raised by reducing a “bad,” no inefficiencyis involved.This might work if the proposal was to earmarkfor IFD some revenues from a cap-and-tra<strong>de</strong>system, like the German government actually doeswithin the European Emissions Trading System.Economists generally admit that a cap-and-tra<strong>de</strong>system is more efficient than specific Pigoviantaxes, for it lets the market compute the optimalamount of the tax: the state only has to fix thecap, and the market calculates carbon prices. 64However, the government of Germany remains anexception in using the Emissions Trading System asan IFD mechanism, and few other governments arelikely to follow suit. The international cooperationrequired to create an international cap-and-tra<strong>de</strong>system would be even more difficult to achieve.More likely to be adopted is the World Bank’sand IMF’s proposal for a specific tax on the carbonproduced by international aviation and maritimefuel. Not being broad-based, such a tax wouldbe discriminatory: It would hit internationalpassengers (again) and internationally-shippedgoods. The IMF estimates that a US$25 tax pertonne of CO 2 would lead to a 2%-4% price increaseon air tickets, and a 0.2%-0.3% price increase onseaborne imports. 65 Since the elasticity of <strong>de</strong>mandfor maritime transport (which carries mainlygoods) is lower than for air passenger transport, 66we should therefore expect a smaller excess bur<strong>de</strong>nin maritime shipping.This result must be qualified by three factors.First, the excess bur<strong>de</strong>n in airline passenger transportwould be relatively high (given the high elasticity of<strong>de</strong>mand in many sub-markets). Second, the excessbur<strong>de</strong>n in maritime shipping would still be nonnegligible,as 90% of world tra<strong>de</strong> (measured by tonnekilometer)is carried by ship. 67 Third, if the carbontax is really set at US$25/ton, which is much higherthan the implicit tax imposed by the EU Emissions59. Matheson (2011), p. 9.60. The Economist (2013c).61. Matheson (2011).62. Stiglitz (1989).63. UNDP (2012), p. 18.64. It should be noted however that <strong>de</strong>termining the optimal cap is notnecessarily less arbitrary than finding the optimal tax.65. IMF (2011), p. 7.66. Coto-Millán et al. (2005), p. 369, and passim.67. IMF (2011), p. 16.20Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientChart 6Estimated Elasticities of Trading Volume with Respect to Transaction CostsSourceCountryMarketElasticityBaltagi et al. (2006)ChinaStock market-1ChinaStock market-0.5Chou and Wang (2006)TaiwanFutures market-1TaiwanFutures market-0.6 to -0.8Ericsson and Lindgren (1992)MultinationalStock market-1.2 to -1.5Hu (1998)MultinationalStock market0Jackson and O’Donnell (1985)UKStock market-0.5(-1.7)*Lindgren and Westlund (1990)Swe<strong>de</strong>nStock market-0.9 to -1.4Schmidt (2007)MultinationalForeign exchange-0.4Wang et al. (1997)United StatesS&P 500 In<strong>de</strong>x Futures (CME)-2United StatesT-Bond futures (CBT)-1.2United StatesDM Futures (CME)-2.7United StatesWheat futures (CBT)-0.1United StatesSoybean futures (CBT)-0.2United StatesCopper futures (COMEX)-2.3United StatesGold futures (Comex)-2.6Wang and Yau (2000)United StatesS&P 500 In<strong>de</strong>x Futures (CME)-0.8 (-1.23)*United StatesDM Futures (CME)-1.3 (2.1)United StatesSilver futures (CME)-0.9 (1.6)United StatesGold futures (CME)-1.3 (1.9)*Long-run elasticities in parenthesesSource: Reproduced from Matheson (2011), p. 17.,,Trading System on other industries, it would remaindiscriminatory compared to the latter.In view of standard economictheory, the proposed IFD carbontaxes might be less inefficient thanthe other taxes reviewed thus far. ,,Some argue that a carbon tax on internationalaviation and maritime fuel would not bediscriminatory because it would actually correctcurrent tax preferences: these fuels are not subjectto excise taxes when used for internationalshipping; moreover, in most countries, no VATs orgeneral sales taxes are charged on international airtickets. 68 However, the exoneration of internationaltransport fuel may be justified by the fact thatexports are not subject to indirect taxes, and thattaxing international fuel would amount to taxingexported goods and services including tourism.Also, airlines arriving at or <strong>de</strong>parting fromEuropean airports are already required to obtainEmissions Trading System allowances—althoughit could be countered that most of the allowancesare still given for free and are thus more akin to asubsidy than a tax. 6968. Ibid., pp. 5 and 15.69. See http://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/transport/aviation/allowances/in<strong>de</strong>x_en.htm. By virtue of the Coase theorem, an Emissions TradingSystem is still more efficient than a specific tax, though – see Coase(1960) and Lemieux (2008), pp. 264-281.Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 21


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientThe picture is thus mixed. Some factors pointin one direction by suggesting a higher excessbur<strong>de</strong>n from carbon taxes, while some push theother way. It seems reasonable to conclu<strong>de</strong> that, inview of standard economic theory, the proposedIFD carbon taxes might be less inefficient than theother taxes reviewed thus far, which explains their“average” mark for efficiency in Chart 4.Tobacco taxAt first sight, another tax on tobacco wouldseem to meet the efficiency criterion of standardpublic finance. Tobacco has a low elasticity of<strong>de</strong>mand (estimated at around 0.4 in the shortrun). 70 Thus, an excise tax on tobacco reducesquantity <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d relatively little and thus causesa small excess bur<strong>de</strong>n. If specific taxes (as opposedto more efficient broa<strong>de</strong>r-based taxes) are to belevied, tobacco and other “sinful” 71 products seemto qualify as good candidates.This argument, however, does not take intoaccount a few important consi<strong>de</strong>rations. First,<strong>de</strong>mand for tobacco is more elastic in the longrun (on the or<strong>de</strong>r of 0.75), 72 generating a higher<strong>de</strong>adweight loss as time passes. With time, moresmokers adjust to the higher prices generated bytaxes, and either quit smoking or reduce theirconsumption. Recall that the excess bur<strong>de</strong>n comesfrom the fact that consumers consume less ofsomething that they would prefer to consume moreof, and that carries a production cost lower than thevalue they attach to the good. Opponents of smokinghave <strong>de</strong>veloped complicated and sophisticatedcounter-claims to the standard economic argumentthat consumer sovereignty should apply to tobaccoas well as to other goods, but these counter-claimsare ultimately unconvincing. For example, far frombeing badly informed about the health risks oftobacco, smokers overestimate, not un<strong>de</strong>restimate,the health risks of smoking; and they already paymuch more in taxes than what their tobacco-relateddiseases cost other taxpayers. 73Moreover, the argument for a new tobaccotax on top of the current ones assumes thatblack markets will not un<strong>de</strong>rmine its collection.There is already a lot of tobacco smuggling andcounterfeiting: The WHO estimates an average rateof illegal cigarettes of 11.5% in G20+ countries, 74but the rate in some countries, including Canada,is much higher. 75 It may be that the point on theLaffer curve has been reached at which highertobacco tax rates will lead to a higher drop in thequantity <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d of legal cigarettes so that totaltax revenues will in fact <strong>de</strong>crease. At any rate, theywould raise little new revenue.For all these reasons, adding a new tobaccotax on top of the existing ones would likely beinefficient.Special Drawing Rights allocationsThe inflationary impact of new SDRs allocatedto the governments of <strong>de</strong>veloping countries would<strong>de</strong>pend on the actual amounts of new allocationsand on the reactions of central banks in the US, theEurozone and the UK (countries whose currenciesserves as international reserve currencies). AsHarvard Professor Richard Cooper argues, 76 thenew SDRs could have no impact if these centralbanks <strong>de</strong>ci<strong>de</strong>d to sterilize the new money by<strong>de</strong>creasing their own money supply. In this case,the new SDRs would amount to a subsidy from theUS, the Eurozone and the UK to the <strong>de</strong>velopingcountries receiving the new SDRs, and a hid<strong>de</strong>ntax on the resi<strong>de</strong>nts of the subsidizing countries. Ifwe cannot count on central banks to sterilize thenew SRD money, inflation would be generated, theamount of which would <strong>de</strong>pend on the amount ofnew SDRs created. Although not usually analyzedin terms of <strong>de</strong>adweight loss, inflation has a similar70. Becker et al. (1994); WHO (2011), p. 26.71. Of course, to call them “sinful” is to apply a moral judgment; froman economic viewpoint, they are ordinary products to the individualswho enjoy them.72. Becker et al. (1994).73. Viscusi (1990). A summary of the different arguments and referencescan be found in Lemieux (2000, 2001).74. WHO (2011), p. 34.75. It was recently estimated at 30.5% in Quebec; see Lemieux (2007), p. 9.76. Cooper (2011).22Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are Inefficienteffect by falsifying price signals and distorting theallocation of resources. 77 So either SDR allocationsare small and do little to help <strong>de</strong>veloping countries;or else they are substantial and they are likely togenerate inflation. In any case, whether they aresterilized or not, new SDR allocations wouldrepresent a tax. The efficiency of this tax wouldprobably be poor.2.3 Administrative CostsSecondly, how do the main IFD taxes fare withregard to the administrative cost criterion? Theadministrative costs of a tax (collection, enforcement,and compliance) are virtually impossible tomeasure, if only because it is impossible to apportionthe overhead cost of the whole tax and enforcementsystem among specific taxes. Taxpayers’ compliancecosts are also difficult to measure. We canhowever make some qualitative points.,,The administrative costs ofa tax (collection, enforcement, andcompliance) are virtually impossibleto measure, if only because it isimpossible to apportion theoverhead cost of the whole taxand enforcement system amongspecific taxes. ,,At least for the French government, theadministrative costs of the airline tax appear to below, if only because it was simply an addition to anexisting civil aviation tax. However, it is worth notingthat the French auditor ad<strong>de</strong>d that “a tax created exnihilo would have been much more costly, whichmay explain why many countries hesitate to adoptsuch a tax.” 78 According to the French government,the compliance cost for the airlines is “marginal.”One large airline evaluates its administration costat 0.5% of the tax collected, 79 but the proportionis probably larger for smaller airlines. Hence our77. Lemieux (2013), pp. 133-135 and 140-141.78. Cour <strong>de</strong>s comptes (2010), p. 6.79. Ibid., p. 7.evaluation of the administrative cost of this tax as“low to average” in Chart 4.The administrative costs of an FTT <strong>de</strong>pendlargely on which financial instruments it wouldapply to. The extreme case would be if, in or<strong>de</strong>r tominimize distortions, it were applied to all financialtransactions, including <strong>de</strong>rivatives and foreignexchange transactions. The complexity of financialtransactions and the diversity of intermediariesraise administrative and enforcement challenges.A study by the IMF’s John Brondolo pru<strong>de</strong>ntlyconclu<strong>de</strong>d that FTTs were administratively feasiblebut required “a targeted enforcement programbacked by an appropriate penalty regime.” 80 In lightof Brondolo’s assessment, it is reasonable to rate theadministrative costs of FTTs as between averageand high.Carbon taxes would likely carry higheradministrative costs than FTTs, especially if theydid not take the form of a well-oiled and i<strong>de</strong>al capand-tra<strong>de</strong>system. An IMF study documents thatcarbon taxes are expensive to establish and, often,to collect. 81 This is especially true of excise taxes onmaritime shipping, as ships have a wi<strong>de</strong> choice ofwhere to buy their fuel. Moreover, any carbon tax onshipping would impose costs on tourism and otherexports (as well as imports) of <strong>de</strong>veloping countries.In or<strong>de</strong>r to counter these costs, the IMF proposescomplex transfers to the governments of harmedcountries, which would greatly complicate analready complex tax and increase its administrativecosts. Consequently, we are conservative in sayingthat the administrative costs of such taxes would beaverage to high even if the IMF itself does not seem<strong>de</strong>terred by the problems it points out.Although, to our knowledge, no estimate existsfor the cost of collecting and enforcing currenttobacco taxes, it is probably quite high given thecontinuous encroachment of black markets insmuggled and counterfeit tobacco products. Anadditional IFD levy on top of current taxes wouldprobably see the cost of enforcement rise sharply atleast in <strong>de</strong>veloped countries (and all this for littleincrease in revenue, if any).80. Brondolo (2011), p. 45.81. IMF (2011).Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 23


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientCreating money is administratively easy, sothe administrative cost of SDR allocations wouldbe low (even if, as we saw, their economic cost maynot be). This is the only IFD tax (among the mainactual or projected ones) that would certainly carrylow administrative costs.2.4 FlexibilityThird, consi<strong>de</strong>r the flexibility criterion fora good tax. In the first sense that Stiglitz gives to“flexibility,” IFD taxes are certainly not the mostflexible taxes with regard to the business cycle;like any indirect tax, their rates do not vary withthe cycle. In<strong>de</strong>ed, they may hit particularly hard atthe bottom of the business cycle. 82 As for Stiglitz’smore general flexibility criterion—that changingthe tax rates should not be too politically difficultwhen economic circumstances change—it is notsatisfied by IFD taxes either. Any internationallyagreed-upontax is more difficult to change than apurely national one. The only exception might bethe rate of issuance of new SDRs, assuming that aninternational bureaucracy was granted the powerto make these <strong>de</strong>cisions alone. This is why Chart 4ranks the flexibility of IFD taxes as poor, except forSDR allocations.,,Any internationally-agreed-upontax is more difficult to changethan a purely national one. ,,2.5 Political Responsibility andAccountability: TransparencyThe fourth requirement for a good tax proposedby Joseph Stiglitz is the political responsibilityor accountability criterion. This criterion can beinterpreted as requiring that an easily-i<strong>de</strong>ntifiablegovernment be accountable for the tax. Somemight want such a government to be a national82. Note however that the main arguments against IFD taxes arestructural, not cyclical. IFD taxes have been un<strong>de</strong>r discussion overmore than one complete economic cycle, and a major one (the airticket tax) was actually introduced at the peak of the last cycle. Thesetaxes will continue to be discussed irrespective of the economicoutlook.government, but this is not saying much becausenational governments can always choose to <strong>de</strong>legatetheir power to supra-national authorities: the EU isonly the most notable example. A narrower exampleis the International Oil Pollution Compensation(IOPC) Funds, which directly collect money fromprivate companies, but enforcement remains at thenational level, and any national government couldchoose to transfer the money itself. 83 As for currentIFD taxes (the airline ticket tax, and the portionof Emissions Trading System revenues that theGerman government transfers to environmentalprotection in <strong>de</strong>veloping countries), <strong>de</strong>legationis even more restricted: Not only are the taxesestablished by national laws, but they are collectedby national agencies, enforced by the nationalgovernments involved, and typically consi<strong>de</strong>redofficial <strong>de</strong>velopment assistance when they areactually transferred to international agencies. 84However we <strong>de</strong>fine the “sovereign” state, IFD taxesthus appear acceptable.Exactly what “political responsibility” or“accountability” means is not always clear, however.In<strong>de</strong>ed, Stiglitz himself extends the concept when hestates that it is “<strong>de</strong>sirable for the government not totry to take advantage of uninformed citizens.” 85 Thisrequires, at a minimum, that the tax be visible by theindividuals who actually support it and, at a higherlevel of transparency, that they know what it will beused for. IFD taxes meet this criterion poorly.,,Most IFD taxes, currentand planned, are hid<strong>de</strong>nand complicated. ,,Most IFD taxes, current and planned, arehid<strong>de</strong>n and complicated. The airline tax is buriedin the price of airline tickets (together with anotherairport tax in France), so the taxpayer is likely tobe unaware that he is paying it. He will be even lessaware of what the tax is supposed to finance. Thereis no relation between the service the taxpayeris receiving (airline travel) and what the tax is83. IMF (2011), p. 22.84. UNDP (2012). On the French air ticket tax, see Cour <strong>de</strong>s comptes(2010).85. Stiglitz (1988), p. 397.24Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are Inefficientsupposed to pay for (health programs in <strong>de</strong>velopingcountries), making the whole process as obscure asit can be.Much the same can also be said for theproposed solidarity tobacco contribution. FTTsand carbon taxes may also end up hid<strong>de</strong>n in theprice consumers pay for goods and services—in theprice of goods shipped by sea, for instance. It is truehowever that in the case of carbon taxes, there is arelation between what they tax and the services theyare <strong>de</strong>emed to ren<strong>de</strong>r (environmental protection)to the extent of course that the tax revenues wouldnot serve to pay for other sorts of <strong>de</strong>velopmentactivities. As for SDR issuance, it would be amongthe most obscure of taxes.For these reasons, we consi<strong>de</strong>r that IFD’s successin meeting the political responsibility criterion is“mostly poor” in virtually all cases, as indicated inChart 4. The qualifier “mostly” recognizes that aneasily-i<strong>de</strong>ntifiable government remains responsiblefor them, even if most taxpayers do not know thatthese taxes exist or what they serve to finance. SDRissuance especially would be <strong>de</strong>eply hid<strong>de</strong>n andclearly constitute a poor tax in view of the politicalresponsibility criterion.2.6 Fairness and Tax Inci<strong>de</strong>nceThe fifth criterion of a good tax accordingto standard public finance is fairness. As alreadysuggested, one problem is <strong>de</strong>termining whatfairness or equal treatment means. The implicitnotion of fairness in official discussions of IFDtaxes seems to be concomitant with progressivityof taxation and redistribution from rich to poor.As this implicit notion also dominates standardpublic finance discussions, we may adopt it for thepurpose of evaluating IFD taxes.The problem, however, is to find out whoactually pays a tax or, in economic terms, tocalculate its inci<strong>de</strong>nce. Ultimately, all taxes arepaid by physical individuals, whether they beconsumers, workers or sharehol<strong>de</strong>rs. The theory oftax inci<strong>de</strong>nce shows that a tax is often not paid, orat least not fully paid, by the individuals or entitiesagainst whom it is assessed.For example, indirect taxes on goods arenormally shared between suppliers and consumers,whether they are nominally charged to the buyeror to the seller. 86 To see this, suppose a tax is leviedagainst suppliers. Since their marginal cost hasincreased, they will reduce their quantity supplied.Quantity <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d is now higher than quantitysupplied, and the price will be bid up by customers,which is just another way of saying that supplierswill realize that they can charge more. As the priceincreases, customers end up effectively paying partof the tax. The exact shares paid by suppliers andconsumers <strong>de</strong>pend on the elasticity of <strong>de</strong>mand andthe elasticity of supply. 87And this is only the first part of the story. Ifconsumers hit by a tax can import the good fromother countries (legally or illegally), they will, ina second step, reduce their domestic purchases,eventually leading to lower wages in the relevantdomestic industry. Because of these shifts, it oftenhappens that salaried employees end up supportingmost domestic taxes, including corporate taxes;they are the least mobile factor of production, andso the tax buck stops there. 88Consi<strong>de</strong>red in this light, IFD taxes may very wellbe regressive. Despite UNITAID’s undocumentedclaim that the FTT would be paid by the rich, 89Thornton Matheson, an economist with the IMF,persuasively argues that it would, in the long run,fall on employees or consumers as investors wouldreduce their investments in financial firms (so thatthe rate of return in the industry would remain thesame). 90 Carbon taxes don’t fare well either on theprogressivity-regressivity criterion, as they wouldultimately be paid either by the consumers of goodsproduced with carbon-related inputs or by theworkers producing these goods. In fact, the IMFadmits that carbon taxes would need complicatedcompensation arrangements in or<strong>de</strong>r not to harmpoor workers in <strong>de</strong>veloping countries (in their86. Musgrave (1959), pp. 287-311; Stiglitz (1988), pp. 411-436. A good,short <strong>de</strong>scription of the problem of tax inci<strong>de</strong>nce can be found in IMF(2011), p. 23.87. The elasticity of supply is analogous to the elasticity of <strong>de</strong>mand; it is<strong>de</strong>fined as the proportional change in quantity supplied that resultsfrom a change in price.88. See Geloso (2010) and the references cited therein.89. UNITAID (2011), p. 10.90. Matheson (2011), pp. 23-26.Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 25


Why New International Taxes for Development Are Inefficienttourist industry, for example). 91 As for tobaccotaxes, we do observe that they are in large partshifted to smokers. Since smokers have statisticallylower incomes than non-smokers, a new IFD“solidary tobacco contribution” would likely bea regressive tax, and thus unfair according to theprevailing vision. 92 The inci<strong>de</strong>nce of the inflationgenerated by the creation of SDRs is difficult toestimate, but it is likely that it would also violate thestandard criterion of fairness, as ordinary peopleare among the main victims of inflation.taken into consi<strong>de</strong>ration, is poor (except perhapsfor the current airline tax). IFD taxes are obviouslybad taxes from the viewpoint of standard publicfinance.Among current and proposed IFD taxes, onlythe air transport levy, assuming it hits mainlybusiness and first-class customers (because ofits higher rates for these customers), would seemto fare well according to the standard fairnesscriterion. Thus, IFD taxes generally appear to beunfair according to standard public finance (seeChart 4).,,Among current and proposedIFD taxes, only the air transport levy,assuming it hits mainly business andfirst-class customers, would seemto fare well according to thestandard fairness criterion.2.7 Serious Questionsabout IFD Taxes,,What general conclusion can be drawnabout IFD taxes from a standard public financeviewpoint? As they represent a package ofheterogeneous measures, their evaluation is noteasy. Our analysis suggests (see the summary inChart 4) that their economic efficiency is generallypoor (except perhaps for carbon taxes); that theiradministrative costs tend to be significant (exceptfor the current airline tax and the proposedissuance of SDRs); that their flexibility is poor; thattheir political accountability is mostly poor; andthat their fairness, especially when tax inci<strong>de</strong>nce is91. IMF (2011).92. See Gravelle (2007).26Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientCHAPTER 3Are IFD Taxes Efficient?A Public Choice ApproachWhy are bad taxes like the IFD varietyproposed and adopted at all? If we cannot answerthis question, our analysis is incomplete andinsufficient.In truth, our analysis this far ignores manyfeatures of the real world. If market failures exist,it is equally true that we observe governmentfailures, and the latter should also be taken intoaccount in evaluating tax policy. 93 Governmentsare not perfect. Over the past half-century, a newschool of economic analysis called the “PublicChoice” school has analyzed public policy in thislight. 94 Public Choice analysis start from a simplehypothesis: State actors, whether bureaucrats (civilservants), politicians or voters, are just ordinaryindividuals who mainly pursue their own interestin the public as well as in the private sphere. Thisstrand of analysis helps us look at “politics withoutromance,” 95 as James Buchanan (laureate of the 1986Nobel Prize in economics) put it, and provi<strong>de</strong>s analternative to the standard public finance approachfor evaluating public policy. 963.1 Tax ExploitationOne sort of government failure lies in thedanger of exploitation, including tax exploitation,of one class of citizens by another. 97 The term“solidarity” can easily serve as a smokescreen for93. Tullock et al. (2002); Shughart (1999), pp. 171-173, and passim.94. See Tullock et al. (2002), and Lemieux (2004).95. Buchanan (2003).96. On the differences between the orthodox and the Public Choiceapproach to public finance, see Buchanan and Musgrave (1999).On p. 245, Buchanan summarizes his <strong>de</strong>finition of efficiency: “[I]f Iobserve someone with apples and somebody else with oranges, I don’twant to try to say a particular allocation of oranges and apples in afinal position is better than in the other allocation. If I observe themtrading without <strong>de</strong>frauding each other, whatever emerges, emerges,and that is the way I <strong>de</strong>fine what is efficient.”97. On tax exploitation, see Brennan and Buchanan (1980).tax exploitation. In practice, the most politicallypowerful groups are the ones that will monopolizesuch “solidarity” to their own benefits. Thesefavoured groups sometimes represent the poor, butnot always, as the analysis of tax inci<strong>de</strong>nce suggests.,,With the possible exception ofcarbon taxes, IFD taxes can easilybe exploitative because there is norelation between what the individualpays for and what he thinkshe is getting. ,,With the possible exception of carbon taxes,IFD taxes can easily be exploitative because thereis no relation between what the individual pays forand what he thinks he is getting. The “solidaritylevy on air tickets,” the FTT, the “solidarity tobaccocontribution,” and SDRs are used (or would beused) to pay for health and <strong>de</strong>velopment in foreigncountries, but they are buried in the prices of totallydifferent goods. By the very <strong>de</strong>sign of IFD taxes, thelink between the tax and what the taxpayer gets isbroken. This broken link is not a bug of IFD taxes,it is a feature. Carbon taxes may be consi<strong>de</strong>redan exception if they contribute to protecting theenvironment for the benefit of the taxpayers whoultimately pay them (that is, the consumers whobuy final products or the workers who support partof the taxes), but note that these taxpayers have nopractical way of figuring out what they pay andwhat they get.IFD taxes are hid<strong>de</strong>n redistributive taxes. Theyare meant to transfer money from Peter to Paul.Peter may be a rich man in a <strong>de</strong>veloped countryand Paul a poor man in a <strong>de</strong>veloping country,but it may also happen that Peter is a poor manin a rich country and Paul is a rich man in a poorcountry. Our analysis of the “fairness” of IFD taxeshas revealed that IFD taxes are not necessarilypaid by the rich. Hence the danger that people in<strong>de</strong>veloping countries, through politicking at theUN and in other international organizations, coul<strong>de</strong>xploit taxpayers in <strong>de</strong>veloped countries. IFDtaxes may also serve to redistribute income within<strong>de</strong>veloped countries if they favour some domesticMontreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 27


Why New International Taxes for Development Are Inefficientfirms (railroad or truck shipping companies, forexample) over domestic competitors (air carriers).3.2 Rent-SeekingRent-seeking, a related sort of governmentfailure, is the process whereby individuals andorganizations will try (through lobbying andpolitical activities) to obtain money or otherprivileges from a government that has the powerto grant them. New sources of financing increasethis power, ceteris paribus. Special interestsengaged in rent-seeking subvert government fromits purported task of protecting the public interestand realizing economic efficiency. Because ituses up resources that could have been <strong>de</strong>votedto productive economic activities instead, andbecause it results in distortions through taxes,subsidies and regulations, rent-seeking reducesGDP and incomes. Along these lines, a voluminouseconomic literature on rent-seeking has sprung upover the last four <strong>de</strong>ca<strong>de</strong>s or so. 98Private companies engage in rent-seeking.Tariffs and other forms of protection from foreigncompetitors represent one form of rent-seeking.An example is the complex system of foreign tra<strong>de</strong>control, licensing, and subsidies that characterizedIndia until recently and greatly retar<strong>de</strong>d thatcountry’s <strong>de</strong>velopment. 99 An example closer toour topic in this chapter lies in the field of carbontaxes: The IMF notes that the most efficient capand-tra<strong>de</strong>system might be open to lobbies tryingto get free allowances, which is one reason why theinternational organization favours specific carbontaxes. 100Rent-seeking also occurs within governments,as shown by the mo<strong>de</strong>rn theory of bureaucracy.Assuming that government bureaucrats areordinary individuals, they will try to furthertheir own interests by obtaining the highestremuneration or the best perks they can get. If98. See Buchanan et al. (1980).99. Kimenyi and Tollison (1999), pp. 210-211.100. IMF (2011), pp. 48-49.bureaucrats did not put their own interests at thetop of their priorities, they would not form, or tryto form, tra<strong>de</strong> unions, but at any rate, they canpursue their interests without them. A bureaucratis more likely to get good working conditions andhave bright career prospects if the bureau he worksfor has a large budget and carries out prestigiousmissions. Bureaucrats will therefore try to increasethe size of their bureau and to extend the latter’smissions. They can do this by persuading political<strong>de</strong>cision makers that they need more money toaccomplish their mandates, which is relatively easyto do because they have the insi<strong>de</strong> in<strong>format</strong>ionto <strong>de</strong>termine what is really nee<strong>de</strong>d to manage theprograms adopted by politicians. 101Bureaucrats’ misaligned incentives can beanalyzed with another tool in the economist’stoolbox: principal-agent theory. Politicians, i.e.,the principals, want to attain certain objectives,but their agents, the numerous layers ofbureaucrats who implement the programs, havetheir own personal and career objectives. Theseagents’ personal objectives do not coinci<strong>de</strong> withthe principals’ will, and to make matters worse,their performance is more difficult to monitorand control in government organizations than inprivate firms submitted to competition and the testof the market. Principal-agent theory conclu<strong>de</strong>sthat the official objectives of <strong>de</strong>velopment bureauswill often not be pursued efficiently. 102The behaviour of bureaucrats is importantto un<strong>de</strong>rstand because between the politicians indonor countries and the recipient poor in <strong>de</strong>velopingcountries stand a number of bureaucratic agencies,both national and international. Many bureaucratsmay sincerely want to alleviate poverty, but theirfirst priority is their own professional survivaland success. If the mo<strong>de</strong>rn theory of bureaucracyis correct, it is in the interest of a recipient agencyto divert as much of the donor’s money as possibleto its own remuneration and perks; and it isin the donor agency’s interest not to object toostrenuously to such inefficiencies because, after all,101. Nate (1999); Moe (1997); Wintrobe (1997).102. See, for example, Gibson et al. (2005), pp. 43-44.28Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


the bureaucrats on the donor si<strong>de</strong> earn a living bygiving money (other people’s money). Bureaucratsin donor agencies need to make donations as muchas recipient agencies need to put their hands onthem—a double moral hazard problem. 103Economist Ronald Nate argues that thefavourable treatment of bureaucrats is amplifiedin non-<strong>de</strong>mocratic countries because the rulershave more need for the bureaucracy’s support andbecause corruption is more likely to <strong>de</strong>velop. 104Note, however, that nothing corrupt or illegal needsto occur: Bureaucrats automatically spend on theirown bureaucratic goals some of the money given tothem for <strong>de</strong>velopment projects.All these bureaus, whether in donor countries,in recipient countries, or at the international level,are thus motivated to “move the money” more thanto actually further sustainable <strong>de</strong>velopment. ThePhilippines’s National Irrigation Administration,for example, gets at least 40% of its operatingbudget from capital money financed mainly byinternational <strong>de</strong>velopment loans, and the resultinglack of maintenance constantly calls for new capitalexpenditures, which are repeatedly supplied by thesame international donors. 105 The internationalagencies on the supply si<strong>de</strong> of <strong>de</strong>velopment aidalso pursue bureaucratic goals. Well-known<strong>de</strong>velopment economist William Easterly observes:U.N. agencies working on <strong>de</strong>velopmentissues do not have a stellar record; they oftenappear to spend most of their energies onlarge international summits that accomplishlittle besi<strong>de</strong>s preparing for further summits.Nor should nongovernmental organizationsbe automatically assumed to be superior toofficial aid agencies. 106It is no surprise that these bureaus, both on thegiving and on the receiving end, are after innovativeways to raise and spend money. It is no surprisethat many of these bureaus are strong proponentsof new IFD taxes.103. Araral (2009), p. 127 and passim.104. Nate (1999), pp. 160-163.105. Araral (2009).106 Easterly (2003), p. 38.Why New International Taxes for Development Are Inefficient,,The limited analysis that is availablesuggests that IFD bureaucracies aresubject to perverse incentives. ,,The limited analysis that is available suggeststhat IFD bureaucracies are subject to perverseincentives. A partial audit of the agencies thatbenefit from the French airline tax was carried outin 2010 by the auditor of the French government,the “Cour <strong>de</strong>s comptes.” 107 The Cour <strong>de</strong>s comptesaudited the two direct beneficiaries of the Frenchair ticket tax, UNITAID (which receives about 90%of the proceeds) and IFFIm (which gets the rest). 108As IFFIm is more or less controlled by GAVI, theCour <strong>de</strong>s comptes also conducted a partial audit ofGAVI.The auditors ma<strong>de</strong> many relevant observations.They noted large increases in IFFIm’s operatingcosts of 16% in 2007, 19% in 2008, and 92% in2009 as well as large remuneration costs. 109 Chart7 shows an average remuneration of €160,000 peremployee (in 2009), which reached €199,000 whentraining, representation and travel costs wereinclu<strong>de</strong>d. These costs, said the French auditor, are“cause for concern.” 110 The auditors also notedthat GAVI’s Geneva and Washington offices arerelatively “comfortable” compared to the officefacilities of government bureaucrats in donorcountries, “not to mention those of governmentbureaucrats in recipient countries.” 111 The auditormentioned that UNITAID had organized majorconferences in Geneva, Boston, Dakar, and Nairobi,but that the costs of the “very numerous meetingsand conferences” were not available. 112The reason why rent-seeking (whether fromprivate companies, business associations, tra<strong>de</strong>unions, or government bureaucrats) works is whateconomists call the logic of collective action. 113Small interest groups with concentrated benefitswin the rent-seeking game by imposing diffusecosts on larger groups. The potential beneficiaries107. Literally the “Audit Court” in English.108. Cour <strong>de</strong>s comptes (2010), p. i.109. Ibid., pp. 71-73.110. Ibid., p. 72.111. Ibid., p. 74.112. Ibid., p. 27.113. The seminal work is Olson (1965).Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 29


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientChart 7GAVI’s Remuneration Costs and Average Remuneration in Full-Time Equivalent20062007200820092010Regular personnel548590103124Contractuals008.54.50Remuneration (US$ million)7.7213.0918.720.7Average cost per employee ($)Remuneration143,000154,000190,000160,000160,000Training, staffing12,0008,0008,00010,0007,000Travel and representation39,00034,0007,00028,00028,000Total average cost per employee (US$)194,000197,000205,000199,000*ForecastSource: Cour <strong>de</strong>s comptes (2010), p. 73.are more motivated to engage in collective actionthan the victims. This is why farmers, when theyare numerous, as they are in <strong>de</strong>veloping countries,are exploited by the small urban establishment,while the small minority of farmers in <strong>de</strong>velopedcountries exploits the large majority of taxpayercustomersthrough subsidies and protectionmeasures. 114 Robert Bates, a professor of economicsat Duke University, has argued that the governmentsof <strong>de</strong>veloping African countries act as agents forthe concentrated interests of the urban minorityand organized labour, and work against the diffuseinterests of the rural majority. 115Similarly, most IFD taxes (tobacco taxes beingthe main exception) levy (or would levy) a smallamount of money from a large number of peoplewho will, therefore, not be motivated to resist,while the direct recipients are a small numberof bureaucrats in national or internationalbureaucracies. UNITAID <strong>de</strong>scribes the air ticketlevy as a “painless addition to the cost of a ticket.” 116Similarly, an FTT or a carbon tax would add littleto the expenses of the ultimate taxpayer, that is, theworker whose salary would be slightly lower or theconsumer who would pay slightly higher prices.A little inflation generated by new SDRs wouldonly take small individual amounts from a vastmultitu<strong>de</strong>.Fifteen years ago, Professor Charles Rowley claimedthat “[a]n estimated $15 billion—more than thetotal annual aid received by African countries—flees Africa each year, wealth that has been illegallyacquired and transferred by African elites, many ofwhom pay lip service to socialism.” 117 Rent-seekingmay not always be so obvious, it may not always beillegal, but it is always a costly problem.,,The typical IFD tax is <strong>de</strong>signedas a way for governments to raisemore money without meetingtaxpayer resistance. ,,Politicians’ incentives are often no better than thoseof bureaucrats. Governments seeking <strong>de</strong>velopmentaid form powerful lobbies in internationalorganizations. Donor governments often actout of motives that trump compassion, such asprestige, influence, or strategic power. The Frenchgovernment wants increased visibility in UNITAIDand more influence over IFFIm and GAVI. 118 Andgovernments are forever seeking new ways to raisenew revenues, a push that is exacerbated by thehigh level of public <strong>de</strong>bt around the world.114. Lemieux (2008), pp. 364-366115. Bates (1998), especially pp. 331-358.116. At http://www.unitaid.eu/en/resources-2/events/9-uncategorised?start=75.30117. Rowley (1999), p. 251.118. Assemblée nationale (2011), pp. 21-22; Cour <strong>de</strong>s comptes (2010), p.115 and passim.Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are Inefficient3.3 Hid<strong>de</strong>n and Inefficient Taxes:Transparency AgainWe are now in a position to extend our previousdiscussion of transparency. In Chapter 2, we sawthat IFD taxes (the current ones and most of themajor ones un<strong>de</strong>r consi<strong>de</strong>ration) were hid<strong>de</strong>n andnon-transparent. The government failures reviewedin the present chapter explain why. The typical IFDtax is <strong>de</strong>signed as a way for governments to raisemore money without meeting taxpayer resistance.This lack of transparency is not a bug, but onceagain, an integral feature of IFD taxes.Consi<strong>de</strong>r the general picture. Politicians indonor countries extend their international influence(and thus, often, their influence at home) by givingmoney to other governments and to internationalorganizations. Politicians in recipient countrieshave an interest in supplementing their budgetswith cheap international money. The bureaucratsmanning donor and recipient agencies have thesame interests. All the incentives seem to point inthe same direction. More generally, politicians arealways after more money with which to woo votersor satisfy special interests. The problem is to raisethe money without meeting taxpayer resistance.Hence the ten<strong>de</strong>ncy to impose taxes that will flyun<strong>de</strong>r the radar.Now consi<strong>de</strong>r the advantages of (current andproposed) IFD taxes. Not only are they often easyto hi<strong>de</strong>, but they are generally levied in smallamounts spread over a large number of taxpayers(or ultimate taxpayers). Given the logic of collectiveaction, no individual taxpayer is going to spendmuch time or other resources fighting a tax thatcosts him little; on the other hand, the bureaucratsand foreign governments who benefit will expendmuch effort lobbying for it.At least one IFD tax is even partly hid<strong>de</strong>n fromlegislators. Although the French air ticket tax ispaid into the account of the Agence française <strong>de</strong>développement, its proceeds are not accounted foras normal receipts but are hid<strong>de</strong>n in an annex ofthe government’s budget documents. 119 One IFDtax that we have not reviewed may provi<strong>de</strong> an119. Cour <strong>de</strong>s comptes (2010), p. 7.even better example of a well-hid<strong>de</strong>n tax: futuregovernment commitments, and thus future taxes,against which IFFIm issues bonds on capitalmarkets, are specifically <strong>de</strong>signed not to be recor<strong>de</strong>din national public <strong>de</strong>bt accounts. It was, says theCour <strong>de</strong>s comptes, a “political choice of France andthe other governments that <strong>de</strong>signed or adopted”this method. 120 The French auditor criticized suchcreative accounting.Not only are IFD taxes not transparent, but theinternational <strong>de</strong>velopment agencies that benefitfrom them are not paragons of transparency either.UNITAID is formally audited by the WHO, ofwhich it is a part; the WHO gives this mandateto India’s Auditor general who, as of mid-2010,still had to carry out a single formal audit. 121 Hefinally did produce audited statements in April2012, but only going back to 2008. 122 Internationalorganizations do not normally open their books toany other than their own auditors, which makesin<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nt inquiry difficult. Both the WHOand UNICEF, which benefit from a large part ofUNITAID’s money, refused the Cour <strong>de</strong>s comptesaccess to their internal audits. 123 The French auditor,who was thus unable to carry out a full audit, raisedquestions, and ma<strong>de</strong> recommendations, about thelack of transparency of international organizationsthat benefit directly or indirectly from the Frenchairline ticket tax. On the audit issue, the Cour<strong>de</strong>s comptes admits that no further bureaucraticlayers should be ad<strong>de</strong>d to what are already verybureaucratic organizations—which raises otherquestions about these organizations. A subsequentreport by a committee of the French NationalAssembly states that the auditing procedures atUNITAID, IFFIm and GAVI are not satisfactory. 124International agencies are not subject toaccess-to-in<strong>format</strong>ion laws like those of donorcountries. However, it should be noted that this isdue to international rules accepted by the donorgovernments themselves and transcribed intotheir own national laws. In Canada, for example,120. Ibid., pp. 91-92 and 124.121. Ibid., pp. 26 and 29.122. UNITAID (2012a).123. Cour <strong>de</strong>s comptes (2010), p. 29.124. “Les audits internes et externes <strong>de</strong>s structures Unitaid et du groupeIffim GAVI laissent à désirer.” Assemblée nationale (2011), p. 18.Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 31


Why New International Taxes for Development Are Inefficientsection 13 of the fe<strong>de</strong>ral Access to In<strong>format</strong>ion Actspecifically exclu<strong>de</strong>s in<strong>format</strong>ion that internationalagencies consi<strong>de</strong>r confi<strong>de</strong>ntial:13. (1) Subject to subsection (2), the headof a government institution shall refuse todisclose any record requested un<strong>de</strong>r this Actthat contains in<strong>format</strong>ion that was obtainedin confi<strong>de</strong>nce from(a) the government of a foreign state or aninstitution thereof;(b) an international organization of statesor an institution thereof… 125As Bertin Martens, an economist withthe European Commission and an experton <strong>de</strong>velopment aid, puts it diplomatically,international bureaucracies “may be somewhatshiel<strong>de</strong>d against direct political pressure fromtheir member states.” He notes that they “can alsoplay-off member states with different objectivesagainst each other and build majority coalitionsin the Board to advance the agency’s interests.” 126The UNDP, one of the main agencies agitating forIFD taxes, is run by a <strong>de</strong>cision council where bothdonor states and recipient states are represented,the latter in larger number than the former. 127 Itwould be unwise to expect it to recommend savingsin international <strong>de</strong>velopment aid.,,tobacco. Its current activism for an IFD tobacco taxcan be seen as just another battle in the same fight.IFD taxes appear to be more aconsequence of government failure—rent-seeking by bureaucrats and politicalgames—than an efficient way ofraising money to correctmarket failures. ,,Bertin Martens is pessimistic about theprospect of making international assistanceagencies more transparent and accountable. Anyattempt at evaluating them is itself subject topolitical manipulation, there is no market feedbackmechanism, and the incentives of <strong>de</strong>velopmentbureaucracies are not conducive to efficiency. 129Why should they be trusted with new IFD taxes?In general, we can conclu<strong>de</strong> that IFD taxesappear to be more a consequence of governmentfailure—rent-seeking by bureaucrats and politicalgames—than an efficient way of raising money tocorrect market failures.Shiel<strong>de</strong>d from ordinary <strong>de</strong>mocratic controlsand captured by their internal bureaucracies,international agencies often become vectors ofspecial interest agendas. The case of the WHO isinteresting in this regard. For at least two <strong>de</strong>ca<strong>de</strong>s,starting long before the IFD push for a so-called“solidarity” tobacco tax, the WHO and otherinternational bureaucracies have used all possible(and, we would say, impossible) arguments, fromexternalities to religion, 128 against consumers of125. Access to In<strong>format</strong>ion Act (RS.C., 1985, c. A-1), at http://laws-lois.justice.gc.ca/eng/acts/A-1/page-6.html#h-10.126. Martens et al. (2002), p. 14.127. Ibid., p. 15.128. On the WHO’s use of religious arguments against tobacco, see forexample WHO (1999) and El Awa (2004).129. Martens et al. (2002), pp. 14-15, 156-158, 176, and passim.32Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientCHAPTER 4Does DevelopmentAid Actually PromoteDevelopment?IFD taxes are predicated on three hypotheses.The first is that they can raise <strong>de</strong>velopment money inways that are economically efficient and acceptableto the citizenry of donor countries. A second, less<strong>de</strong>manding hypothesis is that IFD taxes will at leastincrease the resources <strong>de</strong>voted to <strong>de</strong>velopmentaid. The third hypothesis is that <strong>de</strong>velopment aidactually promotes <strong>de</strong>velopment. We have seen thatthe first hypothesis is doubtful. We will now showthat the second and third are very doubtful too.4.1 Development Aid andDevelopment Resources:The Fungibility of MoneyIs it not true that IFD taxes (current andproposed) actually raise money for good causes?This is not as obvious as it might appear at firstglance. The problem is the fungibility of money,that is, whether IFD taxes actually increase the netresources <strong>de</strong>voted to international <strong>de</strong>velopmentprojects, or just substitute for what would otherwisebe ordinary <strong>de</strong>velopment assistance.Fungibility is the property of a good of whichdifferent units are easily substitutable. Cars, forexample, are not fungible, at least from an ownershipviewpoint: if a friend borrows your car, it mattersvery much whether he returns the same car or someother car. Money, in the sense of cash, is fungible:if your friend borrows one dollar from you, it doesnot matter whether he returns the same dollar billor some other. If you give a friend one dollar to buya toothbrush for you, it does not matter whether hemakes the purchase with this exact dollar bill oranother one he had in his pocket. Moreover—andthis gets us closer to our topic—your friend coulduse another dollar he had put asi<strong>de</strong> for the expresspurpose of buying a toothbrush for you, and usethe one you gave him to buy chocolate for himselfinstead. It is because money is fungible that a giftor a subsidy can be used for a different purposethan that for which it was granted, and that thesubstitution is difficult to i<strong>de</strong>ntify.Development aid is fungible because therecipient government can use part of it to coverprojects or activities it would have carried outanyway, and use the rest for some other purposes. 130These other purposes can be the survival orthriving of recipient bureaus, 131 which as we saw is atypical goal of bureaucrats. In other words, officialearmarking is only a label and does not changethe consequences of fungible money: Earmarkedmoney can effectively be spent on something else.For example, according to econometric estimatesby Howard Pack and Janet Rothenberg Pack,<strong>de</strong>velopment aid in the Dominican Republicbetween 1968 and 1986 was totally diverted awayfrom its stated purposes and toward <strong>de</strong>bt repaymentand <strong>de</strong>ficit reduction. 132 The Philippines irrigationcase mentioned above is of the same sort. Thus wecannot be sure that an activity financed by IFDtaxes in a <strong>de</strong>veloping country does not replace anexpenditure that the recipient government wouldhave otherwise ma<strong>de</strong> from its own resources.The UNDP is well aware of the issue:In reality, earmarking may be, at best, onlypartially effective. For earmarking to havesome effect on the composition of governmentexpenditure in the beneficiary country, theearmarked aid should not be fully fungible. If itis fully fungible—i.e. a government can offsetdonor spending by reducing its own expenditureon the same purpose—earmarking may notsucceed in increasing the amount of moneythat goes into the specific purpose for whichthe money is earmarked. 133130. See Devarajan and Swaroop (1998).131. Araral (2009).132. Pack and Pack (1993).133. UNDP (2012), p. 31. See also Adugna (2009).Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 33


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientMoney is also fungible in the donorgovernment’s hands. A new donation can partlyor totally replace what the government would havegiven in another form. We may therefore won<strong>de</strong>rif funds raised through IFD taxes really servetheir official purpose or just replace what donorgovernments would have given anyway. The UNDPrecognizes the problem in relation to IFD:There are also risks that donors will reduce theirfuture investments in traditional ODA [official<strong>de</strong>velopment assistance] as a consequence. 134An indication that the fungibility of moneymay be at work within donor governments is thatthe money collected through IFD taxes in bothFrance and Germany has been treated as official<strong>de</strong>velopment assistance. 135 A good illustrationthat the fungibility of money also plays on thereceiving si<strong>de</strong> is found in India: Between 2006and 2009, this country received 6% of UNITAID’sbenefits, 136 while the Indian government had itsown space program and is planning to set up itsown international <strong>de</strong>velopment agency. 137 TheUN suggests that, <strong>de</strong>spite some estimates of IFD’simpact being measured in billions of dollars,“probably only a few hundred million dollars havebeen ad<strong>de</strong>d annually.” 138,,We may won<strong>de</strong>r if funds raisedthrough IFD taxes really serve theirofficial purpose or just replace whatdonor governments wouldhave given anyway. ,,Thus, it is far from clear that IFD taxessignificantly increase the pool of international<strong>de</strong>velopment resources.4.2 Evi<strong>de</strong>nce on the Impactof Development AidThis brings us to the third hypothesis. Isinternational aid effective in promoting economic<strong>de</strong>velopment and thus long-term solutions topoverty? The 1960s, 1970s and 1980s witnessed a“long and inconclusive” <strong>de</strong>bate among economistson the efficiency of <strong>de</strong>velopment aid, 139 whichremained supported by conventional wisdom. Astime passed, more and more doubts were raised. In1972, economist Peter Bauer started arguing that“foreign aid is clearly not necessary for economic<strong>de</strong>velopment, as is obvious from the very existenceof <strong>de</strong>veloped countries. … Nor is foreign aid asufficient condition.” 140 Much more economicresearch has since been done that has contributedto a changing consensus.Casual observation is rather unfavourable tothe efficiency of <strong>de</strong>velopment aid. Consi<strong>de</strong>r Africa.Chart 8 shows how, from the 1970s until the 1990s,economic growth in Africa fell as <strong>de</strong>velopment aidshot up. “International donors spent $300 billionin aid for sub-Saharan Africa between 1981 and2001,” The Economist wrote in 2005. “Yet in thesame period the number of Africans living on $1a day nearly doubled from 164m to 313m.” 141 Overthe course of the 1980s and 1990s, real income perperson in Africa shrank by nearly 10%. 142Some economists, notably at the World Bank,produced evi<strong>de</strong>nce that <strong>de</strong>velopment assistanceis useful but only when combined with policiesconducive to economic growth by the recipientstates. 143 However, William Easterly (who waslong an economist with the World Bank) and hisco-researchers showed that the impact of aid evenwith good domestic policies becomes statistically134. UNDP (2012), p. 38.135 Ibid., p. 22.136. Cour <strong>de</strong>s comptes (2010), p. 37.137. The Economist (2011). See also “A Global Shift in Foreign Aid, Startingin India,” New York Times, November 15, 2012, at http://india.blogs.nytimes.com/2012/11/15/a-global-shift-in-foreign-aid-starting-inindia/.138. UN (2012), p. 3.139. Easterly (2003), p. 26.140. Bauer (1978), p. 97. Bauer also argued against simplistic redistributionarguments: “[M]aking the rich poor,” he wrote, “does not make thepoor rich.” (Ibid., p. 120)141. The Economist (2005)142. The Economist (2013d).143. Burnsi<strong>de</strong> and Dollar (2000).34Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientChart 8Development Aid and Economic Growth in Africa*17.00%aid as percentage of GDPper capita growth2.00%Aid as percentage of GDP15.00%13.00%11.00%9.00%7.00%1.50%1.00%0.50%0.00%Growth per capita5.00%-0.50%197019711972197319741975197619771978197919801981198219831984198519861987198819891990199119921993199419951996199719981999*Aid is given as a percentage of recipient countries’ GDP. Rates of per capitaGDP growth are 10-year moving averages.Source: Easterly (2003), p. 35.insignificant when only a few parameters of theanalysis are modified. 144There is no correlation between <strong>de</strong>velopmentassistance and economic growth even when therecipient governments carry out good publicpolicies. Consi<strong>de</strong>r Chart 9, in which the horizontalaxis gives a measure of international aid combinedwith good domestic policies, the vertical axismeasures growth of GDP per capita, and each datapoint is shown by an IMF country co<strong>de</strong> and anaccompanying number referring to the successive4-year averages used (over the 1970-1997 period).The wi<strong>de</strong> scatter of points shows that there isno correlation between economic growth and<strong>de</strong>velopment aid even when the latter is combinedwith good domestic policies.We can see this in another way: Between1980 and 2002, the 10 <strong>de</strong>veloping countries withthe highest rates of per capita economic growth(median growth rate of 3.8%) got 0.23% of their144. Easterly (2003); Easterly et al. (2004).GDP in aid, while the 10 with the lowest rates ofeconomic growth (-1.9%) received 10.9% of theirGDP in aid. 145 One could object that such statisticsreflect the fact that slow-growing countriesreceive more aid precisely because they havepoor prospects—that is, one could argue that thecausality works the other way. But sophisticate<strong>de</strong>conometric research that tries to measure thedirection of causality dispels this objection.Raghuram Rajan of the University of Chicago andArvind Subramanian of the Peterson <strong>Institut</strong>efor International Economics studied a sampleof some 80 <strong>de</strong>veloping countries over the period1960-2000, and conclu<strong>de</strong>d that “there is no robustpositive relationship between aid and growth,”and that “it is difficult to discern any systematiceffect of aid on growth.” 146According to Easterly, “the i<strong>de</strong>a that ‘aid buysgrowth’ is an integral part of the founding myth145. Easterly (2006), pp. 346-347.146. Rajan and Subramanian (2008), p. 660. Note that fungibility may haveexerted an influence on this sort of result.Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 35


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientChart 9 Correlation Between Economic Growth(Combined with Good Domestic Policies) and Development Aid, 1970-1997**Development aid (combined with good domestic policies) ismeasured on the horizontal axis, GDP growth on the vertical axis.Source: Easterly et al. (2004), p. 778.and ongoing mission of the aid bureaucracies” 147 —which brings us back to the conclusions of theprevious chapter.,,There is no correlation between<strong>de</strong>velopment assistance and economicgrowth even when the recipientgovernments carry out goodpublic policies. ,,4.3 <strong>Institut</strong>ions andEconomic FreedomThe fundamental reason why <strong>de</strong>velopmentaid is often inefficient is the misalignment ofincentives: Both bureaucrats and politicians faceincentives that are not conducive to economicgrowth. Moreover, instead of promoting goodincentives and institutions (social, economic, andpolitical institutions), <strong>de</strong>velopment aid has oftenun<strong>de</strong>rmined them. In a scientific article entitled“The Curse of Aid,” three economists (includingone from the World Bank) argue that <strong>de</strong>velopmentaid can be a curse when it reinforces politicians’rent-seeking and thus prevents <strong>de</strong>velopment.These experts, Simeon Djankov et al., studied 108countries that received <strong>de</strong>velopment aid over many<strong>de</strong>ca<strong>de</strong>s, and found a negative correlation betweenthe share of <strong>de</strong>velopment aid in GDP and theevolution of <strong>de</strong>mocratic institutions. 148 In the samevein, The Economist notes that foreign assistance inthe 1960s poured money into grand projects thatfailed, and encouraged bad government. 149147. Easterly (2003), p. 34.148. Djankov et al. (2008).149. The Economist (2011).36Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientChart 10Economic Freedom and GDP per Capita, 201040,000$37,69135,000GDP per capita, 2010(current international $)30,00025,00020,00015,00010,0005,000$5,188$6,596$16,957,,0When we look at data acrosscountries, we find a clear positivecorrelation between economicfreedom on the one hand and, onthe other hand, the level andgrowth of income. ,,Economic freedom, one institution that appearsessential for economic <strong>de</strong>velopment and growth,is generally less respected in poor countries. Thisis arguably the main reason why they are poor. 150When we look at data across countries, we finda clear positive correlation between economicfreedom on the one hand and, on the other hand,the level and growth of income. Consi<strong>de</strong>r Chart10: The resi<strong>de</strong>nts of the countries with the lowest<strong>de</strong>gree of economic freedom (measured by theFraser <strong>Institut</strong>e in<strong>de</strong>x of economic freedom 151 ) havea per capita GDP (or income) of US$5,188, whilethe freest ones enjoy an average per capita incomeof US$37,691. Chart 11, which uses a differentLeast Free Third Second Most FreeEconomic Freedom QuartileSource: Gwartney, Lawson, and Hall (2012), p. 23.in<strong>de</strong>x, 152 shows a similarly high correlation.Moreover, as can be seen in Chart 12, the annualrate of economic growth (that is, of per capita GDPgrowth) increases from the least economicallyfree countries (1.58% per year) to the freest ones(3.56% per year).Development aid does not necessarily workin favour of economic freedom. Axel Dreher ofHei<strong>de</strong>lberg University and Kai Gehring of theUniversity of Göttingen find that the evi<strong>de</strong>nceis unclear. Multilateral aid (from internationalorganizations) is associated with some increasein economic freedom, while bilateral aid (fromnational governments) seems associated with a<strong>de</strong>crease in the quality of governance. If there isa positive relationship, it <strong>de</strong>veloped after the ColdWar, when the aid paradigm moved away fromstrategic consi<strong>de</strong>rations and economic planning,and more toward economic freedom. A paralleltrend is the promotion of tra<strong>de</strong> and capital flows byinternational aid agencies after the 1980s. 153150. Gwartney and Holcombe (1999).151. Gwartney et al. (2012), p. 23.152. Miller et al. (2012).153. Dreher and Gehring (2012).Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 37


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientChart 11Correlation Between Economic Freedom and GDP per Capita, 2010Free international tra<strong>de</strong> is an importantcomponent of economic freedom. It is also a sinequa non condition for the <strong>de</strong>velopment of poorcountries. 154 Governments of rich countries areoften not eager to liberalize tra<strong>de</strong> with poorcountries, especially in agricultural products.When, in 2002, George W. Bush was promising alarge increase in American <strong>de</strong>velopment assistance,he was also taking steps to hamper tra<strong>de</strong> with poorcountries. 155 “Aid is past, tra<strong>de</strong> is future,” IndianForeign Minister Salman Khurshid recently said. 156Other private activities related to tra<strong>de</strong> playan important role in the take-off of <strong>de</strong>veloping154. Easterly (2002), pp. 229-231.155. The Economist (2002a, 2002b).156. “A Global Shift in Foreign Aid, Starting in India”, New York Times,November 15, 2012, at http://india.blogs.nytimes.com/2012/11/15/aglobal-shift-in-foreign-aid-starting-in-india/.38Source: Miller et al. (2012), p. 3.countries. Direct and portfolio investment into<strong>de</strong>veloping countries is more than twice thesize of official <strong>de</strong>velopment assistance. 157 TheEconomist notes that private assistance fromthe Gates Foundation—however ill-advised itsrecommendations regarding IFD taxes may be—“isas important as [that of] many donor governments(and much more innovative).” 158 Remittancesfrom immigrants in rich countries correspond tomore than half of official <strong>de</strong>velopment assistance(excluding <strong>de</strong>bt relief) in the 48 least <strong>de</strong>velopedcountries. 159The experience of many countries illustratesthe fact that economic freedom is more efficient157. OECD (2012), p. 269. See also Picciotto (2009).158. The Economist (2011)159. The Economist (2012).Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientChart 12Economic Freedom and Economic Growth, 1990 to 20104.03.53.56%Growth (%) GDP per capita3.02.52.01.51.01.58%2.38%2.78%0.50.0Least Free Third Second Most FreeEconomic Freedom QuartileSource: Gwartney, Lawson, and Hall (2012), p. 23.than <strong>de</strong>velopment assistance. While official<strong>de</strong>velopment assistance has not increased as aproportion of GDP since 1960, 160 many poorcountries have <strong>de</strong>veloped. The progress of theso-called Asian Tigers (Hong Kong, South Korea,Singapore, and Taiwan) has been especiallystriking. China is another example although, ofcourse, economic freedom still has a long way togo in that country. 161 Like Hong Kong, China onlyreceived trivial amounts of aid over the years. 162Similarly, the current growth of Africa seemslargely due to international tra<strong>de</strong> and foreigndirect investment. “Africa’s retreat from socialisteconomic mo<strong>de</strong>ls,” observes The Economist, “hasgenerally ma<strong>de</strong> everyone better off.” 163 Foreigndirect investment in Africa has gone from$15 billion in 2002 to $46 billion in 2012. The samemagazine reports that the continent now has threemobile phones for every four people, the same asIndia. 164 In Kenya, where the technology sector hasbeen liberalized, one third of the country’s GDPflows through the cellphones of Safaricom (a localphone operator in competition with many others)and its money-transfer service. 165 Real income percapita in Africa has jumped by more than 30% overthe past 10 years, after shrinking by nearly 10%during the previous two <strong>de</strong>ca<strong>de</strong>s. 166This chapter has reviewed the evi<strong>de</strong>nceregarding the five <strong>de</strong>ca<strong>de</strong>s of <strong>de</strong>velopment aidfailure, and the reasons that explain it. Ad<strong>de</strong>d tothe fungibility of subsidies, a general misalignmentof incentives has ma<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>velopment aid ineffectiveif not downright harmful. The importance of goodinstitutions, including economic freedom andinternational tra<strong>de</strong>, was neglected if not counteredby <strong>de</strong>velopment aid.160. OECD (2012), p. 266.161. See Coase and Wang (2012).162. Easterly (2003), p. 32.163. The Economist (2013d).164. Ibid.165. The Economist (2013e).166. The Economist (2013d).Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 39


,,IFD taxes are in many waysthe epitome of inefficient<strong>de</strong>velopment aid. ,,The current UN <strong>de</strong>velopment strategy magnifiesthe errors of the past. “[O]ur goal,” claims thesecretary general of the organization, “must be asingle, coherent global agenda,” 167 which he <strong>de</strong>rivesfrom the Millennium Development Goals, fromwhich IFD sprang. Such a coherent global agendaassumes unanimity among citizens plus an i<strong>de</strong>alstate. Ricardo Hausmann, director of the Centerfor International Development at Harvard University,writes:The MDG framework is a top-down <strong>de</strong>signakin to the Encyclopaedia Britannica. It shouldbe superse<strong>de</strong>d by a self-organizing alternativeakin to Wikipedia. … This is not unlike the<strong>de</strong>bate between central planning and selforganizationin the economy. 168IFD taxes must be consi<strong>de</strong>red in view ofwhat we know about the poor performance of<strong>de</strong>velopment aid. They are not only subject to thesame problems, but are in many ways the epitomeof inefficient <strong>de</strong>velopment aid. The money theyraise is fungible, so we have no way of knowing ifWhy New International Taxes for Development Are Inefficientthey actually serve to increase the total amount of<strong>de</strong>velopment aid—assuming that aid is useful. Andthey do not address the crucial issue of economicfreedom in recipient countries.167. UN (2013).168. Hausmann (2013).40Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientCONCLUSIONIFD taxes provi<strong>de</strong> a unique window forstudying how a bad i<strong>de</strong>a can evolve, from the 2000UN Assembly to the creation of the solidarity levyon airline tickets and the current profusion ofproposals for similar taxes.Our analysis shows that IFD taxes combinenearly all the possible faults a tax can have. Withonly a small number of specific exceptions, IFDtaxes are inefficient, carry high administrativecosts, are inflexible, are hid<strong>de</strong>n from taxpayers, andare of very questionable fairness. They are opaqueand break the link between what the taxpayerpays for and what the taxpayer gets. They are theproduct of, and will further fuel, rent-seeking bygovernment bureaucrats. They lend themselves toinefficient coalition politics at the internationallevel. It is difficult to resist the conclusion thatthey are more of a money grab by politicians andbureaucrats than anything else. Because of thefungibility of money, they may not even resultin a net increase in <strong>de</strong>velopment assistance. Theypartake in the paradigmatic failure of <strong>de</strong>velopmentaid over the past five <strong>de</strong>ca<strong>de</strong>s.Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 41


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientBibliographyAdugna, A<strong>de</strong>be (2009), How Much of Official Development Assistance is Earmarked?, CFP Working Paper No. 2, athttp://siteresources.worldbank.org/CFPEXT/Resources/CFP_Working_Paper_No2.pdf.Araral, Eduardo (2009), “The Strategic Games that Donors and Bureaucrats Play: An <strong>Institut</strong>ional Rational ChoiceAnalysis,” Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 19, pp. 853-871.Assemblée nationale (2011), Rapport d’in<strong>format</strong>ion sur la taxe sur les billets d’avion et l’utilisation <strong>de</strong>s recettes, July 12,2011, at http://www.assemblee-nationale.fr/13/pdf/rap-info/i3645.pdf.Atkinson, Anthony B., Ed. (2005), New Sources of Development Finance (Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press).Bates, Robert H. (1998), “Governments and Agricultural markets in Africa,” in Robert H. Bates Ed., Toward a PoliticalEconomy of Development: A Rational Choice Perspective (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1998), pp. 331-358.Bauer, Peter T. (1972), Dissent on Development: Studies and Debates in Development Economics (Cambridge MA:Harvard University Press).Becker, Gary S., Michael Grossman, and Kevin M. Murphy (1994), “An Empirical Analysis of Cigarette Addiction,”American Economic Review 84:3 (June 1994), pp. 396-418.Brennan, Geoffrey, and James M. Buchanan (1980), The Power to Tax: Analytical Foundations of a Fiscal Constitution(Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press).Brondolo, John D. (2011), Taxing Financial Transactions: An Assessment of Administrative Feasibility, IMF WorkingPaper, at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2011/wp11185.pdf.Buchanan, James M. (2003), “Public Choice: Politics Without Romance,” Policy 19:3 (Spring 2003), pp. 13-18, athttp://www.cis.org.au/images/stories/policy-magazine/2003-spring/2003-19-3-james-m-buchanan.pdf.Buchanan, James M., Robert D. Tollison, and Gordon Tullock, Eds. (1980), Toward a Theory of the Rent-SeekingSociety (College Station TX: Texas A&M University Press).Buchanan, James M., and Richard A. Musgrave (1999), Public Finance and Public Choice (Cambridge MA andLondon UK: MIT Press).Burnsi<strong>de</strong>, Craig, and David Dollar (2000), “Aid, Policies, and Growth,” American Economic Review 90:4 (September2000), pp. 847-868.Coase, Ronald (1960), “The Problem of Social Cost,” Journal of Law and Economics 3, pp. 1-44.Coase, Ronald, and Ning Wang (2012), How China Became Capitalist (New York: Palgrave Macmillan).Cooper, Richard (2011), Is SDR Creation Inflationary?, IMF Policy Paper, January 7, 2011, at http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2011/010711a.pdf.Coto-Millán, Pabol, José Baños-Pino, and José Villaver<strong>de</strong> Castro (2005), “Determinants of the Demand for MaritimeImports and Exports,” Transportation Research Part E 41, pp. 357-372.Cour <strong>de</strong>s comptes (2010), Rapport 58-2 sur la taxe sur les billets d’avion et l’utilisation <strong>de</strong> ses recettes, November 30,2010, at http://www.assemblee-nationale.fr/13/pdf/rap-info/i3645.pdf.42Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientDevarajan, S., and V. Swaroop (1998), The Implications of Foreign Aid Fungibility for Development Assistance, World BankPolicy Research Working Paper No. 2022, at http://elibrary.worldbank.org/<strong>de</strong>liver/2022pdf;jsessionid=5mhqfiqiq94dm.z-wb-live-01?itemId=/content/workingpaper/10.1596/1813-9450-2022&mimeType=pdf.Djankov, Simeon, Jose G. Montalvo, and Marta Reynal-Querol (2008), “The Curse of Aid,” Journal of Economic Growth13:3, pp. 169-194.Dreher, Axel, and Kai Gehring (2012), “Does Aid Buy (Economic) Freedom,” in Gwartney et al. (2012), pp. 219-246.Easterly, William (2002), The Elusive Quest for Growth: Economists’ Adventures and Misadventures in the Tropics(Cambridge MA, and London UK: MIT Press).Easterly, William (2003), “Can Foreign Aid Buy Growth?” Journal of Economic Perspectives 17:3 (Summer 2003), pp. 23-48.Easterly, William (2006), The White Man’s Bur<strong>de</strong>n: Why the West’s Efforts to Aid the Rest Have Done So Much Ill and SoLittle Good (New York: Penguin Press).Easterly, William, Ross Levine, and David Roodman (2003), New Data, New Doubts: Revisiting “Aid, Policies, andGrowth,” Working Paper 26, Revised June 2003, Center for Global Development, at http://www.cg<strong>de</strong>v.org/files/2764_file_cgd_wp026.pdf.Easterly, William, Ross Levine, and David Roodman (2004), “Aid, Policies, and Growth: Comment,” American EconomicReview 94:3 (June 2004), pp. 774-780.El Awa, Fatimah (2004), “The Role of Religion in Tobacco Control Interventions,” Bulletin of the World HealthOrganization 82:12 (December 2004), pp. 894-895, at http://www.who.int/bulletin/volumes/82/12/en/.Fan, Victoria Y., and Rachel Silverman (2012), Finding its Niche? Rethinking UNITAID’s Raison d’Être, at http://www.cg<strong>de</strong>v.org/doc/blog/UNITAID-Essay.pdf.Gates, Bill (2011), Innovation with Impact: Financing 21 st Century Development: A Report by Bill Gates to G20 Lea<strong>de</strong>rs,at http://www.gatesfoundation.org/~/media/GFO/Documents/2011%20G20%20Report%20<strong>PDF</strong>s/Executive%20Summary/execsummaryenglish.pdf.Geloso, Vincent (2010), The Negative Effects of Corporate Taxes on Investment and on Workers, <strong>Montréal</strong> Economic<strong>Institut</strong>e, December 2010, at http://www.iedm.org/files/point1210_en.pdf.Gibson, Clark C., et al. (2005), The Samaritan’s Dilemma: The Political Economy of Development Aid (Oxford and NewYork: Oxford University Press).Gillen, David W., William G. Morrison, and Christopher Stewart (2002), Air Travel Demand Elasticities: Concepts, Issuesand Measurements, Government of Canada, at http://www.fin.gc.ca/consultresp/Airtravel/airtravStdy_-eng.asp.Girishankar, Navin (2009), Innovating Development Finance: From Financing Sources to Financial Solutions, PolicyResearch Working Paper 5111, World Bank, at https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/4300/WPS5111.pdf?sequence=1.Gravelle, Jane G. (2007) The Cigarette Tax Increase to Finance SCHIP, CRS Report to Congress, June 19, 2007, at http://www.policyarchive.org/handle/10207/bitstreams/19336_Previous_Version_2007-06-19.pdf.Gwartney, James, Robert Lawson, and Joshua Hall (2012), Economic Freedom of the World. 2012 Annual Report, Fraser<strong>Institut</strong>e, at http://www.freetheworld.com/2012/EFW2012-complete.pdf.Gwartney, James D., and Randall G. Holcombe (1999), “Economic Freedom, Constitutional Structure, and Growth inDeveloping Countries,” in Kimenyi and Mbaku (1999), pp. 33-59.Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 43


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientHausmann, Ricardo (2013), “Time for A Wikipedia Overseas Aid Policy,” Financial Times, March 18, 2013, athttp://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/04478<strong>de</strong>4-8fc4-11e2-ae9e-00144feabdc0.html#axzz2Nzz4cOCB.IMF (2011), Market-Based Instruments for International Aviation and Shipping as a Source of Climate Change, athttp://www.imf.org/external/np/g20/pdf/110411a.pdf.IMF (2012), Special Drawing Rights: Factsheet, at http://www.imf.org/external/np/exr/facts/sdr.htm.Kimenyi, Mwangi S. and Robert D. Tollison (1999), “Rent Seeking, <strong>Institut</strong>ions, and Economic Growth,” in Kimenyiand Mbaku (1999), pp. 199-221.Kimenyi, Mwangi S. and John Mukum Mbaku, Eds. (1999), <strong>Institut</strong>ions and Collective Choice in Developing Countries:Applications of the Theory of Public Choice (Al<strong>de</strong>rshot UK and Brookfield VT: Ashgate Publishing Company).Landau, Jean Pierre, et al. (2004), Rapport à Monsieur Jacques Chirac Prési<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>de</strong> la République, Groupe <strong>de</strong> travail surles nouvelles contributions financières internationales, English version, at http://www.diplomatie.gouv.fr/en/IMG/pdf/LandauENG1.pdf.Lemieux, Pierre (2000), “The Economics of Smoking,” Library of Economics and Liberty, June 28, 2000, athttp://www.econlib.org/library/Features/feature5.html.Lemieux, Pierre (2001), “The World Bank’s Tobacco Economics,” Regulation 24:3 (Fall 2011), pp. 16-19, at http://www.cato.org/sites/cato.org/files/serials/files/regulation/2001/10/lemieux.pdf.Lemieux, Pierre (2004), “The Public Choice Revolution,” Regulation 27:3 (Fall 2004), pp. 22-29.Lemieux, Pierre (2006), “Social Welfare, State Intervention, and Value Judgments,” The In<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nt Review 11:1(Summer 2006), pp. 19-36, at http://www.in<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nt.org/pdf/tir/tir_11_01_02_lemieux.pdf.Lemieux, Pierre (2007), The Un<strong>de</strong>rground Economy: Causes, Extent, Approaches, <strong>Montréal</strong> Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e, athttp://www.iedm.org/files/cdr_nov07_en.pdf.Lemieux, Pierre (2008), Comprendre l’économie. Ou comment les économistes pensent (Paris: Les Belles Lettres).Lemieux, Pierre (2013), The Public Debt Problem: A Comprehensive Gui<strong>de</strong> (New York: Palgrave Macmillan).Martens, Bertin, et al. (2002), The <strong>Institut</strong>ional Economics of Foreign Aid (Cambridge UK and New York: CambridgeUniversity Press).Matheson, Thornton (2011), Taxing Financial Transactions: Issues and Evi<strong>de</strong>nce, IMF Working Paper, at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2011/wp1154.pdf.Miller, Terry, Kim R. Holmes, and Edwin J. Feulner (2012), 2012 In<strong>de</strong>x of Economic Freedom, Heritage Foundation, athttp://www.heritage.org/In<strong>de</strong>x/pdf/2012/book/In<strong>de</strong>x_2012.pdf.Moe, Terry M. (1997), “The Positive Theory of Bureaucracy,” in Mueller (1997), pp. 455-480.Mueller, Dennis C. Ed. (1997), Perspectives on Public Choice: A Handbook (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press)Musgrave, Richard A. (1959), The Theory of Public Finance (New York: McGraw-Hill).Nate, Ronald M. (1999), “The Economics of Bureaucracy,” in Kimenyi and Mbaku (1999), pp. 145-167.OECD (2010), Development Finance Challenges 2010-2015, n.d. (presumed 2010), at http://www.oecd.org/dac/stats/45836579.pdf.44Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientOECD (2011), Mapping of Some Important Innovative Finance for Development Mechanisms, at http://www.leadinggroup.org/IMG/pdf/DCD-DAC-STAT-RD_2011_1-RD1-ENG_IFD-3.pdf.OEDC (2012), Development Co-operation Report 2012: Lessons in Linking Sustainability and Development, athttp://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/<strong>de</strong>velopment/<strong>de</strong>velopment-co-operation-report-2012_dcr-2012-en.Olson, Mancur (1965), The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups (Cambridge MA: HarvardUniversity Press).Oum, Tae Hoon, W.G. Walters II, and Jong-Say Yong (1992), “Concepts of Price Elasticities of Transport Demand andRecent Empirical Estimates,” Journal of Transport Economics and Policy 26:2 (May 1992), pp. 139-154, at http://www.bath.ac.uk/e-journals/jtep/pdf/Volume_XXV1_No_2_139-154.pdf.Pack, Howard, and Janet Rothenberg Pack (1993), “Foreign Aid and the Question of Fungibility,” Review of Economicsand Statistics 75:2 (1993), pp. 258-265.Picciotto, Robert (2009), “Development Effectiveness: An Evaluation Perspective,” in George Mavrotas and MarkMcGillivray, Development Aid: A Fresh Look (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2009), pp. 180-210.Pigou, Arthur Cecil (1932), The Economics of Welfare (London: Macmillan, 1952).Rajan, Raghuram G., and Arwind Subramanian (2008), “Aid And Growth: What Does the Cross-Country Evi<strong>de</strong>nce ReallyShow?” Review of Economics and Statistics 90:4 (November 2008), pp. 643-665.République Française (2013), Taxe <strong>de</strong> solidarité sur les billets d’avion: 1 milliard d’euros collecté par les companies aériennesau <strong>de</strong>part <strong>de</strong> la France, Ministère <strong>de</strong> l’Écologie, du Développement durable et <strong>de</strong> l’Énergie, press release, January 23, 2013,at http://www.<strong>de</strong>veloppement-durable.gouv.fr/IMG/pdf/CP_DGAC_taxe_solidarite_vf.pdf.Rowley, Charles K. (1999), “Rent Seeking and Rent Extraction from the Perspective of Africa,” in Kimenyi and Mbaku(1999), pp. 223-255.Sandor, Elisabeth, Simon Scott, and Julia Benn (2009), Innovative Financing to Fund Development: Progress and Prospects,Development Brief, OECD, at http://www.oecd.org/dac/effectiveness/44087344.pdf.Shughart, William F. II (1999) “The Interest-Group Theory of Government in Developing Economy Perspective,” inKimenyi and Mbaku (1999), pp. 169-198.Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1988), Economics of the Public Sector, 2 nd edition (New York and London: W.W. Norton & Company).Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1989), “Using Tax Policy to Curb Speculative Short-Term Trading,” Journal of Financial ServicesResearch 3, pp. 101-115.Stiglitz, Joseph E. (2000), Economics of the Public Sector, 3 rd edition (New York and London, W.W. Norton & Company).The Economist (2002a), “A Fresh Start,” March 20, 2002, at http://www.economist.com/no<strong>de</strong>/1055273.The Economist (2002b), “What the Presi<strong>de</strong>nt Giveth…,” March 28, 2002, at http://www.economist.com/no<strong>de</strong>/1057246.The Economist (2005), “Neo-Optimism,” November 18, 2005, at http://www.economist.com/no<strong>de</strong>/5135423.The Economist (2011), “Aid 2.0,” August 13, 2011, at http://www.economist.com/no<strong>de</strong>/21525899.The Economist (2012), “Capital to the World’s Poorest Countries,” November 27, 2012, at http://www.economist.com/blogs/graphic<strong>de</strong>tail/2012/11/focus-4.Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e 45


Why New International Taxes for Development Are InefficientThe Economist (2013a), “Crunch Time for the World’s Most Important Carbon Market,” February 16, 2013, athttp://www.economist.com/news/finance-and-economics/21571940-crunch-time-worlds-most-important-carbonmarket-extremely-troubled-scheme.The Economist (2013b), “Europe’s Financial-Transactions Tax: Bin It,” February 23, 2013, at http://www.economist.com/news/lea<strong>de</strong>rs/21572205-plans-transactions-tax-ought-be-dropped-bin-it.The Economist (2013c), “Plans for a Transaction Tax Ought To Be Dropped,” February 23, 2013, at http://www.economist.com/news/lea<strong>de</strong>rs/21572205-plans-transactions-tax-ought-be-dropped-bin-it.The Economist (2013d), “A Hopeful Continent,” March 2, 2013, at http://www.economist.com/news/special-report/21572377-african-lives-have-already-greatly-improved-over-past-<strong>de</strong>ca<strong>de</strong>-says-oliver-august.The Economist (2013e), “Doing it My Way,” March 2, 2013, at http://www.economist.com/news/specialreport/21572379-i<strong>de</strong>ological-competition-between-two-diametrically-opposed-economic-mo<strong>de</strong>ls-doing-it-my.The Economist (2013f), “Oops,” April 27, 2013, at http://www.economist.com/news/finance-and-economics/21576673-worries-grow-about-ill-thought-out-new-european-tax-oops.Tullock, Gordon, Arthur Seldon, and Gordon L. Brady (2002), Government Failure: A Primer in Public Choice(Washington DC: Cato <strong>Institut</strong>e).UN (2003), Monterrey Consensus on Financing for Development, at http://www.un.org/esa/ffd/monterrey/MonterreyConsensus.pdf.UN (2012), World Economic and Social Survey 2012: In Search of New Development finance – Overview, athttp://www.un.org/en/<strong>de</strong>velopment/<strong>de</strong>sa/policy/wess/wess_current/2012wess_overview_en.pdf.UN (2013), “Secretary-General’s Remarks to Meeting with the Group of 77 and China,” March 12, 2013, athttp://www.un.org/sg/statements/in<strong>de</strong>x.asp?nid=6650.UNDP (2012), Innovative Financing for Development: A New Mo<strong>de</strong>l for Development Finance? at http://www.undp.org/content/undp/en/home/librarypage/poverty-reduction/<strong>de</strong>velopment_cooperationandfinance/innovative_financingfor<strong>de</strong>velopmentanewmo<strong>de</strong>lfor<strong>de</strong>velopmentfinance/.UNITAID (2011), Tax on Financial Transactions: An Implementation Gui<strong>de</strong>, at http://www.unitaid.eu/images/NewWeb/documents/Finance/UTD-Report-TTF_en.pdf.UNITAID (2012a), Audited Financial Report for the Period 2010-2011, at http://www.unitaid.eu/images/budget/Financial%20Statements%202010%202011%20final%20%2028%2003%202012%20with%20auditors%20opinion.pdf.UNITAID (2012b), UNITAID 5 Year Evaluation: Summary, at http://www.unitaid.eu/images/Five-yearevaluation/5YE%20Exec%20Summary-UNITAID%202012-12-03%2016h00.pdf.Viscusi, W. Kip (1990), “Do Smokers Un<strong>de</strong>restimate Risks?” Journal of Political Economy 98 (1990), pp. 1253-1269.WHO (1999), Meeting on Tobacco and Religion – Meeting Report, May 3, 1999, at http://www.who.int/tobacco/media/en/religioneng.doc.WHO (2011), The Solidarity Tobacco Contribution: A New International Health-Financing Concept Prepared by theWorld Health Organization, at www.who.int/nmh/events/un_ncd_summit2011/ncds_stc.pdf.Wintrobe, Ronald (1997), “Mo<strong>de</strong>rn Bureaucratic Theory,” in Mueller (1997), pp. 429-454.46Montreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e


About the authorsYOURI CHASSINYOURI CHASSIN is an economist and research coordinator at theMontreal Economic <strong>Institut</strong>e. He holds a master’s <strong>de</strong>gree in economicsfrom the Université <strong>de</strong> <strong>Montréal</strong> and spent a term in Mexico City duringhis studies. Before joining the MEI, he was an economic analyst at theQuebec Employers Council (CPQ) and an economist at the Center forInteruniversity Research and Analysis on Organizations (CIRANO), wherehe worked in particular on the book Le Québec <strong>économique</strong> 2009. His interestin public policy issues goes back to his university days during which hecollaborated with the Quebec Fe<strong>de</strong>ration of University Stu<strong>de</strong>nts (FEUQ),with the Conseil permanent <strong>de</strong> la jeunesse and with Force Jeunesse.He is the author of several studies on public finance, education and taxation.He is frequently invited to take part in conferences and <strong>de</strong>bates, andto comment on economic affairs in the media. He recently spoke at theManning Networking Conference where he presented sensible i<strong>de</strong>as onreforming Equalization, and he appeared before the House of CommonsStanding Committee on Natural Resources on the topic of market diversificationin the energy sector.PIERRE LEMIEUXPIERRE LEMIEUX is an economist who has published many books on economicand political issues. In addition to his many aca<strong>de</strong>mic articles, he hassigned several articles in the international financial press and has also chairedseveral international aca<strong>de</strong>mic seminars. He holds an M.A. in philosophyfrom the Université <strong>de</strong> Sherbrooke and an M.A. in economics from theUniversity of Toronto. He is affiliated with the Department of ManagementSciences of the Université du Québec en Outaouais.


ISBN 978-2-922687-43-9

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!