20.04.2016 Views

9_Law and State_Volume 17

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

58 Johann Hellwege<br />

traditional exports of primary goods, such as agricultural products <strong>and</strong><br />

raw materials which are subject to extreme fluctuations. The establishment<br />

of a domestic consumer goods industry, however, also led anew to<br />

dependency upon imports. Of course these imports were of a different<br />

kind, namely capital goods, raw materials, semi-manufactured products,<br />

etc. Where formerly one could, without great relative repercussions, restrict<br />

the import of consumer goods during periods of balance of payments<br />

difficulties, now by contrast a restriction on the new imports also meant<br />

jeopardizing the level of production, income <strong>and</strong> employment. The dependencia<br />

school rightly points out that import requirements, in consequence<br />

of the policy of substitution, have grown more inflexible. It must be<br />

started, however, that this is by no means proof that this results from<br />

dependencia. Furthermore, actual foreign currency savings through import<br />

substitution can only be achieved if the new import needs, which arise<br />

with domestic industrialization, at the same time are sufficiently matched<br />

with already successfully substituted imports as a consequence of investments<br />

already made earlier. The high degree of diversification of the<br />

larger national Latin American economies, which has been achieved with<br />

unusual rapidity <strong>and</strong> as a rule without specialization according to the<br />

principle of comparative advantage, seems to indicate that phase extensions,<br />

for considerations of currency needs, are hardly aimed at.<br />

To the extent that empirical investigations have been carried out on<br />

the connection between import substitution <strong>and</strong> currency requirements,<br />

these reach different conclusions about the savings effect22. On the other<br />

h<strong>and</strong>, however, it may be supposed that import requirements would be<br />

even greater today if one assumes that changes in dem<strong>and</strong>, which appeared<br />

through import substitution, <strong>and</strong> the same income growth, would have<br />

taken place without this process. Yet there can be no question that Latin<br />

American import substitution policy has involved hindrances of exports<br />

which have contributed considerably to the development of bottlenecks in<br />

their balance of payments. Thus internal price relationships have frequently<br />

been changed in favour of the new industries <strong>and</strong> at the expense<br />

of the traditional production of primary goods. The over-evaluation of<br />

domestic currency signified a further difficulty for raw materials <strong>and</strong><br />

agricultural products which made up the major portion of exports. The<br />

industries originating in the course of the import substitution process were,<br />

for various reasons, not in a position to export sufficient industrial goods<br />

to compensate for the falling returns on the export of raw materials <strong>and</strong><br />

agricultural products. On a comparative international scale, domestic<br />

industries’ cost level was not always raised to unusual levels by low<br />

efficiency; but frequently it was the officials who hampered competition

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!