14.08.2023 Views

The Salopian Summer 2023

v2

v2

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

22<br />

SCHOOL NEWS<br />

Economics is not just about Money<br />

Nick Zafar has taught in the Shrewsbury School Economics Faculty since September 2018.<br />

He runs the Economics Society. This is the text of the lecture he recently delivered in the<br />

Barnes <strong>The</strong>atre as part of a lecture series entitled Dialogues.<br />

It is the start of the<br />

first lesson with a<br />

new class. I advise<br />

my new students<br />

that the moment<br />

they stepped into<br />

my classroom they<br />

agreed to leave their<br />

humanity behind.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y were now<br />

embarking on a<br />

course to become<br />

superhuman, to<br />

understand and<br />

explain things that<br />

are currently just<br />

a blur of facts, figures and opinions swimming in the ether<br />

of their consciousness. I would explain that it was not my<br />

role to get them a good A level grade, that was their job. My<br />

job was to turn them in to economists, and the rest would<br />

follow naturally. <strong>The</strong>y would be able to intelligently discuss<br />

economic affairs with their parents and stand their ground,<br />

challenging opinions and long-held perceptions.<br />

<strong>The</strong> start to this process often involves the post-it sticker (I am<br />

sure there are more high-tech ways of doing this) exercise.<br />

Each student writes down one word that economics means to<br />

them and sticks it on the whiteboard. Unsurprisingly, the word<br />

that appears most often is “money”. So starts the journey of<br />

re-education.<br />

Adam Smith, often referred to as the ‘father of modern<br />

economics’, is still the prime influence on the way we view<br />

economics in the Western world. He suggested:<br />

1. Wealth is created through productive labour,<br />

2. Self-interest motivates people to put resources to best use.<br />

He set this out in his work An Inquiry into the Nature and<br />

Causes of the Wealth of Nations in 1776, where he suggests<br />

that self-interest and competition ensures sufficient goods are<br />

produced at the lowest price to meet the demands of people,<br />

and better products are produced at lower prices due to<br />

competition.<br />

Traditional economic theory, based on Adam Smith’s work,<br />

believes that all needs and wants are met by an economy<br />

where buyers and sellers meet and determine an appropriate<br />

price which in turn is a measure of worth for all things that<br />

people desire. Over-pricing cannot occur because the buyers<br />

will not pay it and under-pricing will not occur because the<br />

suppliers will supply at this price. Everything will be priced<br />

fairly, and everyone will be happy.<br />

With resources allocated efficiently through this mechanism<br />

(often referred to as the “invisible hand”) there will be no<br />

abject poverty, extreme inequality, environmental destruction<br />

et cetera.<br />

One can challenge traditional economic theory by discrediting<br />

its underlying assumptions, including the existence of perfect<br />

information, perfect mobility of resources, homogenous<br />

products etc. However, disciples will respond by asserting the<br />

assumptions are ideals that, while unrealistic, are still worth<br />

pursuing as a yardstick of desirability. <strong>The</strong>y will argue that<br />

rational human beings will strive for these ideals and therefore<br />

that they remain valid.<br />

This piece of work, which has earned Adam Smith the<br />

accolade of being the “father of modern economics”, is 247<br />

years old, yet still substantially informs government policy and<br />

thinking today. It informs political discourse. It informs the<br />

teaching of economics which in turn perpetuates allegiance to<br />

it by the next generation of economists.<br />

247 years ago, the British economy was in its industrial<br />

revolution heyday, with a manufacturing base fed by cheap<br />

resources from a sprawling empire that reached every corner<br />

of the Earth.<br />

247 years later, the British economy, in common with most<br />

developed economies, relies upon a highly developed service<br />

sector fuelled by communication technology that would have<br />

been regarded as magic in Adam Smith’s time.<br />

247 years ago, environmental concerns were not even<br />

conceived of, let alone recognised as arguably the biggest<br />

crisis the world faces.<br />

On a macro level, the success of economic policy is generally<br />

gauged by reference to the achievement of key economic<br />

objectives, the most important of which is generally regarded<br />

as economic growth. Economic growth is measured by<br />

reference to the gross domestic product or gross national<br />

income of a nation which in simple terms is an indication<br />

of the wealth of a country. So, GDP or GNI is a measure<br />

of material wealth. If we can maximise this, and therefore<br />

average incomes, we maximise satisfaction. That’s the way<br />

traditional thinking goes.<br />

However, an American economist by the name of Richard<br />

Easterlin observed a puzzling phenomenon. Between 1946<br />

and 1970, the US witnessed remarkable economic expansion.<br />

And yet surveys failed to show any upsurge in happiness<br />

throughout this period of post-war boom. This trend, as you<br />

can see in the graph on the following page, has continued.<br />

Easterlin Paradox<br />

<strong>The</strong> Easterlin Paradox suggests that, once a basic level of<br />

income has been achieved (in the US in the 1960s that was<br />

considered to be $10,000) further increases do not increase<br />

happiness.<br />

This naturally raises the question of how ‘happiness’ is<br />

measured. Most economists and academics have shied<br />

away from the task of trying to measure what they see as<br />

unquantifiable. Fortunately, not all.<br />

Measuring happiness usually involves surveys asking people<br />

to report their own happiness levels. In attempting to do this,<br />

researchers have found that it becomes possible to measure<br />

the immeasurable. This is done by attributing measurable<br />

indices to generally agreed human desirables of happiness<br />

which affect broader welfare levels. <strong>The</strong>se generally agreed<br />

human desirables include levels of literacy, access to health<br />

care, political freedom, quantity of leisure, income levels<br />

and pollution levels. Although not a comprehensive list of<br />

happiness-deriving factors, it would be hard to argue that they<br />

do not significantly contribute to happiness.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!