24.02.2013 Views

TH`ESE Docteur de l'Université Paris-Dauphine Morgan HERVÉ ...

TH`ESE Docteur de l'Université Paris-Dauphine Morgan HERVÉ ...

TH`ESE Docteur de l'Université Paris-Dauphine Morgan HERVÉ ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

alargelyover-allocatedmarket. Theover-supplyofallowancescomparedto<br />

<strong>de</strong>mand triggered a strong price correction (phase I price <strong>de</strong>creased by 64%<br />

between April 24th and May 2nd). On May 15th, the official release by the<br />

EC of aggregated emissions for the year 2005 did little to dissipate doubts<br />

over too large an emissions cap for Phase I. In April 2007 and 2008, the process<br />

was smoother and more streamlined to prevent similar major impact<br />

on market prices. The fact that market participants had no expectations of<br />

scenario reversal during phase I also helped.<br />

As regards the use of Kyoto offsets in phase I of the European scheme,<br />

the European so-called ”linking directive” (which was adopted in 2004) permits<br />

the use of CDM offsets for compliance purpose. The use in phase I is<br />

theoretically unrestricted (i.e. compliance could be achieved by surren<strong>de</strong>ring<br />

solely Kyoto offsets). Nevertheless, this was prevented by (1) the long<br />

wait to have the ITL (Kyoto registry) operational (which only happened in<br />

late 2007), (2) the practical constraint to have the CITL (EU ETS registry)<br />

connected to the ITL. Initially scheduled for April 2007 (Alberola and <strong>de</strong><br />

Dominicis, 2006 [5]), the connection was <strong>de</strong>layed to October 2007 and then<br />

to December 2007 2 . Afterwards it was obvious that no CERs would be<br />

available for use in the EU ETS during phase I.<br />

Banking opportunities for unused allowances from phase I to II, initially<br />

very limited to France and Poland only, were ren<strong>de</strong>red unattractive by EC<br />

<strong>de</strong>cisions on several NAPs for phase II in October-November 2006. In short,<br />

any allowance carried forward to phase II would <strong>de</strong>crease the member state’s<br />

corresponding NAP II emissions cap. This triggered a price disconnect between<br />

phase I EUA price and that of phase II. The i<strong>de</strong>a behind this EC<br />

move was to prevent that phase I excess allowances would be carried forward<br />

towards phase II which would have un<strong>de</strong>rmined the constraint of the<br />

scheme.<br />

Figure 1.1 <strong>de</strong>picts the evolution of the price of the Phase I EUA over its<br />

lifetime. We see the price shock that occurred during the first ”true-up”<br />

event and the price disconnect that ensued. Nevertheless, apart from those<br />

major price shocks, the price of the EUA respon<strong>de</strong>d to market fundamentals,<br />

that is information regarding the supply of allowances (NAPs) and<br />

<strong>de</strong>mand for emissions (industrial activity, the relative price of gas and coal,<br />

temperature and precipitation data, etc.).<br />

2 According to the UNFCCC secretariat (reported in Tendances Carbone, 2007, [6]).<br />

12

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!