13.10.2014 Views

Estimating Distributions of Counterfactuals with an Application ... - UCL

Estimating Distributions of Counterfactuals with an Application ... - UCL

Estimating Distributions of Counterfactuals with an Application ... - UCL

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

398 CARNEIRO, HANSEN, AND HECKMAN<br />

TABLE 5<br />

FACTUAL AND COUNTERFACTUAL RETURNS FOR PERSONS WHO GO TO HIGH<br />

SCHOOL OR COLLEGE<br />

Gross Return High School 1 College 2<br />

College vs. high school (relative) + −0.0180 0.0126<br />

Std. error 0.1590 0.0178<br />

Net returns<br />

College vs. high school (relative) ++ −0.2398 0.3161<br />

Std. error 0.2502 0.3178<br />

College vs. high school (relative) +++ −0.4227 0.1892<br />

Std. error 0.5770 0.0144<br />

1 + E((V c /V h ) − 1 | choice = high school).<br />

2 + E((V c /V h ) − 1 | choice = college).<br />

1 ++ E((V c /V h − ln P)/(V h + ln P) | choice = high school).<br />

2 ++ E((V c /V h − ln P)/(V h + ln P) | choice = college).<br />

1 +++ E((V c /V h − ln P)/(V h ) | choice = high school).<br />

2 +++ E((V c /V h − ln P)/(V h ) | choice = college).<br />

NOTE: We make the distinction between the second <strong>an</strong>d third line in<br />

this table because in our framework we c<strong>an</strong>not separate nonmonetary<br />

costs from nonmonetary benefits <strong>of</strong> going to college, so we allocate<br />

ln P both ways.<br />

for psychic returns in <strong>an</strong>alyzing schooling choices. Among high school graduates,<br />

95.90% do not regret not going to college (measured in utils), but 85.26%<br />

regret the decision fin<strong>an</strong>cially. The marginal treatment effect has the same general<br />

shape when present values <strong>of</strong> earnings are used instead <strong>of</strong> gross utility (see<br />

Figure 8).<br />

Table 8 shows the probability <strong>of</strong> being in decile i <strong>of</strong> the college potential discounted<br />

earnings distribution conditional on being in decile j <strong>of</strong> the high school<br />

potential earnings distribution. (These are gross earnings.) It shows that neither<br />

<strong>an</strong> independence assumption across counterfactual outcomes, which is the Veil<br />

<strong>of</strong> Ignor<strong>an</strong>ce assumption used in applied welfare theory, (see, e.g., Sen, 1973)<br />

or in aggregate income inequality decompositions (DiNardo et al., 1996), nor a<br />

perfect r<strong>an</strong>king assumption, which is sometimes used to construct counterfactual<br />

joint distributions <strong>of</strong> outcomes (see, e.g., Heckm<strong>an</strong> et al., 1997 or Athey <strong>an</strong>d<br />

Imbens, 2002) are satisfied in the data. There is a strong positive dependence<br />

between potential outcomes in each counterfactual state, but there is no perfect<br />

dependence. There are subst<strong>an</strong>tial nonzero elements outside the diagonal.<br />

We get similar results for utility (discounted log earnings). See Table A13 at our<br />

website.<br />

We have already shown that there is a large dispersion in the distribution <strong>of</strong><br />

utilities, utility returns, earnings, <strong>an</strong>d earnings returns to college. However, this<br />

dispersion c<strong>an</strong> be due to heterogeneity that is known at the time the agent makes<br />

schooling decisions, or it c<strong>an</strong> be due to heterogeneity that is not predictable by the<br />

agent at that time. Figure 9 plots the densities <strong>of</strong> the unforecastable component<br />

<strong>of</strong> college gross utilities at the time college decisions are made for fixed X values,

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!