23.03.2015 Views

2008 - 2009 - Pinsent Masons Water Yearbook 2012 - 2013

2008 - 2009 - Pinsent Masons Water Yearbook 2012 - 2013

2008 - 2009 - Pinsent Masons Water Yearbook 2012 - 2013

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

PART 1: THE WORLD OF WATER <strong>2008</strong>-<strong>2009</strong><br />

By commoditising water, (treating it as an economic good and charging to recover the costs of<br />

service provision) funding can be made available for improving water services and its prudent<br />

use is encouraged. Private sector participation has been used by a number of countries in order<br />

to support attaining these objectives. The reasoning behind this has been access to new<br />

sources of funding along with the scope for improved efficiency of service delivery, linked to a<br />

series of performance targets. Between 1995 and 2005, World Bank supported PSP and<br />

Privatisation (in Chile) projects involved investment of USD12.8billion for water only contracts<br />

and USD26.8billion for water and sewerage contracts (World Bank 2005). There are a number<br />

of studies pointing towards efficiencies attained by the private sector, for example, research by<br />

Europe Economics (Europe Economics 2003) for Ofwat the England & Wales’ water regulator<br />

found that ‘privatised infrastructure companies have reduced unit operating expenditure by<br />

some 1.25 to 3.5% per annum more than might have been expected in the absence of a<br />

“privatisation effect” … greater efficiency following privatisation and the introduction of incentive<br />

regulation.’ Indeed, the report identified a scope for 1.5-3.0% per annum real base operating<br />

and capital maintenance expenditure and 2.0-4.0% per annum real base service operating<br />

expenditure from 2003-13, 14-24 years after the companies were originally privatised.<br />

PSP as a public health driver<br />

Another factor favouring PSP can be its impact on public health Galiani et al (2005) found that<br />

child mortality in Argentina fell by 5-7% during the 1990s in areas of Argentina where water<br />

services were run by the private sector compared with those where services were still run by the<br />

public sector, with a 24% fall in the poorest municipalities. It is evident that such an outcome will<br />

only take place when suitable mechanisms exist to ensure affordability and prevent<br />

disconnections for non-payment taking place.<br />

As noted by Budds & McGranahan (2003) the 1992 Dublin principles were influential in<br />

establishing a sympathetic climate towards PSP. Principle 4 states that ‘Managing water as an<br />

economic good is an important way of achieving efficient and equitable use, and of encouraging<br />

conservation and protection of water resources (WMO 1992).<br />

Concessions and local capacity building<br />

A number of cases have emerged where water concessions have been used to enable a<br />

country to develop its water manage capabilities with the aim of becoming a regional centre. In<br />

the Philippines, Manila <strong>Water</strong> having been listed on its local bourse is now being developed to<br />

participate in bulk water projects in the Philippines and water O&M contracts in Asia (Manila<br />

<strong>Water</strong>, 2006). Morocco’s ONEP seeks to develop the country’s experience with PSP so that the<br />

country can in turn become a regional leader in O&M and technical support projects in Western<br />

Africa (ONEP 2006). ONEP’s experience comes from its relationship with the LYDEC<br />

concession serving Casablanca and a number of other concessions, with LYDEC again having<br />

been listed on its local course.<br />

The need for attractive contract exit routes<br />

To date, four concessions which were awarded to international companies have seen a local<br />

initial public offering (IPO): EMOS (Chile, 2002-04), LYDEC (Morocco, 2005), Tallinna Vesi<br />

(2004) and Manila <strong>Water</strong> (Philippines, 2006), along with a mooted IPO for Maynilad <strong>Water</strong><br />

(Philippines, originally proposed for <strong>2008</strong>). An IPO was envisaged for Aguas Argentinas, before<br />

contract conditions deteriorated inexorably. A local IPO transfers at least part of the<br />

shareholding in the contract from international to local hands and devolves corporate activities<br />

towards the local level. They can also act as a material boost to local bourses because a well<br />

managed water utility is typically regarded as an attractive, low risk investment.<br />

Pro-poor policy implementation<br />

There is a considerable debate about the applicability of rising block tariffs (Casablanca and<br />

Malaysia,) versus the use of direct subsidies (Chile and Macao). Rising block tariffs work on the<br />

principle of low water usage per account having a low fixed cost per unit of water, which rises as<br />

the user consumes more. This is meant to mean that water for necessity is relatively cheap and<br />

49<br />

<strong>Pinsent</strong> <strong>Masons</strong> <strong>Water</strong> <strong>Yearbook</strong> <strong>2008</strong>-<strong>2009</strong>

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!