12.07.2015 Views

On the real effects of private equity investment: evidence from new ...

On the real effects of private equity investment: evidence from new ...

On the real effects of private equity investment: evidence from new ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Working Paper SeriesNo 1078 / august 2009<strong>On</strong> <strong>the</strong> Real Effects<strong>of</strong> Private EquityInvestmentEvidence <strong>from</strong>New Business Creationby Alexander Popovand Peter Roosenboom


WORKING PAPER SERIESNO 1078 / AUGUST 2009ON THE REAL EFFECTSOF PRIVATE EQUITYINVESTMENTEVIDENCE FROM NEWBUSINESS CREATION 1by Alexander Popov 2and Peter Roosenboom 3In 2009 all ECBpublicationsfeature a motiftaken <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong>€200 banknote.This paper can be downloaded without charge <strong>from</strong>http://www.ecb.europa.eu or <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> Social Science Research Networkelectronic library at http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=1436894.1 We thank Marco Da Rin, Philipp Hartmann, Ulrich Hege, Florian Heider, Josh Lerner, Simone Manganelli, Marina Martynova, Eric Nowak,Enrico Perotti, Jose Luis Peydro, Richard Rosen, Per Stromberg, Krishnamurthy Subramanian, and Gregory Udell, as well as seminarparticipants at <strong>the</strong> ECB, <strong>the</strong> 18 th IT&FA conference, <strong>the</strong> 2008 EFA meeting, <strong>the</strong> RICAFE2 third conference, <strong>the</strong> 11 th Symposiumon Finance, Banking and Insurance, <strong>the</strong> 2009 MFA meeting, and <strong>the</strong> Federal Reserve Bank <strong>of</strong> Chicago for valuable comments.A special thanks is extended to Luc Laeven for providing us with <strong>the</strong> Amadeus and D&B data. We also thank Lieven Baertand Kim Bonnema for outstanding research assistance. The opinions expressed herein are those <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> authorsand do not necessarily reflect those <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> European Central Bank or <strong>the</strong> Eurosystem.2 European Central Bank, Financial Research Division, Kaiserstrasse 29, D-60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany;tel. +4969 1344 8428, email: Alexander.Popov@ecb.europa.eu3 Department <strong>of</strong> Finance, Rotterdam School <strong>of</strong> Management (RSM), Erasmus University Rotterdam,Burgemeester Oudlaan 50, NL 3062PA Rotterdam, The Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands;tel: +3110 408 1255; e-mail: proosenboom@rsm.nl


© European Central Bank, 2009AddressKaiserstrasse 2960311 Frankfurt am Main, GermanyPostal addressPostfach 16 03 1960066 Frankfurt am Main, GermanyTelephone+49 69 1344 0Websitehttp://www.ecb.europa.euFax+49 69 1344 6000All rights reserved.Any reproduction, publication andreprint in <strong>the</strong> form <strong>of</strong> a differentpublication, whe<strong>the</strong>r printed orproduced electronically, in whole or inpart, is permitted only with <strong>the</strong> explicitwritten authorisation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> ECB or <strong>the</strong>author(s).The views expressed in this paper do notnecessarily reflect those <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> EuropeanCentral Bank.The statement <strong>of</strong> purpose for <strong>the</strong> ECBWorking Paper Series is available <strong>from</strong><strong>the</strong> ECB website, http://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/scientific/wps/date/html/index.en.htmlISSN 1725-2806 (online)


CONTENTSAbstract 4Non-technical summary 51 Introduction 72 Data 102.1 EVCA yearbooks 102.2 Amadeus database 122.3 US industry-level entry data 142.4 Sample construction 153 Empirical methodology 174 Results 184.1 Private <strong>equity</strong> and entry: main results 184.2 Private <strong>equity</strong> and entry: contemporaneousvs. long-term effect 204.3 Alternative measures <strong>of</strong> propensity to entry 214.4 Private <strong>equity</strong> and access to finance 234.5 Endogeneity and selection 254.6 Robustness 285 Conclusion 30References 33Tables 37Appendix 46European Central Bank Working Paper Series 49ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 20093


AbstractUsing a comprehensive database <strong>of</strong> European firms, we study how <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong>affects <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> firm entry. We find that <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> benefits <strong>new</strong>business incorporation, especially in industries with naturally higher entry rates andR&D intensity. A two standard deviation increase in <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> explainsas much as 5.5% <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> variation in entry between high-entry and low-entry industries.We address endogeneity by exploiting data on laws that regulate <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong><strong>investment</strong>s by pension funds. Our results hold when we correct for barriers to entry,general access to credit, protection <strong>of</strong> intellectual property, and labor regulations.Keywords: <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong>, venture capital, firm entryJEL Classification: G24, L26, M134ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


Non-technical summaryRecent years have spurred interest in <strong>the</strong> role <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> in <strong>the</strong>financing <strong>of</strong> small <strong>new</strong> firms. While banks are <strong>of</strong>ten reluctant to finance such firmsbecause <strong>of</strong> high uncertainty, information asymmetry, and agency costs, <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong>investors are specialized to overcome <strong>the</strong>se problems through <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> stagedfinancing, <strong>private</strong> contracting and active monitoring. These unique features make <strong>the</strong>mmore likely to finance early stage and technology companies than banks. This paperinvestigates <strong>the</strong> previously unexplored effect that <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>s have on<strong>new</strong> business creation in Europe. This question is highly relevant to policy makersgiven that <strong>the</strong>y <strong>of</strong>ten perceive venture capital as an important contributor to <strong>the</strong> risingleadership <strong>of</strong> US firms in high technology industries. Hoping to rival this success, <strong>the</strong>European Union stimulates venture capital <strong>investment</strong> in an attempt to make Europe ahotbed for entrepreneurship.Our study contributes to <strong>the</strong> literature in two main ways. First, although <strong>the</strong>re is alarge body <strong>of</strong> empirical literature looking at <strong>the</strong> effect <strong>of</strong> finance on firm entry, <strong>the</strong> vastmajority <strong>of</strong> it has studied <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> banks on business formation. While <strong>the</strong> effect<strong>of</strong> banking sector development and restructuring on small business formation iscertainly important, <strong>the</strong> effect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>, especially start-up finance,is probably equally important and largely understudied. Secondly, while academicinterest in venture capital has been growing steadily, <strong>the</strong>re is still a remarkably limitedresearch on <strong>the</strong> <strong>effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> and venture capital on <strong>the</strong> <strong>real</strong> economy.Several recent studies have argued that venture capital can be credited with stimulatinginnovation, spurring entrepreneurial spawning, and enhancing productivity growth.However, most <strong>of</strong> this interest has focused on US <strong>evidence</strong>. This paper thus provides<strong>the</strong> first cross-country cross-industry study <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> effect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> on<strong>new</strong> business creation in Europe, using data <strong>from</strong> Amadeus on entry and data <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong>European Venture Capital Association on firm creation. The data also enables us todistinguish between stages and investor types and to include <strong>the</strong> <strong>effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> later stage<strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong>, like buyout finance.We first study if <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>, aggregated as well as by stagedistribution, affects <strong>the</strong> extent <strong>of</strong> incorporation, using data on 1998-1999 and on 2006-2007. We aim at identification by following a difference-in-differences methodologybased on cross-country cross-industry interaction <strong>effects</strong>. This approach allows us tobypass <strong>the</strong> omitted variables problem that has plagued traditional research bycontrolling for unobservable characteristics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> industries <strong>of</strong> interest as well as <strong>the</strong>business environment in <strong>the</strong> respective country. We find that <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> incorporationin naturally high-entry and R&D-intensive industries is significantly higher incountries with a larger volume <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> relative to GDP, and this isparticularly true for smaller firms.We conduct extensive robustness tests to correct for endogeneity and for <strong>the</strong> classicindustry- and country-level determinants <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> business creation suggested by <strong>the</strong>literature. While previous studies have show that regulations <strong>the</strong> firm needs to meet inorder to be registered as a limited liability company explain a large portion <strong>of</strong> thisvariation, we show that <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> finance is also a very important determinant <strong>of</strong>firm entry when entry barriers are accounted for. Fur<strong>the</strong>r accounting for access t<strong>of</strong>inance in general and for o<strong>the</strong>r regulatory and legal characteristics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> businessECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 20095


environment leaves <strong>the</strong> main results unchanged. Finally, we account for <strong>the</strong> possibilitythat <strong>the</strong>se results are driven by reverse causality. We use <strong>the</strong> variation in prudentialregulation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>investment</strong> behavior <strong>of</strong> pension funds as an instrument for <strong>the</strong> supply<strong>of</strong> PE funds. Our results prove robust to this IV procedure.This paper serves to shed light on <strong>the</strong> contribution <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> t<strong>of</strong>irm creation in Europe. We show that VC’s contribution to creative destruction in <strong>the</strong>European context is very tangible, and has an important role alongside regulatory, tax,and labor market reforms in promoting a dynamic EU economy. In that context, avariety <strong>of</strong> policy initiatives, undertaken in recent years and aimed at promoting anactive venture capital industry, are expected to stimulate fur<strong>the</strong>r Europe’s younginnovative firms.6ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


1 IntroductionIt is generally accepted that access to credit is an important determinant <strong>of</strong> …rm entry andgrowth (Rajan and Zingales (1998)). However, banks are <strong>of</strong>ten reluctant to …nance small<strong>new</strong> …rms because <strong>of</strong> high uncertainty, information asymmetry, and agency costs (Beck et al.(2005)). Private <strong>equity</strong> investors are specialized to overcome <strong>the</strong>se problems through <strong>the</strong> use<strong>of</strong> staged …nancing, <strong>private</strong> contracting, and active monitoring (Hellmann (1998); Gompersand Lerner (1999, 2001a); Kaplan and Stromberg (2001)) and are <strong>the</strong>refore more likely to…nance early stage and technology companies than banks.In this paper, we investigate<strong>the</strong> previously unexplored e¤ect that <strong>the</strong>se <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>s have on <strong>new</strong> businesscreation in Europe. This question is highly relevant to policy makers given that <strong>the</strong>y <strong>of</strong>tenperceive venture capital as an important contributor to <strong>the</strong> rising leadership <strong>of</strong> US …rmsin high technology industries (Gompers and Lerner (2001b)). Hoping to rival this success,<strong>the</strong> European Union stimulates venture capital <strong>investment</strong> in an attempt to make Europea hotbed for entrepreneurship (Aernoudt (1999); Gilson (2003)). This paper puts <strong>the</strong> ideathat venture capital fosters <strong>new</strong> business creation to <strong>the</strong> test.Our study makes two key contributions to <strong>the</strong> literature. First, although <strong>the</strong>re is a largebody <strong>of</strong> empirical literature looking at <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> …nance on …rm entry, <strong>the</strong> vast majority<strong>of</strong> it has studied <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> developments in <strong>the</strong> banking sector on business formation,with mixed results. Petersen and Rajan (1995) show that …nancial liberalization hurts smallyoung companies because creditors in competitive credit markets …nd it more di¢ cult tointernalize <strong>the</strong> bene…ts <strong>of</strong> assisting those …rms. However, Black and Strahan (2002) …nd<strong>evidence</strong> that <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> incorporation increases as a result <strong>of</strong> banking deregulation, and ina related paper Cetorelli and Strahan (2006) use a measure <strong>of</strong> bank deregulation to show howaverage …rm size in an industry decreases with bank competition, arguably due to increasedentry rates. Regarding general credit market development, Aghion et al. (2007) …nd thatdeeper and more developed banking sectors are associated with higher entry <strong>of</strong> small …rmsin sectors which are more dependent on external …nance. While <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> banking sectorECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 20097


development and restructuring on small business formation is certainly important, <strong>the</strong> e¤ect<strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>, especially start-up …nance, is probably equally important andlargely understudied. This paper aims to …ll this gap.The second contribution is that we add to a remarkably limited research on <strong>the</strong> e¤ects<strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> on <strong>the</strong> <strong>real</strong> economy. Kortum and Lerner (2000) show that venture capital<strong>investment</strong> in <strong>the</strong> United States is associated with more innovation as measured by patentcounts and patent citations. Gompers et al. (2005) examine <strong>the</strong> propensity <strong>of</strong> publicly traded…rms to create <strong>new</strong> venture backed …rms. They …nd that younger public …rms located inmain hubs <strong>of</strong> venture capital activity are <strong>the</strong> most likely to create <strong>new</strong> ventures. Tang andChyi (2008) …nd that venture capital <strong>investment</strong> enhances productivity growth. Regarding<strong>new</strong> business formation, we are only aware <strong>of</strong> one study that examines <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> venturecapital at <strong>the</strong> regional level in <strong>the</strong> U.S. Mollica and Zingales (2007) report that …rm entryand innovation increase in U.S. regions that attract more venture capital. Our paper addsto this literature by providing <strong>the</strong> …rst comprehensive cross-country study examining <strong>the</strong>e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> on …rm entry in Europe. Moreover, our European data enables usto distinguish between stages and investor types and does not focus on <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> venturecapital alone but also includes <strong>the</strong> e¤ects <strong>of</strong> later stage <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong>, like buyout …nance.There are two main mechanisms suggested by <strong>the</strong> literature via which <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> ingeneral and venture capital in particular should lead to higher rates <strong>of</strong> business incorporation.First, nascent entrepreneurs may recognize <strong>the</strong> need for capital in <strong>the</strong> future andonly establish …rms when <strong>the</strong>y have reasonably high expectations <strong>of</strong> obtaining such funding.This implies that not just start-up …nance, but later …nancing stages, like expansion …nance,should matter too for …rm entry. Second, …rms may be engaged in "entrepreneurial spawning",that is, <strong>the</strong> propensity <strong>of</strong> former employees <strong>of</strong> publicly traded …rms to start <strong>the</strong>ir owncompanies. There are several competing explanations for that. Christensen (1997) has arguedthat large, established …rms are incapable <strong>of</strong> adopting radical <strong>new</strong> technologies becauseit would disrupt <strong>the</strong>ir established way <strong>of</strong> organizing business. It is also possible that <strong>the</strong>se…rms cannot evaluate <strong>new</strong> disruptive technologies as <strong>the</strong>y fall outside <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir line <strong>of</strong> business8ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


(Stein (2002)). Firms sometimes choose to not adopt <strong>new</strong> technologies although <strong>the</strong>y can,because this would lead to a decline in <strong>the</strong> productivity <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir existing businesses (Schoar(2002)). In all <strong>of</strong> those cases, venture capital would be <strong>the</strong> obvious …nancing tool for <strong>the</strong><strong>new</strong> …rms born out <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se technologies. Finally, Gompers et al. (2005) …nd <strong>evidence</strong> thatentrepreneurial spawning is related to <strong>the</strong> fact that employees <strong>of</strong> established …rms are trainedand conditioned to be entrepreneurs by being exposed to <strong>the</strong> entrepreneurial process and byworking in a network <strong>of</strong> entrepreneurs and venture capitalists. It needs to be emphasizedthat in this paper we only examine empirically <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> on <strong>new</strong> businesscreation, ra<strong>the</strong>r than studying <strong>the</strong> exact channels via which this e¤ect works.The literature has distinguished entry into an industry <strong>from</strong> …rm creation.The …rstaccounts for <strong>the</strong> migration <strong>of</strong> …rms across industries, while <strong>the</strong> second emphasizes pureentrepreneurship (de novo …rms). We focus on <strong>the</strong> second approach and de…ne entry as <strong>the</strong>incorporation <strong>of</strong> a previously nonexistent …rm in <strong>the</strong> respective industry and country. Ourdata comes <strong>from</strong> Amadeus, a comprehensive database <strong>of</strong> corporations across a number <strong>of</strong>developed and transition countries in Europe, in combination with country-level data on<strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> and venture capital <strong>investment</strong> in Europe <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> European Venture CapitalAssociation (EVCA) yearbooks.We …rst study if <strong>the</strong> volume <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>, aggregated as well as by stagedistribution, a¤ects <strong>the</strong> extent <strong>of</strong> incorporation, using data on 1998-1999. We aim at identi-…cation by following <strong>the</strong> di¤erence-in-di¤erences methodology …rst introduced by Rajan andZingales (1998) and focus on cross-country cross-industry interaction e¤ects. In essence, westudy whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> fraction <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> incorporation is higher in an industry with higher "natural"entry rates when <strong>the</strong>re is more <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> ‡owing into <strong>the</strong> country. This approachallows us to bypass <strong>the</strong> omitted variables problem that has plagued traditional research bycontrolling for unobservable characteristics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> industries <strong>of</strong> interest as well as <strong>the</strong> businessenvironment in <strong>the</strong> respective country. We …nd that <strong>the</strong> rate <strong>of</strong> incorporation in naturallyhigh-entry industries is signi…cantly higher in countries with a larger volume <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong><strong>investment</strong> relative to GDP, and this is particularly true for smaller …rms. The same appliesECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 20099


to industries which are more R&D intensive.We also look at staging and investor type, distinguishing between VC and buyouts, aswell as between independent, captive, semi-captive, and public funds.We …nd that <strong>the</strong>e¤ect <strong>of</strong> venture capital and start-up …nance is comparable to <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> total <strong>private</strong><strong>equity</strong> …nance, but that it was stronger in 2006-2007 than it was in 1998-1999. We also …ndthat while cross-country di¤erences in <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> by independent funds isboth economically and statistically signi…cant, <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> captive and public funds on <strong>new</strong>business entry is at best non-existent. While Klapper et al. (2006) show that regulations<strong>the</strong> …rm needs to meet in order to be registered as a limited liability company explain alarge portion <strong>of</strong> this variation, we show that <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> …nance is still a very importantdeterminant <strong>of</strong> …rm entry when entry barriers are accounted for.In a …ne-tuning <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> basic approach, we account for <strong>the</strong> possibility that <strong>the</strong>se results aredriven by reverse causality, that PE is a proxy for o<strong>the</strong>r types <strong>of</strong> …nancial development, andthat it is a proxy for o<strong>the</strong>r characteristics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> business environment. We use <strong>the</strong> variationin prudential regulation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>investment</strong> behavior <strong>of</strong> pension funds as an instrument for <strong>the</strong>supply <strong>of</strong> PE funds. Our results are robust to this IV procedure, as well as to accounting foraccess to …nance in general and for o<strong>the</strong>r regulatory and legal characteristics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> businessenvironment.The paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2 we summarize <strong>the</strong> data. Section 3 describes<strong>the</strong> empirical methodology. Section 4 presents <strong>the</strong> empirical results. Section 5 concludeswith <strong>the</strong> main …ndings <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> paper.2 Data2.1 EVCA yearbooksThis paper uses data <strong>from</strong> two main sources: on <strong>new</strong> business formation <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> …rmlevelAmadeus database, and on <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> EVCA yearbooks. TheEVCA yearbooks compile annual data on <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> funds raised, funds allotted to10 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


venture capital, and <strong>the</strong> actual allocation <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>. We use <strong>the</strong> data for<strong>the</strong> 1998-1999 period, and in robustness tests for <strong>the</strong> 2006-2007 period.Three caveats are in place. First, while <strong>the</strong> EVCA yearbooks try to be exhaustive interms <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> European countries <strong>the</strong>y cover, in some cases <strong>the</strong>y discontinue <strong>the</strong>ir reporting(e.g. Iceland after 2001). In o<strong>the</strong>rs - notably, <strong>the</strong> <strong>new</strong> EU members <strong>from</strong> Central Europe(Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and Slovakia) - EVCA only started reporting PE activityin 1998.Finally, for <strong>the</strong> Baltic and South-East European EU members EVCA has onlyrun pilot projects limited in duration (Bulgaria in 2003 and 2004, Latvia in 2001, Romania2000-2004, and Slovenia in 2003), or reported <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> jointly for severalcountries (Croatia and Slovenia, as well as Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania in 2005). Understandably,in cases when <strong>the</strong>re were too few years included, or when it was judged impossibleto disaggregate reliably <strong>the</strong> information on <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong>, <strong>the</strong> data was not used. Apart <strong>from</strong>current EU members, <strong>the</strong> EVCA yearbooks also include information on Iceland, Norway, andSwitzerland.The second caveat deals with <strong>the</strong> reporting <strong>of</strong> <strong>investment</strong> by US <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> houses. Ifa deal has been backed by both a US and a European <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> house, <strong>the</strong> deal is splitinto two parts. The part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>investment</strong> coming <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> European <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> …rm isallocated to <strong>the</strong> respective European country, and <strong>the</strong> part <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>investment</strong> coming <strong>from</strong><strong>the</strong> US <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> …rm is allocated to <strong>the</strong> US. However, if <strong>the</strong> US PE …rm has no o¢ cein Europe, <strong>the</strong>n its <strong>investment</strong> is not included in <strong>the</strong> EVCA …gures. In addition, concerningUS <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> houses investing in Europe, only <strong>investment</strong>s made by those having o¢ cesin Europe are taken into consideration. This would imply that if a US PE …rm, which hasno o¢ ce in Europe, invests in a European company, <strong>the</strong> <strong>investment</strong> would not be includedin <strong>the</strong> EVCA …gures. While <strong>the</strong> vast majority <strong>of</strong> US <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> houses operate through<strong>the</strong>ir European o¢ ces, it is still <strong>the</strong> case that <strong>the</strong> EVCA data is by construction incomplete.Finally, while EVCA o¤ers disaggregated data on <strong>the</strong> allocation <strong>of</strong> actual <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong><strong>investment</strong> across industries, it uses its own classi…cation <strong>of</strong> 17 groups <strong>of</strong> industries, and itonly reports <strong>the</strong> composition <strong>of</strong> <strong>investment</strong> by country <strong>of</strong> management ra<strong>the</strong>r than countryECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200911


<strong>of</strong> destination.We …rst recalculated <strong>investment</strong> by industry and country <strong>of</strong> destinationassuming <strong>the</strong> same pattern applies across industries as across aggregate volumes 1 . Next, weused <strong>the</strong> special translation key provided by <strong>the</strong> EVCA to translate <strong>the</strong> EVCA industriesinto 2-digit NACE rev. 2 and <strong>the</strong>n into 2-digit NACE rev. 1.1 industries in order to be ableto match <strong>the</strong>m to <strong>the</strong> Amadeus database. In some cases <strong>the</strong> NACE two-digit industries fallunder two or more di¤erent EVCA industries at <strong>the</strong> same time, and this double countingwas resolved by assigning <strong>the</strong> 2-digit NACE industry to only one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> two or more EVCAindustries interchangeably or dropping those altoge<strong>the</strong>r. The …nal results reported are robustto using di¤erent variants <strong>of</strong> this industry translation key.Table 1 summarizes <strong>the</strong> information on total actual <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> normalizedby GDP, both for <strong>the</strong> 1998-1999 and <strong>the</strong> 2006-2007 period.It gives a clear idea <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>volatility <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> both in aggregate and in relative terms. For example,total <strong>investment</strong> has decreased by a magnitude <strong>of</strong> 2 in <strong>the</strong> Czech Republic (<strong>from</strong> 0.042 to0.023) and by a magnitude <strong>of</strong> 6.5 in Greece (<strong>from</strong> 0.027 to 0.004), but it has almost tripledin <strong>the</strong> UK (<strong>from</strong> 0.465 to 1.215), quadrupled in Sweden (<strong>from</strong> 0.2 to 0.82) and increased bya magnitude <strong>of</strong> 12 in Denmark (<strong>from</strong> 0.029 to 0.353). It is important to note that our resultsare robust to <strong>the</strong>se country-level developments.2.2 Amadeus databaseThe …rm-level data come <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> Amadeus database.Amadeus is a commercial pan-European database provided by Bureau van Dijk, containing …nancial information on over10 million public and <strong>private</strong> companies in 38 European countries. It combines data <strong>from</strong>over 30 specialist regional information providers (IPs). The data is created by collectingstandardised annual accounts (for up to 10 years), consolidated and unconsolidated, for approximately9 million companies throughout Europe, including Central, Eastern, and South-1 EVCA reports aggregate PE <strong>investment</strong> by country <strong>of</strong> management and country <strong>of</strong> destination and PE<strong>investment</strong> in each industry by country <strong>of</strong> management only. We recalculate industry PE <strong>investment</strong> bycountry <strong>of</strong> destination assuming that <strong>the</strong> ratio between total and per-industry <strong>investment</strong> is <strong>the</strong> same forcountry <strong>of</strong> management and for country <strong>of</strong> destination. For <strong>the</strong> 2006-2007 wave, however, <strong>the</strong> disaggregateddata come by country <strong>of</strong> destination.12 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


Eastern Europe. The database contains detailed …rm-level accounting data for a number<strong>of</strong> …nancial ratios, activities, and ownership. While initially received <strong>from</strong> over 50 di¤erentvendors across Europe, <strong>the</strong> data is <strong>the</strong>n transformed into a single format enabling comparisonacross countries. The focus <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Amadeus database is on …nancial information, like…rm pro…t, revenue, assets, debt, and value added. In addition to that, Amadeus provides…rm-level information on year <strong>of</strong> incorporation and employment. We use <strong>the</strong> former to calculate<strong>the</strong> age <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> …rm, hence <strong>the</strong> share <strong>of</strong> "<strong>new</strong>" …rms in each industry-country-year. Thevariable we create is referred to as Entry ij , and it denotes <strong>the</strong> share <strong>of</strong> …rms less than 2-yearsold in country i in industry j, calculated separately for 1998-1999 in <strong>the</strong> main regressions,and for 2006-2007 in <strong>the</strong> robustness tests. We only count <strong>the</strong> …rms that are at least 1 fullyear <strong>of</strong> age to reduce measurement error.Finally, Amadeus uses <strong>the</strong> 3-digit NACE industry classi…cation standard, which we aggregateat <strong>the</strong> 2-digit level in order to have a su¢ cient number <strong>of</strong> …rms in each industry foreach country. Columns 2 and 4 <strong>of</strong> Table 2 summarize our main Amadeus data, aggregatedat <strong>the</strong> country level, for <strong>the</strong> two time periods <strong>of</strong> interest.<strong>On</strong>e main concern is that <strong>the</strong> years 1998-1999 chosen for <strong>the</strong> main empirical exercisesmay not be "steady state" in terms <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> business incorporation as <strong>the</strong>y were too closeto <strong>the</strong> peak <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> dot-com bubble. Similar concerns apply to <strong>the</strong> period 2006-2007 whichcoincided with <strong>the</strong> peak <strong>of</strong> ano<strong>the</strong>r business cycle. For that reason, we calculated averageentry rates over <strong>the</strong> 1995-2007 period, using data on entry rates <strong>from</strong> Eurostat, and <strong>the</strong>ncompared <strong>the</strong> long-term averages to data for 1998-1999 and 2006-2007, again <strong>from</strong> Eurostat.Columns 3 and 5 <strong>of</strong> Table 2 presents <strong>the</strong> deviation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> latter <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> long-term averagesin percentage terms, for 1998-1999 and 2006-2007, respectively. The average deviation for<strong>the</strong> 1998-1999 sample is 5.9%, and only in three <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> countries in <strong>the</strong> sample is it higherthan 7%. This gives us con…dence that <strong>the</strong> years 1998-1999 are pretty much "steady state"in terms <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> business creation. The same applies to <strong>the</strong> second period chosen. 22 The little overall variation in entry rates is signi…ed by <strong>the</strong> fact that even <strong>the</strong> years 2000 and 2001, whichcoincided with <strong>the</strong> peak <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> internet bubble, show an average deviation <strong>of</strong> only 8.4% <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> samplelong-term average.ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200913


2.3 US industry-level entry dataAs a benchmark for <strong>new</strong> business incorporation into an industry, we use data on …rm entryin <strong>the</strong> respective NACE rev. 1.1 2-digit industry in <strong>the</strong> US, <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> Dun and Bradstreetdatabase <strong>of</strong> over 7 million corporations over <strong>the</strong> period 1998-1999.The methodology <strong>of</strong>using US industry characteristics as a benchmark in cross-country cross-industry studieswas …rst introduced by Rajan and Zingales (1998), who argued that <strong>the</strong> composition <strong>of</strong>US industries in terms <strong>of</strong> external …nance usage can be viewed as <strong>the</strong> industries’"natural"or "technological" composition, because US …nancial markets are relatively friction-free,compared with o<strong>the</strong>r …nancial markets around <strong>the</strong> world, including most industrial countries.The methodology has been used, among o<strong>the</strong>rs, by Beck et al.(2008) to calculate <strong>the</strong>"natural" share <strong>of</strong> small …rms in an industry, by Claessens and Laeven (2003) to calculate<strong>the</strong> industry’s "natural" usage <strong>of</strong> intangibles, and most recently by Klapper et al. (2006) tocalculate <strong>the</strong> "natural" rate <strong>of</strong> business incorporation, which we use in this paper.It needs to be pointed out that proxying <strong>the</strong> "natural" rate <strong>of</strong> industry entry by entryin <strong>the</strong> respective industry in <strong>the</strong> US is somewhat arbitrary. It relies on <strong>the</strong> assumption thatbureaucratic barriers to entry are lower <strong>the</strong>re than in any country in Europe, and that <strong>the</strong>cost <strong>of</strong> …nancial intermediation and start-up …nancing is su¢ ciently lower in <strong>the</strong> US than inEurope as a whole. This technique does not argue that industries in <strong>the</strong> US have achieved<strong>the</strong> …rst best in terms <strong>of</strong> entry, but that <strong>the</strong> …nancial and regulatory environment is relativelymore conducive to entry than <strong>the</strong> countries in our sample. For example, while entry costs in<strong>the</strong> US are around 0.5% <strong>of</strong> per capita GNP, in our sample <strong>of</strong> European countries <strong>the</strong>y areon average around 20%; and while venture capital <strong>investment</strong> in <strong>the</strong> US in 1998-1999 wasabout 0.2% <strong>of</strong> GDP, it stood at 0.1% <strong>of</strong> GDP in <strong>the</strong> UK, 0.05% <strong>of</strong> GDP in France and 0.02%<strong>of</strong> GDP in Germany, with <strong>the</strong>se three countries receiving <strong>the</strong> lion share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong><strong>investment</strong> in Europe. Certainly, <strong>the</strong> entry costs in <strong>the</strong> US are non-zero, and it is impossibleto know if <strong>the</strong> optimal amount <strong>of</strong> venture capital <strong>investment</strong> is not much larger than 0.2%<strong>of</strong> GDP, but what matters is that <strong>the</strong>se characteristics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> US business environment aresuperior than in <strong>the</strong> countries in our sample.For robustness purposes, however, similar14 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


to Claessens and Laeven (2003), we replace <strong>the</strong> US industry characteristics with industrycharacteristics <strong>from</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r regions in some speci…cations.In Table 3, we compare <strong>the</strong> industry entry rates in <strong>the</strong> US to an aggregated measure<strong>of</strong> European entry <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> Amadeus-EVCA dataset. In more than half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> industries,entry in <strong>the</strong> US is at least marginally higher than in Europe as a whole.2.4 Sample constructionWe employ <strong>the</strong> same sample selection procedure to <strong>the</strong> Amadeus dataset as Klapper et al.(2006) to see whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> survives <strong>the</strong> inclusion <strong>of</strong> barriersto entry in a sample where <strong>the</strong>se barriers were already shown to be signi…cant. We initiallyuse <strong>the</strong> 2001 edition <strong>of</strong> Amadeus and limit <strong>the</strong> sample to <strong>the</strong> years 1998 and 1999. The year2000 is not used due to some incompleteness <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> information in each Amadeus editionconcerning <strong>the</strong> previous year. The years prior to 1998 are not used due to <strong>the</strong> well-knownsurvivorship problems <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Amadeus database: when a …rm ceases existing, Amadeus keepsa record <strong>of</strong> it for 4 years, and <strong>the</strong>n takes it out <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> database. Consequently, while eachyearly addition <strong>of</strong> Amadeus contains data for more than 4 years back, <strong>the</strong> sample <strong>of</strong> …rmsone will …nd reported for <strong>the</strong> time-period 4 years and more prior to <strong>the</strong> year <strong>of</strong> issuing, willnot include many …rms who existed in that year, but exited <strong>the</strong> market after that. Using <strong>the</strong>data indiscriminately will <strong>the</strong>refore induce survivorship bias and misrepresent <strong>the</strong> volume <strong>of</strong>entry, and so we focus our attention to <strong>the</strong> years 2 and 3 prior to <strong>the</strong> year <strong>the</strong> database wasissued. In later robustness tests, in which we use <strong>the</strong> 2008 edition <strong>of</strong> Amadeus, we similarlyfocus our attention on <strong>the</strong> sample <strong>of</strong> …rms in 2006-2007.Firms in <strong>the</strong> …nal dataset we use are also required to have basic accounting informationon <strong>the</strong> variables we are interested in (year <strong>of</strong> incorporation, employment, assets, etc.). Thisapproach excludes phantom …rms created for tax purposes. We drop …rms that report onlyconsolidated statements in order to avoid double-counting …rms and subsidiaries abroad.We exclude industries where <strong>the</strong> activities are country-speci…c, namely agriculture, forestry,…shing, and mining.We also exclude utilities and post and telecommunications, whichECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200915


tend to be heavily regulated and/or state-owned, and <strong>the</strong> …nancial services sector because,arguably, …nancial …rms are subject to speci…c regulations which do not apply for o<strong>the</strong>r …rms(for example, initial capital requirements). Finally, we exclude <strong>the</strong> public sector, education,<strong>the</strong> social sector, <strong>private</strong> households, and activities that cannot be classi…ed. We are leftwith 37 NACE industries.At <strong>the</strong> country level, we exclude <strong>the</strong> East European and South-East European countriesdue to insu¢ cient availability <strong>of</strong> data on <strong>investment</strong> by <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong>, although <strong>the</strong>secountries are covered by Amadeus. The same applies to Luxembourg. Likewise, we excludeSwitzerland, which has comprehensive coverage on <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>, but itsAmadeus coverage is compromised by <strong>the</strong> fact that small …rms are not required to …le. Finally,we use Eurostat to con…rm to what extent Amadeus is representative <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> …rm sizedistribution in <strong>the</strong> respective country. We <strong>the</strong>n exclude Iceland, Ireland, and Portugal, forwhich <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> employment in …rms with more than 250 employees in Amadeus to employmentin …rms with more than 250 employees in Eurostat is less than 0.5, and/or forwhich <strong>the</strong> di¤erence between <strong>the</strong> share <strong>of</strong> small …rms (10-50 employees) in Amadeus and inEurostat is more than 0.25. The sample thus reached represents <strong>the</strong> best match <strong>of</strong> Amadeusand EVCA data that is possible to construct while avoiding limited coverage, insu¢ cientobservations and country-speci…c industry scope and legal requirements problems. The …nalsample consists <strong>of</strong> 2,788,680 …rms for 1998-1999 in 16 countries: Austria, Belgium, Czech Republic,Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Italy, Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands, Norway,Poland, Spain, Sweden, and UK. Firm-level information is <strong>the</strong>n aggregated at <strong>the</strong> industrylevel and matched with <strong>the</strong> EVCA data to create a dataset consisting <strong>of</strong> 571 2-digit NACErev. 1.1 industry-country data points (37 industries in 16 countries, with 21 data pointsmissing). Due to our sample selection method, we do not use 3 <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 17 EVCA industries(o<strong>the</strong>r electronics, …nancial services, and agriculture).Table 4 gives <strong>the</strong> conversion key <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> 2-digit NACE rev 1.1 industries into <strong>the</strong> EVCAindustries used in robustness regressions. Note that out <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 37 NACE rev. 1.1 industries,12 fall exclusively under 1 EVCA class, for 10 more than 70% <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> 3-digit subclasses16 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


fall under 1 EVCA class, and for 15 industries <strong>the</strong>re is a clear "winner" (majority <strong>of</strong> 3-digitclasses), but still <strong>the</strong> possibility <strong>of</strong> a measurement error remains. In <strong>the</strong>se empirical exercises,we use di¤erent ways <strong>of</strong> matching <strong>the</strong> industries in <strong>the</strong> third group to EVCA classes, and wealso perform <strong>the</strong> analysis after excluding <strong>the</strong>m altoge<strong>the</strong>r. The reported results are robustto this method.Our sample selection procedures leaves us with <strong>the</strong> same sample as in Klapper et al.(2006) in terms <strong>of</strong> business entry. This allows us to test <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> onbusiness entry accounting for <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> entry barriers in a sample in which <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong>entry barriers has already been documented.3 Empirical methodologyWe use a cross-industry cross-country regression as our main empirical model:Entry ij = 0 + 1 (EV CA i(k) Entry US ) + 2 (X i Z j ) + 3 D i + 4 D j + " ij (1)where Entry ij denotes <strong>the</strong> share <strong>of</strong> …rms less than 2-years old in country i in industry j;EV CA (i)k denotes <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> in country i, or in EVCA industry class k incountry i, normalized by <strong>the</strong> country’s GDP and measured as total volume or disaggregatedby stage; Entry US denotes <strong>the</strong> "natural" industry entry rate, as measured using US data;X i is a vector <strong>of</strong> country characteristics; Z j is a vector <strong>of</strong> industry characteristics 3 ; D i is amatrix <strong>of</strong> country dummies; D j is a matrix <strong>of</strong> industry dummies; and " ij is <strong>the</strong> idiosyncraticerror.This speci…cation has become very popular in <strong>the</strong> …nance and growth literature because italleviates <strong>the</strong> small sample problem <strong>of</strong> cross-country regressions, and it allows for eliminating<strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> unobservables characteristics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> business environment by including countrydummies. Industry indicator variables are also included to account for unobservable industry-3 We use j to denote NACE Rev. 1.1 industry class and k to denote EVCA industry class as <strong>the</strong>y are notidentical, but <strong>the</strong>y can be matched.ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200917


speci…c e¤ects. Critically, we are interested in <strong>the</strong> magnitude and statistical signi…cance <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> estimate <strong>of</strong> 1 . This interaction term measures <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> on<strong>new</strong> business incorporation accounting for <strong>the</strong> industry’s "technological" entry rate. Private<strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> is expected to make it easier for …rms to enter <strong>the</strong> market, and that e¤ectis expected to be larger in industries in which <strong>the</strong>re are high "natural" entry rates. Hence,we expect <strong>the</strong> sign <strong>of</strong> 1 to be positive. Note that we are not able to identify <strong>the</strong> direct e¤ect<strong>of</strong> PE <strong>investment</strong> and <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> industry’s "natural" entry rate, as those are fully captured by<strong>the</strong> two sets <strong>of</strong> …xed e¤ects.It has become regular practice in <strong>the</strong> literature to account for potential convergence e¤ects(that is, <strong>the</strong> fact <strong>the</strong> larger sectors may have naturally lower entry rates) by controlling for<strong>the</strong> industry share (see, for example, Cetorelli and Strahan (2006) and Beck et al. (2008)).We proxy this by <strong>the</strong> fraction <strong>of</strong> industry sales out <strong>of</strong> total sales in <strong>the</strong> country as reportedin <strong>the</strong> Amadeus database.Finally, in <strong>the</strong> main empirical exercise, we use average data for 1998-1999. Later, forrobustness purposes, we perform <strong>the</strong> same estimation on data <strong>from</strong> 2006-2007.4 Results4.1 Private <strong>equity</strong> and entry: main resultsIn Table 5, column (i) we present <strong>the</strong> basic OLS regression when <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> (asreported by EVCA) is aggregated by country <strong>of</strong> destination. The coe¢ cient on <strong>the</strong> interactionterm is signi…cantly positive, implying that relative entry into industries with naturallyhigher entry is disproportionately higher in countries with large levels <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong><strong>investment</strong>, normalized by GDP. What <strong>the</strong> coe¢ cient means numerically is <strong>the</strong> following:let’s take a high entry-industry (at <strong>the</strong> 75th percentile <strong>of</strong> entry) and a low-entry industry(at <strong>the</strong> 25th percentile), and let’s take two countries which score high (75th percentile) andlow on <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> (25th percentile). The two countries in mind are Hungary (low) andDenmark (high), with <strong>the</strong> di¤erence between <strong>the</strong> two being 0.859.Then, <strong>the</strong> estimated18 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


coe¢ cient implies that <strong>the</strong> di¤erence in entry rates between <strong>the</strong> high-entry and <strong>the</strong> lowentryindustry are 0.44 percentage points higher in Denmark than in Hungary. Thus, allelse equal, an entrepreneur envisioning starting a …rm in a high-entry industry is to a largerdegree better o¤ by operating in Denmark ra<strong>the</strong>r than in Hungary than an entrepreneurwho wants to enter a low-entry industry. It is also useful to think <strong>of</strong> it in terms <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> actualvariations in entry rates between <strong>the</strong> 75th percentile and a 25th percentile industry which is8%. Hence, <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> accounts for 5.5% <strong>of</strong> that di¤erence.This simple empirical test shows that …rst, <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> has a <strong>real</strong> e¤ectthrough …rm creation. 4Second, <strong>the</strong> magnitude <strong>of</strong> increasing <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> bytwo standard deviations in our 16-country sample is about half <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> loweringentry barriers by two standard deviations in <strong>the</strong> 24-country sample used by Klapper et al.(2006). 5 In later tests, we perform horse race regressions to compare <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong><strong>equity</strong> against <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> barriers to entry, property rights protection, tax burden, ando<strong>the</strong>r characteristics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> business environment, and in all cases <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> remains asigni…cant predictor <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> variation in cross-country cross-industry entry rates.In <strong>the</strong> rest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> columns <strong>of</strong> Table 5, we test <strong>the</strong> basic result using di¤erent methodologiesand sample speci…cations. In column (ii), we account for left and right censoring by replacing<strong>the</strong> OLS speci…cation with a Tobit one. The rationale behind this is that entry rates areleft-truncated at 0 and right-truncated at 1. The coe¢ cient <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> interaction term does notchange, however, it becomes statistically signi…cant at <strong>the</strong> 1% level. Next, we exclude <strong>the</strong>sub-sample <strong>of</strong> transition countries (column (iii)). The 1990s were a vibrant period in <strong>the</strong>economic history <strong>of</strong> Central Europe in terms <strong>of</strong> privatization, and we would like to eliminate<strong>the</strong> possibility that a large number <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> <strong>private</strong> …rms are actually old state-owned …rmswhich have been counted only after <strong>the</strong>y became <strong>private</strong>.Our results are robust to <strong>the</strong>exclusion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>se countries, but <strong>the</strong> magnitude <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> coe¢ cients and <strong>the</strong> resulting numericale¤ect decreases slightly. We also look at <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> on incorporation <strong>of</strong> small4 However, before addressing <strong>the</strong> endogeneity probelm, we will be using <strong>the</strong> word "e¤ect" with caution.5 Klapper et al. (2006) …nd that entry barriers explain about 10% <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> entry di¤erence between highandlow-entry industries.ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200919


…rms only (less than 10 employees, column (iv)). The reason for that is that our e¤ect so farcould be upward biased by <strong>the</strong> fact that some <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> "<strong>new</strong>" …rms in our sample may in factbe <strong>the</strong> result <strong>of</strong> M&A. We …nd that <strong>the</strong> di¤erence in small …rm entry rates between a highanda low-entry industry (75th percentile vs. 25th percentile) is 4.6%, and so a coe¢ cient <strong>of</strong>0.263 implies that di¤erences in <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> explains about 9.5% <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> meandi¤erence. We can thus conclude that <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> has a <strong>real</strong> e¤ect on …rm creation, andthis e¤ect is strongest for small <strong>new</strong> …rms.Finally, we replace our variable measuring entry rates with a variable measuring exit rates.Entry and exit are considered complementary in creative destruction <strong>the</strong>ories (Schumpeter(1942); Aghion and Howitt (1992; 1998); Geroski (1995)). We use data <strong>from</strong> Eurostat on <strong>the</strong>share <strong>of</strong> …rms who dropped <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> sample at time t but were in it at time t1 to proxy for<strong>the</strong> exit element <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> creative destruction hypo<strong>the</strong>sis. The implicit hypo<strong>the</strong>sis being testedis that entry rates are also a¤ected by unobservable variables like entrepreneurial culture andrisk attitudes, and so observing an e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> on entry rates mayoverstate <strong>the</strong> true e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> by having <strong>the</strong> true e¤ect contaminated by demandconsiderations. Exit rates are much more likely to be determined by <strong>the</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> fundsra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> demand for <strong>the</strong>m; one most likely channel for that e¤ect is that ine¢ cientincumbent …rms will leave <strong>the</strong> population <strong>of</strong> …rms faster under pressure <strong>from</strong> more e¢ cientPE-backed <strong>new</strong>comers. The last column <strong>of</strong> Table 5 con…rms that <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>works well along <strong>the</strong> lines <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>ory <strong>of</strong> creative destruction, with its e¤ect on exits beingeconomically and statistically at least as strong as <strong>the</strong> measured e¤ect on entry.4.2 Private <strong>equity</strong> and entry: contemporaneous vs. long-terme¤ectThere are a number <strong>of</strong> robustness checks we need to perform on our measure <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong>.First, we have only regressed so far <strong>new</strong> business entry in 1998-1999 on <strong>the</strong> contemporaneousmeasure <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>. Alternatively, we could do so using an average measure20 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


<strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> over several years back. Such an approach would make sure that<strong>the</strong> estimated e¤ects are not biased by a temporary idiosyncratic shock to <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong><strong>investment</strong>, especially given <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> ‡uctuation <strong>of</strong> <strong>investment</strong> highlighted in Table 1.It is also conceivable to hypo<strong>the</strong>size that <strong>new</strong> entrants pay more attention to <strong>the</strong> long-termstate <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> industry ra<strong>the</strong>r than to current <strong>investment</strong> because long-term<strong>investment</strong> patterns usually convey more information about <strong>the</strong> future availability <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong><strong>equity</strong> …nance. For example, <strong>the</strong> business registration fees and <strong>the</strong> initial <strong>investment</strong> areusually …nanced with own funds or with …nancial help <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> "three F" (family, friends, andfools), and hence <strong>the</strong> incentive to start a company which will later be …nanced with venturecapital or expansion money, or outright bought by a <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> investor, is provided by<strong>the</strong> long-term presence <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> investors ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> current state <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> market.Indeed, our <strong>evidence</strong> suggests that <strong>the</strong> long-term presence <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> also associatedwith higher relative entry than contemporaneous one (Table 6). In fact, for both total <strong>new</strong>…rms and <strong>new</strong> …rms with less than 10 employees, <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> longer-term <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> iseven higher, suggesting that it goes beyond <strong>the</strong> direct a¤ect <strong>of</strong> actually …nancing <strong>the</strong> seedand start-up stages <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> …rm’s life. This is along <strong>the</strong> lines <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>ories outlined in <strong>the</strong>introduction, with <strong>new</strong> …rms not only being born out <strong>of</strong> old relationships between venturecapital and entrepreneurship, but also <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> expectation <strong>of</strong> getting …nance in later stagesvia expansion …nancing.4.3 Alternative measures <strong>of</strong> propensity to entryNext, we account for <strong>the</strong> possibility that our measure <strong>of</strong> entry is not <strong>the</strong> best proxy <strong>of</strong>propensity to entry. Prior literature (e.g. Gerotski (1995)) has suggested that exit rates area good proxy for propensity to entry because higher …rm creation is necessarily associatedwith higher …rm destruction.In <strong>the</strong> …rst two columns <strong>of</strong> Table 7, we use <strong>the</strong> Dun andBradsteet data to calculate <strong>the</strong> average share <strong>of</strong> exiting …rms for 1998-1999, per 2-digitindustry. US industry exit rates turn out to be as good proxies for propensity to entry asUS entry rates, in <strong>the</strong> sense that <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> on entry is relativelyECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200921


higher for industries with higher exit rates, repeating <strong>the</strong> results <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> previous estimation.However, <strong>the</strong> result only holds when we perform <strong>the</strong> estimation for <strong>the</strong> <strong>new</strong> …rms with lessthan 10 employees only (column (ii)).We next make use <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>new</strong> …rms are generally small because entry by larger…rms may re‡ect M&A activity. As much as it applies to <strong>the</strong> rest <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> world, it should alsoapply to our benchmark US case. We <strong>the</strong>refore replace <strong>the</strong> original proxy for "natural" entrywith a measure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> average industry entry rates over 1998-1999 for small and mediumenterprises (SMEs), or …rms with less than 250 workers. When we apply that methodology,<strong>the</strong> estimate <strong>of</strong> 1 remains positive, implying relatively higher entry due to <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong><strong>investment</strong> in industries that have higher entry by SMEs in <strong>the</strong> US. The estimates aresigni…cant at <strong>the</strong> 5% level. This result holds for entry by <strong>new</strong> …rms in di¤erent size classes.Finally, we use Claessens and Laeven’s (2003) insight that it is not necessary to use USdata to calculate "natural" industry characteristics, as long as we use benchmark data <strong>from</strong>a business environment that greatly outperforms <strong>the</strong> countries in <strong>the</strong> dataset in terms <strong>of</strong>business opportunities, …nance, and regulations. They show that using UK and Hong Kongdata to calculate "natural" intangibles usage yields identical results as when using <strong>the</strong> USbenchmark. We test that prediction by using UK data <strong>from</strong> Amadeus ra<strong>the</strong>r than US oneto calculate industry entry rates. This methodology also accounts for <strong>the</strong> fact that what weassume are "natural" or "technological" entry rates could be driven by peculiarities <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> USindustry structure. Using a UK benchmark makes sure that we are pinning entry in Europein general against an industrial structure which is more oriented towards manufacturing than<strong>the</strong> US, and against a legal system which is more creditor-friendly than <strong>the</strong> US (La Portaet al. (1998)). We exclude <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> regressions <strong>the</strong> industry data points <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> UK. Theregression results con…rm that entry in <strong>the</strong> UK and entry in <strong>the</strong> US are similar benchmarksfor natural propensity to entry. Our estimates for 1 are signi…cant at least at <strong>the</strong> 1%, butonly when we look at total <strong>new</strong> …rms.22 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


4.4 Private <strong>equity</strong> and access to …nanceAfter accounting for <strong>the</strong> possibility that our main proxy for "natural" propensity to entry isimperfect, we next account for <strong>the</strong> possibility that <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> is a mere proxyfor o<strong>the</strong>r types <strong>of</strong> …nance or for return to <strong>investment</strong>. For instance, countries with highervolumes <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> will tend to have better developed banking sectors, soour measure <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> will be capturing <strong>the</strong> e¤ects <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> credit market on entry viabusiness loans. Also, countries with dynamic PE and VC industries will tend to have higherinvestor protection, and so again our volume measure will be contaminated by <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> expected return on <strong>investment</strong> on entry. Most importantly, as Perotti and Volpin (2007)argue, <strong>the</strong> volume <strong>of</strong> …nance may matter less than access to …nance per se. Hence, our PEmeasure might be picking up <strong>the</strong> e¤ect on <strong>new</strong> business entry <strong>of</strong> easier access to all kinds <strong>of</strong>…nance, including consumer loans and mortgages. In all <strong>of</strong> those cases, our estimates wouldbe biased.Therefore in Table 8 we proceed to measure <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> onentry alongside <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> …nance in general. In column (i), we show <strong>the</strong> estimates <strong>of</strong>a regression which includes a measure <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> credit by commercial banks, normalizedby GDP. This measure is widely accepted as a good proxy for a range <strong>of</strong> …nancial issues,like access to business loans, depth <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> …nancial sector a¤ecting <strong>the</strong> ability <strong>of</strong> …nancialplayers to gain access to <strong>investment</strong> opportunities, etc. (Rajan and Zingales (1998); Becket al. (2008)). The e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> credit on <strong>new</strong> business entry is both economically andstatistically signi…cant, as expected.Importantly, <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>remains signi…cant, although in <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> all …rms its magnitude decreases somewhat.However, in <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> …rms with less than 10 employees, <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> in <strong>new</strong>business incorporation remains as strong as before (column (v)).Next, we account for <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>private</strong> credit is also a volume measure and thus animperfect proxy for access to …nance. Therefore, we employ a formal proxy for access to…nancial services (columns (ii) and (vi)) taken <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> World Bank’s "Finance for All?Policies and Pitfalls in Expanding Access" which is a composite indicator measuring <strong>the</strong>ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200923


percentage <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> adult population with access to an account with a …nancial intermediary.While this index captures more than access to business loans, it is a better measure than<strong>the</strong> volume <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> credit <strong>of</strong> how easy it is to access …nancial services in general. Thecorrelation between <strong>the</strong> two measures is 0.71, implying that <strong>the</strong>y are highly but not perfectlycorrelated, and so <strong>the</strong> formal index could indeed be capturing more access issues than <strong>private</strong>credit. Again, while it is correlated with <strong>new</strong> business incorporation, including it in <strong>the</strong>regression doesn’t eliminate <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> on …rm entry. While in <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong>total <strong>new</strong> …rms <strong>the</strong> estimate <strong>of</strong> 1 again loses part <strong>of</strong> its economic and statistical signi…cance,it remains <strong>the</strong> case that <strong>the</strong> volume <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> …nance impacts business creationindependent <strong>of</strong> general access to …nancial services.We also look at investors’protection. Rajan and Zingales (2003) argue that <strong>the</strong> absence<strong>of</strong> regulation protecting investors could be a very e¢ cient barrier to <strong>new</strong> …rm creation. Theright measure <strong>of</strong> …nancial development, <strong>the</strong> argument goes, would capture not only <strong>the</strong> easewith which any entrepreneur or company with a sound project can obtain …nance, but also <strong>the</strong>con…dence with which investors anticipate an adequate return. The previous two measureswe used would <strong>the</strong>n be a poor proxy for this investor con…dence, and we next proceed toincorporate in our regression a direct measure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> degree to which individual <strong>investment</strong>sare protected by <strong>the</strong> legal system in <strong>the</strong> country. 6The indicator we employ is a composite<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> quality <strong>of</strong> three indices: transparency <strong>of</strong> transactions, liability for self-dealing, andshareholders’ability to sue o¢ cers and directors for misconduct. As expected, this index hasa very signi…cant e¤ect on entry when interacted with our measure <strong>of</strong> "natural" entry rates,pointing to <strong>the</strong> fact that investors indeed take into account <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> legal protectiona¤ecting <strong>the</strong> expected return to individual <strong>investment</strong>s in start-up companies.Tellingly,<strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> on business entry survives this extension <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> basicmodel (columns (iii) and (vii)).Finally, we do a horse race in which we include all country-level measures used in Table8 so far interacted with our measure <strong>of</strong> natural industry entry (columns (iv) and (viii)).6 Perotti and Volpin (2007) also use this measure as a proxy for access to …nance.24 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


We …nd that <strong>private</strong> credit doesn’t enter signi…cantly anymore, and access to …nance isinsigni…cant in <strong>the</strong> case <strong>of</strong> entry <strong>of</strong> all <strong>new</strong> …rms, but in general, our results con…rm that<strong>the</strong> depth <strong>of</strong> …nancial system, access to …nance and investor protection all matter for entry.Importantly, <strong>the</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> interaction continues to enter positively and statisticallysigni…cantly, albeit with a somewhat decreased order <strong>of</strong> magnitude.4.5 Endogeneity and selectionThe empirical methodology chosen is traditionally prone to endogeneity problems. A measuredpositive coe¢ cient on <strong>the</strong> composite term <strong>of</strong> interest does not automatically implycausality; it could be that <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> is endogenous to …rm entry rates, or it couldbe that a set <strong>of</strong> omitted variables is jointly driving both <strong>the</strong> propensity to enter and <strong>the</strong>propensity to invest in start-up companies, in interaction with our industry characteristics<strong>of</strong> choice. The traditional solution in this line <strong>of</strong> research is to use an instrumental variables(IV) procedure to account for this potential endogeneity. It has been generally agreedthat <strong>the</strong> country’s legal origin is a strong predictor <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> legal regulation and <strong>the</strong>quality <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> …nancial system nowadays (La Porta et al. (1998)). However, in <strong>the</strong> case<strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> and entry <strong>the</strong>re are two problems which may reduce legal origin to anine¢ cient instrument. For one, it could be that <strong>the</strong> link between <strong>the</strong> exogenous component<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> legal system and <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> is relatively weak, but more importantly,it is conceivable that legal systems a¤ect entry via channels o<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>,like barriers to entry, for instance. Hence, we ra<strong>the</strong>r look at <strong>the</strong> types <strong>of</strong> lawsthat were in place in <strong>the</strong> 1990s, regulating <strong>the</strong> ability <strong>of</strong> pension funds managers to engagein <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>. The method is akin to Kortum and Lerner (2000), who use a1979 clari…cation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA) "Prudent man"rule by <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>of</strong> Labor allowing pension funds to engage in PE <strong>investment</strong>s as aninstrument for VC <strong>investment</strong>. 7The idea is that <strong>the</strong> increased supply <strong>of</strong> funds reduces <strong>the</strong>7 Gompers and Lerner (1999) show that VC <strong>investment</strong> increases more than …ve-fold following <strong>the</strong> ERISA"Prudent man" rule clari…cation by <strong>the</strong> US Department <strong>of</strong> Labor.ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200925


cost <strong>of</strong> …nancing to venture capitalists, and hence serves as a supply shifter, while it has noe¤ect on <strong>the</strong> availability <strong>of</strong> ideas that need start-up …nance. 8We create a dummy equal to 1 if pension funds were allowed to invest in <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong>in <strong>the</strong> respective country prior to <strong>the</strong> sampling period, and to zero o<strong>the</strong>rwise. We also createa variable which is constructed by interacting <strong>the</strong> pension funds dummy with <strong>the</strong> averagesize <strong>of</strong> pension funds in <strong>the</strong> respective country as share <strong>of</strong> GDP over <strong>the</strong> 1995-1999 period 9 .Being correlated with <strong>the</strong> predetermined components <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> and venture capital<strong>investment</strong> and exogenous to current business opportunities makes <strong>the</strong>se variables reasonableinstruments, even in a small-sample context with linear estimation. 10In an (unreported)exercise we …nd that a …rst-stage regression including <strong>the</strong> two instruments one at a time, aswell as toge<strong>the</strong>r, explains between up to 65% <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> cross-country variation in <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong>,with an F-value <strong>of</strong> up to 12.5. In addition, countries that enacted such a measure have seen<strong>the</strong>re PE funds raised increase by 95.5% more on average over <strong>the</strong> period 1991-1999 thancountries which did not. We report <strong>the</strong> estimates <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> second stage in columns (i)-(ii)and (vi)-(vii) <strong>of</strong> Table 9. We …nd that <strong>the</strong> estimate <strong>of</strong> 1 is still positive and still highlysigni…cant, and does not vary dramatically in magnitude <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> estimates <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> OLSregressions.However, a common ‡aw <strong>of</strong> this method is that countries with large industries withhigh natural entry may have both higher entrepreneurial culture (resulting in more entryregardless <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>) and higher levels <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> (dueto higher demand for all types <strong>of</strong> …nance). <strong>On</strong>e method to control for that possibility is toexclude <strong>the</strong> industries that are in <strong>the</strong> right tail <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> industry size distribution. We restrictour sample to <strong>the</strong> industries that are in <strong>the</strong> bottom tertile, bottom two tertiles, or outside <strong>the</strong>top 10% <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir country’s industries in terms <strong>of</strong> size. When we do that, in all cases we get8 Unfortunately, given <strong>the</strong> aggregated data we are provided with, it is impossible to construct a moredirect proxy <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> …nance.9 The data for pension funds size in <strong>the</strong> 1990s comes <strong>from</strong> Eurostat.10 It is possible that <strong>the</strong>se laws were enacted following pressure <strong>from</strong> a growing PE industry, or a lack <strong>of</strong>entrepreneurial activity (which would make <strong>the</strong>m correlated with PE and hence null <strong>the</strong> exclusion restriction).It is a fact, however, that <strong>the</strong> formal motive expressed during <strong>the</strong> legislative process has universally beendiversi…cation <strong>of</strong> risk (EVCA yearbooks, 1991-1999).26 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


estimates which are still positive and signi…cant, similar to magnitude to <strong>the</strong> ones estimatedpreviously, and <strong>the</strong>y do not vary much regardless <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> de…nition <strong>of</strong> "small industries" thatwe use. The coe¢ cient after <strong>the</strong> exclusion <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> top 10% is reported in columns (iii) and(viii) (for entry by all …rms and by …rms with less than 10 employees, respectively).Ano<strong>the</strong>r selection concern is that in countries whose culture is adverse to entrepreneurialactivity (and hence, <strong>the</strong>re is naturally less entry), <strong>the</strong>re are also stricter rules guiding <strong>private</strong><strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>, as <strong>the</strong> local legislatures would be adverse to business activity in general.We account for that possibility by distinguishing <strong>the</strong> general quality <strong>of</strong> laws in <strong>the</strong> respectivecountry. The above argument would imply that if it is a selection problem, <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong><strong>investment</strong> will have a larger e¤ect in countries where <strong>the</strong> quality <strong>of</strong> laws is generally lower.This is not <strong>the</strong> case; in fact as indicated in columns (iv) and (ix), <strong>the</strong> e¤ect is <strong>the</strong> opposite– more <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> leads to relatively higher entry in high-entry industries in countrieswith well-developed legal systems, implying no omitted variable bias.Finally, we have to account for <strong>the</strong> possibility that by focusing on legal entry, we may beoverlooking activity in <strong>the</strong> informal sector. To account for <strong>the</strong> possibility that our results arebiased by not considering a potentially large dynamics in <strong>the</strong> informal sector, we next useEnste and Schneider’s (2000) measure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> size <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> informal economy to control for that.In columns (v) and (xi) <strong>of</strong> Table 9, we regress …rm entry on two triple interaction terms,in which <strong>the</strong> industry natural entry-country <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> has been interactedwith dummies for high and low degree <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> informal economy, where low share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>informal economy equals 1 if <strong>the</strong> country is in <strong>the</strong> bottom tertile <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> informal economyshare, and to 0 o<strong>the</strong>rwise, and high share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> informal economy equals 1 if <strong>the</strong> country isin <strong>the</strong> top tertile <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> informal economy, and to 0 o<strong>the</strong>rwise. The coe¢ cient on <strong>the</strong> tripleinteraction term including <strong>the</strong> low informal economy dummy is positive, implying that incountries where for tax or regulatory reasons <strong>the</strong>re is little activity in <strong>the</strong> informal sector,<strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> is indeed associated with higher entry in industries that naturally have higherentry rates.ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200927


4.6 RobustnessWe conduct an extensive robustness analysis whose detailed exposition is left for a companionpaper available upon request for <strong>the</strong> sake <strong>of</strong> brevity. We …rst estimate <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong><strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> on entry, accounting for <strong>the</strong> standard industry determinants <strong>of</strong> entry thathave been suggested by <strong>the</strong> literature.In particular, it has been pointed out that entryrates are a¤ected negatively by …nancial dependence and capital intensity, and positivelyby technological opportunities and industry growth, among else. 11We <strong>the</strong>refore want tomake sure that <strong>the</strong> e¤ects we are measuring are not driven by o<strong>the</strong>r industry characteristicsfor which our measure <strong>of</strong> "natural entry" is a proxy. We …nd that some characteristics <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> business environment matter for entry exactly as predicted: higher intellectual propertyprotection is associated with higher entry in industries that naturally invest more in R&D,and lower entry costs are associated with relatively higher entry in industries that are growingfaster. Importantly, in all cases higher <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> keeps its independent e¤ecton entry, and this e¤ect is still relatively stronger for naturally high-entry industries. Thise¤ect also survives <strong>the</strong> "horse race".Next, we look at a set <strong>of</strong> characteristics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> business environment, which <strong>the</strong> literaturehas identi…ed as predictors <strong>of</strong> entry: entry barriers, labor regulations, human capital, intellectualproperty rights protection, and taxes. To <strong>the</strong> degree that all <strong>of</strong> those tend to followa similar path over time, <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> on entry could be contaminatedby developments along o<strong>the</strong>r dimensions <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> business environment. We accountfor all those possibilities by including an interaction <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> industry’s natural propensityto entry with ano<strong>the</strong>r characteristic <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> business environment, one at a time, and all <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong>m simultaneously. We con…rm that barriers to entry have a detrimental e¤ect on entryrates. We …nd that labor regulations have no signi…cant e¤ect on entry, although Europe istraditionally regarded as a labor constrained environment. Better protection <strong>of</strong> intellectualproperty rights is associated with relatively more entry in high-entry industries, which alsotend to be <strong>the</strong> ones that are <strong>the</strong> most intangibles-intensive. Finally, cross-country variation11 See Geroski (1995) for a summary <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> empirical <strong>evidence</strong> on that.28 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


in pro…t taxes does little to explain <strong>the</strong> cross-country cross-industry variation in entry ratesbetween high and low entry industries, and nei<strong>the</strong>r does a higher level <strong>of</strong> human capital oraccounting for <strong>the</strong> business cycle. Again, <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> survives all robustnesschecks, including <strong>the</strong> horse race.As mentioned before, our data contains information on <strong>the</strong> distribution <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong><strong>investment</strong> across 17 di¤erent industries as classi…ed by EVCA. This calls for a disaggregatedapproach in which we replace our measure <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> at <strong>the</strong> country level(EV CA i ) with a measure <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> at <strong>the</strong> country and industry level(EV CA ik ). The …rst di¢ culty is that <strong>the</strong> disaggregated data comes by country <strong>of</strong> management,unlike data on total <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>, which is reported both by country<strong>of</strong> management and country <strong>of</strong> destination. We convert <strong>the</strong> industry data by country <strong>of</strong>management into country <strong>of</strong> destination by assuming that in each industry, <strong>the</strong> gap between<strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> by country <strong>of</strong> management and by country <strong>of</strong> destination is <strong>the</strong> same as <strong>the</strong>gap between <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> by country <strong>of</strong> management and by country <strong>of</strong> destination for <strong>the</strong>whole economy. This approach is obviously prone to measurement error and so <strong>the</strong> resultswe report should be taken with caution. The second di¢ culty deals with <strong>the</strong> issue <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>NACE rev. 1.1 -> EVCA industry classi…cation translation key, highlighted in Section 2,for which we use <strong>the</strong> translation key developed and presented in Table 4. After repeating<strong>the</strong> estimation reported in Table 5, this time with disaggregated industry data, <strong>the</strong> e¤ect on<strong>new</strong> business incorporation <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> interaction <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> with <strong>the</strong> industry’s "natural"entry rates are still economically and statistically signi…cant.Finally, we use <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> data <strong>from</strong> EVCA also allows us to account for <strong>the</strong>staging <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> (seed, start-up, expansion and replacement, and buyout),and for <strong>investment</strong> by type <strong>of</strong> investor (independent, captive, semi-captive, or publicfunds). The caveats <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> previous paragraph apply again in <strong>the</strong> sense that <strong>the</strong> data onstaging and investor type comes by country <strong>of</strong> management only, and so our conversion<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> data into country <strong>of</strong> destination relies on <strong>the</strong> assumption that <strong>the</strong> gap between, forexample, venture capital <strong>investment</strong> by country <strong>of</strong> management and by country <strong>of</strong> destinationECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200929


is <strong>the</strong> same as <strong>the</strong> gap between <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> by country <strong>of</strong> management and by country<strong>of</strong> destination. However, in 2006 EVCA started reporting <strong>the</strong> stage distribution <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong><strong>equity</strong> …nance by country <strong>of</strong> destination too. Hence, in this last empirical exercise, we matchdata <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> 2006-2007 EVCA yearbooks with data <strong>from</strong> Amadeus on entry for 2006-2007,using <strong>the</strong> 2008 CD. 12 We …nd that investor type matters: all <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> PE <strong>investment</strong>on <strong>new</strong> business entry comes <strong>from</strong> <strong>investment</strong> by independent investors, while <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong>captive, semi-captive and public funds is at best non-existent. We also …nd that in 2006-2007,start-up …nance, VC and total <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> have an equally strong e¤ect on <strong>new</strong> businessincorporation. <strong>On</strong>e way to read this is that nascent entrepreneurs anticipate future …nancingneeds and are more likely to decide to start <strong>the</strong>ir own business at a time when more venturecapital is available.A second explanation is o¤ered by entrepreneurial spawning whereventure-backed …rms are more likely to create o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>new</strong> ventures (Gompers et al., (2005)).However, this remains just a hypo<strong>the</strong>sis until a more re…ned empirical approach looks into<strong>the</strong> channels via which <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> a¤ects <strong>new</strong> business incorporation.5 ConclusionThis paper uses a cross-industry cross-country estimation technique in <strong>the</strong> spirit <strong>of</strong> Rajanand Zingales (1998) to identify <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> and venture capital <strong>investment</strong>in general and start-up …nance in particular on entrepreneurship. We use two waves <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>Amadeus database, which includes data on about three million …rms all across Europe: asample for <strong>the</strong> years 1998-1999 in <strong>the</strong> main empirical analysis, and a sample <strong>from</strong> 2006-2007for robustness purposes. The Amadeus represents one <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> largest data sets on European…rms <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong>se periods, and it is made particularly valuable by <strong>the</strong> fact that it includesextensive data on SMEs, <strong>private</strong> as well as publicly traded corporations, and is not limitedto manufacturing like many similar data sets. It also includes data on <strong>the</strong> age <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> …rmand its year <strong>of</strong> incorporation, giving us <strong>the</strong> opportunity to proxy entry rates by <strong>the</strong> share <strong>of</strong>12 The same selection criteria apply as in Section 2.4.30 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


young …rms across <strong>the</strong> full range <strong>of</strong> NACE Rev 1.1 industries.We match that data to data <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> European Venture Capital Association (EVCA) on<strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> in general and start-up …nance in particular in Western Europe andsome Central European countries. We average <strong>the</strong> data <strong>from</strong> 1998-1999 to match with <strong>the</strong>…rst wave <strong>of</strong> Amadeus, and <strong>from</strong> 2006-2007 for <strong>the</strong> second wave. We examine 16 countries,37 NACE double-digit Rev. 1.1 industries, and 14 EVCA industry classes.We …nd that <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> has a bene…cial e¤ect on entry, which is relativelyhigher for industries which naturally have higher entry rates and are more R&D intensive.The e¤ect remains strong once we exclude <strong>investment</strong> allocated to buy-outs, suggesting thatearly stage …nance is important in this respect. Our results hold both in 1998-1999 and 2006-2007, when we account for industry size, and when we exclude <strong>the</strong> transition economies. Theresults stay unchanged after we address <strong>the</strong> endogeneity problem (does <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> induceentry or is it attracted to countries with a more dynamic industrial structure?) by usingan IV procedure in which variation in national prudential regulation guiding <strong>the</strong> <strong>investment</strong>behavior <strong>of</strong> Europe’s pension funds is used as an instrument for <strong>the</strong> supply <strong>of</strong> PE funds.We argue that by o¤ering a unique combination <strong>of</strong> ownership and incentives, <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong><strong>investment</strong> seems to lower <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> start-up capital and result in higher industry dynamics.The results are generally robust to using di¤erent proxies for entry, contemporaneous orhistorical volumes <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>, and to correcting for omitted variable bias.We also …nd that <strong>the</strong> e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> is higher in countries with better judicialsystems and in countries with smaller share <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> informal economy. This result is onlylogical: to <strong>the</strong> extent that <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> targets industries that rely heavily on intangibleassets like intellectual property, licenses and patents, its e¤ect should be more pronouncedin countries where <strong>the</strong> returns to those are protected by <strong>the</strong> legal system. At <strong>the</strong> same time,we …nd that <strong>the</strong> relatively higher e¤ect <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> on entry in high-entryindustries is robust to accounting for o<strong>the</strong>r industry characteristics, as well as for o<strong>the</strong>rcharacteristics <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> business environment that have been suggested by <strong>the</strong> literature asdeterminants <strong>of</strong> entry rates.ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200931


This paper is, to our knowledge, <strong>the</strong> …rst attempt to empirically link <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong><strong>investment</strong> to industry entry in a cross-country cross-industry setting. Our results imply that<strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> in general and venture capital in particular have a positive e¤ect in potentiallybringing <strong>new</strong> ideas to <strong>the</strong> marketplace in <strong>the</strong> shape <strong>of</strong> young companies. In this paper we arenot interested in <strong>the</strong> pro…tability <strong>of</strong> this enterprise, but as far as <strong>real</strong> e¤ects are concerned,<strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> seems to generate value through fostering entrepreneurial activityin <strong>the</strong> economy. A number <strong>of</strong> important questions remain unanswered due to <strong>the</strong> nature<strong>of</strong> our data.For example, what is <strong>the</strong> relative importance <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> di¤erent channels viawhich <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> and venture capital a¤ect entry? Is it more anticipatory considerationswhere nascent entrepreneurs are aware <strong>of</strong> future …nancing needs and are more likely todecide to start <strong>the</strong>ir own business at a time when more venture capital is available? Or isit entrepreneurial spawning where venture-backed …rms are more likely to create o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>new</strong>ventures? Future research can greatly contribute by addressing those questions.32 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


References[1] Aernoudt, R., 1999. European policy towards venture capital: myth or <strong>real</strong>ity? VentureCapital, 1(1), 47-58.[2] Aghion, P., T. Fally, and S. Scarpetta, 2007. Credit constraints as a barrier to <strong>the</strong> entryand post-entry growth <strong>of</strong> …rms. Economic Policy, 22, 731-779.[3] Aghion, P., and P. Howitt, 1992. A model <strong>of</strong> growth through creative destruction.Econometrica, 60(2), 323-351.[4] Aghion, P., and P. Howitt, 1998. Endogenous Growth Theory. MIT Press: Cambridge,MA.[5] Barro, R., and J.-W. Lee, 2000. International data on educational attainment: updatesand implications. CID Working Paper No. 42.[6] Beck, T., A. Demirgüç-Kunt, and V. Maksimovic, 2005. Financial and legal constraintsto growth: does …rm size matter? Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance, 60(1), 137-177.[7] Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, L. Laeven, and R. Levine, 2008. Finance, …rm size, andgrowth. Journal <strong>of</strong> Money, Credit, and Banking, 40(7), 1379-1405.[8] Black, S.E., and P.E. Strahan, 2002. Entrepreneurship and bank credit availability.Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance, 57(6), 2807-2833.[9] Bresnahan, T., and P. Reiss, 1988. Do entry conditions vary across markets? BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity 3, 833-881.[10] Botazzi, L., M. Da Rin, and T. Hellmann, 2008. Who are <strong>the</strong> active investors? Evidence<strong>from</strong> venture capital. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics, 89(3), 488-512.[11] Caves, R., M. Winston, and M. Hurwitz, 1991. Patent expiration, entry, and competitionin <strong>the</strong> US pharmaceutical industry. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 6, 1-66.ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200933


[12] Cetorelli, N., and P.E. Strahan, 2006. Finance as a barrier to entry: bank competitionand industry structure in local U.S. markets. Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance, 61(1), 437-461.[13] Christensen, Clayton M., 1997. The Innovator’s Dilemma: When New TechnologiesCause Great Firms to Fail. Harvard Business School Press: Boston, MA.[14] Claessens, S., and L. Laeven, 2003. Financial development, property rights, and growth.Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance, 58(6), 2401-2436.[15] Da Rin, M., Di Giacomo, M., and A. Sembenelli, 2008. Firm entry dynamics and <strong>the</strong>taxation <strong>of</strong> corporate pro…ts: <strong>evidence</strong> <strong>from</strong> Europe. CentER Discussion Paper SeriesNo. 2008-65.[16] Davis, S.J., J. Haltiwanger, J.Lerner, and J. Miranda, 2008. Private <strong>equity</strong> and employment.U.S. Census Bureau Center for Economic Studies Paper No. CES-WP-08-07.[17] De Soto, H., 1990. The O<strong>the</strong>r Path. Harper and Row: New York, NY.[18] Enste, D., and F. Schneider, 2000. Shadow economies: Size, causes, and consequences.Journal <strong>of</strong> Economic Literature, 38(1), 77-114.[19] Geroski, P.A., 1995. What do we know about entry? International Journal <strong>of</strong> IndustrialOrganization, 13(4), 421-440.[20] Gilson, R. J., 2003. Engineering a venture capital market: lessons <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> Americanexperience. Stanford Law Review, 55(4), 1067-1103.[21] Gompers, P.A., and J. Lerner, 1999. The Venture Capital Cycle. MIT Press: Cambridge,MA.[22] Gompers, P.A., and J. Lerner, 2001a. The Money <strong>of</strong> Invention. Harvard Business SchoolPress: Boston, MA.[23] Gompers, P.A., and J. Lerner, 2001b. The venture capital revolution. Journal <strong>of</strong> EconomicPerspectives, 15 (2), 145-168.34 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


[24] Gompers, P.A., J. Lerner, and D.S. Scharfstein, 2005. Entrepreneurial spawning: publiccorporations and <strong>the</strong> formation <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> ventures, 1986-1999. Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance, 60(2),577-614.[25] Hellmann, T., 1998. The allocation <strong>of</strong> control rights in venture capital contracts. RANDJournal <strong>of</strong> Economics, 29(1), 57-76.[26] Hellmann, T., and M. Puri, 2000. The interaction between product market and …nancingstrategy: <strong>the</strong> role <strong>of</strong> venture capital. Review <strong>of</strong> Financial Studies, 13(4), 959-984.[27] Klapper, L., L. Laeven, and R. Rajan, 2006. Entry regulation as a barrier to entrepreneurship.Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics, 82(3), 591-629.[28] Kaplan, S., and P. Stromberg, 2001. Venture capitalists as principals: contracting,screening, and monitoring. American Economic Review, 91(2), 426-430.[29] Kortum, S., and J. Lerner, 2000. Assessing <strong>the</strong> contribution <strong>of</strong> venture capital to innovation.RAND Journal <strong>of</strong> Economics, 31(4), 674-692.[30] La Porta, R., F. Lopez de Silanes, A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny, 1998. Finance and law.Journal <strong>of</strong> Political Economy, 106(6), 1113-55.[31] Lafontaine, F., and J. Sivadasan, 2008. Do labor market rigidities have microeconomice¤ects?Evidence <strong>from</strong> within <strong>the</strong> …rm. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics,Forthcoming.[32] Mollica, M., and L. Zingales, 2007. The impact <strong>of</strong> venture capital on innovation and <strong>the</strong>creation <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> businesses. University <strong>of</strong> Chicago Working paper.[33] Park, W., and J.C. Ginarte, 1997. Intellectual property rights and economic growth.Contemporary Economic Policy, 15(3), 51-61.[34] Perotti, E., and P. Volpin, 2007. Investor protection and entry. Tinbergen InstituteDiscussion Paper 07-006/2.ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200935


[35] Petersen, M., and R. Rajan, 1995. The e¤ect <strong>of</strong> credit market competition on lendingrelationships. The Quarterly Journal <strong>of</strong> Economics, 110(2), 407-443.[36] Rajan, R., and L. Zingales, 1998. Financial dependance and growth. American EconomicReview, 88(3), 559-586.[37] Rajan, R., and L. Zingales, 2003. The great reversal: <strong>the</strong> politics <strong>of</strong> …nancial developmentin <strong>the</strong> 20th century. Journal <strong>of</strong> Financial Economics, 69(1), 5-50.[38] Schoar, A., 2002. E¤ects <strong>of</strong> corporate diversi…cation on productivity. Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance,57(6), 2379-2403.[39] Schumpeter, Joseph A. The Process <strong>of</strong> Creative Destruction. Unwin. 1942.[40] Stein, Jeremy C., 2002. Information production and capital allocation: decentralizedversus hierarchical …rms. Journal <strong>of</strong> Finance, 57(5), 1891-1921.[41] Tang, M.-C., and Y.-L. Chyi, 2008. Legal environments, venture capital, and total factorproductivity. Contemporary Economic Policy, 26, 468-481.36 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


Table 1Summary statistics: EVCA data on <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>CountryTotal PE <strong>investment</strong>over GDP, in %Total PE <strong>investment</strong>over GDP, in %Austria 0.027 0.079Belgium 0.119 0.084Czech Republic 0.042 0.023Denmark 0.029 0.353Finland 0.111 0.149France 0.117 0.375Germany 0.081 0.145Greece 0.027 0.004Hungary 0.052 0.086Italy 0.082 0.131Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands 0.271 0.403Norway 0.112 0.164Poland 0.093 0.064Spain 0.062 0.265Sweden 0.200 0.820UK 0.465 1.215The data are averaged for <strong>the</strong> period 1998-99 (columns 2) and for 2006-2007 (column 3), and areaggregated over industries. The respective values include all <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> in <strong>the</strong> respectiveEuropean country by European banks and <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> houses, as well as <strong>from</strong> international banksand <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> houses which have a European branch or partner. Source: EVCA yearbooks.ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200937


Table 2Summary statistics on entry, by countryNew firms (


Table 3Entry rates by industry in Europe against <strong>the</strong> US benchmarkNew firms as %<strong>of</strong> all firms, 1998-1999, EuropeNew firms as% <strong>of</strong> all firms,1998-1999, US2-digit NACE rev 1.1 code and industry nameManufacturing15. Food products and beverages 9.6 10.416. Tobacco products 16.1 14.817. Textiles 9.3 13.718. Wearing apparel; dressing and dying <strong>of</strong> fur 9.5 12.819. Tanning and dressing <strong>of</strong> lea<strong>the</strong>r; luggage, handbags, saddlery,harness, and footwear 8.6 18.220. Wood and products <strong>of</strong> wood and cork, except furniture 11.2 1221. Pulp, paper and paper products 9.5 10.622. Publishing, printing and reproduction <strong>of</strong> recorded media 11.2 1123. Coke, refined petroleum products, and nuclear fuel 10.8 11.524. Chemicals and chemical products 9.3 12.225. Rubber and plastic products 10.9 926. O<strong>the</strong>r non-metallic mineral products 9.3 11.627. Basic metals 12.2 9.828. Fabricated metal products, except machinery and equipment 11.5 11.429. Machinery and equipment not elsewhere classified 10.4 8.630. Office machinery and computers 15.8 17.431. Electrical machinery and apparatus not elsewhere classified 11.0 11.832. Radio, television, and communication equipment and apparatus 13.8 16.533. Medical, precision, and optical instruments, watches, and clocks 9.7 11.434. Motor vehicles, trailers, and semi-trailers 10.8 10.435. O<strong>the</strong>r transport equipment 13.0 1636. Furniture; manufacturing not elsewhere classified 11.7 15.8Construction45. Construction 13.7 16.3Trade50. Sale, maintenance and repair <strong>of</strong> motor vehicles andmotorcycles; retail sale <strong>of</strong> automotive fuel 13.4 10.251. Wholesale trade and commission trade, except <strong>of</strong> motor vehicles 14.9 10.652. Retail trade, except <strong>of</strong> motor vehicles and motorcycles; repair <strong>of</strong>personal and household goods 15.2 14.4Hotels and restaurants55. Hotels and restaurants 14.8 11.8Transportation60. Land transport; transport via pipelines 16.0 16.861. Water transport 11.9 11.262. Air transport 13.5 12.463. Supporting and auxiliary transport activities, and travel agencies 14.5 13.5Services70. Real estate activities 16.0 10.671. Renting <strong>of</strong> machinery and equipment without operator and <strong>of</strong>personal and household goods 18.0 12.672. Computer and related services 22.4 21.473. Research and development 17.0 13.174. O<strong>the</strong>r business activities 18.4 19.4O<strong>the</strong>r93. O<strong>the</strong>r services activities 17.0 13The values reported are averaged over 1998 and 1999, for Europe (column 2) and <strong>the</strong> US (column 3). Thefraction <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> firms is calculated as <strong>the</strong> number <strong>of</strong> firms 2 or less years old over all firms in this particularindustry. Source: Amadeus database (column 2) and Dun and Bradstreet (column 3)ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200939


Table 42-digit NACE rev. 1.1 industry classification -> EVCA industry classification conversion keyNACE rev 1.1 industry classEVCA industry class22, 32 Communications24, 30, 32, 33, 72 Computer73 Biotechnology23, 33, 85 Medical and health related23, 24 Energy15, 16, 17, 18, 19, 34, 35, 36, 50, 51, 52, 55, 63, 93 Consumer products26, 27, 28, 29 Industrial products24, 25 Chemicals and chemical related31 Industrial automation20, 21 O<strong>the</strong>r manufacturing60, 61, 62 Transportation61, 63, 71, 74 O<strong>the</strong>r services45 Construction70 O<strong>the</strong>rSource: EVCA -> NACE rev. 2 and NACE rev. 2 -> NACE rev. 1.1 translation key.40 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


Table 5Private <strong>equity</strong> and firm entry: measuring PE <strong>investment</strong> at <strong>the</strong> country levelIndustry shareEntry US * Private <strong>equity</strong>(i)OLS(ii)Tobit(iii)TobitFraction <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> firms Fraction <strong>of</strong> exited firmsPE <strong>investment</strong> PE <strong>investment</strong> Excluding trans. economies Small firms only PE <strong>investment</strong>-0.005 -0.005 0.156 -0.026 -0.012(0.09) (0.109) (0.116) (0.055) (0.101)0.300 0.300 0.189 0.263 0.239(0.112)** (0.078)*** (0.079)** (0.117)** (0.059)***Observations 571 571 471 571 571R 2 0.60 0.56 0.63(iv)OLS(v)OLSThe reported estimates are <strong>from</strong> OLS regressions (columns (i) and (iv)-(v)) and <strong>from</strong> a Tobit regression (columns (ii) and (iii)). The dependent variable is <strong>the</strong>ratio <strong>of</strong> all <strong>new</strong> firms to total firms (in columns (i)-(iii)), <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> all <strong>new</strong> firms with less than 10 employees to total firms (column (iv)), and <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong>all exited firms to total firms by 2-digit NACE rev. 1.1, averaged for 1998-1999 (column (v)). Industry share is <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> industry sales to total sales by allindustries in each country. Entry US is <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> firms to total firms in <strong>the</strong> US, by 2-digit NACE rev. 1.1. Private <strong>equity</strong> measures actual <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong><strong>investment</strong> at <strong>the</strong> country level, normalized by GDP, averaged for 1998-1999. All regressions include a constant, 2-digit industry dummies and countrydummies, not reported. White’s heteroskedasticity corrected standard errors standard errors are reported in paren<strong>the</strong>ses. ***, **, and * report significance at<strong>the</strong> 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. See Appendix 1 for detailed variable definitions and sources.ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200941


Table 6Private <strong>equity</strong> timing and firm entryIndustry shareEntry US * Private <strong>equity</strong>(i)OLSPE <strong>investment</strong>, 3-yearaverage(ii)OLS(iii)OLSAll firms Small firmsPE <strong>investment</strong>, 4-yearaveragePE <strong>investment</strong>, 3-yearaverage(iv)OLSPE <strong>investment</strong>, 4-yearaverage-0.004 -0.003 -0.024 -0.023(0.091) (0.091) (0.054) (0.054)0.349 0.390 0.313 0.362(0.131)*** (0.156)*** (0.138)** (0.163)**Observations 571 571 571 571R 2 0.60 0.60 0.56 0.56The reported estimates are <strong>from</strong> OLS regressions. The dependent variable is <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> all <strong>new</strong> firms to total firms (columns (i)-(ii)) and <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> all <strong>new</strong>firms with less than 10 employees to total firms (columns (iii)-(iv)), by 2-digit NACE rev. 1.1 and averaged for 1998-1999. Industry share is <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong>industry sales to total sales by all industries in each country. Entry US is <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> firms to total firms in <strong>the</strong> US, by 2-digit NACE rev. 1.1. Private<strong>equity</strong> measures actual <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> at <strong>the</strong> country level, normalized by GDP, and averaged over 1997-1999 (columns (i) and (iii)) and 1996-1999 (columns (ii) and (iv)). All regressions include a constant, 2-digit industry dummies and country dummies, not reported. White’s heteroskedasticitycorrected standard errors standard errors are reported in paren<strong>the</strong>ses. ***, **, and * report significance at <strong>the</strong> 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. SeeAppendix 1 for detailed variable definitions and sources.42 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


Table 7Alternative proxies for propensity to enterIndustry share(i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (iv) (vi)Fraction <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> firmsFirm exit rates, US SME entry rates, US Firm entry rates, UKAll firms Small firms All firms Small firms All firms Small firms-0.002 -0.018 -0.036 -0.003 0.004 0.022(0.119) (0.072) (0.118) -0.118 (0.119) -0.1180.018 0.029Exit US * Private <strong>equity</strong>(0.026) (0.017)*Entry by SMEs US *0.234 0.207Private <strong>equity</strong> (0.107)** (0.107)**Entry UK * Private <strong>equity</strong>0.271 0.086(0.106)*** (0.094)Observations 571 571 571 571 534 534R 2 0.60 0.61 0.60 0.55 0.60 0.67The reported estimates are <strong>from</strong> OLS regressions. The dependent variable is <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> firms to total firms (columns (i), (iii), and (v)) and <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong>firms with less than 10 employees to total firms (columns (ii), (iv), and (vi)), by 2-digit NACE rev. 1.1 and averaged for 1998-1999. Industry share is <strong>the</strong>ratio <strong>of</strong> industry sales to total sales by all industries in each country. Exit US is <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> firms that ceased to exist to total firms in <strong>the</strong> US. Entry bySMEs US measures entry rates by small or medium enterprises only (


Table 8Private <strong>equity</strong> and alternative proxies for financeIndustry share(i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) (vi) (vii) (viii)All firms Small firmsPrivate creditover GDPAccess t<strong>of</strong>inanceInvestors’protectionHorse race Private creditover GDPAccess t<strong>of</strong>inanceInvestors’protectionHorse race-0.015 -0.010 -0.003 -0.008 -0.022 -0.03 -0.022 -0.019(0.109) (0.108) (0.109) (0.108) (0.069) (0.068) (0.067) (0.068)Entry US * Private <strong>equity</strong> 0.232 0.207 0.237 0.217 0.317 0.295 0.131 0.169(0.093)*** (0.085)*** (0.100)** (0.128)* (0.059)*** (0.054)*** (0.065)** (0.082)**Entry US *0.583 0.195 0.375 0.072Private credit over GDP (0.333)* (0.409) (0.222)* (0.267)Entry US *0.028 0.029 0.014 0.545Access to finance (0.011)*** (0.012)** (0.006)* (0.795)Entry US *0.198 0.209 0.242 0.221Investors’ protection (0.118)* (0.126)* (0.078)*** (0.083)***Observations 571 571 571 571 571 571 571 571R 2 0.63 0.69 0.68 0.69 0.64 0.64 0.64 0.64The reported estimates are <strong>from</strong> OLS regressions. The dependent variable is <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> firms to total firms (columns (i)-(iv)) and <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> firms with lessthan 10 employees to total firms (columns (v)-(viii)), by 2-digit NACE rev. 1.1 and averaged for 1998-1999. Industry share is <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> industry sales tototal sales by all industries in each country. Entry US is <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> firms to total firms in <strong>the</strong> US, by 2-digit NACE rev. 1.1. Private credit over GDPmeasures <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> credit allocated by commercial banks to country total GDP. Access to finance measures general access to external finance byhouseholds and businesses. Investor’s protection measures <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> legal protection <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>investment</strong> in <strong>the</strong> country. All regressions include aconstant, 2-digit industry dummies and country dummies, not reported. White’s heteroskedasticity corrected standard errors standard errors are reported inparen<strong>the</strong>ses. ***, **, and * report significance at <strong>the</strong> 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. See Appendix 1 for detailed variable definitions and sources.44 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


Table 9Endogeneity and selection issuesIndustry shareEntry US * Private <strong>equity</strong>High legal efficiency *(i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) (vi) (vii) (viii) (ix) (x)All firms Small firms onlyPE lawsand fundsizeSmallindustriesonlyHigh-lowlegalefficiencyHigh-lowshadoweconomy PE lawsPE lawsand fundsizeSmallindustriesonlyHigh-lowlegalefficiencyHigh-lowshadoweconomyPE laws0.001 -0.019 0.328 -0.095 -0.017 -0.016 0.019 0.082 -0.031 -0.034(0.091) (0.097) (0.239) (0.092) (0.091) (0.053) (0.059) (0.157) (0.059) (0.065)0.253 0.242 0.276 0.234 0.293 0.264(0.144)* (0.121)** (0.120)** (0.143)* (0.135)** (0.126)**0.268 0.275Entry US * Private <strong>equity</strong> (0.121)** (0.122)**Low legal efficiency *-0.435 0.179Entry US * Private <strong>equity</strong> (0.472) (0.302)Low share shadow econ *0.278 0.262Entry US * Private <strong>equity</strong> (0.122)** (0.122)***High share shadow econ *0.283 0.174Entry US * Private <strong>equity</strong> (0.176) (0.127)Observations 571 571 515 438 443 571 571 515 438 443R 2 0.60 0.60 0.59 0.66 0.67 0.56 0.57 0.54 0.63 0.68The reported estimates are <strong>from</strong> an IV regression (columns (i)-(ii) and (vi)-(vii)) and <strong>from</strong> OLS regressions (columns (iii)-(v) and (viii)-(x)). The dependentvariable is <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> firms to total firms (columns (i)-(v)) and <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> firms with less than 10 employees to total firms (columns (vi)-(x)), by 2-digit NACE rev. 1.1 and averaged for 1998-1999. Private <strong>equity</strong> measures actual <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> at <strong>the</strong> country level, normalized by GDP. Private<strong>equity</strong> laws is a dummy equal to 1 if by 1998 pension funds were allower to invest in risk capital markets in <strong>the</strong> respective country. In columns (ii) and (vi), <strong>the</strong>dummy is interacted with <strong>the</strong> actual size <strong>of</strong> pension funds assets as share <strong>of</strong> GDP. Columns (iii) and (viii) perform <strong>the</strong> analysis on <strong>the</strong> sample <strong>of</strong> all industriesexcluding <strong>the</strong> top 10% in terms <strong>of</strong> share <strong>of</strong> sales. Industry share is <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> industry sales to total sales by all industries in each country. Entry US is <strong>the</strong> ratio<strong>of</strong> <strong>new</strong> firms to total firms in <strong>the</strong> US, by 2-digit NACE rev. 1.1. High(low) legal efficiencies are dummies equal to 1 if <strong>the</strong> country is in <strong>the</strong> top(bottom) 33% interms <strong>of</strong> legal efficiency, and to 0 o<strong>the</strong>rwise. High(low) share shadow economy are dummies equal to 1 if <strong>the</strong> country is in <strong>the</strong> top(bottom) 33% in terms <strong>of</strong>implied size <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> un<strong>of</strong>ficial economy, and to 0 o<strong>the</strong>rwise. All regressions include a constant, 2-digit industry dummies and country dummies, not reported.White’s heteroskedasticity corrected standard errors standard errors are reported in paren<strong>the</strong>ses. ***, **, and * report significance at <strong>the</strong> 1%, 5% and 10%level, respectively. See Appendix 1 for detailed variable definitions and sources.ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200945


Appendix 1. Variables: definitions and sourcesVariableDefinition and sourceEVCA dataPrivate <strong>equity</strong>Actual PE <strong>investment</strong> by European banks, mutual funds and PE houses, as well asby international PE investors with a European branch or partner, normalized byGDP; by country or European Venture Capital Association (EVCA) industryclassification. Source: EVCA yearbooksSeed and start-up finance Actual PE <strong>investment</strong> by European banks, mutual funds and PE houses, as well asby international PE investors with a European branch or partner, normalized byGDP, allocated to seed and start-up firms; by country. Source: EVCA yearbooksSeed,start-up & expansion Actual PE <strong>investment</strong> by European banks, mutual funds and PE houses, as well asby international PE investors with a European branch or partner, normalized byGDP, allocated to all <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> deals expect for buyouts; by country. Source:EVCA yearbooksIndependent PENon-independent PEPrivate <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> by independent PE funds, normalized by GDP, allocatedto all <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> deals; by country. Source: EVCA yearbooksPrivate <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> by captive, semi-captive and public PE funds,normalized by GDP, allocated to all <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> deals; by country. Source:EVCA yearbooksAmadeus dataEntryNumber <strong>of</strong> firms 2 years or younger as a fraction <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> total firms. Averaged for1998-1999 and 2006-2007. Used at <strong>the</strong> 2-digit NACE rev. 1.1 level andaggregated weighted by employment at <strong>the</strong> EVCA industry classification level.Source: AmadeusExit Number <strong>of</strong> exited firms as a fraction <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> total firms. Averaged for 1998-1999and 2006-2007. Used at <strong>the</strong> 2-digit NACE rev. 1.1 level and aggregated weightedby employment at <strong>the</strong> EVCA industry classification level. Source: AmadeusEntry by small firmsNumber <strong>of</strong> firms 2 years or younger with less than 10 employees as a fraction <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> total firms. Averaged for 1998-1999 and 2006-2007. Used at <strong>the</strong> 2-digit NACErev. 1.1 level and aggregated weighted by employment at <strong>the</strong> EVCA industryclassification level. Source: AmadeusIndustry share Fraction <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> industry’s sales in total sales. Averaged for 1998-1999 and 2006-2007. Used at <strong>the</strong> 2-digit NACE rev. 1.1 level and aggregated weighted byemployment at <strong>the</strong> EVCA industry classification level. Source: AmadeusUS benchmarkEntry USEntry rates for US corporations. Calculated for 2-digit NACE industries (originaldata on a 4-digit SIC level). Average for <strong>the</strong> years 1998-99. Source: Dun &Bradstreet.46 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


Exit USExit rates for US corporations. Calculated for 2-digit NACE industries (originaldata on a 4-digit SIC level). Average for <strong>the</strong> years 1998-99. Source: Dun &Bradstreet.Entry by SMEs US Entry rates for US corporations with less than 250 employees. Calculated for 2-digit NACE industries (original data on a 4-digit SIC level). Average for <strong>the</strong> years1998-99. Source: Dun & Bradstreet.Entry UKCapital intensityR&D intensityFinancial dependenceIndustry growthEntry rates for UK corporations. Calculated for 2-digit NACE industries (originaldata on a 4-digit SIC level). Average for <strong>the</strong> years 1998-99. Source: Dun &Bradstreet.Measure <strong>of</strong> physical capital usage, equal to <strong>the</strong> industry-level median <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> ratio<strong>of</strong> physical capital used to sales. The numerator and denominator are summed overall years for each firm before dividing. Computed for all U.S. firms for <strong>the</strong> period1990-99. Calculated for 2-digit NACE industries (original data on a 4-digit SIClevel). Source: Compustat.Measure <strong>of</strong> dependence on research and development, equal to <strong>the</strong> industry-levelmedian <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> R&D expenses to sales. The numerator and denominator aresummed over all years for each firm before dividing. Computed for all U.S. firmsfor <strong>the</strong> period 1990-99. Calculated for 2-digit NACE industries (original data on a4-digit SIC level). Source: Compustat.Industry-level median <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> ratio <strong>of</strong> capital expenditures minus cash flow overcapital expenditures. The numerator and denominator are summed over all yearsfor each firm before dividing. Cash flow is defined as <strong>the</strong> sum <strong>of</strong> funds <strong>from</strong>operations, decreases in inventories, decreases in receivables, and increases inpayables. Capital expenditures include net acquisitions <strong>of</strong> fixed assets. Thisdefinition follows Rajan and Zingales (1998). We compute this measure for allU.S. firms for <strong>the</strong> period 1990-99. Calculated for 2-digit NACE industries(original data on a 4-digit SIC level). Source: Compustat.Measure <strong>of</strong> industry growth, equal to <strong>the</strong> industry-level median <strong>of</strong> value added perworker. The numerator and denominator are summed over all years for each firmbefore dividing. Computed for all U.S. firms for <strong>the</strong> period 1990-99. Calculatedfor 2-digit NACE industries (original data on a 4-digit SIC level). Source:Compustat.Country-level variablesPrivate credit over GDPAccess to financeInvestors’ protectionRatio <strong>of</strong> domestic credit to <strong>the</strong> <strong>private</strong> sector scaled by GDP, average over <strong>the</strong>period 1995-99. Source: International Monetary Fund’s International FinancialStatistics (IMF-IFS).General index <strong>of</strong> access to external finance by households and businesses. Source:Finance for All? The World Bank, 2007.Index <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> protection <strong>of</strong> investors, calculated as an average <strong>of</strong> threeindices: transparency <strong>of</strong> transactions, liability for self-dealing, and shareholders’ability to sue <strong>of</strong>ficers and directors for misconduct; averaged over 1995-1999.Source: Doing Business Database (WB).ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200947


Share shadow economyShare <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> informal economy, calculated as <strong>the</strong> size <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> informal economy asa percentage <strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong>ficial GNI. Average over <strong>the</strong> period 1999-2000. Source: Ensteand Schneider (2000).Property rights protection Index <strong>of</strong> degree <strong>of</strong> protection <strong>of</strong> intellectual property rights. Source: Park andGinarte (1997).Entry proceduresNumber <strong>of</strong> procedures to register a business. Data for <strong>the</strong> year 1999. Source:Djankov et al. (2002).Labor regulations Index <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> legal ease <strong>of</strong> hiring and firing workers; averaged over 1995-1999.Source: Doing Business Database.Pr<strong>of</strong>it taxHuman capitalOutput gapPension funds sizeMeasure <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> marginal tax on pr<strong>of</strong>it. Source: PriceWaterHouseCoopersWorldwide Taxes 1999-2000).Average years <strong>of</strong> schooling for an individual in <strong>the</strong> respective country. Source:Barro and Lee “International Data on Educational Attainment” dataset.Difference between actual and potential GDP, averaged for 1998-1999 and2005/2006. Source: Econ stats online, http://www.econstats.com/weo/V027.htmAssets held by all pension funds in <strong>the</strong> respective country normalized by GDP andaveraged for 1998-1999. Source: Eurostat48 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009


European Central Bank Working Paper SeriesFor a complete list <strong>of</strong> Working Papers published by <strong>the</strong> ECB, please visit <strong>the</strong> ECB’s website(http://www.ecb.europa.eu).1049 “Labour force participation in <strong>the</strong> euro area: a cohort based analysis” by A. Balleer, R. Gómez-Salvadorand J. Turunen, May 2009.1050 “Wealth <strong>effects</strong> on consumption: <strong>evidence</strong> <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> euro area” by R. M. Sousa, May 2009.1051 “Are more data always better for factor analysis? Results for <strong>the</strong> euro area, <strong>the</strong> six largest euro area countriesand <strong>the</strong> UK” by G. Caggiano, G. Kapetanios and V. Labhard, May 2009.1052 “Bidding behaviour in <strong>the</strong> ECB’s main refinancing operations during <strong>the</strong> financial crisis” by J. Eisenschmidt,A. Hirsch and T. Linzert, May 2009.1053 “Inflation dynamics with labour market matching: assessing alternative specifications” by K. Christ<strong>of</strong>fel, J. Costain,G. de Walque, K. Kuester, T. Linzert, S. Millard and O. Pierrard, May 2009.1054 “Fiscal behaviour in <strong>the</strong> European Union: rules, fiscal decentralization and government indebtedness”by A. Afonso and S. Hauptmeier, May 2009.1055 “The impact <strong>of</strong> extreme wea<strong>the</strong>r events on budget balances and implications for fiscal policy” by E. M. Lisand C. Nickel, May 2009.1056 “The pricing <strong>of</strong> subprime mortgage risk in good times and bad: <strong>evidence</strong> <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> ABX.HE indices” by I. Fenderand M. Scheicher, May 2009.1057 “Euro area <strong>private</strong> consumption: Is <strong>the</strong>re a role for housing wealth <strong>effects</strong>?” by F. Skudelny, May 2009.1058 “National prices and wage setting in a currency union” by M. Sánchez, May 2009.1059 “Forecasting <strong>the</strong> world economy in <strong>the</strong> short-term” by A. Jakaitiene and S. Dées, June 2009.1060 “What explains global exchange rate movements during <strong>the</strong> financial crisis?” by M. Fratzscher, June 2009.1061 “The distribution <strong>of</strong> households consumption-expenditure budget shares” by M. Barigozzi, L. Alessi, M. Capassoand G. Fagiolo, June 2009.1062 “External shocks and international inflation linkages: a global VAR analysis” by A. Galesi and M. J. Lombardi,June 2009.1063 “Does <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong> spur innovation? Evidence <strong>from</strong> Europe” by A. Popov and P. Roosenboom,June 2009.1064 “Does it pay to have <strong>the</strong> euro? Italy’s politics and financial markets under <strong>the</strong> lira and <strong>the</strong> euro” by M. Fratzscherand L. Stracca, June 2009.1065 “Monetary policy and inflationary shocks under imperfect credibility” by M. Darracq Pariès and S. Moyen,June 2009.1066 “Universal banks and corporate control: <strong>evidence</strong> <strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong> global syndicated loan market” by M. A. Ferreiraand P. Matos, July 2009.1067 “The dynamic <strong>effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> shocks to wages and prices in <strong>the</strong> United States and <strong>the</strong> euro area” by R. Duarteand C. R. Marques, July 2009.ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 200949


1068 “Asset price misalignments and <strong>the</strong> role <strong>of</strong> money and credit” by D. Gerdesmeier, H.-E. Reimers and B. R<strong>of</strong>fia,July 2009.1069 “Housing finance and monetary policy” by A. Calza, T. Monacelli and L. Stracca, July 2009.1070 “Monetary policy committees: meetings and outcomes” by J. M. Berk and B. K. Bierut, July 2009.1071 “Booms and busts in housing markets: determinants and implications” by L. Agnello and L. Schuknecht, July 2009.1072 “How important are common factors in driving non-fuel commodity prices? A dynamic factor analysis”by I. Vansteenkiste, July 2009.1073 “Can non-linear <strong>real</strong> shocks explain <strong>the</strong> persistence <strong>of</strong> PPP exchange rate disequilibria?” by T. Peltonen, M. Sagerand A. Popescu, July 2009.1074 “Wages are flexible, aren’t <strong>the</strong>y? Evidence <strong>from</strong> monthly micro wage data” by P. Lünnemann and L. Wintr,July 2009.1075 “Bank risk and monetary policy” by Y. Altunbas, L. Gambacorta and D. Marqués-Ibáñez, July 2009.1076 “Optimal monetary policy in a <strong>new</strong> Keynesian model with habits in consumption” by C. Leith, I. Moldovanand R. Rossi, July 2009.1077 “The reception <strong>of</strong> public signals in financial markets – what if central bank communication becomes stale?”by M. Ehrmann and D. Sondermann, August 2009.1078 “<strong>On</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>real</strong> <strong>effects</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>private</strong> <strong>equity</strong> <strong>investment</strong>: <strong>evidence</strong> <strong>from</strong> <strong>new</strong> business creation” by A. Popovand P. Roosenboom, August 2009.50 ECBWorking Paper Series No 1078August 2009

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!